You are on page 1of 7

PERSPECTIVES

Crisis in Indian Agriculture population but only to provide a source


of livelihood to the poor. The gross
irrigated area increased notably from
Can It be Overcome? 23 million hectares in 1950–51 to 93
million hectares in 2013–14, that is, by
four times.
M V Nadkarni Tremendous diversification has taken
place in agriculture in post-independ-

P
The crisis in Indian agriculture, olicymakers and agricultural ex- ence India. At the time of independence,
which has been building up for perts often focus more on increas- agriculture was dominated by the pro-
ing the productivity of land than duction of foodgrains. In the following
decades, is not one of declining
the welfare of the farmer. Increasing land decades, not only crop diversification has
profitability but of non-viability and water productivity is important, but taken place but substantial progress has
of the bulk of landholdings. The it is only instrumental in improving the been made in animal husbandry, horti-
number of these holdings is fast welfare of the farmer and his family. The culture, and floriculture. From being a net
welfare of the people at large cannot be importer, India has become a net exporter.
increasing, and even the extent
brought about by neglecting the farmer. As a result, the annual compound rate of
of non-viable land in the total Recognising the importance of the agri- growth of the agricultural part of the
cultivable area is expanding. cultural producer and “to take care of gross domestic product (GDP) at constant
Merely boosting the productivity the needs of the farming community,” prices increased from 2.18% between
the Government of India recently re- 1950–51 and 1970–71 to 2.96% between
of smallholdings is not sufficient,
named the ministry of food and agri- 1971–72 and 1990–91 and further to
and their non-viability hinders culture as the ministry of agriculture 3.02% between 1991–92 and 2012–13
capital formation in agriculture. and farmers’ welfare. When we speak (Nadkarni 2016: 80).
The main reason behind the crisis of the farmer, however, the hired agri- Another achievement in the agricul-
cultural labourer is also included as tural sector may surprise a few, as it is
is that employment opportunities
he is also a producer in his own right. contrary to what is normally believed.
in non-agricultural sectors are not But, if the farmer himself is in penury, Instability in the production, area, and
growing fast enough. how can we expect him to pay a fair yield of foodgrains, not necessarily at
wage for labour? A crisis in agriculture the individual farm levels or even at the
affects all those who depend on it for district levels, but at the aggregated
livelihood, and that is a substantial part national level has decreased. While ana-
of the population. lysing the three periods 1950–51 to
1970–71 (20 years), 1971–72 to 1990–91
Achievements and Progress (20 years), and 1991–92 to 2012–13 (22
Before we discuss the crisis, let us take years), it was found that the coefficient
note of the huge progress that has taken of variation adjusted for the trend con-
place in the agriculture sector in the last sistently declined from period to period
six decades to get a balanced view. in production, area as well as in the yield
While India’s population increased 3.5 per hectare of foodgrains (Nadkarni 2016:
times from 361 million in 1951 to about 76). The same thing was observed in the
1,270 million in 2014, India’s foodgrain agricultural GDP at constant prices be-
production increased during the same tween the same periods (Nadkarni 2016:
period by five times from 51 million 80). This decreasing instability may have
An earlier version of this article was delivered tonnes to 253 million tonnes and milk been due to an increase in irrigation and
as the 15th Professor L S Venkataramanan agricultural diversification. There may
production by 8.6 times from 17 million
Memorial Lecture at the ISEC, Bengaluru,
on 14 February 2017. Thanks are due to
tonnes to 146 million tonnes. This made be considerable fluctuations at the dis-
Khalil Shah of the Institute for Social and India self-reliant in food, mainly through aggregated levels, but the country as a
Economic Change for promptly providing the an increase in yields and cropping inten- whole has the resilience to deal with
requested data. sity. The net sown area under cultiva- downfall anywhere by rushing support
M V Nadkarni (mvnadkarni1968@gmail.com) tion increased between 1950–51 and to those who suffer. Where then is the
is an economist and honorary visiting 2012–13 by less than 18% in the course of crisis? Our agricultural sector may have
professor at the Institute for Social and 62 years. This happened not because it done fairly well so far, but unless its
Economic Change, Bengaluru.
was needed for feeding the growing unhealthy internal contradictions are
28 APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
PERSPECTIVES

resolved it may collapse, with tragic 65%, compared with India’s less than 43%. political pressures from vested interests
human implications. Rain-fed areas in India produce nearly half have come in the way of more equitable
of the country’s crop output. This is one and economical use of water. With a more
Farmer Suicides reason why the average productivity per economical and equitable use of water
A high incidence of suicides by farmers hectare in Indian agriculture is lower than and rational choice of crops, it should be
since the 1990s (Deshpande and Arora in China. Under the circumstances, one of possible to irrigate more lands now even
2010) has been witnessed. Going by the the biggest challenges for India has been with the given availability of water.
National Crime Records Bureau of India to develop some resilience at least against The development of wise irrigation
statistics, nearly three lakh farmers com- minor droughts. Whatever success we have management and adaptation strategies to
mitted suicide in India between 1995 and had in the past in meeting this challenge is face water shortage is becoming critically
2013. Ballabh and Batra (2016) observe no guarantee of its success in the future. important in the face of global warming
that the actual number of farmers’ suicides It is particularly distressing that though or climate change. Birthal et al (2014) have
may have been higher because some states the proportion of irrigated area is on the warned that their projections indicate a
did not initially report suicides during whole low in the country, several states loss of agricultural productivity in India
this period. Also, some of the suicides have already reached the upper limits of due to rising temperatures by 6% in the
were not included in the statistics because sustainable irrigation, with groundwater short term (by 2035), 12% in the medium
according to the police those committing being overexploited. It was tube well irri- term (by 2065), and 16% in the long term
them were not recorded as farmers. Only gation which gave a boost to the green (by 2100). The rise in temperature will
those owning land were considered as revolution, but it is precisely in the major require more irrigation to alleviate its
farmers and those taking land on informal foodgrain producing states that the ex- impact on agriculture. An economical use
lease and cultivating were not. Actually, traction rates of groundwater are unsus- of water to extend the benefits of irriga-
these informal tenants are more vulner- tainably high. These states are Punjab, tion to more areas is thus urgent. Birthal
able and face higher risks. Reports on some Haryana, Uttar Pradesh, Rajasthan, et al (2014: 484) further observe that it is
suicides were deliberately suppressed or Karnataka, and Tamil Nadu. The incidence possible to extend irrigation to further
underestimated by state governments of failed wells is also fairly high. Only in 25% to 30% of area by conservation in
(Ballabh and Batra 2016: 381). Farmers’ a few states, the potential of groundwater existing irrigated areas and also by rain-
suicides are the most telling and poignant irrigation is not yet fully realised. These water harvesting. Narayanamoorthy and
symptom of the human crisis facing Indian are mainly the eastern states such as Deshpande (2005) have pointed out that
agriculture. It is a systemic or structural Bihar, West Bengal, Assam, Jharkhand and technologies like drip irrigation, which
crisis, if not a total crisis in all aspects. Odisha (Sasmal 2014: 231–32). The scope conserve water and enable the extension
This crisis has not suddenly emerged, for further extending canal irrigation by of given irrigation water to more areas,
but has been building up since decades building more big dams is limited because even though capital intensive, are econo-
and needs to be analysed. they have huge negative externalities in mically viable. This would be even more
the form of loss of forest areas and dis- so if water is taken into account at its eco-
Inefficient Use of Irrigation Water placement of human beings. There is, logical or scarcity value and not the face
First, we need to note that India’s agricul- however, scope for minor projects, includ- value at which the farmer gets it.
ture is even now largely rain-fed, and ing watershed development, rainwater
rainfall is tending to become more erratic harvesting, and recharging groundwater Surplus Workforce in Agriculture
and uncertain. Marginal lands which were aquifers (Chandrakanth et al 2004; We can price inputs scientifically at their
and should have been left as forests are Chandrakanth 2015). scarcity value for an industry if it is com-
now being cultivated. The bulk of culti- Despite scarcity of water, irrigation is mercially viable. If it is not, and if the
vated area in India is quite vulnerable to not practised efficiently. Large chunks of survival of the industry is important for
climate change. It is common now for irrigated areas have gone out of cultiva- the economy and from a humanitarian
farmers in some parts of the country to tion due to salinity which occurs due to angle, as in agriculture, there should be
experience prolonged droughts and unsea- over-irrigation or growing water-intensive limits to treating it as a normal business
sonal rains, resulting in huge crop losses. crops in places where lightly irrigated enterprise which could be charged ration-
India’s situation becomes clear when crops are more desirable. There have been ally for the inputs. Subsidisation and
contrasted with China. While China has some technological breakthroughs in re- support would be inevitable no matter
over three times more total land than India, cent years in the method of cultivation of what the World Trade Organization (WTO)
its arable area is only about 112 million water-intensive crops like rice (like the might say. Ironically, even industries
hectares, which is less than India’s 155 System of Rice Intensification), which have that are in a much more favourable situ-
million hectares in 2012–13. In other words, shown that an economical use of water ation get direct and indirect subsidies as
while only 11.3% of total land area is under can actually increase productivity not incentives for investment and employ-
agriculture in China, nearly 53% of land only per unit of water, but also per unit of ment creation. The structural weakne-
is under agriculture in India. But the pro- land. Growing more sugar cane than we sses of agriculture have been pointed out
portion of irrigated area in China is over actually need is one of the instances of how before by several economists including
Economic & Political Weekly EPW APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 29
PERSPECTIVES

V M Dandekar (1976, 1994), V K R V Rao non-agricultural sectors. That has indeed The case of Kenya is conspicuous. It
(1983), V M Rao (1994) and Rao and been the pattern of economic growth has the highest relative income per worker
Hanumappa (1999), but they are worsen- almost all over the world. The relative in agriculture, which is more than twice as
ing with the passage of time. Dandekar income per agricultural worker declines high as compared to average per worker
had summed up the situation thus: only if employment absorption from the income in non-agricultural sectors. Kenya
(T)he problem of Indian agriculture is the agricultural into non-agricultural sectors gained independence in 1963, and since
disproportionately large burden of population is slower than the rate of growth of agri- then its population has doubled. Only
which it has to bear and which causes net
culture. Table 2 compares an Indian ag- 15.9% of its workforce in 2011 was in agri-
capital consumption rather than capital cre-
ation in agriculture. Hence, to transform tra- ricultural worker’s relative income with culture, contributing 29.3% of its gross
ditional subsistence agriculture into com- that in other countries. national product (GNP). Less than one-
mercially viable agriculture, the surplus The ratio is generally lower than one fifth of Kenya’s land is under cultivation.
population must be withdrawn from agricul-
in all countries except Kenya, where it is The secret of Kenya’s high relative income
ture, that is, from current operations of cul-
tivation, and conditions must be created above two. Kenya is followed by Malaysia, per worker in agriculture lies in the culti-
whereby capital from outside agriculture Israel, the United States (US) and Australia vation of high-value crops. It is a leading
may flow into agriculture. (1994: 29) which also have high ratios, indicating producer of tea and coffee and also a lead-
How can the surplus population from practically no disparity bet ween agricul- ing exporter of fresh produce: cabbage,
agriculture be absorbed into other sec- ture and non-agricultural sectors in aver- onions, mangoes, and flowers. However,
tors? This can happen only if the eco- age per worker income. According to the the country is not yet self-sufficient in food.
nomic growth in other sectors is not only ratios in 2011, India ranked the third lowest There are striking differences between
significant but also creates employment among the selected 30 countries. What India and Kenya. In 2011, India had a
and does not cause displacement of labour. is particularly sad about India is that its population density of 382 people per
Unfortunately, despite the growth, these position in this respect has worsened over square kilometre; Kenya had only 66
sectors have not been able to absorb the last four decades, which is also the case people per square kilometre. The per
much of the surplus labour because they with the Philippines, Indonesia, Vietnam, capita total GDP of India in 2011 was
believe in economising on labour. The pro- Bangladesh, Mexico, and Sri Lanka. $1,460, while it was only $1,025 in Kenya.
portion of workforce engaged in agricul- However, quite a few countries have While the headcount ratio of poverty in
ture, taking both cultivators and labourers improved the per worker relative income India around 2011 was 22%, it was 42%
together, has declined only slowly over in agriculture—the most noticeable being in Kenya. Yet, it seems that on an average
the decades, from 69.8% in 1971 to 64.9% Malaysia, Israel and the US. These countries an agricultural worker in Kenya, by
in 1991, and further to 54.6% in 2011. In prove that per worker income in agricul- which one means both cultivators and
contrast, the share of agriculture in GDP ture need not be worse than that in other hired workers, must be earning more
at constant prices fell much more sharply sectors. They have achieved this mainly by than their Indian counterparts.
from 39.7% in 1970–71 to 29.5% in drawing a significant portion of their agri- Most of the hired agricultural labour
1990–91 and further to a mere 11.3% in cultural workforce into other sectors. Thus, in Kenya is organised into a country-
2010–11. The ratio of per worker income the share of agriculture in the total work- wide union to fight for their rights. In
in agriculture to the same in non-agricul- force which was as high as 48% in Malay- spite of the differences between the two
tural sectors, which was already low at sia in 1971 declined to 11.5% in 2011. In countries, we have to see if we can learn
only 0.28% in 1971, crashed to 0.15% in the US, it was already low at 4% in 1971 from Kenya’s experience in boosting
2011 (Table 1). Thus, the relative position and fell further to a mere 1.6% in 2011. income from agriculture through high-
of workers is worsening fast. Table 2: Ratio of per Worker Income in Agriculture* to per value crops, without ignoring
Worker Income in Non-agricultural Sectors in Selected Countries the fact that it is yet to achieve
(in Descending Order of the Ratio as in 2011)
Relative Income per Farm Worker 1971 2011 1971 2011 self-sufficiency in food and yet
Let us now look at the situation in India Kenya – 2.1889 Philippines 0.5536 0.2959 to remove poverty. It is likely
in an international context. The declin- Malaysia 0.430 0.995 Brazil 0.2865 0.2888 that there is great inequality
Israel 0.7087 0.9491 Japan 0.2290 0.2816
ing share of agriculture both in GDP and US 0.565 0.854 Indonesia 0.4571 0.2753
in the Kenyan agricultural
total employment has been observed in Australia – 0.8480 Vietnam 0.3510** 0.2378 sector, more than in India,
all countries due to the faster growth Algeria – 0.7791 Bangladesh 0.3661 0.2378 particularly between cash crop
of both income and employment in New Zealand – 0.7345 S Korea – 0.2327 producers and subsistence
UK – 0.6247 Chile – 0.2304 producers and between cash
Table 1: Declining Relative Income per Worker
in Agriculture S Africa 0. 1878 0.5361 Mexico 0.2354 0.224
Russia – 0.4942 Sri Lanka 0.3648 0.2156
crop cultivators and labo-
Share (%) of Agriculture in: 1971 1991 2011
GDP at constant prices 39.7 29.5 11.3 Pakistan 0.4157 0.4281 Tanzania – 0.2046 urers. This would suggest
Total workforce 69.8 64.9 54.6 Egypt – 0.4119 China 0.1211 0.1974 that merely aiming for a high
Ratio of per worker GDP in Uzbekistan – 0.3748 India 0.2610 0.1890 relative income per worker
agriculture to per worker GDP EU – 0.3565 Thailand 0.1223 0.1888 on an average may not solve
in non-agricultural sectors 0.28 0.23 0.15 Nigeria – 0.3033 Iran – 0.1802
*Including forestry and fishery. ** For the year 1991.
the problem of poverty with-
Source: Calculated from National Accounts Statistics of CSO
and Population Census. Source: Calculated by the author from data in World Bank (2016). in agriculture.
30 APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
PERSPECTIVES

This article tries to probe whether there hectares in 1970–71 to 1.84 hectares in to make them viable? This was exactly
is any evidence of the relative income 1980–81, to 1.33 hectares in 2000–01, what the green revolution did, but it also
per agricultural worker vis-à-vis that of and further down to just 1.11 hectares in commercialised agriculture as never be-
non-agricultural worker increasing with 2010–11. This is not due to agricultural fore. The farmers had to buy inputs like
the increase in per capita GDP across areas being put to non-agricultural uses, seeds, fertilisers, and pesticides from
countries. However, the rank correlation since the decline in the total operated the market. Farm operations had to be
coefficient between the ratio of income land has been relatively small, only 2.3% completed in the shortest time possible.
per agricultural worker over income per over the four decades. But, during the same The larger holdings could easily overcome
non-agricultural worker and the per cap- period, the number of operational holdings the disadvantage of having less family la-
ita total GDP across the 30 selected coun- nearly doubled, increasing from 70 million bour per hectare through mechanisation
tries turned out to be only +0.30, which in 1970–71 to 138.3 million (Table 3). of farm operations. They could go for
was not statistically significant, though One may say, averages can hide ine- bore wells or tube wells which the small
positive. The case of Kenya is one of a quality. Dantwala had once observed farmers could not afford. Credit was also
negative relation bet ween the two. that Indian agriculture might have been more easily available to the large farmers
However, several high-income countries dominated by small farmers but not by than to the smaller ones. Though it was
have also higher ratios of relative income small farms, since the proportion of claimed by the enthusiasts of the green
per agricultural worker. Relatively high- large and medium farms together, that revolution that it was scale-neutral be-
income countries like Malaysia, Israel, the is all those holdings above the size of cause inputs like seeds and fertilisers
US, South Africa and Japan and middle- two hectares which were expected to be were quite divisible according to the size
income countries like China and Thai- viable, accounted for over 78% of the to- of the holdings, in actual practice, small
land achieved an increase in the relative tal operated land in 1970–71. In 2010–11, farmers were put under stress. They had
income per agricultural worker along this proportion declined to 55%. We may to buy inputs from the market, whereas
with economic growth compared to their feel that even now they operate a little earlier they were self-reliant, using
position in 1971. However, the Philippines, over half of the total area, but that is not home-grown seeds and farmyard ma-
Indonesia, Vietnam, Bangladesh, Mexico, likely to be so in future, say in 2020–21. nure. The monetisation of inputs made
Sri Lanka, and India suffered a decline in The proportion of the number of hold- the viability question sharper still.
this regard. Pakistan and Brazil maintained ings above two hectares declined from Another way of improving the viability
or very slightly improved their position. A 30% to just 15% between 1970–71 and of small farmers is to shift to high-value
declining ratio is worrisome in the case of 2010–11. These holdings have also been crops like vegetables and flowers. Their
India because even in 1971 the relative facing a fast decline in their average dependence on market inputs may not
position of the agricultural workers was size, though not as much as in the over- decline by such a shift, but their depend-
already low, and it has significantly dete- all average for all holdings. ence on the market for selling increases
riorated in the 40 years thereafter. The proportion of holdings which can- sharply. Unless these high-value crops are
not earn enough income for the farmer produced under arrangements like con-
Declining Size of Landholdings to feed his or her family and invest in his tract farming, their viability for farmers
The continuously declining average size or her farm, that is below two hectares, might not improve vastly. Unfortunately,
of holdings in India due to its agriculture increased in number from 70% in 1970– even contract farming does not cover
being “crowded” has been noted by many 71 to 85% in 2010–11. The average size of many farmers. The minimum support price
(Joshi 2015). The average size of an op- these small and marginal holdings toge- regime is expected to protect farmers
erational holding has declined from 2.28 ther increased somewhat from 0.48 hec- against a crash in post-harvest prices. But,
Table 3: Growing Structural Weakness in Indian Agriculture tares in 1970–71 to 0.60 hec- the bulk of farm produce is not covered
1970–71 1980–81 2000–01 2010–11 tares in 2010–11. But this is by this regime. Even where crops are
Proportion (%) of operational small consolation as it has eligible or are covered, farmers, particu-
holdings with 2 hectares or below 70 75 82 85
taken place because of the larly in distant corners, are either not
Proportion (%) of area operated
by holdings with 2 hectares or below 22 26 39 45
subdivision of viable hold- aware of it or do not have access to it.
Proportion (%) of operational ings due to population pres- Deshpande, therefore, has described this
holdings with more than 2 hectares 30 25 18 15 sure. Unless the population so-called facility as the “Moon in the
Proportion (%) of area operated pressure on agriculture is Mirror” (Deshpande and Naika 2004).
by holdings with more than 2 hectares 78 74 61 55
reversed, Indian agriculture Uncertainty in prices is still a major chal-
Average size of all holdings 2.28 1.84 1.33 1.11
Average size of holdings with
would be dominated not lenge for all the farmers, particularly for
2 hectares or below 0.48 0.48 0.63 0.60 only by small farms but also the small, and this uncertainty specially
Average size of holdings with by small farms accounting affects producers of fruit and vegetables.
more than 2 hectares 6.00 5.33 4.43 4.25
for more than half of the Even at the retail level, tomato prices per
Total number of operational holdings
(in million) 70.1 88.8 119.9 138.3
total land. kilo have fluctuated from `5 to `80 re-
Total operated area (in million hectares) 162.1 163.8 159.4 158.3 Well, why not increase the cently. Being perishable, the adoption of
Source: Agricultural Statistics at a Glance. producti vity of smallholdings such crops is particularly risky. It is said
Economic & Political Weekly EPW APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 31
PERSPECTIVES

that the farmer is the only producer who inputs used in National Income Accounts, should be higher and positive in most of
is penalised for producing more. have gone increasingly in its favour the cases on an average.
since 1980–81 (Nadkarni 2016: 83). The crisis in Indian agriculture is, there-
Profitability Agriculture In view of the near constancy in the fore, neither one of decline or stagnation
There is a general impression that profit- ratios of agricultural output over inputs in productivity nor one of adverse terms
ability of Indian agriculture has declined in real terms, an improvement of terms of of trade any more, though particular crops
in general. At the national level, the ratios trade in favour of agriculture does indi- or states concerned may need some atten-
of agricultural output to inputs at con- cate an increase in profitability. Thus, the tion. There is no general crisis of profit-
stant prices (calculated from National impression of a general decline in the ability as such. A crop grown on a tiny
Accounts Statistics) have been more or profitability of agriculture is not true at farm, even if highly profitable in terms
less constant around the mean at 2.62 least at the aggregate level. Therefore, this of rate of return over cost, may not make
between 1980–81 and 2012–13 and showed hypothesis has to be examined at the level the farm viable in itself if the total abso-
no statistically significant trend. The of individual crops in selected individual lute profit is not enough to take the fam-
highest level of the ratio was 2.84 in states known for growing them (Table 4). ily above the poverty level.
1996–97 and the lowest was 2.46 in Table 4 presents a mixed picture. Tak- The crisis in Indian agriculture is struc-
1987–88 (Nadkarni 2016: 83). The terms ing the important crop of paddy first and tural in nature and is quite basic. It is a
of trade of agriculture, calculated by ignoring Uttarakhand (which was a part crisis of viability itself, arising from the
dividing the GDP deflator for agricul- of Uttar Pradesh during the first period, non-viable size of holdings, and has deep-
tural output by the same for agricultural and no separate data for it is available), ened over the last several decades. Though
Table 4: Average Rates of Profit (% over the C1, C2 and Revised C2) profitability has declined in the crisis of viability is not a crisis of profit-
in Selected Crops and States in India five states out of eight and in- ability per se, it is certainly not good for
Crop State TE 1983–84 TE 2013–14
creased in the remaining private capital formation in agriculture
Cost C1 Cost C2 Cost C1 Cost C2 Revised
Cost2 three. Whether this differ- and its long-term profitability. What prof-
Paddy Andhra Pradesh 51.6 7.7 72.4 13.6 13.3 ence is due to better procure- itability we may find today might not be
Assam 44.8f 11.0f -7.2 -24.2 -24.2 ment and support operations sustainable in the long run as agriculture
Bihar 110.2 24.4 17.3 -6.3 -6.8 in these three states (Andhra is becoming increasingly non-viable.
Odisha 71.4d 24.0d 6.0 -16.3 -16.9
Pradesh, Punjab and Uttar
Punjab 63.0g 20.1g 163.0 39.6 39.5 Viability Crisis
Pradesh) needs further prob-
Tamil Nadu 53.7a 17.3a 31.6 9.7 9.7
Uttar Pradesh 43.0 8.2 60.4 19.1 18.7
ing. For wheat, another im- An important implication of non-viability
Uttarakhand – – 42.9 9.5 6.7 portant cereal, there is an in- of agriculture is its vulnerability to cri-
West Bengal 68.4 b 20.1 b 13.4 -11.6 -11.6 crease in profitability in all ses. A sufficiently viable holding should be
Wheat Haryana 65.0 27.0 120.2 38.3 36.9 the four states for which data able to earn enough for the cultivator so
Madhya Pradesh 74.2f 21.7f 137.5 49.0 48.8 for both periods are available. that he can not only meet his family’s
Chhattisgarh – – 27.0 -3.6 -3.6 We may recall that wheat is consumption needs and current inputs
Punjab 59.3g 19.2g 178.2 42.9 41.7
the best procured crop. As far costs but also able to save something for
Uttar Pradesh 59.8d 22.8d 85.5 25.8 23.6
as jowar is concerned, there investments and meet any exigencies
Uttarakhand – – 85.4 27.3 24.5
Jowar Karnataka 70.1 27.9 45.4 8.7 8.1
is a decline in profitability in like a crash in production either due to
Maharashtra 46.2c 18.2c 10.3 -6.9 -7.0 both the major jowar grow- droughts or pest attacks.
Gram Madhya Pradesh 106.8 g 36.7 g 92.6 30.0 29.7 ing states, Karnataka and The structural weakness of Indian
Chhattisgarh – – 46.5 7.2 6.8 Maharashtra. The profitability agriculture makes it unprepared to tackle
Uttar Pradesh 90.0f 32.5f 47.5 5.5 4.8 of growing gram has declined climate change and to remain resilient.
Sugar cane Maharashtra 79.3e 39.5e 94.4 46.8 46.2 in both the states for which Struck by a drought, a non-viable farmer
Uttar Pradesh 160.6 77.9 172.2 69.2 69.2 data is available for both pe- tends to sell his productive assets like
Uttarakhand – – 151.2 74.5 73.8
riods. If we look at groundnut, bullocks because he cannot get loans for
Groundnut Andhra Pradesh 39.7 -1.4 60.0 8.1 7.6
Gujarat 47.4c 19.4c 48.3 19.1 18.8
while profitability has incre- meeting consumption needs in a dro-
Cotton Gujarat 40.4 14.2 68.4 31.9 31.7 ased in Andhra Pradesh, it has ught. Even when the situation returns to
Maharashtra 29.1 7.2 26.3 4.3 4.3 remained more or less the normal, he would still be unable to culti-
(i) TE – Triennial average ending with the year indicated. same in Gujarat. As for cotton, vate due to the loss of productive assets.
(ii) C1 = All actual expenses in cash and kind incurred in production by owner,
interest on value of owned capital assets (excluding land), and imputed
there is an increase in its Moreover, even if a farmer takes a loan
value of family labour. profitability in Gujarat, but a for meeting investment needs, he should
(iii) C2 = C1 + rental value of owned land (net of land revenue) and rent paid
for leased-in land.
slight decline in Maharashtra. earn enough surplus over current costs
(iv) Revised C 2 = Cost C2 estimated by taking into account statutory The rates of return as calcu- and consumption to return the loan and
minimum or actual wage whichever is higher.
(v) a = 1979–80 to 1981–82; b = 1982–83 to 1984–85; c = 1982–83 to
lated here are over costs, pay interest by instalments at least. Non-
1986–87; d = 1983–84 to 1986–87; e = 1983–84 to 1987–88; f = 1984–85 to which include the imputed viable farmers sometimes cannot do that
1986–87; g = 1985–86 to 1987–88; and (-) = not available or undivided state.
Source: Computed from CACP Kharif and Rabi Price Policy Reports covering
cost of family labour. The cash because either the holding is not viable
several marketing seasons Nadkarni (1993: 29). rates of return, therefore, enough to make the investment paying,
32 APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
PERSPECTIVES

or because of crop loss, or because of a To add to the woes of farmers, the needs of small farmers and other such
post-harvest crash in the prices. When Bharatiya Janata Party-led government in measures can only help the farmers to a
he cannot return a loan, he loses face, 2015 attempted to dilute the historic pro- limited extent. These will not help in the
cannot get further loans, and thinks of farmer Right to Fair Compensation and long run because these do not address the
an escapist solution in the form of sui- Transparency in Land Acquisition, Reha- basic structural weakness of agriculture
cide, with the hope that his family may bilitation and Resettlement Act of 2013 which lies in the small or non-viable size of
get some relief or compensation from the through an amendment. The amendment agricultural holdings. These holdings are
government after his death. The increas- sought to make the acquisition of agricul- tending to become smaller and smaller,
ing dependence on the government to tural land by industries easier. When the and it is this problem that has to be solved.
tide over crises is a sure sign of increas- attempt to amend the law through a series
ing non-viability and vulnerability. of land ordinances failed, the central Suggested Measures
Earlier, the marginal and small farm- government encouraged the states to Any measures undertaken to resolve the
ers could survive because they had com- pass their own land acquisition laws. It is crisis in agriculture cannot ignore the lot
mon lands where they could graze their reported that some states like Tamil Nadu, of agricultural labourers or wage workers.
animals and extract a good deal of their Gujarat, and Telangana have already Their proportion in the total agricultural
biomass needs both for their farms and passed laws or amendments which do workforce has been steadily increasing
homes. These common lands, which had not incorporate the safeguards built into in India since 1961, from 24.0% in 1961 to
earlier informally subsidised these farm- the 2013 act (Ramesh and Khan 2016). 45.6% in 2001, and to 54.9% in 2011. For
ers and made them viable, have greatly The 2013 act not only requires fair the first time, agricultural labourers have
declined in size and number now and have compensation, rehabilitation and reset- outnumbered farmers now. It is neces-
become non-existent or at least insignifi- tlement of farmers whose lands are to be sary that any policy on agriculture should
cant in most places. Farmers, particularly acquired, but also calls for a proper social seek to improve their living standards,
with larger holdings, used to grow trees impact assessment of the project which but a real improvement in their conditions
suitable for leaf manure and fodder. Now involves land acquisition. This provision is cannot be expected unless the viability
with increased pressure on land, resulting perceived by many as not being business- of agriculture improves.
in subdivision of holdings, every inch of friendly. There is no doubt that cultivation Some agricultural workers, both culti-
it tends to be used for crop cultivation in India has been extended to even mar- vators and labourers, have been trying
with little space left for growing trees. ginal lands and that the area under culti- to overcome this crisis by seeking em-
Regular rotational or seasonal fallow- vation is relatively much higher than in ployment in nearby towns or cities,
ing was practised by farmers earlier in other countries. However, a significant without giving up agriculture altogether.
order to enable the soil to replenish its portion of this cultivated land is now They commute to cities almost daily for
fertility. Now the farmers are not volun- degraded. This seems to suggest that there work while still residing in villages and
tarily following the practice and tend to is a case for transferring some land, parti- cling on to their agricultural holdings as
leave their land fallow only during dro- cularly if degraded, for non-agricultural a source of security. However, this can-
ughts. Considerations of sustainability uses. But this cannot be done arbitrarily not be a sustainable solution to the via-
are sacrificed on the whole now, making without instituting safeguards for farmers. bility crisis in agriculture.
agriculture more vulnerable to climate The 2013 act does not ban the transfer of To solve this problem, policymakers
change. Thus, the structural weakness land from agriculture to non-agricultural should aim to maximise employment in
of agriculture affects not only its viability, sectors, but only imposes safeguards for the non-agricultural and agricultural
but also its sustainability. protecting farmers’ rights so that they do sectors, rather than concentrating on
The structural weakness of Indian agri- not become destitute. Any amendment or maximising economic growth rates per
culture is also affecting the health of the state law which can result in increasing the se. Between 2000 and 2010, India’s na-
land adversely. It is estimated that about extent of destitution in agriculture, even tional output grew at an unprecedented
96.4 million hectares of India’s land area, if it is in the name of stepping up growth, rate of 7.7% per annum, but employment
which constitutes 29.3% of the total land is meaningless and has to be resisted. A grew only by a mere 0.3% per annum
mass of the country, was degraded during further loss of land without reducing the (Joshi 2016: 60). Such jobless growth
2011–13. In 2003–05, for which a compa- dependence on agriculture as a source of has only increased the dependence on
rable estimate is available, the extent of livelihood for the rural population would agriculture since it has to absorb the re-
degraded area was 94.5 million hectares only further reduce the size of holdings sidual workforce.
(Chaudhury and Roy 2016). This trend is and undermine the viability of agriculture. More than a century ago, Mahatma
disturbing, for in less than a decade, nearly Agriculture in the country cannot devel- Gandhi had given much thought to the
two million hectares of precious land have op further without addressing its basic relative poverty of farmers and their
been lost to degradation or desertification. structural weakness. Stepping up the pro- underemployment and had advocated
This has added to the structural crisis in ductivity per hectare, growing high value supplementing their income by income
agriculture since effective or usable land crops, subsidising agricultural inputs, ex- from cottage industries, including hand-
per cultivator has been further reduced. tending marketing support tailored to the spinning and khadi, first in his book Hind
Economic & Political Weekly EPW APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 33
PERSPECTIVES

Swaraj (published first in 1909) and then In addition to maximising employ- References
in his subsequent writings (Parel 2010). ment opportunities outside agriculture Ballabh, Vishwa and Pooja Batra (2016): “Farmers
in Distress and Resources under Stress: A Com-
His advice seems to have relevance even so as to absorb agricultural workers, pletely Neglected Subject,” Vicissitudes of Agri-
now. Things would have been better if there is also a need to directly address culture in the Fast Growing Indian Economy,
C Ramasamy and K R Ashok (eds), New Delhi:
we had cared to follow the Gandhian the problem of non-viability. Of course, Academic Foundation, pp 377–400.
model of decentralised village-based de- measures like increasing the productivity Birthal, P S et al (2014): “How Sensitive Is Indian
Agriculture to Climate Change?” Indian Journal
velopment at least to some extent. This of crops, growing high-value crops, and of Agricultural Economics, Vol 69, No 4, pp 474–87.
would have been environment-friendly diversification of agriculture should Chandrakanth, M G (2015): Water Resource Economics:
Towards a Sustainable Use of Water for Irriga-
and would have helped minimise the im- continue. But, besides these, there has to tion in India, New Delhi: Springer.
pact of climate change (Nadkarni 2015). be an effective and widespread move- Chandrakanth, M G, B Alamelu and M G Bhat (2004):
“Combating Negative Externalities of Drought:
Economic sectors that have higher em- ment for consolidation of non-viable Ground Water Recharge through Watershed
ployment intensity should be identified. holdings into viable ones. Farmers par- Development Programme,” Economic & Political
Weekly, Vol 39, No 11, pp 1164–70.
Decentralised industries, which are scat- ticipating in this movement should be Chaudhury, Sriroop and Mimi Roy (2016): “Halting
tered all over the country, can provide ei- given special incentives. Desertification,” Deccan Herald, 15 November, p 10.
CACP (various years): Kharif and Rabi Price Policy
ther part-time or full-time employment Farmers selling non-viable holdings Reports, Commission for Agricultural Costs and
in rural areas and should be particularly should be assured of not only a fair price Prices, Department of Agriculture and Cooper-
ation, Ministry of Agriculture, Government of
encouraged. Agro-processing units in the for their land, but also alternative em- India, New Delhi.
small-scale sector have a great growth ployment opportunities. Banks should Dandekar, V M (1976): “Crop Insurance in India,”
Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 11, No 26.
potential and should be encouraged as extend credit to small farmers buying — (1994): “Transforming Traditional Agriculture:
far as possible without compromising on additional land to make their holdings A Critique of Professor Schultz,” Indian Economy
1947–92—Vol 1: Agriculture, New Delhi: Sage,
the quality of the product. The consum- viable. There should, however, be no pp 96–126.
ers, whether rural or urban, need to feel force or unreasonable pressure applied to Deshpande, R S and Saroj Arora (eds) (2010): Agricul-
tural Crisis and Farmer Suicides, New Delhi: Sage.
confident that the products of these in- sell non-viable holdings. If the farmers Deshpande, R S and T Raveendra Naika (2004):
dustries are not inferior to those pro- are not willing to sell their non-viable Moon in the Mirror: Farmers and Minimum Sup-
port Prices in Karnataka, Institute for Social &
duced by large-scale industries. holdings outright, they should be free to Economic Change, Bengaluru, Monograph 7.
These industries need to be given mar- lease out tiny holdings to a farmer who can Joshi, P K (2015): “Has Indian Agriculture Become
Crowded and Risky? Status, Implications and
keting support in innovative ways, which consolidate them into a viable one and the Way Forward,” Indian Journal of Agricultural
can be done even by the private sector. pay a fair rent. The lease market may have Economics, Vol 70, No 1, pp 1–41.
Joshi, Vijay (2016): India’s Long Road: The Search
Private industrial enterprises, which can to be liberalised and formally recognised for Prosperity, Gurgaon: Allen Lane.
assure quality control and provide mar- so as to make it possible for tenants to Nadkarni, M V (1993): Agricultural Policy: Issues,
Concepts and Instruments, Development Research
keting support, can adopt decentralised access bank credit for investment. Group, Study 5, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai,
small or cottage industries, and govern- The government should encourage February.
— (2015): “Gandhi’s Civilizational Alternative and
ment banks can provide them with credit cooperative farming under which not Dealing with Climate Change,” Journal of Social
support on a preferential basis. Decentral- only a large number of non-viable hold- & Economic Development, Vol 17, No 1, pp 90–103.
— (2016): “Indian Agriculture through Challenges—
ised economic sectors can spread techni- ings can be consolidated but even agro- Old and New,” Vicissitudes of Agriculture in the
cal and artistic skills and enterprising processing industries can be started. Fast Growing Indian Economy, C Ramasamy
and K R Ashok (eds), New Delhi: Academic
spirit even in rural areas and can coexist Special incentives can be offered to such Foundation, pp 71–85.
with large industries, where economies cooperative farming enterprises. How- Narayanamoorthy, A and R S Deshpande (2005):
Where Water Seeps!—Towards a New Phase in
of scale are conspicuous. An indiscrimi- ever, highly individualistic attitudes India’s Irrigation Reforms, New Delhi: Academic
nate resort to labour-saving devices has come in the way of getting together in a Foundation.
Parel, Anthony (ed) (2010): Gandhi—Hind Swaraj
to be checked somehow in large indus- joint cooperative spirit. Once economic and Other Writings, New Delhi: Cambridge
tries. Incentives may be devised for im- benefits of mutual trust and sociability University Press.
Ramasamy, C and K R Ashok (eds) (2016): Vicissi-
proving employment intensity of growth. are realised, a mighty force of economic tudes of Agriculture in the Fast Growing Indian
It is also necessary to improve the qual- enterprise and growth can be released for Economy—Challenges, Strategies and the Way
Forward, New Delhi: Academic Foundation.
ity of education available for rural people. the welfare of all involved. The forma- Ramesh, Jairam and Muhammad A Khan (2016):
Currently, education standards are so poor tion of dairy and sugar cooperatives and “Winking at the States,” Hindu, 2 November, p 10.
Rao, V K R V (1983): India’s National Income—
that many students enrolled in middle water markets in rural India is an exam- 1950–80, New Delhi: Sage.
school are not able to do simple arithmetic ple of institutional innovation. Can we Rao, V M (1994): “Farmers in Market Economy:
calculations, write a few sentences on their hope that the serious viability crisis af- Would Farmers Gain Through Liberalisation?”
Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics,
own, and read and understand a textbook fecting Indian agriculture might release Vol 49, No 3.
properly. Children of poor farmers and this potential force, which can boost the Rao, V M and H G Hanumappa (1999): “Marginalisa-
tion Process in Agriculture: Indicators, Outlook,
agricultural labourers cannot hope to get formation of social capital in the rural and Policy,” Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 34,
No 52.
more remunerative alternative employ- society? In any case, agricultural policy in Sasmal, Joydeb (2014): “Foodgrains Production in
ment opportunities with their poor edu- India should also take care of new institu- India—How Serious Is the Shortage of Water
Supply for Future Growth?” Indian Journal of
cational qualifications and are forced to tion building without giving up its old Agricultural Economics, Vol 69, No 2, pp 229–42.
depend on agriculture for their livelihood. concerns like stepping up productivity. World Bank (2016): “World Development Indicators.”

34 APRIL 28, 2018 vol lIiI no 17 EPW Economic & Political Weekly

You might also like