You are on page 1of 11

Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Land Use Policy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/landusepol

Let the cows graze: An empirical investigation on the trade-off between T


efficiency and farm animal welfare in milk production

Hinrich D. Schultea, , Linda Armbrechtb, Rasmus Bürgerc, Matthias Gaulyd, Oliver Musshoffa,
Silke Hüttele
a
Farm Management Group, Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Faculty of Agricultural Sciences, University of Goettingen, Platz der Göttinger
Sieben 5, 37073 Göttingen, Germany
b
Livestock Production System Group, Department of Animal Science, Faculty of Agricultural Sciences, University of Goettingen, Albrecht-Thaer-Weg 3, 37075 Göttingen,
Germany
c
Thaer-Institute, Faculty of Life Sciences, Humboldt Universität zu Berlin, Hannoversche Straße 27, 10115 Berlin, Germany
d
Faculty of Science and Technology, Free-University of Bolzano, Piazza Università 5, 39100 Bolzano, Italy
e
Production Economics Group, Institute of Food and Resource Economics, Bonn University, Meckenheimer Allee 174, 53115 Bonn, Germany

A R T I C LE I N FO A B S T R A C T

JEL classification: To investigate whether farm animal welfare comes at the cost of dairy farm performance, and the role that
D24 pasture-access thereby plays, we analyse a rich sample of 45 dairy farms in Germany with a scientific measure of
Q12 farm animal welfare. Based on directional efficiency measure that acknowledges sequential preferences such that
Q18 farm animal welfare becomes relevant after technical efficiency, we cannot find a trade-off between farm animal
Keywords: welfare and technical milk efficiency. Pasture-based production systems can be at least as efficient or even more
Farm animal welfare efficient compared to confinement systems, despite lower milk yields. Neglecting sequential preferences would
Technical efficiency bias efficiency in provision of farm animal welfare by pasture-systems. Farms from all types of dairy systems
Pasture
determine the efficient frontier, where efficiency increases with herd size, and is linked with higher profits. We
Milk production
conclude that pasture-access may help but does not guarantee higher levels of animal welfare. These results
Data envelopment analysis
question governmental support for pasture access regarding the provision of farm animal welfare.

1. Introduction argumentation, in complex production systems such as dairy, the most


profitable milk yield, as a measure of productivity, does not accompany
Farm animal welfare (FAW) has gained considerable attention in optimal levels of FAW. Against the backdrop that many consumers find
recent decades, with a notable influence on consumers’ food choices existing husbandry practices inacceptable (Roosen et al., 2016), several
(Lagerkvist and Hess, 2011). The majority of studies reveal that con- policy measures to incentivise production at higher levels of FAW, in-
sumers’ willingness to pay (WTP) increases with higher standards of cluding pasture access for cows, have emerged (Ingenbleek et al., 2012;
farm animal welfare (e.g., Kehlbacher et al., 2012; Napolitano et al., Veissier et al., 2008). The idea is that farms receive compensation since
2008). Interestingly, this also holds true for dairy products produced in pasture access requires sacrificing (milk) productivity and thus profit-
pasture-based systems. Consumers perceive pasture access as a positive ability to provide higher levels of FAW. The question whether simply
contributor to welfare (Cardoso et al., 2016; Ellis et al., 2009) and even providing pasture-access warrant payments because farms have to sa-
use it as a criterion to assess the level of FAW of the production system crifice milk yield and profitability to increase dairy cows’ welfare,
(Schuppli et al., 2014). Access to pasture is in fact used as an important however, remains open.
sales argument (Weinrich et al., 2014), although the specific role of From animal science perspective, most animals prefer to stay on
pasture access on dairy cow welfare is not that straightforward (Arnott pasture, if cows are given the choice between pasture or confinement in
et al., 2017). Contrarily, Lusk and Norwood (2011) argue that an experimental setting (Charlton et al., 2011; Legrand et al., 2009;
FAW directly relates to the husbandry system. Based upon their Motupalli et al., 2014). Studies in the field of animal science, however,


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: hinrich.schulte@agr.uni-goettingen.de (H.D. Schulte), linda.armbrecht@agr.uni-goettingen.de (L. Armbrecht),
rasmus.buerger@agrar.hu-berlin.de (R. Bürger), matthias.gauly@unibz.it (M. Gauly), oliver.musshoff@agr.uni-goettingen.de (O. Musshoff),
s.huettel@ilr.uni-bonn.de (S. Hüttel).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.07.005
Received 30 January 2018; Received in revised form 2 July 2018; Accepted 3 July 2018
0264-8377/ © 2018 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

report mixed findings concerning specific health and welfare effects of the first to use the multi-disciplinary scientific animal welfare measure
pasture access. Benefits result from more space, and easily accessible within an efficiency analysis framework. To cross-validate the as-
lying opportunities, which increases the lying times of cows, leading to sumption of sequential preferences we further provide results of a
lower levels of aggression (e.g., Burow et al., 2011). Furthermore, re- standard efficiency approach. Our study will help to inform the dis-
duced integument alterations, hair loss, lesions and swellings have been cussion on whether policy support for pasture access can be justified by
reported for cows with pasture access (Burow et al., 2013). While some improved animal welfare, and whether pasture-based systems can ef-
authors report positive health effects related to reduced lameness ficiently provide farm animal welfare.
(Barker et al., 2010; Chapinal et al., 2013; de Vries et al., 2015), others The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: first, we review
could not determine any effects on claw health (Baird et al., 2009; the relevant literature and present the analytical framework (Section 2).
Chapinal et al., 2010). Moreover, high-yielding cows might suffer from Then, we describe the dataset and how farm animal welfare is measured
insufficient energy intake with pasture feeding, which in turn leads to based on the WQP (Section 3). In Section 4, we present the empirical
nutritional and metabolic stress, with a negative impact on welfare strategy and in Section 5, we present and discuss the results. In the final
(Vance et al., 2012). Beyond this, parasites that accompany grazing section, we conclude.
might also reduce positive impacts on FAW (Bennema et al., 2011;
Vanderstichel et al., 2012). 2. Background, related literature and research framework
From production economics perspective, dairy farm performance
has often been examined using technical, economic and environmental The percentage of dairy farms in Europe with pasture access
efficiency (cf. among others Breustedt et al., 2011; Wettemann and dropped from 52% in 2008 to 35% in 2012 (Reijs et al., 2013). This
Latacz-Lohmann, 2017). Only few studies directly relate farm (tech- trend contradicts consumers’ increased interest in pasture-based sys-
nical) efficiency to cow health status, as one aspect of welfare, and tems but is the result of higher economic pressure induced by less stable
report a positive relationship (e.g., Barnes et al., 2011; Lawson et al., and lower output prices, as well as the EU’s milk market policy, which
2004a). The specific role of pasture access in this regard has thus far features reduced market support. Cost pressure might lead to changes in
received only little attention. The study of Allendorf and Wettemann feeding strategies with tendencies to more maize-based rations given
(2015) forms one exception and does not support any relationship be- the higher energy yield per hectare compared to grassland. In addition,
tween dairy cow welfare, pasture access and performance. These stu- benefits of higher technical efficiency in milk production on specialized
dies, however, rely on lameness or somatic cell counts as simplistic farms have been reported (e.g., Pieralli et al., 2017). Farms with larger
proxies for dairy cows’ welfare and thus neglect the high complexity herds might also benefit from economies of scale. Trends for larger
and multi-dimensionality of animal welfare. Furthermore, these studies herds and more specialization might partly explain the trend in pasture
do not consider FAW as a central part of the production process, as is use in Western Europe since providing pasture access for larger herds
argued by McInerney (2004), and simply relate efficiency scores to can be more demanding on the grassland itself (given a confined
health status or pasture access indicators. In a recent study Henningsen grazing area). Against this backdrop, several policy schemes of the
et al. (2018) acknowledge that animal welfare can in fact positively second pillar of the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy have been de-
impact the production process and its performance, though their em- voted to counteract the trends in grassland and pasture-use. These
pirical analysis reveals only a weak relationship between welfare and measures target at keeping grassland in production to maintain land-
performance for Danish pig farmers. Evidence for the dairy sector that scapes, functioning of ecosystems, but also enhancing biological di-
acknowledges the complexity of farm animal welfare and peculiarities versity and farm animal welfare. The latter programmes’ success is
under pasture-access is thus far not available. often hampered by low acceptance rates among farmers. Schreiner and
Our study aims to close this gap by empirically investigating the Hess (2017) argue that the high personal animal welfare standards of
relationship between dairy farm performance, pasture access of dairy farmers are often mismatched with the design of such programmes.
cows and their welfare status. The objectives are twofold. Firstly, we Farmers might fear disutility from participation, for instance, by suf-
empirically investigate the potential trade-off between dairy farm per- fering a loss of autonomy. This, however, does not necessarily imply
formance and FAW. Secondly, we analyse whether this potential trade- that farmers do not include farm animal welfare in their goal setting.
off differs systematically due to pasture access. We refer to technical Hansson and Lagerkvist (2015) distinguish in this context between use
efficiency as one major dimension of performance besides economic and non-use. Use values are directly related to productivity and denote
efficiency, productivity and effectiveness.1 Our study relies on a rich the necessity of animal well-being to ensure productivity, while non-use
dataset of 45 dairy farms located in north-western Germany, where in values include the remaining issues that provide utility to the farmer,
addition to all dairy branch-specific costs, a sophisticated measure to although they are not directly related to productivity or even coun-
assess dairy cow welfare based on the Welfare Quality® Protocol (WQP) tervailing. For decision makers with high non-use values, it is reason-
for cattle (Welfare Quality®, 2012) is available. Our study directly re- able to allocate inputs towards animal health and well-being although
lates to research by Gocsik et al. (2016), who used the WQP-index in such actions neither directly nor indirectly correspond to increased
their analysis on the cost-efficiency of improvements in broiler welfare. productivity. The question remains whether such investments in FAW
In contrast and following Asmild and Hougaard (2006), we refer to a come at the cost of productivity or may even ensure economic effi-
directional efficiency measure that acknowledges behavioural patterns ciency or both.
of farm managers with sequential preferences: improvements in pure Another strand of research has emerged analysing the direct con-
technical efficiency might be the primary goal of the farm and after tribution of FAW towards productivity. For instance, Lawson et al.
having achieved the desired level of efficiency, farm animal welfare (2004b) found no relationship between milk production, technical ef-
might become the next relevant focus. Therefore, in this study, we ficiency and reproductive disorders, as did Hansson and Öhlmér (2008).
consider farm animal welfare as a second output alongside milk and are Contrary to this, higher technical efficiency could be proven to be as-
sociated with a lower frequency of milk fever but also with a higher rate
of digestive disorders (Lawson et al., 2004a). In addition, Barnes et al.
1 (2011) found healthier herds with fewer incidences of lameness were
Technical efficiency is one major dimension of performance besides eco-
nomic efficiency, productivity and effectiveness. While productivity usually correlated with higher levels of technical efficiency. As Lawson et al.
describes the relationships between all inputs and outputs at the farm level, (2004a) emphasise, the choice of variables to measure animal welfare
efficiency is a normative measure of specific input-output relations. may influence empirical evidence given the complex nature of farm
Effectiveness is also a normative measure used to capture whether an intended animal welfare, where health is just one dimension. Resulting re-
output level is produced, irrespective of the current efficiency level. lationships between productivity and animal welfare are therefore

376
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

method dependent and finding an appropriate measure remains a assessment of farm animal welfare according to the WQP consists of
challenge. several measures used to determine welfare criteria (cf. Table A1 in the
Two general ideas to measure farm animal welfare exist (cf. Appendix). These welfare criteria are summarised by four indicators:
Henningsen et al., 2018). Resource-based measures, such as space in the housing, feeding, behaviour and health each range from 0 to 100,
barn, water availability or playing/brushing facilities, are directly where the overall assessment takes the mean of these four indicators
under the control of the farmer. These offer the main advantage con- (cf. Table A1). Measuring farm animal welfare according to the WQP
cerning predictability and assessment. For instance, policymakers offers the advantage that it directly relates to the animals’ needs and
might increase the required space for each cow and dairy farmers could behavioural patterns. In turn, dairy farmers also benefit from the use of
react by adjusting their management accordingly. Such measures bear the WQP since the index gives a basis for comparison to improve the
the disadvantage of not evaluating the animal’s constitution directly. conditions of animals (Gieseke et al., 2014). According to the scheme of
Outcome-based measures, in contrast, essentially focus on assessing the the WQP, pasture access enters the measure directly. That is, pasture
animals (Botreau et al., 2009) and to a lesser extent on the use of re- would increase the score compared to confinement systems, even if all
sources (Botreau et al., 2013). Even though these measures report a remaining measures are identical. To investigate exactly this relation-
realistic picture of the animal, data collection is time-consuming and ship, we follow Armbrecht et al. (2015) and argue that a higher score
expensive. In our study, we make use of the advantages of outcome- for the majority of the sample farms by system and not by cow-based
based evaluation of dairy cow welfare by relying on the evaluation assessment would not adequately reflect the situation. To ensure com-
scheme of the EU’s Welfare Quality project (cf. Keeling, 2009). How the parability of welfare without such biases, we left out the positive
welfare status of livestock relates to specific husbandry systems, such as scoring by pasture access in the WQP. Data were collected twice per
pasture-based milk production, and whether higher farm animal wel- farm by one person, first at the end of the pasture season (July–October
fare goes along with sacrificing milk productivity if opting for such 2014) and second at the end of the barn season (January–April 2015).
systems, is thus far still under debate. According to Lusk and Norwood We base our calculations on mean values of both visits. The total WQP
(2011), lower productivity would mainly be due to the more extensive index shows comparably high levels for the sampled farms with rather
nature of pasture-based systems but ensuring higher FAW. However, low levels of variation across groups. For greater details we refer to
the dairy farm manager, as caretaker of the animals, influences the Armbrecht et al. (2015) and Table A2 in the Appendix.
production process with his or her knowledge, skills and preferences. We can rely on information on dairy branch-specific costs for the
These might be sequential and a farmer might decide to first achieve economic year 2013/14 and 2014/15 including major branch-specific
efficiency in milk production and then prioritise input allocation to- cost positions such as those for feed, labour, veterinary costs, land,
wards farm animal welfare whilst still maintaining efficiency (cf. depreciation and implicit interest for capital. Given that the WQP refers
Asmild and Hougaard, 2006). Henningsen et al. (2018) even argue that to 2014/15, we concentrate on this year regarding the economic data
the production process determines animal welfare and that given its but present all results for the year 2013/14 as a robustness check in the
complexity, the respective animal welfare status might likewise affect Appendix (see Table A3 for descriptive statistics).
the production process as a prerequisite to achieving productive per- Overall, no dairy farm of our sample consists of more than 280 cows
formance. If in addition, for instances driven by non-use values, FAW and hence the sample farms could be categorised as medium-large
contributes to the farmer’s utility, then FAW likely adds to consumers’ compared to the average across Germany. On average, dairy farms in
utility. Farm animal welfare may even be characterized as a public good Germany have 61 cows and in the state of Lower Saxony, 85.5 cows
provided by farmers since nobody can be excluded from consumption (Destatis, 2017, p. 57), where the group with longest grazing times
(e.g., Bennett, 1995; Lusk, 2011).2 (> 10 h) in the sample operates at a mean herd size of about 121 cows
Our approach addresses these issues by enhancing the output vector (cf. Table 1). The group with medium grazing times (6–10 h) reveals a
by farm animal welfare within a directional distance function approach mean herd size of about 140 cows. Comparing milk yields, those farms
to measure technical efficiency. This allows us to investigate firstly the in the confinement group and the group with < 6 h pasture access show
potential trade-off between FAW and productivity and secondly whe-
ther pasture-based systems have an advantage in the provision of farm Table 1
animal welfare. Descriptive statistics for the year 2014/15.
Pasture Pasture Pasture Confinement
> 10 h 6 h – 10 h <6h
3. Study region and data
Herd size [#] mean 120.58 134.52 140.17 125.10
Our dataset contains data for branch-specific cost and profits for 45 SD 47.44 49.44 64.48 57.84
Milk [kg ECM per cow and day] mean 27.09 26.75 30.60 30.61
dairy farms in the Federal State of Lower Saxony, in north-western
SD 3.23 3.24 2.67 2.92
Germany. These farms are located within one of the main milk pro- Profit [ct. per kg ECM] mean −3.75 −7.20 −6.52 −9.64
ducing regions in Germany, where cows typically have pasture access. SD 3.11 4.15 4.17 4.55
The grazing period usually ranges from April to September. Our dataset WQP overall index [0,100] mean 47.02 47.11 48.36 45.28
includes farms with different levels of pasture length if pasture access SD 5.11 3.47 6.59 3.98

was at least 120 days per year, measured by an indicator: > 10 h, Costs [ct. per kg ECM]
6–10 h, or < 6 h pasture access per day. Besides, the data includes a Labour mean 8.93 9.42 8.90 9.69
SD 1.62 1.43 1.47 1.52
control group with year-round confinement systems, in similar ranges
thereof for pasture and silage mean 3.46 4.02 3.76 4.29
of herd size to ensure comparability, and presupposed willingness to Feed mean 11.83 12.71 12.98 14.00
collaborate. SD 1.26 1.48 1.47 1.24
We rely on the WQP for cattle (Keeling, 2009; Welfare Quality®, thereof for pasture and silage mean 3.64 4.18 3.42 3.62
2012) to assess dairy cow welfare, which has been classified primarily Veterinary mean 1.13 1.25 1.54 1.37
SD 0.81 0.43 0.27 0.29
as a outcome-based measure (Fraser et al., 2013). The overall Land and capital mean 0.96 1.43 1.02 1.16
SD 0.35 0.64 0.32 0.30
N 12 12 13 8
2
This argumentation, however, has been critically debated: some authors
argue that animal welfare is not a public good Mann (2005), while Harvey and Note: Own calculations; SD = standard deviation; N denotes the number of
Hubbard (2013) classify the regulations of farm animal welfare levels as a farms per group out of a total of 45 farm observations.
public good.

377
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

the highest yields. On average, these cows produce 3 kg of energy- level an output-oriented production can be further justified given that
corrected milk (ECM) per day more than the cows in the groups with farms under the EU’s milk quota scheme adjust the number of cows to
longer pasture access. The sampled farms’ operate above the German meet the quantity restriction but optimize milk yields for given input
average of 7746 kg per cow per year in 2016, presuming 305 days of capacities. Under the standard approach, established by Färe et al.
lactation (BLE, 2017). Furthermore, and in comparison to the year (1985) referring to Coelli et al. (2005) for further details, the idea is to
2013/2014 (see Appendix Table A3), the farm profits in 2014/2015 measure how the k -th farm could radially expand the output vector y k
were relatively low. Year 2014/15 was characterized by low milk as much as possible to become efficient. The boundary is a piece-wise
prices, which could be partly explained by the Russia embargo in au- linear production function representing the technically efficient output.
tumn 2014, where important export markets broke away. In addition, The radial expansion of the output vector y k produces a projected point
the end of the European Union’s milk quota scheme was in April 2015 on the surface of this technology. This framework offers a starting point
and many farms have taken this opportunity to expand production as typically carried out in the literature, where we implicitly assume
quantity already before with non-negligible supply effects. that farm animal welfare and milk output restrict input use in the same
All costs are related to the production of 1 kg of energy-corrected manner. To approach the relevance of FAW as an output, we apply the
milk (ECM) with 4.0% fat and 3.4% protein. Labour and feed amount variable selection procedure by Pastor et al. (2002). As suggested by
are the main cost positions and reflect approximately 60% of the costs. Sirvent et al. (2005), the output may be treated as irrelevant if after
Labour, feed and veterinary costs vary by group: the group with dropping the output farm animal welfare, the TE score of technically
6 h – 10 h pasture time show the highest labour cost among the pasture efficient farms changes by more than 10%; this must hold for at least
groups, while the confinement group reveals the highest mean labour 15% of the farms.
cost overall (cf. Table 1). Pasture-based milk production is known to be The standard modelling approach, however, may neglect that dairy
labour-intensive, as supported by these numbers, though more hired farm managers decide upon sequential preferences. That is, it might be
labour and potentially higher qualifications might be needed in con- the primary goal to achieve a high productivity (milk yield) first and
finement systems. Furthermore, our dataset allows us to differentiate then, sequentially farm animal welfare becomes a relevant goal.
how the cost of feed and labour were related to the production of silage Alternatively, it might even be that farms opt for pasture-access because
and pasture. Related to this differentiation, the labour costs for the of beneficiary effects for the animals and accept lower milk yields, al-
pasture and silage production are slightly higher for confinement sys- though the questions remain whether this comes at the cost of techni-
tems than for pasture-based systems. However, similar patterns do not cally efficiency. From a societal perspective, another question arises,
hold for feed costs. namely whether pasture-based systems provide farm animal welfare
more efficiently. To address these questions, we switch in a second step
to a directional measurement. Directional DEA refers a proportional
4. Empirical strategy adjustment approach based on directional distance functions
(Chambers et al., 1996). In contrast to the fixed direction of measuring
The aim of our study is to empirically investigate the relationship efficiency, directional distance functions allow us to evaluate the levels
between pasture access, dairy cow welfare based on the scientific farm of efficiency in any direction from the observation points (Asmild et al.,
animal welfare indicator WQP, and farm performance. We rely on 2003; Bogetoft and Hougaard, 1999). This gives us the opportunity to
technical efficiency as a major dimension of farm performance obtained measure the efficiency related to a specific variable while keeping the
by a Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA).3 Against the backdrop that remaining outputs fixed. Interpreting the efficiency score of dairy farms
FAW cannot be priced, it remains a challenge to identify the trade-off will either be based on adjusting farm animal welfare ( yFAW ) or milk
between productivity and farm animal welfare in an allocative manner. yield ( yMI ). Hence, we are able to quantify the improvement potential of
Also, a long-lasting discussion exists about whether technical and eco- FAW efficiency while keeping the level of milk yield fixed. The direc-
nomic efficiency coincide. Hence, we refer to previous studies’ results tional output distance function is defined as:
that more efficient farms tend to have higher levels of income (Bravo-
Ureta and Rieger, 1991; Dartt et al., 1999). To justify this measure, we ⎯→

D0 (x , y; gy ) = max{β : (y + βgy ) ∈ P (x )}.
relate the obtained efficiency scores to the profit measure of the milk
production branch of the dairy farms in our sample using a linear re- The value of β represents the distance between the observation
gression. y = (yMI , yFAW ) and a point on the production frontier ( y + βgy ). The
The DEA approach rooting back to Charnes et al. (1978), known as a direction vector, g = (g yMI , g yFAW ) , determines the direction in which
benchmarking tool, follows the idea of generating the best-practice efficiency is measured. We repeated this procedure twice, (i) in the
production frontiers and evaluating relative efficiencies of different direction of milk yield to get technical efficiency, by assuming g = (1,0) ,
entities (Bogetoft and Otto, 2011). A main advantage of the DEA is that and (ii) calculating FAW-efficiency by assuming g = (0,1) . Given the
no ex-ante assumptions about the production frontier must be made. production technology P (x ) and the direction vector g , the directional
The possibility of including monetary input and output factors together distance function determines the maximum feasible expansion of the
with non-monetary ones such as the WQP offers another advantage, two outputs to reach the production frontier. Hence, given the output-
particularly in contexts where the time intense data collection limits the oriented view, the larger the distance between frontier and observation
total number of farm observations (cf. Korhonen and Luptacik, 2004; is, the higher is the efficiency score. To obtain the output directional
Pérez Urdiales et al., 2016; Picazo-Tadeo et al., 2012; Sutherland et al., distance β k for the k th farm, we followed the DEA procedure of
2012). Bogetoft and Otto (2011) also within the R package Benchmarking.
We approach the empirical investigation from two sides. We start While milk yield and FAW determine the two-dimensional output,
with a standard DEA output-oriented approach, where we consider we consider labour and feed cost as the main inputs in both steps be-
farm animal welfare and milk yield as two outputs.4 Besides our interest cause they reflect approximately 60% of the costs. Given the low
to investigate the cow welfare-milk production relationship, at the cow number of observations relative to the number of potential inputs, we
again followed the selection procedure to identify additional relevant
3
We refer to Lakner and Breustedt (2017) and the cited literature therein inputs among veterinary, land and capital costs. In case of over-speci-
who present an excellent overview of organic farming efficiency, in which dairy fication we would assess a large portion of the farm observations as
farm performance in particular is addressed. efficient or nearly efficient (Podinovski and Thanassoulis, 2007). As
4
Throughout all steps of the efficiency analysis, we have used the R package Asmild and Hougaard (2006), we presume variable returns to scale in
Benchmarking (Bogetoft and Otto, 2015). both steps since the convexity assumption under the variable returns to

378
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

scale assumption leads to the most cautious estimates of the respective Table 3
efficiency scores. To measure if, and how, economies of scale matter, Technical and FAW Efficiency (2014/15) - directional distance DEA.
we carry out a regression-based approach, where herd size is regressed Technical Efficiency FAW-Efficiency
on the technical and FAW efficiency scores estimated by Ordinary Least
Squares (OLS) as suggested by Hoff (2007) and McDonald (2009). Fi- Confinement Mean 1.23 1.53
SD 0.14 0.36
nally, to investigate how profit is related to technical and FAW-effi-
< 6 h pasture Mean 1.16 1.29
ciency, we regressed the respective efficiency scores on the income of SD 0.15 0.34
the dairy branch, which is again estimated by OLS. 6 h-10 h pasture Mean 1.15 1.25
SD 0.11 0.18
> 10 h pasture Mean 1.07 1.20
5. Results and discussion SD 0.06 0.19

Note: output-orientation and variable returns to scale were considered. N = 42


The variable selection procedure determined land, capital and ve- because for three farms no efficiency score could be generated.
terinary costs, as non-relevant inputs besides labour and feed for the
dairy farms in our sample (see Table A4 in the Appendix). Hence, all direction of animal welfare, that is, the score captures potential in-
DEA steps rest on inputs labour and feed costs as inputs. Starting with creases in FAW to reach the frontier while the milk yield is held con-
the findings from the standard DEA approach, we consider two outputs, stant but for the same input combination (labour and feed cost). FAW-
milk and farm animal welfare. For comparison reasons, we present the efficiency can be interpreted in a similar manner as the technical milk
model with one output (milk) as well (cf. Table 2). Since we refer to an efficiency: a high score for instance, reveals higher efficiency in pro-
output-oriented approach, farms with a TE-Score higher than 1, all viding farm animal welfare. That is, for the same level of feed and input
outputs must be proportionally expanded by the efficiency score to be cost a higher level of farm animal welfare is achieved compared to
technically efficient. Reported scores equal to 1 indicate a fully-efficient farms with a lower FAW-efficiency score.
farm operating on the production frontier. Comparing by group, we find The results of the directional DEA again reveal some differences
no substantial differences in efficiencies, except for farms in the ex- between the mean technical efficiency of the farms in the confinement
tensive pasture group with more than 10 h, which show slightly higher system group and the extensive pasture based system keeping the cows
efficiencies despite the lower level of milk yield. Moreover, some ten- for more than 10 h on the pasture (Wilcoxon rank sum test; p-
dency that farms with confinement systems could improve efficiency by value = 0.028). This also holds for the FAW-efficiency direction, where
increasing milk yield prevails under both model specifications. Using we find differences between mean scores of confinement and all pas-
the Wilcoxon-rank sum test as suggested by Banker et al. (2010), equal ture-based groups. According to the rank-sum test we cannot reject
scores between these two groups are rejected (p-value = 0.0242 DEA- differences if cows have pasture access with more than 10 h (p-
Base; p-value = 0.0273 DEA FAW-output; other differences are re- value = 0.075) and between 6 h and 10 h (p-value = 0.098) against
jected). Based upon the selection procedure and given the minor dif- confinement, respectively. For the year 2013/14, we do find similar
ferences in mean DEA scores of both models (cf. Table 2), these findings patterns, though not at significant levels (see Table A6 in the Ap-
suggest farm animal welfare to be a non-relevant output and non-de- pendix). From this, we conjecture that pasture-based farms in the
terminant of the production frontier in milk production for our sample sample operate at higher efficiency in both directions, even though at
(cf. Table A4). These findings may suggest that at first glance dairy lower milk yields on average (cf. Table 1). These findings are somewhat
farmers in this study seem to optimize milk yield rather than farm contrary to those reported by Allendorf and Wettemann (2015), who
animal welfare irrespective of pasture-access. When comparing the did not find any effect of pasture; however, these authors did not
mean of the efficiency scores between groups across years, the results consider farm animal welfare as variable in their DEA and purely rely
are not similar, yet it still holds that FAW is not a relevant output (see on health indicators and a simple dummy variable indicating pasture
Table A5 in the Appendix for the efficiency analysis referring to the access in a second stage regression.
year 2013/14). The directional DEA approach as pursued here offers a more so-
Dairy farms, however, might rank milk yield and farm animal phisticated view given the complexity of FAW. While in the standard
welfare differently, where an optimisation towards milk yields might be DEA model FAW is identified as a non-relevant output, the results of the
the primary goal. Differentiating the dimensions of the output vector by directional DEA indicate that farms in the pasture-groups more effi-
using a directional DEA allows us to capture whether farms face se- ciently provide FAW with a weak tendency that FAW-efficiency may
quential preferences in a sense that improvement potentials concerning increase in pasture-access time. For the sample dairy farms pasture-
farm animal welfare will be realized after technical efficiency is access seems to be a preferable production option as a result of opti-
achieved. In Table 3, we report the mean efficiency scores in both di- mizing farm performance at given conditions. Since these farms do not
rections by group, where we refer to “pure” technical efficiency in a benefit from a specific pasture-milk program or any other policy mea-
classical sense in the direction of the milk output while the level of FAW sures regarding pasture or farm animal welfare, pasture-access can be
is kept constant. Vice versa, FAW-efficiency refers to efficiency in the treated as a result of farmers’ rationale irrespective of debated ex-
pectations on livestock production systems by society. Even though the
findings suggest that pasture access could even facilitate a better per-
Table 2
formance of dairy farms in both directions, we cannot not conclude that
Standard DEA results for the year 2014/15.
pasture-access guarantees higher levels of animal welfare, also because
DEA: milk output DEA: milk and FAW output peer farms that determine the efficient frontier stem from all groups.5
Confinement mean 1.23 1.23
To investigate further the potential trade-off between farm animal
SD 0.14 0.14 welfare and technical efficiency, which is already questioned by the
< 6 h pasture mean 1.15 1.13 mean efficiency scores at the group level, we plot the individual FAW-
SD 0.15 0.14 efficiency scores against the technical efficiency scores (cf. Fig. 1 and
6 h-10 h pasture mean 1.14 1.12
Fig. A1 in the Appendix for the year 2013/14). If there was a trade-off
SD 0.11 0.10
> 10 h pasture Mean 1.08 1.06
SD 0.07 0.06
5
This further supports the assumption of one technology for the production
Note: output-orientation under variable returns to scale; N = 45 farms. process.

379
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

6. Concluding remarks

This study was motivated by the question of how to warrant will-


ingness to pay for pasture-based milk production because of increases in
farm animal welfare along with sacrificing milk productivity from a
production economics perspective. To investigate the relationship be-
tween pasture access, farm animal welfare and production perfor-
mance, we employ a detailed dataset of dairy branch-specific costs and
profit for 45 dairy farms in north-western Germany. By relying on a
scientific outcome-based farm animal welfare measure according to the
Welfare Quality® Protocol, the dataset offers certain advantages over
similar studies with more observations but more simplistic welfare
measures and farm accounting data that are not branch-specific. We
Fig. 1. Technical and FAW Efficiency (2014/15) - directional distance DEA.
exploit technical efficiency as a central dimension of economic per-
Note: output-orientation and variable returns to scale were considered.
formance by using Data Envelopment Analysis. Based on a standard
approach, where farm animal welfare is considered as a second output,
between farm animal welfare and technical efficiency, we would expect we find that pasture-based milk production can be as or more efficient
more observations in the upper-left (high FAW-TE, low TE) or in the than confinement systems but farm animal welfare as a non-relevant
lower-right (low FAW-TE, high TE) regions in Fig. 1. As indicated by output. Efficiency scores in terms of a proportional expansion of both
Fig. 1, both efficiency scores reveal a positive and significant correla- outputs cannot capture sequential preferences such as improvements
tion with each other (cf. Table A7 in the Appendix) suggesting that farm with regards to farm animal welfare will be treated after technical ef-
animal welfare must not be sacrificed by efficiency and vice versa. In ficiency is achieved and would hence offer misleading interpretations
other words, similar and efficient input combinations enhance technical regarding farm animal welfare. Instead, we suggest a directional dis-
efficiency as well as FAW-efficiency. Based on these findings, we tance function approach. We first find that farm animal welfare and
question the existence of a trade-off between farm animal welfare and technical efficiency are positively correlated and no evidence of a trade-
technical efficiency. We conjecture that farmers’ value farm animal off exists. Second, the results show higher efficiency levels, both on a
welfare in the production process. These findings are in contrast to technical level and in terms of animal welfare provision, for pasture
Hansson and Öhlmér (2008) who could not find any relationship be- based-systems. That is, higher technical efficiency is observed with a
tween technical efficiency and animal health, though their measures more efficient provision of animal welfare for those offering the animals
seem not appropriately capturing the complexity of farm animal wel- access to pasture, despite lower milk yields on average. The results
fare. further reveal a positive relation of size and efficiency for the sample
To investigate the relationship between technical and farm animal farms, where the maximum herd size does not exceed 280. These
welfare efficiency and scale, we regress herd size on the respective ef- findings do not support the argumentation that specialization, and
ficiency scores (see Table A8 in the Appendix). We find that larger herds larger herds are per se more demanding and thus challenge pasture-
are linked to higher efficiency scores. Hence, size can interpreted to be based milk production, also because the bottleneck availability of sui-
important to realise efficiencies for our sampled farms. This holds not table grassland. Our sample shows that (moderately) larger herds’
only for technical efficiency, but also for farm animal welfare. Note- pasture access can be managed efficiently, also regarding farm animal
worthy, these relationships are based on herd sizes that do not exceed welfare. However, very large herds may no longer benefit from pasture
280 cows. In the range of herd sizes of the sample farms, the finding is access due to potentially negative effects on cows’ well-being due to
plausible; however, we cannot conclude from these findings on con- long walking distances, which could not be analysed in this study.
siderably larger herd sizes. Referring to Islam et al. (2015), the high We conjecture that pasture-based dairy systems may appear see-
performance of pasture based milk producing farms may no longer hold mingly (economically) inefficient in this debate, also because ag-
under considerably larger herd sizes. For instance, increasing walking gregated productivity measures or only milk yield are often taken as a
distances for the cows might lead to lower milk yields, milk losses on simplified base. But, pasture access does not automatically lead to an
the pasture but also to stress for the animals potentially leading to lower efficient provision of welfare. Given that we find farms from all groups
efficiency scores. The given data set does not allow us to investigate the determining the most efficient peers approximating the production
likely non-linear relation between efficiency in both directions and herd frontier, we conjecture that higher milk yield and specialization in
sizes. confinement systems do not come at the cost of animal welfare per se.
Finally, since we treat technical efficiency as a major dimension of This result somewhat contradicts common beliefs of some consumers
farm performance and technically more efficient farms might not ne- that it is only the small dairy farms with pasture-access that are able to
cessarily show a higher overall farm performance, we investigate the provide animal welfare and only by sacrificing performance. As such,
relationship between the contribution of the dairy branch to farm our results add to the discussion initiated by Lusk and Norwood (2011)
profits and both efficiency measures. Therefore, we regress the effi- that changing the animal husbandry system might have an effect on the
ciency scores on the branch-specific profitability measure, where the productivity and animal welfare, but it is not guaranteed.
results indicate a positive relationship (see Table A9 in the Appendix). From these results, we conclude that governmental support should
That is, increasing efficiency in either of the directions fosters profit- rather be designed to improve the management skills of dairy farmers in
ability. This result is in line with findings from previous studies ana- order to increase their efficiency in both directions instead of sup-
lysing technical and economic efficiency in the dairy sector (e.g., Bravo- porting a specific animal husbandry system or purely pasture access.
Ureta and Rieger, 1991) and supports the positive relationship between This would lead to more technically efficient farming, providing more
farm performance and farm animal welfare discussed by Henningsen efficiently farm animal welfare whilst not discriminating against spe-
et al. (2018). cific animal husbandry systems. To increase overall levels of livestock

380
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

welfare at the aggregate level, we follow the argumentation of promising path of future research for analysing the production of dif-
Kehlbacher et al. (2012) and suggest assessing farm animal welfare ferently ranked goods from a production economics perspective.
directly rather than solely supporting specific systems. Price premiums Nonetheless, this study has a number of limitations: the low number of
depending on the outcome-based level of animal welfare instead of observations limits generalizations to be drawn. Further, the production
whether the animals have pasture access or not offer a higher trans- process as well as the welfare of the livestock highly depends on
parency for consumers and can even be justified given the public-good management and personal norms, beliefs and values. Within this study,
character of farm animal welfare. However, the cost-intensity of such we cannot identify to which extent the difference in the technical ef-
policy programs based on direct livestock welfare measures must be ficiency scores can be causally explained by pasture access or man-
taken into consideration. On-farm measures such as the Welfare Quality agement skills. Future research could consider these issues while in-
Protocol® are costly and would require a high administration burden. vestigating economic efficiency of farms. In addition, given that pasture
New technologies such as automated scanning of animals’ body con- access might contribute to robustness and overall lifetime of the ani-
ditions might offer further possibilities for the future design of such mals, which in turn could be an investment for farms, a dynamic per-
measures to ease the provision of sufficient levels of animal welfare, as spective would be desirable.
well as transparency in food production.
Given cows’ preferences and the importance of pastures from an
Declaration of interest
agri-environmental and sustainability point of view asks for a combined
view of an overall farm animal welfare measurement and specific
All authors confirm that no actual or potential conflict of interest
production systems with pasture access for the animals in such pro-
including any, financial, personal or other relationships with other
grammes. Pasture use may foster maintenance of grassland with its
people or organizations within three years of beginning the submitted
positive environmental effects by ecosystem services (e.g., biodi-
work exist that could inappropriately influence, or be perceived to in-
versity). These aspects also constitute public goods induced by pasture
fluence, the outcome of the underlying article.
access (Cooper et al., 2009; Drake, 1992; Lefebvre et al., 2014) and
should be considered in policy design. After all, pasture access remains
highly appreciated by consumers, not only in terms of animal welfare, Acknowledgements
but also for the aesthetic landscape it provides. The background of the
declining number of grazing animals in Europe supports the argu- The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the
mentation of taking both, farm animal welfare and the role of pastures Ministry for Science and Culture of Lower Saxony (MWK) within the
within the ecosystem into account. Future research must consider the collaborative research project SAM, Analysis of Dairy Production:
environmental aspect of different pasture-based systems explicitly to Grazing versus Indoor Housing of Dairy Cows, Support Code: ZN 286,
inform the policy debate. Due to a lack of data, these dimensions were University of Rostock and the German Federal Ministry of Food and
not part of our analysis. Agriculture within the programme for ecological farming
Our study must be viewed as a first step towards creating a frame- (Bundesprogramm Ökologischer Landbau) for ÖKOTAWEK, Support
work for quantitative animal welfare production economics and offers a Code: 2812NA009.

Appendix A

A.1 Data details

Table A1
Structure of the Welfare Quality® Assessment protocol for cattle (Botreau et al., 2009; Welfare
Quality®, 2012).
Welfare criteria Welfare principle

Absence of prolonged hunger (body condition score) Feeding


Absence of prolonged thirst (functioning of water points)
Comfort around resting (time needed to lie down) Housing
Thermal comfort (as yet no measure is developed)
Ease of movement (presence of tethering)
Absence of injuries (integument alternations) Health
Absence of disease (nasal discharge)
Absence of pain induced by management procedures (tail docking)
Expression of social behaviours (agonistic behaviours) Behaviour
Expression of other behaviours (access to pasture)
Good human-animal relationship (avoidance distance)
Positive emotional state (qualitative behaviour assessment)

Note: Measurement examples for the criteria are given in parentheses. The principles are determined
by the criteria and scores range from 0-100. The overall assessment is the average of the principles.
Access to pasture was not taken into account as a measure.

381
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

Table A2
Descriptive statistics of the WQP and its principals.
Pasture Pasture 6 h- Pasture Confinement
> 10 h 10 h <6h

Feeding mean 42.55 43.32 53.61 54.15


SD 20.47 17.09 7.10 12.43
Behaviour mean 36.98 34.77 35.09 39.67
SD 3.93 3.85 6.59 3.66
Housing mean 63.37 62.14 61.46 49.02
SD 8.83 6.90 7.73 5.50
Health mean 45.18 48.22 43.29 38.28
SD 7.72 6.86 4.12 8.10
Overall mean 47.02 47.11 48.36 45.28
SD 5.11 3.47 64.48 3.98

Note: for details see Armbrecht et al. (2015).

Table A3
Descriptive statistics for the year 2013/2014.
Pasture Pasture Pasture Confinement
> 10 h 6 h-10 h <6h

Herd size [#] mean 112.16 125.25 134.92 121.74


SD 38.17 49.40 58.36 58.03
Milk yield [kg ECM per cow and day] mean 27.98 28.10 31.19 31.39
SD 2.63 3.16 2.81 1.27
Profit [ct. per kg ECM] mean 2.34 3.78 1.84 4.64
SD 5.02 2.72 4.04 4.55
WQP overall index [0.100] mean 47.02 47.11 48.36 45.28
SD 5.11 3.47 58.36 3.98

Costs [ct. per kg ECM]


Labour mean 10.72 9.87 10.67 10.42
SD 2.28 2.53 1.72 1.84
thereof for pasture and silage mean 3.52 3.88 3.93 3.41
Feed mean 12.65 12.70 13.81 13.42
SD 2.07 1.24 1.48 2.01
thereof for pasture and silage mean 3.12 3.43 3.47 2.71
Veterinary mean 1.12 1.34 1.44 1.26
SD 0.67 0.43 0.44 0.31
Land and capital mean 1.12 1.24 0.99 0.94
SD 0.57 0.49 0.35 0.29
N 12 12 13 8

Note: Own calculations; SD = standard deviation; N denotes the number of farms per group out of a total of 45 farm observations.

A.2 Additional results

Table A4
Variable selection procedure.
Candidate Number of observations of DMUs with TE > 1.10

2013/14 2014/15

Veterinary costs (input) 2 2


Costs for land and capital (input) 1 1
FAW-WQP (output, based on WQP score) 1 1

Note: Variables were considered relevant for the TE of DEA applications if more than 15% of the DMU (more than 6 farms in
our sample) changed their TE score by at least 10% after the decision making unit became efficient and the candidate was
excluded. Note, within all steps evaluating the respective candidates, standard DEA is conducted assuming inputs labour and
feed costs and milk yield as output.

382
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

Table A5
DEA-base output oriented approach for the year 2013/14.
DEA-Base DEA FAW-output

confinement mean 1.19 1.19


SD 0.20 0.20
< 6 h pasture mean 1.23 1.22
SD 0.15 0.15
6 h-10 h pasture mean 1.16 1.14
SD 0.10 0.11
> 10 h pasture mean 1.14 1.14
SD 0.14 0.14

Note: output-orientation and variable returns to scale were considered.

Table A6
Technical and FAW Efficiency (2013/14) - directional distance DEA and output-oriented.
Technical Efficiency FAW-Efficiency

Confinement mean 1.19 1.46


SD 0.12 0.42
< 6 h pasture mean 1.22 1.46
SD 0.16 0.27
6 h-10 h pasture mean 1.16 1.28
SD 0.11 0.21
> 10 h pasture mean 1.15 1.33
SD 0.14 0.24

Note: output-orientation and variable returns to scale were considered. N = 43 because for two farms no efficiency scores could be
generated.

Fig. A1. Technical and FAW Efficiency (2013/14) - directional distance DEA and output-oriented.

Table A7
Correlation between Technical and FAW Efficiency.
Year Method FAW-Efficiency

Technical Efficiency 2013/14 Kendall 0.78***


Spearman 0.59***
2014/15 Kendall 0.84***
Spearman 0.64***

Note:*** indicates significantly rejecting the null hypothesis for zero coefficients according to t-test at the 1% level.

Table A8
Size effects on efficiency (OLS).
Dependent variable Year Constant Size Coefficient

FAW-Efficiency 2013/14 1.5941*** −0.0018*


2014/15 1.6460*** −0.0026***
Technical Efficiency 2013/14 1.2951*** −0.0009**
2014/15 1.2998*** −0.0012***

Note: OLS regression for efficiencyi = α 0 + βherd herdsizei + εi , where εi denotes the error term. ***,** denotes the respective significance level to reject the null
hypotheses of βherd = 0 and α 0 = 0 of a t-test at the 1% and 5% level, respectively.

383
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

Table A9
Influence of Technical and FAW-Efficiency on farm profit.
Dependent variable Year Efficiency Constant Coefficient

Profit 2013/14 FAW 4.10 −0.98


Technical −14.07*** −9.58**
2014/15 FAW 0.38 −4.78**
Technical −13.49** −17.54***

Note: OLS regression for : profiti = α 0 + βeff efficiencyi + εi , where εi denotes the error term. ***,** denotes the respective significance level to reject the null hypotheses
of βeff = 0 and α 0 = 0 of a t-test at the 1% and 5% level, respectively.

References 160–166. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1751731112001395.


Cardoso, C.S., Hotzel, M.J., Weary, D.M., Robbins, J.A., von Keyserlingk, M.A.G., 2016.
Imagining the ideal dairy farm. J. Dairy Sci. 99 (2), 1663–1671. https://doi.org/10.
Allendorf, J.J., Wettemann, P.J.C., 2015. Does animal welfare influence dairy farm effi- 3168/jds.2015-9925.
ciency? A two-stage approach. J. Dairy Sci. 98 (11), 7730–7740. https://doi.org/10. Chambers, R.G., Chung, Y., Färe, R., 1996. Benefit and distance functions. J. Econ. Theory
3168/jds.2015-9390. 70 (2), 407–419. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeth.1996.0096.
Armbrecht, L., Lambertz, C., Albers, D., Gauly, M., 2015. Tierwohl von Milchkühen bei Chapinal, N., Goldhawk, C., Passillé, A.M., de, Keyserlingk, M.A.G., von, Weary, D.M.,
Stall-und Weidehaltung—Ein Vergleich anhand des Welfare Quality Protokolls. In: Rushen, J., 2010. Overnight access to pasture does not reduce milk production or
1st ed. In: Busch, G., Gieseke, D., Ikinger, C., Kühl, S., Pirsich, W. (Eds.), Tierhaltung feed intake in dairy cattle. Livest. Sci. 129 (1-3), 104–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
im Spannungsfeld von Tierwohl, Ökonomie und Gesellschaft. Tierwohl-Tagung in livsci.2010.01.011.
Göttingen, 07.- 08. Oktober 2015, vol. 1. Georg-August-Universität Department für Chapinal, N., Barrientos, A.K., von Keyserlingk, M.A.G., Galo, E., Weary, D.M., 2013.
Agrarökonomie und Rurale Entwicklung, Göttingen, pp. 70–72. Herd-level risk factors for lameness in freestall farms in the northeastern United
Arnott, G., Ferris, C.P., O’Connell, N.E., 2017. Review: Welfare of dairy cows in con- States and California. J. Dairy Sci. 96 (1), 318–328. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.
tinuously housed and pasture-based production systems. Animal 11 (2), 261–273. 2012-5940.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S1751731116001336. Charlton, G.L., Rutter, S.M., East, M., Sinclair, L.A., 2011. Preference of dairy cows: in-
Asmild, M., Hougaard, J.L., 2006. Economic versus environmental improvement poten- door cubicle housing with access to a total mixed ration vs. access to pasture. Appl.
tials of Danish pig farms. Agric. Econ. 35 (2), 171–181. https://doi.org/10.1111/j. Anim. Behav. Sci. 130 (1-2), 1–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.applanim.2010.11.018.
1574-0862.2006.00150.x. Charnes, A., Cooper, W.W., Rhodes, E., 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision making
Asmild, M., Hougaard, J.L., Kronborg, D., Kvist, H.K., 2003. Measuring inefficiency via units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2 (6), 429–444. https://doi.org/10.1016/0377-2217(78)
potential improvements. J. Prod. Anal. 19 (1), 59–76. https://doi.org/10.1023/ 90138-8.
A:1021822103696. Coelli, T.J., Prasada Rao, D.S., O’Donnell, C.J., Batesse, G.E., 2005. An Introduction to
Baird, L.G., O’Connell, N.E., McCoy, M.A., Keady, T.W.J., Kilpatrick, D.J., 2009. Effects of Efficiency and Productivity Analysis, 2nd ed. Springer, New York XVII, 349 S.
breed and production system on lameness parameters in dairy cattle. J. Dairy Sci. 92 Cooper, T., Hart, K., Baldock, D., 2009. Provision of public goods through agriculture in
(5), 2174–2182. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.2008-1333. the European Union. Report Prepared for DG Agricultural and Rural Developement,
Banker, R.D., Zheng, Z., Natarajan, R., 2010. DEA-based hypothesis tests for comparing Contract No 30-CE-02330911/00-28. Institute for European Enviromental Policiy,
two groups of decision making units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 206 (1), 231–238. https://doi. London 396 pp.
org/10.1016/j.ejor.2010.01.027. Dartt, B.A., Lloyd, J.W., Radke, B.R., Black, J.R., Kaneene, J.B., 1999. A comparison of
Barker, Z.E., Leach, K.A., Whay, H.R., Bell, N.J., Main, D.C.J., 2010. Assessment of la- profitability and economic efficiencies between management-intensive grazing and
meness prevalence and associated risk factors in dairy herds in England and Wales. J. conventionally managed dairies in Michigan. J. Dairy Sci. 82 (11), 2412–2420.
Dairy Sci. 93 (3), 932–941. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.2009-2309. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.S0022-0302(99)75492-5.
Barnes, A.P., Rutherford, K.M.D., Langford, F.M., Haskell, M.J., 2011. The effect of la- de Vries, M., Bokkers, E.A.M., van Reenen, C.G., Engel, B., van Schaik, G., Dijkstra, T., de
meness prevalence on technical efficiency at the dairy farm level: an adjusted data Boer, I.J.M., 2015. Housing and management factors associated with indicators of
envelopment analysis approach. J. Dairy Sci. 94 (11), 5449–5457. https://doi.org/ dairy cattle welfare. Prev. Vet. Med. 118 (1), 80–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
10.3168/jds.2011-4262. prevetmed.2014.11.016.
Bennema, S.C., Ducheyne, E., Vercruysse, J., Claerebout, E., Hendrickx, G., Charlier, J., Destatis, 2017. Land- Und Forstwirtschaft, Fischerei: Viehbestand Und Tierische
2011. Relative importance of management, meteorological and environmental fac- Erzeugung. Fachserie 3 Reihe 4, Wiesbaden, 2030400167004.
tors in the spatial distribution of Fasciola hepatica in dairy cattle in a temperate Drake, L., 1992. The non-market value of the Swedish agricultural landscape. Eur. Rev.
climate zone. Int. J. Parasitol. 41 (2), 225–233. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpara. Agric. Econ. 19 (3), 351–364. https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/19.3.351.
2010.09.003. Ellis, K.A., Billington, K., McNeil, B., McKeegan, D.E.F., 2009. Public opinion on UK milk
Bennett, R., 1995. The value of farm animal welfare. J. Agric. Econ. 46 (1), 46–60. marketing and dairy cow welfare. Anim. Welf. 18 (3), 267–282.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.1995.tb00751.x. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Lovell, C.A.K., 1985. The Measurement of Efficiency of
BLE, 2017. Milchleistung je Kuh in Deutschland in den Jahren 1900 bis 2016 (in Production. Springer, Dordrecht 216 pp.
Kilogramm). Accessed 28 November 2017. https://de.statista.com/statistik/daten/ Fraser, D., Duncan, I.J.H., Edwards, S.A., Grandin, T., Gregory, N.G., Guyonnet, V.,
studie/153061/umfrage/durchschnittlicher-milchertrag-je-kuh-in-deutschland-seit- Hemsworth, P.H., Huertas, S.M., Huzzey, J.M., Mellor, D.J., Mench, J.A., Spinka, M.,
2000/. Whay, H.R., 2013. General principles for the welfare of animals in production sys-
Bogetoft, P., Hougaard, J.L., 1999. Efficiency evaluations based on potential (non-pro- tems: the underlying science and its application. Vet. J. (Lond., Engl.: 1997) 198 (1),
portional) improvements. J. Prod. Anal. 12 (3), 233–247. https://doi.org/10.1023/ 19–27. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tvjl.2013.06.028.
A:1007848222681. Gieseke, D., Lambertz, C., Traulsen, I., Krieter, J., Gauly, M., 2014. Beurteilung von
Bogetoft, P., Otto, L., 2011. Benchmarking With DEA, SFA, and R. Springer New York, Tiergerechtheit in der Milchviehhaltung – Evaluierung des Welfare Quality
New York, NY 351 pp. Protokolls. Züchtungskunde 86 (1), 58–70.
Bogetoft, P., Otto, L., 2015. Package’ Benchmarking’. Accessed 30 April 2018. https:// Gocsik, É., Brooshooft, S.D., Jong, I.C., de, Saatkamp, H.W., 2016. Cost-efficiency of
cran.r-project.org/web/packages/Benchmarking/Benchmarking.pdf. animal welfare in broiler production systems: a pilot study using the Welfare Quality®
Botreau, R., Veissier, I., Perny, P., 2009. Overall assessment of animal welfare: strategy assessment protocol. Agric. Syst. 146, 55–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agsy.2016.
adopted in welfare quality. Anim. Welf. 18 (4), 363–370. 04.001.
Botreau, R., Winckler, C., Velarde, A., Dalmau, A., Butterworth, A., Keeling, L.J., Veissier, Hansson, H., Lagerkvist, C.J., 2015. Identifying use and non-use values of animal welfare:
I., 2013. Integration of data collected on farms or at slaughter to generate an overall evidence from Swedish dairy agriculture. Food Policy 50, 35–42. https://doi.org/10.
assessment of animal welfare. In: Blokhuis, H., Miele, M., Veissier, I., Jones, B. (Eds.), 1016/j.foodpol.2014.10.012.
Improving Farm Animal Welfare. Science and Society Working Together: the Welfare Hansson, H., Öhlmér, B., 2008. The effect of operational managerial practices on eco-
Quality Approach. Wageningen Academic Publishers, Wageningen, pp. 147–174. nomic, technical and allocative efficiency at Swedish dairy farms. Livest. Sci. 118 (1-
Bravo-Ureta, B.E., Rieger, L., 1991. Dairy farm efficiency measurement using stochastic 2), 34–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.livsci.2008.01.013.
frontiers and neoclassical duality. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 73 (2), 421. https://doi.org/10. Harvey, D., Hubbard, C., 2013. Reconsidering the political economy of farm animal
2307/1242726. welfare: an anatomy of market failure. Food Policy 38, 105–114. https://doi.org/10.
Breustedt, G., Latacz-Lohmann, U., Tiedemann, T., 2011. Organic or conventional?: op- 1016/j.foodpol.2012.11.006.
timal dairy farming technology under the EU milk quota system and organic sub- Henningsen, A., Czekaj, T.G., Forkman, B., Lund, M., Nielsen, A.S., 2018. The relationship
sidies. Food Policy 36 (2), 223–229. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2010.11.019. between animal welfare and economic performance at farm level: a quantitative
Burow, E., Thomsen, P.T., Sørensen, J.T., Rousing, T., 2011. The effect of grazing on cow study of Danish pig producers. J. Agric. Econ. 69 (1), 142–162. https://doi.org/10.
mortality in Danish dairy herds. Prev. Vet. Med. 100 (3-4), 237–241. https://doi.org/ 1111/1477-9552.12228.
10.1016/j.prevetmed.2011.04.001. Hoff, A., 2007. Second stage DEA: comparison of approaches for modelling the DEA score.
Burow, E., Thomsen, P.T., Rousing, T., Sørensen, J.T., 2013. Daily grazing time as a risk Eur. J. Oper. Res. 181 (1), 425–435. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2006.05.019.
factor for alterations at the hock joint integument in dairy cows. Animal 7 (1), Ingenbleek, P.T.M., Immink, V.M., Spoolder, H.A.M., Bokma, M.H., Keeling, L.J., 2012.

384
H.D. Schulte et al. Land Use Policy 79 (2018) 375–385

EU animal welfare policy: developing a comprehensive policy framework. Food Oper. Res. 50 (4), 728–735. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.50.4.728.2866.
Policy 37 (6), 690–699. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2012.07.001. Pérez Urdiales, M., Lansink, A.O., Wall, A., 2016. Eco-efficiency among dairy farmers: the
Islam, M.R., Garcia, S.C., Clark, C.E.F., Kerrisk, K.L., 2015. Modelling pasture-based au- importance of socio-economic characteristics and farmer attitudes. Environ. Resour.
tomatic milking system herds: system fitness of grazeable home-grown forages, land Econ. 64 (4), 559–574. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9885-1.
areas and walking distances. Asian Australas. J. Anim. Sci. 28 (6), 903–910. https:// Picazo-Tadeo, A.J., Beltrán-Esteve, M., Gómez-Limón, J.A., 2012. Assessing eco-efficiency
doi.org/10.5713/ajas.14.0385. with directional distance functions. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 220 (3), 798–809. https://doi.
Keeling, L. (Ed.), 2009. An Overview of the Development of the Welfare Quality® org/10.1016/j.ejor.2012.02.025.
Assessment Systems. Univ. School of City and Regional Planning, Cardiff V, 97 S. Pieralli, S., Hüttel, S., Odening, M., 2017. Abandonment of milk production under un-
Kehlbacher, A., Bennett, R., Balcombe, K., 2012. Measuring the consumer benefits of certainty and inefficiency: the case of western German farms. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ.
improving farm animal welfare to inform welfare labelling. Food Policy 37 (6), 44 (3), 425–454. https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbx001.
627–633. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2012.07.002. Podinovski, V.V., Thanassoulis, E., 2007. Improving discrimination in data envelopment
Korhonen, P.J., Luptacik, M., 2004. Eco-efficiency analysis of power plants: an extension analysis: some practical suggestions. J. Prod. Anal. 28 (1-2), 117–126. https://doi.
of data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 154 (2), 437–446. https://doi.org/ org/10.1007/s11123-007-0042-x.
10.1016/S0377-2217(03)00180-2. Reijs, J.W., Daatselaar, C.H.G., Helming, J.F.M., Jager, J., Beldman, A.C.G., 2013.
Lagerkvist, C.J., Hess, S., 2011. A meta-analysis of consumer willingness to pay for farm Grazing Dairy Cows in North-West Europe: Economic Farm Performance and Future
animal welfare. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 38 (1), 55–78. https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/ Developments With Emphasis on the Dutch Situation. LEI Wageningen UR, The
jbq043. Hague 124 pp.
Lakner, S., Breustedt, G., 2017. Efficiency analysis of organic farming systems‐a review of Roosen, J., Dahlhausen, J.L., Petershammer, S., 2016. Acceptance of animal husbandry
concepts, topics, results and conclusions. German J. Agric. Econ. 66 (2), 85–108. practices: the consumer perspective. Proceedings in Food System Dynamics, 2016:
Lawson, L.G., Agger, J.F., Lund, M., Coelli, T., 2004a. Lameness, metabolic and digestive Proceedings in System Dynamics and Innovation in Food Networks 2016 260–267.
disorders, and technical efficiency in Danish dairy herds: a stochastic frontier pro- https://doi.org/10.18461/pfsd.2016.1630.
duction function approach. Livest. Prod. Sci. 91 (1-2), 157–172. https://doi.org/10. Schreiner, J.A., Hess, S., 2017. The role of non-use values in dairy farmers’ willingness to
1016/j.livprodsci.2004.07.016. accept a Farm animal welfare programme. J. Agric. Econ. 68 (2), 553–578. https://
Lawson, L.G., Bruun, J., Coelli, T., Agger, J.F., Lund, M., 2004b. Relationships of effi- doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12203.
ciency to reproductive disorders in Danish milk production: a stochastic frontier Schuppli, C.A., Keyserlingk, M.A.G., von, Weary, D.M., 2014. Access to pasture for dairy
analysis. J. Dairy Sci. 87 (1), 212–224. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.S0022-0302(04) cows: responses from an online engagement. J. Anim. Sci. 92 (11), 5185–5192.
73160-4. https://doi.org/10.2527/jas.2014-7725.
Lefebvre, M., Espinosa, M., Gomez y Paloma, S., Paracchini, M.L., Piorr, A., Zasada, I., Sirvent, I., Ruiz, J.L., Borrás, F., Pastor, J.T., 2005. A Monte Carlo evaluation of several
2014. agricultural landscapes as multi-scale public good and the role of the common tests for the selection of variables in DEA models. Int. J. Info. Tech. Dec. Mak. 4 (03),
agricultural policy. J. Environ. Plann. Manage. 58 (12), 2088–2112. https://doi.org/ 325–343.
10.1080/09640568.2014.891975. Sutherland, L.-A., Gabriel, D., Hathaway-Jenkins, L., Pascual, U., Schmutz, U., Rigby, D.,
Legrand, A.L., Keyserlingk, M.A.G., von, Weary, D.M., 2009. Preference and usage of Godwin, R., Sait, S.M., Sakrabani, R., Kunin, W.E., Benton, T.G., Stagl, S., 2012. The
pasture versus free-stall housing by lactating dairy cattle. J. Dairy Sci. 92 (8), ‘Neighbourhood Effect’: a multidisciplinary assessment of the case for farmer co-or-
3651–3658. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.2008-1733. dination in agri-environmental programmes. Land Use Policy 29 (3), 502–512.
Lusk, J.L., 2011. The market for animal welfare. Agric. Hum. Values 28 (4), 561–575. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2011.09.003.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-011-9318-x. Vance, E.R., Ferris, C.P., Elliott, C.T., McGettrick, S.A., Kilpatrick, D.J., 2012. Food intake,
Lusk, J.L., Norwood, F.B., 2011. Animal welfare economics. Appl. Econ. Perspect. Policy milk production, and tissue changes of Holstein-Friesian and Jersey x Holstein-
33 (4), 463–483. https://doi.org/10.1093/aepp/ppr036. Friesian dairy cows within a medium-input grazing system and a high-input total
Mann, S., 2005. Ethological farm programs and the “market” for animal welfare. J. Agric. confinement system. J. Dairy Sci. 95 (3), 1527–1544. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.
Environ. Ethics 18 (4), 369–382. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10806-005-7049-y. 2011-4410.
McDonald, J., 2009. Using least squares and tobit in second stage DEA efficiency analyses. Vanderstichel, R., Dohoo, I., Sanchez, J., Conboy, G., 2012. Effects of farm management
Eur. J. Oper. Res. 197 (2), 792–798. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.07.039. practices and environmental factors on bulk tank milk antibodies against gastro-
McInerney, J., 2004. Animal Welfare, Economics and Policy: Report on a Study intestinal nematodes in dairy farms across Canada. Prev. Vet. Med. 104 (1-2), 53–64.
Undertaken for the Farm & Animal Health Economics Division of Defra. DEFRA, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.prevetmed.2011.09.022.
Exeter, UK Accessed 15 November 2016. http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov. Veissier, I., Butterworth, A., Bock, B., Roe, E., 2008. European approaches to ensure good
uk/20110318142209/http://www.defra.gov.uk/evidence/economics/foodfarm/ animal welfare. Appl. Anim. Behav. Sci. 113 (4), 279–297. https://doi.org/10.1016/
reports/documents/animalwelfare.pdf. j.applanim.2008.01.008.
Motupalli, P.R., Sinclair, L.A., Charlton, G.L., Bleach, E.C., Rutter, S.M., 2014. Preference Weinrich, R., Kuehl, S., Zuehlsdorf, A., Spiller, A., 2014. Consumer attitudes in Germany
and behavior of lactating dairy cows given free access to pasture at two herbage towards different dairy housing systems and their implications for the marketing of
masses and two distances. J. Anim. Sci. 92 (11), 5175–5184. https://doi.org/10. pasture raised milk. Int. Food Agribus. Manage. Assoc. 17 (4), 205–221.
2527/jas.2014-8046. Welfare Quality®, 2012. Welfare Quality® Assessment Protocol for Cattle. Welfare Quality
Napolitano, F., Pacelli, C., Girolami, A., Braghieri, A., 2008. Effect of information about Consortium, Lelystad, Netherlands 182 pp.
animal welfare on consumer willingness to pay for yogurt. J. Dairy Sci. 91 (3), Wettemann, P.J.C., Latacz-Lohmann, U., 2017. An efficiency-based concept to assess
910–917. https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.2007-0709. potential cost and greenhouse gas savings on German dairy farms. Agric. Syst. 152,
Pastor, J.T., Ruiz, J.L., Sirvent, I., 2002. A statistical test for nested radial dea models. 27–37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agsy.2016.11.010.

385

You might also like