You are on page 1of 9

MOVIES, MASS CONSUMERS, AND CRITICS: ECONOMICS

AND POLITICS OF A TWO-SIDED MARKET

BRIAN GOFF, DENNIS WILSON and DAVID ZIMMER∗

Most analyses of the film market treat it as a single entity where producers make films
based on average consumer interest while critics serve as forecasters or signalers of film
quality to these consumers. We describe the film market as two-sided—a mass market
(average consumer) side and a high quality/artistic (cineaste) side—that each influence
film maker production decisions and critical reviews as critics balance the preferences
of mass market consumers and their own more artistic inclination. Using 1,824 films
released during 2000–2014, we examine determinants of box office revenues and critical
reviews, while addressing the overlap between them. Our results indicate that consumers
and critics respond differently not only to film rating but also to film budgets, story
sources, genre, and political content. We then use the dichotomy between average and
high quality, artistic film consumers as a basis for understanding the normative views
of the film markets relative to other two-sided markets as well as the political economy
of film regulation. (JEL C30, D10, Z11)

I. INTRODUCTION revenues, but critics received it favorably with


a 94% score on Rotten Tomatoes and eight
Like all market goods and services, con- Academy Award nominations.
sumers evaluate motion pictures and express Both market revenues and critical reviews
their views via expenditures. Within the motion have received attention from empirical
picture industry, professional film reviewers researchers in economics and marketing. DeVany
(critics) also evaluate films, and these reviews and Walls provide several contributions (1997,
are a prominent feature of the film market place. 1999, 2002, 2004), along with Eliashberg,
Sometimes the evaluations by these two groups Elberse, and Leenders (2006), Liu (2006), Elliott
agree, as in the case of Avatar, which boasted and Simmons (2008), Weinstein (1998), Swami,
an 83% reviewer rating on Rotten Tomatoes Eliashberg, and Weinberg (1999), Holbrook
and generated $750 million at the box office. (1999), and DeVany and Lee (2001).1 The
Sometimes common consumers and critics do influences of critics and critics’ influences on
not agree; critics panned Armageddon with a revenues have been investigated, but to a sig-
41% rating on Rotten Tomatoes while consumers nificantly lesser extent. Eliashberg and Shugan
spent a sizable $202 million. This outcome (1997) examine the role that critics play in
is reversed with a film such as Fargo, which influencing commercial box office performance.
generated only $24 million in U.S. box office Their findings suggest critical reviews are gen-
erally a useful forecasting tool for long-term
∗ The authors thank Tyler Cowen, Craig Depken, Art revenue success. However, they conclude crit-
DeVany, Bob Tollison, and participants in the WKU Eco- ical reviews are poor short-term indicators.
nomics Workshop for comments on earlier versions. Ginsburgh and Weyers (1999) find that consumer
Goff: Department of Economics, Gordon Ford College evaluations are more consistent over time than
of Business, Western Kentucky University, Bowling
Green, KY 42101. Phone 270-745-6401, Fax 270-745-
3190, E-mail brain.goff@wku.edu 1. Eliashberg (2005) and DeVany (2004) provide exten-
Wilson: Department of Economics, Gordon Ford College sive background to the film industry and literature about it.
of Business, Western Kentucky University, Bowling
Green, KY 42101. Phone 270-745-2632, Fax 270-745-
3190, E-mail dennis.wilson@wku.edu ABBREVIATION
Zimmer: Department of Economics, Gordon Ford College
of Business, Western Kentucky University, Bowling MLE: Maximum Likelihood
Green, KY 42101. Phone 270-745-6401, Fax 270-745-
3190, E-mail david.zimmer@wku.edu

doi:10.1111/coep.12180
Contemporary Economic Policy (ISSN 1465-7287) © 2016 Western Economic Association International
2 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

expert evaluations. Reinstein and Snyder (2005) demonstrate that consumers and critics respond
show a small impact of two well-known review- differently to certain film traits. In particular,
ers, Siskel and Ebert, on consumers which is critics respond favorably to films rated “R,” but
larger for dramas and films with a fairly limited rated-R films tend to perform worse at the box
screen release. These contributions treat critics office. Furthermore, while critics show an affinity
either as signalers to the general consumer mar- for documentaries and films with political slants,
ket with regard to film quality or as indicators documentaries and/or political content appear to
(forecasters) of market interest. However, there have no association with box office performance.
is an important question regarding the direction Critics show particular disdain for horror films,
of causality—do reviewers influence revenues but such movies do relatively well at the box
or do revenues, and forecasts of them, influence office. The results also indicate the complex
the reviews? Empirical studies typically have role of a film’s budget, with high-budget films
ignored the causality question altogether and enjoying box office success, but generally little
focused on either revenues or reviews using respect from critics.
reduced form models. Some regression estimates The two-sided nature of the market also
assume causality running from reviewers to provides a useful structure with which to under-
consumers and have conditioned film success stand the long-running political economy of
on critical reviews. These results, however, film regulation and censorship. Rather than
are difficult to interpret given that both rev- these long-running battles reflecting different
enues and reviewers are influenced not only by economic forces, we discuss how our approach
unmeasured film traits but also by unobserved helps to integrate the politics into the fundamen-
differences between consumers’ and critics’ tal economic structure of the market. We also
quality perceptions.2 discuss how the normative implications for two-
Underlying many of the previous theoretical sided markets are not appropriate benchmarks in
and empirical methods is the idea that movie mar- the case of artistic markets with two sides such
kets are single-dimensional, in that film makers as film markets.
target a specific consumer group with the goal of
maximizing profits. In contrast, we propose that
movie markets are divided into more than one II. TWO SIDES: MASS CONSUMERS
consumer group. One side of the market is the AND ARTISTIC, ELITE CONSUMERS
general movie going public, which represents the We propose that film markets can be viewed as
primary source of box office revenues. The other a specific, and in some ways unusual, example of
consumer group is the elite, artistic and movie a two-sided market. The literature on multi-sided
insider. The artistic side of the market has an markets, although somewhat in flux, identifies
objective not easily captured by box office suc- three basic conditions which define them3 : (1)
cess of a film. Thus, consumer-based revenues two (or more) sets of customers interact through
and critical reviews may reflect different sides of an intermediary (supplier); (2) some type of net-
the consumer market. While some characteristics work externality exists in that the decisions of
of movies may influence both parts of the mar- each set of customers affect the outcomes of the
ket in the same direction, other film characteris- other sets, often indirectly; (3) the externality is
tics may exert opposing influences on revenues not readily internalized by each customer set due
and reviewers. to high transaction costs of information.
Using a joint framework, which allows film The movie industry incorporates all three of
traits to have disparate impacts on different sides those conditions, albeit in previously unapplied
of the film market, this paper investigates dispar- ways. There are two groups of customers: a
ities between the mass market and artistic, elite mass market group and an artistic, elite group.4
consumer groups, treating box office revenues These two groups are served by and connected
as indicative of mass market appeal, and critical through an intermediary supplier, namely film
approval as indicative of success among the
high-end, artistic group. Our empirical results
3. Some of the key contributions that express and explain
these conditions include Evans (2003), Armstrong (2006),
2. Studies that have explored empirical strategies for Rochet and Tirole (2006), Rysman (2009), and Weyl (2010).
identifying the causal impact of reviews of box office perfor- The last is the more general in nature.
mance include Holbrook and Addis (2007), Hennig-Thurau, 4. The term “cineaste” is popularly used to describe indi-
Marchand, and Hiller (2012), and works cited therein. viduals in this high-end, artistic market.
GOFF, WILSON & ZIMMER: MOVIES, MASS CONSUMERS, AND CRITICS 3

producers. The mass market consumers com- markets has moved away from flagging some
monly prefer films with large budgets, broad markets as multi-sided and others as not. Rather,
family appeal, special effects, fast-paced action, recent research emphasizes the extent to which
strong comedic elements, and related charac- specific markets demonstrate the three charac-
teristics. The more artistic consumers generally teristics defined above (Weyl 2010). So while
prefer films with more character development, the ice cream industry may exhibit limited ele-
more complex story lines, timely or controver- ments of multi-sidedness, the automobile market,
sial subject matter or images, nuanced produc- with vast heterogeneity in styles and consumer
tion qualities, and related artistic characteristics. preferences, may show a much larger extent of
Film critics not only play an important role as multi-sidedness.
the primary representative for the more artistic The bulk of economic analysis of film mar-
side of the market but also share connections and kets has treated critics merely as signalers to
influences with the common consumer and the consumers or forecasters of consumer interest.
industry producers. Critics, in these frameworks, are exogenous to
Regarding the second requirement for multi- other participants and do not act as intermedi-
sided markets, the decisions of each group of aries. But recognizing that the movie industry
consumers influence the other group, usually shows some extent of two-sidedness, this paper
indirectly. Notably, while film critics share per- investigates disparities between the two con-
sonal preferences more consistent with those sumer groups, with box office revenues and
of artistic, elite consumers, those same critics critical success indicating success among the
also care about signals they send to the mass two consumer groups. Clearly some disparities
of consumers. Critics provide reviews that fol- between the two consumer groups must exist,
low artistic favor, but those reviews are often which, in turn, alters the incentives faced by
heard by the more common movie-going public. movie producers. For example, while financial
Similarly, film producers draw utility from both success clearly matters to Hollywood exec-
profits and acclaim from critics and artistic utives, film producers have utility functions
consumers. By contrast, film producers’ desire that also depend on critical acclaim and rep-
to satisfy one consumer group may sometimes utation. The attention and prestige given to
negatively affect the other group. For example, events that focus on the critical acclaim for
from a simple profit maximizing, multi-product movies, such as the Academy Awards, SAG
perspective, Hollywood systematically makes Awards, and Golden Globe Awards, further
too many R-rated movies.5 However, R-ratings, highlight its unique role and importance in
or at a minimum PG-13, is almost a necessity to this market.
receive critical acclaim and acknowledgement
from award presenting organizations.
Finally, regarding the third requirement for III. EMPIRICAL MODEL OF REVENUES
multi-sided markets, information regarding film AND REVIEWS
quality is “costly” in the sense that, regard-
less of the specific group to which a consumer The two-sided structure calls for an empirical
belongs, film quality can be, at best, only par- approach that treats the two sides as separate, but
tially observed prior to consuming the product potentially over-lapping, statistical processes. We
(i.e., viewing the film). And even after con- treat box office revenues as a close approximation
suming the product, information regarding film for mass market consumer valuation, and we view
quality can be, at best, only partially conveyed to critical reviews as the salient measure of success
other consumers, due to the subjective nature of on the artistic side of the market.
assessing artistic entertainment. Data are drawn from 1,824 U.S.-released
To be sure, any market with product films released between 2000 and 2014 that made
heterogeneity contains some elements of in excess of $1 million dollars and for which all
multi-sidedness (Rysman 2009). Initiated by data are available.6 We use a $1 million threshold
Spence (1975), the literature on multi-sided because films below that level generally have
limited releases, with consumers and reviewers
5. Sundarem and Williams (2005) show that G- and
PG-rated films between 2000 and 2003 generated return 6. The 2009 data are for part of the year. Box office,
on investment of 94 and 72% while R-rated films were rating, screenplay source, genre category, and release date are
at 28%. Revenue figures for films from 1989–2003 show from Internet Movie Database available at http://www.imdb.
similar differences. com/.
4 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

often unaware of their existence.7 Market rev- TABLE 1


enues are U.S. box office receipts, converted in Descriptive Statistics for Continuous Variables
2014 dollars using the Consumer Price Index.8 (Dollar Figures Are Converted to 2014 Dollars
Critical reviews are given by the Rotten Toma- Using the Consumer Price Index)
toes’ “Tomatometer,” which aggregates critical
Standard
reviews of “top critics” into a number on the Mean Deviation
0–100 scale. To qualify as a “top critic,” Rotten
Box office revenues (in million $) 63.8 85.2
Tomatoes requires that the critic be published in Budget (in million $) 51.6 53.7
an outlet ranking in the top 10% of circulation, Rotten Tomatoes top critics (0–100) 49.6 28.5
employed as a film critic at a national broadcast
outlet for at least 5 years, or be employed at an Note: Data for films released 2000–2014 that earned at
editorial-based website with at least 1.5 million least $1 million in revenue.
monthly unique visitors for at least 3 years.
Rotten Tomatoes also reports a “Tomatometer”
corresponding to “all” critics, regardless of TABLE 2
stature. When compared to “top” critics, “all” Frequency Distributions for Categorical
critics appeared to be slightly more inclined to Variables (N = 1,824 films)
like rated-R films and movies with political slants
and somewhat less likely to enjoy action films. Percent
Otherwise, results were very similar to those Rating
reported below, which focus on “top” critics. R-rating 41.1
PG-rating 14.4
In addition, we utilize data on rating, screen- Screenplay source
play source, genre, release season, and political Book 23.7
content. We include dummies for films rated R Original 53.1
Genre
and films rated PG. We include two screenplay Documentary 1.5
source categories: book and original. Genre is Horror 7.5
subdivided into five categories: documentary, Romantic 10.1
horror, romantic, action, and western. Release Action 20.8
Western 0.7
season equals one for films opening during the Politics
slow movie-goer months of January or February PFS nominated 3.5
and zero otherwise. We also include a dummy Release season
January/February 12.7
for December release. (Adding other month December 4.5
dummies did not substantially alter the main Star power
conclusions.) To provide an arms-length mea- Star actor and/or director 3.3
sure of political content, we construct a binary
variable that equals one for films receiving award Note: Data for films released 2000–2014 that earned at
least $1 million in revenue. PFS, Political Film Society.
nominations from the Political Film Society.9
Finally, we add a dummy for the presence of
a “star” actor and/or director (defined as Jack
Nicholson, Meryl Streep, Dustin Hoffman, Tom average film earned a score of approximately 50
Hanks, Clint Eastwood, Steven Spielberg, and/or from top critics. Table 2 displays the frequency
Oliver Stone). distributions for the categorical variables. R-rated
Table 1 displays descriptive statistics for box films account for a large percentage, 41%, of
office revenues (converted to 2014 dollars), all films, while PG-rated films account for
budget (converted to 2014 dollars), and critical only 14%. Original screenplays are much more
reviews. The average film grossed $64 million in common than books as sources. Within genres,
the U.S. with a budget of $52 million, while the action films are the most frequent type, while
only 3.5% of all films in our sample received
7. While $1 million may be an arbitrary cutoff, there are an award nomination from the Political Film
very limited “top critic” reviews for movies that gross under Society. Nearly 13% of the films were released
this limit and may lead to data consistency issues with their during the slow January/February season and
inclusion.
8. Movies also produce revenues through video/DVD
approximately 3.3% of films have “star” actors
sales and merchandising. and/or directors. Pairwise correlations among
9. These data are available at http://www.polfilms.com/ the explanatory variables did not point to any
previous.html. obvious collinearity problems.
GOFF, WILSON & ZIMMER: MOVIES, MASS CONSUMERS, AND CRITICS 5

TABLE 3
MLE Results
Reviews Log box office revenues
Coeff. St. Err. Coeff. St. Err.
Log (budget) −4.06** 0.60 0.74** 0.03
Rated R 6.87** 1.41 −0.28** 0.06
Rated PG 0.51 1.92 0.02 0.08
Book 6.77** 1.84 −0.09 0.08
Original −1.21 1.59 0.04 0.07
Documentary 10.08* 5.21 0.38* 0.22
Horror −19.65** 2.43 0.64** 0.10
Romantic −7.21** 2.12 0.02 0.09
Action −1.31 1.66 0.12* 0.07
Western −2.01 7.44 0.08 0.32
Politics 8.58** 3.45 −0.21 0.15
Star power 11.99** 3.58 0.39** 0.15
Jan/Feb release −13.05** 1.89 0.08 0.08
Dec release 3.97 3.04 0.01 0.13
Constant 118.78** 10.57 4.54** 0.45
σ (st. dev.) 26.55** 0.44 1.12** 0.02
ρ (correlation between unobservables) 0.21** 0.02

*p < .10; **p < .05.

Previous research, which has primarily and ϕ2 represents the density of the bivariate
focused on the impact of critics, has regressed normal distribution with correlation ρ. We find
box office performance on critical reviews the values of (β1 , β2 , ρ) that maximize the log
(Eliashberg and Shugan 1997; Elliott and Sim- likelihood function. (Using copula functions,
mons 2008). We avoid this approach for two we experimented with alternative distributional
reasons. First, we are not concerned with the forms, both for the joint and marginal processes,
impact of reviews on revenues, at least not to explore whether skewness in box-office per-
directly. Rather, we seek to determine which film formance impacted our main findings. Results
traits disparately affect critical reception and box from those alternative estimators, not presented
office performance. Second, we wish to account in this paper, showed results similar to those
for unmeasured (in our data) film-specific presented below.) This approach produces nearly
attributes that affect both critics and consumers. identical estimates compared to Zellner’s seem-
Such omitted variable issues would normally ingly unrelated regression model, but it allows a
introduce endogeneity bias into regressions of recoverable correlation term, even when reviews
revenues on reviews. and revenues are specified as functions of the
For these reasons, we require a model that same covariates. That correlation term is impor-
treats critics’ and consumers’ behaviors as joint, tant because, in results presented below, we seek
rather than conditional, processes. To that end, we to calculate joint and conditional probabilities of
estimate the joint distribution of critical reviews critical and financial success for certain kinds
and (logged) box office revenues by maximum of films.
likelihood (MLE), treating the joint distribu- Table 3 reports MLE estimates. The most
tion of reviews and revenues as bivariate nor- interesting results are those that produce dis-
mal. Letting yi1 and yi2 denote, respectively, parate effects on reviews and box office revenues.
film i’s critical review and (logged) box office Rated-R films seem more popular among critics
performance, the log likelihood function takes than with the movie-going public. Film critics
the form assign higher reviews to movies with R ratings;
∑ (( ) ( ) ) an R rating is found to boost a film’s “grade” by
ln ϕ2 yi1 − X′i β1 , yi2 − X′i β2 ; ρ 6.9 points on the 0–100 scale. On the other hand,
i
rated-R films earn approximately 28% less at
where Xi denotes a vector of observable movie the box office compared to nonrated–R movies.
traits, β1 and β2 include estimable coefficients, In contrast, critics show a particular distaste
6 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

for horror films, docking such films nearly 20


( )
points, but horror films are popular with movie Pr y2i > yM
2 |y1i > y1
goers, earning 64% more at the box office ( ( ) ( )
compared to their non-horror counterparts, all = 1 − Φ y1 |X′i ̂β1 − Φ yM ′̂
2 |Xi β2
else equal. ( ( ) ( ) ))
It is also noteworthy that certain movie +Φ2 Φ y1 |X′i ̂ β1 , Φ yM2 |X ′̂
i β2 ;̂
ρ
attributes appear to be important to film critics,
but not to the movie-going public. For example, ( ( ))
critics tend to give worse reviews to romance ∕ 1 − Φ y1 |X′i ̂β1
movies and to films released during the slow
January/February period. But neither of those The first two are marginal probabilities, while
attributes appears to significantly correlate with the third is a conditional. The term Φ2 rep-
box office performance. Additionally, critics resents the bivariate normal cumulative distri-
appear favorably inclined toward movies based bution function. Note that only the conditional
on books and politically slanted films, but probability explicitly incorporates the correlation
neither of those traits appears to affect box between unobservables. Using guidance from our
office performance. data, we set the average review y1 = 50 and the
Perhaps the most interesting result concerns a median revenue yM 2
= $38, 000, 000. The circum-
film’s budget. Higher-budget films tend to receive flex notation indicates the substitution of con-
less favorable critical reception, but budget pos- verged estimates.
itively correlates with box office performance. Table 4 presents these three probabilities for
Finally, the bottom row reveals a positive, and several types of movies. The first column reports
precisely estimated, correlation term, indicating estimates for an action movie, which, for pur-
that unmeasured traits that tend to garner higher poses of this discussion, we treat as the “base-
reviews also tend to correlate with better box line” film. The probability of an above-average
office performance. For example, perhaps the critical review is 0.44, while the probability of an
presence of a particular actor or director tends to above-median box office performance is 0.49. On
endear the film to both fans and critics. the other hand, given an above-average critical
response, the probability of above-median box
office performance increases to 0.57.
The next three columns modify certain traits of
IV. PROBABILITIES OF CRITICAL AND FINANCIAL
SUCCESS
the baseline movie. For example, if the baseline
movie has a “star” actor and/or director, the prob-
To distill the estimates into something more ability of a positive critical response increases to
intuitive, we calculate three probabilities based 0.62, and the probability of above-median box
on the MLE estimates: office performance increases to 0.63. The prob-
ability of financial success given critical success
• The probability that a movie will receive an
increases to 0.68. On the other hand, if the base-
above average review
line film is rated R, the probability of a posi-
( ) ( ) tive critical response increases by 0.10, while the
Pr y1i > y1 = 1 − Φ y1 |X′i ̂ β1 probability of above-median box office perfor-
mance decreases by 0.10. Similarly, the proba-
• The probability that a movie will earn bility of financial success given critical success
above-median revenues decreases by 0.12.
The next two columns show the effects of
( ) book-derived scripts and political slants. The
( ) ′̂
Pr y2i > yM directions and magnitudes are similar to the
2 = 1 − Φ y2 |Xi β2
M
effects of rated-R films; they boost critical
response while hindering box office perfor-
where yM denotes the sample median of revenues.
2 mance. The final column shows estimates for
The notation Φ represents the cumulative distri-
rated-R horror films, a category often lambasted
bution function of the normal distribution.
by critics. Indeed, such films are only 0.28 likely
• The probability that a movie will earn to garner positive reviews. However, rated-R hor-
above-median revenues, given that it receives an ror films are 0.58 likely to enjoy above-median
above-average critical review financial success. Moreover, the rare horror film
GOFF, WILSON & ZIMMER: MOVIES, MASS CONSUMERS, AND CRITICS 7

TABLE 4
Predicted Probabilities of Above-Average Reviews and Above-Median Revenues for Movies with
Various Traits
Predicted probabilities of critical and financial success for movies with
various traits
Probability of above-average review 0.44 0.62 0.54 0.54 0.57 0.28
Probability of above-median revenues 0.49 0.63 0.39 0.46 0.42 0.58
Probability of above-median revenues 0.57 0.68 0.45 0.52 0.47 0.67
given above-average review
Movie traits
Original action • • • • •
Star power •
Original horror •
Rated R • •
Based on book •
Political slant •

Note: All movies in this table have median budgets and are not released in January, February, or December.

that enjoys critical praise faces a 0.67 chance of increments.11 The ineffectual enforcement cou-
above-median financial success. pled with growing social and political criticism
It should be noted that we interpret conditional of artistic censorship prompted the industry to
probabilities in Table 4 as measures of statisti- develop the MPAA ratings system in 1968. The
cal association rather than causality. The nonlin- expanding boundaries for PG films and further
ear functional forms of the MLE setup, to some public criticism led to revisions, including the
extent, serve as a source of identification. But we introduction of the PG-13 rating in the 1980s and
prefer not to rely on this argument as a substi- the NC-17 rating in the 1990s. During the Reagan
tute for more substantive identification strategies. administration, the “Moral Majority” became
Nevertheless, even when interpreted through the an outspoken group against sexual and profane
lens of statistical association, the estimates, con- content in films. Several religious groups, includ-
sistent with implications of our theoretic frame- ing Catholic priests and fundamentalist groups,
work, highlight the disparate influencers of movie mounted campaigns against the 1988 film The
consumers and critics. Last Temptation of Christ.12
Those ongoing political and social conflicts
are typically posed as a rent-seeking battle
V. PUBLIC POLICY IMPLICATIONS between social conservatives and Hollywood
film producers. But while the rent-seeking label
The motion picture industry has a long his- may be useful, it is also superficial in that it fails
torical interaction with social norms and public to address why film producers would steer the
policy, and the multi-sided market structure pro- ratio of films toward a relatively high percentage
vides a useful lens with which to make sense of of R-rated films relative to large money G and
past and current social and regulatory debates. In PG films. Budget size and risk may matter, but
the 1930s, the film industry imposed the Motion why not G and PG films with smaller budgets?
Picture Production Code, or “Hays Code,” that This confusion dissipates to some extent when
restricted content in films. Although it reflected the market is viewed as having two consumer
self-regulation by the industry rather than public groups—mass market and artistic, elite—with
regulation, the Code emerged after a decade film producers seeking to satisfy both sides of
or more of public pressure, as evidenced by
the introduction of film censorship bills in a
majority of states.10 Enforcement of the Code 11. See Joseph Burstyn, Inc. v. Wilson, 343 U.S. 495
(1952).
eroded in the 1950s and 1960s as film makers
12. It should be noted that objections to film content
pushed at its boundaries in a series of small are not all from religious or political conservatives. Feminist
opposition arose to Dressed to Kill while gays and lesbians
criticized Basic Instinct. A detailed history of sources of
10. Black (1996), Jeff and Simmons (2001), and Wittern- criticism to film and pressure for regulation is provided in
Keller (2008) provide historical details to this era. Lyons (1997).
8 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

the market. Spence (1975) provides a seminal drawing a distinction between marginal and aver-
model of producer decisions where both price and age consumers. This distinction also generates
quality are endogenously chosen. At the center an influential normative policy benchmark; if the
of Spence’s model is a distinction between aver- marginal consumer’s utility function is identical
age consumers and marginal consumers in which to the average consumer, the quality decisions of
producers base decisions on the response of the private, unregulated producers over small qual-
marginal consumer, but social welfare is driven ity changes match the social optimum. Other-
by the average consumer. Where the marginal wise, a divergence of the value of quality for
consumer values a small change in quality more the marginal and average consumer provides a
than the average consumer, producers will over- rationale for regulation. Based on this social wel-
supply quality. fare approach, there are too many “high qual-
Applying this insight to film markets provides ity/artistic” R-rated films produced for marginal
a straightforward explanation of the observed film consumers and professional critics.13 Social
lobbying for and against particular kinds of con- welfare could be increased with public policy
tent, as well as the relative supply of the two that forced film makers to produce more films
kinds of films. Artistic, elite film consumers are “for the masses” through some kind of regula-
the marginal consumers while the mass mar- tory mechanism.
ket consumers—those driving large box office Yet, in this regard, movie markets along
revenues—are the average consumers. Those with other artistic markets provide an interest-
average consumers desire more G- and PG-rated ing study in public choice both at large and
films, while marginal consumers attempt to pro- among economists. Ironically, while a regulation
tect artistic freedom and R-rated films. rationale because of over- or under-supply of
In this political struggle, critics often take on quality relative to a social optimum might be
the role of agents and advocates for the artistic, applied by some social critics to purchases of
elite consumers, expressing outrage at “censor- high quality items such as granite countertops or
ship.” This follows our two-sided perspective high-end appliances, few of these critics advo-
in that critics share the preferences of artistic cate stronger “quality” regulation with regard to
consumers. However, critics must balance these artistic endeavors. Instead, in artistic settings,
preferences against the risk of alienating mass quality regulation takes a pejorative connotation
market readers of their reviews. Likewise, film of “censorship” and “homogeneity.” Yet, through
producers sometimes act as agents for the artistic, the marginal-average normative lens, much of
elite consumers, but they are conflicted in that the specialized production in art could be viewed
they also care about profits. As a result, they strike as welfare diminishing from society’s viewpoint.
a balance between making more artistic films and By the time of Spence’s piece, the social wel-
trying to find ways to placate the mass market. fare conclusions and the premises behind regu-
lation based on average consumer welfare had
already been called into question through a vari-
VI. CONCLUSION
ety of widely cited sources. A common theme
The preceding analysis and discussion has in those contributions is the diminished weight
centered on three main points. First, film markets placed on the average consumer or agent. Apply-
can be viewed as having a two-sided structure ing that theme to our topic, films (or other artis-
with mass market consumers and artistic, elite tic endeavors) need not appeal to large masses in
consumers. Second, the two-sided nature causes order to increase social welfare.
valuation by mass consumers as reflected in box
office revenues to diverge from valuation by crit- REFERENCES
ics as reflected in their reviews. It also causes film
makers to under-produce films with mass mar- Armstrong, M. “Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” RAND
Journal of Economics, 37, 2006, 668–91.
ket appeal such as G- and PG-rated films. Third, Black, G. D. Hollywood Censored: Morality Codes,
the two-sided structure also explains the political Catholics, and the Movies. Cambridge: Cambridge
and social conflict over film regulation and con- University Press, 1996.
DeVany, A. Hollywood Economics: How Extreme Uncer-
tent in which artistic consumers, abetted by film tainty Shapes the Film Industry. London: Routledge,
makers and critics, stand on opposite sides with 2004.
advocates for more “family friendly” films.
The positive analysis of two-sided markets 13. Weyl (2010) explains how that under some condi-
extends back to Spence’s (1975) contribution, tions, there can be under-provision of quality.
GOFF, WILSON & ZIMMER: MOVIES, MASS CONSUMERS, AND CRITICS 9

DeVany, A., and C. Lee. “Quality Signals in Information Cas- Holbrook, M. “Popular Appeal versus Expert Judgments of
cades and the Dynamics of the Distribution of Motion Motion Pictures.” Journal of Consumer Research, 26,
Picture Box Office Revenues.” Journal of Economic 1999, 144–55.
Dynamics and Control, 25, 2001, 593–614. Holbrook, M., and M. Addis. “Taste Versus the Market: An
DeVany, A., and W. D. Walls. “Motion Picture Profit, the Sta- Extension of Research on the Consumption of Popular
ble Paretian Hypothesis, and the Curse of the Superstar.” Culture.” Journal of Consumer Research, 34, 2007,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28, 2004, 415–24.
1035–57. Jeff, L. L., and J. L. Simmons. The Dame in the Kimono:
. “Does Hollywood Make Too Many R-Rated Movies? Hollywood, Censorship, and the Production Code. Lex-
Risk, Stochastic Dominance, and the Illusion of Expec- ington: University Press of Kentucky, 2001.
tation.” Journal of Business, 75, 2002, 425–51. Liu, Y. “Word of Mouth for Movies: Its Dynamics and Impact
. “Uncertainty in the Movie Industry: Does Star Power on Box Office Revenues.” Journal of Marketing, 70,
Reduce the Terror of the Box Office?” Journal of Cul- 2006, 74–89.
tural Economics, 23, 1999, 285–318. Lyons, C. The New Censors: Movies and the Culture Wars.
. “The Market for Motion Pictures: Rank, Rev- Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press, 1997.
enue, and Survival.” Economic Inquiry, 35, 1997, Reinstein, D. A., and C. M. Snyder. “The Influence of Expert
783–97. Reviews on Consumer Demand for Experience Goods:
Eliashberg, J. “The Film Exhibition Business: Critical Issues, A Case Study of Movie Critics.” Journal of Industrial
Practice, and Research,” in A Concise Handbook of Economics, 53, 2005, 27–51.
Movie Industry Economics, edited by C. Moul. New Rochet, J. C., and J. Tirole. “Two-Sided Markets: A Progress
York: Cambridge University Press, 2005, 138–62. Report.” RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 2006,
Eliashberg, J., and S. Shugan. “Film Critics: Influencers or 645–7.
Predictors?” Journal of Marketing, 61, 1997, 68–78. Rysman, M. “Economics of Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of
Eliashberg, J., A. Elberse, and M. A. A. M. Leenders. “The Economic Perspectives, 25, 2009, 125–43.
Motion Picture Industry: Critical Issues in Practice, Cur- Spence, A. “Monopoly, Quality, and Regulation.” Bell Jour-
rent Research, and New Recent Directions.” Marketing nal of Economics, 6, 1975, 417–29.
Science, 25, 2006, 638–61. Sundarem, S., and H. J. Williams. Profitability Study of
Elliott, C., and R. Simmons. “Determinants of UK Box Office MPAA-Rated Movies. Grand Rapids, MI: The Dove
Success: The Impact of Quality Signals.” Review of Foundation, 2005.
Industrial Organization, 33, 2008, 93–111. Swami, S., J. Eliashberg, and C. B. Weinberg. “Silver
Evans, D. S. “The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Screener: A Modeling Approach to Movie Screens
Markets.” Yale Journal on Regulation, 20, 2003, Management.” Marketing Science, 18, 1999, 352–72.
325–81. Weinstein, M. “Profit-sharing Contracts in Hollywood: Evo-
Ginsburgh, V., and S. Weyers. “On the Perceived Quality lution and Analysis.” Journal of Legal Studies, 27, 1998,
of Movies.” Journal of Cultural Economics, 23, 1999, 67–112.
269–283. Weyl, E. G. “A Price Theory of Multi-Sided Platforms.”
Hennig-Thurau, T., A. Marchand, and B. Hiller. “The Rela- American Economic Review, 100, 2010, 1642–72.
tionship between Reviewer Judgments and Motion Pic- Wittern-Keller, L. Freedom of the Screen: Legal Challenges
ture Success: Re-Analysis and Extension.” Journal of to State Film Censorship, 1915–1981. Lexington:
Cultural Economics, 36, 2012, 249–83. University Press of Kentucky, 2008.

You might also like