You are on page 1of 13

Environmental Science and Pollution Research (2020) 27:2760–2772

https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-019-07158-8

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Urban concentration, non-renewable energy consumption,


and output: do levels of economic development matter?
Rafael Alvarado 1 & Cristian Ortiz 1,2 & Diana Bravo 3 & José Chamba 1

Received: 8 August 2019 / Accepted: 21 November 2019 / Published online: 13 December 2019
# Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2019

Abstract
The accelerated urbanization process generates a significant increase in energy, whose sources are mainly polluting. The harmful
effects of both processes are reflected in climate change. This article examines the equilibrium and causality relationship among
urban concentration, non-renewable energy consumption, and the real per capita output in 110 countries during 1971–2017.
Using data from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (2018), we classify countries into four groups according to
their level of development. Our evidence suggests that urban concentration has a negative effect on real per capita output in high-
income countries, while non-renewable energy consumption has a positive effect on all groups of countries. The cointegration
tests show that there is short- and long-term equilibrium in all groups of countries. The results of the DOLS and PDOLS models
indicate that the strength of the cointegration vector is weak in most of the countries and groups analyzed. The Granger-type
causality tests show that there is bidirectional causality from the real per capita output to the urban concentration in high and
middle-low-income countries. There is unidirectional causality from the population concentration towards the real per capita
output in the low-income countries; from the non-renewable energy consumption to the real per capita output in high-income
countries; from the real per capita output to the non-renewable energy consumption in the countries of medium-high and
medium-low income; and from urban concentration to non-renewable energy consumption in high- and medium-high-income
countries. Our results highlight the importance of promoting policies of urban planning and generation and consumption of
renewable energy without limiting the expansion of the output.

Keywords Urban concentration . Real per capita output . Non-renewable energy . DOLS . PDOLS

JEL classifications O57 . C23 . C01

Introduction
Responsible editor: Muhammad Shahbaz
One of the main characteristics of modern economies is the
* Rafael Alvarado constant increase in the rate of urban concentration, particu-
jose.r.alvarado@unl.edu.ec
larly in countries in transition to development. According to
Cristian Ortiz
data from the United Nations (2014), about 54% of the
cristian.ortiz@unl.edu.ec world’s population lived in urban areas in 2014 and estimate
that this percentage will reach 66% in 2050. United Nations
Diana Bravo
dbbravo@utpl.edu.ec points out that the largest urban expansion will occur in India,
China, and Nigeria, which together will account for 37% of
José Chamba
the expected increase between 2014 and 2050, and almost
jose.chamba@unl.edu.ec
90% of this increase will occur in Asia and Africa. In 1990
1
Carrera de Economía, Universidad Nacional de Loja, Loja, Ecuador there were ten megacities in the world with more than 10
2 million inhabitants, and in 2014 it increased to 38 megacities.
Departamento de Economía, Universidad Católica del Norte,
Antofagasta, Chile The accelerated urbanization process implies greater demand
3 for energy by households and firms. A significant part of the
Departamento de Economía, Universidad Técnica Particular de Loja,
Loja, Ecuador global energy consumption comes from non-renewable
Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2761

sources, which generates a greater amount of emissions of the low-middle-income countries (LMIC), and finally, the
polluting gases with harmful effects on climate change. fourth group consists of low-income countries (LIC). The
Some empirical evidence finds bidirectional causality among availability of data for the three variables limited the research
the consumption of non-renewable energy and the emissions to the 1971–2017 period for 110 countries. The models were
of polluting gases (Saboori and Sulaiman 2013), particularly estimated after assuring that the variables do not have the
in countries that are experiencing an accelerated urbanization problem of the unit root through the tests of Levin et al.
process. Moreover, the available evidence suggests the pres- (2002) and Breitung (2000).
ence of positive externalities originated in the growth of urban The first part of the econometric strategy is to estimate a
areas, which are reflected in the real per capita output (Yang model with generalized least squares (GLS) to measure the
et al. 2017), at least within certain income ranges (Henderson direction of the relationship among the three variables.
2000). This effect is more robust in countries with a medium Second, we estimate the long- and short-term relationship
level of development, where urban expansion is an important using Pedroni (1999, 2001) heterogeneous cointegration
source of economic growth and improvements in the quality techniques and Westerlund (2007) error correction models
of life (Henderson 2003; World Bank 2009). However, excess for panel data. Finally, we applied the Granger-type causality
urban concentration can generate efficiency problems based test developed by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012). Similar
on a per capita income threshold (Easterly and Levine 1997; methodological strategies have been used by Ozturk et al.
Brülhart and Sbergami 2009; Atienza and Aroca 2013; (2010); Salim et al. (2014); Bakirtas and Akpolat (2018), re-
Alvarado et al. 2017a). spectively. The results of the GLS model show that urban
The urban agglomeration offers several economic and so- concentration and non-renewable energy consumption have
cial benefits for workers and firms, for example, transportation a positive effect on the real per capita output at all income
costs decrease, facilitate the interaction between supply and levels, except in high-income countries. The cointegration test
demand, facilitate the communication among economic developed by Pedroni (1999) showed that the variables are
agents and the specialization of the labor force, allow the cointegrated in the long term. Likewise, the cointegration tests
physical infrastructure to be used at lower cost, develop the proposed by Westerlund (2007) indicate that there is equilib-
labor market, and disseminate the advantages of technology rium relationship among the variables included in the re-
and knowledge (Henderson 2003; Romer 1989; Martin and search. The results of the dynamic panel model with ordinary
Ottaviano 2001; Fujita and Thisse 2003; Rosenthal and least squares (PDOLS) proposed by Pedroni (2001) show that
Strange 2004). Likewise, urban concentration facilitates ac- the strength of the cointegration vector is not strong in most
cess to telecommunications and financing (Glaeser et al. countries and groups of countries. Similarly, using DOLS
1992). However, the speed and magnitude of the urbanization models, we find that there is a long-term relationship among
process pose enormous challenges in the sustainable develop- the variables. Finally, we find bidirectional Granger-type cau-
ment of the countries, especially in the aspects related to the sality among the real per capita output and the urban concen-
growing energy demand and environmental pollution. As ur- tration in the HICs and LMICs; unidirectional causality from
ban centers grow, pollution problems associated with poor the real per capita output to non-renewable energy consump-
urban planning also increase, with greater emphasis on coun- tion in the MHIC and MLIC; and unidirectional causality
tries in transition to economic development. In addition, weak from the urban concentration to non-renewable energy con-
environmental regulation reinforces the growth of greenhouse sumption in the HICs and MHICs.
gas emissions and to a greater extent in developing countries. Our research offers a new look at the causal nexus among
In parallel, there is contradictory evidence on the effect of non-renewable energy consumption and real per capita prod-
non-renewable energy consumption on the real per capita out- uct, including the dynamics of urban concentration, where a
put. The nexus that relates energy consumption and per capita strong demand for energy originates and is responsible for a
output is urban concentration, because urban inhabitants con- significant portion of emissions greenhouse gases. Second, the
sume more energy and pollute the environment more than classification of countries according to their level of income
their rural counterparts. In this context, the objective of this allows capturing the heterogeneity associated with the produc-
research is to examine the short- and long-term causal rela- tive structure and obtaining more consistent results (Alvarado
tionship among urban concentration, non-renewable energy et al. 2017b: Alvarado et al. 2018). Third, we evaluate the
consumption, and the growth of real per capita output at a strength of the cointegration vector among the variables,
global level and groups of countries. In order to capture the which has been little studied in the literature that relates the
differences in the productive structure and in the level of de- urban concentration, the non-renewable energy, and the real
velopment, the countries were classified into four groups fol- per capita output. Finally, we include in the debate about the
lowing the Atlas method (2018). The first group consists of nexus among non-renewable energy consumption and the out-
high-income countries (HIC), the second group is formed by put of the importance of the application of policies of sustain-
middle-high-income countries (MHIC), in the third group are able development associated with the urban concentration,
2762 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

where the massive consumption that happens in the urban in rural areas, the cost is high. However, there are also known
centers can accelerate the economic growth, but at the same diseconomies of agglomeration, such as wage gaps between
time, they can increase the environmental pollution. Is impor- urban and rural areas (Balchin et al. 1995) and environmental
tant that policy makers promote sustainable energy consump- pollution. A part of the empirical evidence has found positive
tion patterns and adequate urban planning as mechanisms to externalities of urbanization (Firebaugh 1979; Frick and
reduce the harmful effects of climate change, without limiting Rodríguez-Pose 2018), and another part shows that the pro-
the expansion of the output. cesses of urban concentration can generate urbanization with-
In addition to the introduction, this article is organized in out efficiency, in particular in some countries of Africa and
four parts. In the second part, we summarize the conclusions Latin America (Fay and Opal 2000; Brückner 2012; Alvarado
and findings of the most relevant previous empirical works et al. 2017a), where the sustained growth of the urban concen-
and highlight the theoretical contributions that support our tration does not necessarily improve the quality of life of the
estimates. The third section contains a description of the data population, but the excess of concentration population in large
sources and the transformations to obtain the variables. We cities can generate inefficiency from certain thresholds of the
also propose the econometric strategy used to verify the hy- real per capita output (Easterly and Levine 1997; Brülhart and
pothesis. The fourth section shows the results and the discus- Sbergami 2009; Atienza and Aroca 2013). This has led to
sion with the findings presented in the previous literature. some countries opting to adopt mechanisms to reduce levels
Finally, in the last part, it shows the conclusions and policy of urbanization, including policies to strengthen controls on
implications that were raised from the results. rural-urban migration (Yao et al. 2015). The results of the
research that suggest that there is no relationship among the
per capita output and urban concentration is limited (Bucci
Review of the literature 2008; Jedwab et al. 2015).
At the same time, it is evident that as the urban concen-
The accelerated urbanization process experienced by emerg- tration increases, the demand for energy for the consump-
ing and developing countries generates enormous challenges tion of households and the productive processes of firms
for public planning and has several implications derived from also increase. Several research shows that the increase in
the interaction between market forces. This process is associ- urban concentration leads to increased consumption of
ated with one of the great challenges of modern development: non-renewable energy (Salim and Shafiei 2014; Yang
meeting the growing energy needs. Research on the causal et al. 2017; Gozgor et al. 2018), with greater emphasis on
link among economic growth and urbanization has been con- markets emerging economies (Bakirtas and Akpolat 2018),
solidated over time (Henderson and Wang 2007; Martin and whose urbanization processes are associated with the con-
Ottaviano 2001). There is empirical evidence that suggests the solidation of the manufacturing industry. China and India
existence of unidirectional causality from urban concentration are a clear example of this fact. It is logical to expect that
towards economic growth (Williamson 1965; Henderson the benefits of concentration will be greater than the costs
2003, 2005, 2010; Glaeser and Henderson 2017). On the other of congestion or diseconomies of agglomeration up to a
hand, there is partial evidence in favor of bidirectional causal- threshold of development. However, from the point of
ity, where economic development implies the transition from a view of environmental sustainability, the increase in urban
mainly agricultural and rural economy to a manufacturing concentration, which increases energy consumption, leads
economy (Prebisch 1962; Singer 1950; Gylfason 2001; to environmental deterioration due to an increase in emis-
Sachs and Warner 2001), whose economies tend later to spe- sions of polluting gases and other forms of environmental
cialize in the service sector, which are located mainly in urban degradation (Alvarado and Toledo 2017; Alvarado et al.
areas (Hwang 2006; Young 1991; Matsuyama 1992; Salim 2018). This demonstrates the need for an urgent change
and Shafiei 2014). During the process of urbanization, posi- in the energy matrix, where the energy consumed comes
tive externalities arise, and efficiency increases that stimulates from nonpolluting sources and at the same time, the expan-
economic growth. In developing countries, about 75% of the sion of the output is not limited. Consequently, there is a
output is produced in cities (Asuad 2001). Urban concentra- need to robustly identify the causal effect among the non-
tion responds to several factors, including the natural increase renewable energy consumption and the real per capita
in population or a lower urban mortality rate (Jedwab et al. output in a generalized manner over an extended period
2015; Jedwab and Vollrath 2015) and migration from rural and a large set of countries. The results found by Noor
areas to cities (Christaller 1966), generating benefits of ag- and Siddiqi (2010) indicate the existence of unidirectional
glomeration such as the reduction of transportation costs and causality from per capita output to energy consumption.
the transition to service activities (Moomaw 1981; Fujita et al. The relationship among energy consumption and output
2001). Urban concentration facilitates the transfer of knowl- has been studied extensively, generating different policy
edge and technology within urban areas (Lucas 1988), while implications. However, the evidence remains divergent
Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2763

(Razzaqi et al. 2011). In addition, several studies support Data and methodology
the feedback hypothesis (bidirectional causality), and this
means that a higher energy consumption is expected to Statistical sources
generate growth and vice versa (Eggoh et al. 2011).
Likewise, the productive structure differs significantly be- The data used in this research comes from the World Bank.
tween countries. For example, there are net-exporting coun- The variables included in the research are the real per capita
tries of energy, while others are net importers. Some countries output (GDP), the non-renewable energy consumption in kg
have a greater preference for sustainable energy, and others of oil per capita (NRE), and the urban concentration measured
consume energy from polluting sources (World Bank 2018a, by the urbanization rate (UC). The three variables are mea-
b, Gozgor et al. 2018). This structure can determine the direc- sured in annual growth rates. The research includes 110 coun-
tion of causality between growth and energy. Mehrara (2007) tries during 1971–2017. In practice, we cannot expect the
finds evidence of a strong unidirectional causality from eco- same strength of the relationship between the variables in all
nomic growth to energy consumption in oil-exporting coun- countries; rather, the intensity of the strength of the relation-
tries. Chiou-Wei et al. (2008) and Bakirtas and Akpolat (2018) ship between the three series differs depending on the produc-
find results that support the existence of causality from the tive structure and the level of development (Alvarado and
output towards energy consumption. Belke et al. (2011) offer Toledo 2017; Alvarado et al. 2018). Consequently, we use
results in favor of bidirectional causality, specifically for 25 the Atlas method to group the 110 countries into four groups
OECD countries, whose results are similar to those obtained based on their real per capita gross national income (GNI).
by Nasreen and Anwar (2014), who find that, in 15 countries Following to Ortiz et al. (2019), LICs are those that have a
in Asia, there is bidirectional causality among the output and GNI of US $ 1025 or less, MLICs are those that have a GNI
the energy consumption, even after controlling for modern among US $ 1026–4035, MHICs have a GNI between US $
patterns of open economies such as commercial opening. 4036–12,475, and HICs are those with a GNI of US $ 12,476
Conclusions obtained by Lee (2005) are similar for a group or more. In econometric regressions, the dependent variable is
of developed countries. Using cointegration techniques, they the growth rate of the real per capita output, and the indepen-
find that the non-renewable energy consumption, renewable dent variables are the annual growth rates of the population
energy, and per capita output have a long-term relationship concentration and the annual growth rate of non-renewable
(Halicioglu and Ketenci 2018) in 30 sub-Saharan African energy consumption.
countries, while Adams et al. (2018) find that cointegration Several countries have experienced significant changes in
relationships exist in only 7 of the 15 countries of the their urban structure, and a greater urban concentration can be
European Union. found in relative terms in many developing countries (World
The empirical evidence that relates some measure of Bank, 2018). Some countries in Asia and Africa are a clear
urban concentration, the non-renewable energy consump- example of this. Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of the
tion, and the real per capita output is limited. Among the series. The variables form an exactly balanced panel with 5060
few exceptions is the research developed by Kanjilal and observations over 46 years (t = 1, 2, …, 46) and 110 countries
Ghosh (2013), who find a long-term relationship between (i = 1, 2, …, 110). The real per capita output is more stable
energy, urbanization, and output in India, while the within countries than between countries, the standard deviation
Granger-type causality tests indicate unidirectional causal- (SD) between countries is 1.562, and within countries is 4.884.
ity that goes from energy to output and from economic Similarly, population concentration shows greater variability
activity to urbanization. Likewise, Zhao and Wang (2015) between countries than within countries, and the SD between
show that there is a short- and long-term relationship countries is 1.689, which exceeds the standard deviation within
among energy, urbanization, and economic growth in countries (1.337). The consumption of non-renewable energy
China. These authors find bidirectional causality ranging has greater stability within countries than between countries,
from urbanization rate to energy consumption and from the SD within the countries is approximately 7, and the SD
output to urbanization rate. Finally, Liu (2009) found that among the countries is approximately 1.80.
there is a stable long-term relationship among total energy
consumption, population, output and urbanization, and uni- Empirical strategy
directional causality that goes from urbanization to total
energy. However, these results do not allow us to generalize In order to examine the causal link among urban concentra-
the findings globally because they are focused on research tion, non-renewable energy consumption and the real per
in countries or groups of countries. Likewise, the lack of capita output, globally and by groups of countries, the empir-
coherence of the results and the lack of comparability arise ical strategy is divided into three stages. Each stage is applied
due to the sample of data and the diversity of the econo- for the 110 countries included in the research and for the
metric methodologies (Chen et al. 2007; Ozturk 2010). groups according to the economic development achieved.
2764 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

Table 1 Statistical description of


the variables Description Dimension Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum N

GDP (annual growth) Overall 1.985 5.126 − 64.997 53.932 N = 5060


Between 1.562 − 2.282 7.744 n = 110
Within 4.884 − 67.855 51.074 T = 46
UC (annual growth) Overall 2.757 2.148 − 5.268 17.089 N = 5060
Between 1.689 0.163 8.140 n = 110
Within 1.337 − 4.549 12.883 T = 46
NRE (annual growth) Overall 1.387 7.174 − 69.690 88.060 N = 5060
Between 1.787 − 1.847 11.416 n = 110
Within 6.950 − 66.445 84.508 T = 46

The classification of the countries into four groups allows to is the term that can represent panel-specific means according
determine if the level of development matters in the strength the specification; and eit is a stationary error term. Equation 4b
of the relationship of the three variables analyzed in this re- formalizes the unit root test of Levin, Lin and Chu (2002)
search. In the first stage, we estimate a regression model using when the variance is heterogeneous between the panels. In
generalized least squares (GLS), which generates estimators addition, this test constitutes a robust test of the results of
consistent with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation with equation 4a.
panel data: p
Δyit ¼ ∅i yit−1 þ z;it φi þ ∑ Δyit− j þ eit ð4aÞ
Y it ¼ λ0 þ λ1 URit þ λ2 NRE it þ φit ð1Þ j¼1

pi
where Yit represents the economic growth of the real per capita Δyit ¼ ∅i yit−1 þ z;it φi þ ∑ θij Δyit− j þ μit ð4bÞ
j¼1
output of country i in period t, URit the urbanization rate is a
proxy of the variable urban concentration, and NREit is the Next, we use the Breitung test (2000) from the following
non-renewable energy consumption, from country i in period equation:
t, respectively. Finally, φit represents the error term. The re-
pþ1
sults obtained in this stage are of interest because they indicate yit ¼ αi;t þ ∑ βik xit−k þ εit ð5Þ
the sign and the size of the effect of the independent variables k¼1
on the dependent variable. In the second stage, we verify the
existence of a long- and short-term equilibrium relationship The use of Breitung (2000) unit root tests ensures that the
among the three variables. In order to ensure that the series do series do not have a trend component and that the results of
not have the problem of the unit root, the dependency tests in cointegration and causality tests are reliable. Following
the cross sections suggest the homogeneity of the unit root. Ozturk et al. (2010), in the third stage, we verified the long-
Therefore, unit root tests were applied that implicitly consid- term cointegration relationship between the urban concentra-
ered such homogeneity. Hadri (2000) developed a procedure tion, the non-renewable energy consumption, and the growth
to verify the existence of unitary root in the series based on the of the real per capita output through the cointegration test of
Lagrange multiplier test, who plated the null hypothesis that Pedroni (1999) for panel data:
all panels are stationary (trend). An advantage of this test is Yit ¼ αit þ δit t þ γ 1i UC it þ γ 2i NREit þ ε1it ð6Þ
that it allows the incorporation of a fixed effect and time trends
in the data generating process (Choi 2001; Breitung 2000; The parameters αit and δit allow to capture the fixed
Baum 2006). In addition, we use the unit root test with and effects of the country and the deterministic trend of time
without tendency. Equation 2 formalizes the unit root test in respectively. The term ε1it is the estimated residuals that
general; however, the tests are performed for each series indi- represent deviations from the long-term relationship. This
vidually. test proposes seven different statistics, which are based on
the residuals of the cointegration regression for the test of
yit ¼ ∅i yit−1 þ z;it φi þ eit ð2Þ the null hypothesis of non-cointegration. These test statis-
Δyit ¼ ∅i yit−1 þ z;it φi þ eit ð3Þ tics are panel v, panel rho, group rho, panel t (nonpara-
metric), group t (nonparametric), panel (parametric t), and
where the null hypothesis is then H0 : ρi = 0 for all i versus the group (parametric t). In the fourth stage, following Salim
alternative Ha : ρi < 0. Likewise, i = 1, …, N indexes panel; t = et al. (2014) and after confirming that the variables in-
1, …, T indexes time; yit represent the variable being tested; yit cluded in the model are cointegrated in the long term, it
Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2765

is possible to incorporate the error correction vector assumed to be constant over time. The model is established as
(VEC). From Eq. 3 through the error correction test of a fixed coefficient model with fixed individual effects. The
Westerlund (2007) for panel data: null hypothesis is that the dependent variable does not cause
Granger-type causality to the independent variable in at least
0 Pi
GDPit ¼ δ 1i d t þ α1i GDPit−1 −B0 1i UC it−1 ∑ α1iJ GDPit− j ð7Þ one panel.
j¼1
Pi Pi
−B0 2i NREit−1 ∑ α2iJ GDPit− j þ ∑ Y1ij UC it− J
j¼1 j¼−qi
Pi
þ ∑ Y2ij NRE it− J þ e1it
j¼−qi Results and discussion
In Eqs. 4 and 5, there are three possible scenarios. The first In the Table 2, the Hausman test (1978) showed the existence
is that if dt = 0, there are no deterministic components in the of a difference among the parameters using models of fixed
growth rates of urbanization and the consumption of non- effects and random effects, accordingly, and we choose to
renewable energy. The second scenario is that if dt = 1, the estimate a model with fixed effects. Also, the Wald test
GDPit has a constant. In the third case, if dt = (1 – t)´, the modified to detect heteroskedasticity and the Wooldridge
GDPit has a constant and a trend. For simplicity, we assume test (1991) to detect serial autocorrelation point out the need
that the k-dimensional vector of both UR it and NRE it to estimate the parameters of Eq. 1 using generalized least
representing urbanization and non-renewable energy con- squares (GLS) for panel data (Wooldridge 2002). The fixed
sumption, respectively, is random and independent of eit. In effects of time and by country were included in the regressions
addition, we assume that these errors are independent through in order to obtain estimators consistent with heteroscedasticity
i and t. The null hypothesis of this test is that there is no short- and serial autocorrelation. The results are reported for the
term cointegration. Equation 8 verifies if the growth rates of global panel and for the four groups of countries. We found
the real per capita output, urban concentration, and non- that the urban concentration has a negative effect on the global
renewable energy consumption are cointegrated with slopes panel and the HICs, while in the MHICs, MLICs, and LICs,
βi. The null hypothesis of this test is that βi = 1, which implies there is a positive effect on the real per capita output, although
that there is a strong cointegration relationship among the in the MLIC and LIC the effect is statistically not significant.
variables. In the sixth stage, after estimating the short- and One of the possible reasons that in low-middle and low-in-
long-term relationship between the variables as well as the come countries energy consumption does not have a signifi-
strength of the cointegration vector, following Bakirtas and cant effect on the product is that energy consumption is mainly
Akpolat (2018), we used the Granger-type causality test for- associated with household consumption and not necessarily
malized for panel data by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) from with processes of the production.. Consequently, the effect on
the following equations: economic growth is not significant. On the other hand, we
r r show empirical evidence that non-renewable energy generates
ðrÞ ðrÞ
GDPit ¼ α1i þ ∑ γ 1i GDPit−r þ ∑ β 1i UC it−r þ ε1it ð9Þ a positive and statistically significant effect on all levels of
r¼1 r¼1
income, except in LIC where a statistically nonsignificant co-
r r
ðr Þ ðr Þ
UC it ¼ α2i þ ∑ γ 2i UC it−r þ ∑ β2i GDPit−r þ ε2it ð0Þ efficient is found. These results offer preliminary information
r¼1 r¼1 on the negative effect of population concentration on real per
r
ðk Þ
r
ðr Þ capita output, as other researchers have already identified
GDPit ¼ α3i þ ∑ γ 3i GDPit−r þ ∑ β3i NREit−r þ ε3it ð11Þ
r¼1 r¼1 (Easterly and Levine 1997; Brülhart and Sbergami 2009;
r r Atienza and Aroca 2013; Alvarado et al. 2017a). In our re-
ðrÞ ðr Þ
NREit ¼ α4i þ ∑ γ 4i NREit−r þ ∑ β4i GDPit−r þ ε4it ð12Þ search, following the Atlas method of the World Bank, HICs
r¼1 r¼1
are those that have a per capita gross national income greater
r r
ðr Þ ðrÞ than US $ 12,476, a threshold similar to that found by Brülhart
NRE it ¼ α5i þ ∑ γ 5i NREit−r þ ∑ β 5i UC it−r þ ε5it ð13Þ
r¼1 r¼1 and Sbergami (2009), who emphasize that excessive concen-
r
ðr Þ
r
ðr Þ tration can lead countries to generate inefficiency due to con-
UC it ¼ α6i þ ∑ γ 6i UC it−r þ ∑ β6i NRE it−r þ ε6it ð15Þ gestion costs. In addition, it is necessary to add the costs gen-
r¼1 r¼1
erated by environmental pollution caused by large urban cen-
where βi = βi(1), …. , βi(r) and αi denotes the individual effects ters. In the MHIC, there are countries with an accelerated
that must be corrected in time and r represents the length of the urbanization process that move towards development, such
lag and is assumed to be the same for all the cross section units as China, Brazil, Turkey, Mexico, Argentina, Malaysia, and
ðr Þ
of the panel, where the panel is balanced. The terms γ i and Thailand, among others. At the same time, the effect of non-
ðr Þ
βi corresponding to each equation denote the lag and slope renewable energy consumption is positive and significant in
parameters that differ between groups, respectively, which are all groups, with the exception in the LICs.
2766 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

Table 2 Results of the baseline


model Variables Global High Medium-high Medium-low Low
income income income income

Urban concentration − 0.193*** − 0.306*** 0.486*** 0.0854 0.123


(− 6.37) (− 3.80) (3.85) (0.77) (0.87)
Non-renewable energy 0.168*** 0.0730*** 0.209*** 0.151*** 0.0271
(19.76) (7.62) (11.96) (7.97) (0.68)
Constant 2.752*** 3.350*** − 1.807 1.678*** − 0.834
(9.55) (6.79) (− 1.43) (1.49) (− 0.57)
Serial correlation test (p 0.10 0.31 0.22 0.72 0.85
value)
Fixed effects (year) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Fixed effects (country) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 5060 1932 1426 1196 506

Note: The t statistic is reported in parentheses; * indicates statistical significance of the p value < 5%, ** < 1%, and
*** < 0.1%

In the next steps, all the results of the five tests reported in different levels of significance; therefore, our results indicate
Table 3 show that the variables are stationary in levels. that the growth rate of the population concentration, the non-
Therefore, they have an integration order of I (0). These results renewable energy consumption, and the real per capita output
ensure the cyclicity of the series and the consistency of the has a joint movement and is simultaneous during the period
subsequent causal results. 1971–2017 at all income levels. Our results agree with the
In the next stage of this investigation, we verified the exis- results of Zhang et al. (2017), who find that the real per capita
tence of long- and short-term cointegration vectors among the output, non-renewable energy consumption, urbanization, and
variables. To determine the existence of long-term equilibri- CO2 emissions have a long-term relationship. Ozturk et al.
um, we used the heterogeneous panel cointegration test devel- (2010) also found that the energy consumption and the prod-
oped by Pedroni (1999), which allows transversal interdepen- uct are cointegrated in all income levels studied (LIC, MLIC,
dence with different individual effects. Table 4 reports the and MHIC). Similarly, Lee (2005) also found long-term
statistics within and between the dimensions. All the statisti- cointegration between non-renewable energy consumption
cians reject the null hypothesis of non-cointegration in the and output in 18 upper-middle income countries. Our results

Table 3 Results of the unit root


test Groups Levin, Li, and Chu Breitung Levin, Li, and Chu Breitung
Without trend With trend

Global GDP − 36.08a − 11.53a − 35.3a − 10.93a


UC − 11.48a 11.11 − 8.6b − 1.79a
NRE − 58.69a − 12.43a 55.01a − 7.34a
High income GDP − 21.23a − 7.24a − 22.43a − 7.22a
UC − 7.33a 6.21 − 5.43a − 1.02a
NRE − 37.22a − 8.52a − 36.35a − 4.68a
Medium-high income GDP − 17.35a − 7.33a − 18.62a − 5.32a
UC − 4.63a − 6.57 − 4.45a − 1.23c
NRE − 30.22a − 7.57a − 28.23a − 5.45a
Medium-low income GDP − 19.23a − 4.43a − 19.45a − 7.48a
UC − 9.32a 4.64 − 8.45a − 3.45a
NRE − 31.54a − 6.31a − 30.43a − 4.34a
Low income GDP − 14.13a − 4.22a − 15.22a − 3.44a
UC 2.96b 6.42b 0.45c − 0.05c
NRE − 15.46a − 1.1a − 13.33a − 5.27a

Note: c indicates statistical significance at 5%, b at 1%, and a at 0.1%


Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2767

Table 4 Result of the cointegration test

Dimension Statistic Global High income Medium-high income Medium-low income Low income

Within Panel v-statistic 5.94a 3.43a 3.3a 2.3a 2.2a


Panel p-statistic − 28.9a − 16.4a − 15.8a − 15.0a − 11.1a
Panel PP-statistic − 39.1a − 21.3a − 13.9a − 12.5a − 9.5a
Panel ADF statistic − 31.6a − 17.6a − 21.3a − 20.1a − 14.8a
Between Panel p-statistic − 24.6 a − 13.7a − 23.1a − 20.7a − 15.5a
Group PP-statistic − 41.4 a − 21.9a − 18.0a − 16.1a − 13.3a
Group ADF statistic − 31.9a − 17.7a − 19.6a − 15.1a − 12.3a

Note: a denotes statistical significance at the level of 1%

also agreed with the results found by Salim et al. (2014) in its the short term. Salim et al. (2014) also find causal relation-
study for 29 OECD countries, which shows the existence of a ships with short-term cointegration vectors, both for renew-
long-term equilibrium relationship among the consumption of able energy and non-renewable energy that directly affect
renewable, non-renewable energy, industrial production, and GDP. Also, our findings are coupled with the results found
economic growth. by Zhang et al. (2017), which also find cointegration vectors
In the next stage, to obtain the equilibrium, we used a in the short term between GDP, non-renewable energy con-
cointegration model for panel data developed by Westerlund sumption, urbanization, and CO2 emissions as well as finding
(2007), whose results are reported in Table 5. Our results show a positive and significant short-term relationship between the
the existence of a short-term equilibrium in the variables of a variables in their study, for countries with different income
global level and in all groups of countries. These results are levels.
consistent with the studies conducted by Lee (2005), who In the next stage, derived from the results of Table 4, we
found cointegration vectors in the short term and showed pos- analyze some other relevant aspects such as the strength of the
itive effects of non-renewable energy consumption in GDP in cointegration vector. Our models for measuring this
cointegration force, as performed by Ozturk et al. (2010), are
based on the equation proposed by Pedroni (2001) formalized
Table 5 Results of the Westerlund cointegration test in Eq. 6 of this research. Table 6 reports the results of the
DOLS model for individual countries. These results reveal
Levels of development Statistic Value Z value P value
that many of the economies around the world are still depen-
Global Gt − 3.67 − 14.33 0.00 dent on non-renewable energy for their overall economic
Ga − 21.21 − 10.84 0.00 growth. In terms of urbanization, the results indicate that ur-
Pt − 44.93 − 23.21 0.00 banization rates negatively affect several HICs. Therefore, ur-
Pa − 25.76 − 23.71 0.00 ban concentration cannot be corrected by itself with economic
High income Gt − 3.58 − 8.10 0.00 development, as is often assumed within literature (Frick and
Ga − 20.82 − 6.35 0.00 Rodríguez-Pose 2018).
Pt − 26.93 − 13.42 0.00 In order to obtain the strength of the cointegration vector by
Pa − 23.99 − 12.95 0.00 groups of countries, Table 7 shows the results of the PDOLS
Medium-high income Gt − 3.90 − 9.08 0.00 panel estimates with and without time variables. The estima-
Ga − 20.76 − 5.41 0.00 tors βi of the different income levels do not approach 1, which
Pt − 22.56 − 10.89 0.00 rejects the null hypothesis and concludes that the force of the
Pa − 25.61 − 12.46 0.00 cointegration vector is not strong. The results of the individual
Medium-low income Gt − 3.67 − 6.98 0.00 tests and the panel tests overwhelmingly reject the null hy-
Ga − 22.10 − 5.89 0.00 pothesis of a strong relationship that ranges from urbanization
Pt − 23.98 − 13.65 0.00 rates and non-renewable energy consumption to the real per
Pa − 27.84 − 13.09 0.00
capita output. These results are consistent with the research of
Low income Gt − 3.42 − 3.51 0.00
Ozturk et al. (2010) who find a weak cointegration relation-
Ga − 21.85 − 3.71 0.00
ship between non-renewable energy consumption and real per
capita output.
Pt − 9.24 − 1.83 0.03
In the fourth stage, we determined the Granger-type
Pa − 17.28 − 3.33 0.00
causality of the variables from the formalization
2768 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

Table 6 DOLS panel test results for countries individually

HIC UR NRE MHIC UR NRE MLIC UR NRE LIC UR NRE

Australia 1.48 − 0.30** Albania − 2.86 0.47** Bangladesh 0.07** 0.72** Benin − 0.73** − 0.93
Austria − 0.21** − 0.13** Algeria − 2.90 0.48** Bolivia 0.31** 0.24** D.R Congo 3.24** 3.82
Bahrain − 0.34** 0.87** Angola 4.76 − 1.85 Cameroon 1.15 1.16 Ethiopia 0.56** − 2.81
Belgium 0.21** − 0.10** Argentina 1.18 1.80 R. Congo 2.82 − 0.05** Haiti − 0.23** − 0.33**
Brunei − 1.39 0.16** Bahamas − 1.55 1.26 C.Marfil 1.73 0.36** India 0.61** 0.30**
Canada − 1.2 0.69** Belarus − 1.60 1.06 Egypt − 2.85 0.42** Mozambique − 0.96 − 1.39
Chile − 0.98** 0.60** Botswana 0.52** 0.94 Salvador 1.35 0.35** Nepal − 0.39** 1.99
Croatia 0.8** 0.37** Brazil 2.11** 0.82 Ghana 2.34 0.37** Nigeria 1.60 − 0.11
Cyprus 2.63 0.10** Bulgaria − 3.77 1.21** Honduras 2.96 0.29** Senegal − 1.39 0.58**
R.Czech 1.10 1.05 China 2.08 − 0.16** Indonesia − 1.86 1.04 Tanzania 0.11** 0.43**
Denmark − 1.13 0.22** Colombia − 7.12 0.24** Iran − 4.49 0.66** Zimbabwe 0.75** 1.33
Finland 0.59** 1.02 Costa Rica 0.58** 0.26** Iraq 0.16** − 0.50**
France − 0.59** 0.13** Cuba 3.12 1.27 Mongolia 2.49 − 0.04**
Germany − 0.05** − 0.22** Dominican R. 1.34 0.54** Morocco 2.15 − 0.06**
Greece 5.20** 0.56** Ecuador − 1.22 0.45** Myanmar 3.79 0.64**
Guatemala − 1.09 0.47** Gabon 2.69 1.56 Nicaragua 1.02 1.12
Iceland − 1.31 0.24** Hungary − 0.2** 0.39** Norway − 1.89 0.23**
Ireland 0.42** 0.90 Jamaica − 2.98 0.56** Philippines − 0.8** 0.39**
Israel − 0.79** 0.57** Jordan − 2.75 0.23** Sri Lanka 0.68** − 0.05**
Italy − 2.11 − 0.06** Lebanon 0.83** 0.56** Sudan 0.27** − 0.59**
Japan − 1.92 − 0.11** Libya 5.71 − 1.47 Syrian − 2.68 0.07**
Kuwait − 2.12 0.23** Malaysia − 0.1** 0.85** Tunisia 0.68** 0.45**
Luxembourg − 1.25 0.41** Mauritius − 2.39 1.11 Vietnam − 0.8** 0.33**
Malta − 4.43 − 0.07** Mexico 0.13** 0.64** Yemen 0.35** 0.53**
Netherlands 0.47** 0.14** Panama − 0.7** 0.58** Zambia 0.26** 1.04
N.Zealand − 0.17** 0.34** Paraguay − 2.98 1.16 Kenya − 0.1** 1.73
Oman 0.61** 0.04** Peru 1.67 0.75**
Pakistan 1.17 0.77** Romania − 0.7** 0.88**
Poland 0.14** 0.36** Thailand − 0.2** 0.70**
Portugal − 0.38** 0.52** Turkey − 0.5** 0.43**
S.Arabia − 1.43 0.13** Venezuela 0.86 0.33**
Singapore − 0.04** 0.21**
R.Slovak −0.38** 0.52**
Spain 0.26** 0.55**
Sweden 0.31** 0.73**
Switzerland − 0.15** 0.35**
T&Tobago 0.78** 0.65**
U. Emirates 0.20** − 0.08**
UK − 0.17** 0.57**
USA 0.20** − 0.11**
Uruguay 0.30** 0.65**
Korea, Rep. 0.80** 0.31**

Note: ** indicates rejection for H0: βi=1

developed by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) and found MHIC where Granger causality is not shown in any di-
that bidirectional causality exists among the growth rate rection, and in LIC where causality is observed unidirec-
of per capita GDP and the rate of urbanization, in all tional Granger from the growth rate of urbanization to the
countries. Income levels (UCi, t ↔ GDPi, t, except for GDP per capita growth rate (UC i , t → GDP i , t ),
Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2769

Table 7 Results of PDOLS for countries groups

With dummy time Without dummy time

UR NRE UR NRE

Groups PDOLS t-statistics PDOLS t-statistics PDOLS t-statistics PDOLS t-statistics


Global − 0.26* − 3.483 0.53* 23.164 − 0.07* − 3.402 0.66* 25.764
High income − 0.13* − 1.740 0.34* 11.714 − 0.22* − 0.118 0.44* 16.295
Medium-high income − 0.59* − 0.931 0.59* 13.212 − 0.16* − 3.792 0.72* 17.661
Medium-low income 0.93* 2.489 0.42* 7.221 0.48* − 1.579 0.54* 9.246
Low income 0.29* − 0.456 0.26* 0.522 − 0.55* − 1.783 1.60* 5.746

Note: * indicates rejection for H0: βi=1

bidirectional causality was also found between the rate of GDP growth rate (NREi, t ↔ GDPi, t) in the GLOBAL
growth of non-renewable energy use and the per capita and HIC panel and unidirectional causality in the MHIC
and MLIC of the product towards energy consumption
(GDPit → NREit) and no address causal in the HIC. On
Table 8 Results of the causality tests of Dumitrescu and Hurlin the other hand, unidirectional causality is observed in
Causalidad Group W- Z-bar p value the GLOBAL, HIC, and MHIC from the urbanization rate
bar towards energy consumption (UCi, t → NREi, t) and no
relation of Granger-type causality in the MLIC and LIC.
Global 1.72 5.39 0.000 These results are contrary to those found by Zhang et al.
UC → GDP High income 1.87 4.05 0.000 (2017) who find unidirectional causality from the use of
Medium-high income 1.37 1.48 0.238 non-renewable energy towards economic growth in the
Medium-low income 1.74 2.70 0.020 MHIC in his study conducted for countries with different
Low income 2.05 2.48 0.030 income levels in the world. They are also contrary to the
Global 2.55 11.58 0.000 results obtained by Lee (2005) which show that the long-
High income 3.86 13.27 0.000 and short-term causes range from energy consumption to
GDP → UC Medium-high income 0.80 − 0.76 0.379 GDP, but not vice versa in developing countries (Table 8).
Medium-low income 2.95 7.04 0.000 Our results are consistent with the results of Salim and
Low income 1.42 1.00 0.417 Shafiei (2014) which show a bidirectional causality in the
Global 1.33 2.49 0.051 short and long term between GDP growth and non-
High income 1.59 2.76 0.020 renewable energy consumption for OECD countries.
NRE → GDP Medium-high income 1.03 0.12 0.945 They also coincide with the results obtained by
Medium-low income 1.29 1.06 0.419 Alvarado et al. (2019) who find bidirectional causality
Low income 1.26 0.61 0.649 b etwe e n re n ewa bl e, no n- re ne wa ble en e rg y, an d
Global 1.98 7.36 0.000 economic growth for Latin American countries. In
High income 2.14 5.31 0.000 another study, Salim et al. (2014) also agree with our
GDP → NRE Medium-high income 2.15 4.55 0.000 results, given that they show bidirectional causality be-
Medium-low income 1.74 2.69 0.021 tween industrial production and the consumption of re-
Low income 1.46 1.09 0.368 newable and non-renewable energy in the short and long
Global 1.15 1.11 0.493 term in the OECD countries. Ozturk et al. (2010) also
High income 1.40 1.89 0.126 show results very similar to ours. Causality tests reveal
NRE → UC Medium-high income 1.09 0.36 0.875 that there is a causality in two directions among the UC
Medium-low income 0.54 − 1.62 0.097 and the GDP for the middle-income countries. In the con-
Low income 1.71 1.68 0.150 text of urbanization, our results coincide with the results
Global 1.77 5.80 0.000 of Zhang et al. (2017), who find causality from the urban-
High income 1.71 3.31 0.004 ization rate to economic growth. Arvin et al. (2015) also
UC → NRE Medium-high income 2.24 4.88 0.000 find coincident results as they find unidirectional causality
Medium-low income 1.29 1.05 0.421 from per capita output towards urbanization and show
Low income 1.88 2.07 0.072 bidirectional causality between these variables in their
study for the G-20 countries.
2770 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

Conclusions and policy implications sources can be successful if production processes incorporate
technology (Zafar et al. 2019; Sinha et al. 2019). The effective
This paper analyzes the effect of urbanization rates and non- protection of the environment requires greater attention when
renewable energy consumption on real GDP per capita in the designing public policies.
period 1971–2016 for a dynamic panel of data from 110 coun-
tries of the world, where we have classified countries accord- Acknowledgments The authors express their gratitude to the Club de
Investigación de Economía (CIE), Loja Ecuador.
ing to their income level through the Atlas method (2016)
developed by the World Bank. The results of this research
show that: First, in the baseline GLS regressions, we find that
the urbanization rate has a negative effect on the global panel References
and the HICs, while in the MHIC, the MLIC, and the HIC,
Adams S, Klobodu E, Apio A (2018) Renewable and non-renewable
there is a positive effect on economic growth, although in the energy, regime type and economic growth. Renew Energy 125:
MLIC and HIC, the effect is statistically not significant. On 755–767
the other hand, we demonstrate that the non-renewable energy Alvarado R, Toledo E (2017) Environmental degradation and economic
has a positive and statistically significant effect on all levels of growth: evidence for a developing country. Environ Dev Sustain
19(4):1205–1218
income, except in HIC where a statistically nonsignificant Alvarado R, Correa-Quezada R, Tituaña-Castillo M (2017a) Internal mi-
coefficient is found. Second, through the cointegration tests gration and urbanization without efficiency in developing countries:
of Pedroni (1999), we find that the growth rates of population evidence for Ecuador. Pap Poblac 23(94):99–123
concentration, non-renewable energy consumption, and real Alvarado R, Iñiguez M, Ponce P (2017b) Foreign direct investment and
economic growth in Latin America. Econ Anal Policy 56:176–187
GDP per capita are cointegrated in the long term at all levels
Alvarado R, Ponce P, Criollo A, Córdova K, Khan MK (2018)
of income. The DOLS models confirm the GLS regressions, Environmental degradation and real per capita output: new evidence
since they show negative effects of the urbanization rate in at the global level grouping countries by income levels. J Clean Prod
most of the PIAs and positive in the MHIC, MLIC, and 189:13–20
Arvin M, Pradhan R, Norman N (2015) Transportation intensity, urban-
HIC, while the consumption of renewable energy has a posi-
ization, economic growth, and CO2 emissions in the G-20 countries.
tive effect on the most countries of all income levels. The Util Policy 35:50–66
DOLS and PDOLS models also reveal that the strength of Alvarado R, Ponce P, Alvarado R, Ponce K, Huachizaca V, Toledo E
the long-term cointegration vector is weak in most countries (2019) Sustainable and non-sustainable energy and output in Latin
since the beta parameters are not close to 1. Third, through America: A cointegration and causality approach with panel data.
Energy Strategy Reviews, 26, 100369.
cointegration tests of Westerlund (2007), it was found that the Asuad, N. (2001). Economía regional y urbana. Introducción a las teorías,
growth rates of the urban population, non-renewable energy técnicas y metodologías básicas. Benemérita Universidad
consumption, and real GDP per capita are cointegrated in the Autónoma de Puebla, México.
short term, since the presence of statistically significant Atienza M, Aroca P (2013) Concentration and growth in Latin American
countries. In: regional problems and policies in Latin America.
cointegration vectors was found in the data panels studied. Springer, Berlin, pp 113–133
And fourth, through the Granger-type causality tests devel- Bakirtas T, Akpolat A (2018) The relationship between energy consump-
oped by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012), it was found that tion, urbanization, and economic growth in new emerging-market
bidirectional Granger-type causality exists between the per countries. Energy 147:110–121
capita output and the urban concentration in the HICs and Balchin, P. N., Bull, G. H., & Kieve, J. L. (1995). Urban land economics
and public policy. Macmillan International Higher Education.
MLICs; unidirectional causality from the urbanization rate to Baum, C. F., & Christopher, F. (2006). An introduction to modern econo-
the output in the HIC; bidirectional causality between energy metrics using Stata. Stata press.
consumption and per capita product in the GLOBAL and HIC Belke A, Dobnik F, Dreger C (2011) Energy consumption and economic
panel; unidirectional causality from the product to energy con- growth: new insights into the cointegration relationship. Energy
Econ 33(5):782–789
sumption in the MHICs and MLIC; and unidirectional causal- Breitung J (2000) Nonparametric tests for unit roots and cointegration. J
ity from the urbanization rate to the energy consumption in the Econ 108(2):343–363
GLOBAL, HIC, and MHIC panel. One implication of eco- Brückner M (2012) Economic growth, size of the agricultural sector, and
nomic policy derived from this research is that countries urbanization in Africa. J Urban Econ 71(1):26–36
should promote mechanisms to achieve efficient urbanization, Brülhart M, Sbergami F (2009) Agglomeration and growth: cross-
country evidence. J Urban Econ 65(1):48–63
which does not limit the expansion of the output but does not Bucci A (2008) Population growth in a model of economic growth with
disproportionately increase emissions of polluting gases. In human capital accumulation and horizontal R&D. J Macroecon
addition, policy makers should promote the transition towards 30(3):1124–1147
energy consumption patterns from renewable sources, which Chen S, Kuo H, Chen C (2007) The relationship between GDP and
electricity consumption in 10 Asian countries. Energy Policy
can consolidate efforts aimed at reducing the adverse effects 35(4):2611–2621
of climate change. The process of transition from energy from Chiou-Wei, S., Chen, C., & Zhu, Z. (2008). Economic growth and energy
non-renewable sources to an energy matrix of renewable consumption revisited
Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772 2771

Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20:249– Martin P, Ottaviano G (2001) Growth and agglomeration. Int Econ Rev
272 42(4):947–968
Christaller W (1966) Central places in southern Germany. Prentice Hall Matsuyama K (1992) Agricultural productivity, Comparative Advantage
Dumitrescu E, Hurlin C (2012) Testing for granger non-causality in het- and Economic Growth. J Econ Theory 58(2):317–334
erogeneous panels. Econ Model 29(4):1450–1460 Mehrara M (2007) Energy consumption and economic growth: the case
Easterly W, Levine R (1997) Africa's growth tragedy: policies and ethnic of oil exporting countries. Energy Policy 35(5):2939–2945
divisions. Q J Econ 112(4):1203–1250 Moomaw R (1981) Productivity and city size: a critique of the evidence.
Eggoh J, Bangake C, Rault C (2011) Energy consumption and economic Q J Econ 96(4):675–688
growth revisited in African countries. Energy Policy 39:7408–7421 Nasreen S, Anwar S (2014) Causal relationship between trade openness,
Fay M, Opal C (2000) Urbanization without growth: a not so uncommon economic growth and energy consumption: a panel data analysis of
phenomenon, vol 2412. World Bank Publications, Washington D.C Asian countries. Energy Policy 69:82–91
Firebaugh, G. (1979). Structural determinants of urbanization in Asia and Noor S, Siddiqi M (2010) Energy consumption and economic growth in
Latin America, 1950-1970. American Sociological Review, 199- South Asian countries: a co-integrated panel analysis. Int J Human
215. Soc Sci 5(14):921–926
Frick S, Rodríguez-Pose A (2018) Change in urban concentration and Ortiz C, Alvarado R, Salinas A (2019) The effect of military spending on
economic growth (No. 1803). Utrecht University, Department of output: new evidence at the global and country group levels using
Human Geography and Spatial Planning, Group Economic panel data cointegration techniques. Econ Anal Policy 62:402–414
Geography Ozturk I (2010) A literature survey on energy–growth nexus. Energy
Fujita M, Thisse J (2003) Does geographical agglomeration foster eco- Policy 38(1):340–349
nomic growth? And who gains and loses from it? Jpn Econ Rev Ozturk I, Aslan A, Kalyoncu H (2010) Energy consumption and econom-
54(2):121–145 ic growth relationship: evidence from panel data for low and middle
Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables A (2001) The spatial economy: cities, income countries. Energy Policy 38(8):4422–4428
regions, and international trade. MIT Press Pedroni P (1999) Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous
Glaeser E, Kallal H, Scheinkman, & Shleifer, A. (1992) Growth in cities. panels with multiple regressors. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 61(S1):653–670
J Polit Econ 100(6):1126–1152 Pedroni P (2001) Purchasing power parity tests in cointegrated panels.
Glaeser E, Henderson V (2017) Urban economics for the developing Rev Econ Stat 83(4):727–731
world: an introduction. J Urban Econ 98:1–5
Prebisch R (1962) The economic development of Latin America and its
Gozgor G, Lau C, Lu Z (2018) Energy consumption and economic
principal problems. Econ Bull Latin Am 1:1–22
growth: new evidence from the OECD countries. Energy 153:27–34
Razzaqi, S., Bilquees, F., & Sherbaz, S. (2011). Dynamic relationship
Gylfason T (2001) Natural resources, education, and economic develop-
between energy and economic growth: evidence from D8 countries.
ment. Eur Econ Rev 45(4–6):847–859
The Pakistan Development Review, 437-458.
Hadri K (2000) Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data. Econ
Romer P (1989) Human capital and growth: theory and evidence (No.
J 3:148–161
w3173). National Bureau of economic research
Halicioglu F, Ketenci N (2018) Output, renewable and non-renewable
Rosenthal S, Strange W (2004) Evidence on the nature and sources of
energy production, and international trade: evidence from EU-15
agglomeration economies. In: Handbook of Regional and Urban
countries. Energy 159:995–1002
Economics, vol 4, pp 2119–2171
Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics.
Econometrica, 1251-1271. Saboori B, Sulaiman J (2013) CO2 emissions, energy consumption and
Henderson V, Wang H (2007) Urbanization and city growth: the role of economic growth in association of southeast Asian nations
institutions. Reg Sci Urban Econ 37(3):283–313 (ASEAN) countries: A cointegration approach. Energy 55:813–822
Henderson V (2000) The effects of urban concentration on economic Sachs J, Warner A (2001) The curse of natural resources. Eur Econ Rev
growth (No. w7503). National bureau of economic research 45(4–6):827–838
Henderson V (2003) The urbanization process and economic growth: the Salim R, Shafiei S (2014) Urbanization and renewable and non-
so-what question. J Econ Growth 8(1):47–71 renewable energy consumption in OECD countries: an empirical
Henderson V (2005) Urbanization and growth. Handb Econ Growth 1: analysis. Econ Model 38:581–591
1543–1591 Salim R, Hassan K, Shafiei S (2014) Renewable and non-renewable
Henderson V (2010) Cities and development. J Reg Sci 50(1):515–540 energy consumption and economic activities: further evidence from
Hwang J (2006) Introduction of new goods, convergence and growth, vol OECD countries. Energy Econ 44:350–360
15. Department of Economics, Harvard University Singer H (1950) The distribution of gains between investing and borrow-
Jedwab R, Vollrath D (2015) Urbanization without growth in historical ing countries. Am Econ Rev 40(2):473–485
perspective. Explor Econ Hist 58:1–21 Sinha A, Sengupta T, Alvarado R (2019) Interplay between technological
Jedwab R, Christiaensen L, Gindelsky M (2015) Demography, urbaniza- innovation and environmental quality: formulating the SDG policies
tion and development: rural push, urban pull and urban push? The for next 11 economies. J Clean Prod 242(1):118549 In Press
World Bank, Washington, D. C Working Paper United Nations (2014) World urbanization prospects, the 2011 revision.
Kanjilal K, Ghosh S (2013) Environmental Kuznets’s curve for India: Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs,
evidence from tests for cointegration with unknown structural Washington D.C
breaks. Energy Policy 56:509–515 Westerlund J (2007) Testing for error correction in panel data. Oxf Bull
Lee C (2005) Energy consumption and GDP in developing countries: a Econ Stat 69(6):709–748
cointegrated panel analysis. Energy Econ 27(3):415–427 Williamson J (1965) Regional inequality and the process of national
Levin A, Lin C, Chu C (2002) Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic development: a description of the patterns. Econ Dev Cult Chang
and finite-sample properties. J Econ 108(1):1–24 13(4, part 2):1–84
Liu Y (2009) Exploring the relationship between urbanization and energy Wooldridge J (1991) On the application of robust, regression-based diag-
consumption in China using ARDL (autoregressive distributed lag) nostics to models of conditional means and conditional variances. J
and FDM (factor decomposition model). Energy 34(11):1846–1854 Econ 47(1):5–46
Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Wooldridge J (2002) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel
Econ 22(1):3–42 data. MIT Press, Cambridge
2772 Environ Sci Pollut Res (2020) 27:2760–2772

World Bank (2009). Informe sobre el desarrollo mundial 2009. Una Zafar MW, Shahbaz M, Hou F, Sinha A (2019) From nonrenewable to
nueva geografía económica. Washington DC, disponible en http:// renewable energy and its impact on economic growth: the role of
siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2009/Resources/WDR_ research & development expenditures in Asia-Pacific economic co-
OVERVIEW_ES_Web.pdf (visitado por última vez el 22/2/2010) operation countries. J Clean Prod 212:1166–1178
World Bank (2018). World Development Indicators, Washington D.C. Zhang Z, Zhang A, Wang D, Li A, Song H (2017) How to improve the
World Bank. (2018). Atlas Method GNI per capita, Washington D.C. performance of carbon tax in China? J Clean Prod 142:2060–2072
Yang Y, Liu J, Zhang Y (2017) An analysis of the implications of China’s Zhao Y, Wang S (2015) The relationship between urbanization, economic
urbanization policy for economic growth and energy consumption. J growth and energy consumption in China: an econometric perspec-
Clean Prod 161:1251–1262 tive analysis. Sustainability 7(5):5609–5627
Yao X, Zhou H, Zhang A, Li A (2015) Regional energy efficiency, carbon
emission performance and technology gaps in China: A meta-
Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdic-
frontier non-radial directional distance function analysis. Energy
tional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Policy 84:142–154
Young A (1991) Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of interna-
tional trade. Q J Econ 106(2):369–405

You might also like