You are on page 1of 16

564088

research-article2015
CRS0010.1177/0896920514564088Critical SociologyMeans

Article

Critical Sociology

Generational Precarity, Education,


1­–16
© The Author(s) 2015
Reprints and permissions:
and the Crisis of Capitalism: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0896920514564088
Conventional, Neo-Keynesian, crs.sagepub.com

and Marxian Perspectives

Alexander J Means
SUNY, Buffalo State College, USA

Abstract
In the wake of the global financial crisis, societies across the world are attempting to manage
potentially destabilizing levels of youth unemployment and underemployment. New terms have
entered the popular lexicon such as ‘generation jobless’, ‘the new underclass’, and ‘the precariat’
in order to describe a generation of young people struggling to acquire secure livelihoods in the
most dismal labor market since the Great Depression. This article draws on analytical resources
from critical sociology of education and heterodox political economy in order to critique
orthodox economic diagnoses of generational precarity as a human capital problem. It argues that
while neo-Keynesian accounts provide an important corrective to certain aspects of conventional
(neoclassical/neoliberal) viewpoints, they ultimately fall short of the explanatory power of
Marxian analysis, particularly concerning the primacy of class relations and the contradictory role
of employment within an increasingly crisis-ridden global capitalism.

Keywords
crisis theory, human capital, political economy, precarity, youth employment

Introduction
In the wake of the global financial crisis, societies across the world are attempting to manage
potentially destabilizing levels of youth unemployment and underemployment. New terms have
entered the popular lexicon such as ‘generation jobless’, ‘the new underclass’, and ‘the precariat’
in order to describe a generation of young people struggling to acquire secure livelihoods in the
most dismal labor market since the Great Depression. The economic insecurity of the young repre-
sents an emerging site of social conflict and a looming challenge to the ongoing legitimacy of
dominant economic, social, and political arrangements (Mason, 2012). Within mainstream

Corresponding author:
Alexander J Means, Department of Social and Psychological Foundations of Education, SUNY, Buffalo State College,
1300 Elmwood Avenue, Buffalo, NY 14222, USA.
Email: alexmeans1@gmail.com

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


2 Critical Sociology 

discussions, it is often suggested that the primary mechanism to manage the youth employment
crisis is through more and better education. It is argued that educational systems need to become
more closely aligned with emergent human capital imperatives in order to produce the highly
skilled, flexible and entrepreneurial workers said to be required to fill and invent the jobs of the
future (Cowen, 2013; Goldin and Katz, 2008). Such views are now dominant in the mainstream
media and in the business press. They have also worked to shape global educational policy through
transnational organizations such as the World Bank and the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) that advocate for privatization, standardization, and corporate manage-
rialism across national education systems (Ball, 2012; Olssen and Peters, 2005). However, despite
incessant calls for educational reform and human capital investment, mounting evidence indicates
that global education systems are in fact producing a global surplus of credentialed, highly skilled
workers at rates far faster than they can be effectively integrated into the world economy (Brown
et al., 2011). At the same time, transformations in the global division of labor and the organization
of production and work have diminished the job prospects and driven down the real wages of
young workers, contributing to deepening generational ‘precarity’ across many parts of the world
(Standing, 2011). This has only been aggravated as a stagnant transnational capital attempts to
reconstitute itself through short-term speculative fixes and austerity arrangements that serve to
deepen inequality, while placing a further drag on economic recovery and employment for the
majority of workers (McNally, 2009; Streeck, 2014).
Critical sociologists of education have long observed the various ways that educational systems
are implicated in reproducing and legitimating relations of capital accumulation and class stratifi-
cation (Bourdieu and Passeron, 1977; Bowles and Gintis, 2011). These perspectives have also
demonstrated how labor market conditions such as relative levels of employment are largely pro-
duced externally to educational systems through the market, property, and power relations imma-
nent to capitalist societies. This article does not attempt to provide a new model for either refining
or refuting the relative ‘correspondence’ (or lack thereof) between education and the reproduction
of workforce skills and/or a hierarchical class structure (Livingstone, 1995, 2009; Rikowski, 1997).
Rather the article draws on analytical resources from critical sociology of education and heterodox
political economy in order to critique orthodox neoliberal and neo-Keynesian diagnoses and pre-
scriptions for addressing generational precarity. Drawing examples mainly from the United States
and Canada, it suggests that education conceived as human capital development for youth employ-
ment is largely an ideological construct that obscures and individualizes underlying structural ten-
sions and contradictions. It argues that while neo-Keynesian accounts provide an important
corrective to certain aspects of conventional (neoclassical/neoliberal) economic viewpoints, they
ultimately fall short of the explanatory power of Marxian analysis, particularly concerning the
primacy of class relations and the contradictory role of employment within an increasingly crisis-
ridden global capitalism.

Framing the Crisis: The Undereducated American and


Overeducated Canadian
The youth employment crisis is symptomatic of a broad failure of global capitalism and of societies
to provide meaningful and dignified livelihoods to the next generation. The International Labor
Organization (ILO) has warned of a ‘scarred’ generation of youth ‘facing a dangerous mix of high
unemployment, increased inactivity and precarious work in developed countries, as well as persis-
tently high working poverty in the developing world’ (ILO, 2013). It estimates that in 2013, 12.6
percent, or around 73 million youth between the ages of 15 and 24 were unemployed globally, only
a fraction off the post-crash peak of 12.7 percent in 2009. Not surprisingly, the crisis is most acute

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 3

in the poorest regions where 90 percent of the world’s youth live. The ILO estimates that up to
two-thirds of youth in parts of the developing world are currently ‘underutilized’, meaning they are
either unemployed, in irregular or informal employment, or are ‘inactive’ in employment, educa-
tion, or training. In the European Union and other advanced economies of the OECD like the
United States and Canada, unemployment rates of youth ages 15–24 have also soared by almost 25
percent since 2008, and as of 2012, were at a two-decade high of 18.1 percent (Greece, Spain,
South Africa, and Portugal each have rates over 40 percent). Additionally, a staggering number of
youth across the OECD, around 40 percent, are precariously employed in temporary jobs, typically
with low pay and few if any benefits, while 15 percent of all youth are completely inactive in
employment, education or training.
Like their counterparts across the OECD, millions of young people in the United States and
Canada are struggling to acquire secure employment. Both nations have youth unemployment rates
that are double the national average, 16 percent in the USA and 14 percent in Canada (Addressing
Youth Unemployment and Underemployment: AYUU, 2014; Ayers, 2013; Canadian Center for
Policy Alternatives: CCPA, 2014; Shierholz et al., 2013). Additionally, increasing numbers of
youth in both nations are precariously employed and/or underemployed (40 percent by some esti-
mates), while close to 15 percent are inactive in employment, education, or training. These figures
are far from abstractions. Widespread employment insecurity and declining real wages, soaring
costs of college tuition, and staggering levels of student debt mean that vast numbers of young
people are facing a future of great uncertainty and hardship. The negative impacts are not only felt
in significantly reduced lifetime earnings and savings, but are experienced in elevated anxiety,
stress, depression, and self-blame. Furthermore, the consequences are not only personal, but eco-
nomic and societal as well. Youth unemployment and underemployment lowers demand for goods
and services, which perpetuates a cycle of economic stagnation. It also reduces the tax base, while
at the same time labor market insecurity generates elevated need for government investments in
areas such as public education, job training, health care, and unemployment insurance (Reich,
2012; Stiglitz, 2012). It is also essential to point out that the youth employment crisis reflects and
exacerbates deeply rooted and expanding class and race inequalities across societies (Therborn,
2013). Youth from working class, immigrant, and racially marginalized backgrounds face many
additional barriers to acquiring steady work. They are more likely to face discrimination in hiring
and have to cope with geographical and social isolation that limits access to affordable transporta-
tion, housing, high quality schools, and employment opportunities (Wilkinson and Pickett, 2009).
For instance, in the United States, African American youth make up 16 percent of Americans aged
20 to 24, but they constitute 23 percent of young adults inactive in the labor market (Ayers, 2013).
Similarly, Latino youth make up 21 percent of Americans aged 20 to 24, but constitute 23 percent
of inactive young adults. These figures do not include the disproportionate number of youth of
color who have been discarded by the new economy and warehoused in American (and Canadian)
prisons via the drug war and the criminalization of poverty (Alexander, 2010; Wacquant, 2009).
Media representations often frame the youth employment crisis as an educational problem. For
instance, in Canada, the youth unemployment crisis is often said to derive from overeducation (or
at least education of the wrong type, too many humanities degrees for instance) (see Sorenson and
Gillis, 2013; Venn, 2013). Young people in Canada, it is argued, are facing a job market oversatu-
rated with college and university graduates, which translates into elevated competition in the labor
market. Anxieties reflecting the overeducation narrative are widely discussed in the Canadian
media. In 2013, Maclean’s Magazine ran a story describing this generation of Canadian post-sec-
ondary graduates as ‘history’s most cultivated underclass’ (Sorensen and Gillis, 2013). A 2013
Canadian Broadcasting Company (CBC) documentary, titled ‘Generation Jobless’, covered similar
ground. It posed the question: ‘Why are so many young Canadians overeducated and unemployed?’

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


4 Critical Sociology 

(CBC, 2014) Despite roughly similar rates of youth unemployment and underemployment, as well
as post-secondary attainments (Canada is ranked second in the OECD and the USA fifth) (OECD,
2014), the popular narrative is quite different in the United States. While still represented as an
educational problem, the youth employment crisis is said to stem from undereducation (Carnevale
and Rose, 2011; Goldin and Katz, 2008). From this perspective, the United States educational
system is said to be failing to provide enough skilled graduates relative to their demand and that
this is hampering economic recovery and job growth. Unlike in Canada, the educational system in
the USA is said to be in a terminal crisis. This point of view is represented in countless news sto-
ries, editorials, and in journalistic accounts such as in Thomas Friedman’s (2007) influential The
World Is Flat. It is succinctly articulated in a report by Anthony Carnevale and Stephen Rose
(2011) titled ‘The Undereducated American’. In this report, Carnevale and Rose argue the United
States needs 20 million additional college graduates by 2025 in order to keep up with rising demand
in the economy.
These narratives of undereducation and overeducation are largely ideological constructs. This is
not to suggest that undereducation (as an absence of formal skills or training) does not render some
young people unqualified for certain kinds of work, or that overeducation (as a surplus of formal
skills, or of the wrong kind of skills) does not render some young people overqualified for certain
kinds of work. These two factors are in fact coextensive and highly variable upon a host of factors
(Livingstone, 2009). However, as I detail in the following sections, neither undereducation nor
overeducation provide an adequate empirical or theoretical explanation for generational precarity,
largely due to flawed conventional economic assumptions regarding the dynamic relationship
between formal education, employment, and capitalism.

Conventional Perspectives: Youth Employment as a Human


Capital Problem
Conventional perspectives are rooted in neoclassical/neoliberal rationalities enamored with
abstract mathematical models and theorems oriented to proving the ‘natural’ efficiencies and equi-
librium tendencies of self-regulating markets (which the models and theorems are of course prede-
termined to prove). These perspectives represent the now dominant post-Keynesian tilt of the
economics discipline that germinated in the postwar period, solidified in the aftermath of the eco-
nomic crisis of Fordism in the 1970s, and eventually triumphed during the post-Cold War era of
global capitalist development (Brenner, 2006; Galbraith, 2014; Harvey, 2005).
Conventional perspectives drive popular narratives such as the undereducated American and
overeducated Canadian and suggest that technological change and the level of human capital
development through educational training are the primary factors in determining employment for
youth today. They stubbornly cling to a version of Say’s law that suggests supply of skilled labor
creates its own demand. Unlike classical political economists like Adam Smith, who calculated
labor as a homogenous input, conventional viewpoints reflect the now broadly accepted notion of
investment-related labor differentiation popularized by Gary Becker (1964), that suggests educa-
tion (imagined exclusively and narrowly as human capital development) increases the marginal
productivity of labor, and therefore enhances growth in employment, wages, and economic output.
The general idea is that workers with high skill levels drive innovation and economic growth,
which simultaneously increases demand in the employment structure for workers (who assume
ever more responsibility for acquiring advanced educational attainments).
A recent and influential articulation of these ideas can be found in the work of Claudia Goldin
and Lawrence Katz (2008) who have analyzed the relationship between education, technology, and
employment through what they call skills-biased technological change (SBTC). They argue that

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 5

the most significant factor in determining employment and income distribution is the capacity of
educational systems to meet human capital requirements of new technology. They argue that eco-
nomic expansion and reductions in inequality in the United States and other advanced economies
during the middle part of the 20th century, which they refer to as the ‘human capital century’, were
driven by mass expansion of public education that kept pace with technical innovations and atten-
dant demand for enhanced skills. They state:

… we have emphasized the existence of an ongoing and relentless race between technology and education.
Economic growth and inequality are the outcomes of the contest. As technological change races forward,
demands for skills – some new and some old – are altered. If the workplace can rapidly make adjustment,
then economic growth is enhanced without greatly exacerbating inequality of economic outcomes. If, on
the other hand, the skills that are currently demanded are produced slowly and if the workforce is less
flexible in its skill set, then growth is slowed and inequality widens. Those who can make the adjustments
as well as those who gain the new skills are rewarded. Others are left behind. (p. 254)

The SBTC thesis coincides with the widespread claim that a primary driver of youth unemploy-
ment today is a skills/jobs mismatch where employers supposedly cannot find workers with the
right capacities for current job requirements. Goldin and Katz, as well as others committed to the
SBTC and skills/jobs mismatch explanations, suggest that increasing the number of college gradu-
ates and refocusing their training will generate employment for youth and lower income inequality
as an increasing supply of highly skilled workers rises to meet current demand as well as stimulate
new demand for employment. MIT economist David Autor and his colleagues have offered a com-
plementary perspective to the SBTC and skills/mismatch theses (Autor, 2010; Autor and Dorn,
2013). They observe that technological changes such as robotization and automation have contrib-
uted to a ‘polarization’ of the employment structure over the last three decades. They further sug-
gest that technology and enhanced mobility of capital and production under globalization have
‘hollowed out’ middle income employment in the United States as well as other advanced econo-
mies like Canada. These are ‘routine’ jobs that are easy to automate and outsource such as bank
tellers, clerical workers, and middle managers. Simultaneously, they claim that the bulk of job
growth has occurred at the top of the wage hierarchy in analytical sectors such as STEM (science,
technology, engineering and mathematics) and finance, and at the bottom in low wage service jobs
that are difficult if not impossible to automate or outsource. Autor and Dorn (2013) observe:

… computerization is not reducing the quantity of jobs, but rather degrading the quality of jobs for a
significant subset of workers. Demand for highly educated workers who excel in abstract tasks is robust,
but the middle of the labor market, where the routine task-intensive jobs lie, is sagging. Workers without
college education therefore concentrate in manual task-intensive jobs – like food services, cleaning and
security – which are numerous but offer low wages, precarious job security and few prospects for upward
mobility.

Autor and Dorn are not overly pessimistic about the polarization of work and their prescriptions are
closely aligned with the SBTC and skills/jobs mismatch arguments. They suggest:

… citizens should invest more in their education. Spurred by growing demand for workers performing
abstract job tasks, the payoff for college and professional degrees has soared; despite its formidable price
tag, higher education has perhaps never been a better investment.

Thus the ‘jobs polarization’ argument tracks with the SBTC and skills/jobs mismatch theses that
suggest that the answer for resolving the youth employment crisis is to reform education so as to
elevate and tailor the skills of the young to meet and stimulate demand in employment.

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


6 Critical Sociology 

In his book Average Is Over (2013), George Mason University economist Tyler Cowen extends
these arguments while offering a decidedly more pessimistic assessment of the prospects of young
workers. ‘The labor market troubles of the young’, he writes, ‘are a harbinger of the new world of
work to come’ (p. 3). Cowen suggests that in the future, young people with the right education,
skills, and training will continue to gain a competitive advantage and garner a ‘wage premium’
over their less educated peers. However, he also describes a zero-sum world where intelligent
machines will increasingly substitute for human labor and in the process radically remake the
employment structure. ‘Whether we wish to call those machines “AI,” “software,” “smart phones,”
“superior hardware and storage,” “better integrated systems,” or any of the above. This is the wave
that will either lift you or that will dump you’ (p. 6). He writes:

The key questions will be: Are you good at working with intelligent machines or not? Are your skills a
complement to the skills of a computer, or is the computer doing better without you? Worst of all, are you
competing against the computer? Are computers helping people in China and India compete against you?
If you and your skills are a complement to the computer, your wage and labor market prospects are likely
to be cheery. If your skills do not complement the computer, you may want to address that mismatch. Ever
more people are starting to fall on one side of the divide or the other. That’s why average is over. (pp. 4–5)

The idea that ‘average is over’ signals Cowen’s insistence that the radical polarization of labor and
income is inevitable and unalterable. In his view, advances in robotics, automation, and computing
power are creating a ‘hyper-meritocracy’ where the highly educated and motivated few (top 5%)
will perform demanding cognitive work and lead enriching lives, while the majority will face a
reality of growing economic redundancy and diminished opportunity. One of the few growth
industries that Cowen identifies for youth who may not be technically inclined is in the provision
of new forms of personal services to the rich. He states:

We can expect a lot of growth in personal services, even if those jobs do not rely very directly on computing
power. The more the high earners pull in, the more people will compete to serve them, sometimes for high
wages and sometimes for low wages. This will mean maids, chauffeurs, and gardeners for the high earners,
but a lot of service jobs won’t fall under the service category as traditionally construed … It sounds a little
silly but making the high earners feel better in just about every aspect of their lives will be a major source
of job growth in the future. Better about the world. Better about themselves. Better about what they have
achieved. (pp. 22–23)

Cowen’s description of the future is dystopian. However, it is also typical of conventional neolib-
eral perspectives in that it ideologically positions capitalism as an immutable and objective mecha-
nism for distributing ethical outcomes. The only real choice, or option, is to adapt by reconfiguring
our educational systems to prepare youth physically and psychologically for a future defined by
ruthless competition over increasingly scarce jobs and resources. Without too much hyperbole, the
logical extension of his argument would be that for secondary and higher educational systems to
provide pathways for youth into the job market they should downsize in all areas unrelated to the
core ‘value adding’ STEM fields (areas such as literature, philosophy, political science, fine arts)
and invest in creating degree programs in areas that provide services to the rich such as elite spa
therapy, plastic surgery rehabilitation, yoga instruction, personal training, and butler etiquette.
Ultimately, Cowen’s vision for young people is a winner-take-all future that mirrors a digitalized,
neo-feudal version of Downtown Abbey. This vision, of course, reflects a right-wing cultural poli-
tics that justifies the degradation of existential possibilities for youth through the conflation of
personal virtue with the rough justice of the market. Within this vein, Cowen argues that a majority
of young workers today are simply not hirable. He suggests this is due to laziness in young men

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 7

and what he refers to as ‘baby lust’ in young women that render them incapable of upgrading their
human capital. Such views are hardly unique. For instance, Charles Murray (2010) argues that
joblessness cannot be understood separately from the apparent disintegration of self-restraint and
‘family values’ among the middle and working classes. Similarly, New York Times columnist
David Brooks (2012) suggests that the rich simply have better values, work harder, and instill the
right attitude for educational achievement in their children. In these views, supporting youth
employment is positioned as a task for education and human capital cultivation, but it will only
succeed if the middle and working classes embrace a new ascetic moralism and inculcate a renewed
sense of grit, resiliency, and personal discipline in the young. Cowen suggests that in the future,
shantytowns should be built on the outskirts of major cities in the USA in order to provide cheap
living conditions for the underserving multitude who fail to maximize their human capital (to add
value to ‘smart machines’) through the requisite exercise of moral rectitude and competitive indi-
vidualism (pp. 244–5).
It is in orthodox neoliberal narratives like Cowen’s that the human capital framing of genera-
tional precarity as an educational problem reveals itself for what it is, a blatant form of ideology
that justifies and legitimates a social formation based upon the exploitation of the many by the
few. Here technology becomes an alibi for a host of broader contradictions, tensions, and conflicts
immanent to the political and moral economy of global capitalism. Education, in turn, is not only
positioned as a means for producing skills and capacities to meet the demands of employers, but
also as an ethical scene of subjectification whereby young people are to develop a habitus that
submits to the rhythm of supposedly immutable economic laws and a new disciplinary regime of
technologically-mediated, precarious living labor. Thus diagnoses and prescriptions of the youth
employment crisis as an educational problem individualize the structural conditions of insecurity
generated by neoliberal capitalism and attendant transformations at the level of the state. It does
so through perpetuating a fallacy, long discredited in critical sociological analysis of education,
that relative educational investment and individual (meritocratic) acquisition of educational cre-
dentials (undereducation and overeducation) are the primary determinants of employment (and
inequality) as well as the primary solution for resolving unemployment (Bowles and Gintis, 2011;
Livingstone, 2009).

Neo-Keynesian Perspectives: Youth Employment as a Policy


Problem
Writing in The Guardian, Dean Baker (2013) of the Center for Economic and Policy Research
observes that conventional economic explanations such as those offered by Goldin and Katz,
Autor, and Cowen regarding the primacy of education and technology serve to obfuscate rather
than illuminate the core issues driving youth unemployment today. He states:

This story is comforting to elites because it means that inequality is something that happened, not
something they did. They won out because they had the skills and intelligence to succeed in a dynamic
economy, whereas the huge mass of workers that are falling behind did not. In this story the best we can
do for the left behinds is empathy and education. We can increase their opportunities to upgrade their skills
in the hope that more of them may be able to join the winners. (Baker, 2013)

Such observations are not meant to deny the powerful role of education and technology in shaping
labor market conditions. A 2013 study by Carl Benedict Frey and Michael Osbourne of the
University of Oxford, has suggested that up to 47 percent of job categories in nations like the
United States and Canada are under ‘high risk’ of automation over the next two decades (this

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


8 Critical Sociology 

doesn’t include offshoring). According to the study, the next round of automation will include a
considerable number of white-collar occupations such as management, accounting, technical writ-
ing, legal work, and teaching. What is essential to point out is that the dislocating effects of new
technology for the present and future employment prospects of young people have little relation to
the relative educational and/or skill level of the population (undereducation or overeducation).
Neo-Keynesian economists like Dean Baker, Joseph Stiglitz, Jeff Madrick, Lawrence Mishel,
Heidi Shierholz, and Paul Krugman thus argue that conventional narratives of skill-biased techno-
logical change and skills/jobs mismatch simply do not provide adequate explanations for youth
employment dynamics. Drawing broadly on Keynesian principles, they reject supply-side ration-
alities that suggest human capital development generates its own demand and thus that education
is either the primary cause and/or solution to high levels of unemployment and underemployment
among youth. In contrast, they observe that in the current economic climate, advanced economies
like the United States and Canada have simply not been creating enough jobs in aggregate relative
to demand. They also note that the fastest growing job opportunities are in low wage sectors that
do not require advanced educational credentials, skills, or training, and contrary to Autor’s ‘jobs
polarization’ theses, they point out that there simply hasn’t been any growth in high skill and high
wage employment over the last decade. Jeff Madrick (2013) summarizes the consequences for
young workers in the United States:

The economy is simply not producing enough jobs. Between 1992 and 2000, 18 million people joined the
workforce. Between 2000 and 2010, only 2.2 million were able to join. With far fewer jobs available, those
with more experience get picked first, while those entering the workforce for the first time get picked last.
The recession has exacerbated this trend, as older workers delay retirement in hopes of rebuilding the
savings lost in the downturn. Those aged fifty-five and older are the only group whose labor-force
participation has actually increased in recent decades. They are taking the part-time jobs kids used to get
as store clerks and cashiers … Meanwhile, recent college graduates are left to take the jobs that once went
to high school graduates and even dropouts.

Across advanced economies, college graduation rates have risen to historic levels at the same time
that job prospects and wages for college-educated workers have precipitously fallen. For instance,
in the United States ‘between 2000 and 2012, the real (inflation-adjusted) wages of young high
school graduates declined 12.7 percent, and the real wages of young college graduates declined 8.5
percent’ (Sheirholz et al., 2013). This reflects, of course, that many skilled college and university
graduates are stuck in jobs that do not require advanced skills or a degree. According to the OECD,
Canada has the highest overqualification rate of advanced nations at 27 percent for all of its work-
ers (Finlayson, 2014). This helps to explain attraction to the narrative that young Canadians are
overeducated. However, the United States is not far behind with an overqualification rate of 20
percent. This rate spikes for young college graduates:

The share of Americans ages 22 to 27 with at least a bachelor’s degree in jobs that don’t require that level
of education was 44 percent in 2012 … a year-long survey ending in July 2012 of 500,000 Americans ages
19 to 29 showed that 63 percent of those fully employed had a bachelor’s degree, and their most common
jobs were merchandise displayers, clothing-store and cellular phone sales representatives. (Peralta, 2014)

In the highly touted STEM fields, educational systems are in fact producing many more graduates
than there are jobs, raising further questions concerning the SBTC and skills/jobs mismatch argu-
ments. The Economic Policy Institute reports that for every two students graduating with a STEM
degree from an American university each year, only one is hired into a STEM job (Salzman et al.,
2013). In information science and engineering, the United States graduates 50 percent more

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 9

students than are hired into those fields each year, while real wages for these workers are stuck at
1990 levels (Salzman et al., 2013). This isn’t to argue that there are not situations where industry
is having a hard time filling positions, but that the reasons, as those like Peter Cappelli (2012) have
documented, do not reflect an overall skills shortage, but that corporations have cut or eliminated
on-the-job training and are often offering such low pay that they cannot find skilled workers will-
ing to take open positions. Where there are shortages of skilled workers such as in the trade profes-
sions, this reflects policy decisions in secondary and higher education since the 1990s where
vocational education was devalued under the rationale that everyone was now going to become a
knowledge worker or an entrepreneur (a rationale that has not panned out). Moreover, substantial
evidence indicates that global educational systems are currently producing a global surplus of cre-
dentialed, highly skilled workers far beyond current employment requirements. The effect of this
surplus has been to empower transnational capital to exploit a global ‘labor arbitrage’ or ‘auction’
for cut-rate low and highly skilled labor (i.e. race to the bottom) that has eroded the employment
prospects and repressed wages for young workers (Bellamy Foster and McChesney, 2012; Brown
et al., 2011).
Given these observations, neo-Keynesians argue that youth employment is contingent upon a
much broader set of political-economic problems to be resolved through state intervention and
progressive policy solutions. They point to three decades dominated by supply-side management
rationalities and regressive tax policies; steep cuts to public investments in infrastructure, educa-
tion, and social services; deregulatory excesses leading to multiple speculative financial bubbles
and busts; the decline of unions and bargaining power of workers; soaring compensation by execu-
tives, hedge fund managers, and bankers; and the domination of state policy by transnational cor-
porate interests increasingly unmoored from geographical constraints and primarily concerned
with socializing their costs (and losses) while keeping taxes and wages as low as possible (regard-
less of the social or environmental costs) (Krugman, 2011; Reich, 2012; Stiglitz, 2012). As a result,
and despite the fact that the productivity of the average worker has increased dramatically over the
last three decades, economic gains have accrued almost exclusively to investors, owners, and exec-
utive managers. Simultaneously, as middle and working class livelihoods have dramatically
declined, households have taken on unprecedented levels of private debt to keep up with soaring
costs of living. These trends have created structural problems and imbalances that have had devas-
tating consequences for youth employment including ever-deeper recessions, jobless recoveries,
and anemic rates of economic growth. The result has been a stunning expansion of inequality and
staggering economic insecurity and uncertainty, felt most acutely by young workers. Heidi
Shierholz, Natalie Sbadish, and Nicholas Finio (2013) of the Economic Policy Institute thus attrib-
ute the dismal job market for youth to stagnating economic growth and the exhausted purchasing
power of workers. They note:

The large increase since 2007 in the unemployment and underemployment rate of young college graduates,
and in the share of employed young college graduates working in jobs that do not require a college degree,
underscores that today’s unemployment crisis among young workers did not arise because these young
adults lack the right education or skills. Rather, it stems from weak demand for goods and services, which
makes it unnecessary for employers to significantly ramp up hiring.

Ultimately, neo-Keynesians suggest that education simply cannot resolve the youth employment
crisis and/or labor market insecurities more broadly. Paul Krugman (2011) notes:

… if we want a society of broadly shared prosperity, education isn’t the answer – we’ll have to go about
building that society directly. We need to restore the bargaining power that labor has lost over the last 30

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


10 Critical Sociology 

years, so that ordinary workers as well as superstars have the power to bargain for good wages. We need
to guarantee the essentials, above all health care, to every citizen. What we can’t do is get where we need
to go just by giving workers college degrees, which may be no more than tickets to jobs that don’t exist or
don’t pay middle-class wages.

Neo-Keynesians like Krugman thus advocate for rethinking public policy to directly address the
youth employment crisis. This includes using the state to provide demand-side stimulus through
infrastructure spending, public investment, and public job creation. Their general prescription for
addressing the crisis is therefore oriented to a new social compact that includes the extension of
economic rights as well as civil and political rights to workers. Neo-Keynesian perspectives thus
rightly reject the ideological claims of conventional economists that if left alone capitalism natu-
rally tends toward equilibrium and full employment, particularly if educational systems continue
to keep pace with technological development. They also recognize the inherently political nature
of markets and the centrality of the state in providing the rules of the road for capital accumulation.
However, neo-Keynesians are primarily concerned with finding the right policy solutions to make
capitalism ‘work’ in the interest of generating demand for economic growth and full employment.
In other words, they assert that the disequilibrium tendencies of capitalism can be brought into
equilibrium through enlightened use of state interventions. Here the labor market insecurities of
youth are largely viewed as a governmental problem and a policy issue rather than symptomatic of
deeper conflicts located within capitalism itself. Thus, like conventional perspectives, neo-Keynes-
ians view the youth employment crisis primarily through a technocratic lens. However, rather than
looking to self-regulating markets and market-based educational logics of human capital develop-
ment as solutions to the crisis, they advocate for new regulatory mechanisms to stimulate aggregate
demand and promote direct generation of employment through the state (which would also include
training and retraining workers for new types of jobs demanded by technological change).
Therefore, absent from both conventional and neo-Keynesian perspectives is any sense of how
class relations (as a bundle of conflicts over financial, cultural, and social capital) and real histori-
cal political conditions (balance of social, racial, gendered, and ideological forces in relation to the
state and capital) function to shape the underlying dynamics of education and employment in rela-
tion to the inherent structural contradictions and disequilibrium tendencies of capitalism (Bowles
and Gintis, 1975, 2011).

Marxian Perspectives: Youth Employment as Symptom of


Systemic Crisis
The analytical power of Marxian perspectives is that they position the plight of young workers
within a broader set of dynamics that go beyond the surface of supply and demand frameworks of
orthodox neoliberals and neo-Keynesians. They cast doubt on the capacity of either education or
state policy to generate and maintain equilibrium and full employment under capitalism. Rather
education, employment, and state policy are viewed as reflective of more complex and irreconcil-
able tensions. Foremost is recognition that capitalism’s own internal necessity to perpetually
expand contains within itself fundamental disequilibrium tendencies and barriers to accumulation
that are internal to the normal functioning of the system. This stems from four basic features of
capitalism (Harvey, 1991, 2007, 2010, 2014; Marx, 1992[1867], Vol. 1).

1. The first is that capitalism is based on endless accumulation and growth, which is charac-
terized by and accomplished through the production and realization of surplus value (i.e.
profit). This can be shorthanded, in the language of Marx in the first volume of Capital, as
the perpetual ‘accumulation of capital for accumulation’s sake’.

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 11

2. The second is that capitalism is based on a central antagonistic relation between capital and
labor. This antagonism arises out of what Marx referred to as the ‘organic composition’ of
capital. This is composed of ‘constant capital’, or private ownership and investments in
productive forces (plant, machinery, tools etc.), and ‘variable capital’, which refers to the
wages allocated to labor. Profit reflects the gap between variable capital, or wages allo-
cated, and the surplus value generated by labor in the production process. This surplus
value is appropriated by capital as capital – a portion of which must be reinvested to sup-
port expansion of production for endless accumulation.
3. The third is that capitalism is based on ruthless inter-firm competition. This impels indi-
vidual capitalists to always seek new ways of reducing their operating costs and increasing
efficiency in production. They do so by seeking out the lowest possible wage for labor and
through productivity enhancing innovations, technologies, and organizational strategies.
This allows capitalist firms to increase their market share and capture relative surplus value
at the expense of competitors. The losers are either taken over and therefore absorbed by
ever-larger monopolistic competitors, or they go bust.
4. The fourth is that capitalism requires maintaining a balance between expanded accumulation
and a relative level of unemployment. This is reflected in what Marx referred to as the
‘reserve army’ of workers. According to Marx, the circuits of capital accumulation tend to
increase demand for labor as growth is stimulated and employers seek to expand production
and hiring. However, if demand for labor rises too high, and too quickly, it empowers work-
ers relative to capital and places upward pressure on wages, which can squeeze profits and
ultimately threaten to bring capital accumulation to a standstill. Thus, as similarly dictated
by the demands of inter-capitalist competition, capital must constantly increase efficiencies
within production that displace workers and keep labor in a subordinate position. In this way
capital produces a relative surplus population to compete against and hold down the wages
of those actively employed. However, as capital attempts to minimize wages and maximize
labor saving efficiencies, what it saves in production comes back to haunt it at the moment
of realization. Here inter-capitalist competition and the need to maintain a relative surplus
population necessitate innovations in production that represses real wages and create redun-
dant populations. In turn, the working-classes lack the purchasing power to participate in the
consumption necessary to spur the endless compound growth demanded by capital.

David Harvey (1991, 2007, 2010, 2014) suggests that these features of a capitalist political
economy are inherently dynamic, unstable, ever shifting, geographically contingent, interdepend-
ent, and conflict ridden. Harvey argues that crises arise out of various types of potential barriers or
antagonisms to the continuous realization of surplus value along the circuit of accumulation (M-C-
M’). He lists eight such antagonisms that can disrupt accumulation:

(1) inability to mass together enough original capital to get production under way (“barriers to entry”
problems); (2) scarcities of labor or recalcitrant forms of labor organization that can produce profit
squeezes; (3) disproportionalities and uneven development between sectors within the division of labor;
(4) environmental crises arising out of resource depletion and land and environmental degradation; (5)
imbalances and premature obsolescence due to uneven or excessively rapid technological changes driven
by the coercive laws of competition and resisted by labor; (6) worker recalcitrance or resistance within a
labor process that operates under the command and control of capital; (7) underconsumption and
insufficient effective demand; (8) monetary and financial crises (liquidity traps) inflation or deflation) that
arise within a credit system that depends on sophisticated credit instruments and organized state powers
alongside a climate of faith and trust. At each one of these points internal to the circulation process of
capital, there exists an antinomy) a potential antagonism that can irrupt as an open contradiction (to use the
language that Marx frequently deploys in Capital). (Harvey, 2010: 337–8)

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


12 Critical Sociology 

Any of these potential antagonisms whether stemming from capital/labor relations, nature, tech-
nology, or financial crisis can produce constraints to expanded reproduction. However, as attempts
are made to constantly maximize and expand productive potential, there is a general tendency to
generate excess capacity and capital relative to available demand and reinvestment opportunities.
Such crises of overaccumulation, Harvey argues, create situations where surpluses of capital and
surpluses of labor sit side by side with no clear way of reconnecting them. This is visible today as
trillions of dollars in corporate profits sit on the sidelines with seemingly few avenues for profita-
ble reinvestment. At the same time, growth continues to lag while the majority of workers, and
especially the young, confront declining wages and growing employment insecurity, debt, and
income inequality (problems which place a further drag on demand and economic growth). In the
1980s and 1990s, the incorporation of vast labor reserves and the opening of new markets through
trade ‘liberalization’ in Asia and across the global South, the intensive movement of capital into
ever riskier forms of deleveraging and financial speculation, combined with tax cut stimulus and
the extension of easy credit to consumers for houses and consumer goods were able to offset these
tendencies to overaccumulation. However, as those like John Bellamy Foster and Robert
McChesney (2012) argue, such strategies now appear exhausted as capital confronts new geo-
graphical (imperial), technological (innovative), and ecological (natural) barriers to expansion.
They observe that the consequences of global economic stagnation will disproportionately impact
the next generation. This is represented symptomatically by the employment crisis facing youth
across large swaths of the world.

The world economy as a whole is undergoing a period of slow-down. The growth rates for the United
States, Europe, and Japan at the center of the system have been sliding for decades. In the first decade of
this century these countries experienced the slowest growth rates since the 1930s; and the opening years
of the second decade look no better. Stagnation is the word economists use for this phenomenon. In human
terms it means declining real wages, massive unemployment, a public sector facing extreme budget crisis,
growing inequality and a general and sometimes sharp decline in the quality of life. It produces all sorts of
social and political crises, and these crises and their consequences will likely be the defining events of the
coming generation. For the majority of the population – excluding the big winners at the top – it feels like
an endless crisis. (Bellamy Foster and McChesney, 2012: vii)

The central insight of Marxian crisis theory is that such stagnation does not constitute an aberra-
tion, but is in fact the normal state of mature capitalist economies. Thus the brief period of rapid
growth and near full employment in the postwar era in North America, Western Europe, and Japan
during the so-called Golden Age of capitalism is to be viewed as an exception rather than an his-
torical norm, made possible largely by massive devaluation of capital during the war. As interna-
tional competition began to mature in the late 1960s and 1970s, the global economy began to revert
to ‘normal’ patterns of slow growth similar to that of the 19th century (Brenner, 2006; Galbraith,
2014). China and India over the last 30 years are also examples of rapid economic growth; how-
ever, significant barriers to long-term growth are now increasingly visible in both of these national
contexts. There is thus a growing recognition even among orthodox economists such as Lawrence
Summers (2014), Paul Krugman (2013), and Robert Gordon (2012) that ‘secular’ stagnation has
now become the new normal and is likely a permanent condition. Alan Nasser (2014) describes the
consequences of permanent stagnation for workers:

… capitalism has reached an overripe state in which workers are suffering slow-motion but inexorable
obsolescence and pauperization and are forced to rely increasingly on borrowing to make ends meet, while
the system is now capable of producing unparalleled private profits which cannot be profitably invested in
private production, lent to cash-strapped households or entirely consumed …We are left with a superfluity

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 13

of both workers and funds representing potential purchasing power and/or investment, and a paucity of
profitable investment opportunities in the private sector. This is typical of capitalist crisis, in which we
have too much capital and too many workers.

Orthodox diagnoses and prescriptions cannot explain or resolve the youth employment crisis
because they do not recognize that its origins lie within the property, power, and class relations
internal to capitalism (and how the property and class structure is inflected by history, ideology,
geography, race, gender, ethnicity, nationality, etc.). And, because of this, they refuse to acknowl-
edge the need to alter the underlying dynamics of the system. Instead neoliberal economists offer
human capital development and endless deregulated speculative bubbles as ways to stimulate
employment and growth. Neo-Keynesians rightly reject austerity and support expanded govern-
ment social investments to stimulate economic activity. However, like the neoliberals, they never
question the underlying logic of private appropriation of surplus value and endless compound
growth (no matter the mounting social and ecological consequences) that make a return to Golden
Age Keynesian equilibrium and full employment impossible. Therefore to counter generational
precarity and promote flourishing livelihoods (i.e. work defined by its social value and not simply
its economic utility) for the next generation will require a much broader conversation and forward-
looking exercise of the imagination. If the projections of both orthodox and heterodox economists
are to be believed, the future currently appears as one of increasing precariousness defined by a
vulgar race to the bottom for ever more scarce resources and degraded livelihoods for the majority
of workers. However, unlike most orthodox economists, heterodox thinkers like Eric Olin Wright
(2010), Richard Wolffe (2012), Alan Nasser (2014), David Harvey, (2014), James Galbraith (2014),
David Graeber (2013) and others have argued that there is no reason why we have to accept this
state of affairs and why we can’t make basic modifications to our economic and political systems
to ensure that everyone who wanted one had access to a well-remunerated livelihood. For instance,
Nasser (2014) states:

The diagnosis of the current malaise points to the only workable prescription. No one thinks that an
entirely automated economic system is possible or desirable. There is always work to be done that can and
should be done by people. Since there are too many workers for the work that needs to be done, if what
work there is were to be distributed among all workers, all workers would be employed, and at much
shorter hours. Leisure time would increase greatly … Wages could under these circumstances be increased
by directing to workers the revenue gains from ever-increasing productivity, and no less importantly, by
turning the uninvestible trillions held by financial and nonfinancial corporations over to working people
… There you have it: full employment, less work, more leisure and higher incomes.

Realizing such alternative possibilities for the future of livelihoods requires engaged contesta-
tions over ideology, which brings the question of education back into the discussion, but in a dif-
ferent frame. The financial crisis has made contradictions within global capitalism, such as growing
inequality and labor market insecurity among the young, sharper and more visible. Such contradic-
tions are readily apparent in the inadequacy of overeducation and undereducation narratives in the
United and Canada as explanations for the youth employment crisis. As I have pointed out, young
people are here said to be either undereducated or overeducated in the wrong areas, requiring skill
enhancement in technical fields, innovation, and entrepreneurialism. However, as the relative scar-
city of STEM jobs in relation to qualified graduates in the United States and Canada suggests, the
reality is that the new economy requires a relatively small number of highly skilled workers with
advanced technical and cognitive capacities. To complicate matters, and despite rhetorical empha-
sis on generating high level human capital through education in order to save capitalism, schools
and universities are increasingly subject to intensive forms of defunding, standardization,

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


14 Critical Sociology 

routinization, and corporate managerialism that are eroding their educational missions (Arthur,
2012; Means, 2013a; Newfield, 2008; Saltman, 2012; Slater, 2014). While strategic investments
are being made, they are typically concentrated in areas of secondary education that serve the elite
and in research areas of higher education likely to bring a return to private industry – such as
energy and mineral extraction, business innovation, pharmaceuticals, biotechnology, and military-
defense (Pierce, 2012). It is difficult to see how these trends will result in enhancing the broad-
based creative, technical, and innovative labor market capacities of all young people. In contrast,
dominant educational trends appear more likely to reproduce a stratified political economy and
division of labor consisting of a small number of elite owners and managers alongside a mass of
workers facing declining wages and likelihood of accelerating rates of technologically-induced
obsolescence (Means, 2013b, 2014).
Calls for human capital development and/or the view that new state regulations can resolve this
situation for young workers fail to make these connections between the structure of education and
current objective demands of capital for labor. While education can enhance capacities of labor and
therefore improve employment opportunities for individuals (not to mention promote critical forms
of culture, knowledge, and consciousness), and state policies can stimulate economic activity and
employment through various mechanisms, these strategies cannot resolve deeper structural trends
that are hollowing out jobs, driving down wages, and creating vast surplus populations of low and
highly skilled workers alike. We need to think far more creatively about the kinds of societies we
want to live in – societies where young people, workers, and the environment are subject to a vul-
gar race to the bottom, or societies committed to flourishing forms of democratic social organiza-
tion and nature–society relations. The youth employment crisis is now often described in the media
as a ‘ticking time bomb’ (Blua, 2012; Coy, 2011) reflecting growing anxieties among elites that a
potential ‘lost generation’ of young workers poses a looming threat to the status quos. This is a
rational concern particularly in light of the eruption of youth-led protests, riots, and social mobili-
zations in recent years from London, Madrid, Santiago, Cairo, to Montreal that have sought to
directly confront and challenge neoliberal hegemony (Mason, 2012). Ultimately, being in solidar-
ity with the young is necessary for achieving alternative economic, social, educational, and work
arrangements as a foundation for sustainable and emancipatory futures beyond neoliberal precarity
(De Lissovoy, 2008).

Funding
This research received no specific grant from any funding agency in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit
sectors.

References
Addressing Youth Unemployment and Underemployment (AYUU) (2014) Submission to the Premier’s
Council on Youth Opportunities. Available at: http://ofl.ca/wp-content/uploads/2014.02.27-SUB-
UnderEmployment.pdf (accessed 21 December 2014).
Alexander M (2010) The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of Colorblindness. New York: The
New Press.
Arthur C (2012) Financial Literacy Education: Neoliberalism, the Consumer, and the Citizen. Rotterdam:
Sense Publishers.
Autor D (2010) The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the U.S. Labor Market: Implications for Employment
and Earnings. Boston, MA: The Hamilton Project and the Center for American Progress/Brookings
Institution/MIT.
Autor D and Dorn D (2013) How technology wrecks the middle class. New York Times, August: 24.
Ayers S (2013) America’s 10 Million Unemployed Youth Spell Dangers for Future Economic Growth. Boston,
MA: The Center for American Progress/MIT.

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


Means 15

Baker D (2013) Technology didn’t kill middle class jobs, public policy did. The Guardian, 26 November.
Ball S (2012) Global Education Inc: New Policy Networks and Neoliberal Imaginary. New York: Routledge.
Becker G (1964) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bellamy Foster J and McChesney R (2012) The Endless Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Blua A (2012) ‘An economic time bomb’: The world’s unemployed youth. The Atlantic.
Bourdieu P and Passeron J (1977) Reproduction in Education, Society, and Culture. Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage.
Bowles H and Gintis S (1975) The problem with human capital: A Marxian critique. American Economic
Association 65(2): 74–82.
Bowles H and Gintis S (2011) Schooling in Capitalist America, 2nd edn. Chicago: Haymarket Books.
Brenner R (2006) The Economics of Global Turbulence. New York: Verso.
Brooks D (2012) The great divorce. New York Times, 30 January.
Brown P, Lauder H and Ashton D (2011) The Global Auction: The Broken Promises of Education, Jobs, and
Income. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Canadian Broadcasting Company (CBC) (2014) Generation jobless. Available at: http://www.cbc.ca/doc-
zone/episodes/generation-jobless (accessed 21 December 2014).
Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives (CCPA) (2013) The Young and the Jobless.
Cappelli P (2012) Why Good People Can’t Get Jobs: The Skill Gap and What Companies Can Do About It.
Philadelphia, PA: Wharton Digital Press.
Carnevale A and Rose S (2011) The Undereducated American. Washington, DC: Georgetown Public Policy
Institute. Available at: http://cew.georgetown.edu/undereducated (accessed 21 December 2014).
Cowen T (2013) Average Is Over: Powering America beyond the Age of the Great Stagnation. New York:
Dutton.
Coy P (2011) The Youth Unemployment Bomb. Bloomberg Business Week, 2 February.
De Lissovoy N (2008) Power, Crisis, and Education for Liberation. New York: Palgrave.
Finlayson J (2014) The plight of the overeducated worker. Troy Media. Available at: http://www.troymedia.
com/2014/01/13/the-plight-of-the-overeducated-worker/ (accessed 21 December 2014).
Frey CB and Osbourne MA (2013) The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerization?
Available at: http://www.oxfordmartin.ox.ac.uk/downloads/academic/The_Future_of_Employment.pdf
(accessed 21 December 2014).
Friedman T (2007) The World Is Flat. New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux.
Galbraith JK (2014) The End of Normal: The Great Crisis and the Future of Growth. New York: Simon and
Schuster.
Goldin C and Katz R (2008) The Race between Education, Technology, and Labor. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Gordon R (2012) Is U.S. Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronting Six Headwinds (Working Paper,
August). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Graeber D (2013) On the phenomenon of bullshit jobs. Strike Magazine, 17 August.
Harvey D (1991) The Condition of Postmodernity. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.
Harvey D (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Harvey D (2007) The Limits to Capital. New York: Verso.
Harvey D (2010) A Companion to Marx’s Capital. New York: Verso.
Harvey D (2014) Seventeen Contradictions and the End of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2013) Global employment trends for youth in 2013: A genera-
tion in crisis. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/global/research/globalreports/global-employment-trends/
youth/2013/lang–en/index.htm (accessed 10 October 2014)
Krugman P (2011) Degrees and dollars. New York Times, 6 March.
Krugman P (2013) A permanent slump? New York Times, 17 November.
Livingstone DW (1995) Searching for missing links: Neo-Marxist theories of education. British Journal of
Sociology of Education 16(1): 53–73.
Livingstone DW (2009) Education and Jobs: Exploring the Gaps. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Madrick J (2013) The real lost generation. Harper’s Magazine, December.

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016


16 Critical Sociology 

Marx K (1992[1867]) Capital: Volume 1: A Critique of Political Economy. New York: Vintage Books.
Mason P (2012) Why Is It Kicking Off Everywhere: The New Global Revolutions. New York: Verso.
McNally D (2009) Global Slump: The Economics and Politics of Crisis and Resistance. Oakland, CA: PM
Press.
Means AJ (2013a) Schooling in the Age of Austerity: Urban Education and the Struggle for Democratic Life.
New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Means AJ (2013b) Creativity and the biopolitical commons in secondary and higher education. Policy Futures
in Education 11(1): 47–58.
Means AJ (2014) Beyond the poverty of national security: Toward a critical human security perspective in
educational policy. Journal of Education Policy 29(2): 719–741.
Murray C (2010) Coming Apart: The State of White America, 1960–2010. New York: Crown Forum.
Nasser A (2014) The alternative to long-term austerity: Less work, higher wages: No longer a mere possibil-
ity. Counterpunch, 3–5 October.
Newfield C (2008) Unmaking the Public University: The Forty-Year Assault on the Middle Class. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
OECD (2014) Education at a glance. Available at: http://www.keepeek.com/DigitalAsset-Management/oecd/
education/education-at-a-glance-2014_eag_highlights-2014en#page19 (accessed 21 December 2014).
Olssen M and Peters MA (2005) Neoliberalism, higher education, and the knowledge economy: From the free
market to knowledge capitalism. Journal of Education Policy 20(3): 313–335.
Pierce C (2012) Education in the Age of Biocapitalism: Optimizing Educational Life for a Flat World. New
York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Peralta K (2014) College grads taking low-wage jobs displace less educated. Bloomberg, 8 March.
Reich R (2012) Beyond Outrage: What Has Gone Wrong with Our Economy and Democracy and How to Fix
It. New York: Vintage.
Rikowski G (1997) Scorched earth: Prelude to rebuilding a Marxist educational theory. British Journal of the
Sociology of Education 18(4): 551–574.
Saltman K (2012) The Failure of Corporate School Reform. New York: Paradigm.
Salzman H, Kuehn D and Lowell L (2013) Guest workers in the high-skill labor market. Washington, DC:
Economic Policy Institute. Available at: http://www.epi.org/publication/bp359-guestworkers-high-skill-
labor-marketanalysis/ (accessed 20 December 2014).
Shierholz H, Sabadish N and Finio N (2013) The class of 2013: Young graduates face dim job prospects.
Available at: http://www.epi.org/publication/class-of-2013graduatesjob-prospects/ (accessed 15 June
2014).
Slater G (2014) Education as recovery: Neoliberalism, school reform, and the politics of crisis. Journal of
Education Policy (DOI: 10.1080/02680939.2014.904930).
Sorenson C and Gillis C (2013) The new underclass: Why a generation of well-educated, ambitious, smart
young Canadians has no future. Macleans, 16 January.
Standing G (2011) The Precariat: The New Dangerous Class. London: Bloomsbury.
Stiglitz J (2012) The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers our Future. New York:
W.W. Norton.
Streeck W (2014) How will capitalism end? New Left Review 87 (May–June): 35–64.
Summers L (2014) U.S. economic prospects: Secular stagnation, hysteresis, and the zero lower bound.
Business Economics 49(2): 65–73.
Therborn G (2013) The Killing Fields of Inequality. Malden, MA: Polity.
Venn D (2013) Generation jobless: Young Canadians overeducated and unemployed. Vital Signs.
Available at: http://www.vitalsignscanada.ca/en/news-356-generation-joblessyoung-canadians-
overeducated (accessed 21 December 2014).
Wacquant L (2009) Punishing the Poor: The Neoliberal Government of Social Insecurity. Durham, NC: Duke
University Press.
Wilkinson R and Pickett K (2009) The Spirit Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Societies Stronger. New
York: Bloomsbury Press.
Wolffe R (2012) Democracy at Work: A Cure for Capitalism. Chicago: Haymarket Books.
Wright EO (2010) Envisioning Real Utopias. New York: Verso.

Downloaded from crs.sagepub.com at KoBSON on August 30, 2016

You might also like