You are on page 1of 9

European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

European Journal of Operational Research


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ejor

Production, Manufacturing and Logistics

Using MSRP to enhance the ability of rebates to control distribution channels


Shilei Yang a,1, Charles L. Munson b,2, Bintong Chen c,*
a
School of Business Administration, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu, Sichuan 610074, PR China
b
College of Business, Box 644736, Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164-4736, United States
c
Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering, University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Manufacturers have increasingly instituted widespread mail-in rebate programs in recent years. Two pri-
Received 6 June 2009 mary purposes for rebates are to: (1) more directly impact consumer demand by reducing net retail price,
Accepted 18 December 2009 and (2) capitalize on consumers’ slippage behavior because not all consumers who intend to redeem the
Available online 24 December 2009
rebate at purchase time end up actually redeeming it. However, retailers can counteract the power of
rebates to impact demand by simply raising the retail price by the amount of the manufacturer’s rebate.
Keywords: We show that by combining a manufacturer’s suggested retail price (MSRP) along with a rebate, the man-
Supply chain management
ufacturer can better control the channel by inhibiting the retailer’s ability to raise price, particularly when
Marketing
Rebates
consumers exhibit loss aversion. As a result, incorporating MSRP with a rebate promotion plan increases
MSRP the manufacturer’s profit. More surprisingly, the profit of the supply chain as a whole also increases, and
Channel control the channel efficiency increases as well. In fact, contrary to results from the existing rebate literature sug-
gesting that rebates should always be offered whenever slippage exists, we demonstrate that MSRP can
actually be a more effective tool than rebates in managing retailer and consumer behavior when consum-
ers do not have sufficient loss aversion and the slippage rate is low enough.
Published by Elsevier B.V.

1. Introduction ‘‘fully 40% of all rebates never get redeemed”, which gives manu-
facturers a large enough ‘‘arbitrage” space. Due to slippage, manu-
Originating in the 1960s, mail-in rebates have become a popular facturers can potentially accrue large profits by using rebates to
form of consumer promotion in today’s retail markets, especially attract consumers who subsequently fail to redeem them.
for products such as electronics, automobiles, and durable goods. In addition to the slippage benefits, rebate promotions allow
In fact, rebates have become the expected norm in some indus- manufacturers to bypass retailers and offer price reductions di-
tries: ‘‘Rebates are the meat and potatoes of the ultimate tech deal, rectly to consumers. The intention is to reduce the impact of dou-
no matter what you are buying” (Unger, 2009). The total face value ble marginalization3 and increase total consumer demand by
of rebates was estimated to be $6 billion in the US in 2005 (Grow lowering the net retail price. However, rebate promotions cannot
and Chhatwal, 2005). Even though mail-in rebate business is spur demand if the retailers completely counteract direct discounts
increasing while the use of traditional cents-off coupons is declin- by raising the corresponding retail prices by the amount of the re-
ing (Bulkeley, 1998), there is not much research on consumer pro- bate. Researchers have shown theoretically that the retailer tends
motion by rebates (Neslin, 2002). The traditional explanations for to increase price after a manufacturer offers a rebate (Gerstner and
offering rebates focus on using them to price discriminate among Hess, 1991; Aydin and Porteus, 2009; Arcelus et al., 2006). Claims
consumers (Gerstner and Hess, 1991). More recent researchers of this type of retailer behavior from disgruntled consumers can be
have shown that manufacturers are implementing rebate pro- found regularly on forum websites (e.g., Digital Photography Review,
grams to exploit consumers’ slippage behavior (Silk, 2004; Chen 2008; TractorByNet.com, 2005).
et al., 2005; Gilpatric, 2009). Slippage occurs when consumers By law, manufacturers cannot dictate prices to retailers; they
are enticed to purchase as a result of a rebate offer but later fail can only publicly suggest a retail price at which the product is ex-
to apply for the rebate. Grow and Chhatwal (2005) report that pected to sell. This recommended retail price is usually called the

3
Double marginalization refers to the phenomenon of two parties in a vertical
* Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 302 831 2756. supply chain each setting prices to maximize their own profits, producing a final
E-mail addresses: syang@swufe.edu.cn (S. Yang), munson@wsu.edu (C.L. Mun- consumer price being higher and resulting demand being lower than what would
son), bchen@udel.edu (B. Chen). result from optimization of the full supply chain. In other words, as each link in the
1
Tel.: +86 28 87354893. supply chain takes out its own ‘‘cut” (profit margin), consumers see higher prices and
2
Tel.: +1 509 335 3076. fewer units are sold.

0377-2217/$ - see front matter Published by Elsevier B.V.


doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2009.12.018
128 S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135

manufacturer’s suggested retail price (MSRP). The MSRP is typi- papers are equivalent to traditional coupons, which do not cap-
cally printed on the sales tag, the product tag, or the featured ture the inconsistency between consumers’ purchase behaviors
advertising, all of which can easily be observed by consumers at and redemption behaviors. Only recently have quantitative
the time of purchase. In the Internet age, there is a tendency for researchers studied the impact of mail-in rebates on distribution
consumers to adopt the MSRP as one of the most official and pop- channels.
ular reference prices when they price shop the Internet to deter- Chen et al. (2007) find that as long as some customers that are
mine a reference point before placing an order. For example, attracted by a mail-in rebate will forgo the rebate, offering rebates
many eBay e-tailers provide a hotlink to the specific model on is always beneficial for manufacturers. Unlike the sequential deci-
the manufacturer’s website that states the MSRP information sion making in that paper, Aydin and Porteus (2009) adopt simul-
(Hardesty and Suter, 2005). Deal and bargain sites (fatwallet.com, taneous Nash equilibrium decision making to compare consumer
techdeals.net, etc.) typically list a hot rebate deal with the MSRP, rebates to channel rebates. Two recent papers (Khouja, 2006; Arce-
for example, ‘‘MSRP $300 machine sells for $150 after $100 MIR.” lus et al., 2006) study the problem of the joint pricing-inventory
Some online retailers such as mikescamera.com even display three decision involving rebates with different models: Khouja (2006)
prices for rebate promoted products: MSRP, Mike’s price, and price uses a deterministic EOQ-based model, while Arcelus et al.
after rebates. (2006) implement a stochastic newsvendor-based model. Khouja
In this paper, we explore the following questions. Will the addi- et al. (2008) solve the models for jointly determining optimal price
tion of MSRP to a rebate program increase the manufacturer’s prof- and rebate value for heterogeneous consumer markets. Cho et al.
it? How will the profits of the whole supply channel be impacted? (2009) consider a competitive vertical channel where both the
Will channel efficiency be affected? What are the primary drivers manufacturer and the retailer could possibly offer rebates at regu-
that characterize the equilibrium structure of the respective chan- lar frequency. They show that it is in the common interest for both
nel prices and rebates? the manufacturer and the retailer to improve the effectiveness of
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the manufacturer’s rebate program, which is also illustrated in
the related literature. In Section 3, we describe the modeling envi- our paper. Previous channel-based research on rebate promotion
ronment. Section 4 presents the equilibrium solutions and pro- has used a pre-determined demand function, whereas we derive
vides an analytical answer to the questions of MSRP impact on the demand function using a consumer utility-based approach that
manufacturer’s profit, system profit, and channel efficiency. Sec- captures the aspects of demand that are particularly relevant to
tion 5 presents analytical and numerical sensitivity analysis to products with rebates.
add more insight into our primary research questions. Finally, we A number of authors have examined the rebate-related channel
summarize major findings and identify potential areas for future coordination issues. Yue et al. (2006) study the supply chain coor-
research in Section 6. dination of cooperative advertisement together with rebate pro-
motion. Nalla et al. (2008) find that a manufacturer-sponsored
rebate program cannot effectively coordinate the channel, but a re-
2. Relevant literature tailer-sponsored rebate together with a wholesale price discount
can achieve coordination. Khouja and Zhou (2009) introduce
We focus in this paper on mail-in rebates, which can only be incentive contract mechanisms, which negatively link the manu-
redeemed after purchasing the product at the regular price. The facturer’s rebate value and the retailer’s retail price via MSRP, to
redemption of rebates typically requires consumers to perform limit the retailer’s price increase. They show that these contracts
arduous tasks (filling out forms, clipping labels, and mailing always increase the channel’s and manufacturer’s profits. Unlike
them). Although the marketing literature on sales promotion is Khouja and Zhou’s paper where the manufacturer actively adjusts
saturated with both theoretical and empirical works, only a hand- the rebate value according to the changes of retail price, our ap-
ful of papers have attempted to explain the existence and the proach with MSRP restricts the retailer’s pricing ability due to con-
influence of the slippage phenomenon. Soman (1998) suggests sumers’ intrinsic reference pricing and loss aversion effects
that consumers’ purchase decisions for products offering a de- (described next).
layed incentive can be independent of the decisions to redeem The consumers’ reference price effect can be attributed to two
the delayed incentives themselves. The author finds that consum- theories: adaptation level theory (Helson, 1964) and prospect the-
ers perceptually underestimate the effort of redeeming the rebate. ory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). Both theories suggest that con-
Based on Soman’s research, Silk (2004) experimentally suggests sumers do not make decisions solely based on purchase price, but
that the discrepancy between consumers’ redemption confidence they have a standard by which they can evaluate the current price.
and their actual redemption behavior causes the slippage. Inter- The utility (satisfaction) from comparing the purchase price rela-
estingly, recent research on brain-imaging (McClure et al., 2004) tive to the reference price is called transaction utility, or deal value.
finds that consumers are engaging different neural activities As a counterpart to transaction utility, acquisition utility is the va-
when making a decision on choosing delayed or immediate lue derived from the intrinsic utility provided by an item, relative
incentives. Other researchers provide different explanations for to its purchase price (Neslin, 2002). So the total value of a transac-
slippage by building in behavioral factors, such as consumers’ tion to a consumer is the sum of acquisition utility and transaction
anchoring and adjustment on effort-discounting (Gourville and utility. Prospect theory further suggests that losses (negative trans-
Soman, 2005), different post-purchase states (Chen et al., 2005), action utility) should loom larger than gains (positive transaction
and present-biased preferences (Gilpatric, 2009). Some papers utility), i.e., loss aversion effects. The support for the existence of
have begun to address how to take advantage of slippage behav- the reference price and loss aversion effects can be found in a vari-
ior. Moorthy and Soman (2005) address a way to exacerbate the ety of empirical studies (see Kalyanaram and Winer, 1995 for a re-
slippage effects by highlighting the reward and partially conceal- view) and a recent brain-imaging study (Tom et al., 2007). Our
ing the effort required to redeem. Moorthy and Lu (2007) indicate paper adopts a contextual mechanism (Rajendran and Tellis,
that rebates are more efficient than coupons in price discriminat- 1994), in which the consumers utilize a currently available price
ing between consumer types. as the reference point instead of using a historical price stored in
Early channel studies on rebates can be traced to several pa- memory. Specifically, we use the MSRP to serve as an external ref-
pers by Gerstner and Hess (Gerstner and Hess, 1991, 1995; Gerst- erence point (Mayhew and Winer, 1992; Hardesty and Suter,
ner et al., 1994); however, the ‘‘instant” rebates discussed in their 2005).
S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135 129

Fig. 1. A Schematic Framework of the Modeling Environment.

3. The modeling environment


Table 1
Summary of notation.
Fig. 1 displays our proposed market environment, in which a
s A summary measure of product quality level
manufacturer sells a product to final consumers through an inde-
t Consumer type
pendent retailer. The manufacturer serves as the Stackelberg lea- b The highest consumer type level
der in this system, and the retailer serves as the follower (i.e., Pr The retail price determined by the retailer
backward induction is used to obtain the subgame perfect Nash Ps The MSRP determined by the manufacturer
equilibrium). The sequence of decisions begins with the manufac- a The coefficient for reference price effect when Ps > Pr
b The coefficient for reference price effect when Ps < Pr
turer determining the wholesale price w and the rebate face value
rs Estimated probability that consumers expect to redeem the
R, along with announcing the MSRP Ps. Given the manufacturer’s rebates at the time of purchase
decisions, the retailer then chooses the retail price Pr. Both parties ro Proportion of consumers who actually redeem the rebates
seek to maximize their respective profits. q The slippage rate = (rs  ro)/rs
u A consumer’s overall utility
We model the effects of rebates on an aggregate level. The
R The rebate face value determined by the manufacturer
parameter rs represents the estimated probability that consumers w The wholesale price determined by the manufacturer
expect to redeem the rebates at the time of purchase. By introduc- D The market demand
Q
ing rs, we can measure the desirability of a rebate promotion, i.e., Qm
The profit of the manufacturer
consumers treat a rebate of $1 as being equivalent to a direct dis- The profit of the retailer
Qr
The profit of the integrated channel
count of $ rs. On the other hand, the parameter ro represents the ac- I
 
h(a, b) The threshold level on slippage = max 0; að1þbÞðb aÞ
tual proportion of consumers who redeem the rebates after their ð1þaÞð1þbÞ

purchases. The slippage rate q, therefore, is defined as (rs  ro)/rs,


representing the degree to which consumers fail to redeem a re-
bate that they originally had planned to redeem. Table 1 summa-
sume that consumer types are distributed uniformly on [0, b],
rizes this and other notation used throughout the paper.
which captures consumer heterogeneity in the market. Similar
Utilizing multiple levers, the manufacturer strives to dictate the
assumptions using the uniform distribution can be found in classic
behavior of the other two channel members: (1) the retailer – di-
marketing literature (Moorthy, 1988; Blattberg and Wisniewski,
rectly via w and indirectly via Ps, and (2) consumers – directly via
1989; Rhee, 1996).
R and indirectly via Ps.
Given that the retailer can choose any retail price Pr, consumers
can enjoy utility gain a(Ps  Pr) when they observe Ps > Pr; how-
3.1. Consumer demand ever, they suffer utility loss b(Ps  Pr ) when Ps < Pr. Here, a and b
are the coefficients for the reference price effect, i.e. the impor-
We define the product’s quality level s > 0 as a summary mea- tance weight on transaction utility relative to an importance
sure denoting the product’s overall attractiveness, exclusive of weight of 1 on product retail price.4 We set 0 < {a, b} 6 1 to ensure
price. We use s to incorporate all of the product’s attributes, such that the importance weight on transaction utility derived from the
as product value, reliability, durability, service, warranty, etc. reference effect cannot be greater than the importance weight on
Given that consumers differ in their willingness to pay for the acquisition utility derived from the economic value of the purchase.
product, we define a consumer of ‘‘type” t as one who is willing In other words, the range of alpha and beta is designed to normalize
to pay up to ts dollars for the utility (satisfaction) derived from the impact of the reference price effect on the utility function, given
consuming the product with quality level s. A consumer who is the range of values for the other part of the utility function. We fur-
more quality sensitive is designated as a ‘‘higher” type. As such,
higher type consumers are willing to pay more for the same prod- 4
In reality, coefficients a and b can be influenced by price, promotion, past
uct than lower type consumers. Alternatively, the consumer’s type purchase experience, etc. Researchers typically estimate these coefficients from
can be viewed as the importance weight on overall quality relative scanner data containing consumers’ purchase records (see Erdem et al., 2001 for
to an importance weight of 1 on product retail price. We further as- examples of empirical estimation).
130 S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135

aP s
ther assume a < b to capture the loss aversion effect. This assumption Pr ¼ rs Rþ
1þa
and at P r ¼ bsþr1þb
s RþbP s
, respectively. Fig. 2 illustrates the
is explained theoretically by prospect theory and also supported by kinked demand curve.
empirical findings (see Kalyanaram and Winer, 1995).
To illustrate, consider an example with a = 0.10, b = 0.20, and 3.2. The retailer and manufacturer objectives
the MSRP Ps = $50. If the retailer prices the product at Pr = $40, then
the consumers’ utility will increase by 0.10(10) = 1. On the other Without loss of generality, we assume no variable costs for the
hand, if the retailer prices the product above the MSRP at retailer other than wholesale price and no production costs for the
Pr = $60, then the consumers’ utility will decrease by 0.20(10) = 2. manufacturer (see, for example, Lal, 1990; Chu and Desai, 1995).
Loss aversion exists because the utility loss of 2 for a $10 price pre- Based on the demand function in (2), the retailer’s profit function
mium over the MSRP is greater than the utility gain of 1 for a $10 can be written as:
price discount under the MSRP. In other words, consumers are Y
ðPr jw; R; Ps Þ ¼ ðPr  wÞ  DðPr ; R; Ps Þ:
more dissatisfied with pricing above the MSRP than they would
r
be satisfied with the same level of pricing below the MSRP.
When both a rebate promotion and an MSRP are present, our The manufacturer will choose the optimal combination of w, R and
assumptions on consumer behavior imply that the consumer’s Ps to maximize its profit by anticipating the retailer’s best response
overall utility is Pr*(w, R, Ps). The manufacturer’s profit function can be written as:
Y  
u ¼ ts  ðP r  rs RÞ þ aðPs  Pr Þþ  bðPr  Ps Þþ ; ð1Þ ðw; R; P s Þ ¼ ðw  r o RÞ  D Pr ðw; R; Ps Þ; R; Ps :
m

where (x)+ = max{0, x}.


A consumer will purchase the product if u P 0, where 0 is the 4. Equilibrium strategies
reservation utility for each consumer. Some logical boundary con-
ditions include: (A1) 0 < a < b 6 1, (A2) 0 < ro 6 rs 6 1, (A3) 4.1. Rebate combined with MSRP
Pr P w P roR, Pr P rsR, and (A4) w 6 Ps 6 bs, Ps P rsR.
The consumer’s utility function (Eq. (1)) above can be expressed As the retailer has to take into account the consumer’s reference
as: price effect, its optimal choice depends upon the four sub-func-
 tions of D(Pr, R, Ps) and can be characterized by the following
ts  ðPr  r s RÞ þ aðPs  Pr Þ when P s P Pr ;
u¼ lemma:
ts  ðPr  r s RÞ þ bðPs  Pr Þ when P s < Pr :
Lemma 1. The retailer’s optimal choice of retail price Pr, depending on
By integration, the derived demand function can be obtained as w and R, is given by:
8
> 1 P r 6 rs Rþ aPs
; 8 rs RþaPs
>
>
>
1þa
>
> 1þa
6 Ps for w 6 aPs þr 1þa
s Rbs
;
>
< bsð1þaÞPr þrs RþaPs r s RþaPs
< Pr 6 Ps ; >
>
bs 1þa > bsþr
< 2 þ 2ð1þ
w s Rþ aP s
< P for aP s þr s Rbs
< w < Ps  rs RþbsP s
;
DðPr ; R; Ps Þ ¼ ð2Þ aÞ s 1þa 1þa
>
>
bsð1þbÞPr þr s RþbPs
P s < Pr < bsþr1þb
s RþbP s
; Pr ðw; R;Ps Þ ¼
>
> bs >
> Ps for Ps  rs RþbsP s
6 w 6 P s  rs RþbsP s
;
>
: >
> 1þa 1þb
0 Pr P bsþr s RþbPs
: >
: w bsþrs RþbPs r s RþbsP s
1þb
2
þ 2ð1þbÞ > Ps for Ps  1þb < w 6 Ps :
aP s
Obviously the lowest retail price is Pr ¼ rs Rþ1þa
, since the retailer can-
not convince any additional consumers to purchase the product by Proof. See online supplements. h
further reducing its retail price. On the other end, if the retailer
chooses P r > bsþr1þb
s RþbP s
, there will be no consumers left to buy the We can observe that if the wholesale price w is sufficiently low,
product. The demand function D(Pr, R, Ps) has two kinks at the retailer chooses a retail price that is low enough to reach all
consumer types such that the customer demand equals 1. The re-
tail price is nondecreasing in w, from below the suggested price
Ps to eventually above Ps. Notice that there is a segment of w ,
i.e., P s  rs RþbsP
1þa
s
6 w 6 P s  rs RþbsP
1þb
s
, in which the manufacturer
can induce the retailer to adopt the suggested price Ps.
Anticipating the retailer’s reaction to w, R and Ps, the manufac-
turer follows the optimal strategies summarized in the following
proposition.
Proposition 1. The manufacturer’s optimal strategy is jointly deter-
mined by the consumers’ slippage behavior and their magnitude of loss
aversion, as shown in Table 2.

Proof. See online supplements.


From Table 2 we observe that, when using an MSRP, the manu-
facturer will provide rebates only after the slippage rate breaks the
threshold level h(a, b). It can be easily verified that this threshold
level on slippage rate is strictly decreasing in b. Hence, if consum-
ers have sufficient loss aversion, i.e., b P 2a/(1  a), h(a, b) be-
comes 0 and Table 2 reduces to three columns. In that case, the
manufacturer should provide rebates given any positive slippage
rate, which is consistent with the existing rebate literature. How-
ever, if consumers do not have sufficient loss aversion, i.e.,
Fig. 2. The Kinked Demand Curve. b < 2a/(1  a), h(a, b) is greater than 0, implying that an effectively
S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135 131

Table 2
The equilibrium solution sets of independent channelb.

Labela N/L S/E M/G L/G


Conditions 0 6 q < h(a, b) hða; bÞ 6 q < b b
6q< 1 1
q P 1þb
1þb 1þb 1þb
1þ2ð1þbÞð1qÞ
 
w bs bs 2þb
2 2ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ bs 2þ2b þ 12 ð1  qÞ bs
R 0 1þb
 bs ð1þbÞ
 bs bs
rs
2ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ rs ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ rs
Ps bs bs bs bs
3þ2ð1þbÞð1qÞ
 
Pr 3
4 bs
bs 3ð2þbÞ
2þ2ð1þbÞð1qÞÞ bs 4ð1þbÞ þ 14 ð1  qÞ bs
D 1þa ð1þbÞ ð1þbÞ 1
4 2ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ 2þ2ð1þbÞð1qÞÞ 4 ð2 þ b  ð1 þ bÞ  ð1  qÞÞ
Q
1þa
r 16 bs
ð1þbÞ
bs ð1þbÞ
bs 1
16ð1þbÞ ð2 þ b  ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞ2 bs
4ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2 4ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2
Q
1þa
m 8 bs
ð1þbÞ
4ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ bs
ð1þbÞ
bs 1
8ð1þbÞ ð2 þ b  ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞ2 bs
2ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2
Q Q
3ð1þaÞ ð1þbÞð2þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ
r þ m 16 bs bs 3ð1þbÞ
bs 3
16ð1þbÞ ð2 þ b  ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞ2 bs
4ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2 4ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2

a
X/Y  rebate size/retail price, where X 2 (N  none, S  small, M  medium, L  large), and Y 2 (L  <MSRP, E  = MSRP, G  >MSRP).
b
At the corner points where q = h(a, b) and q = b/(1+ b), the equilibrium solution can be any combination of the two consecutivesolution sets. Moreover,  When q = 0 and
b P 2a/(1  a), R, Pr and Ps have multiple solutions, which can be represented by w ¼ ð1 þ j  1þb bs 1þb bs 3þb
2þbÞ 2 ; R ¼ j  4þ2b  r s , and P r ¼ P s ¼ ð1  jÞ 4þ2b þ j bs, where j 2 [0, 1] is a
fraction parameter.

Fig. 3. A Schematic Framework for the Independent Channel.

priced MSRP should actually replace a rebate (the N/L column of of the kinked demand function from Fig. 2. The channel profit func-
Table 2) under a low enough slippage rate. This surprising result tion can be written as:
reveals that if both MSRP and rebates are available, the manufac- Y
ðPr ; R; Ps Þ ¼ ðPr  ro RÞ  DðPr ; R; Ps Þ:
turer may not necessarily provide rebates even when positive slip-
I
page exists. In any case, once the slippage rate breaks the threshold
level h(a, b), a rebate should be offered, and the rebate amount is Following similar proof techniques of Proposition 1, we can derive
then increasing in q. Fig. 3 illustrates the progression as a function the optimal strategies for the integrated channel, summarized in
of the slippage rate. Proposition 2 below.
Proposition 2. The optimal strategies for the integrated channel are
4.2. Further analysis of the MSRP benefits shown in Table 3.

In this subsection, we further demonstrate the improvement to 4.2.3. MSRP improvement for profit and channel efficiency
manufacturer’s profit, channel profit, and channel efficiency by As shown in Proposition 3 below, the introduction of MSRP al-
including MSRP with a rebate policy. For this analysis, we first need lows the manufacturer to have more control over channel pricing,
to determine the equilibrium strategies of a rebate-only policy, as leading to both its own and system-wide benefits.
well as the optimal strategies for an integrated channel.
Proposition 3. Introducing an MSRP along with a consumer rebate
provides the following benefits: (1) the manufacturer’s profit is higher
4.2.1. Rebate-only policy
To evaluate the case where the manufacturer offers a rebate to
the final consumers but does not incorporate an MSRP, we set
Table 3
a = b = 0, eliminating the MSRP from the demand function. The The optimal solution sets for the integrated channelb.
equilibrium conditions collapse to the M/G column of Table 2, with
b = 0. Similar to the exiting rebate literature, we see that the man- Labela N/L S-M/E L/G L/E

ufacturer should always provide rebates in the presence of Condition q 6 1þa a a


1þa <
b
q < 1þb b
1þb
1
6 q < 1þb 1
q P 1þb
slippage. R 0 bs
2ro
bs
rs
bs
rs
Ps bs bs bs bs
  
Pr bs bs 1 þ 12 1þb
1
 q bs bs
2
4.2.2. Integrated channel
D 1þa 1 1 1
2 ð1 þ ð1 þ bÞqÞ
To demonstrate the impact of MSRP on channel efficiency, we Q
2 2ð1qÞ
ð1þaÞ 1
4ð1qÞ bs
1
þ ð1 þ bÞqÞ2 bs qbs
need to analyze a vertically integrated distribution channel. If the I 4 bs 4ð1þbÞ ð1

manufacturer and the retailer act as one company, the wholesale a


X/Y  rebate size/retail price, where X 2 (N  none, S  small, M  medium,
price w as a decision variable disappears, and manufacturer can L  large), and Y 2 (L  <MSRP, E  =MSRP, G  >MSRP)
b
dictate the actual retail price. Hence, system profits are maximized At the corner points where q = a/(1 + a) and q = b/(1 + b), the optimal solution
by choosing the optimal combination of (Pr, R, Ps) for each segment can be any combination of the two consecutive solution sets.
132 S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135

than it would be with a rebate policy alone, (2) the system profit is 5. Sensitivity analysis and numerical studies
higher than it would be with a rebate promotion alone, and (3) the
channel efficiency increases as long as a rebate is offered. 5.1. Analytical sensitivity analysis

Based on the equilibrium policies of Tables 2 and 4 summarizes


Proof. To prove statements (1) and (2), we compare the profits analytical sensitivity analysis when either the slippage rate or loss
between the joint MSRP-rebate promotion versus the rebate pro- aversion increases.
motion alone. We examine each of the segments of Table 2 Slippage rate and loss aversion are the big drivers in this envi-
separately. ronment, as demand and the profit of both parties are all increasing
in both slippage rate and loss aversion. For example, in the real
(a) In the N/L segment, we need to prove that marketplace we observe substantial use of rebates for software
products due to high slippage. With slippage rates ranging be-
Pm þ Pr jjoint Pm jjoint ð1 þ aÞð2  qÞ2
¼ ¼ > 1 () tween 80% and 90% (Bulkeley, 1998), approximately 60% of the
Pm þ Pr jrebate Pm jrebate 4
 software sold through major retailers comes with a rebate (Becker,
1 2002). (Industry slippage rates are typically reported as the per-
q < 2 1  pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi :
1þa centage of purchasers who receive rebate checks.) Some software
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi producers even provide free-after-rebate software products to lure
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ð1 þ bÞð2 þ a  2 1 þ
Since  aÞ þ ðb  aÞ > 0 ) hða; bÞ < 2ð1  1=
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi more purchasers.
1 þ aÞ, the condition q < 2 1  1= 1 þ a holds automatically in
the N/L segment. Thus, both the manufacturer’s and the channel’s The results of the L/G segment are a bit surprising: Pr decreases
profits are higher than in the rebate-only case. as the slippage rate q increases. To benefit from a high slippage
(b) In the S/E segment, we need to prove that rate, the manufacturer prefers a high customer demand. There
are two approaches to increasing demand: either increasing the re-
Pm jjoint ð1 þ bÞð2  qÞ2 bate value or reducing the retail price. Since the rebate has reached
¼ > 1 () ð1 þ bÞð2 þ q2 Þ > 2;
Pm jrebate 2ð1 þ ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞ its maximum level in the L/G segment, the manufacturer and the
retailer have to decrease w and Pr, respectively, to boost customer
which is true;
demand enough to fully exploit the benefit of high slippage.
Pm þ Pr jjoint ð1 þ bÞð2 þ ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞð2  qÞ2 At the same time, rebate promotions become more effective
¼ when consumers exhibit significant loss aversion. This occurs be-
Pm þ Pr jrebate 3ð1 þ ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞ2
cause the manufacturer can lower the net price to consumers
> 1 () 4b þ b2  qð1 þ bÞðð1 þ bÞ through a rebate while the retailer will be unable to completely
þ 2ð1  qÞ þ ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞ2 Þ > 0: offset the rebate amount with a higher retail price. In fact we see
from Table 4 that the retail price is actually decreasing in some
Since f(q) = 4b + b2  q(1 + b)((1 + b) + 2(1  q ) + (1 + b)(1  q)2) is segments as loss aversion increases. At the same time, the manu-
b b 3b2
decreasing in q when q < 1þb ; f ðqÞ > f ðq ¼ 1þbÞ ¼ 1þb > 0 holds in facturer is increasing the rebate amount until it reaches the upper
the S/E segment. Thus, both the manufacturer’s and the channel’s bound. Thus, we observe that manufacturer has more control on
profits are higher than in the rebate-only case. the retailer’s behavior when the magnitude of loss aversion
(c) In the M/G segment, the function f ðxÞ ¼ ð1þð1x qÞxÞ2 is increas- increases.
ing in x when 1 < x < 11 q, which leads to f ðx ¼ 1Þ ¼ ð21qÞ2 <
ð1þbÞ 5.2. Numerical studies
f ðx ¼ 1 þ bÞ ¼ ð1þð1þbÞð1qÞÞ2
, so both the manufacturer’s and
channel’s profits are higher than in the rebate-only case.
P þP j P j qÞ2 ð2qÞ2 5.2.1. Base case example
(d) In the L/G segment, PmmþPrrj joint ¼ Pmmj joint ¼ ð1þð1þbÞ
4ð1þbÞ
,
rebate rebate To illustrate some of our findings, we introduce a base case
which is an increasing function in 1 + b, so
2 2
 
2 2
example with the following parameter settings: bs = $300, a = 0.2,
Pm jjoint
Pm j > ð1þqÞ 4ð2qÞ ¼ 2þq2q > 1, implying that both the b = 0.4, rs = 0.9, and ro = 0.7 (implying q = .22). For the joint
rebate

manufacturer’s and the channel’s profits are higher than in MSRP-rebate policy, using the S/E column of Table 2, the manufac-
the rebate-only case. turer will choose a wholesale price of $228.19, an MSRP of $300,
and a consumer rebate of $111.70. In turn, the retailer will set
Next, to prove statement (3), we compute the channel effi- the retail price equal to the MSRP of $300. The resulting demand
ciency, which is defined as the ratio of the independent channel
profit to the integrated channel profit, i.e., (Pm + Pr)/PI. The
Table 4
channel efficiency of the rebate-only promotion is less than 3/4, Analytical sensitivity analysis.
i.e., PmPþIPr ¼ 3
< 34. Note that a rebate is offered in both
ð2þqq2 Þ2 Sensitivity S/E M/G L/G
independent and integrated channels only when q > a/(1 + a). First,
analysis
it is easy to verify that the channel efficiencies of joint promotion
w ; with q and " Constant ; with q and ;
in the S/E and L/G segments are all greater than 3/4, and the result
with b with b
follows immediately. For the M/G segment, we have the following:
R " with q and " "with q and " Constant
with b with b
 2
Pm þ Pr ð1 þ bÞ Ps Constant
¼3 " with q and ; ; with q and ;
PI ð1 þ ð1 þ bÞð1  qÞÞð1 þ ð1 þ bÞqÞ Pr Constant
with b with b
3
> () 1  qð1 þ bÞð1  qÞ > 0: D " with q and " with b
ð2 þ q  q2 Þ2 Q
r " with q and " with b
The condition 1  q(1 + b)(1-q) > 0 holds because q(1 + b) < 1. Q
m " with q and " with b
Therefore, we have proven that the channel efficiency improves Q Q
r þ m " with q and " with b
with joint promotion in each rebate-offered segment of Table 2. h
S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135 133

will be 0.3351. Profits will be $50.27 and $24.06 for the manufac- Fig. 5 illustrates the same variation on q, but this time focusing
turer and retailer, respectively, for a total system profit of $74.33. on comparing the joint MSRP-rebate policy with a rebate-only pol-
By comparison, using a rebate-only policy, setting a = b = 0, and icy. The joint promotion results in a lower retail price, higher prof-
using the M/G column of Table 2, the manufacturer will choose a its for the manufacturer and the system, and better channel
wholesale price of $300 and a consumer rebate of $187.50. In turn, efficiency (approximately 10% better after the rebate is offered)
the retailer will set the retail price of $384.38, which creates a net as compared to the rebate-only policy. We can observe that MSRP
price to the consumer of $196.88, compared to a net price in the helps the manufacturer to restrict the retailer’s tendency to in-
joint MSRP-rebate case of $188.30. Demand in the rebate-only case crease its price when rebates are offered to consumers.
is 0.2813, or 16.05% less than in the joint case. Profits will be Finally, we explore how the slippage rate and loss aversion
$47.46 and $23.73 for the manufacturer and retailer, respectively, jointly affect the manufacturer’s profitability. By varying b be-
for a total system profit of $71.19. All three profits are lower than tween a (=0.2) and 0.8, we can observe from the three-dimensional
their joint-policy counterparts. Finally, using Table 3, the channel graph of Fig. 6 that the stronger the magnitude of loss aversion, the
efficiency for the joint policy is 77.08% compared to 63.54% for larger the manufacturer’s profits. However, the profit contribution
the rebate-only policy. These results are all consistent with Propo- of the loss aversion effects is smaller than that brought on by slip-
sition 3. page effects. And, as expected, high loss aversion coupled with high
slippage creates the largest profit opportunity for the manufacturer
5.2.2. Sensitivity analysis on slippage rate and loss aversion when implementing a joint MSRP-rebate policy.
To examine the effect of slippage rate on some of the major
equilibrium values from Table 2, we take the base case example
and iterate ro between 0.10 and 0.90 in increments of 0.01. The val- 6. Conclusion
ues of Im, D, R, Ps, Pr and w are plotted in Fig. 4. From these graphs,
we can observe that the manufacturer’s profit and the market de- In this paper, we have demonstrated how the addition of MSRP
mand increase smoothly with the slippage rate; however, the to a consumer rebate policy affects system behavior in a distribu-
curve of the optimal rebate value R increases in a partially stepwise tion channel with reference-dependent consumers. This promotion
fashion with the slippage rate. From graph (d), we can observe that combination is linked to two consumer behavior characteristics:
the retail price follows nearly the same pattern as the wholesale slippage behavior and loss aversion. Existing literature suggests
price, as expected. that the manufacturer can profit by consumers’ slippage, which

Fig. 4. Sensitivity Analysis on Equilibrium Values as the Slippage Rate Varies.


134 S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135

Fig. 5. Comparison of the Joint vs. Rebate-Only Policies as the Slippage Rate Varies.

Fig. 6. Joint Effects of Loss Aversion and Slippage Rate on the Manufacturer’s Profit.
S. Yang et al. / European Journal of Operational Research 205 (2010) 127–135 135

is also supported by our results. Furthermore, the manufacturer Digital Photography Review, 2008. <http://forums.dpreview.com/forums/
read.asp?forum=1029&message=27989678>.
can introduce an MSRP to exploit consumers’ loss aversion and bet-
Erdem, Tulin., Mayhew, G., Sun, B., 2001. Understanding reference-price shoppers:
ter control the channel, thus enhancing the effectiveness of con- A within- and cross-category analysis. Journal of Marketing Research 38 (4),
sumer rebates even more. In fact, we have demonstrated that 445–457.
both the manufacturer and the system will benefit from combining Gerstner, E., Hess, J., 1991. A theory of channel price promotions. The American
Economic Review 81 (4), 872–886.
MSRP information with a rebate promotion. Under certain condi- Gerstner, E., Hess, J., 1995. Pull promotions and channel coordination. Marketing
tions, an MSRP should replace a rebate, and under all other condi- Science 14 (1), 43–60.
tions, the MSRP will enhance the effectiveness of the rebate. Gerstner, E., Hess, J.D., Holthausen, D.M., 1994. Price discrimination through a
distribution channel: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review 84 (5),
According to industry reports, slippage rates can rise as high as 1437–1445.
60% for electronics (Spencer, 2002) to even 90% for software prod- Gilpatric, Scott M., 2009. Slippage in rebate programs and present-biased
ucts (Bulkeley, 1998). This reveals why so many companies are preferences. Marketing Science 28 (2), 229–238.
Gourville, John T., Soman, Dilip, 2005. The Consumer Psychology of Mail-in Rebates:
issuing rebates nowadays, especially for electronics which usually a Model of Anchoring and Adjustment. Working Paper, Harvard Business
have MSRP information easily available. Even for a promoted prod- School. <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=875658>.
uct facing high rebate redemptions, publically announcing the Grow, Brian, Chhatwal, Rishi, 2005. The Great Rebate Runaround. Business Week,
December 5, p. 34.
MSRP to consumers will help manufacturing firms increase profit- Hardesty, David, Suter, Tracy, 2005. E-tail and retail reference price effects. The
ability and control the distribution channel. Journal of Product and Brand Management 14 (2), 129–136.
Hopefully, our results will provide insights for researchers who Helson, Harry, 1964. Adaption Level Theory. Harper And Row, New York.
Kahneman, Daniel, Tversky, Amos, 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision
would like to further analyze the slippage phenomenon on rebates
under risk. Econometrica 47 (2), 263–291.
and the loss aversion effect on MSRP. One extension would be to Kalyanaram, Gurumurthy, Winer, Russell.S., 1995. Empirical generalization from
associate the redemption rate with the consumer’s type, i.e. reference price research. Marketing Science 14 (3-2), 161–169.
assuming ro is decreasing with t. With this assumption, rebate pro- Khouja, Moutaz, 2006. A joint optimal pricing, rebate value, and lot sizing model for
maximizing profits. European Journal of Operational Research 174, 706–723.
motions can price-discriminate between consumer types after pur- Khouja, Moutaz, Zhou, J., 2009. The Effect of Delayed Incentives on Supply Chain
chase, which implies that high consumer types have a low Profits and Consumer Surplus. Production and Operations Management,
probability to redeem because they usually have high redemption doi:10.1111/j.1937-5956.2009.01076.x.
Khouja, Moutaz, Robbins, S.S., Rajagopalan, H.K., 2008. Optimal pricing and delayed
costs and low marginal utilities of income. Hence, the manufac- incentives in a heterogeneous consumer market. Journal of Revenue and Pricing
turer can possibly achieve higher profits by only serving the high Management 7 (1), 85–105.
consumer types. Another line of extension would be to apply this Lal, Rajiv, 1990. Improving channel coordination through franchising. Marketing
Science 9 (4), 299–318.
model to the research on new product design. In that case, the Mayhew, Glenn E., Winer, Russell S., 1992. An empirical analysis of internal and
manufacturer can adjust the product quality level s, which has an external reference prices using scanner data. Journal of Consumer Research 19
increasing production cost such that the manufacturer needs to (1), 62–70.
McClure, Samuel M, David, I.Laibson, George, Loewenstein, Jonathan, D.Cohen,
determine an optimal quality level. Finally, researchers could 2004. Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards.
incorporate the important promotional mix element of advertising Science 306 (5695), 503–507.
into these models. Moorthy, K.Sridhar, 1988. Product and price competition in a duopoly. Marketing
Science 7 (2), 141–168.
Moorthy, K.Sridhar, Lu, Qiang, 2007. Coupons versus rebates. Marketing Science 26
Appendix A. Supplementary data (1), 67–82.
Moorthy, K. Sridhar, Soman, Dilip, 2005. On the Marketing of Rebates: Having Your
Cake and Eating It Too? Working Paper, University of Toronto. <http://
Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=875657>.
the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2009.12.018. Nalla, Vijayender Reddy, Veen, J., Venugopal, V., 2008. Mail-in-Rebates vs.
Combined Rebate Mechanism: Which of them is More Effective for Supply
Chain Coordination? Working Paper, Nyenrode Business Universiteit. <http://
References papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1094725>.
Neslin, Scott A., 2002. Sales promotion. In: Weitz, B., Wensley, R. (Eds.), Handbook of
Arcelus, F.J., Kumar, Satyendra, Srinivasan, G., 2006. Retailer’s response to alternate Marketing. Sage Publications Ltd., London, UK, pp. 310–338.
manufacturer’s incentives under a single-period, price-dependent, stochastic- Rajendran, K.N., Tellis, Gerard J., 1994. Contextual and temporal components of
demand framework. Decision Sciences 36 (4), 599–626. reference price. Journal of Marketing 58 (1), 22–34.
Aydin, Goker, Porteus, Evan L., 2009. Manufacturer-to-retailer versus manufacturer- Rhee, Byong-Duk, 1996. Consumer heterogeneity and strategic quality decisions.
to-consumer rebates in a supply chain. In: Agrawal, N., Smith, S.A. (Eds.), Retail Management Science 42 (2), 157–172.
Supply Chain Management. Springer, New York, pp. 237–270. Silk, Timothy Guy, 2004. Why Do We Buy But Fail to Redeem? Examining the
Becker, David, 2002. Rebates Key for Retail Software Sales. CNET News.com, Breakage of Mail-in Rebates. Doctoral Dissertation, University of Florida.
November 12. Soman, Dilip, 1998. The illusion of delayed incentives: Evaluating future effort-
Blattberg, Robert C., Wisniewski, Kenneth J., 1989. Price-induced patterns of money transactions. Journal of Marketing Research 35 (4), 427–437.
competition. Marketing Science 8 (4), 291–309. Spencer, Jane, 2002. As Cash-Back Offers Multiply, So Do Obstacles for Consumers.
Bulkeley, William M., 1998. Rebates’ secret appeal to manufacturers: Few Wall Street Journal (Eastern edition), p. D.1.
consumers actually redeem them. Wall Street Journal (Eastern edition), p. B.1. Tom, Sabrina M, Craig, R.Fox, Christopher, Trepel, Russell, A.Poldrack1, 2007. The
Chen, Yuxin, Moorthy, Sridhar, John Zhang, Z., 2005. Price discrimination after the neural basis of loss aversion in decision-making under risk. Science 315 (5811),
purchase: Rebates as state-dependent discounts. Management Science 51 (7), 515–518.
1131–1140. TractorByNet.com, 2005. <http://www.tractorbynet.com/forums/kubota-buying-
Chen, Xin, Li, Chung-Lun, Simchi-Levi, David, 2007. The impact of manufacturer pricing/66105-gr2100-price-increase.html>.
rebates on supply chain profits. Naval Research Logistics 54, 667–680. Unger, Drew, 2009. How to get Insane Deals: The Ultimate Tech Challenge. CPA
Cho, Soo-Haeng, McCardle, K.F., Tang, C.S., 2009. Optimal pricing and rebate Advisor, <http://www.cpaadvisor.us/sub/2_tech_challenge.htm>.
strategies in a two-level supply chain. Production and Operations Management Yue, Jinfeng, Jill, Austin, Min-Chiang, Wang, Zhimin, Huang, 2006. Coordination of
18 (4), 424–446. cooperative advertising in a two-level supply chain when manufacturer offers
Chu, Wujin, Desai, Preyas S., 1995. Channel coordination mechanisms for customer discount. European Journal of Operational Research 168, 65–85.
satisfaction. Marketing Science 14 (4), 343–359.

You might also like