You are on page 1of 7

Marketing as Production:

The Development of a Concept

Donald F. Dixon
Penn State Great Valley

The conventional view of marketing as somehow adding The definition of marketing in terms of types of value or
to the work of manufacturing is rooted in the concept of utility generated has been criticized in the marketing litera-
production as the creation of material attributes. A view of ture. Alderson argues that "It is a highly arbitrary procedure
marketing as an integral part of a productive process to divide the utility to the consumer into two parts and to say
generating "bundles of utilities" has a long history in that one part is created by production and the other by mar-
economic analysis. This approach offers several advantages keting" (1957, p. 68). In referring to the distinction drawn
for marketing thought. between form and other aspects of utility, Alderson remarks:
"There is only one kind of utility--namely the value which
a product contributes to the potency of an assortment... All
economic activities create a single form of utility" (1957,
p. 198).
INTRODUCTION Beckman also argues against any distinction between mar-
keting and manufacturing: "The best current economic think-
In economic theory production is "The process of increas- ing" is that "values are created through the addition of
ing the capacity of goods to satisfy human desires or of utilities, which are capacities in goods or services to satisfy
rendering services capable of satisfying human desires" human wants." Moreover:
(Sloan and Zurcher 1970, p. 348). Marketing activity falls
within this definition. However, the way that marketing It is now generally recognized among economists
textbooks have differentiated marketing from other produc- and other students of the subject that the creation
tive activity has created theoretical difficulties. For example, of these utilities spells the creation of economic
a generation of marketing students have been told that values and that this is the essence of production.
"Stated simply, the job of manufacturing is to create form This means that whoever creates these utilities is
utility, while marketing's job is to provide time, place, and engaged in production, so that a wholesaler or a
possession utility" (McCarthy 1981, p. 5). retailer who normally creates place, time, and pos-
Cox identifies a significant problem arising from this session utilities is as much a producer as is a proces-
approach: sor who changes a product from one form to another
(1957, p. 8).
By a long-established convention, what manufactur-
ers and farmers do results in "production," or "value Beckman concludes that "It is high time that we all get in
added." What "distributors" do is more likely to be line with sound economic thinking and stop the silly argu-
counted as a "margin," a "bill," or simply a "cost." ment" about who is engaged in production and who is not
The bias inherent in this usage undoubtedly makes (1957, p. 9).
much more difficult a disinterested evaluation of Although Beckman's conclusion is similar to Alderson's,
what marketing is and does (Cox 1965, p. 26). the conceptual foundations underlying the two discussions
are different; each writer uses a different concept of value.
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science
Beckman is arguing in terms of value-in-exchange, basing
Volume 18, Number 4, pages 337-343. his calculation of value added upon "the selling value" of
Copyright 9 1990 by Academy of Marketing Science. products ( 1957, p. 7). On the other hand, Alderson is reason-
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved. ing in terms of value-in-use. Because the exchange transac-
ISSN 0092-0703. tion increases the utility of the assortment held, "It creates

JAMS 337 FALL, 1990


MARKETING AS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENT OF A CONCEPT

value in the sense that there is greater value in use after the of his labor9 And this "changing for the better" can occur
exchange" (1957, p. 198). Clearly Atderson's concept of in several ways:
utility as "increasing the potency of an assortment" differs
from Beckman's "selling value." Either because he has bettered the thing, or because
The failure to recognize different meanings of "value" the value of the thing has changed with the change
leads to conflicting interpretations of economic theory. In of place, or time, or on account of the dangers he
McCarthy, the distinction between marketing and other pro- incurs in transferring the item from one place to
ductive activities lies in "what economists believe" (McCar- another, or again in having it carried by another
thy 1981, p. 665), while "the best current economic think- (13th c., 77.4).
ing" leads Beckman to consider such a distinction to be
By the close of the Middle Ages the Schoolmen understood
"silly9 Such confusion also leads to a misunderstanding of
the influence of economic theory upon the analysis of mar- that value arises from the creation of form, time and place
utility, and risk bearing. The analytical similarity between
keting as a productive process9 Barrels asserts that "In 1900
the contribution to a product's usefulness made by merchants
there was no clear concept of marketing as a productive
activity or as a contribution to economic production" (1962, and other economic agents was generally acknowledged.
p. 16). This situation is said to have obtained because A Seventeenth Century secular work written by Nicholas
"economists" were mainly concerned with "value in tangible Barbon (d. 1698), who Schumpeter considers "one of the
goods created in the process of physical production." Con- top half dozen English seventeenth century economists"
sequently, "New concepts of value were required after 1900" (1954, p. 294), gives the impression that the contribution
(1962, p. 15). The inference seems to be that marketing of marketing activities is so obvious that it does not require
writers in the United States developed these new concepts9 elaboration: "The Value of all Wares arises from their Use.
This paper demonstrates that there was a clear concept 9 Use of Things are to supply the Wants and Neces-
of marketing as a productive process at the turn of the sities of Man." Two types of wants are identified, those of
century. The discussion traces two streams in the develop- the body and of the mind. The wants of the mind are infinite:
ment of value and utility theory in the literature of "Man naturally Aspires, and as his Mind is elevated, his
economics9 Value as usefulness or utility, underlying Alder- Senses grow more refined, and more capable of Delight;
son's work, is examined first, and then the focus shifts to his Desires are inlarged, and his Wants increase with his
exchange value, that underlies Beckman's position. Finally, Wishes."
the treatment of marketing in the context of utility by some What is the role of marketing in this process? Barbon
early marketing writers are examined. states simply that "The Use of Trade is to make, and provide
things Necessary, or useful for the Support, Defence, Ease,
Pleasure, and Pomp of Life." In the event that this statement
is not sufficiently clear, many participants in the productive
USE VALUE process are listed, among whom appear various types of
manufacturers and retailers (Barbon 1690, p. 21).
Aristotle distinguishes between use value or utility, and In the following century the concept of subjective utility
exchange value (4th c. B.C., I, iii, 10). However, it is the was carried to its logical conclusion by Ferdinando Galiani
Medieval Schoolmen who give utility its primacy of position (1728-1787), the Italian economist who Schumpeter consid-
in economic analysis, arguing that the origin of economic ers "one of the ablest minds that ever became active" in
value lies in the needs of consumers. St. Augustine (d. 604), economics (1954, p. 292). Galiani asserts that "It is certain
the first archbishop of Canterbury, holds that the price of that nothing has a price among men except pleasure, and
marketable goods depends upon their usefulness or utility that only satisfactions are purchased" (1751, p. 304). This
to men (5th c9 709149 view makes it possible to develop the precise mechanism
The originator of the concept of subjective utility is the by which marketing activities create use value.
Franciscan, Pierre de Jean Olivi (1248-1298), who asserts An early effort to accomplish this is found in the work
that one aspect of the value of a commodity is "according of Etienne B. de Condillac (1715-1780), the noted French
to how it is more or less pleasing to our will to have it in philosopher and associate of Rousseau9 The discussion be-
our possession," and "In this way one person considers a gins with the statement that the value of goods is based
commodity, which appears inferior to another, very much upon the use made of them, and this is based upon men's
to be appreciated." Thus value will vary "within some suit- needs9 Two types of needs are identified: those that are "a
able range, with respect to times, places and persons" (13th consequence of our makeup," such as food, and those "born
c., f. 295c). out of our practice of choosing to satisfy our natural needs
And the times and places that influence value are recog- by particular methods9 It is especially interesting that social
nized as contributions made by marketing activity9 St. needs, which "are a consequence of civilized societies," are
Thomas Aquinas (c. 1225-1275), the best known of the as "natural" as the need for food, for example (1776, p. 6).
Schoolmen, confirms that "The price of saleable things The demonstration of the significance of marketing ac-
. . . depends upon the usefulness to man" (13th c., 779 tivities begins in the chapter titled "How Commerce In-
This "usefulness" created by altering commodities, gener- creases the Stock of Wealth":
ates income; if a man "sells at a higher price something that We have seen that commerce, which consists of the
he has changed for the better, he would receive the reward exchange of one thing for another, is carried on

JAMS 338 FALL, 1990


MARKETINGAS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENTOF A CONCEPT

principally by merchants, trafficers and wholesalers. textbook dominated English economics in the early
We now try to understand the utility which society nineteenth century, states:
derives from all these men who have established
themselves between producers and consumers. It is plain that the capital and labour employed in
carrying commodities from where they are produced
to where they are to be consumed, and in dividing
There are two steps in the argument. First, the transaction
them into minute proportions, so as to suit the wants
itself creates wealth. Each party gains something that they
of consumers, are really as productive as if they
prefer to that given in exchange.
were employed in agriculture or manufacturing . . . .
This idea that the transaction itself creates value is not
We do not owe our fires exclusively to the miner, or
often stated explicitly, but it survived until the end of the
exclusively to the coal-merchant. They are the result
nineteenth century. Henry George (1839-1897), the Ameri-
of the conjoined operations of both (l 825, p. 177).
can economist noted for his view that land values represented
monopoly power and should bear the entire tax burden, Toward the end of the century the argument was cast in
argues: more modern terms. A work coauthored by John Hobson
(1858-1940), "an archeretic in the heyday of Marshallian
In itself exchange brings about a perceptible increase supremacy" (Schumpeter 1954, p. 832), held that "logically,
in the sum of wealth . . . . Each of the two parties to and in the last resort... 'utilities and conveniences' are non-
an exchange aims to get, and as a rule does get, material; that is to say, they consist of the 'services' rendered
something that is more valuable to him than what by instruments" (Mummery and Hobson 1889, p. 16).
he gives . . . . Thus there is in the transaction an actual Moreover, these writers carry the analysis through an entire
increase in the sum of wealth, an actual production marketing channel. The process of producing a pair of shoes
of wealth (1898, p. 33 1). is traced from the animal providing the hide to the ultimate
consumer, to show that raw material gathers value continu-
Besides the direct creation of value by the completion of ously "by change of form or change of place."
a transaction, marketing activity also makes an indirect con- The modem form of this line of reasoning was introduced
tribution. It makes it possible for transactions to take place: by the Austrian School. W. Stanley Jevons (1835-1882),
"Exchange gives value to the abundance of production, "one of the most genuinely original economists who ever
which without exchange would not have any value." lived" (Schumpeter 1954, p. 826), is considered a member
Specialists must conduct this exchange because "it would of the Austrian School despite his English birth because he
be uneconomic for the producer to go to the market rather independently discovered concepts associated with the
than remaining at work in his fields." The contribution of School. Jevons holds that value depends entirely upon util-
marketers is shown by analogy: ity. "The keystone of the whole Theory of Exchange" is the
concept of marginal utility (1871, p. 95). He notes that one
limitation of this proposition is that quantities are not infi-
A spring that disappears in the rocks and sand is
nitely divisible: "There is always, in retail trade, a conve-
not wealth for me; but it becomes wealth if I build
nient unit below which we do not descend in purchases.
an aqueduct to carry it to my fields. This spring
Paper may be bought inquires, or even in packets, which it
represents the surplus production of the farmers,
may not be desirable to break up" (1871, p. 125). A corollary
and the aqueduct represents the merchants.
is that marketing activity, which enables purchasers to match
more closely the size of the unit purchased to the amount
In conclusion, "exchange is also, in the last analysis, a required, results in exchange being more perfectly adjusted.
source of wealth" (1776, p. 50). From his general proposition Jevons derives a result that
This result is accepted by J.B. Say (1769-1832), the counters the "fallacious tendency to believe that the whole
French economist whose treatise offered the first popular benefit of trade depends upon the difference in prices" ( 1871,
treatment of economic principles. However, Say objects to p. 142). That is, "he who pays a high price must have a
Condillac's argument that the contribution of marketing is great need of that which he buys, or very little need of that
indirect: "The value added by commerce to the things ex- which he pays for it; on either supposition there is gain by
changed is not operated by the act of exchange, but by the exchange." The rule is that "no one will buy a thing unless
commercial operations that precede it." The activities of he expects advantage from the purchase" (1871, p. 145).
marketing create utility directly, and in a manner that is no Karl Menger (1840-1921), the founder of the Austrian
different than other types of productive activities. Transport, School, develops a similar argument in his chapter on "The
for example, increases value because a good is more useful Theory of Exchange." Two individuals are seen adjusting
in one place than another: "Transportation is a modification their assortments of goods by exchange, and thereby increas-
that the trader gives to the commodity, whereby he adapts ing their joint utility. In his concluding paragraph Menger
to our use what was not before available." All branches of clearly states that the work of marketing contributes to the
industry increase value in this manner, that is, by the "ap- well-being of individuals in the same way as other productive
proximation to the customer.., by fitting them [resources] activities:
for the use of mankind" (1803, Vol. I, p. 9).
Other nineteenth century writers did little more than repeat An economic exchange contributes, as we have
Say's argument. John R. McCulloch (1789-1864), whose seen, to the better satisfaction of human n e e d s . . .

JAMS 339 FALL, 1990


MARKETING AS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENT OF A CONCEPT

just as effectively as a physical increase of economic tion, which further increases economic efficiency.
goods. All persons who mediate exchange are there- Robert Torrens (1780-1864), English soldier and
fore--provided always that the exchange operations economist, sees marketing as the transport and exchange of
are economic--just as productive as the farmer or "articles of wealth" acquired from other sectors of the
manufacturer. For the end of economy is not the economy. The first marketing activity, transport, makes a
physical augmentation of goods, but always the ful- direct contribution to wealth: "Many articles which possess
lest satisfaction of human needs (1871, p. 190). utility in one place, do not possess it in another place; and
therefore, the industry which conveys such articles is instru-
Thus, during the nineteenth century writers in Austria, En- mental in conferring utility" (1821, p. 153). To this extent,
gland, and France, offered a clear conception of the produc- Torrens agrees with the utility approach and departs from
tive contribution of marketing to the usefulness of com- Smith's position.
modities. Moreover, these writers unequivocally demonstrate The second marketing activity, exchange, which has "an
that there is no analytical distinction between the contribu- indirect operation in the formation of riches," is divided
tion of marketing and other types of productive activity. into two parts. First, it makes possible the division of labor:
"The divisions of employment to which the exchange of
commodities gives occasion, augment, to an astonishing
EXCHANGE VALUE degree, the productive power of human industry." The sec-
ond role of exchange is to make a continuous market by
A parallel stream of thought, focusing upon exchange setting up warehouses and shops for the "collection and
value rather than use value, can be traced to Adam Smith vending of commodities." As a result, each producer,
(1723-1790). Although Smith is aware of use value, as "knowing where he can at all times be supplied.., is ena-
"expressing the utility of some particular object" (1776, p. bled to devote his whole time and labor to his proper calling."
28), he devotes his attention to exchange value. Wealth In short, exchange gives "a more continued and uninter-
consists of tangible goods, not the use made of them. rupted motion to the cultivator and the manufacturer" (1821,
But even in the context of exchange value, Smith shows p. 177).
that merchants are productive, just as manufacturers are, The position taken by Torrens is equivocal at best. No
because their labor "fixes and realizes itself in some particu- conceptual scheme is introduced to Justify a different treat-
lar object or vendible commodity, which lasts for some time ment of the two types of marketing activity. If utility is
at least after that labor is past" (1776, p. 314). produced by movement in space, why is there not a similar
Additional arguments also are presented. Where Smith effect from movement in time? Alternatively, there is a
speaks of retail activity as breaking and dividing goods into spatial aspect to exchange activity since it involves "setting
small parcels, he argues that this enables the workman who up warehouses and shops." Why then is it that transport
purchases from the retailer to reduce inventory costs. As a does not also contribute to the division of labor?
result the workman can earn a greater profit, which more Such analytical inconsistencies were resolved as an under-
than compensates for the higher price he pays. The standing of the direct contribution of marketing to exchange
wholesaler also makes a contribution, by affording a ready value emerged during the remainder of the nineteenth cen-
market to the manufacturer, by taking his goods off his tury. The foundation of this subsequent work was provided
hands as fast as he can make them, and by sometimes even by James Mill (1773-1836), Scottish philosopher and
advancing funds. Thus the manufacturer may produce "a economist, and father of John Stuart Mill. Mill's Elements
much greater quantity of goods than if he was obliged to of Political Economy is unique in its organization into four
dispose of them himself to the immediate consumers, or chapters: Production, Distribution, Interchange, and Con-
even to the retailers" (1776, p. 342). sumption. This is the first time that the treatment of ex-
Here, as in Condillac's analysis, the contribution of mar- change, Mill's "interchange," is identified as a separate
keting is indirect. But in Smith's scheme the nature of this topic, and it established the pattern for the next generation
indirect contribution has immense significance, because it of writers. This pattern focused attention upon marketing
has to do with the division of labor. The division of labor activities because it was necessary to assign them to one of
plays a dominant role in The Wealth of Nations because it the categories in the quadripartite arrangement. Various writ-
leads to increased output. There are two ways in which ers argued for the placement of marketing into one or another
marketing activity contributes to the division of labor. First, of the categories, but agreement was finally reached that
if a workman must perform marketing activities rather than marketing activity was part of the production process.
doing his own work, then the potential gains from his The relevant discussion Mill's Elements consists of little
specialization cannot be enjoyed. In addition, since the more than the argument that "The agency of man can be
marketer is also a specialist, this means that the work of traced to very simple elements. He does nothing but produce
marketing is carried out at the lowest possible price. motion. He can move things toward one another, and he
The second way in which marketing makes a contribution can separate them from one another" (1821, p. 5). This
arises because the extent to which specialization is possible brief statement is of the utmost significance, for it removes
depends upon the amount of work to be done. That is, "The completely the possibility of any conceptual distinction be-
division of labor is limited by the extent of the market." By tween the work of marketing and that of any other productive
lowering costs and prices, marketing activity increases mar- activity. Indeed, it leads to the same conclusion as the utility,
ket size. Increased market size leads to increased specializa- or use value approach.

JAMS 340 FALL, 1990


MARKETINGAS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENTOF A CONCEPT

John Stuart Mill (1806-1873), the classical economist of the earth. Yet they are both properly called pro-
whose textbook dominated English economics for two gen- ducers. What do they produce? Simply quantities
erations, restated the argument of the Elements: of utility. And how do they produce quantities of
utility? Simply by putting things in their proper
Putting things into fit places for being acted upon places. Man can only move things, and when he
by their own internal forces, and by those residing moves them in a suitable manner he creates utilities
in other natural objects, is all that man does, or can (1889, p. 143).
do, with matter. He only moves one thing to or from
another... He has no other means of acting on mat- Thus, although the Classical writers emphasized exchange
ter than moving it. value, it was seen that production resulted not in the creation,
but modification of matter, so that there could be no analyti-
This proposition inevitably brought J.S. Mill to accept Say's cal distinction drawn between marketing and other produc-
view of the significance of utility: tive activities. This point is restated by Alfred Marshall
(1842-1924), whose Principles was the most influential
All the labour of all the human beings in the world economics textbook in the late nineteenth and early twentieth
could not produce one particle of matter . . . . Though centuries:
we cannot create matter, we can cause it to assume
properties, by which, from having been useless to Man cannot create material things... He really only
us, it becomes useful. What we produce, or desire produces utilities; or in other words, his efforts and
to produce, is always, as M. Say rightly terms it, sacrifices result in changing the form or arrangement
an utility. Labour is not creative of objects but of of matter to adapt it better for the satisfaction of
utilities (1848, p. 24). wants . . . . It is sometimes said that traders do not
produce; that while the cabinet-maker produces fur-
Yet even John Stuart Mill is trapped by the weight of trad- niture, the furniture dealer merely sells what is al-
ition. Despite his recognition of utility, he argues that the ready produced. But there is no scientific foundation
term "production" must refer not to utility but wealth. And for this distinction. They both produce utilities, and
wealth can be created only by utilities "fixed or embodied neither of them can do more (1890, p. 63).
in any object." Marketing activity adds properties to objects:
"It adds the property of being in the place where they are
wanted, instead of being in some other place; which is a DEVELOPMENTS IN THE
very useful property, and the utility it confers is embodied EARLY TWENTIETH CENTURY
in the things themselves" (1848, p. 47).
This definition of production as adding properties to mat- American economics textbooks published in the early
ter was widely accepted by later writers. But, although the twentieth century, and thus contemporary with some early
process of production was a unitary one, it nevertheless was U.S. marketing literature, continued to present the argu-
subdivided according to the types of "properties" added to ments that had developed in the nineteenth century. For
matter. For example, Henry Sidgwick (1838-1900), English example, Irving Fisher (1867-1947) postulates two attri-
philosopher and economist, offers a tripartite arrangement butes of wealth, "materiality" and "ownership." He then
of agriculture, manufacturing, and commerce distinguished divides the process of production into three categories. The
by "the nature of the utility produced" (1883, p. 91). first two of these, "transformation," which changes form,
The American economist Francis A. Walker (1840- and "transportation," which changes position, are viewed
1897), identifies time, place, and form value, "in respect as so closely related that the distinction is "merely one of
of their origin," but denies any analytical distinction between convenience" (1910, p. 80). Both include marketing ac-
form and other aspects of utility. Walker emphasizes that tivities. The third category of production is "exchange,"
the creation of value does not imply any change in form: which alters ownership. Fisher's contribution to marketing
"However little the material may be wrought, and by what- theory is his demonstration of the unity of the production
ever agencies that little may be effected, we may say that process by including marketing activity in each of this three
wealth is produced whenever value is added or acquired categories of production.
through any act or process" (1888, p. 33). John Bates Clark (1847-1938), classifying labor "accord-
Another list of values, offered in a textbook by Richard ing to the particular result which it accomplishes," refers to
T. Ely (1854-1943), American economist, includes elemen- various types of utility. His discussion of form utility,
tary, form, place, and time value. Marketing produces time explicitly includes marketing activity:
and place value by adding properties to goods, "namely the
property of being in the right place and of being there at A form utility is created when a raw material is
the right time" (1889, p. 177). But the connection with fashioned into a new shape, subdivided, or com-
utility is made explicit, so that marketing is productive in bined with other materials, as is done in manufactur-
the same sense as other branches of industry: ing, and, in a certain way, in commerce. Buying
goods in bulk and selling them in small quantities
Man creates no new matter. Neither the farmer nor is the creating of form utilities and makes an addition
the merchant adds one atom to the existing material to total wealth.

JAMS 341 FALL, 1990


MARKETING AS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENT OF A CONCEPT

After offering two examples of this, Clark concludes that output suggests the starting point. A market offering must
"Merchants are not mere exchangers, for they make positive be perceived as meeting the needs of a purchaser. That is,
additions to the utility of goods" (1907, p. 17). the purpose of marketing activity is to supply output "Neces-
These examples have a common theme, but perhaps the sary, or useful for the Support, Defence, Ease, Pleasure,
best generalization is that of Frank Taussig (1859-1940), and Pomp of Life" (Barbon 1690). Emphasis must be placed
who states that economic theory "is often brought to unity on the concept of "useful," since "only satisfactions are
and consistency by the analysis of production as ending in purchased" (Galiani 1751).
utilities" and adds that "no conclusions of importance for Usefulness is increased by the "approximation to the cus-
economics flows from the distinction between those who tomer" (Say 1803). When this process results in a market
shape material wealth and those who bring about utilities transaction, usefulness is increased directly, because each
of other kinds" (1911, p. 17). party gains more than is given up in exchange (Condillac
Some early marketing writers in the U.SI were familiar 1776; George 1898; Jevons 1871). Most of the sources re-
with contemporary economic theory, and incorporated the viewed held that usefulness is indirectly increased by ac-
analysis of production in their textbooks. Ralph Starr Butler, tivities such as breaking and dividing, transport, storage,
for example, begins his discussion by defining a producer and "nonmaterial" elements, such as information.
as "one who creates utility," and notes that "The definition Marketing systems also contribute to usefulness by reduc-
says nothing about the kind of utility created." Reference ing the cost of its production. When markets are expanded,
is made to Ely's work to justify the position that "A producer specialization increases, so that costs fall. The Classical
is one who creates any kind of utility." It is concluded that School also understood that the emergence of specialized
the middleman is a producer (1923, p. 22). marketing organizations reduce cost by reducing uncertainty;
Ralph Breyer reaches the same conclusion in the following that is, it gives "a more continued and undisturbed motion"
decade. Specific citations are no longer provided; Breyer (Torrens 1821).
simply reviews "a few fundamentals of economics." The Alderson called for "a marketing interpretation of the
reader is informed that "the economist.., defines 'produc- whole process of creating utility" (1957, p. 69). The ele-
tion' as the creation of utilities, and 'utility' as the capacity ments of such an interpretation were available early in the
to satisfy a want." From a description of marketing functions Twentieth Century. The task of responding to Alderson's
it becomes clear that marketing creates all types of utilities, challenge remains.
and "It is evident, then, that marketing is a productive activ-
ity" (1934, p. 13).
The stream of economic thought, as well as the work of
some early marketing writers in the U.S. provides a justifi- REFERENCES
cation for Alderson's rejection of the notion that different
aspects of utility can be attributed to production and market- Alderson, Wroe. 1957. Marketing Behavior and Executive Action.
ing (1957, p. 68). But Alderson seems unaware of his pre- Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.
Aquinas, Sancti Thomae. 13th c. Summa Theologica. Parmae: Petri Fiac-
cursors. First, he views his position as unique, commenting cadori [1855].
that "It may appear to stretch the meaning of marketing to Aristotle. 4th c. B.C. Politics. H. Rackman, tr. London: Win. Heinemann
imply that it is concerned with changes in form utility" [1959].
(1965, p. 27). Moreover, he has difficulty in reconciling Augustini, Sancti. 5th c. Enarratio in Psalmum. Migne: Patrologiae
his argument with the "conventional view," for he admits Latinae.
Barbon, Nicholas. 1690. A Discourse of Trade. Baltimore: The John Hop-
that "The choice of methods for changing the form is indeed kins Press [1903].
within the realm of production technology." Ultimately, he Bartels, Robert. 1962. The Development of Marketing Thought.
is forced into an indirect justification of his position: "The Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.
decision to change the form at all is explicitly or implicitly Beckman, Theodore N. 1957. "The Value Added Concept As A Measure-
ment of Output." Advanced Management (April): 6-9.
a marketing decision" (1965, p. 27).
Breyer, Ralph F. 1934. The Marketing Institution. New York: McGraw-
Hill.
Butler, Ralph Starr. 1923. Marketing and Merchandising. New York:
IMPLICATIONS FOR MARKETING THEORY Alexander Hamilton Institute.
Clark, John Bates. 1907. Essentials of Economic Theory. New York: The
Macmillan Company [1924].
The "conventional view" of marketing as adding proper- Condillac, Etienne B. de. 1776. Le Commerce et le Gouvernement. Paris:
ties to matter, caused a problem for Alderson and "makes Lecointe et Durey [1821].
more difficult a disinterested evaluation of what marketing Cox, Reavis. 1965. Distribution in a High-Level Economy. Englewood
is and does" (Cox 1965). This view also underlies the dis- Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
satisfaction with marketing theory that led to the services Ely, Richard T. 1889. An Introduction to Political Economy. New York:
The Chautauqua Press.
marketing literature. If marketing is the process that adds Fisher, Irving. 1910. Elementary Principles of Economics. New York: The
properties to matter, then it cannot contribute to the produc- Macmillan Company.
tion of "immaterial" goods. These problems do not arise Galiani, Ferdinando. 1751. Della Moneta. In: Early Economic Thought.
once the contribution of the two streams of thought examined Arthur E. Monroe, ed. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
George, Henry. 1898. The Science of Political Economy. New York:
above are recognized. Schalekenbach Foundation [1941].
Since marketing has to do with satisfying needs, the em- Jevons, W. Stanley. 1871. The Theory of Political Economy. New York:
phasis of the Schoolmen and other early writers on system Kelley and Millman [1957].

JAMS 342 FALL, 1990


MARKETING AS PRODUCTION: DIXON
THE DEVELOPMENT OF A CONCEPT

McCarthy, E. Jerome, 1981. Basic Marketing. Homewood, IL: Richard Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth
D. Irwin. of Nations. New York: Modern Library [1937].
McCulloch, John R. 1825. Principles of Political Economy. Edinburgh: Taussig, Frank. 1911. Principles of Economics. New York: The Macmillan
Adam and Charles Black [1844]. Company.
Marsh all, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. New York: The Macmil- Torrens, Robert. 1821. An Essay on the Production of Wealth. New York:
lan Company [1920]. Augustus M. Kelley [1965].
Menger, Carl. 1871. Principles of Economics. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press Walker, Francis A. 1888. Political Economy. New York: Henry Holt.
[1950].
Mill, James. 1821. Elements of Political Economy. London: Henry G.
Bohn [ 1844].
Mill, John Stuart. 1848. Principles of Political Economy. London: ABOUT THE AUTHOR
Longmans Green [ 1871 ].
Mummery, A.F., and J.A. Hobson. 1889. The Physiology of Industry.
New York: Kelley and Millman [1956]. Donald F. Dixon is a Professor of Marketing in the Graduate
Olivi, Pierre de Jean. 13th c. Quaestiones de permutatione rerum, de Management Program at Penn State Great Valley, near
emptionibus et venditionibus. Manuscript.
Say, Jean Baptiste. 1803. Le Traite d'economie politique. Boston: Wells Philadelphia. He received a B.A. in economics from Brown
and Lilly [1821]. University (1951), and M.B.A. in marketing from Wharton
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: (1952), and a Ph.D. in economics from the London School
Oxford University Press.
Shaw, Arch. 1915. Some Problems in Market Distribution. Cambridge: of Economics (1961). His area of specialization is market-
Harvard University Press. ing. He has published articles in economics, buyer behavior,
Sidgwick, Henry. 1883. The Principles of Political Economy. London: channels of distribution, marketing theory, multinational
Macmillan and Company [1887].
Sloan, Harold S., and Arnold J. Zurcher. 1970. Dictionary of Economics. marketing, and the history of marketing thought, and (with
New York: Barnes & Noble. I.F. Wilkinson) a textbook, The Marketing System.

JAMS 343 FALL, 1990

You might also like