You are on page 1of 61

lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Summary A Survey of Corporate Governance by Shleifer


Vishny
Corporate Governance and Restructuring (Maastricht University)

StuDocu is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university


Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)
lOMoARcPSD|3637180

A  survey  of  Corporate  Governance  -­‐  Shleifer  &  Vishny  


 
I.  Agency  Problem  
1)  Contract  between  management  and  financiers  
-­‐  Complete  contracts  for  managers  are  infeasible  
-­‐  problem  of  allocation  of  rights  
-­‐  enforcement  by  outside  courts:  business  judgment  rule  often  keeps  courts  out  of  companies'  affairs  
-­‐  even  if  investors  have  the  right  to  interfere,  they  often  lack  knowledge,  information,  size  (in  case  of  
small  investors)  to  do  so  
 
2)  Management  discretion  
-­‐>  managers  end  up  with  significant  control  rights  (discretion)  over  how  to  allocate  investors'  funds  
-­‐  managers  act  for  their  own  benefits  
-­‐  simple  cash  out:  steal  money  and  run  away  
-­‐  transfer  pricing:  managers  sell  assets,  etc.  to  independent  companies  they  own  themselves  at  
below  market  prices  
-­‐  use  funds  for  less  direct  personal  benefits  such  as  perquisites  
-­‐  expanding  company  beyond  what  is  rational  
-­‐  managers  stay  on  the  job  even  if  they  are  no  longer  competent  or  qualified  to  run  the  firm  
(costly)/managers  resist  to  getting  replaced  
-­‐  "duty  of  loyalty"  to  shareholders;  violated  if  investors  would  'bribe'  managers  not  to  take  inefficient  
actions    
 
3)  Incentive  contracts  
-­‐  align  manager's  interests  with  those  of  the  investors  
-­‐  possible  forms:  stock  options,  share  ownership,  threat  of  dismissal  
-­‐  optimal  incentive  contract  determined  by  manager's  risk  aversion,  importance  of  his  decisions,  
ability  to  pay  for  cash  flow  ownership  up  front  
-­‐  problem:  incentive  contracts  create  enormous  self-­‐dealing  opportunities    
-­‐>  managers  might  negotiate  for  such  contracts  in  situations  where  they  will  benefit  from  it  
example:  before  an  announcement  that  will  very  likely  raise  stock  price,  a  manager  has  a  strong  
incentive  to  negotiate  for  a  contract  that  grants  him  stock  options  
 
4)  Evidence  of  agency  costs  
-­‐  managerial  decisions  might  reflect  personal  interest  rather  than  those  of  investors:  reinvest  instead  
of  returning  free  cash  to  investors  
examples:  diversification,  growth  are  rather  managerial  objectives  than  to  shareholders  
-­‐  evidence:  trades  of  shares  with  superior  voting  rights  for  a  premium  
 
II  .  Financing  without  Governance  
-­‐  possible  reasons  for  possibility  of  financing  without  Governance:  managers  and  firms  have  
reputation,  excessive  optimism  of  investors  
-­‐  reputation  might  make  managers  deliver  on  their  agreements  even  if  they  can't  be  forced    
-­‐  motivation  for  managers:  acquire  ability  to  raise  funds  in  the  future  
 
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

III.  Legal  protection  


-­‐  differences  of  corporate  governance  systems  stem  from  the  difference  in  nature  of  legal  obligations  
of  managers  to  their  financiers  as  well  as  in  the  difference  how  courts  interpret  and  enforce  these  
obligations  
-­‐  most  important  legal  right  of  shareholders:  voting  
-­‐  Stalin:  "It  is  important  not  how  people  vote,  but  who  counts  the  votes"  
-­‐>  how  are  voting  rights  protected  by  courts?  
-­‐  effectiveness  of  boards:  corporate  boards  might  be  captured  by  management  
-­‐  OECD  adopted  idea  of  management's  "duty  of  loyalty"  to  shareholders  
-­‐  "duty  of  loyalty"  main  elements:  legal  restriction  on  self-­‐dealing  and  issues  of  additional  securities  
(such  as  equity)  to  management  and  its  relatives  
-­‐  bankruptcy  process  often  very  complicated:  multitude  diverse  creditors  -­‐>  very  costly,  takes  years  
to  complete,  creditors  often  renegotiate  outside  of  formal  bankruptcy  proceedings^  
 
IV.  Large  investors  
1)  Large  investors  
-­‐  most  direct  way  to  align  cash  flow  and  control  rights  of  outside  investors  
-­‐  incentive  to  collect  information  and  monitor  management  because  easier  access  to  disciplining  
actions  (large  investors  or  concentration  of  minority  shareholders  have  more  power)  
-­‐  effectiveness  of  large  investors,  who  govern  via  their  voting  rights,  is  depending  on  the  legal  
protection  of  those  rights  
 
2)  Takeovers  
-­‐  rapid-­‐fire  mechanism  for  ownership  concentration  
-­‐  management  controlled  by  possibility  of  takeover  (in  the  course  of  which  it  would  get  replaced)  
-­‐  problems:  sufficient  expensiveness  leads  to  addressing  of  only  major  performance  failures  
-­‐  problem:  increase  of  agency  costs  (bidding  management  might  want  to  take  over  for  private  
benefits  of  control  and  thus  overpay)  
-­‐  problem:  liquid  capital  market  as  requirement  as  vast  amount  of  capital  is  needed  on  short  notice  
(junk  bond  financing)  
-­‐  problem:  opposition  by  managerial  lobbies  (political  pressure  led    to  anti-­‐takeover  legislation)  
 
3)  Large  Creditors  
-­‐  banks!!  
-­‐  variety  of  control  rights  when  firm  defaults  or  violates  debt  covenants  (which  are  easy  observe  and  
assess  by  courts)  
-­‐  powerful  because  banks  typically  lend  short  term  -­‐>  borrowers  have  to  come  back  at  short,  regular  
intervals  for  more  funds  
-­‐  large  creditors  often  combine  substantial  cash  flow  rights  and  ability  to  interfere  in  the  major  
decisions  of  the  firm  
-­‐  often  banks  end  up  with  holding  equity  and  debt  of  firms  -­‐>  similar  to  large  investors,  though  with  
better  legal  protection  (or  rather,  their  rights  are  easier  to  enforce)  
 
V.  Cost  of  large  investors  
-­‐  problem:  large  investors  are  not  diversified  (obvious,  but  not  so  important)  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

-­‐  problem:  large  investor  represent  own  interest  that  does  not  necessarily  coincide  with  other  
investors,  employees,  management  
-­‐  problem:  inefficient  expropriation  through  pursuit  of  personal  (nonprofit-­‐maximizing)  
-­‐  problem:  incentive  effects  of  expropriation  on  other  stakeholders  (expropriation  might  make  
management,  employees  reduce  their  firm-­‐specific  human  capital  investments)  
-­‐  problem:  expropriation  of  other  investors,  employees,  managers  (large  investor  might  treat  herself  
at  expense  of  other  people  involved  through  special  dividends  or  exploiting  other  business  
relationships  with  companies  they  control)  
-­‐  evidence:  relationship  between  shares  with  superior  voting  rights  (equals  significant  private  
benefits  of  control)  and  expropriation  of  minorities  
-­‐  large  investors  get  too  powerful  resulting  of  them  exploiting  the  firms  they  control  
-­‐  problem  might  be  weakened  due  to  the  fact  that  the  large  investor  might  have  its  own  agency  
problems  
 
VI.  Specific  governance  arrangements  
1)  Debt  VS  Equity  
-­‐  equity  is  difficult  to  valuate,  so  investors  valuate  debt  (or  rather  the  collateral)  
-­‐  debt  can  be  seen  as  a  contract  that  gives  the  creditor  the  right  to  repossess  collateral  in  case  of  a  
default/bad  state  
-­‐  benefit:  reduction  of  agency  costs,  such  as  preventing  managers  from  investing  in  negative  NPV  
projects  or  forcing  managers  to  sell  assets  that  worth  more  in  alternative  use  
-­‐  main  cost  of  debt:  firms  may  be  prevented  from  undertaking  good  projects  because  of  debt  
covenants  keep  them  from  raising  additional  funds  
-­‐  debt  -­‐>  concentrated  ownership?!  
-­‐  legal  protection  of  creditors  is  generally  better  than  of  equity  holders  
-­‐  BUT:  concentrated  equity  (possibly  equals  direct  control  over  firm)  can  be  more  powerful  than  
concentrated  debt  
-­‐  equity  holders  have  ability  to  extract  some  payments  from  management  in  form  of  dividends  
(equity  holders  can  threaten  managers  to  vote  for  fire  them  or  liquidate  the  firm  -­‐>  management  
pays  dividends  to  hold  them  off)  
-­‐  dividends  for  equity  equals  interest  for  debt  
-­‐  equity  ownership/financing  common  for  young  companies  or  firms  with  intangible  assets  
-­‐  mature  economies/firms  typically  use  bank  financing  
-­‐  question:  how  can  firms  raise  equity  financing?  reputational  effects,  excessive  returns,  speculative  
bubble,  investor  overoptimism    
 
2)  LBO  
-­‐  group  of  investors  (old  managers,  specialized  buyout  firm,  banks,  public  debt  holders)  buy  out  
minority  shareholders  -­‐>  concentrated  equity  ownership  -­‐>  reduction  of  agency  problems  -­‐>  increase  
in  profits  (targets  of  LBOs  often  highly  diversified  companies:  noncore  divisions  are  sold  shortly  after  
LBO)  
-­‐  principal  purpose  of  LBO:  temporary  financing  tool  for  implementation  of  drastic  short-­‐term  
improvements  
-­‐  BUT:  LBO  typically  not  permanent  organizations,  also  problems  of  heavily  concentrated  ownership  
 
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

3)  Cooperatives  and  state  ownership  


-­‐  possible  alternative  to  counter  problems  of  concentrated  ownership:  cooperatives,  state  ownership  
-­‐  BUT:  in  reality  state  ownership  broadly  inconsistent  with  efficiency  argument  (1.  state  firms  do  not  
appear  to  serve  public  interest  better;  2.  state  firms  are  typically  extremely  inefficient  and  their  
losses  result  in  huge  drains  on  their  countries'  treasuries)  
-­‐  bureaucrats  end  up  having  extremely  concentrated  control  rights,  but  their  interests  are  mostly  
dictated  by  political  interests;  at  best  only  indirectly  concerned  about  profits  
-­‐>  wave  of  privatization  
-­‐  common  problem  of  privatization:  no  large  investor  is  created  leaving  managers  with  more  
discretion  
 
VII.  Which  system  is  best?  
1)  Legal  protection  and  large  investors  
-­‐  legal  protection  of  investors  (voting  rights,  power  to  pull  collateral;  large  investors  as  well  as  
minority  shareholders)  and  some  form  of  concentrated  ownership  essential  
 
2)  Evolution  of  governance  systems  
-­‐  political  pressure  plays  an  equally  important  role  in  the  evolution  of  governance  systems  as  
economic  pressure  
-­‐    legal  systems  have  developed  to  accommodate  the  prevailing  power  (e.g.  banks  in  Germany,  Japan)  
-­‐    no  conclusion  about  which  is  the  most  efficient  system  
 
3)  What  kind  of  large  investors?  
-­‐  US  style  takeovers  (LBO)  or  more  permanent  large  shareholders  (Germany,  Japan)?  
-­‐  contra  US  style:  impose  short  horizons  on  the  behavior  of  corporate  managers,  reduced  efficiency  
of  investment  
-­‐  pro  US  style:  more  radical,  possibly  effective  restructuring  of  economy;  due  to  extensive  legal  
protection  of  small  investors,  young  firms  are  able  to  raise  capital  in  the  stock  market  better  than  
everywhere  else  
-­‐  contra  permanent  large  shareholders/bank  system:  banks  are  not  really  tough  in  corporate  
governance;  large-­‐investor-­‐oriented  governance  system  discourages  small  investors  from  
participating  in  financial  markets  
 
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Using  Project  Finance  to  Fund  Infrastructure  Investments                      Brealey,  Cooper  &  Habib  (1996)  

Project  Finance  as  a  Response  to  Agency  Problems  

• Agency   problems   arise   from   the   differing   and   sometimes   conflicting   interests   of   the   various  
parties  involved  in  any  large  enterprise    
• In  order  to  solve  this  problem,  all  parties  must  be  provided  with  incentives  to  work  together  for  
the  common  good  –  to  a  certain  extent  this  can  be  achieved  by  a  company’s  financial  structure  
o Managers   taking   equity   stakes   in   their   company   as   one   solution   to   the   agency   problem  –  
exposing  the  manager  to  part  of  the  business’  risk  (inventive  creation  and  transfer  of  risk  
from  the  shareholder  to  the  manager)  
o A   problem   coming   along   with   this,   is   that   managers   generally   are   not   diversified   –   unlike  
shareholders   –   and   hence,   managers   require   higher   returns   for   bearing   this   risk   (this  
method  is  beneficial  ONLY  to  the  extent  that  it  improves  EFFICIENCY)  
 
• In   Project   Finance,   a   complex   series   and   financing   arrangements   divides   the   different   risks  
associated  with  the  project  among  various  parties  involved  in  the  project  
o These   transfers   of   risk   might   not   be   advantageous   in   themselves   but   have   important  
incentive  effects  

Ownership,  Capital  Structure,  and  Incentives  

• The  reason  for  the  contractual  arrangements  is  to  ensure  that  a  project  company  is  not  exposed  
to  an  abuse  of  monopoly  power,  and  to  provide  all  parties  to  the  project  with  the  incentives  to  
act  efficiently  by  transferring  the  risk  of  poor  performance  to  those  best  able  to  manage  it  
• Since   there   is   a   limit   on   how   much   can   be   written   in   such   contracts   and   how   efficiently   these   can  
be  monitored,  contractual  arrangements  are  complemented  by  financing  arrangements  
o The   equity   holdings   that   the   contractor   and   the   operator   have   in   the   project   company  
provide  them  with  an  incentive  to  be  efficient  by  making  them  residual  claimants  whose  
profits  depend  on  how  well  the  project  facility  is  built  and  operated  
• Generally,  project  companies  are  highly  leveraged  –  average  debt-­‐ratio  is  around  60%  
o Such   leverage   is   used   even   though   there   is   a   shortage   of   potential   lenders   for   project  
finance   and   that   it   is   costly   to   structure   the   project   to   make   these   high   debt   ratios  
possible  
o Lenders   lend   directly   to   the   project   company   rather   than   to   the   sponsors   &   they   have  
only  limited  recourse  to  the  sponsors  in  case  of  default  by  the  project  company  
• Modigliani  &  Miller  
o In  perfectly  competitive  markets,  company  value  would  be  independent  of    the  degree  of  
leverage;   value   cannot   be   enhanced   simply   by   concentrating   debt   in   a   subsidiary   or   an  
associated  company  
o The   total   CF   to   all   security   holders   is   independent   of   whether   debt   is   located   in   a   project  
company  or  in  its  parent  company  

The  Impact  of  PF  in  an  M&M  World  

• Under   M&M,   project   finance   does   not   affect   the   total   value   of   the   firm   and   project   finance   can  
potentially  affect  value  when  debt  default  is  costly  
• In  a  M&M  world  w/o  taxes,  PF  has  no  impact  on  the  total  value  of  the  firm  (total  CFs  are  identical  
for  traditional  finance  projects  and  project  finance  projects)  
• In   a   complete   securities   market,   this   guarantees   that   the   total   firm   value   is   independent   of   the  
way  that  financial  claims  on  the  firm  are  structured  
• Project  Finance  rearranges  the  states  of  the  world  in  which  default  occurs  –  thus,  PF  can  change  
the  associated  costs  of  default  
 
• Many  of  these  explanations  are  related  to  the  incompleteness  of  contracts:  
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

a) Bankruptcy  Costs  
• Total   CFs   to   investors   are   independent   of   whether   the   firm   employs   project   financing  
when   bankruptcy   costs   are   assumed   to   be   zero   (as   in   an   M&M   world)   –   however,   PF  
changes  the  states  of  the  world  in  which  the  debt  is  in  default  (from  stage  1,2,3  to  stage  
1,3,5)  –  thus,  PF  changes  the  expected  costs  of  default  
• Projects  undertaken  by  project  companies  usually  have  low  bankruptcy  costs  since  their  
assets  are  largely  tangible  assets  which  are  largely  unscathed  in  case  of  bankruptcy  
• The  low  cost  of  bankruptcy  for  these  companies  may  thus  explain  why  project  companies  
carry  heavy,  non-­‐recourse  debt  loads  
b) Taxes  
• Only  when  a  project  is  located  in  a  high-­‐tax  country,  the  project  company  however  is  in  a  
lower-­‐tax   country,   the   sponsor   may   benefit   from   locating   the   debt   in   the   high-­‐tax    
country  –  thus  decreasing  the  company’s  tax  shield  
• Nevertheless,  this  doesn’t  explain  why  debt  has  limited  recourse  nor  does  it  explain  the  
debt  concentration  once  the  sponsor  and  the  project  company  are  located  in  the  same  
country  
c) Myopia  
• Some   arguments   for   placing   the   debt   in   the   project   company   assume   that   lenders   are  
blinkered  –  PF  allows  the  debt  to  be  off-­‐Balance-­‐Sheet  to  the  sponsors  
• However,  it  is  doubtful  that  lenders  are  misled  by  such  strategems  
d) Political  Risk  
• Need  for  financing  arrangements  that  make  it  difficult  for  the  government  to  take  actions  
that  may  render  the  project  unprofitable  
• This  can  be  achieved  by  arranging  for  the  host  government  to  take  equity  in  the  project  
or  to  create  an  extensive  reliance  on  limited  recourse  financing  
• Protection   against   political   risk   may   go   far   towards   explaining   the   debt   structure   of  
project  companies  in  developing  countries  –  it  does  not  explain  why  projects  in  politically  
stable  countries  are  also  heavily  levered  
e) Information  Costs  
• The  granting  of  a  loan  clearly  requires  that  lenders  evaluate  the  creditworthiness  of  the  
borrower  and  monitor  his  use  of  the  assets  financed  by  the  loan  
• A  possible  benefit  of  PF  (and  the  associated  lack  of  recourse)  is  that  it  allows  lenders  to  
the  project  to  confine  their  evaluation  and  monitoring  to  the  project  only  and  saves  them  
from  having  to  evaluate  and  monitor  sponsors  as  well  
f) Free  Cash  Flow  
• Leverage  ensures  that  cash  is  needed  to  service  debt  (and  is  not  frittered  away,  e.g.  by  
investing  in  negative  NPV  projects  as  argued  by  Michael  Jensen)  
• Thus   heavy   debt   financing   can   provide   stronger   incentives   both   to   generate   more   cash  
and  to  pay  out  what  cash  cannot  be  profitably  reinvested  in  the  company  

Conclusion  

• There  are  two  reasons  why  the  allocation  of  debt  could  matter:  
1. The  parent  companies   may   find   it   difficult   or   costly   to   monitor   the   efficiency   with   which   cash  
is  used  within  the  project  company,  and  thus,  cannot  prevent  the  waste  of  FCF  
2. When  there  is  more  than  one  parent  company,  the  owners  may  have  different  views  about  
how   to   use   cash   –   by   ensuring   that   CFs   are   used   to   repay   debt,   such   disagreements   are  
avoided  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Political   Risk,   Development   Banks   and   the   Choice   of   Recourse   in  


Syndicated  Lending  
 
Christina  Hainz  
Stefanie  Kleimeier  
 
 
Abstract:    
• How  to  design  loan  contracts  for  project  finance  in  countries  with  high  political  
risk  
o Limited  recourse  loans  and  
o participation  of  development  banks  mitigate  political  risks  
• Terms   of   the   loan   contract   depend   on   the   political   risk   as   well   as   the   legal   and  
institutional  environment  
 
 
2.  The  Impact  of  Political  Risk  and  Law  &  Institutions  on  the  Loan  Contract  
 
2.1  Features  of  the  loan  contract  
• Generally  a  loan  contract  contains  risk  management  measures  in  order  to  reduce  
the  risk  of  the  lender  (bank)  in  order  to  minimize  the  probability  of  default,  loss  
or  both  
• Two  important  measures  are:  
o Which  legal  entity  receives  the  loan  (i.e.  how  is  the  contact  structured)?    
à  Limited  recourse  project  finance  loans  
o Is   a   development   bank   participating  
à  Participation  of  development  banks  
 
Limited  recourse  project  finance  loans  
• Parties  involved  in  the  loan  may  create  a  legally  independent  project  company:  
o Equity  financing  from  one  or  more  of  the  sponsoring  firms  
o Debt   financing   through   the   bank   loans   to   the   independent   company  
à  ensures  that  liability  is  limited  to  independent  firm,  lenders  have  no  or  
only  limited  recourse  to  sponsors  (=limited  recourse  loan)  
• Project   finance   loans   are   set   up   with   several   contractual   agreements   with  
different  parties:  
o Specific  risks  (completion,  operating,  revenue,  price…  risks)  are  allocated  
to   those   parties   who   are   best   able   to   manage   them  
à   reduction   of   project   risk,   agency   cost   and   increases   transparency  
about  the  project  
 
 
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Participation  of  development  banks  


• Structures  of  syndicates  are  used  to  reduce  risk  
• A  particularly  important  part  of  the  syndicate  are  development  banks  (DB)  
o DB’s  have  special  status  
o Help  mitigate  risk  associated  with  government  policies  and  practices  
o DBs  are  known  as  political  umbrellas  
o International  Finance  Corporation  (World  Bank  Group)  is  known  to  have  
high  bargaining  power  because:  
• Provide  financial  aid  and  finance  many  projects  
• frequently  interact  with  governments  
 
è  Limited  recourse  PF  loans  and  DBs  are  used  to  mitigate  political  and  other  country  
related  risks.  
 
2.2  Country-­‐level  risks  
Political  risk  
• Political   risk   (PR)   is   very   important   factor   influencing   probability   that   a   loan   is  
serviced  as  scheduled.  
• Three  broad  categories:  
o Traditional  PR  
Risks  related  to    
§ expropriation  
§ currency  convertibility  and  transferability  
§ political  violence  
o Regulatory  risk  
Risks  arising  from  unanticipated  regulatory  changes    
§ Changes  in  taxation    
§ Changes  in  foreign  investment  laws  
o Quasi-­‐commercial  risk  
Risks  that  arise  when  project  contends  with  state-­‐owned  suppliers  or  
customers  à  ability  or  willingness  to  fulfill  contractual  obligations  
towards  project  is  questionable  
• PR  comprises  broad  range  of  risks  with  different  attributes:  
o Some   are   easy   to   identify   ex   post   (changes   in   transferability)   some   are  
not  (changes  in  tax  law)  
o Some   are   closely   related   to   individual   business   (expropriation,   regulatory  
changes)   some   apply   to   whole   society   but   have   impact   on   business  
(corruption)  
è  Investment  related  PR,  General  PR  
 
How  to  deal  with  political  risk?  
• Project  finance  structure  
o Financial  flows  become  highly  transparent  for  loans  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o Cash  flows  become  verifiable,  government  interventions  become  visible  


à   This   applies   to   investment   related   PR.   General   PR   cannot   be   mitigated  
through  project  finance  structure.  
• Participation  of  DBs  
o Help  mitigate  both  investment  related  and  general  political  risk  
o Provide   political   umbrella   since   they   interact   frequently   with   different  
government  bodies  
o If  government  wants  to  intervene  in  project  (negatively),  participation  of  
DB  can  
• use  special  status  to  mitigate  problems  
• influence  government’s  decision  as  the  government  thinks  about  
its  reputation  at  DB  after  intervening  in  project  and  may  therefore  
not  intervene  
 
• ICRG   (International   Country   risk   guide)   provides   various   measures   of   political  
risk:  
bureaucracy   quality,   corruption,   democratic   accountability,   ethnic   tensions,  
external   conflict,   government   stability,   internal   conflict,   investment   profile,   law  
and  order,  military  in  politics,  religious  tensions,  socioeconomic  conditions  
 
Law  and  Institutions  
Legal   and   institutional   risks   (LIR)   are   highlighted   as   important   risks   for   loan   contract  
designing,  which  can  be  managed  by  two  characteristics  of  project  finance:  
• high  transparency  of  cash  flows  
• limited  recourse  
 
Therefore  
• Through  separate  legal  entity  and  the  fact  that  it  is  heavily  financed  by  debt  
management  commits  itself  to  monitoring  
• Transparent  financial  flows  influence  managers  behavior  
 
è  project  finance  can  influence  incentives  if  legal  and  institutional    environment  are  
not  able  to  shape  them    
 
In  contrast  to  mitigating  political  risk  DBs  have  difficulties  addressing  problem  in  legal  
and  institutional  environments.  Legal  provisions  in  corporate  law  can  not  be  easily  
changed;  implementation  of  law  is  often  difficult  and  very  hard  to  address  for  DBs  
 
In  their  analysis  they  capture  two  different  aspects  of  law  and  institutions:  
• The  country’s  corporate  governance  system  (legal  protection  of  shareholder  
minorities  etc.)  
• The  country’s  creditor  rights  (in  case  of  default)  
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Other  country  level  control  variables  


Next  to  the  risks  mentioned  above  other  factors  can  be  included  to  model  e.g.:  
• Legal  enforcement  
• country  risk  
• corruption  
• financial  or  economic  development  
 
3.  Data  and  Methodology  
Data  is  retrieved  from  Dealscan  Database.  Methodology  is  simple  regression.  No  new  
formulas  etc...  
4.  Results  
4.1.  The  use  of  Project  Finance  and  the  Participation  of  DBs  
• PF  most  important  in  Africa  and  Middle  East  
• PF  loans  fund  assets  in  countries  that  are  politically  riskier,  have  weaker  
corporate  governance  systems,  stronger  creditor  rights  and  are  of  equal  
economic  performance  
• DBs  invest  in  countries  with  high  political  risk,  weaker  corporate  governance,  
similar  creditor  rights  and  poorer  economic  performance.  
• Full  recourse  loans  without  DBs  fund  investments  in  countries  that  are  politically  
safer,  strong  corporate  governance,  strong  economic  perf.  and  similar  creditor  
rights.  
• DBs  have  no  preference  to  project  finance  and  full  recourse  loans  
 
4.2.  Relevance  of  Political  Risk  and  Law  &  Institutions  
• Higher  political  risk  à  PF  is  correlated  to  corporate  governance  and  creditor  
rights,  unrelated  to  economic  performance  and  legal  origin  (French/German)  
• Better  Corporate  Governance  à  PF  correlated  to  political  risk  and  corporate  
governance,  less  related  to  creditor  rights  
• Lower  Corporate  Governance  à  PF  is  more  likely  since  framework  of  project  
finance  can  substitute  weak  legal  environments  (2.2)  
• PF  is  used  for  riskier  investments  with  longer  life  
 
• Higher  political  risk  à  probability  of  DB  participation  is  increased.  Indicates  that  
DBs  provide  political  umbrella  
 
• PF  is  used  to  manage  investment  related  PR  
• Multinational  DB  participation  is  used  to  manage  general  PR  
• National  DB  participation  is  used  to  manage  investment  related  PR  
 
5.  Conclusion  
From  the  study  authors  derive  following  suggestions:  
• If  investment  related  PR  is  high,  project  finance  structure  as  well  as  DB  
participation  can  reduce  the  risk  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• If  general  PR  is  high,  best  way  to  deal  with  it  is  to  have  DB  in  syndicate  
• The  study  contributes  that  not  only  law  and  institutions  influence  the  loan  
contract  but  also  political  risk.  In  their  variables  PR  is  actually  even  more  
important  
• With  respect  to  law  and  institutions  the  use  of  project  finance  decreases  for  
better  corporate  governance  provisions  and  increases  for  better  creditor  rights.  
In  contrast  participation  of  development  banks  is  not  correlated  with  the  legal  
and  institutional  environment.  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Project  Finance  as  a  driver  of  economic  growth  in  low-­‐income  countries      Kleimeier  &  Versteeg  

Hypothesis  that  project  finance  (PF)  is  beneficial  to  the  least  developed  economies  as  it  is  able  to  compensate  
for   a   lack   of   domestic   financial   development.   The   contractual   structure   unique   to   PF   improves   investment  
management   and   governance.     Results   show   that   PF   fosters   economic   growth   and   that   its   effect   is   strongest   in  
low-­‐income  countries,  where  financial  development  and  governance  is  weakest   (and  transaction  costs  are  high)  
(investigation  of  90  countries  between  1991  and  2005).  

Introduction  

• Financial  development  leads  not  only  to  an  increase  in  the  quantity  of  capital  but  –  more  importantly  –  
also   to   an   improvement   in   the   quality   of   capital.   It   is   through   the   quality   of   capital   that   finance  
contributes  to  growth  
• PF   with   its   contractual   structure   can   substitute   for   underdeveloped   financial   markets   and   thus   the  
authors   perceive   PF   as   a   high-­‐quality   financial   instrument   that   leads   to   better   investment  
management  and  governance  and,  ultimately,  to  more  economic  growth  
• PF   is   designed   to   reduce   transaction   costs,   especially   those   arising   from   a   lack   of   information   on  
possible   investments   and   capital   allocation,   insufficient   monitoring   and   enforcement   of   corporate  
governance,  risk  management  etc.  
• Increase  in  annual  growth  by  0.67  percentage  points  in  low-­‐income  countries  can  be  observed  

Financial  development,  project  finance  and  economic  growth  

Theory  and  Evidence  on  the  finance-­‐growth  nexus  

• Generally,  financial  markets  can  stimulate  the  quality  of  capital  in  several  ways  [Levine]:  
a. Well-­‐developed   markets   improve   resource   allocation   and   allow   easier   access   to   capital   for  
entrepreneurs,  thus  lowering  their  financial  constraints  and  financing  costs  
è Ex-­‐ante  information  production  and  the  efficient  allocation  of  capital  
b. Financial   markets   play   a   vital   role   in   CG   by   dealing   with   agency   costs   and   informational  
asymmetries  
è Ex-­‐post  monitoring  of  investments  and  enforcing  CG  
c. Markets  facilitate  the  pooling  and  sharing  of  risks  (diversification)  
è The  facilitation  of  diversification  and  the  management  of  risk  
d. Markets  mobilize  and  pool  savings  
è The  mobilization  and  pooling  of  savings  
e. They   ease   the   exchange   of   goods   and   services   –   empirical   evidence   supports   the   view   that  
financial  markets  stimulate  economic  growth  
è The  facilitation  of  transactions  
• Guidelines  on  how  to  develop  financial  markets  when  they  are  still  nascent:  
a. Import  capital  from  abroad  
a. It   can   supplement   low   levels   of   domestic   capital   stocks,   lower   the   cost   of   capital   and  
increase  the  scope  of  risk  diversification  
b. The  quality  matters  –  not  the  quantity  –  an  economy  should  first  focus  on  relatively  safe  
capital  flows  before  benefiting  from  riskier  types  of  capital  

Which  types  of  ‘safe’  capital  are  suitable  for  emerging  markets?  

a) Portfolio   equity   investments:   they   are   known   to   reduce   the   cost   of   capital   for   domestic   firms,  
increase   risk   sharing   and   stimulate   the   improvement   of   CG   –   BUT   a   country   can   only   receive   equity  
inflows  if  the  domestic  stock  market  is  well  developed  –  as  this  is  seldom  true  for  emerging  markets,  
this  puts  sever  limitations  on  the  use  of  international  equity  financing  
b) Foreign  Direct  Investment  (FDI):  it  is  a  long-­‐term  investment  which  minimizes  currency-­‐  and  maturity-­‐
mismatches;   it   is   further   beneficial   in   terms   of   transfers   of   technology,   managerial   skills   etc.  
Importantly,   FDI   does   not   rely   on   the   existence   of   a   well-­‐developed   domestic   financial   market   and  
firms   can   in   part   substitute   the   domestic   financial   market   through   FDI   –   a   firm   exerts   direct   control  
over   operations,   reduces   information   asymmetries   and   can   thus   alleviate   some   of   the   problems  
connected  with  inadequate  contract  enforcement  etc.  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

è FDI  has  been  found  to  have  a  positive  effect  on  economic  growth  –  however,  it  is  only  beneficial  if  a  
certain  threshold  of  development  in  the  country  has  been  reached;  in  an  environment  with  a  lack  of  
human  capital,  lack  of  institutions  etc.  these  positive  effects  can  all  be  hampered  
è FDI   only   has   a   positive   impact   on   high-­‐income   countries;   positive   effects   in   developing   countries   do  
not  materialize  

The  Growth-­‐enhancing  properties  of  project  finance  

• Project  Finance  defined  as  “the  creation  of  a  legally  independent  project  company  financed  with  equity  
from   one   or   more   sponsoring   firms   and   non-­‐recourse   debt   for   the   purpose   of   investing   in   a   capital  
asset”  [Esty]  
o Generally   used   for   new,   stand-­‐alone,   complex   projects   with   large   risks   and   massive  
informational  asymmetries  
• The  lead  banks  become  project  insiders  through  working  with  the  project  sponsors  during  the  initial  
screening  and  structuring  phase,  and  are  responsible  for  funding  the  loan  in  the  global  syndicated  loan  
market  by  attracting  other  banks  to  become  members  of  a  loan  syndicate  
• These  loans  are  non-­‐recourse  (they  finance  the  project  company  with  no  or  limited  support  from  the  
sponsors)   and   thus   the   syndicate   bears   much   of   the   project’s   business   risk   (given   the   project’s   high  
leverage,  business  risk  must  be  reduced  to  a  feasible  level)  
o This   is   the   main   advantage   of   PF   –   the   ability   to   allocate   specific   risks   to   those   parties   best  
able   to   manage   them   –   besides   the   financial   arrangements,   a   large   set   of   contractual  
arrangements  is  aimed  at  risk  management  
è Allows   PF   to   substitute   underdeveloped   financial   markets   hence,   functioning   relatively   well   in   the   least  
developed  countries  (LDCs)  
• ADVANTAGES:  
I. Improved  Resource  Allocation  and  decreased  cost  of  capital  
o PF  reduces  transaction  costs  as  a  syndicate  of  banks  provides  the  majority  of  the  funds  
and  delegates  the  major  screening  and  arranging  tasks  to  the  syndicate’s  lead  banks  
o PF   can   improve   the   efficiency   of   capital   allocation   as   it   targets   sectors   that   are  
bottlenecks  in  LDCs  
o Generally,   funds   for   large   capital   investments   in   developing   countries   are   often   only  
available  from  the  public  sector  –  BUT  they  lack  the  managerial  expertise    
§ PF  can  overcome  this  by  explicitly  taking  these  financing  needs  into  account  and  
by   transferring   the   management   to   the   private   sector   and   can   thus   lead   to   a  
more  effective  allocation  of  capital  
o Also   does   PF   reduce   the   agency   cost   of   underinvestment   caused   by   risky   debt   while  
increasing  the  value  of  the  tax  shield  of  debt  
o The   separation   of   the   project   from   the   sponsor   improves   the   transparency   of   the  
investment  thereby  making  it  easier  to  screen  
o Also  are  the  lead  banks  expected  to  have  superior  screening  skills  due  to  their  standing  as  
sophisticated  multinational  banks  and  in  some  cases  their  regional  specialization  
II. Monitoring  and  CG:  
o Separation   of   the   project   from   the   sponsoring   firm   improves   CG   as   management   is  
decentralized  and  project-­‐specific  incentives  are  created  for  managers  
o The  waste  of  FCFs  during  operation  is  reduced  due  to  high  leverage  and  the  inclusion  of  a  
cash-­‐waterfall  as  part  of  the  contractual  structure  
o The   extensive   contractual   structure   reduces   project   risk,   controls   agency   cost   and  
increases  transparency  about  the  project,  thereby  improving  CG  
o Legally,  if  local  legal  systems  are  not  well  developed,  it  is  possible  to  choose  for  example  
US  or  UK  law  for  the  finance  and  project  agreements  to  circumvent  problems  
o With   regards   to   political   risk,   PF   cannot   fully   mitigate   this   risk   but   there   is   some   evidence  
that   it   may   at   least   reduce   it   –   development   banks   are   especially   effective   in   reducing  
political   risk   since   they   are   acting   as   political   umbrellas   when   included   in   the   loan  
syndicate  [PF  is  the  preferred  financing  tool  in  countries  with  high  political  risk  and  poor  
CG]  
III. Cross-­‐Sectional  Diversification:  
o If  investors  cannot  diversify  cross-­‐sectional  risk,  then  savings  will  not  flow  towards  high-­‐
return  investments  which  can  boost  growth  –  PF  will  not  alter  the  risk  appetite  of  local  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

investors,  but  as  international  capital  it  is  not  limited  by  the  same  constraints  and  thus  
more   likely   than   domestic   capital   to   flow   to   the   above-­‐mentioned   growth-­‐enhancing  
projects  
IV. Inability  to  mobilize  and  pool  savings  and  to  facilitate  transactions:  
o PF   is   designed   to   deal   with   large   investments   and   syndicates   normally   consist   of   large  
(international)   banks   –   it   should   not   be   hindered   much   by   an   inability   to   pool   savings   nor  
by  an  inability  to  facilitate  transactions  
o PF   can   do   little   to   help   improve   the   market’s   ability   to   pool   domestic   savings   and  
facilitate  domestic  transactions  –  it  can  only  help  in  meeting  the  need  for  large  sums  of  
money  for  single  investments  which  cannot  be  met  by  domestically  pooled  savings  

Summary  

• PF  is  very  flexible  and  can  easily  be  adopted  to  different  economic  and  political  environments  
• Its  structure  enhances  ex-­‐ante  screening  and  ex-­‐post  corporate  governance  
• PF   is   well   suited   to   deal   with   political   risk   and   suffers   only   minimally   from   the   market’s   inability   to  
manage  risk,  pool  savings  or  facilitate  transactions  
 

Data  and  Methodology  

• Approach  of  using  a  neo-­‐classical  growth  framework:  these  models  presume  that  the  GDP  per  capita  
of   each   country   converges   towards   equilibrium   (assuming   that   a   country   is   not   at   its   steady   state   –  
hence,  transitional  dynamics  such  as  financial  development  are  important  determinants  for  economic  
growth)  
• The  Starting  Model:  
𝐺𝑅𝑂𝑊𝑇𝐻! = 𝛽! + 𝛽! ln 𝐼𝑁𝐼𝑇𝐼𝐴𝐿  𝐺𝐷𝑃! + 𝛽! 𝑃𝐹! + 𝛽! +! 𝑋!" + 𝜀!  
!
è Model   is   based   on   this   empirical   specification   mentioned   above   and   visualizes   growth   in   country   I   as   a  
function  of  initial  GDP,  project  Finance  PF  and  a  set  of  further  control  variables  X  
è The  selected  control  variables  X  include  schooling,  population  growth,  and  government  consumption  
è A   dummy   is   included   for   the   sub-­‐Saharan   countries   in   the   sample   to   account   for   the   stylized   finding  
that  growth  rates  are  systematically  lower  in  this  region  

in   the   extended   specification,   a   larger   set   of   control   variables   will   be   used,   measuring   also   economic,  
population-­‐related  and  institutional  characteristics  

• The   chosen   variables   are:   FDI   and   thus   measure   its   effect   on   growth   with   that   of   PF;   further  
investigate  the  effect  of  PF  on  growth  dependent  on  economic  development  of  the  recipient  countries  
è The  starting  equation  is  estimated  as  an  OLS  regression  for  a  panel  of  three  5-­‐year  periods;  to  control  
for  possible  endogeneity  we  also  estimate  a  3SLS  instrumental  variable  model  

Results  (Growth  and  PF)  

• When  comparing  the  annual  volume  of  newly  signed  PF  deals  in  real  US$  (2005),  it  becomes  clear  that  
the  use  of  PF  has  increased  over  time  from  $16bn  in  1991  to  just  ca.  $69bn  in  2005  
• While   the   total   numbers   are   substantial,   PF   is   relatively   small   in   comparison   to   the   GDP   of   the  
recipient   country   (size   of   new   PF   deals   in   most   years   less   than   0.01%   of   GDP,   in   countries   with   the  
highest  use  PF  deals  amount  to  0.2%  of  GDP)  
• FDI  inflows  are  normally  in  the  range  of  1%  and  5%  of  GDP  –  table  1  shows  a  remarkable  trend  
o High   growth   countries   raise   substantially   more   funds   in   form   of   PF   than   low-­‐growth  
countries;  also  do  these  countries  have  more  PF  inflows  than  both  low-­‐growth  countries  and  
the  average  country  in  the  sample  
è More  PF  is  associated  with  higher  growth  
 
• Although  total  PF  flows  are  substantial  and  large  growth  notwithstanding,  flows  of  PF  remain  rather  
small  relative  to  the  GDP  of  the  recipient  country  
• OLS   estimation   of   Equation   1   –   sample   of   90   countries   with   selected   control   variables   (schooling,  
population   growth,   government   consumption,   and   a   dummy   for   the   SSA   countries)   –   extended  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

regressions   are   added   institutional   quality   (law),   the   black   market   premium,   inflation   and   the   trade  
volume  (openness)  
• Generally,   initial   income   has   a   significant   negative   impact   on   growth,   indicating   that   (conditional)  
convergence   is   present;     sub-­‐Saharan   countries   and   countries   with   high   inflation   or   high   population  
growth   face   lower   GDP   growth,   while   more   schooling   and   a   better   rule   of   law   have   significant   positive  
effects  on  economic  growth  
• With   respect   to   PF,   the   main   results   show   that   PF   is   not   unambiguously   correlated   with   economic  
growth  –  although  positive,  PF  is    not  significantly  correlated  with  growth  
• PF   will   be   most   beneficial   in   LDCs   with   a   weak   domestic   financial   system   –   PF   is   only   significant  
contingent  on  the  host  country’s  economic  development  (income  level)  
è PF     has   a   positive   impact   on   growth,   but   the   effect   is   only   significant   for   the   low-­‐income   countries   and  
not  in  the  middle-­‐  and  high-­‐income  countries  

These   growth   effects   of   PF   might   be   driven   by   benefits   unique   to   PF   –   or   as   well   by   more   general  
spillovers  of  PF  as  foreign  capital  à  Include  a  measure  of  FDI  in  order  to  control  for  these  effects  

o While  a  high-­‐income  country  might  well  be  financed  by  a  syndicate  of  domestic  banks,  in  low-­‐
income  countries  the  syndicate  will  likely  be  dominated  by  foreign  banks  
è FDI  is  highly  significant  for  all  income  levels  and  PF  remains  significant  for  low-­‐income  countries  
è This   indicates   that   in   low-­‐income   countries   it   is   indeed   PF   with   its   unique   features   that   is   beneficial   to  
the  country’s  growth  

Robustness  Check  

• Results  are  robust  even  when  considering  for  endogeneity  


• When   excluding   all   observations   which   belong   to   the   top   5%   in   terms   of   PF   relative   to   GDP,   the  
findings  confirm  that  PF  is  a  driver  of  economic  growth  (results  are  even  stronger)  

Conclusion  

• The  results  show  that  PF  promotes  growth  in  particular  in  low-­‐income  countries  
• These   countries   gain   an   up   to   0.67%   point   increase   in   annual   economic   growth,   when   increasing   their  
th th
level  of  PF  from  the  25  percentile  to  the  75  
• Given   the   relatively   low   volume   of   PF   as   a   percentage   of   GDP,   such   growth   effect   seems   very  
substantial  
• Another  possible  explanation  can  be  sought  in  the  industry  distribution  of  PF  in  low-­‐income  countries:  
38%  of  PF  is  invested  in  infrastructure  projects,  a  sector  which  is  clearly  important  in  these  countries  
• The  structure  of  PF  leads  to  extensive  and  effective  screening  and  PF  is  also  likely  to  flow  to  growth  
enhancing  industries  
• With   regard   to   CG,   PF   creates   transparency   combined   with   strong   monitoring   incentives   for   the  
investment  
• Overall,  PF  is  an  effective  tool  to  deal  with  high-­‐risk  environments  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

The  economic  Motivations  for  Using  Project  Finance  –  Benjamin  C.  Esty  
 
Introduction  
Modigliani  and  Miller’  “irrelevance”  proposition  
• Key  assumption:  financing  and  investment  decisions  are  separable  and  independent  activities  
Ø corporate  financing  decisions  do  not  affect  firm  value  
 
Rise  of  project  finance  provides  evidence  that  financing  structures  DO  matter.  
 
Project  finance  solves  two  financing  problems  
• PF  reduces  costs  of  agency  conflicts  inside  project  companies  
• PF  reduces  opportunity  costs  of  underinvestment  due  to  leverage  and  incremental  distress  
costs  in  sponsoring  firms  
 
Why  project  finance?  
Project  finance  involves  both  an  investment  decision  involving  a  capital  asset  and  a  financing  decision  
 
Important  assumption  
• Decision  for  PF  reflects  attempt  to  reduce  total  financing  costs,  simultaneously  increasing  
firm  value  
• The  need  to  raise  external  capital  makes  it  significantly  more  difficult  to  find  negative  NPV  
projects  (because  bankers  need  to  be  convinced  first)  
 
Three  motivations  for  using  project  finance:  
1) Agency  cost  motivation  
• Certain  assets  (large,  tangible  assets  generating  high  free  cash  flows)  are  susceptible  to  costly  
agency  conflicts  
• asset-­‐specific  governance  system  (contracts,  concentrated  ownership,  board  of  directors,  
separate  incorporation,  high  leverage)  to  address  conflicts  between  ownership  and  control  
when  few  other  disciplining  methods  are  present  or  effective  (manager’s  discretion)  
o e.g.  high  leverage  counters  manager’s  discretion  as  project  managers  are  forced  to  
use  FCF  for  repayment  of  debt  which  is  totally  dependent  upon  the  project’s  CF;  no  
safety  net  like  with  corporate  debt  (corporate  balance  sheet  =  safety  net)  
• Joint  ownership  and  high  leverage  to  discourage  costly  agency  conflicts  between  owners  and  
related  parties  (opportunistic  behavior,  “hold-­‐up”;  strategic  behavior  of  suppliers  of  critical  
inputs  or  expropriation  of  host  governments)  
• only  two  classes/sources  of  capital  (with  three  types  of  capital:  senior  bank  loans,  
subordinated  debt,  equity)  reduce  conflicts  between  debt  holders  and  equity  holders  
 
2) Debt  overhang  motivation  
• Allocating  project  returns  to  new  capital  providers  in  a  way  that  can’t  be  replicated  using  
corporate  debt:  solves  leverage-­‐induced  underinvestment  
• Also:  project  finance  allows  firms  with  moderate  leverage  to  raise  funds  and  invest  without  
becoming  highly  leveraged,  thus  avoiding  the  opportunity  cost  of  underinvestment  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• PF  eliminates  all  recourse  to  sponsor’s  balance  sheet  as  well  as  the  possibility  that  new  
capital  will  subsidize  pre-­‐existing  claims  with  higher  seniority/reduce  value  of  junior  claims  
• Risk  averse  managers  do  not  invest  as  investment  would  require  company’s  CF  to  be  used  for  
repayment  of  debt,  also  raising  the  leverage  ratio;  project  finance  typically  for  timely  limited  
assets  →  no  need  to  consider  future  investment,  re-­‐investment  
 
3) Risk  management  
• Investing  in  risky  assets  can  generate  incremental  distress  costs  
• Isolating  asset  in  a  standalone  project  reduces  possibility  of  risk  contamination  (failing  asset  
drags  an  otherwise  healthy  sponsor  into  distress),  and  …  
o …  the  possibility  that  a  risky  asset  imposes  indirect  distress  costs  (e.g.  negative  
influence  on  investment  decisions  of  sponsor’s  other  divisions)  on  a  sponsor  even  
short  of  actual  default,  and  …  
o …  the  need  for  co-­‐insurance  by  sponsoring  firm  
• Maximum  loss  equals  equity  commitment  (which  is  comparably  low  due  to  high  leverage)  
• Risk  management  via  organizational  form  where  financial  instruments  do  not  exist/are  
expensive  or  where  a  possibility  of  a  total  loss  exists,  contrary  to  traditional  risk  
management’s  use  of  financial  instrument  or  derivatives  
• value-­‐enhancing  
• particularly  effective  in  case  of  binary  risk  (e.g.  negative  event  happened  or  not,  with  
potential  to  render  project  virtually  worthless)  
• diversification  (financing  via  joint  incorporation  or  corporate  finance)  versus  specialization  
(separate  incorporation  or  project  finance)  
• motivation  for  risk  management  can  also  be  seen  as  motivation  of  a  risk  averse  manager  
trying  to  minimize  threats  to  his/her  poorly  diversified  (as  he  is  only  involved  in  this  project)  
human  capital  
• mitigation  of  political  risk  might  be  limited  when  (exemplary)  host  country  seizes  collaterals  
 
 
Defining  project  finance  
Project  companies  have  evolved  as  institutional  structures  that  reduce  the  cost  of  performing  
important  financial  functions:  
• pooling  resources  
• managing  risk  
• transferring  resources  through  time  and  space  
 
Structural  attributes  of  project  companies  
• Organizational  structure:  separate  incorporation  –  legally  independent  from  sponsor(s)  
• Capital  structure:  very  high  leverage  similar  to  LBOs  (average  ratio  of  70%)  
• Ownership  structure:  highly  concentrated  debt  (nonrecourse;  mostly  syndicated  bank  loans)  
and  equity  (1-­‐3  sponsors;  almost  always  privately  held)  ownership  structures  
• Board  structure:  boards  comprised  of  affiliated  (“gray”)  directors  from  sponsors  
• Contractual  structure:  high  amount  of  contracts  for  supply  of  inputs,  purchase  of  outputs  
(off-­‐take  or  purchase  agreement),  construction,  operation  
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

[Framework  for  analysis]  


Deadweight  costs  (DWC)  resulting  from  capital  market  imperfections  and/or  frictions  
• Transaction  costs  
• Agency  costs  
• Distress  costs  
• Information  costs  
• Taxes  
 
Investment  value  =  (Present  value  of  project  CF)  –  (DWC  of  project)  –  (DWC  of  sponsor)  
Assumption:  project  NPV  is  positive  and  does  not  change  with  financing  structure  
 
→  use  project  finance  whenever  total  DWC  are  lower  than  total  costs  under  corporate-­‐financed  
alternatives  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

An  overview  of  Project  Finance  and  Infrastructure  finance  -­‐  Benjamin  C.  Esty,  Aldo  Sesia  
 
Introduction  
• financing  of  capital  expenditures  has  declined  after  economic  crisis  in  2007  
• in  2007:  most  used  financing  mechanism  for  new  or  start-­‐up  companies  
• project  finance  historically  used  by  private  companies  for  industrial  projects  (mines,  pipelines,  
oil  fields)  
• early  1990s:  financing  of  infrastructure  projects  like  toll  roads,  power  plants,  
telecommunication  systems  via  project  financing  
• 2000s:  financing  of  social  infrastructure  projects  like  schools,  hospitals,  prisons  
• infrastructure  investment  linked  to  GDP  growth  by  one-­‐for-­‐one  percentage  (newer  studies  
indicate  a  1-­‐to-­‐1.59  relationship)  
• project  structure  typically  used  for  financing  assets  with  limited  life  =  few  valuable  growth  
options  
 
 
Definition  
"Project  finance  involves  the  creation  of  a  legally  independent  project  company  financed  with  
nonrecourse  debt  (and  equity  from  one  or  more  corporate  entities  known  as  sponsoring  firms)  for  
the  purpose  of  financing  investment  in  a  single-­‐purpose  capital  asset,  usually  with  a  limited  life."  
 
nonrecourse  debt:  dept  repayment  comes  from  the  project  company  only  rather  than  from  any  other  
source  (simply  terms:  debt  is  repaid  using  revenues  of  the  project  company);  no  recourse  to  the  
sponsors  
 
stock-­‐type  investment:  firms  extract  resources  and  sell  output  
flow-­‐type  investment:  use  of  asset  to  generate  cash  flows  
 
legally  independent  entity  that  owns  assets:  form  of  off-­‐balance-­‐sheet  finance,  i.e.  project  assets  and  
liabilities  do  not  appear  on  sponsor's  balance  sheet;  this  assumption  does  not  always  hold  as  
assets/liabilities  can  and  do  appear  in  the  sponsor's  balance  sheet  (e.g.  only  one  sponsor  with  100%  
ownership;  around  60%  of  all  projects)  
 
Comparison  with  ABS,  other  financing  mechanisms  
ABS  (portfolio  of  financial  assets)  versus  single-­‐purpose  capital  asset  
 
portfolio  has  greater  statistical  regularity  (more  predictable  cash  flows  and  default  rates)  
→  can  support  more  debt  
 
industrial  assets:  require  active  management  
financial  assets  (e.g.  receivables):  requires  few,  if  any,  day-­‐to-­‐day  operating  decisions  
 
Are  following  mechanisms  forms  of  project  finance?  
• Secured  debt:  NO;  secured  debt  typically  has  recourse  to  corporate  assets  and  CF,  in  addition  
to  the  secured  assets  or  assets  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Covered  bonds:  NO;  debt  securities  have  recourse  to  corporate  assets,  CF;  backed  by  
financial  assets  (e.g.  mortgages)  rather  than  single-­‐purpose  capital  asset  
• Subsidiary  debt:  NO;  has  recourse  to  corporate  assets,  CF  
• ABS  or  real  estate  investment  trusts  (REITs):  NO;  ABS  or  REITs  hold  financial  assets  rather  
than  single-­‐purpose  capital  asset  
• Commercial  real  estate  development:  YES;  if  developed  as  single  property  
• Joint  ventures:  NO;  unless  JV  is  funded  with  nonrecourse  debt  
NOTE:  many  projects  are  structured  as  incorporated  joint  ventures  
• Vendor  or  trade  finance:  NO;  recourse  to  corporate  assets  (Vendor  finance  similar  to  
secured  debt  in  which  manufacturer  of  the  good  provides  financing)  
• Leases:  NO;  obligation  has  recourse  to  lessor;  no  asset  ownership  by  lessor  
• Privatizations  or  municipal  development  projects:  No;  no  corporate  sponsor  
• Leveraged  and  management  buyouts  (LBOs,  MBOs):  No;  no  corporate  sponsor  
• Project  holding  companies:  Maybe;  with  increase  of  projects,  holding  company  begins  to  
look  more  like  a  corporation  with  cross-­‐collateralized  debt  obligations  
 
Example:  
Independent  power  producer  (IPP):  owns  power  plants  and  finances  them  with  nonrecourse  debt  
In  order  to  create  IPP,  developer  needs  to  sign  four  primary  contracts:  
(1)  construction  and  equipment  contract:  fixed-­‐price,  date-­‐certain,  turnkey  with  experienced  
contractor  
(2)  long-­‐term  fuel  supply  contract  
(3)  long-­‐term  power  purchase  agreement  (PPA)  with  creditworthy  public  utility  
(4)  operating  and  maintenance  contract  
 
Project  finance:  extensive  use  of  contracts  →  contractual  finance  
 
Public-­‐private  partnerships  (PPP)  
• Use  of  private  financial  institutions  and  private  companies  to  construct  and  operate  project  
assets  like  roads,  prisons,  schools  
• governments  use  PPP  to  expand  pool  of  available  funds,  shift  construction  and  operating  
risks  to  private  sector  in  order  to  improve  efficiency  
• governments  and  municipalities  are  better  able  to  bear  large,  long-­‐term  risks  
(macroeconomic  risks)  
 
Private  finance  initiative  (PFI)  
• private  sector  provides  asset,  public  service,  financing  
• public  sector  maintains  ownership  of  asset  
 
 
Factors  that  led  to  increased  use  of  project  finance:  
• Privatization:  former  state-­‐owned  companies  used  PF  to  fund  growth,  investment  
• Deregulation:  created  new  opportunities  for  investment  by  private  sector  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Globalization:  increased  minimum  efficient  scale  for  many  industries  while  depletion  of  
existing  natural  resources  forced  firms  to  search  in  increasingly  remote  and  risky  locations  
for  new  reserves  
• Global  economic  recession:  prompted  governments  to  pass  large  stimulus  packages  
emphasizing  infrastructure  investment  to  spur  economic  growth  
 
 
Current  and  Future  Trends  
1)  Rise  of  infrastructure  finance  
• typically  transportation,  telecommunications,  power/water/sewage/natural  gas  projects;  
recently  schools,  hospitals,  prisons,  government  buildings  
• forecasts  of  infrastructure  spending  are  enormous  
• danger  of  overestimation  and  excessive  leverage:  classic  symptoms  of  asset  bubble  
 
2)  Impact  of  regulatory  and  environmental  policies  
• changes  in  international  banking  regulations  (Basel  II/III)  
• policy  changes  around  management  of  environmental  and  social  risks  (EP  II,  Equator  
Principles)  
• growing  interest  in  renewable  energy  sources  
 
3)  Changing  nature  of  deal  structures  
• return  to  more  structured  deals,  which  in  extreme  means  fixed-­‐price  and  fixed-­‐quantity  
contracts  on  both  input/output  side  of  deal  
• hybrid  structure:  combine  project  and  corporate  finance  
• club  deals:  group  of  banks  commits  to  provide  entire  amount  
• increased  demand  for  funds  from  international  development  financial  institutions  (IDFIs)  
 
4)  Rise  (and  fall)  of  expropriation  risk  
• with  fall  of  commodity  prices  have  fallen,  incentive  to  expropriate  projects  or  renegotiate  
contract  terms  have  diminished,  yet  not  entirely  disappeared  
• projects  with  large  up-­‐front  capital  costs  and  low  ongoing  costs  are  particularly  vulnerable  
• challenge  to  design  sustainable  long-­‐term  contracts  
 
5)  Role  of  China  in  project  finance  
• important  destination  for  investment  (infrastructure,  industrial),  though  with  many  
challenges:  navigating  extensive  government  involvement,  adapt  an  emerging  legal  system  
to  handle  complexity  of  contractual  finance  (deal  structuring,  contractual  enforcement,  
litigation)  
• importer  of  raw  materials  
• Chinese  government,  Chinese  financial  institutions  are  important  as  project  financiers  for  
outward  investment  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.10.2012


Privatization Session 5

Hypothesis Explanation
2.1 The impact of privatization depends on the Welfare theory argues that privatization tends to have the greatest positive impact in those
degree of market failures cases where the role for the government is lessening a market failure is the weakest, i.e., for
SOE’s in competitive markets, or markets that become rapidly competitive.
2.2 Contracting ability impacts the efficiency of state Governments may not be able to credibly formulate objectives. Although changing
and private ownership governments every legislation may lead to inefficiencies. Government goals may be
inconsistent with efficiency and inconsistent with maximizing social welfare.
2.3 Ownership Structure affects the ease with which Government’s transaction costs of intervening in production arrangements and other decisions
government can intervene in firm operations of the firm are greater when firms are privately owned.
2.4 A major source of inefficiency in public firms The state is unlikely to let a SOE go bankrupt. This safety leaves room for inefficiencies.
stems from less-prosperous firms being allowed to Putting harder budget constraints on SOE is not effective in that case.
rely on the government for funding, leading to
‘soft’ budget constraints
2.5 Privatization can impact efficiency through its There is evidence that sales of SOEs showed increased efficiencies on government spending.
effect on government fiscal conditions In some favourable cases, governments used money from SOE sales as savings rather than
spending it to increase government spending.
2.6 At a macroeconomic level, privatization can help Privatizations help to develop factor, product and security markets as they increase
develop product and security markets and competition in the market and thereby raising efficiency.
institutions

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.


Privatization Se

2.3 Policy Alternatives to Privatization

Academic discussions have argued for more competition and deregulation instead of privatization. In
the evidence on the benefits of reform without privatization comes primarily from individual co
where country-specific factors may play an important but unidentified role. However, especially Pol
China noted significant performance improvements of SOEs after implementing enterprise restructurin

Poland: ‘Big Bang’ reform in 1990. This reform deregulated prices, introducing foreign competition
industries, and signalled that tight monetary and fiscal policies would be pursued (e.g. tighter
constraints, tighter bank lending behaviour, etc.). Significant performance improvements on the part
manufacturing companies have been found.

China: The managerial labour market in China underwent an economic reform in the 1980s. Manager
given incentive contracts and were selected by auctions. This initiative resulted in market improvem
the marginal and total factor productivity of 272 Chinese SOEs in the period between 1980 and 1989.

3. Methods of Selling State-Owned Assets

There are several factors influencing the method through which the state-owned asset should be tran
to private ownership:

a) The history of the asset’s ownership


b) The financial and competitive position of the SOE
c) The government’s ideological view of markets and regulation
d) The need to pay off important interest groups in the privatization
e) The government’s ability to credibly commit itself to respect investor’s property rights after divest
f) The capital market conditions and existing institutional framework for corporate governance in the
g) The sophistication of potential investors
h) The government’s willingness to let foreigners own divested assets

3.1 Methods of Privatization

Brada (1996) presents four principal divestment methods, being:

1) Privatization through restitution*


2) Privatization through Sale of State Property**
3) Mass or Voucher Privatization***
4) Privatization from below****

According to empirical studies, the choice of the method of sale is influenced by the country’s
market, its political and firm-specific characteristics. Studies have shown that SIP is the preferred me
sale when capital markets are less developed, SOEs are highly profitable and the offer size is large.

One of the most important questions for governments prior to the sale of a SOE is whether to restruct
SOE prior to the sale or to leave this to the new owners or to sell an asset at once or in stages. The
clear evidence on the benefits or restructuring before the sale. According to studies, restructuring
sale does not improve the net price received for the company.
There is some empirical evidence that small and medium-sized SOEs should be sold ‘as is’ at the be
possible, as quickly as possible.

* Mainly in Eastern European countries where land has been expropriated


** Government trades its ownership claim for an explicit cash payment. First form: Direct sales, second form: SIP, in which so
of a government’s stake in a SOE is sold to investors through a public share offering.
*** Vouchers are distributed to eligible citizens fo bid for stakes in SOEs (esp. in Eastern European Countries). In order to
voucher holders trade their shares after the purchase, post-sale trading of stock is usually prohibited.
**** To finance startup SOEs
3

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.10.2012


Privatization Session 5

3.3 Pricing and allocation of Control and Ownership in SOE sales

1) Pricing Decisions in Asset Sales


One way of selling SOEs is through competitive auctions. Studies have shown that the maximizing the number
of bidders in an open auction is usually the best way to maximize revenues.

2) Pricing and Share and Control Allocation Decisions in SIPs


Control Transfer Decision: Whether to sell the SOE all at once or through a series of partial sales.
Pricing Decision: Whether the offer price should be set by a tender offer, a book-building exercise
or at a fixed price.
Share Allocation Decision: Whether one group of investors is preferable over another.

An empirical study (cf. Table 2) by the authors showed that SIPs are on average 34% underpriced (using the
one-day return at the first day of public offer). Seasoned offers are on average only 10% underpriced.
Furthermore, although governments usually pass on day-to-day operating control of the SOEs to private
owners in the SIP, they usually retain a ‘golden share’ which gives it power to veto certain actions, such as
foreign takeovers.

3.4 The structure of Voucher Privatizations

Voucher privatization is the most controversial method of divesting state-owned assets. The largest problem
arises when the proportion of ownership resulting from a given voucher bid is unknown but the post-
privatization performance largely depends on the skills of the new owners and their stakes in the company.
There are different philosophical approaches to voucher privatization. E.g. in the Czech Republic, post-sale
trading is prohibited, whereas Russia issues only small stakes in firms and allows unrestricted trading of
vouchers afterwards. The performance of firms in Russia that have been privatized through vouchers has
been especially poor.

4. Has privatization improved the financial and operating performance of divested firms?

Many methodological problems arise in empirical studies: Data availability and information. Reporting
standards differ across countries, so comparability is not always given. Using accounting information in order
to compare the operating performance is difficult.

4.1 Empirical Studies employing data from non-transition economics

In most cases, net welfare gains were noticed. Workers on average were better off after privatization.
However, although productivity increased significantly, the level of investment spending dropped, sales force
in many cases was cut by more than half after the privatization.

The summary of empirical studies (cf. Table 4) on average finds


Significant increases in: Output (real sales), operating efficiency, profitability, dividend payments
Significant decreases in: Firm directors
Ambiguous effects on: Capital Spending, leverage, employment declines

Table 5 (below) examines the three-year average operating and financial performance of a combined sample
of 211 newly-privatized firms with the average performance of those same firms during their last three years
as SOEs. All studies at least show limited support for the proposition that privatization leads to significant
improvements in the operating and financial performance of SOEs privatized through public share offering.

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.10.2012


Privatization Session 5

4.2 Empirical Tests of Privatization in Transition Economics

Two classifications of privatizations: Central and Eastern Europe and former Soviet-Union countries. The
major difficulty of analyzing cause and effect of performance improvements in in-transition countries is that
these countries at the time of the privatization undergo massive economic and political changes. Therefore,
data from transition economies is much more problematic and often not available at all.

4.2.1 Central and Eastern Europe

Private ownership and ownership led to greater post-privatization performance and firm restructuring,
especially when new managers were brought into the firm. Employment levels drop for almost all observed
firms.

4.2.2 Former Soviet-Union

Collecting data to evaluate post-privatization performance for the former soviet-union countries is especially
difficult. For Russia, only survey data or anecdotal evidence was available. Furthermore, nation-wide
changes were greater than elsewhere, making it difficult to measure performance improvements.
All studies found a positive association with performance improvements in firms that were divested during
the mass privatization program of the early 90s. However, various factors impact the success of the
privatization. Changing management and allowing foreign investors to own shares in an SOE was crucial to
initiate firm restructuring and to break up old oligarch management structures.

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.10.2012


Privatization Session 5

4.3 Privatization and Economic Reform in China

Even though China launched a market liberalization and privatization program in the late 1970s that raised
labour and factor productivity and privatized all but the largest 300 SOEs, there are still too many
governmental restrictions ban SOEs from being owned by private investors. Only one-third of the stock in
publicly listed SOEs can be owned by individuals; the remaining two-thirds of a company’s shares must be
owned by the state and by domestic (financial) institutions, which are state-owned. The long-term
performance of former SOEs in China has been, consequently, quite poor. The largest barrier to
privatizations though probably is the country’s social safety net that burdens SOEs with many social welfare
responsibilities.

5. Initial and Long-Run Investor Returns from Privatizations

Investors purchasing privatization public offering offerings (PIPO) at the offering price and then sell these
shares on the first day of open market trading, earn significantly high returns (cf. Table 8). This shows that
almost all PIPOs are underpriced, ranging from 39% to 940%. PIPOs are significantly more underpriced than
IPOs.

Multi-national studies showed persuasive evidence on long term excess, market-adjusted return earned by SIP
investors (cf. Table 9). However, there is hardly explanation of precisely why SIP issues out-perform over
time.

6. Privatization’s Impact on Financial Market Development

Global capital markets grew tremendously since the early 1980s. Total world market capitalization increased
by more than 10x between 1983 and 1999. Trading volume raised almost 40x in the same period. In 1999,
companies that were privatized made up approximately 10% of total market capitalization of non-U.S. capital
markets (cf. Table 11).

Privatized firms account for sizeable fractions of the total capitalization of national stock markets: Mexico
(23.6%), Spain (15.4%), Germany (13.1%), Italy (11.8%)…

Besides accounting for large parts of national market capitalization, privatizations have promoted stock
market developments through new share offerings, attracting foreign investors and have played a large role
in bond market development.

7. Privatization’s Impact on International Corporate Governance Practices

OECD countries have established a code of conduct and principles of good corporate governance practices.
Corporate governance impact the interpretation of the effects of privatization. There is empirical evidence
that corporate governance generally and corporate legal systems specifically, influence capital market size,
ownership structure and efficiency. A country’s legal system impacts the operation of financial markets and
corporate governance in that country. Similarly, the structure and operation of a country’s legal system will
affect the impact of privatization. Privatization means a large change in the governance structure of a firm.

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Corporate Governance and Restructuring 23.10.2012


Privatization Session 5

Readings:
• From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization, by: Megginson, Netter, 2000

1. The impact of privatization to date

Historically, the most important denationalizations have been actively initiated by the Thatcher government
in 1979. The government agreed that it should at least own the telecommunications and postal services,
electric and gas utilities, and most forms of non-road transportation (esp. airlines and railroads). Some
politicians even argued that governments should be in possession of important ‘strategic’ manufacturing
industries, such as steel and defence production.

The Adenauer government launched the first large- scale ideologically motivated privatization program of the
post-war era. In 1961, the German government sold a majority stake in Volkswagen in a public share offering
heavily weighted in favour of small investors.

Some other huge privatizations have been the 1984 IPO of British Telecom, the 1987 privatization of NTT
(Japan, transaction value of $40 billion) and the IPO of France Telecom in 1997 ($7.1 billion). Especially
during the 90s, most of the world’s countries launched large privatization programs that usually relied on
public share offerings.
The last region to adopt privatization programs were the former Soviet-bloc countries of Central and Eastern
Europe.

Although China launched a major economic reform and liberalization program in the late 1970s, the overall
number of privatizations has been limited due to existing Chinese social welfare responsibilities that make a
privatization difficult.

2. Why have governments embraced privatization programs?

2.1 The Efficiency of State vs. Private Ownership Theory

Theoretically, the motivations for governments to privatize state-owned enterprises are to:
a) Raise revenue for the state*
b) Promote economic efficiency**
c) Reduce government interference in the economy
d) Promote wider share ownership
e) Provide the opportunity to introduce competition
f) Subject SOE’s to market discipline
g) Develop national capital markets

The various hypotheses for and against the need for privatization are stated in the table below (page 2).

2.2 Empirical Evidence on the Efficiency of State vs. Private Ownership Theory

Diverse empirical studies have examined the performance of private ownership firms and state-owned firms.
Consent on better performance of privately owned enterprises with respect to the following measures of
performance (cf. Table 1: Summary of Recent Empirical Studies comparing Public Versus Private Ownership):

- Profitability
- Efficiency
- Returns

* Cumulative profit during the second half of the 90s was more than $1 trillion, which filled governmental households and eliminated the
need for raising taxes or cutting government services. Privatization proceeds were an average of one and three-quarters percent of GDP.
** Governments perceive the need to regulate/own (natural) monopolies, intervene in the case of e.g. pollution and help provide national
services (education, information, national defence).

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

The   Effects   of   Changes   in   Corporate   Governance   and   Restructurings   on   Operating   Performance:  


Evidence  from  Privatizations  

• Paper   offers   evidence   of   how   restructuring   and   CG   changes   affect   the   firm’s   post-­‐P  
performance  
• Prior   to   P,   governments   may   choose   to  restructure   firms   through   governance   changes   and/or  
restructurings  
• The   results   suggest   that   both   restructuring   and   changes   in   CG   are   important   determinants   of  
post-­‐P  performance  

Introduction  

• Privatization:  the  sale  of  previously  state-­‐owned  enterprises  to  private  owners  
• P  improves  the  financial  and  operating  efficiency  of  divested  firms  
• Evidence   that   pre-­‐P   restructuring   leads   to   stronger   post-­‐P   efficiency   gains   –   evidence   of  
stronger  profitability  gains  for  firms  with  lower  post-­‐P  employee  ownership  and  higher  state  
ownership  –  stronger  output  gains  for  firms  in  competitive  (unregulated)  industries  and  for  
firms  in  developing  countries  

Potential  Sources  of  Post-­‐Privatization  Performance  Improvements  

• P   involves   changes   in   in   CG   due   to   changes   in   ownership   –   the   act   of   P   reduces   state  


ownership   and   some   P   further   re-­‐shuffle   governance   structures   by   providing   ownership   to  
employees  and  foreigners  
• The  ownership  changes  from  P  should  help  redefine  the  firm’s  objectives  and  the  manager’s  
incentives  –  this  should  impact  post-­‐P  performance  
• Transferring   the   firm   from   government   control   provides   greater   entrepreneurial  
opportunities  –  like  restructuring  

Corporate  Governance:  Changes  in  Ownership  

• Privatized  firms  are  more  focused  on  profit  maximization  


• Since   state   owned   enterprises   (SOEs)   pursue   objectives   that   frequently   conflict   with   profit-­‐
maximization,   the   level   of   post-­‐privatization   ownership   retained   by   the   state   should   affect  
the  newly  privatized  firm’s  efficiency  improvements  
o If  the  state  maintains  majority  ownership,  the  firm  is  likely  to  delay  restructuring  and  
maintain   high   levels   of   employment   –   selling   only   a   small   stake   increases   the  
likelihood   of   continuing   government   interference   and   possible   re-­‐nationalization   –  
larger   efficiency   improvements   following   sales   in   which   the   government   no   longer  
maintained  majority  control  
• The   presence   of   foreign   investors   may   also   affect   the   degree   of   post-­‐P   performance  
improvement    
o Return   on   equity   or   revenue   per   employee   is   significantly   higher   for   the   firms   with  
foreign  investors  
• The  amount  of  employee  share  ownership  does  not  spur  performance  improvements  after  P  
o We  expect  employee  ownership  to  negatively  affect  post-­‐P  performance  

Corporate  Governance:  Changes  in  upper  Management  

• We   expect   that   CG   changes   (brought   on   by   different   upper   management)   will   positively  


impact  the  degree  of  post-­‐P  performance  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Restructuring  

• P  is  often  an  initial  step  in  a  transformation  process  whereby  the  state-­‐owned  firm  becomes  
reconfigured   to   compete   as   a   private   enterprise   –   restructuring   is   a   common   part   in   this  
process  

Reasons  for  Restructuring  

a) Response  to  external  shocks  


• Restructuring  generally  seen  as  response  to  significant  shocks  –  ownership  and  institutional  
transformation  brought  about  by  P  seen  as  such  a  shock  
• Restructuring   may   also   be   triggered   by   economic   conditions   (recession   etc)   or   by   market  
pressure   –   newly   privatized   firm   faces   larger   threats   from   these   forces   since   P   frequently  
involves  the  weakening  of  regulatory  protection  and  the  reduction  of  state  subsidies  à  this  
heightened  sensitivity  to  external  shocks  may  contribute  to  greater  restructuring  activity  by  
newly  privatized  firms  
b) Desire  for  efficiency  improvements  
• Restructuring   generally   increases   efficiency   by   transferring   assets   to   firms   that   can   put   the  
resources   to   a   better   use   –   restructuring   involves   the   elimination   of   negative   synergies   –  
since  state-­‐owned  firms  are  seen  as  economically  inefficient,  they  are  prime  candidates  for  
such  restructuring  targeted  for  P  
c) Pursuit  of  new  opportunities  
• New   growth   opportunities   may   motivate   companies   to   restructure   –   thus   newly   privatized  
firms  should  engage  in  restructuring  
d) Change  in  corporate  strategy  
• P   creates   growth   opportunities   and   thus   the   newly   privatized   company   may   engage   in   an  
expansion  strategy  to  pursue  this  potential  

Forms  of  Restructuring  

• 3  forms  of  restructuring  activities:  


1. Organizational/Operational  Restructuring  (Org/Op)  [most  frequent  means  in  their  sample]  
-­‐ The  reorganization  of  the  firm’s  production  methods  and/or  management  structure  
-­‐ It  may  also  involve  changes  in  management  structure  
2. Acquisitions  and  Divestments  (A&D)  
-­‐ Acquisitions  cause  expansion  and  may  represent  an  effort  to  take  advantage  of  opportunities  
-­‐ Divestments  cause  contraction  –  shed  up  unprofitable  units  and  downsizing  
-­‐ In  asset  sell-­‐offs,  the  firm  sells  a  division  or  major  facility  to  an  outside  party  
3. Financial  Restructuring  
-­‐ Involves  a  reduction  in  the  leverage  level  –  done  through  debt  payoffs,  debt  write-­‐offs,  and  
leverage-­‐reducing  recapitalizations  (debt-­‐equity  swaps  etc.)  
-­‐ May  also  include  a  major  refinancing  or  restructuring  of  a  loan  

Other  factors:  Macroeconomic  and  institutional  environments  

• It   is   expected   that   firms   whose   shares   trade   in   more   sophisticated   and   active   equity   markets  
should  display  the  strongest  performance  improvements  
• For   managers   to   feel   the   full   disciplining   pressure   of   the   capital   market,   the   rights   of   the  
individual   shareholder   (particularly   voting   rights)   must   be   enforced   by   the   country’s   legal  
system  
• It  is  expected  that  the  degree  of  shareholder  rights  protection  within  the  country  should  be  
positively  related  to  performance  improvements  following  privatization  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Whether   a   divesting   government   is   “committed”   (to   P   and   economic   reform)   or   “populist”  


(selling  SOEs  just  to  raise  money)  should  significantly  influence  the  performance  of  privatized  
firms  
• Does   the   level   of   development   of   a   nation’s   economy   significantly   affect   post-­‐P   efficiency  
improvements?  
• Having   to   compete   with   other   firms   for   customers   and   market   share   may   provide   the  
pressure  required  to  stimulate  greater  efficiency  and  profitability  
• It  is  tested  for  post-­‐P  performance  differences  between  competitive  and  regulated  firms  

Empirical  proxies  and  testable  predictions  

Corporate  Governance:    

• Newly  privatized  firms  in  all  industries  engage  in  restructuring  


• The  largest  number  of  restructuring  is  by  manufacturing  firms,  majority  of  the  sample  is  from  
the  manufacturing  sector,  telecommunications  industry  exhibit  much  greater  frequency  
• Most  restructuring  occurs  in  Italy  and  England  
• The   type   of   restructuring   varies   by   location   –   Organization/Operational   restructurings  
occurred  in  22  countries,  while  financial  restructurings  took  place  in  8  countries  
• The   legal   origin   does   not   appear   to   affect   the   overall   frequency   of   restructuring   –  
nevertheless   is   can   be   said   that   in   common   law   countries,   the   stronger   financial   market  
orientation   may   contribute   to   a   greater   likelihood   of   financial   restructuring   by   newly  
privatized  firms  
• Majority  of  the  sample’s  restructurings  were  from  OECD  countries  –  there  appears  to  be  no  
immediate  evidence  that  the  country’s  level  of  economic  development  impacts  the  likelihood  
of  restructuring  

Empirical  Results  

• Following  P,  firms  experience  significant  increases  in  profitability,  efficiency,  and  real  output  
in  the  3-­‐year  post-­‐P  period,  compared  to  average  values  from  the  3-­‐year  pre-­‐P  period  
• Changes   in   a   newly   privatized   firm’s   upper   management   may   also   contribute   to  
improvements  in  financial  performance  
• Upon  P,  firms  restructure  to  reduce  employment  and  to  reduce  leverage  
o The  transfer  to  private  ownership  may  lead  to  adjustments  in  employment  
o P   should   trigger   a   decrease   in   leverage   since   SEOs   frequently   received   loans   from  
state  agencies  and  benefited  from  governmental  guarantees  of  creditworthiness  à  
such   state   support   should   be   reduced   following   P   –   firms   may   seek   to   move   to   a  
more  optimal  capital  structure  

Conclusion  

• Results   show   that   restructurings   are   important   determinants   of   post-­‐P   performance   –  


restructuring  leads  to  stronger  efficiency  improvements  
• Changes   in   CG   (especially   ownership   changes)   brought   on   by   P   may   also   contribute   to   the  
performance  improvements  
• Higher  amounts  of  foreign  ownership  lead  to  larger  gains  in  post-­‐P  efficiency  and  lower  levels  
of  employment  
• Real  output  significantly  increases  as  state  ownership  declines  
• Profitability  decreases  as  employee  ownership  increases  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

The  Long-­‐Run  Return  to  Investors  in  Share  Issue  Privatization  

• Statistically   significant   positive   net   returns   for   the   158   unseasoned   SIPs   for   all   holding   periods   and  
compared  with  all  benchmarks  
• Findings  contrast  with  the  patterns  reported  in  previous  research  for  equity  offerings  of  private  firms  in  
the  US  and  other  countries!  

• since  the  early  1960s,  internationally  more  than  $700  billion  have  been  raised  through  the  sale  of  SOEs  
to  private  investors  à  these  P  programs  have  profound  effect  on  the  liquidity  and  total  capitalization  
of  world  security  markets  (21  largest  common  stock  offerings  in  financial  history  have  been  share  issue  
privatization  (SIPs))  
• studies  find  significant  performance  improvements  as  result  of  P  
• the  paper  examines  the  long-­‐run  stock  price  performance  for  privatized  firms  
o systematic  evidence  of  large,  average,  positive  abnormal  performance  for  the  SIPs  is  found  
o the  findings  of  positive  long-­‐run  returns  for  SIPs  contrast  with  the  return  patterns  many  other  
researchers  have  found  for  equity  offerings  of  private  firms  in  the  US  and  other  countries  à  
SIPs  and  private  equity  offerings  are  different  in  many  ways  

Data  and  Methodology  

• the  most  frequent  SIP  issuer  in  the  sample  and  the  country  with  the  largest  total  value  of  all  offers  is  
the  UK  with  27  issues  worth  $52.6  billion  in  November  1997  
• the  second  largest  total  value  of  SIPs  is  Japan  
• the  second  most  frequent  SIP  issuer  is  Hong  Kong  
• to   compute   one-­‐,   three-­‐,   and/or   five-­‐year   buy-­‐and-­‐hold   returns   for   each   issue,   the   return   index   (RI)  
datatype  from  Datastream  is  used  
• the   RI   represents   the   theoretical   aggregate   growth   in   the   value   of   a   share   over   a   given   period,  
assuming  that  dividends  are  re-­‐invested  to  purchase  additional  shares  at  the  closing  price  applicable  
on  the  ex-­‐dividend  date:  

𝑅𝐼! = 𝑅𝐼! ×𝑃𝐼! ÷ 𝑃𝐼!!! × 1 + 𝐷𝑌! ÷ 100𝑁  

where  

RIt  =  return  on  index  on  day  t  


RIt-­‐1  =  return  on  index  on  previous  day  
PIt  =  price  on  index  on  day  t  
PIt-­‐1  =  price  on  index  on  previous  day  
DYt  =  dividend  yield,  in  %,  on  day  t  
N  =  number  of  working  days  in  the  year  (taken  to  be  260)  
 
Results  
• local,   international   and   US   investors   receive   significantly   better   one-­‐year   returns   from   purchasing  
unseasoned   SIP   offerings   than   they   could   over   the   same   period   by   investing   in   the   national   market  
index  (in  local  currency)  or  in  either  the  world  or  US  market  index  or  in  a  US  firm  in  the  same  industry  
Summary  
• SIP  investors  earn  higher  returns  than  do  investors  who  buy  the  local,  world,  or  US  market,  or  who  buy  
a  portfolio  of  industry-­‐matched  firms  
• The  SIP  investors  do  well  
o The   SIPs   in   the   sample   consistently   outperform   their   reference   indexes   and   matching   firm  
portfolios  over  one-­‐,  three-­‐  and  five-­‐year  horizons  
o How   these   investors   have   fares   is   significant   because   SIPs   are   almost   always   the   largest  
equity   offerings   in   the   histories   of   most   nations’   capital   markets,   and   usually   generate   a  
substantial  increase  in  the  number  of  shareholders  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

A  Century  of  corporate  takeovers:  What  have  we  learned  and  there  do  we  stand?  

• We   find   that   patterns   of   takeover   activity   and   their   profitability   vary   significantly   across  
takeover  waves  
• All  waves  still  have  some  common  factors:  they  are  preceded  by  technological  or  industrial  
shocks,   and   occur   in   a   positive   economic   and   political   environment,   amidst   rapid   credit  
expansion  and  stock  market  booms  
• Takeovers  towards  the  end  of  each  wave  are  usually  driven  by  non-­‐rational,  frequently  self-­‐
interested  managerial  decision-­‐making  

Introduction  

• 5   takeover   waves   have   been   examined   in   recent   literature:   those   of   the   early   1900s,   the  
1920s,  the  1960s  and  the  1990s  
o Five  American  takeover  waves,  three  UK  waves  and  2  recent  European  waves  
• Takeover  activity  is  usually  disrupted  by  a  steep  decline  in  stock  markets  and  a  subsequent  
economic   recession,   while   considerable   heterogeneity   in   the   triggers   of   takeover   activity   are  
observed  
• Takeovers   usually   occur   in   periods   of   economic   recovery   –   they   coincide   with   rapid   credit  
expansion,   which   in   turn   results   from   burgeoning   external   capital   markets   accompanied   by  
stock  market  booms  
• The  takeover  market  is  also  often  fuelled  by  regulatory  changes  
• Takeover  waves  are  frequently  driven  by  industrial  and  technological  shocks  
• Managers’   personal   objectives   can   also   significantly   influence   takeover   activity,   to   the   extent  
that   managerial   hubris   and   herding   behavior   increases   during   takeover   waves   which   often  
leads  to  poor  acquisitions  

The  overview  of  takeover  waves  

1. The  1st  wave:  the  Great  Merger  Wave  –  late  1890s  to  1903/05  
-­‐ Period   of   radical   changes   in   technology,   economic   expansion   and   innovation   in   industrial  
processes  
-­‐ The  wave  is  characterized  by  horizontal  consolidation  of  industrial  production  
2. The  2nd  wave:  late  1910s  –  1929  (the  great  depression)  
-­‐ A   move   towards   oligopolies   because   by   the   end   of   the   wave   industries   were   no   longer  
dominated  by  one  giant  firm  but  by    two  ore  mot  corporations  
-­‐ Companies  intended  to  achieve  economies  of  scale  and  build  strength  to  compete  with  the  
dominant  firm  in  their  industries  
3. The  3rd  wave:  late  1950s  –  1973  (oil  crisis)  with  a  peak  in  1968  
-­‐ Very   high   number   of   diversifying   takeovers   that   led   to   the   development   of   large  
conglomerates  
4. The  4th  wave:  1981  –  1987  (stock  market  crash)  
-­‐ With   changes   in   anti-­‐trust   policy,   the   deregulation   of   the   financial   services   sector,   the  
creation  of  new  financial  instruments  and  markets  an  the  technological  process  
-­‐ Conglomerate  structures  created  during  1960s  had  become  inefficient  by  the  1980s  such  that  
companies  were  forced  to  reorganize  their  businesses  
5. The  5th  wave:  1993  –  
-­‐ Surged   along   with   the   increasing   globalization,   technological   innovation,   deregulation   and  
privatization  
-­‐ Takeovers   feature   a   very   international   nature   –   cross   border   transactions   as   a   means   to  
survive  the  tough  international  competition  created  by  global  markets  
-­‐ Main  motive  was  growth  to  participate  in  globalized  markets  

SUMMARY  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Waves  occur  in  periods  of  economic  recovery  


• Waves  coincide  with  periods  of  rapid  credit  expansion  and  booming  stock  markets  
• Takeover   waves   are   preceded   by   industrial   and   technological   shocks   often   in   form   of  
technological   and   financial   motivations,   supply   shocks,   deregulation,   and   increased   foreign  
completion  
• Takeovers  often  occur  in  periods  when  regulatory  changes  take  place  

Takeover  Profitability  across  the  decades  

1. Target-­‐firm  stockholder  return  


-­‐ Share  prices  of  target  firms  significantly  increase  at  and  around  the  announcement  
-­‐ The  size  of  the  announcement  effects  is  similar  for  the  4th  and  the  5th  takeover  waves  
-­‐ The   price-­‐run   up   is   substantial   and   often   even   exceeds   the   announcement   effect   itself   (a  
period   of   one   month   prior   to   the   bid)   à   the   bids   are   anticipated,   and   result   from   rumors,  
information  leakages  or  insider  trading  
-­‐ Target  shareholders  in  successful  but  initially  hostile  M&As  are  offered  higher  premiums  than  
those   in   friendly   M&As   –   when   a   hostile   bid   is   made,   the   target   share   price   immediately  
incorporates  the  expectation  that  opposition  to  the  bid  may  lead  to  upward  revisions  of  the  
offer  price  
-­‐ Target   shareholders   earn   substantially   higher   premiums   in   tender   offers   –   as   the   means   of  
payment   in   mergers   is   usually   equity   whereas   cash   bids   prevail   in   tender   offers,   they   also  
find  that  all-­‐cash  bids  are  more  profitable  tor  target  shareholders  than  are  all-­‐equity  ones  
-­‐ All-­‐equity  bids  trigger  lower  target  returns  than  all-­‐cash  bids  
-­‐ Shareholders  of  target  firms  accumulate  significant  positive  CAARs  in  the  period  around  the  
bid   announcement   –   these   CAARs   can   be   dissected   into   those   realized   prior   to   the   bid  
announcement,  the  announcement  returns,  and  those  realized  after  the  announcement  
-­‐ The  pre-­‐announcements  are  returns  are  significantly  different  
-­‐ Returns  to  the  target  firm  shareholders  have  been  increasing  over  the  takeover  waves    
2. Bidding  firm  stockholder  returns  
-­‐ Bidder   shareholders   realized   announcement   abnormal   returns,   which   are   statistically  
indistinguishable  from  zero  
-­‐ The  one-­‐month  share-­‐price  run-­‐up  prior  to  a  takeover  announcement  is  mostly  insignificant  
for  bidder  shareholders  
-­‐ When  one  considers  the  wealth  effects  over  somewhat    longer  time  windows  of  one  or  two  
months  surrounding  the  announcement,  the  bidders’  CAARs  are  significantly  positive  
-­‐ The   bidders’   CAARs   measured   over   a   wide   time   window   surrounding   the   takeover  
announcements   largely   depend   on   the   type   of   acquisition,   the   means   of   payment,   the  
acquisition  strategy:  
o The   CAARs   of   friendly   takeovers   are   generally   significantly   higher   than   those   of  
mergers,  which  in  turn  are  significantly  larger  than  those  of  hostile  bids  
-­‐ Gains  to  the  bidders  depend  on  the  status  (private  or  publicly  listed)  of  the  target  firm,  with  a  
bid  on  a  private  target  resulting  in  substantially  higher  CAARs  to  the  bidders  
-­‐ The  means  of  payment  also  determines  the  bidders’  CAARs  
o The   announcement   of   all   equity-­‐financed   acquisitions   are   associated   with  
significantly   negative   abnormal   returns   on   the   bidders’   shares,   and   that   these  
takeovers  substantially  underperform  the  all-­‐cash  bids  
o Equity-­‐financed   bids   result   in   positive   and   sometimes   significant   returns   to   the  
bidder  
è Shareholders   of   the   bidding   firm   earn   significant   CAARs   prior   to   and   at   the   announcement   of  
a  takeover  
è There   are   no   significant   differences   in   the   pre-­‐announcement   and   announcement   bidder  
CAARs  across  waves  
è The  differences  emerge  when  post-­‐announcement  and  the  total  returns  are  scrutinized  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

3. Total  Gains  from  Takeovers  


-­‐ Takeovers  are  expected  to  increase  the  combined  market  value  of  the  merging  firms’  assets  
-­‐ Wealth  effects  of  M&As  occurring  in  periods  outside  the  surging  takeover  waves  are  always  
significantly  lower  than  the  gains  earned  during  upward  moving  takeover  waves  
-­‐ The  highest  combined  M&A  gains  are  realized  at  the  beginning  of  takeover  waves  
4. Long-­‐term  wealth  effects  
-­‐ Takeovers  lead  to  a  decline  in  share  prices  over  several  years  subsequent  to  the  transaction,  
while  the  previous  section  has  given  evidence  of  significantly  positive  total  gains  around  the  
announcement  dates  of  M&As  
-­‐ Possible  reason  may  lay  in  other  events  occurring  after  the  takeover  on  the  long  run  which  
might  influence  the  measurement  of  the  firm’s  performance  

Operating  Performance  

• Studies  showing  a  decline  in  post-­‐merger  profitability  employ  earnings-­‐based  measures  while  
studies  showing  merger  gains  are  based  on  cash  flow  performance  measures  

Summary  of  the  evidence  on  takeover  profitability  

• The   conclusions   do   no   entirely   converge   as   to   whether   takeovers   create   or   destroy   company  


value  
• At   their   announcement,   takeovers   trigger   substantial   value   increases.   But   most   of   these  
gains  are  captured  by  the  targets’  shareholders  which  is  not  surprising  as  they  hold  most  of  
the  negotiation  power  
• A  substantial  decline  in  the  acquiring  firms’  share  prices  is  observed  over  the  first  five  years  
subsequent   to   the   event   –   this   suggests   that   the   anticipated   gains   from   takeovers   are   on  
average  non-­‐existent  or  overstated  

Theoretical  Explanations  for  M&A  clustering  and  empirical  evidence  

• 4  groups  of  takeover  theories:  


1. Business  Environment  shocks  
2. Agency  problems  and  corporate  governance  
3. Managerial  hubris  and  herding  
4. Market  timing  

Summary  

• Takeover  activity  occurs  as  a  result  of  external  economic,  technological,  financial,  regulatory  
and  political  shocks  
• When  takeovers  are  a  response  to  such  shocks  and  managers  take  the  shareholders’  interest  
at   heart,   M&A   activity   is   expected   to   lead   to   profit   optimization   and   shareholder   value  
creation  
• In   contrast,   models,   which   explicitly   include   herding,   managerial   hubris,   and   other   agency  
costs  allow  for  the  possibility  that  value-­‐destroying  takeovers  follow  M&A  which  create  value  
• No  single  theory  is  able  to  explain  takeover  activity  and  M&A  waves  
• Takeovers   occurring   early   in   the   wave   are   triggered   by   industry   shocks   –   these   takeovers  
generate   substantial   (short-­‐term)   wealth   to   target   shareholders   and   the   combined  
companies  are  expected  to  create  synergetic  gains  
• The  majority  of  value-­‐destroying  acquisitions  occur  in  the  second  half  of  the  takeover  wave  
• Unprofitable  takeovers  are  a  result  of  both  managerial  hubris  and  agency  problems  

Changing  characteristics  of  takeover  waves  

Explaining  the  rise  and  decline  in  diversification  activity  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• The   improved   efficiency   of   the   external   capital   markets   in   the   1980s   is   considered   the  
foremost   cause   for   the   decline   in   diversifying   takeovers  –   as   the   cost   of   external   finance   had  
fallen,  internal  capital  markets  became  an  unnecessary  and  costly  configuration  

Explaining  the  rise  and  decline  in  hostile  takeovers  

• Hostile   takeovers   were   considered   as   an   alternative   corporate   governance   mechanism   that  


corrects  for  opportunistic  managerial  behavior  
• With   regulatory   changes   in   the   late   1980s   hostile   takeover   activity   decreased  –  they   were   no  
longer   needed   as   a   CG   device,   given   that   there   are   sufficient   number   of   alternative  
governance  mechanisms  

Conclusion  

• Takeovers  usually  occur  in  periods  of  economic  recovery  


• They   coincide   with   rapid   credit   expansion,   which   in   turn   results   from   burgeoning   external  
capital  markets  accompanied  by  stock  market  booms  
• The  takeover  market  is  also  often  fuelled  by  regulatory  changes,  such  as  anti-­‐trust  legislation  
or  deregulation  
• Takeover  waves  are  frequently  driven  by  industrial  and  technological  shocks  
• Managers’   personal   objectives   can   further   influence   takeover   activity:   managerial   hubris   and  
herding  behavior  increase  during  takeover  waves,  often  leading  to  poor  acquisitions  
• Takeover  activity  is  usually  disrupted  by  a  steep  decline  in  stock  markets  and  a  subsequent  
period  of  economic  recession  
• The   bulk   of   M&As   are   expected   to   improve   efficiency   and   trigger   substantial   share   price  
increases  at  the  announcement,  most  of  which  are  captured  by  the  target  firm  shareholders  
• Takeovers  occurring  at  a  later  stage  of  the  takeover  wave  trigger  lower  gains  to  shareholders  
than  those  at  the  beginning  of  the  wave  –  this  indicates  that  waves  tend  to  pass  their  optimal  
stopping   point   and   that   unprofitable   takeovers   occurring   later   in   the   wave   result   from  
limited  information  processing,  hubris,  and  managerial  self-­‐interest  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Chapter  for  M&A  

Reasons  for  M&A:  

1. Economies  of  scale  


2. Creation  of  Synergies  
3. Specialization  à  firms  of  larger  scale  organize  production  into  specialist  groups  
4. Economies  of  scope  à  produce  related  products  at  lower  cost  because  of  experience  with  
existing  products  

Value  increasing  theories:  

Coase:    

1. Weigh  transaction  cost  of  separate  vs.  merged  entities    


2. Transaction  cost  efficiency  

Bradley,  Desai,  Kim,  

1. Mergers  create  synergies  (economies  of  scale,  effective  management,  improved  production,    

Alchian,  Demsetz:  

1. Disciplinary  à  replace  a  poorly  functioning  management  team  

Value  Reducing  theories:  

Jenson:  

1. Agency  costs  due  to  high  amounts  of  free  cash  flows  

Schleifer  and  Vishny:  

1. Managerial  entrenchment  à  managers  make  investments  that  increase  the  manager’s  position  
and  are  not  directly  aligned  with  the  interests  of  shareholder  

Value  Neutral  theories:  

Roll:  

1. Managerial  hubris  à  prone  to  over  self-­‐confidence,  winner  curse  in  bidding  situations  
2. Mergers  can  occur  even  if  they  don’t  have  an  impact  on  the  value  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

The  merger  Process:  

Theory   Combined  Gaines   Gains  Target   Gains  bidder  


Efficiency  /Synergy   +   +   Non-­‐negative  
Agency   -­‐   +   More  negative  
cost/entrenchment  
Hubris   0   +   -­‐  
 

Takeover  Bidding  Process:  

The  winners  curse:  

-­‐ The  bidder  in  a  takeover  attempt  might  face  the  winners  curse  (due  to  asymmetric  info)  
-­‐ If  a  bidder  is  concerned  about  the  real  value  the  bidder  can  offer  stock  rather  than  cash.    
-­‐ Both  bidder  and  target  bar  the  cost  of  overbidding  at  the  time  of  merger  

Bidders  Costs:  

-­‐ Bidding  costs  cost  can  reduce  the  potential  payoff  from  inviting  to  many  people  to  compete  in  
the  bidding  process    
-­‐ one  counteractive    measure  can  be  a  already  signed  termination  fee  à  more  likely  to  choose  the  
first  bid  
-­‐ the  question  is  also  whether  to  obtain  a  toehold  (initial  stake)  à  can  help  recoup  bidding  costs  

Seller  Decision:  

-­‐ An  initial  toehold  in  the  company  might  deter  competition  for  the  bidding  à  lesson  gain  to  seller  
-­‐ Seller  firm  bears  the  costs  borne  by  the  bidders  in  the  auction  à  reduce  nr.  of  bidders  

Appendix:  

Event  studies:  

-­‐ Measuring  the  effect  of  an  event  on  the  stock  price  
-­‐ Choosing  an  event  period  (if  no  other  events  -­‐40;  +40)  
-­‐ Calculate  the  predicted  return  if  no  event  would  have  taken  place  
-­‐ Next  calculated  the  residual  =  actual  return  minus  the  predicted  return  
For  the  three  methods  see  chapter:  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Takeover Defenses and Bargaining Power (Guhan Subramanian)

The “bargaining power hypothesis”: a target with strong takeover defenses will extract
more in a deal than a target with weak takeover defenses.

The modern arsenal of takeover defenses:


• Poison pill: gives the shareholders the right to buy shares of the target (“flip-in”)
the acquirer (“flip-over”) or both at a substantially discounted price in the event
that the acquirer acquires more than a specified percentage of the company’s
shares.
o Vary in potency (specific provision & state corporate law)
o Vulnerable to Proxy-contest (bidder gain control of target’s board)
§ Can be slowed down by staggered boards (staggered boards with
either 2 or 3 year terms of directors)
§ Can be slowed down by “dead hand” pill (pill can be redeemed
only by continuing directors or their approved successors) or “slow
hand” pill (delayed redemption)
o Endorsed in Virginia, Pensylvania and, Georgia and Maryland
o California has not validated any version of a poison pill

Bargaining Power Hypothesis


• Targets with pills achieve higher premiums than targets without pills (provide
managers with greater power to negotiate with outside bidders and therefore get
higher premiums for the target firm shareholders)
o BUT since a poison pill can be introduced at any point in time friendly
takeovers are also negotiated in the “shadow” of a poison pill
o Non-EBS targets achieved on average a 1.8% greater increase from the
initial bid than EBS targets.
o Largest increase in hostile takeover was achieved without the benefit of an
EBS (PeopleSoft’s $26.50 per share as opposed to initial $16.00 per share
from Oracle)

A Model of Bargaining with Defenses


• Baseline model involving bilateral
o Bilateral monopoly between acquirer and target
o no incremental costs of a hostile bid
o complete information
o loyal shareholder target board
• Each of the constraints will be relaxed individually and then analysed

Baseline Case
• Target worth $100 stand-alone $200 to acquirer
o With no takeover defenses → acquiring company offers $101 target
accepts

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o With complete takeover defenses → (target knows that acquirer willing to


pay $199; acquirer knows target would accept a small amount of $101)
using the Nash bargaining game expected outcome is $150
Alternative away from tables
• Buy side alternative: Existence of walk-away alternative puts constraint on the
target’s use of defenses
o If T2 with identical assets has no defenses price of this acquisition would
be $101. if price of T1 goes up acquirer buys T2
o Strategic need, management attention and financing constraints cause the
buy-side alternative to put a constraint to the bargaining power
• Sell-side alternative: (1990; 50 companies) contacted on average 63.2 potential
buyers, 28.7 signed confidentiality agreement, 6.3 due diligence or preliminary
proposals, 2.6 submitted binding written offers
o Revlon duties: target and buyer must leave deal unprotected to permit
higher-value offers
• Extent of constraints of alternatives depends on market thickness
o thin market: defenses may provide bargaining power in the takeover
negotiation
o thick market: defenses are less effective (other potential buyer and sellers
contrain bargaining range)
Hostile Bid costs
• introduction of hostile bid costs further reduces the influence of defenses
o target gains bargaining power because bidder is no longer indifferent
between a negotiated acquisition and a hostile bid, holding deal price
constant.
o Hostile bid costs pushes the predicted outcome against a target with no
defenses towards the outcome against a target with complete defenses
o Three categories of hostile bid costs (all reduce the influence of takeover
defenses on the negotiated outcome):
§ Bidder out of pocket costs: additional out-of-pocket expenses: eg.
Financing costs, tender offer information agents, proxy solicitors,
printing and advertising costs, lawyer and banker fees
§ Bidder reputational costs: future targets are less willing to initiate
negotiations with a bidder that has previously made a hostile
takeover bid
§ Costs imposed on target: (makes the target less attractive for the
bidder to acquire) hostile bid causes operational disruption and
make post-deal integration more difficult
o If fixed hostile costs are greater than the width of the bargaining range,
then a hostile bid is structurally precluded → target’s defenses are
irrelevant for the takeover negotiation
o more potent defenses do not necessarily give additional bargaining power

Information disparities

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• a “blind bid” is subject to the well-known “lemons problem” (bidder has likely
overpaid when target accepts offer)
• “standstill agreement”: under such terms the acquirer agrees (for typically 6-12
months) to
o not increase its stake in the target firm
o not conduct a proxy contest
o not make a tender offer for the target’s stock
in exchange the acquirer gains access to target’s internal documents

• if the standstill agreement is the standard quid pro quo for access to confidential
books and records → then takeover defenses are irrelevant in determining the
final price received by the target shareholders

Agency Costs
• if the target board is not loyal to its shareholders it might use bargaining power
provided by takeover defenses to extract private benefits for itself
• any deal that provides a premium to target shareholders can be improved for both
the target and acquirer managers with a deal that provides less value to the
shareholders and some value to the target managers.
• Defenses may allow target managers to extract private benefits for themselves
rather than a higher premium for shareholders
Summary
• Once
o alternatives away from the table
o hostile bid costs
o asymmetric information
o agency costs
• are introduced in the standard bargaining model it becomes clear that takeover
defenses are a potent weapon against a hostile takeover bid BUT are not
important in most negotiated acquistions
Conclusion
• in the base case takeover defenses increase premiums for targets
• when introducing the 4 real-world factors (alternative walk-away, hostile bid
costs, information disparities, agency costs) → only a fraction of acquisitions are
negotiated in the shadow of a hostile takeover threat
• bargaining power benefits of takeover defenses in negotiated acquisitions recede
and the costs of takeover defenses in the from of higher agency costs of
management come to the fore

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Where M&A pays and where it strays (Robert F. Bruner)

Conventional wisdom on M&A Failure: still hazy after all these years

Problems that occure when making inferences about the profitability of M&As:
• Conventional wisdom generalizes too readily the findings of a single study
• Theres is a tendency to exaggerate the extent of failure
o One-in-a-life-time study periods shouldn’t be generalised opver other time
periods
o Difficulties for M&As can also be due to changes in certain industry
segments (eg. Price collapse in the technology-media-telecommunication
sector tgat strated in 2000)
o There are differences in the type of deals (eg. Stock-for-stock deals are
worse than cash deals)
o Size can matter as well (eg. big deals tend to have more intergration and
regulatory problems)
o There are differences between deals two of public companies and deals of
two private company, where the latter seem to be more profitable for the
buyer

An informed “view” of M&As depends on mastering the scientific findings on the


profitability of M&A and on understanding how profitability varies by type of deals and
companies.

Measurements of M&A Profitability: Better than what?

The benchmark for measuring performance is investor’s required returns. There are 3
possible outcomes
• Value destroyed: investment returns are worse than those required by investors
• Value created: investment returns higher than required
• Value is conserved: normal returns (investment earns its required rate of return)
→ in economic terms an investment is “successful” if it does anything other than destroy
value

3 measure to test whether M&A has been profitable:


• Weak form: did the share price rise? This is a before-and-after comparison (are
shareholders better off after the deal than they were before)
o Weak because it fails to control for other unrelated factors that my have
caused price changes
• Semi-strong form: did the firm’s returns exceed a benchmark? Uses a
benchmark like the return in the S&P500 Index, or sample of peers that did not
merge.
o Control for factors in the industry/entire economy that may have triggered
returns
o Only semi-strong because benchmarks are imperfect

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Strong from: “golden standard” of comparison. Are shareholders better off after
the deal than they would have been if the deal had not taken place?
o True test of the cost of lost opportunity
The following studies summarised below are classified as semi-strong

Event studies: examines abnormal returns to shareholders in the period surrounding the
announcement of a transaction.
• Raw return for one day = (change in share price + any dividends paid)/closing
share price the day before
• Abnormal return = raw return – a benchmark of what investors required that day
o Benchmark here is either CAPM or return on large market index
(S&P500)
• Based on the assumption that stock markets are forward looking and that share
prices are simply the present value of expected future cash flows to shareholders

Accounting studies: examine reported financial results (accouting statements) of


acquirers before and after the acquisitions to see how the financial perfomrnace changed
• Study focuses on variables such as net income, return on equity or assets, EPS,
leverage and liquidity
• Matched comparison of acquirers performance against performance of non-
acquirers with similar size in the same industry

Broad finding: M&A Pays

• Abnormal returns to target firm’s shareholder: 25 studies → M&A


transaction delivers a premium return to target firm shareholders (despite time-
period variations, type of deal, and observation periods)
• Abnormal return’s to buyer firm’s shareholders: 50 studies → 40% negative
returns; 60% positive returns
o 16 studies → (returns to buyers in the years over a multi-year period after
the consummation of the transaction). 11 negative and significant returns
o contaminating events, overvalued stock and industry shocks could all
easily mislead into believing that M&A is unprofitable
o buyers are typically larger than targets (impact of smaller deals is difficult
to measure)
o author’s general conclusion from event studies buyers essentially
break even
• abnormal returns to buyer and target firms combined (net economic gain
from M&A deal):
o large %gain to seller can be offset by small% loss to buyer
o almost all of 24 studies report positive returns (14 report significant
positive returns)
• Reported financial performance of buyers: market’s reaction to the
announcement of a given deal tended to be a reasonably reliable predictor of
future operating improvements with more positive reactions anticipating larger
increases in operating cash flows

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Surveys of executives: both practitioners and scholarly studies seem consistent


with the view that although M&A does not produce abnormal returns, investments
in acquisitions tend at least to cover their cost of capital.
• Conclusion about profitability of M&A:
o M&A does pay on average.
o M&A pays for shareholders target firms
o Most studies of target and buyer firms combined indicate that M&A
transactions create net value
o For bidders alone – 2/3 of the studies conclude that value is at least
conserved if not created
All M&A is local

• Joseph Schumpeter: M&A is one way of capitalizing on turbulence


o 1984-1904: industries characterised by capital-intensive, mass production
manufacturing processes. M&A involved with removing older and less
efficient excess capacitiy from these industries
o 1890-1930: M&A associated with the diffusion of electricity and the
internal combustion engine
o 1971-2001: M&A involved the diffusion of information technology
• Micheal Jensen: creation of new markets (eg. High-yield debt market) stimulated
wave of hostile takeover and leveraged buyouts
• Bruce Wasserstein: 5 main forces driving the merger process:
o Regulatory and political reform
o Technological change
o Fluctuations in financial markets
o Role of leadership
o Tension between scale and focus

Where M&A Pays and where it Strays


(buyer’s perspective)

Neighbourhood map 1: Strategy

Focus versus diversification

• Focus versus diversification: “focusing acquisition” pays better than


diversification.
o Opportunity for cost savings
o Asset reduction
o Other efficiencies
• Diversification may pay if
o a single entity facilitates knowledge transfer among different business
divisions
o reduces financing cost
o creates a critical mass for competitiors
o exploits monitoring thorugh internal capital markets

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• diversification may pay when the buyer and the target are in information intensive
industries
• IN sum
o All else equal focus and relatedness pays better than does unrelated
diversification
o Strategy of unrelated diversification can pay where there are unusual skills
such as running an LBO association or value investing (special managerial
skill could trump the need for strategic linkage)
o Acquisition strategy of relatedness and focus warrants critical scrutiny too;
industries are dynamic

Strategic restructuring pays:

• Divestiture create value for shareholders of sellers (results for buyers are mixed)
• Redeployment of underperforming businesses is greeted positively by investors
• Carve-outs, spin-offs and tracking stock are neutral to beneficial for shareholders
with generally consistent abnormal returns
• Continually reshaping the business to respond to changes in the competitive
environment pays

Initiation of M&A programs

• Market’s systematic positive response to M&A announcements

Strategic synergies

• Include cost savings, revenue enhancements, financial synergies


• M&A pays where synergies are more credible

Grabs for market power

• Horizontal mergers are typically motivated by the prospect of cost savings and
other synergies → more efficient is better (bigger is not necessarily better)

Value acquiring pays, glamour acquiring does not

• Glamour acquiring: companies with high book to market value ratios


• Value acquiring: low book to value ratios

Mergers to use excess cash generally destroys value except when redeployed
profitably
• Value destruction associated with the announcemtn of M&A transactions by firms
with access cash
• Transactions pairing “slack-poor” and “slack-rich” companies tend to be value
increasing

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Neighbourhood map 2: Investment Opportunities

Targets that can be restructured


Mixed evidence
• Targets of hostile tender offers are underperformers with relatively low share
price → bidders expect to earn profits form improving the targets performance
• Targets are healthy but fit very well with the buyer’s strategy

Privately owned assets

• Sizable positive announcement-day return to bidders when they buy private firms
opposed to public firms

Crossing borders

• Targets earn large returns, buyers essentially break-even; on a combined basis


shareholders gain
• Foreign bidders appear to pay more than domestic bidders
o Premium represents payment for the special local knowledge and market
access that the target provides the foreign buyer

Hot and cold M&A markets: misevaluation of buyer firms

• Market “windows of opportunity” close and open over time


o Due to changes in regulation and ..
o ..the appearance of market bubbles
• the more highly valued the buyer the more negative is the investor response to the
acquisition announcement
• Hot M&A market poses a major dilemma to CEO of an overvalued company:
o If you acquire or not, shares will drop
o M&A offers chance to transfer part of prospective losses to target firm
shareholders

Neighbourhood map 3: Deal Design:

From of payment: cash versus stock

• Stock based deals are associated negative returns to the buyer’s shareholders at
deal announcements, whereas cash deals are zero or slightly positive
• Announcement of the payment with share, like the announcement of an offering
of seasoned stock, could be taken as a sign that managers believe the firm’s are
overpriced
• Tender offers amplify the cash-versus-stock effect (cash effect even higher; stock
effect even lower)
• Stock deals also tend to be used
o In friendly deals

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o Buyer’s stock price is relatively high


o Ownership pf buyer is not concentrated
o Deals are larger in size
o Buyer has less cash
LBOs

• Shareholders of target companies earn large abnormal returns


• LBOs transactions are followed by large increases of operating Cash Flow
relative to sales and decreases in capital expenditure

Use of earnouts

• Eranouts and other contingent payment structures can be viewed as providing


stronger performance incentives for selling managers as well as risk management
device for the buyer

Use of collars

• Collar = another risk management device, used in stock-for-stock transactions to


hedge uncertainty about the value of the buyer.
o Changes payments if buyer’s payment rises or falls

Social issues: the merger of equals

• Combined partners of equal influence without a premium payment by one party to


the other (usually mergers by an exchange of shares with a low or zero implied
acquisition premium)
• Targets earn positive abnormal returns that are also smaller than those in other
deals
• Absence of dominance from one side over the other helps to reduce resistance of
target company

Tax exposure

• Half of all acquisitions (study in 1989) are designed to be tax-free or only partly
taxable
• In taxable deals the acquisition premium is more than twice as high
o In taxable deals target company shareholders’ taxes are due immediately
rather than deferred → creates demand for higher payment
o In taxable deals, the buyer is allows to “step up” the tax basis of the
acquired assets (affording a larger depreciation tax shield)

Neighbourhood map 4: Governance:

Governance:

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• Firms with stronger governance practices are more highly valued

Activism by institutional investors

• = (seeking influence in the board of directors and management) LBOs,


replacement of executives underperforming firms, corporate restructuring
• is associated with creation of shareholder value

What managers have at stake

• return to buyer firm’s shareholder is associated with larger equity interests by


managers and employees (transactions under management control influenced
ultimate payoffs from takeover)
• In LBOs managers tend to commit a large portion of their own net worth to the
success of the transaction

Approaching the target: friendly versus hostile

• Larger return to bidders in tender offers than in friendly negotiated transactions


• Higher acquisition premiums for target shareholders in hostile deals
• Unsuccessful takeover attempts often lead to restructurings that unlock value for
shareholders

Use of anti-takeover defenses

• Can help to extract higher prices (only in well-governed compaies)


• Can harm shareholders in purely run firms by entrenching mangers who disregard
their duty to shareholders

Conclusion

• All M&A is local


• You are more likely to fail in M&A when:
o Your organisation enters a fundamentally unprofitable industry or refuses
to exit from one
o Your organisation steps away from what it knows
§ Diversification versus relatedness (but more relevant is knowledge,
mastery and competencies)
o Economic benefits of the deal are improbable or not incremental to the
deal (eg. synergies)
o You fail to seek economic advantage (eg. Paying a premium for a target in
a foreign country)
o There is no creativity in deal-structuring
o Your organisation has poor checks, balances and incentives
• LAST PAGE of the article summarises it in a list of bullet points) J

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Leveraged  Buyouts  and  Private  Equity  


 Kaplan  and  Strömberg  
 
Leveraged  Buyout  -­‐  Definition  
• firm   is   acquired   by   specialized   investment   firm   using   small   portion   of   equity   and   high  
leverage  
• investment  firms  commonly  referred  to  as  private  equity  firms  
• typically  majority  control  of  existing/mature  firm  is  acquired  
 
History/Development  
• emerged  in  1980s,  first  wave  
• highlight  of  first  boom:  buyout  of  RJR  Nabisco  in  1988  
• Jensen  (1989)  predicts  that  LBO/PE  firms  would  become  dominant  corporate  organizational  
form  
o PE  firms  combine  concentrated  ownership  stakes,  high-­‐powered  incentives  for  own  
professionals,  and  lean,  efficient  organization  with  minimal  overhead  costs  
o applying   performance-­‐based   managerial   compensation,   high-­‐leverage   capital  
structures  (often  relying  on  junk  bonds,)  active  governance  to  invested  firm  
o superior   structure   compared   to   typical   public   corporation   with   dispersed  
shareholders,  low  leverage,  weak  corporate  governance  
• crash  of  junk  bond  market  led  to  large  number  of  defaults  and  bankruptcies  of  high-­‐profile  
Buyouts  
• LBOs  of  public  companies  virtually  non-­‐existent  in  early  1990  to  early  2000s  
• PE  firms  focus  on  purchasing  private  companies  
• third  LBO  boom  in  mid-­‐2000s,  including  public-­‐to-­‐private  buyouts  
• decline  in  2008  after  subprime-­‐crisis  
 
PE  Firms  
• typically  organized  as  partnership  or  limited  liability  corporation  (LLC)  
• most  prominent:  Blackstone,  Carlyle,  KKR  
• in  1980s,  rather  small  number  of  professionals  in  PE  firms  (13)  
• these  days,  PE  firms  have  more  than  100  investment  professionals  
 
PE  funds  
• PE  firms  raise  equity  through  PE  funds  
• PE  funds  typically  "closed-­‐end",  i.e.  fixed  number  of  shares  
• investors  commit  to  provide  equity  for  investments  and  management  fees  of  PE  firm  
• Legal:  PE  funds  are  limited  partnerships  
o general  partner  (the  PE  firm)  manages  fund,  provides  at  least  1%  of  capital  
o limited  partners  provide  most  of  the  capital  
o limited   partners:   institutional   investors,   corporate/public   pension   funds,  
endowments,  insurance  companies,  wealthy  individuals  
• usually  fixed  life  (common  are  10  years),  but  possible  extension  of  up  to  3  years  
• PE   firm   has   up   to   5   years   to   invest   the   funds   capital   and   5-­‐8   years   to   return   capital   to  
investors  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• limited  partners  have  little  say  as  long  as  basic  covenants  are  followed  
• common   covenants:   limited   investment   in   one   company,   types   of   securities,   restriction   of  
debt  at  the  fund  level  
• compensation  of  general  partner  (PE  firm)  
o annual   management   fee:   percentage   of   capital   committed   and   after   realization   of  
investments  a  percentage  of  capital  employed  
o share  of  the  profits  of  the  fund  (carried  interests),  typically  20  %  
o deal   and   monitoring   fees   (sometimes   paid   by   portfolio   companies,   i.e.   firms   that   the  
fund  invested  in)  
 
PE  transaction/LBO  procedure  
• after   buy-­‐decision,   PE   firms   typically   pay   premium   of   15-­‐50%   over   current   stock   price   for  
public  companies  
• 60-­‐90%  of  debt  financing  (-­‐>  Leveraged  BO)  
• debt  structure  
o senior  and  secure  debt  -­‐  arranged  by  bank  or  investment  bank;  in  1980s  and  1990s  
often   provided   by   banks;   recently,   institutional   investors   purchase   large   fraction   of  
senior  and  secured  loans  
o junior   and   unsecured   debt   -­‐   financed   via   high-­‐yield   bonds   or   "mezzanine   debt"   (debt  
subordinated  to  senior  debt)  
• capital  from  limited  partners  used  as  equity  to  cover  the  remaining  10-­‐40%  
• new  management  team  of  purchased  company  (can  be  identical  to  pre-­‐buyout  management,  
but  does  not  necessarily  have  to  be)  typically  contributes  small  fraction  to  equity  
 
Commitments  to  PE  funds  (US)  
• 200  million  USD  in  1980  
• 200  billion  USD  in  2007  (1%  of  US  stock  market  value)  
• PE  commitments  appear  to  be  cyclical  
o first  wave  1980s  to  early  1990s,  peak  in  1988  
o second  wave  mid  1990s  to  early  2000s,  peak  in  1998  
o "third  wave"  mid  2000s  to  present,  peak  in  2007/8  
• Commitment  outside  the  US  have  also  grown  substantially  (3  non-­‐US  PE  firms  among  top  12  
firms  in  terms  of  assets  under  management)  
 
Number  of  PE  transactions  
• 17,171  transaction  between  1/1/19970  and  6/30/2007  
• seems  to  be  cyclical  like  commitments  to  PE  funds  (logical!)  
• huge  fraction  of  activity  within  last  few  years  
• first   wave   almost   exclusively   in   US,   Canada,   UK:   relatively   large   transaction   in   mature  
industries  (manufacturing,  retail),  public-­‐to-­‐private  
• after   first   wave,   growth   in   "middle-­‐market"   buyouts   of   non-­‐publicly   traded   firms   (private  
companies/divisions  of  larger  corporations)  and  spread  to  new  industries  (IT,  media,  telecom,  
financial  services,  health  care)  
• during  and  after  second  wave  
o return  of  public-­‐to-­‐private  buyouts  (though  not  as  prominent  as  before)  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o increasing   fraction   of   secondary   buyouts   (i.e.   PE   firms   exiting   old   investments   and  
selling  portfolio  companies  to  other  PE  firms)    
o spread  to  Europe  
• third  wave  magnified  many  of  these  trends,  also  spread  to  Asia  (modest  levels  compared  to  
Western  Europe  and  N.  America)  
 
Manner  and  Timing  of  Exit  
• investment  exit  important  due  to  limited  contractual  lifetime  of  PE  funds  
• types  of  exits  (in  order  of  occurrence):  
o sale  to  strategic  (nonfinancial)  buyer  
o secondary  buyout,  i.e.  sale  to  other  PE  firm  
o IPO  
o other/unknown  (could  be  any  of  the  mentioned  types)  
o bankruptcy  
o sale  to  management  
• holding  periods  roughly  stable,  median  is  around  6  years  
• keep   in   mind   that   secondary   buyouts   mean   that   portfolio   companies   are   still   held   by   PE  
funds  
 
 
 
PE  as  superior  organizational  form?  
 
Financial,  governance,  and  operational  engineering  
• PE  firms  pay  attention  to  management  incentives  
o typically  large  equity  upside  through  stock  and  options  
o management   ownership   increased   by   factor   4   from   going   from   public   to   private  
(Kaplan  1989b)  
o PE  firms  require  management  to  make  meaningful  investment  in  the  company  
o stocks    (equity)and  options  given  to  management  are  illiquid  as  company  is  private,  
i.e.   management   can't   sell   equity   or   exercise   options   until   value   is   proved   by   exit  
transaction  →  reduces  incentive  to  manipulate  short-­‐term  performance  
• leverage  
o pressure  on  managers  not  to  waste  money  as  they  have  to  pay  interest  and  principal,  
i.e.  reduction  of  FCF  problem  
o provides  discipline  to  acquiring  PE  fund  which  has  to  persuade  third-­‐party  investors  
(debt  providers)  to  co-­‐invest  in  deals  
o leverage  potentially  increases  firm  value  through  tax  deductibility  of  interest  
o flipside:  inflexibility  of  required  debt  payments  (in  contrast  to  flexibility  of  payments  
to  equity)  increases  chance  of  costly  financial  distress  
• governance  
o PE  firms  control  boards  of  their  portfolio  companies  and  are  more  actively  involved  
in  governance  then  public  company  boards  
o boards  of  portfolio  companies  are  smaller  and  meet  more  frequently  
o PE  firm  do  not  hesitate  to  replace  poorly  performing  management  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

• operational  engineering  
o PE  firms  often  focused  on  certain  industries  
o PE   firms   use   their   industry   and   operating   knowledge   to   identify   attractive  
investments,   develop   and   implement   value   creation   plans   (add   value   to   portfolio  
companies)  
o make  use  of  internal  or  external  consulting  groups  (or  individuals)  
 
Operating  performance  
• empirical  evidence  on  operating  performance  of  companies  purchased  by  PE  firms  is  largely  
positive  
• Cumming,   Siegel,   and   Wright   (2007)   summarizes:   "LBOs   and   especially   MBOs   enhance  
performance  and  have  a  salient  effect  on  work  practices"  
• exception:  more  recent  public-­‐to-­‐private  buyouts  only  show  modest  increase  in  performance  
• possible  sources  for  misinterpretation:  selection  bias,  LBOs  might  increase  current  cash  flow  
but  hurt  future  cash  flow  
• however,  empirical  evidence  largely  consistent  with  existence  of  operating  and  productivity  
improvements  after  LBOs  
• no  research  on  latest  PE  (third  or  fourth)  wave  
 
Employment  
• Critics:  LBOs  benefit  PE  investors  at  the  expense  of  employees  (job  and  wage  cuts)  
• empirical  evidence  shows  that  employment  increases  post-­‐buyout,  yet  by  less  compared  to  
other  firms  in  the  industry  
• evidence  largely  consistent  with  view  that  economic  value  is  created  in  portfolio  companies  
by  operating  more  efficiently  (due  to  buyout)  
 
Taxes  
• tax  deductions  are  difficult  to  value  accurately  
• can   explain   between   4%   (debt   is   repaid   in   8   years   and   personal   taxes   offset   benefit   of  
corporate  tax  deductions)  and  40%  (permanent  debt  and  no  offset  due  to  personal  taxes)  of  
a  firm's  value  
• true   value   probably   lies   in   between;   reasonable   estimate   seems   to   be   10   to   20%   (1980s),  
lower  for  more  recent  buyouts  
 
Asymmetric  Information  
• PE  firms  potentially  have  superior  information  on  future  performance  of  portfolio  companies  
• Critics:  possible  source  of  inside  information  is  the  incumbent  management  
o incumbent   management   works   "better"   under   new   owners   (PE   firm)   due   to   higher  
incentives  
• empirical   evidence   suggests   that   operating   improvements   are   unlikely   a   result   of   PE   firms  
taking  advantage  of  private  information  
o actual  performance  of  portfolio  companies  lags  the  forecasts  by  the  PE  firm  
o PE   firms   frequently   bring   new   management:   incumbent   management   can't   be   sure  
that  it  will  be  in  a  position  to  receive  high-­‐powered  incentives  from  new  owners  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o boom-­‐and-­‐bust   cycle:   at   times,   PE   firms   overpaid   in   LBOs   and   experienced   losses  


(inside   information   by   incumbent   management   wasn't   enough   to   avoid   periods   of  
poor  returns)  
• instead:  large  financial  returns  to  PE  funds  because  PE  firms  are  able  to  buy  low  and  sell  high  
o PE   firms   identify   undervalued   companies/industries   (taking   advantage   of   market  
timing  and  mispricing)  
o PE  firms  are  good  negotiators  and/or  target  boards  and  management  do  not  get  best    
possible  price  in  these  acquisitions  
 
PE  fund  returns  
• value   creation   by   PE   firms   through   LBOs   does   not   imply   that   PE   firms   generate   superior  
returns  for  limited  partners  
o portfolio  companies  are  purchased  in  competitive  auctions  or  by  paying  premium  to  
public  shareholders  
o limited  partners  pay  meaningful  (considerable  amount  of)  management  fees  
o net  return  for  limited  partners  lower  than  return  of  portfolio  company  for  PE  fund  
• Kaplan  and  Schoar  (2005)  
o  limited  partners  (investors  in  PE  funds)  earn  slightly  less  than  SP500,  net  of  fees;  this  
suggests  that,  gross  of  fees,  they  outperform  the  benchmark  
o their  research  has  two  flaws:  selection  bias,  no  risk  adjustment  
o persistence   in   performance:   performance   of   PE   firm   in   one   fund   predicts  
performance  of  subsequent  funds  
 
Boom  and  Bust  Cycles  in  PE  
• Boom  when  there  is  systematic  mispricing  in  debt  and  equity  markets  
o cost  of  debt  is  relatively  low  compared  to  cost  of  equity  
o PE  firms  can  arbitrage  or  benefit  from  difference  
o this  argument  relies  on  existence  of  market  frictions  that  enable  debt/equity  markets  
to  become  segmented  
• overly  favorable  terms  for  debt  during  first  wave  led  to  high  leverage  (only  10-­‐15%  equity)  
• less  favorable  terms  for  debt  during  second  wave  lead  to  higher  equity  share  (30%)  
• cyclicality  can  also  be  explained  by  looking  at  interest  rates  
• debt   in   LBOs   may   be   driven   more   by   credit   market   conditions   than   by   relative   benefits   of  
leverage  for  portfolio  firm  
• PE  funds  accelerate  investment  pace  when  interest  rates  are  low  
• question:   why   do   borrowings   of   public   firms   not   follow   credit   market   cycles   like   LBOs?  
possible  explanations  
o public  firms  are  unwilling  to  take  advantage  of  debt  pricing  because  managers  dislike  
debt  or  public  market  investors  worry  about  high  debt  levels  
o PE  funds  have  better  access  to  credit  markets  because  they  are  repeated  borrowers  
(reputation  building=cheaper  loans  and  looser  covenants)  
o compensation   structures   of   PE   funds   provide   incentives   to   take   on   more   debt   than  
optimal  for  individual  firm  
• PE   fund   returns   decline   when   more   capital   is   committed   to   this   asset   class   (Boom),  
commitments  to  PE  funds  decline  when  realized  returns  decline  (Bust)  →  cycle  pattern  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

When managers bypass shareholder approval of board appointments:

Evidence from the security market

By Matteo Arena and Stephen Ferri, 15th May 2007

Abstract:

Examine influence of managerial entrenchment to appoint board members without shareholder (sh)
approval. The bigger entrenchment the more likely is shareholder bypassing and the less likely is
announcement of independent director. Aim of bypassing: Perpetuate managerial entrenchment.

Introduction:

• Private placements in which representatives of private investors are appointed to the Board go
hand in hand with lower announcement return
• Why do managers bypass approval? 3 Hypothesis:
• Entrenchment hypothesis: Entrenched manager appoints friendly investor, who is aligned with
current management and who is unlikely to provide tough monitoring to board, the more likely it
is that shareholders oppose his candidate
• Approval irrelevance hypothesis: Managers do not need to bypass approval; shareholders almost
always vote for managers candidates due to proxy committee is appointed by management board
• Monitoring Hypothesis: Private investor wants board position when he should provide more
capital; based on poor corporate governance

Role of shareholder voting in Corporate Governance

• Connection between ownership and control


• Voting rights are alternative to contracts, since in contracts not every part can be foreseen; Voting
rights can be used to ratify decision ex-post
• The more diffuse ownership is the less likely is shareholders incentive to vote or influence
corporate decision; The more routine proposal is classified the more likely is sh’s approval

How do firms appoint directors without sh approval?

Private security issuance without sh approval

• Number of authorized shares in certificate of corporation is larger than outstanding shares


• Blank checked preferred stock provision (Directors can issue preferred stock)
• Issuing convertible notes

But if new issuance in larger than 20% of common stock or is sold at an discount, approval is needed!

Board appointment without sh approval

1. Bylaw does require only range for directors’ amount (e.g. between 5 to 10 directors’). Current
directors can appoint new director till upper limit of range (e.g. if there only 5 directors, additional
5 directors can be appointed). If upper limit range is reached, directors can easily change bylaw
2. Replacement for fired director

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

3. Issuance of Blank Checked Preferred Securities to new investors to elect new director; if the
already exist in charter no extra sh approval is needed
4. If director is already elected, sh can ratify decisions. If board is not staggered election within
12months/if board is staggered - sh might have to wait up to 3 years to ratify director.

Relation between approval of security issuance and approval of board appointments

If company does not have Blank Checked Preferred Stock provision, directors have to as sh for approval
of issuance. Simultaneously sh permit board to appoint new director.

Data

185 private placements of US firms associated with Private Announcments

• Firms that issue convertible preferred shares and appoint more directors are more likely to ask for
sh approval
• On average 1,89 directors are appointed within a Private Placement: 25% change of board
composition
• Firms that don’t ask for approval a smaller, younger and distribute less equity to investors
• Entrenched managers are more likely to bypass sh approval

Determinants of sh approval

• Results are consistent with Entrenchment Hypothesis and Monitoring Hypothesis


è Firms are more likely to bypass sh approval, a) the higher free Cash Flow and b) whether
board chairman is a company manager

Monitoring quality of appointed directors

Entrenchment hypothesis: Managers tend to appoint directors who won’t provide effective monitoring

Approval irrelevance hypothesis: Quality of newly elected directors does not depend on sh approval

Monitoring Hypothesis: Firms that bypass sh approval, will increase board’s monitoring quality

How to test quality of directors? Monitoring effectiveness depends on how many appointed directors are
independent (Number of independent directors is positively related to likelihood of removal of poorly
performing CEO)

Results are confirm with Entrenchment Hypothesis

Market reaction at the time of announcement

Entrenchment hypothesis: Announcement should show less entrenchmentà positive market reaction

Approval irrelevance hypothesis: No effect in market return, since approval is irrelevant

Monitoring Hypothesis: Not very positive market reaction

The analysis adjusts abnormal returns, since usually Private Equity is sold at discount (purchaser should
contribute positively to target firm or should maintain managerial entrenchment)

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Results: Market strongly rewards director announcement for sh approval. Consistent with Entrenchment
hypothesis.

Does sh approval impact performance?

Entrenchment hypothesis: predicts firms asking for sh approval, perform better  

Approval irrelevance hypothesis: predicts, approval does not affect firm’s performance  

Monitoring Hypothesis: predicts: firms asking for approval (to give new investor board position)
underperform firms bypassing sh approval

Operating Performance: Firms seeking for sh approval perform better within 3 years than bypassing firms
(Entrenchment Hypothesis)

Stock Performance: Firms seeking for sh approval outperform bypassing firms

Conclusion, bitches:

1. The greater managerial entrenchment the more likely bypassing sh approval  


2. Positive market reaction after seeking sh approval  
3. In general, entrenchment has more influence on Private Placement than previously believed  
4. Entrenched managers are more likely to nominate directors who are aligned  
5. But: Managers can still easily avoid sh approval and neutralize sh monitoring. Sh still do not have
enough power (although sh can replace directors) to secure “Value-increasing governments
arrangements that management disfavors”.  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

Private  Placements  and  Managerial  Entrenchment  -­‐  Micheal  J.  Barclay,  Clifford  G.  Holderness,  Dennis  
P.  Shehan  

Private  Placements:    The  sale  of  securities  to  a  rather  small  number  of  selected  investors.  

è Private  placements  more  favorable  than  public  stock  offerings  


è Two  hypothesizes  explaining  the  positive  assessment:  

Monitoring  Hypothesis   Certification  Hypothesis  


Private  placements  are  purchased  by  large   Private  placements  are  purchased  by  informed  
investors  who  are  willing  and  able  to:     investors    who  certify  the  value  of  the  entity  by  
1. monitor  the  management   purchasing  large  blocks  of  stock  
2. ensure  efficient  use  of  resources  
3. increase  likelihood  of  value  enhancing  
takeovers  
 

è One  Hypothesis  against  the  favorable  outlook:    

Entrenchment  Hypothesis  
Managers  sell  stock  to  selected  friendly  investors  
who  might  not  act  in  the  best  interest  of  the  
shareholders  à  do  not  “rock  the  boat”  
 

Three  Types  of  Placement:  

Private  Placements  separated  into  three  groups:  

1. Placement  in  which  the  purchaser  is  active  in  the  firms  
2. Placement  in  which  the  purchase  is  top  manager  of  the  firm  
3. Placement  were  purchaser  plays  a  passive  role  in  the  firm  à  no  active  role  in  the  company  

Results:  

Empirical  Results  in  line  with  the  Monitoring  and  Certification  Hypothesis:  

-­‐ Short  run  discount  à    to  compensate  for  the  monitoring  cost  and  certification  of  firm  value  
 
-­‐ Positive  short  run  return  after  the  announcement    à  investors  perceive  the  placement  to  be  
favorable  

Empirical  Results  in  line  with  the  Entrenchment  Hypothesis:  

-­‐              Most  private  placements  acquired  by  passive  investors  

-­‐ Magnitude  of  Discount  à  price  discount  is  higher  for  passive  than  for  active  purchasers    
 

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

-­‐ Discounts  increase  with  the  fraction  placed  and  purchased  by  aforementioned  passive  investors  
à  monitoring  and  certification  costs  are  fixed,  thus  discount  should  decline  with  size  
 
-­‐ Decline  in  long  run  returns  à    for  passive  and  active  investors  
o However,  positive  long  run  return  for  managerial  placements  à  entrenchment  theory  
states  that  managers  issue  stock  to  themselves  when  the  stock  price  is  undervalued  
 
-­‐ Returns  decrease  with  higher  fraction  placed  
 
-­‐ Return  decreases  with  increase  in  discount  
 
-­‐ Purchaser  rarely  becomes  director  or  CEO  à  evidence  against  monitoring  hypothesis  
 
-­‐ Probability  of  takeover  decrease  with  placement  à  in  conflict  with  the  monitoring  hypothesis  
 
-­‐ No  public  reports  on  monitoring  à  no  reason  to  hide  monitoring  reports    
 
-­‐ Comparison  to  block  trades  :    negotiated  purchases  of  shares  from  other  shareholders  
o Block  trades  presage  monitoring  
o On  average  shareholder  favor  block  trades  over  private  placements  à  (lower  discount,  
short  and  long-­‐run  abnormal  return)  

Conclusion:  

-­‐ Total  cost  of  private  placements  (include  discount  +  out  of  the  pocket  costs:  transaction  costs)  is  
two  times  higher  than  for  Seasoned  Equity  Offerings  à  nevertheless,  no  control  of  who  
purchases  the  shares  
-­‐ Positive  announcement  effect  à  however,  neither  the  monitoring  nor  the  certification  
hypothesis  can  explain  the  negative  long  run  returns  
In  Summary:  
-­‐ Support  for  monitoring  and  certification  hypothesis  much  weaker  
-­‐ Strong  and  significant  evidence  for  the  entrenchment  hypothesis  
 
è All  in  all,  theories  regarding  agency  problems  (agency  explanations)  should  be  incorporated  more  
strongly  and  carefully  into  capital  structure  decisions  

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

The impact of corporate governance mechanisms on value increase in


leveraged buyouts
By Erkki Nikoskelainen, Mike Wright

Topic: Value increase of buyout targets and realized value increase in exited leveraged
buyouts

Prior studies:

• Gains in productivity and operating performance


• Buyout markets outside the US
• Free cash flow theory
o Leveraged buyouts à corporate governance mechanisms à reduce agency
costs à increase firm value through improved operating efficiency
• Bankruptcy threat motivates improved operating efficiency
• Leverage and realignment of incentives à positive effect on operating
performance
• Concentrated ownership à ability to monitor and control

Three contributions of the paper:

1) Adds to limited previous research on investor returns in buyouts


2) Extension of several studies on the staying power and survival of buyouts by
providing empirical evidence concerning the relation between corporate governance
structure and a positive return at investment realization.
3) Adds to studies on buyout success examining that return characteristics are different
for buyouts and buyins.

The type of buyout can impact buyout performance:

Buyouts by definition are transactions initiated and led by the incumbent management team of
the target whereas buyins are leveraged buyout transactions initiated and led by private equity
investors together with partially or completely new management team

è Informational asymmetry between buyouts and buyins.


o Buyins involve outsiders with potential consequences for performance

Internal rate of return:

• Return on enterprise value and equity investments is measured by an index-adjusted


IRR.
• Index adjusted EV IRR 22.2% vs. index adjusted EQ IRR 70.5%; correlation of 0.62
showing much variation between these two measures.
• Exit strategies (a way of cashing out):

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

o Under favorable economic conditions, exit opportunities are better due to


active IPO and M&A markets
o IPO (going public)
o Trade sale (sale to strategic investor)
o Secondary offering (selling own stake on the market)
o Receivership (recoup as much of the unpaid loans as possible, liquidation)

Variables for corporate governance mechanisms

1. Gearing (leverage) = D/E ratio


2. The less equity is invested, the greater the equity ownership the management receives
(stronger incentives)
3. Several control variables like size, divestments, acquisitions etc.

Empirical results:

• The return earned on a buyout investment at exit depends to a large extent on exit type
à exit type and decision depend on the need for investment realization and capital
market situations
• For buyouts, size and acquisitions are important drives of returns.

Robustness

• Private equity investors who invest in a large number of small LBOs often invest in
buyouts that go bankrupted.
• Overleveraging of the target companies leads to lower returns.

Conclusion:

• IPO exits outperform trade sale and secondary buyout exits.


o Larger size, highest returns
• Buyouts generate value creation and equity value.
• Managerial equity stake is more related to enterprise value based measures than to
equity based measures.
o Especially in smaller firms
• Governance mechanism are not necessarily the drivers for LBO returns
o For large/successful LBOs management’s equity stake is a driver for LBO
returns
• Size is positively related to value increase
• Acquisitions during the holding period are main drivers for LBO returns
• Larger buyouts perform better à higher investors returns
o Due to higher bankruptcy risk for small LBOs
o Small firms are vulnerable to industry cycles and short term disturbances
o Larger companies have better buffers
o Larger companies have more than one business line à absorb negative shocks
o Investing institutions provide more assistance to large corporations since they
have more equity at risk

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)


lOMoARcPSD|3637180

§ Supporting through more equity injections for operations and fulfilling


covenants
• Acquisitions increase the buyout value and enterprise value.
o Buy-and-build strategies are common
o Acquisitions are used as mechanism to increase scale à lower risk
o Acquisitions as sign of industry consolidation à lower competition à
economies of scale
• Buyout vs buyin returns
o Buyout returns are driven by acquisitions
o Buyout equity returns are negatively affected by divestments
o Buyin equity returns are positively affected by divestments
è Private equity firms applying institutional buyins can drive their returns through
streamlining of target company operations

Realize growth opportunities rather than focus on downsizing.

Downloaded by Alayou Tefera (alayoute@gmail.com)

You might also like