You are on page 1of 5

Introduction to Game Theory and Its Application in Electric Power Markets

for nonzero-sum games was first formu- oner’s dilemma. In the original version of
HARRY SlNGH lated by John Nash, and the Nash equi- the game, there are two players, A and B,
librium is now a universally used who can either cooperate with each
solution concept. other and refuse to provide evidence or
Game theory is a discipline that is used Noncooperative games can be they can defect and implicate the other
to analyze problems of conflict among described using two kinds for formats. player. A concise representation of this
interacting decision makers. It may The first format is the normal or strate game was provided by Aumann. Each
be considered as a generalization of
decision theory to include multiple
players or decision makers.
The concepts used in game the-
ory can be traced back to the work
of Cournot, Bertrand, and v a n
Stackelberg. However, it was not
until 1928 that van Neumann pub-
lished the general theory for solv-
ing zero-sum games. The general
theory for solving zero sum games
became more widely known in 1944
with the work of von Neumann and
Morgenstern. Many of the impor-
tant developments in the field took
place during the period from 1950
t o 1960. The best known among
these is the concept of Nash equi-
librium. Game theory gained addi-
tional prominence as a subject in
1994, when the Nobel prize for eco-
nomics was awarded jointly to John
Harsanyi, John Nash, and Rienhard
Selten for their contributions to the
analysis of equilibria in noncooper-
ative games.
Game theory can be classified
into two areas: cooperative and non-
cooperative. This tutorial provides a gic form, and the second is the exten- player A and B must announce to a refer-
quick introduction to noncooperative sive form. In the sfrutegic form,one deals ee “Give me $1,000” or “Give the other
game theory using applications in elec- with a set of players, a set of choices or player $3,000.” The money under either
tric power markets. strategies available to the players, and a strategy comes from a third party. The
set of payoffs corresponding to these cooperate strategy for each player is to
Noncooperative strategies. The payoff for a given player give the other player $3,000, while the
Game Theory depends not only on the strategy cho- defect strategy is to take $1,000,The pay-
Noncooperative games can be zero-sum sen by that player but also on the strate offs for A and B can be represented as
games or nonzero-sum games. In zero- gies chosen by t h e o t h e r players. shown in Figure 1.
sum games, t h e gains of one player Additionally, it is assumed that the rules The Nash equilibrium in this game
equal the losses of the other player. of the game, the strategies available to involves each player choosing t h e
The solution of zero-sum games was the players, and the payoffs are com- defect strategy even though this is not
first formulated by von Neumann and mon knowledge. Each player is assumed the strategy that maximizes the payoff
Morgenstern. In nonzeromm games, the to act rationally to maximize its profit. for a player. The payoffs for both play-
gains of one player d o not equal the Perhaps the best known problem in e r s can be increased if they both
losses of the other player. The solution noncooperative game theory is the pris- choose the cooperate strategy. Howev-

18 IEEE Computer Applications in Power


strategy j , their payoffs o r Noncooperative games a r e t h e

I Payoff ($) 1 Player B


Cooperate, Defect I gains are represented by a,,
and b,, respectively. A mixed
strategy for player I is a vec-
tor x whose i-th component
foundation for some of the standard
models in oligopoly. The study of oli-
gopoly models is essential to study
market power.
represents the probability of
choosing p u r e strategy i. Cournot Duopoly
Thus x , 2 0 and Z x , = 1. A A Cournot model involves a duopoly
mixed strategy for player I1 is game in which two firms produce an
Figure 1. Prisoner’s dilemma defined analogously. If x and y identical product and must decide how
are a pair of mixed strategies much to produce without knowing the
er, this is not a stable outcome as each for players I and II, their expected gains output decision of the other. For conve-
player h a s a n incentive t o defect are x’Ay and x’By, respectively. A pair of nience, assume that each firm’s cost is
regardless of what the other player mixed strategies (x*, y‘) is said to be a 0. Assume that xI and x, represent the
chooses. A Nash equilibrium exists if, Nash equilibrium if output decisions of each firm. The mar-
for a given set of strategies chosen by ket price is represented by p(x,+x,),
other players, each player’s strategy is (x*)’Ay* t YAY* V x t 0, Z X =~1 where p ( x ) is t h e inverse demand
an optimal response to those strategies. curve. The profits or payoffs for each
Thus, at a Nash equilibrium, a player’s and firm are 1,= p(x, t x,)x? The strategy of
payoff decreases if it changes its strate- each firm is to choose xi in order to
gy assuming all other players’ strategies (x*)’By* 2 (x*)’By V y t 0, Cyi = 1. maximize its profit without knowing the
remain the same. decision of the other firm.
Finite nonzero-sum games are also In other words, (x*,y*) is a Nash equi-
called bimatrix games, given the nota- librium if neither player can gain by uni- Bertrand Duopoly
tion used to represent the payoffs in the laterally changing its strategy. Under a Bertrand model, each firm must
game. A bimatrix game T(A, B) consists A particularly interesting special choose the price at which it is willing to
of two players, each of whom has a case of a Nash equilibrium is a Nash produce. Ignoring bounds on output,
finite number of actions called pure equilibrium in pure strategies, i.e., one we can assume that the lower priced
strategies. When player I chooses pure in which the probability of choosing a firm will capture market share and that
strategy i and player II chooses pure particular strategy is 1 for each player. both firms will have equal outputs at

lllEUROSTAG
Software for the simulation of power system dynamics

A continuous display of both fast and slow phenomena


Accurate simulat

Automatic inte

avenue Ariane 7 , av du GCn6ral de Gaulle


B- I200 Brussels (Belgium) -92 I 4 I Clamart (France)
Tel +32 2 773 79 41 Tei +33 I 47 65 56 00
Fax +32 2 773 88 90 Fax +33 I 47 65 46 88
E-mail eurostag@edf.fr

Product Info - www.ieee.o~magazines/DirectAceess


ma. If both players cooperate, the strike price, and the buyer pays

-
they c a n both charge t h e the seller if the pool price falls below
monopoly price. However, the strike price. A one-way CfD is simi-
each player has an incentive to lar to a financial option contract and
reduce its price slightly and also includes an option fee in addition
capture market s h a r e , even to the strike price and contract quan-
though it knows that both play- tity. Under a one way contract, differ-
ers will be worse off i f they ence payments are made only if the
both cut price. pool p r i c e rises a b o v e t h e s t r i k e
Difference
Payments
price, as shown in Figure 3.
Market Power T h e effect of a CfD is t o fix o r
Mitigation bourid the revenue for a generator. In
Ygiire 2. Payment streams in a CfD Market power can be defined the extreme, where the entire output
as the ability of a market par- of a generator is contracted under a
ticipant to raise prices above CfD, the generator's revenue will be
t h e competitive level by completely insulated from market
$IMWtl price variations, and, consequently,
A two-way restricting output or restrict-
ing new entrants. Horizontal the generator should have no incen-
Strike market power is often associ- tive to raise prices. Ideally, one would
Price ated with a single firm or a few like to contract just the appropriate
firms controlling a large part of fraction of output required to mitigate
the supply. market power.
Hours Although generation divesti- To illustrate how CfDs can elimi-
A: Seller pays buyer, B: Buyer pays seller nate incentives to raise prices, we will
ture has been used as a reme-
d y for t h i s problem in t h e set up a simple Cournot model with
Figure 3. Two-way CID electric power industry, it is two generators (A and B) and one
not always a viable option. In load, as shown in Figure 5. Each of the
such instances, financial con- generators has an incremental cost of
tracts s u c h as contracts for $lO/MWh and a maximum output of
differences (CfD) can be used 75 MW. The strategic decision for the
to accomplish what might be generators is to choose a level of out-
termed as virtual divestiture. put that maximizes their profits. The
Game theory can be used to price is s e t by t h e demand curve,

I
I
study t h e effects of CfDs on which is also shown in Figure 5. We

,
Hours
bidding incentives. The pur- will a s s u m e t h a t e a c h g e n e r a t o r
Figure 4. One-way CfD pose of a CfD is to insulate the chooses between two levels of output,
supplier against the temporal a high output of 75 MW and a low out-
II I price variations in the market. put of 20 MW, as shown in Figure 6.

I A$lO/MWh
The low output may be interpreted as

..l--T-
0 - 75 MW

45
40
ference between
the contract Output(MW) 1 Generator B
Hiah I Low - -

1
pricc ai111 t l i e -- A's output
--c-tt .
prc-vuili iig iiiiir- High
0-150MW 50 100 150 MWh 75 9 s output
B $lO/MWh krt or pool A
0-75MW 20 ' 20 A'soutput
price, as clrpict- LOW
c d i i i Figure 2. 75 20 9 s outpu1
Figure 5. A two generation game A Cil) call be ~. - . .
either twc-way or Figure 6 Output decisions of A and B
equal price. If x@) represents the mar- one-way. A two-
ket demand function, the payoff or prof- way CfD is similar to a
Generator B
it of firm 1 can be represented as financial futures contract Price ($/MWh)
and is defined in terms of High ILow

i.
PAP,) if PI <P2 a strike price ($/MWh),
%(PIA)= P I ~ ( P I )if~ ~ p I = p 2 (1) and a quantity (MWh). As
if PI > P I shown in Figure 2, for the
defined quantity, the sell-
A Bertrand game has a structure er pays the buyer if the
similar to that of the prisoner's dilem- pool price rises above Figure 7. Prices corresponding to output decisions

20 IEEE Computer Applications in Power


for IEEE Computer Applications in Power
EEE Computer Applications in The articles are published with- consultants to tell of unique appli-

I Power is a quarterly magazine


sponsored by the IEEE Power
Engineering Society and
tlet1ic:;itetl to the eicctri-
out discussion or closure, but they
receive peer review from the maga-
cations of computers t o improve
system operation and performance,
and working. QrouDs . . within
thc, trchnicnl socielirs t o
cai powvr i n d u s t r y . I t s tlisscwiiiatc- thcir informa-
focus is 0 1 1 the ai)pIica- tioii to a wid? reiitlcrsliii)
tion of digital d e v i c e s before finalizing conclu-
and associated software s i o n s in p a p e r s o r s t a n -
for power s y s t e m plan- Information for Authors of dards. Articles should be
ning, construction, opera- Technlcal Papers, Articles and about 5,000 words, includ-
tion, maintenance, a n d ing For Further reading,
control Biographies, t a b l e s , a n d
We welcome articles g r a p h i c s . A preliminary
t h a t would not involve copy should b e sent to
the technical details that S.H Horowitz, E-mail
would appeal only to experts within zine's editorial board and selected s.horowitzQ ieee.org or FAX (614)
a specific discipline but would be advisors. T h e articles provide a 777-8057, with followup discussion
of interest t o t h e general power platform for manufacturers and uni- b y E-mail o r p h o n e , (614) 876
engineering community, academe, versity researchers to describe on- 0802, on applicability and submis-
and students. going developments, utilities and sion schedules.

Unbalanced & Balanced Power Flow


*Harmonic Power Flow
Power Quality Analysis (motor starting,

* Short Circuit Analysis


Arbitrary Complex Fault
Network Frequency Scan

Unbalanced & YBalancedCoadFlow


' Short Circuit Analysis

- Overcurrent Protection Coordination


Line Sag &Tension Analysis
* Quick Analysis Programs

- (Fault, Voltage Drop,Motor Flicker Analysi:


Transformer EconomicsISizing
Conductor EconomicsISizing
* EMF Prolile for OIH & UIG Systems
Line & Cable Constants proqrams

(604) 467-8715 Fax: (604) 467-2687


Internet e-mail : powersiOistar.ca
Website : httd/home.istar.ca//-Dowersil

Product Info - www.ieee.org/magazines/DirectAccess Product Info - www.ieee.org/magazines/DireetAeceas


Equity arguments call strained Unit Commitment; Market Power
for solutions that allocate Evaluation in Power Systems with Conges-
Generator B c o s t s t o coalitions in a tion; Market Power Mitigation; Some
Profit ($) manner that guarantees Things Experiments Reveal About Market
that all coalition members Power Opportunities Offered by a Con-
are at least as well off as strained Transmission System; The Best
Generator 2250 B s Drofit
Game in Town: NERC's TLR Rules; and
they would be if they were
A's profit not a part of the coalition. Hacking with Megawatts: Gaming via Gov-
B s profit This is sometimes called ernor Control in a Competitive Generation
the stand-alone test. Solu- Environment.
tions that exactly allocate
Figure 8. Profits without CfD the total costs and satisfy For Further Reading
withholding of capacity with a motiva- the stand-alone test, are Game Theory Applications in Electric Power
tion t o increase prices. If prices called core solutions. Alternative solu- Market.s, IEEE tutorial,99TP-136. 1999.
increase sufficiently, the generator can tion concepts such a s t h e Shapley R. Aumann, "Game Theory," in The New
make a higher profit at the low output. Value are also possible. Palgrave, eds. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, P.
Newman. McMillan.
London, 1987.
D. Fudenberg, J.
Tirole, Game Theo-
ry, The MIT Press,
Cambridge, 1991.
D. Fudenberg,

1 1
D.K. Levine, "The

I A Low
I550
2475 I
-500
-500 BsprofitI
A's profit
II A Low
650
2575
1700
1700 1
As profit
B's profit
Theory of Learning
i n Games," T h e
MIT Press, Cam-
-I
figure 9.Profits with CfD for 30 MW
bridge, 1998.
i p r e 10. Profits with CfD for 10 MW
D.A. Kreps. Game
There are four possible cases to The emphasis in cooperative game Theory and Economic Modeling, Clarendon
consider, depending on the decision theory is on solutions that are equi- Press, Oxford, 1990.
of each generator. The prices corre- table. In contrast, noncooperative H.R.Varian, Microeconomic Analysis,
sponding to these cases are shown in game theory helps us study efficient W.W. Norton and Co., New York, third edi-
Figure 7. Figure 8 shows a Nash equi- solutions under new market designs. tion, 1992.
librium for the case when both gener- Just as we study the stability of an J . von Neumann, 0. Morgenstern,
ators choose low levels of output to engineering system, we can s t u d y Theory o f Games and Economic Behavior,
maximize their profits. However, if a how efficient a market design might Princeton University Press, Princeton
CfD is applied to 30 MW of the genera- be by using game theory. NJ, 1944.
t o r s output, t h e Nash equilibrium The examples in this article were H.P. Young, "Cost Allocation," in Hand-
changes, as shown in Figure 9. The highly simplified. There a r e many book o f Come Theory with Economic Appli-
strike price in the CfD is assumed to other problems that deal with t h e cations, volume 2 , eds. R. Aumann, S. Hart,
equal t h e competitive price of behavior of market participants in North Holland, Elsevier. Amsterdam, 1994.
$40/MWh. In this case, profits a r e transmission networks under con-
maximized at the competitive price gestion that the reader will find of Biography
corresponding to the high output by interest. Harry Singh is manager of Electricity Eco-
each generator. Similarly, Figure 10 nomics at PG&E Energy Services (PG&E
shows the profits if a CfD is applied to Acknowledgment Energy Services is not the same company as
10 MW of the output. This tutorial is based on excerpts from the Pacific Gas and Electric Company, the utility
Game Theory Applications in Electric Power PG&E Energy Services is not regulated by
Cooperative Game Theory Markeb tutorial, which was prepared for the California Public Utilities Commission,
Cooperative game theory, which is presentation at the 1999 IEEE PES Winter and you do not have to buy PG&E Energy
quite different from noncooperative Meeting. The 103-page multiauthor tutori- Services' products in order to continue to
game theory, is generally applied to al book (99TP-136) can be ordered receive qualip regulated services from Pacif-
solve allocation problems. The vari- through IEEE Customer Service. Chapters ic Gas and Electric Company.) Prior to join-
ous solutions proposed for coopera- include: Introduction; Analyzing Strategic ing PG&E Energy Services, he worked with
tive games can b e i n t e r p r e t e d a s Bidding Behavior in Transmission Net- the Pacific Gas and Electric Company in
alternative solutions to an allocation works; Using Game Theory to Study Mar- San Francisco, where he was a part of the
problem. The key ideas involve the ket Power in Simple Networks; Bidding team responsible for setting up the Califor-
concept of coalitions or groups that Strategies for Lagrangian Relaxation Based nia IS0 and PX. He received a PhD in elec-
are formed to benefit from economies Power Auctions; Risk Management Using trical engineering from the University of
of scale. Game Theory in Transmission Con- Wisconsin at Madison.

22 IEEE ComputerApplications in Power

You might also like