You are on page 1of 25

Chapter 12

Unemployment and Inflation

 Learning Objectives
I. Goals of Part 4
A. How macroeconomic policy works and how it can best be used
1. Unemployment and inflation (this chapter)
2. Policy in an open economy—international trade and finance (Ch. 13)
3. Monetary institutions and policy (Ch. 14)
4. Fiscal institutions and policy (Ch. 15)

II. Goals of Chapter 12


A. Describe the Phillips curve relationship between unemployment and inflation (Sec. 12.1)
B. Discuss whether the Phillips curve offers a ‘menu’ of inflation-unemployment combinations
from which policymakers can choose (Sec. 12.2)
C. Identify the costs of unemployment and discuss the natural rate of unemployment (Sec. 12.3)
D. Discuss the types and costs of inflation (Sec. 12.4)
E. Discuss the challenges and costs of reducing inflation (Sec. 12.5)

III. Notes to Eighth Edition Users


A. We add a discussion of the problems that arise if inflation is too low
B. We use the term short-run Phillips curve instead of Phillips curve to clarify the differences
between the short-run and long-run Phillips curves
C. Note that we rearranged and renumbered the numerical problems at the end of the chapter

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 273

 Teaching Notes
I. Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? (Sec. 12.1)
A. Many people think there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment
1. The idea originated in 1958 when A.W. Phillips showed a negative relationship between
unemployment and nominal wage growth in Britain
2. Since then economists have looked at the relationship between unemployment and inflation
3. In the 1950s and 1960s many nations seemed to have a negative relationship between the
two variables
4. The United States appears to be on one Phillips curve in the 1960s (text Figure 12.1)
5. This suggested that policymakers could choose the combination of unemployment and
inflation they most desired
6. But the relationship fell apart in the following three decades (text Figure 12.2)
7. The 1970s were a particularly bad period, with both high inflation and high unemployment,
inconsistent with the Phillips curve
B. The expectations-augmented Phillips curve
1. Friedman and Phelps: The cyclical unemployment rate (the difference between actual and
natural unemployment rates) depends only on unanticipated inflation (the difference between
actual and expected inflation)
a. This theory was made before the Phillips curve began breaking down in the 1970s
b. It suggests that the relationship between inflation and the unemployment rate isn’t stable
2. How does this work in the extended classical model?

Analytical Problem 3 looks at similar analysis in a Keynesian model.

a. First case: anticipated increase in money supply (Figure 12.1; like text Figure 12.3)

Figure 12.1

(1) AD shifts up and SRAS shifts up, with no misperceptions


(2) Result: P rises, Y unchanged
(3) Inflation rises with no change in unemployment
b. Second case: unanticipated increase in money supply (Figure 12.2; like text Figure 12.4)

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


274 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

Figure 12.2
(1) AD expected to shift up to AD2, old (money supply expected to rise 10%), but
unexpectedly money supply rises 15%, so AD shifts further up to AD2, new
(2) SRAS shifts up based on expected 10% rise in money supply
(3) Result: P rises and Y rises as misperceptions occur
(4) So higher inflation occurs with lower unemployment

Numerical Problems 1 and 3 and Analytical Problem 2 look at the misperceptions model and how
it generates behavior like the Phillips curve.

(5) Long run: P rises further, Y declines to full-employment level


c. Expectations-augmented Phillips curve:
   e  h(u  u ) (12.1)
(1) When    , u  u
e

(2) When  <  e, u > u

Numerical Problem 4 uses the expectations-augmented Phillips curve.

(3) When  >  e, u < u


C. The shifting Phillips curve
1. The short-run Phillips curve shows the relationship between unemployment and inflation for
a given expected rate of inflation and natural rate of unemployment
2. Changes in the expected rate of inflation (Figure 12.3; like text Figure 12.5)

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 275

Figure 12.3
a. For a given expected rate of inflation, the short-run Phillips curve shows the trade-off
between cyclical unemployment and actual inflation
b. The short-run Phillips curve is drawn such that    e when u  u
c. Higher expected inflation implies a higher short-run Phillips curve
3. Changes in the natural rate of unemployment (Figure 12.4; like text Figure 12.6)

Figure 12.4
a. For a given natural rate of unemployment, the short-run Phillips curve shows the trade-off
between unemployment and unanticipated inflation

Analytical Problem 1 looks at possible ways to change the natural rate of unemployment.

b. A higher natural rate of unemployment shifts the short-run Phillips curve to the right
4. Supply shocks and the Phillips curve
a. A supply shock increases both expected inflation and the natural rate of unemployment
(1) A supply shock in the classical model increases the natural rate of unemployment,
because it increases the mismatch between firms and workers

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


276 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

(2) A supply shock in the Keynesian model reduces the marginal product of labor and
thus reduces labor demand at the fixed real wage, so the natural unemployment
rate rises
b. So an adverse supply shock shifts the short-run Phillips curve up and to the right
c. The short-run Phillips curve will be unstable in periods with many supply shocks

Numerical Problem 2 looks at the effects of an aggregate demand shock and an aggregate supply
shock on the short-run Phillips curve.

5. The shifting short-run Phillips curve in practice


a. Why did the original Phillips curve relationship apply to many historical cases?
(1) The original relationship between inflation and unemployment holds up as long as
expected inflation and the natural rate of unemployment are approximately constant
(2) This was true in the United States in the 1960s, so the Phillips curve appeared to
be stable
b. Why did the U.S. Phillips curve disappear after 1970?
(1) Both the expected inflation rate and the natural rate of unemployment varied
considerably more in the 1970s than they did in the 1960s
(2) Especially important were the oil price shocks of 1973–1974 and 1979–1980
(3) Also, the composition of the labor force changed in the 1970s and there were other
structural changes in the economy as well, raising the natural rate of unemployment
(4) Monetary policy was expansionary in the 1970s, leading to high and volatile inflation
(5) Plotting unanticipated inflation against cyclical unemployment shows a fairly stable
relationship since 1970 (text Figure 12.7)
II. Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve (Sec. 12.2)
A. Can the Phillips curve be exploited by policymakers? Can they choose the optimal combination
of unemployment and inflation?
1. Classical model: NO
a. The unemployment rate returns to its natural level quickly, as people’s expectations
adjust
b. So unemployment can change from its natural level only for a very brief time
c. Also, people catch on to policy games; they have rational expectations and try to
anticipate policy changes, so there is no way to fool people systematically

Policy Application
The theory of rational expectations explains why the Phillips curve trade-off appeared to be stable
for some time, but failed when policymakers tried to exploit it. In the 1960s people assumed that
any rise in inflation would be temporary. But once policymakers began to exploit the trade-off,
people caught on quickly. Instead of having adaptive expectations, which were rational in the
past, people began to watch what policymakers were doing. Then expected inflation changed
quickly with changes in policy.

2. Keynesian model: YES, temporarily


a. The expected rate of inflation in the Phillips curve is the forecast of inflation at the time
the oldest sticky prices were set
b. It takes time for prices and expected prices to adjust, so unemployment may differ from
the natural rate for some time

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 277

Theoretical Application
The Keynesian models of the early 1970s assumed that people formed adaptive expectations, that
is, that expected inflation depended only on past inflation, so  te  f (t  1, t  2, . . .). According to
rational expectations theory, however, people base their inflation expectations on an economic
model in which inflation depends on other variables, such as the growth rate of the money
supply, the state of the economy, and expectations of future government deficits. Adaptive
expectations could be rational, as in the 1950s and 1960s, because an economic model would
suggest a simple time-series process for inflation. But once the Fed began using monetary policy
for countercyclical policy, or for trying to exploit the Phillips curve, adaptive expectations
became irrational. With rational expectations, people began to anticipate changes in monetary
policy, and the Phillips curve began to shift with changes in policy.

B. In touch with data and research: The Lucas critique


1. When the rules of the game change, behavior changes
2. For example, if batters in baseball were called out after two strikes instead of three, they’d
swing more often when they have one strike than they do now
3. Lucas applied this idea to macroeconomics, arguing that historical relationships between
variables won’t hold up if there’s been a major policy change
4. The short-run Phillips curve is a good example—it fell apart as soon as policymakers tried
to exploit it
5. Evaluating policy requires an understanding of how behavior will change under the new
policy, so both economic theory and empirical analysis are necessary
Theoretical Application
Robert Lucas and Tom Sargent spelled out the implications of the Lucas critique for future work
on macroeconomics and business cycles in their article, “After Keynesian Macroeconomics.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Spring, 1979, pp. 1–16.

C. The long-run Phillips curve


1. Long run: u  u for both Keynesians and classicals
2. The long-run Phillips curve is vertical, since when    e, u  u (Figure 12.5;
like text Figure 12.8)

Figure 12.5

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


278 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

3. Changes in the level of money supply have no long-run real effects; changes in the growth
rate of money supply have no long-run real effects, either
4. Even though expansionary policy may reduce unemployment only temporarily, policymakers
may want to do so if, for example, timing economic booms right before elections helps them
(or their political allies) get reelected

Theoretical Application
For a well written history of the Phillips curve and its usefulness, see the article by Robert J.
Gordon, “The Phillips Curve Now and Then,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper No. 3393, June 1990. For more recent research on the Phillips curve, see the symposium in
the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39 (supplement, Feb. 2007).

III. The Problem of Unemployment (Sec. 12.3)


A. The costs of unemployment
1. Loss in output from idle resources
a. Workers lose income
b. Society pays for unemployment benefits and makes up lost tax revenue
c. Using Okun’s Law (each percentage point of cyclical unemployment is associated with a
loss equal to 2% of full-employment output), if full-employment output is $17 trillion,
each percentage point of unemployment sustained for one year costs $340 billion
2. Personal or psychological cost to workers and their families
a. Especially important for those with long spells of unemployment
3. Costs of unemployment may vary across demographic groups4. There are some
offsetting factors
a. Unemployment leads to increased job search and acquiring new skills, which may lead to
increased future output
b. Unemployed workers have increased leisure time, though most wouldn’t feel that the
increased leisure compensated them for being unemployed

Data Application 
Recent research suggests that the costs of unemployment to individual workers may be higher if they
become unemployed at the same time as many other people. Research by Stephen J. Davis and Till M.
von Wachter, “Recessions and the Cost of Job Loss,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall
2011, pp. 1-72, shows that people who are laid off in periods when the overall unemployment rate is
6% or less lose about 1.4 years’ worth of earnings; but those laid off in periods when the overall
unemployment rate is above 8% lose twice as much, on average.

B. The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate


1. The changing natural rate
a. How do we calculate the natural rate of unemployment?
b. CBO’s estimates: about 5.5% in 2015, somewhat higher than it was in the early 2000s but
somewhat lower than its value in the late 1970s
c. In the 1980s and 1990s, demographic forces reduced the natural rate of unemployment
(text Fig. 12.9)
(1) The proportion of the labor force aged 16–24 years fell from 25% in 1980 to 16%
in 1998 and to 13% in 2015
(2) Research by Shimer showed this is the main reason for the fall in the natural rate

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 279

of unemployment
d. Some economists think the natural rate of unemployment was 4.5% or even lower in the
1990s and 2000s
(1) The labor market became more efficient at matching workers and jobs, reducing
frictional and structural unemployment
(2) Temporary help agencies became prominent, helping the matching process and
reducing the natural rate of unemployment
f. Increased labor productivity may increase the natural rate of unemployment
(1) If increases in real wages lag changes in productivity, firms hire more workers and
the natural rate of unemployment will decline temporarily
(2) Ball and Mankiw found evidence supporting this hypothesis in the 1990s

Data Application
A very different picture of the natural rate of unemployment than that of the CBO comes from
classical economists, who think the natural rate changes much more than the CBO’s measure does.
One version of this can be found in the article “In Search of the Natural Rate of Unemployment,”
by Thomas B. King and James Morley, Journal of Monetary Economics (2007), pp. 550–564.

2. Measuring the natural rate of unemployment


a. Policymakers need a measure of the natural rate of unemployment to use the
unemployment rate for setting policy
b. Economists disagree about how to measure the natural rate of unemployment and the
CBO has often revised its measure
c. Staiger, Stock, and Watson found that the natural rate cannot be measured precisely with
econometric methods, as the confidence interval is very large
d. What should policymakers do in response to uncertainty about the natural rate
of unemployment?
(1) They may wish to be less aggressive with policy than they would be if they knew the
natural rate more precisely
(2) Research (Orphanides-Williams) suggests that the rise of inflation in the 1970s can
be blamed on bad estimates of the natural rate

Analytical Problem 6 looks at events that change the natural rate of unemployment.

IV. The Problem of Inflation (Sec. 12.4)


A. The costs of inflation
1. Perfectly anticipated inflation
a. No effects if all prices and wages keep up with inflation
b. Even returns on assets may rise exactly with inflation
c. Shoe-leather costs: People spend resources to economize on currency holdings;
the estimated cost of 10% inflation is 0.3% of GNP
d. Menu costs: the costs of changing prices (but technology may mitigate this somewhat)

Analytical Problem 4 looks at the costs of anticipated and unanticipated inflation in a cashless
society.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


280 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

Policy Application
Shoe-leather costs are generated by people’s attempt to reduce how much cash they hold.
Implicitly, inflation is like a tax on people’s cash holdings, because the government buys things
with newly printed money (just like it could if it collected taxes to pay for them) and people who
hold cash lose purchasing power (just as if their money was taxed). Some economists have gone
so far as to suggest that using the inflation tax is beneficial to the economy, because much of the
burden is borne by people in the underground economy and foreigners who use U.S. dollars. See
S. Rao Aiyagari, “Deflating the Case for Zero Inflation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review, Summer 1990.

Policy Application
Two other costs of anticipated inflation are increased taxation on capital income and the
mortgage-tilt problem.
Because taxes are based on the dollar value of interest that savers receive, the higher the
inflation rate is, the larger is the government’s tax revenue as a proportion of a saver’s real
return. The increase in the government’s effective real tax rate represents a distortion to the
economy—higher anticipated inflation reduces saving and investment.
Another cost of perfectly anticipated inflation is the problem of “tilting” the real value of loan
payments over time. To see this, suppose inflation were zero and you borrowed $100,000 to buy a
house, repaying the mortgage loan over 30 years. At an interest rate of 5% per year, your monthly
mortgage payment would be $540. In real (inflation-adjusted) terms, the payment would be the
same over time. But if the inflation rate were 5% per year and the mortgage interest rate were
10% per year, your monthly payment would be $880. In real terms, the value of the monthly
payment would be very high initially but decline steadily over time. The real value of your final
payment would be just 23% of your initial payment. (The value of a dollar payment made
30 years in the future at an interest rate of 5% is given by the formula 1/1.0530  $0.23.) A graph
of the real payment amount tilts downward, so this phenomenon is often referred to as the
mortgage-tilt problem. The tilt is greater, the higher is the inflation rate. Because of the
mortgage-tilt problem, homeowners face higher real payments early in the lives of their loans,
when they can probably least afford it, and they may face difficulties getting approved for
mortgages because the initial payment is a larger fraction of their household income. Thus,
anticipated inflation reduces homeownership. (For more discussion of the mortgage-tilt problem
and an estimate of the benefits to eliminating the problem by reducing inflation to zero, see
Dean Croushore, “What Are the Costs of Disinflation?” Business Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, May/June 1992, pp. 3–16.)
2. Unanticipated inflation (   e)
a. Realized real returns differ from expected real returns
(1) Expected r  i   e
(2) Actual r  i  
(3) Actual r differs from expected r by  e – 
(4) Numerical example: i  6%,  e  4%, so expected r  2%; if   6%, actual
r  0%; if   2%, actual r  4%
b. Similar effect on wages and salaries
c. Result: transfer of wealth
(1) From lenders to borrowers when    e
(2) From borrowers to lenders when    e

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 281

Data Application
Since the inflation of the mid-1970 was a surprise to people, it led to a large transfer of wealth.
The biggest winners in the 1970s were homeowners who owned land (which appreciated in value
with inflation) and had fixed-rate mortgages (whose value fell with inflation). The biggest losers
were the wealthy who owned stocks and bonds, as real returns fell dramatically because of
inflation.

d. So people want to avoid risk of unanticipated inflation


(1) They spend resources to forecast inflation

Data Application
In my article, “Inflation Forecasts: How Good Are They?” (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review, May/June 1996), I examine tests of bias in the inflation forecasts of both
consumers and professional forecasters. The forecasts looked very bad in the 1970s, probably
because of the two big oil price shocks in that period. Since then, the forecasts have been very
good, suggesting that the forecasts are formed rationally.

(2) In touch with data and research: Indexed contracts


(a) People could use indexed contracts to avoid the risk of transferring wealth
because of unanticipated inflation
(b) Most U.S. financial contracts are not indexed, with the exception of some
long-term contracts like adjustable-rate mortgages and inflation-indexed bonds
issued by the U.S. Treasury beginning in 1997
(c) Many U.S. labor contracts are indexed by COLAs (cost-of-living adjustments)
(d) Indexed contracts are more prevalent in countries with high inflation

Policy Application
It’s difficult to figure out how to index wages to inflation, or how low inflation should be, when
inflation isn’t measured very well. For an interesting discussion of the issues and implications of
mismeasurement of inflation, see the symposium on “Measuring the CPI” in the Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Winter 1998.

e. Loss of valuable signals provided by prices


(1) Confusion over changes in aggregate prices vs. changes in relative prices
(2) People expend resources to extract correct signals from prices

Data Application
For a review of the empirical evidence on the costs of inflation, see the article by John Driffill,
Grayham E. Mizon, and Alistair Ulph, “Costs of Inflation,” in B. M. Friedman and F. H. Hahn,
eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. II, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers, 1990,
pp. 1013–1066.

3. The costs of hyperinflation


a. Hyperinflation is a very high, sustained inflation (e.g., 50% or more per month)
(1) Hungary in August 1945 had inflation of 19,800% per month
(2) In Zimbabwe, the annual rate of inflation was 1017% in 2006, 10,453% in 2007, and
soared to 55.6 billion percent in 2008, before dropping to 6.5% in 2009

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


282 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

Data Application
There are many wonderful stories one can tell to illustrate the problems that arise in
hyperinflations. For example, there’s the story about the person who goes to the bank with a
wheelbarrow full of money, but can’t get the wheelbarrow through the bank’s door. He goes
inside to get help and when he returns, the money is still there but the wheelbarrow has been
stolen. There’s also the mind-boggling size of the Hyperinflation figures. For example, in
Hungary between August 1945 and July 1946, the purchasing power of a unit of money fell
by a factor of 4 octillion! That’s 4,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000.

b. There are large shoe-leather costs, as people minimize cash balances


c. People spend many resources getting rid of money as fast as possible
d. Tax collections fall, as people pay taxes with money whose value has declined sharply
e. Prices become worthless as signals, so markets become inefficient

4. Can Inflation Be Too Low?


a. Should central banks be concerned about low inflation rates or even deflation (negative
rates of inflation?)
b. Low inflation can be harmful
1. Borrowers are hurt by unexpectedly low inflation, as in the 1930s, when deflation
led to severe financial distress
2. Anticipated deflation also has costs, such as the increase in real wages if nominal
wages are sticky, leading to lower employment
3. Understanding relative prices can also be difficult in a deflationary environment
c. Nominal interest rates cannot generally fall below zero, so under deflation, real interest
rates cannot be very low
1. So a central bank’s ability to reduce real interest rates to combat a recession is
limited
2. For example, if deflation occurs at a rate of 2% (that is, the inflation rate is
negative 2%), the lowest real interest rate possible occurs when the nominal
interest rate is 0%, in which case the real interest rate is 2%
3. However, if inflation were positive 2%, the central bank could achieve a real
interest rate of negative 2%
d. What inflation rate should central banks aim for?
1. Many central banks target inflation around 2%
2. An inflation rate around 2% keeps the costs of inflation fairly low
3. But an inflation rate of 2% is high enough that there is only a small risk that the
economy will suffer from deflation
4. In addition, inflation measures are biased up, so 2% measured inflation means that
true inflation is somewhat lower

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 283

Policy Application
Given the costs of inflation and the vertical long-run Phillips curve, what is the optimal rate of
inflation? Some economists suggest that the optimal rate of inflation is zero or even negative
(so that the nominal rate of interest is zero). See the discussion by Michelle R. Garfinkel, “What
Is an ‘Acceptable’ Rate of Inflation? A Review of the Issues,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, July/August 1989. pp. 3–16. The debate over the pursuit of zero inflation reached its
peak in 1990 in the United States and Canada. Two conferences reflecting research on zero
inflation were held in Canada; see Zero Inflation: The Goal of Price Stability, Richard G. Lipsey,
ed., and Taking Aim: The Debate on Zero Inflation, Robert C. York, ed., both published by the
C.D. Howe Institute, Ottawa, Ontario, 1990. Canada’s central bank adopted a target of zero
inflation in the early 1990s.

V. Fighting inflation: The role of inflationary expectations (Sec. 12.5)


A. If rapid money growth causes inflation, why do central banks allow the money supply to grow
rapidly?
1. Developing or war-torn countries may not be able to raise taxes or borrow, so they print
money to finance spending
2. Industrialized countries may try to use expansionary monetary policy to fight recessions,
then not tighten monetary policy enough later
B. Disinflation is a reduction in the rate of inflation
1. But disinflations may lead to recessions
2. An unexpected reduction in inflation leads to a rise in unemployment along the Phillips curve

Data Application
There are many problems with price indexes; they are imperfect measures of price changes. What
do the indexes do when new goods are introduced? What happens as more efficient stores replace
stores that had higher intermediate costs? How do we account for the fact that people substitute
cheaper goods for higher-priced goods? Inadequate treatment of these questions means the
measures of prices give an overestimate of the inflation rate of 0% to 2%. So a measured
inflation rate of 1% might really mean that the true average price level is constant. See David E.
Lebow, John M. Roberts, and David J. Stockton, “Understanding the Goal of Price Stability,”
Working Paper No. 125, Economic Activity Section, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, April 1992.

C. The costs of disinflation could be reduced if expected inflation fell at the same time actual
inflation fell
D. Rapid versus gradual disinflation
1. The classical prescription for disinflation is cold turkey—a rapid and decisive reduction in
money growth
a. Proponents argue that the economy will adjust fairly quickly, with low costs of
adjustment, if the policy is announced well in advance
b. Keynesians disagree
(1) Price stickiness due to menu costs and wage stickiness due to labor contracts make
adjustment slow
(2) Cold turkey disinflation would cause a major recession

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


284 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

(3) The strategy might fail to alter inflation expectations, because if the costs of the
policy are high (because the economy goes into recession), the government will
reverse the policy

Data Application
Tom Sargent (“The Ends of Four Big Inflations”) suggests that high rates of inflation may be
reduced quickly with little output loss if a country creates an independent central bank and
changes its fiscal policy to eliminate government budged deficits. Robert Gordon (“Why
Stopping Inflation May Be Costly: Evidence from Fourteen Historical Episodes”) suggests that
there have been very few disinflation episodes without substantial output loss; most recent
disinflations have been accompanied by substantial recessions. See their articles in Robert
E. Hall, ed., Inflation: Causes and Effects, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.

2. The Keynesian prescription for disinflation is gradualism


a. A gradual approach gives prices and wages time to adjust to the disinflation

Policy Application
In the late 1980s the Federal Reserve embarked on an attempt at gradualism, at least in their
stated ranges for the M2 monetary aggregate. The Fed lowered the growth range for M2 by
roughly ½ percentage point each year from 1986 to 1994.

b. Such a strategy will be politically sustainable because the costs are low

Data Application
In my article “What Are the Costs of Disinflation?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review, May/June 1992, pp. 3–16, I examine the costs to the economy of reducing
inflation from its existing rate to zero in a variety of models: a Keynesian model, a Monetarist
model, a classical (misperceptions) model, and a hybrid model. The costs of disinflation are
found to be substantially smaller than the benefits in all but the Keynesian model.

E. In touch with data and research: The sacrifice ratio


1. When unanticipated tight monetary and fiscal policies are used to reduce inflation, they
reduce output and employment for a time, a cost that must be weighed against the benefits
of lower inflation
2. Economists use the sacrifice ratio as a measure of the costs
a. The sacrifice ratio is the number of percentage points of output lost in reducing
inflation by one percentage point
b. For example, a study of past disinflations by Laurence Ball found that U.S. inflation
fell by 8.83 percentage points in the early 1980s, with a loss in output of
16.18 percent of the nation’s potential output
(1) The sacrifice ratio was 16.18 divided by 8.83, which equals 1.832
3. Ball studied the sacrifice ratios for many different disinflations around the world in the
1960s, 1970s, and 1980s
a. The sacrifice ratios varied substantially across countries, from less than 1 to almost 3
b. One factor affecting the sacrifice ratio is the flexibility of the labor market
(1) Countries with slow wage adjustment (e.g., because of heavy government
regulation of the labor market) have higher sacrifice ratios

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 285

c. Ball also found a lower sacrifice ratio from cold turkey disinflation than from
gradualism
4. Ball’s results should be interpreted with caution, since it isn’t easy to calculate the loss
of output and because supply shocks can distort the calculation of the sacrifice ratio

Data Application
A version of Ball’s article that is accessible to students is “How Costly Is Disinflation? The
Historical Evidence,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review,
November/December 1993, pp. 17–28.

F. Wage and price controls


1. Pro: Controls would hold down inflation, thus lowering expected inflation and reducing the
costs of disinflation
2. Con: Controls lead to shortages and inefficiency; once controls are lifted, prices will rise
again
3. The outcome of wage and price controls may depend on what happens with fiscal and
monetary policy
a. If policies remain expansionary, people will expect renewed inflation when the controls
are lifted
b. If tight policies are pursued, expected inflation may decline

Analytical Problem 5 looks at what happens if the government uses wage and price controls, but
continues to use expansionary policies.

4. The Nixon wage-price controls from August 1971 to April 1974 led to shortages in many
products; the controls reduced inflation when they were in effect, but prices returned to
where they would have been soon after the controls were lifted
G. Credibility and reputation
1. Key determinant of the costs of disinflation: how quickly expected inflation adjusts
2. This depends on credibility of disinflation policy; if people believe the government and if
the government carries through with its policy, expected inflation should drop rapidly
3. Credibility can be enhanced if the government gets a reputation for carrying out its
promises
4. Also, having a strong and independent central bank that is committed to low inflation
provides credibility
H. The U.S. disinflation of the 1980s and 1990s
1. Fed chairmen Volcker and Greenspan gradually reduced the inflation rate in the 1980s and
1990s
a. They sought to eliminate inflation as a source of economic instability
b. They wanted people to be confident that inflation would never be very high again
2. To judge the Fed’s success, we look at inflation expectations (text Fig. 12.10)
a. Inflation expectations were erratic before 1990
b. Inflation expectations fell gradually from 1990 to 1998 and have been stable since then
3. Inflation expectations were slow to decline initially (in the late 1970s and early 1980s)
because Volcker and the Fed lacked credibility
4. But as inflation continued to fall, the Fed’s credibility increased, and inflation expectations
declined gradually
5. To solidify those expectations, the Fed declared a 2% long-run inflation target in 2012

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


286 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

Data Application
In the severe recession that began in December 2007 and was precipitated by the housing crisis,
inflation declined substantially. Some analysts thought that inflation fell mainly because of the
decline in housing prices. However, as economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
note (see Bart Hobijn, Stefano Eusepi, and Andrea Tambalotti, “The Housing Drag on Core
Inflation,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter, 2010–11, April 5, 2010,
available online at: www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2010/el2010-11.pdf), this was not
the case; instead, prices of most goods and services stopped growing as rapidly as before. Core
inflation including housing prices does not differ much from core inflation excluding housing
prices.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 287

 Additional Issues for Classroom Discussion


1. Additional Costs of Anticipated Inflation
The interaction of the tax system with inflation. Most countries’ tax systems are not perfectly
indexed for inflation. They impose taxes on nominal, not real, returns on investments (bonds and stocks),
which distort the prices on those assets. Also, capital gains are taxed in nominal terms, so investors may
pay a big tax on assets whose value hasn’t even increased in real terms. Eytan Sheshinski, in “Treatment
of Capital Income in Recent Tax Reforms and the Cost of Capital in Industrialized Countries,” in Larry
Summers, ed., Tax Policy and the Economy 4, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990, pp. 25–42, found that
the implicit tax rate on real investment returns exceeded 100% at times in the 1970s, and was over 50% in
the 1980s, all because of taxing nominal returns instead of real returns.
To see this in a simple example (with a simplifying assumption that the real return, not the after-tax real
return, is fixed), consider two cases in which there’s a 30% tax rate. Case A has inflation of 0% and a
nominal interest rate of 2%. An investor loses .6% of the 2% return to taxation, thus netting 1.4% in both
nominal and real terms. In case B, inflation is 5% and the nominal interest rate is 7%. Taxation costs 2.1% of
the 7% return, leaving a nominal after-tax return of 4.9%. Subtracting the inflation rate gives a real after-tax
return of –0.1%. (Though the simplifying assumption generates these results, this seems consistent with the
data.) A solution to this problem is to adjust capital values for inflation before taxing them.
The mortgage tilt problem. Mortgage loans are most often made at fixed rates for long terms. When
inflation is positive, the constant nominal payment over time is much higher in real terms early in the life of
the loan, and lower in real terms later in the life of the loan, because of a higher price level. This means that
the burden of paying the loan is higher when households are younger. So if the households are liquidity
constrained, they may not be able to afford to buy a home as early as they could if there was no inflation.

Here’s a numerical example. Consider a $100,000, 30-year mortgage. In case A inflation is 0% and the
nominal interest rate is 5%. The monthly payment is $540, the real value of which is constant over time.
Using the 28% rule used by lenders today (that a person’s mortgage payment shouldn’t exceed 28% of
income), a person would have to have income of $23,000 to qualify for the mortgage. In case B inflation is
5% and the nominal interest rate is 10%. The monthly payment on the mortgage is $880. But this amount
declines steadily over time in real terms because of inflation. The income needed to qualify for the mortgage
is $37,000. So in case B with higher inflation, the initial monthly payment is higher and the income needed
to qualify for the loan is higher, so inflation discourages homeownership. (Again, the result wouldn’t be so
dramatic except for some simplifications; the 28% rule might become a higher number if inflation were
lower.) There is a potential solution to this problem, which is the introduction of a price-level-adjusted
mortgage (PLAM); but PLAMs haven’t yet been adopted by financial institutions.

2. Can Unemployment Help Workers and the Economy?


If an unemployed worker always accepted the first job offered, unemployment would decrease in the short
run. However, such a practice is likely to reduce output and to lead to more frequent periods of
unemployment over several years. Accepting the first opening made available will often put a person into
a position that does not match his or her skills, preferences, and abilities. When the job and the individual
are not well suited to each other, both the employer and the employee are likely to be dissatisfied and
productivity will tend to be lower. Workers are more likely to leave such positions. Taking additional time
to find a better fit normally will result in the worker finding a situation that makes good use of his or her
skills and abilities. This will often lead to the new employee being very productive and staying with the
new company for a long time.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


288 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

3. Should the Fed Aim for Zero Inflation?


Discuss with your students the ultimate goal of the Federal Reserve (or any other country’s central bank).
Should the goal be to drive inflation to zero? Why is zero the best point to be? Is it good enough for
inflation to be close to zero, but positive, if it’s low and steady?
Here are some things to consider.
First, what is the optimal rate of inflation? Milton Friedman and others have shown theoretically that, in
their models, the optimal rate of inflation is negative. Ideally, the marginal private cost of holding money
(that is, the opportunity cost, which equals the nominal interest rate) should equal the marginal social cost
of holding money, which is zero. For the nominal interest rate to be zero, the inflation rate must equal the
negative of the real interest rate. But a different theoretical model, developed by James Tobin and others,
suggests that the optimal inflation rate is positive because of downward wage and price rigidity, and
(in another model) inflation should be positive to encourage investment. Finally, Martin Feldstein’s
research suggests that the optimal rate of inflation is zero, because otherwise inflation interacts with the
tax system to distort resource allocation.
Second, if the inflation rate is mismeasured (see the discussion of the bias in the CPI in Chapter 2), that
should affect the Fed’s target. If the CPI inflation rate is overstated by 1 to 2 percentage points per year,
then a true target of zero inflation corresponds to measured inflation of 1 to 2 percent.
Third, what are the costs and benefits of reducing inflation? Is achieving lower inflation worth the costs?
Calculations of the sacrifice ratio suggest that to permanently reduce inflation by one percentage point
costs the economy 2 to 3 percentage points of lost output. That’s the cost of the transition to lower inflation.
In addition, there are some permanent costs and benefits of lower inflation. On the cost side, with lower
inflation, the government earns less seignorage revenue from printing money, so it will have to increase
taxes (which distort economic decisions) to make up for the lost revenue. On the benefit side, lower
inflation reduces a number of distortions to the economy. First, a lower inflation rate brings the private
cost of holding money closer to the social cost. Second, a lower inflation rate reduces distortions with the
tax system. Since the tax system doesn’t adequately account for inflation, it subsidizes housing capital at
the expense of other capital, because the returns to housing aren’t taxed.
Finally, how do the costs relate to the benefits? Separate calculations by Martin Feldstein and Andrew
Abel (in Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds., Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1997) both show that the benefits of reducing inflation by
2 percentage points outweigh the costs. Many other researchers have found similar results, though some
economists have found that the costs exceed the benefits.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 289

 Answers to Textbook Problems


Review Questions
1. The Phillips curve is an empirical negative relationship between inflation and unemployment. The
Phillips curve relationship held for U.S. data in the 1960s, but broke down in the 1970s and 1980s.

2. In the original Phillips curve, inflation itself is related to the unemployment rate. In the expectations-
augmented Phillips curve, it is unanticipated inflation (the difference between actual
and expected inflation) that is related to cyclical unemployment (the difference between the
unemployment rate and the natural rate of unemployment). The short-run Phillips curve appears in
the data at times when both expected inflation and the natural rate of unemployment are fixed.

3. In the early 1960s the rate of inflation was fairly low (about 1% to 2%), and it didn’t vary much from
year to year. But supply shocks hit the economy in both the mid- and the late-1970s, causing a rise in
expected inflation and an upward shift in the Phillips curve. Expansionary monetary and fiscal
policies kept inflation high in the 1970s until the Federal Reserve began pursuing contractionary
monetary policy to reduce inflation during 1979–1982. This moved the economy to a lower Phillips
curve, which was maintained in the 1980s. The instability of the Phillips curve is largely because of
higher expected inflation associated with supply shocks in the 1970s.

4. According to the classical point of view, the economy adjusts quickly to changes in inflation, so there
is only a very short period in which unemployment changes because of a change in inflation. Further,
any systematic attempt to reduce unemployment by increasing inflation would be fully anticipated,
and would have no effect on unemployment.
Keynesians believe, however, that there is a temporary trade-off between unemployment and
inflation. If policymakers want to, they can increase inflation to reduce unemployment in the short
run. However, the economy must return to the natural rate of unemployment in the long run, so the
reduction in unemployment is only temporary.

5. Policymakers want to keep inflation low because inflation imposes costs on the economy. Costs of
anticipated inflation include shoe leather costs and menu costs. Costs of unanticipated inflation
include unpredictable transfers of wealth between lenders and borrowers, resources used to reduce the
risk of such transfers, and reduced efficiency because of the difficulty in observing relative prices.
When there is cyclical unemployment, society as a whole loses because of output that is not produced
and the families of the unemployed suffer personal and psychological costs.

6. The natural rate of unemployment is the rate of unemployment that exists when output is at its full-
employment level. This occurs when the only unemployment is frictional and structural, not cyclical.
The natural rate is crucial in understanding the Phillips curve.

The natural rate of unemployment has moved higher over time in the United States and Europe due to
a number of factors. First, demographic changes occurred that raised the natural rate. Groups in the
labor force that have higher rates of unemployment have increased in size relative to groups that have
lower rates of unemployment. Also, there have been structural changes in the economy that may have
raised the natural rate in the 1970s. In Europe, hysteresis has kept the unemployment rate from
declining much after it hit very high levels in the early 1980s. Hysteresis arises because of
government regulation and bureaucratic aspects of firms and labor unions, and due to insiders
keeping outsiders from gaining employment.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


290 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

To reduce the natural rate of unemployment, the government could support job training and worker
relocation, reduce regulations to increase labor market flexibility, reform unemployment insurance, or
create a high-pressure economy.
7. Two costs of anticipated inflation are shoe-leather costs and menu costs. Two costs of unanticipated
inflation are transfers of wealth and confusion of price signals.
If the economy experiences hyperinflation, shoe-leather costs become very large as people try to
minimize their cash holdings. Also, prices change so frequently they cease to serve as signals. Menu
costs do not rise too much, as firms simply quote prices in terms of some other unit of account
(a different country’s currency). Transfers of wealth also occur, especially since the government
loses tax revenue as people delay paying taxes.

8. The greatest potential cost of disinflation is that it may cause a recession. This occurs because
inflation may fall below expected inflation, causing the unemployment rate to rise along
the Phillips curve.
However, if the public anticipates the disinflation, expected inflation will adjust quickly and the costs
of disinflation will be low.

9. One approach to disinflation is a cold turkey strategy. It has the advantage of reducing inflation
quickly, but it may have high costs from increasing unemployment, according to Keynesians.
So, Keynesians suggest a gradualist policy to reduce inflation more slowly but with less rise in
unemployment. This also has the advantage of being politically sustainable, since policymakers
are less likely to back off from disinflation.

10. The Federal Reserve works hard to establish its credibility so that the costs of reducing inflation
will be low. If the Federal Reserve has a great deal of credibility, then people will believe that the
inflation rate will not rise in the future, so the expected inflation rate will be low and stable. The
sacrifice ratio will also be low, so the costs of disinflation will be reduced.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 291

Numerical Problems

1. (a) Equating aggregate demand to short-run aggregate supply gives: 300  10(M/P)  500  P  Pe,
or 300  (10  1000/P)  500  P  50, or 10,000/P  150  P. Multiplying both sides of the
equation by P and rearranging gives P2  150P  10,000  0, which can be factored as (P  50)
(P  200)  0. This has the nonnegative solution P  50. Since Pe is also 50, the expected price
level equals the actual price level, so output is at its full-employment level of 500 and the
unemployment rate is at the natural rate of 6%. These are the long-run equilibrium values of
the three variables as well.
(b) When the nominal money supply increases unexpectedly to 1260, we again equate aggregate
demand to short-run aggregate supply, which gives: 300  10(M/P)  500  P  Pe, or 300 
(10  1260/P)  500  P  50, or 12,600/P  150  P. Multiplying both sides of the equation by
P and rearranging gives P2  150P  12,600  0, which can be factored as (P  60)(P  210)  0.
This has the nonnegative solution P  60. When P  60, the short-run aggregate supply curve
gives Y  500  P  Pe  500  60  50  510. Output of 510 is 2% above full-employment
output of 500, because (510  500)/500  0.02. With a natural unemployment rate of 0.06,
Okun’s Law gives 0.02   2(u  0.06). This can be solved to get u  0.05.
In the long run, Pe adjusts to equal P, output adjusts to its full-employment level of 500, and
unemployment adjusts to the natural rate of 0.06. To find P, use the aggregate demand curve
to get 500  300  10(1260/P), or 200  12,600/P, which can be solved to get P  63.
The results of this exercise are consistent with the existence of an expectations-augmented
Phillips curve. Unexpected inflation reduces unemployment in the short run. In the long run,
however, inflation is higher and unemployment returns to its natural rate.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


292 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

2. (a)   0.10  2(u  0.06)  0.22  2u. This is shown as the Phillips curve labeled PCa in Figure 12.6.
If the Fed keeps inflation at 0.10, then u  0.06, the natural rate of unemployment.

Figure 12.6
(b) With expected inflation rising to 12%, the Phillips curve is   0.12 – 2(u – 0.06)  0.24 – 2u.
This is the Phillips curve labeled PC b in the figure. The higher rate of expected inflation has
caused the curve to shift up relative to where it was in part (a). With the actual inflation rate at
10%, the Phillips curve equation is 0.10  0.12 – 2(u – 0.06), which has the solution u  0.07.
So if the Fed tries to maintain the existing rate of inflation after a shock has raised inflation
expectations, the unemployment rate increases. However, if the Fed could convince people that
the inflation rate really would not rise, so that  e remains at 0.10, then the short-run Phillips
curve would remain at PC a, and the unemployment rate would not increase.
(c) With the natural rate of unemployment rising to 0.08 at the same time that expected inflation
rises to 0.12, the Phillips curve equation is   0.12  2(u  0.08)  0.28  2u. This is the Phillips
curve labeled PC c in the figure. The new short-run Phillips curve is even higher than those for
parts (a) and (b). With the actual inflation rate held to 10%, the equation becomes 0.10  0.28  2u,
which can be solved to get u  0.09. The unemployment rate rises both because the Fed holds
inflation below expected inflation and because the natural rate has increased.
This time, even if the Fed convinced people that inflation would remain just 10%, the
unemployment rate would still rise to 8%, since the natural rate has increased to that level.

3. (a) Beginning in long-run equilibrium, with M  4000, output must be at its full-employment level
of 6000 and the unemployment rate must be equal to the natural rate of .05. Using the values for
Y and M in the AD curve, 6000  4000  2(4000/P), which gives P  4. This is also the expected
price level. Because M has been constant for a long time and is expected to remain constant,
 e  0.
(b) With P e  4, the SRAS curve is Y  6000  100(P  4). The AD curve is Y  4000  2(4488/P).
The intersection of the two curves occurs when 6000  100(P  4)  4000  2(4488/P).
Simplifying terms gives 100P2  1600P  8976  0, which has the solution P  4.4. Plugging this
into the SRAS curve gives Y  6040. From the Okun’s Law equation we get (6040  6000)/6000
 2 (u  0.05), so – 0.00333  u  0.05, so u  .0467. Cyclical unemployment is u  u  
0.0033. Unanticipated inflation is (P  Pe)/Pe  0.10  10%.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 293

(c) The Phillips curve equation is    e  h(u  u ), which gives .10  0  h(.0467  0.05).
This is solved to get h  30. So the slope of the Phillips curve is 30.

4. Since the natural rate of unemployment is 0.06,    e  2(u  0.06), so u  0.06  0.5( e  ),
or u  0.06  0.5( e  ).
(a) Year 1: u  0.06  0.5(0.08  0.04)  0.06  0.02  0.08. The unemployment rate is 0.02 higher
than the natural rate. The percentage that output falls short of full-employment output is
2  0.02  0.04, or 4%.
Year 2: u  0.06  0.5(0.04  0.04)  0.06. The unemployment rate equals the natural rate, since
inflation equals expected inflation. Since unemployment is at its natural rate, output is at its
full-employment level.
Since the output loss was 4 percentage points and inflation declined by 8 percentage points, the
sacrifice ratio is 4/8  0.5.
(b) Use equations: u  0.06  0.5( e – ), output shortfall  2 (u – 0.06).

Year  e u u  0.06 Output Shortfall


1 0.08 0.10 0.07 0.01 0.02
2 0.04 0.08 0.08 0.02 0.04
3 0.04 0.06 0.07 0.01 0.02
4 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.0 0.0
The total output shortfall is 0.02  0.04  0.02  0.0  0.08  8-percentage points of output lost.
Inflation fell by 8 percentage points. So the sacrifice ratio is 8/8  1. Notice that, compared with
part a, the sacrifice ratio is higher, for this slower disinflation.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


294 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

Analytical Problems
1. (a) The reduction in structural unemployment would reduce the natural rate of unemployment and
thus would shift both the expectations-augmented Phillips curve and the long-run Phillips curve
to the left.
(b) Despite the expense of the government program to reduce structural unemployment, it would
have a permanent effect. Monetary expansion can work only temporarily—in the long run it
has no effect.

2. The slope of the short-run aggregate supply curve will be much steeper in economy B, because
producers increase their output only a small amount in response to an increase in price. But economy
A’s short-run aggregate supply curve will be flatter, as people are likely to perceive price changes as
changes in relative price rather than the aggregate price level, and thus will respond more strongly to
changes in prices.
The short-run Phillips curve will also be steeper in economy B, since unemployment, like output,
won’t respond much to a change in inflation. But in economy A, unemployment and output will
respond more strongly to price changes, and the short-run Phillips curve will be flatter.

3. (a) In Figure 12.7, the SRAS curve shifts up 10% each year, as does the AD curve. Unanticipated
inflation is zero, as both actual and expected inflation are 10%. The economy is at full employment,
since firms set their prices to exactly match the increase in the general price level.

Figure 12.7

(b) The surprise increase in the money supply at mid-year leads to a rise in output, as shown in
Figure 12.8 by the shift of the AD curve from AD1 to AD2. Firms don’t adjust their prices, so the
SRAS curve remains fixed at SRAS1. When the money supply rises by its regular 10% at the end
of the year, the AD curve shifts up to AD3 and firms raise their prices by 15%, shifting the SRAS
curve up to SRAS3. Actual inflation is 15%, but expected inflation was only 10%. As a result,
there was a temporary increase in output above its full-employment level, and a temporary
decline in unemployment below the natural rate. Thus for the year as a whole, cyclical
unemployment was negative and unanticipated inflation was positive, just as in the expectations-
augmented Phillips curve.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation 295

Figure 12.8

4. In the cashless society, there would be no shoe-leather costs, as there would be no cash balances
on which to economize. But menu costs would remain for anticipated inflation. The costs of
unanticipated inflation would remain as well: both the risk of wealth transfers plus confusion
in price signals.

5. (a) Figure 12.9 shows the effects of increasing the money supply while holding the price level
constant. Beginning at point A, the intersection of aggregate demand curve AD1 and short-run
aggregate supply curve SRAS1, the increase in the money supply shifts the aggregate demand
curve to AD2. Since prices cannot rise, the short-run equilibrium is at point B, with output above
its full-employment level.

Figure 12.9

(b) When the price controls are removed, the price level will jump up, with the short-run aggregate
supply curve shifting to SRAS2. The new equilibrium is at point C, where there is full
employment.

6. (a) A new law that prohibits people from seeking employment before age eighteen is likely to reduce
the natural rate of unemployment because teenagers have a higher-than-average unemployment
rate. With no teenagers allowed in the labor force, the average unemployment rate would be lower.
(b) A service that makes looking for a job easier is able to match people and jobs more rapidly,
which should reduce the natural rate of unemployment.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


296 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition

(c) If unemployed workers can receive benefits longer, they’ll be in less of a rush to take a job, so
the job-matching process will take longer. As a result, the natural rate of unemployment will rise.
(d) A structural shift in the types of products people buy is likely to raise the natural rate of
unemployment, because it will take time for the economy to shift workers from some types
of occupations to others.
(e) A recession leads to a rise in cyclical unemployment, but doesn’t affect the natural rate of
unemployment.

Working with Macroeconomic Data


1. a. Inflation and unemployment are positively related.
b. Inflation and cyclical unemployment show no apparent relationship.
c. The change in the inflation rate and cyclical unemployment are strongly negatively correlated.
The results support the expectations-augmented Phillips curve with a changing natural rate of
unemployment.

2. A line through the origin with a slope of 2 is very close to the points on the line, confirming
Okun's law.

3. The fraction of unemployed workers who have been unemployed 15 weeks or more usually
rises in recessions and continues rising for a time after recessions end. The fraction of
unemployed workers who have been unemployed 15 weeks or more is positively related to the
unemployment rate. Thus, the costs to society of unemployment are higher in a recession than
in an expansion.

©2017 Pearson Education, Inc.

You might also like