You are on page 1of 13

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/237078258

Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation

Chapter · January 2006


DOI: 10.1007/978-3-7908-1751-5_26

CITATIONS READS

4 49

2 authors:

Piergiorgio Lovaglio Giorgio Vittadini


Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca
70 PUBLICATIONS   602 CITATIONS    120 PUBLICATIONS   1,048 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Health Economics View project

human capital and education View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Piergiorgio Lovaglio on 24 January 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Human Capital Growth
for University Education Evaluation

Pietro Giorgio Lovaglio, Giorgio Vittadini1


Statistics Department, University of Milan-Bicocca, Italy

Summary. In this paper, we propose a method for the evaluation of relative


and impact external efficiency of university studies as effects of education on
the long-term income of graduates. In order to evaluate the “ceteris paribus”
levels and growth we applied a multilevel longitudinal model with random ef-
fects. The variables used in our analysis refer to Human Capital studies. The
Bank of Italy has collected the data used for the analysis in the years 1998,
2000 and 2002.
Keywords. External efficiency, Human capital, Multilevel growth model.

1. The external efficiency of university studies

The organizations that distribute services of public utility, as managers of col-


lective resources, must account for their performances to the funding authori-
ties, the community, and the customers (Hanushek, 1997).
Guidelines are being delineated, at national and international levels, for the
accreditation of university education and research programmes, and services
for the students. The university accreditation processes should not only meet
the ex-ante requirements, but also verify the results.
To evaluate an educational institution, we adopt the outline put forward by
Lockheed & Hanushek’s (1994). The inputs of the system determine whether
the terms "efficiency" or "effectiveness" should be used. The outputs of the
system determine whether the descriptors "internal" or "external" are to be ap-
plied to efficiency and effectiveness (Table 1).

1
This paper is the result of the joint effort of both the authors. G. Vittadini took care of
the final editing of Section 1, whereas P.G. Lovaglio was responsible for all the other
Sections.
356 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

Table 1. Criteria of evaluation for university education

Internal External

INTERNAL EFFECTIVENESS: EXTERNAL EFFECTIVENESS:


University/type of bachelor pro- University/ type of bachelor pro-
Effectiveness
gramme effect on the student gramme effect on employment
achievement Short term Human Capital
EXTERNAL EFFICIENCY
INTERNAL EFFICIENCY : University/ type of bachelor pro-
Efficiency Costs-benefit analysis of the in- gramme effect on the returns of
vestment in higher education investment in higher education
Long term Human Capital

The internal effectiveness and efficiency can be used to self-evaluation of


universities, while the external ones may be the most proper way for evaluat-
ing the universities’ performances (Elias, 2002). As of today, there are very
few studies of the analysis of external efficiency of education based on the
evaluation of the earned income of graduates in the vital cycle. In the follow-
ing, we will define and apply the criteria for the evaluation of organizations
that distribute public utility services.
The investment in higher education may be evaluated in terms of the gradu-
ates’ earned income. In other words, we can evaluate the so-called Human
Capital (HC) of an individual in terms of his or her expected earned income
related to the competences achieved through education (Becker, 1964).
In the following, the evaluation of the university education does not coin-
cide with the estimation of HC, but with the following aims: to evaluate “ce-
teris paribus” the universities’ investment in HC with returns in terms of
earned income (relative efficiency), and if and how the university education is
a real advantage in monetary terms (impact of efficiency).

2. Gain score, added value, and multilevel growth model

In order to overcome the problem of “selection bias” (Garen, 1984) due to


lack of randomization of the individuals between treatments, the effectiveness
and efficiency must be evaluated ceteris paribus, i.e. adjusting the outcome
for the different individual characteristics, university resources, and local job
markets (Fitz-Gibbon, 1997; Scheerens & Bosker, 1997).
To this aim, even if a linear model may be applied, the nature of the de-
pendent variable suggests non-linear approaches. To this purpose, we intro-
duce the concepts of initial performance or pre-test (y1), final status or post-
test (y2), as well as the concept of improvement or gain (y2-y1).
Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation 357

In the gain score approach the “adjusted outcome” is simply the expected
value of gain, E(y2-y1), whereas the added value or residual gain score ap-
proach2 is concerned with the quantity y2-E(y2/y1), i.e. the difference between
the post-test and its expected value E(y2/y1), a result of the regression of y2
onto y1.
Both approaches present some drawbacks. Some researchers highlight the
technical problems associated with the residual gain score approach (Cronbach
& Furby, 1970; Scheerens & Bosker, 1997; Hanushek, 1997, 2002; Willett,
1988; Thum, 2002). First, it is reasonable to expect that the same set of factors
affecting the pre-test would affect the post-test as well. Like the post-test, the
pre-test is measured with error, so that a regression of post-test on a pre-test
score violates the basic regression assumption that covariates are error-free.
This implies that the residual gain score is an inefficient and inconsistent esti-
mator of true change. Secondly, because the pre-test typically explains a large
quota of the post-test outcome, this drastic reduction of residual variance lim-
its the explicative power of other factors, for example the resources of the or-
ganization, its quality and so on.
Other researchers (Rogosa et al., 1982; Rogosa & Willet, 1985; Rogosa,
1995; Singer & Willet, 2003) dispel the notion that gain scores are inherently
unreliable, so demonstrating that the correlation between gain and initial status
(the major drawback of the gain score approach) is merely an artefact of the
design. The nature of the correlation is the outcome of the parameterization we
choose for the growth factors and, as a consequence, the meaning itself we at-
tach to them.
Thum (2002) and Bryk et al. (1998) propose to measure the outcomes in
time series in a longitudinal framework, an approach that allows insertion of
covariates related to the institutions that can affect the performances of the
micro units (students, classes). The repeated measurement approach we adopt
in this paper places the pre-test and the post-test on an equal footing in that
both serve as outcomes in our models. The change with respect to gain scores
is evident in recent research (Collins, 1996; Maris, 1998; Mellenbergh, 1999;
Williams & Zimmerman, 1996).
The second development, known as “hierarchical", “multilevel", “growth”
or “mixed-effects" modelling, provides the methodological complement for a
proper, flexible, treatment of growth data in stratified sampling designs that
are common in educational research settings (repeated measures on students
over time, students nested with schools in the district, etc.).

2
Its origins can be traced to notions of goods, value and wealth in political economy
(Saunders, 1999); value-added analyses address a model for comparison (Goldstein &
Spiegelhalter, 1996) adjusted for the factors out of control for the researchers. Research-
ers have frequently applied the regression analysis of the post-test score on the pre-test
score, motivating this choice with the notion of “fairness" in order to flatten the playing
ground (Good et al. 1975).
358 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

Multilevel models facilitate the study of the effects of covariates of devel-


opment at every level of nesting (Laird & Ware, 1982; Bryk & Raudenbush,
1992; Goldstein, 1995). The advent of multilevel models helped accountability
agencies to avoid the misleading picture conveyed by aggregate scores, such
as the school or district means, and focus on student level and/or change
(Meyer, 1996). Many current accountability systems adopt multilevel models
(Bryk et al., 1998).
A Multilevel Growth Model (MGM) analyses random effects in the sense
that intercept and slopes describing individual trajectories over time vary be-
tween individuals (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992). Such a model requires a speci-
fication of the covariance structure between observations at different times on
the same subject, because it is plausible to assume that observations on the
same unit are correlated (Willett, 1988).
There are two fixed effect factors, treatment and time. Random effects re-
sult from variation between subjects and from variation within subjects.
Measures on the same subject at different times are usually correlated, with
measures taken close in time being more highly correlated than measures
taken far apart. Observations on different subjects are assumed independent,
although the validity of this assumption depends on the study design. Multi-
level models are used with repeated measures data to accommodate the fixed
effects of treatment and time and the covariation between observations on the
same subject at different times.
In a MGM, we will conceptualize the repeated measures as observations
‘nested’ within individuals. To start, we must again specify our model for the
individual trajectory, which we will refer to as the Level 1 (or within-person)
model for intra-individual change:
y tij = π 0ij + π lij timetij + rtij , (1)

where: ytij represents the educational outcome at time t (t=1, .., k) for the i-th
subject (i = 1,…, nj) nested in the j–th institution (university, school, type of
programme) (j = 1,…, m); timetij is the variable time having cardinality equal
to the number of instants; π0ij and π1ij are the intercept (mean of outcome at
timetij=0) and slopes (rate of increase over time) for subject ij. In equation (1),
where for the sake of simplicity we did not insert covariates varying over time,
it is assumed that the outcome follows a linear trend.
We also specify a Level 2 (or between-person) model for inter-individual
differences. The Level 2 model decomposes the individual intercept and
slopes (π0ij and π1ij) into the mean values of the parameter institutions across
individuals (β00j and β10j), in the effect of a set of individual characteristics (xsij
with αsj associated parameter) of subject ij and the individual effect (u0ij and
u1ij).
Finally, the Level 3 model decomposes the mean effect of institutions into
the mean values of the parameters across all institutions (γ000 and γ100), in the
Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation 359

effect of a set of characteristics (grj with associated parameter λr) of institution


j and institution effect (m00j and m10j):

π 0ij = β00j + Σs αsjx sij + u 0ij π lij = β10j + Σsαsjx sij + u lij , (2)

β00j = γ 000 + Σ r λr grj + m00j β10j = γ 100 + Σr λr g rj + m10j . (3)

Each equation presents errors at all nested levels: rtij is the random effect of
time t on the trajectory of outcome evolution for subject ij; u0ij and u1ij are the
random effects of subject ij with respect to the mean trajectory for the subjects
nested in institution j; m00j and m10j are the random effects of institution j with
respect to the mean trajectory for all institutions.
The distribution of the time specific disturbances, individual trajectory pa-
rameters and institutions’ specific parameters are assumed normally distrib-
uted, with zero expectation, and mutually independent:
 rtij   0 Σ 0 0  
     (3)
 u.ij  ~ N 0 ,  0 T 0  
m.. j   0  0 0 G 
    
where Σ is the (k,k) covariance matrix of the time-specific disturbances (rtij), T
the (2,2) covariance matrix of the individual trajectory parameters (u.ij) and G
the (2,2) covariance matrix of the trajectory parameters between institutions
residuals (m..j). Even if MGMs neglect the specification of the covariance be-
tween observations at different times on the same subject, a special attention
must be paid to Σ otherwise we risk incorrect conclusions on fixed effects
(Rogosa, 1995; Laird & Ware, 1982; Cnaan et al., 1997).
The model specified with formulas (1), (2) and (3) is applicable for estimat-
ing the specific effect of institutions on the level (in a temporal instant, m00j)
and on the rate of outcome increase over time (m10j). The model can be ex-
tended (Lovaglio, 2004) to the case of the evaluation of the efficiency among
institutions (relative evaluation) and to that of the distributed service (impact
evaluation).
In the latter case, the model allows to check if an institution that distributes
a service (higher education) obtains better performances in comparison with a
(control) group of subjects with similar characteristics to whom the service
was not distributed. To this aim, a dummy variable Iij – which assumes value 0
for subject i of the control group and 1 otherwise – is inserted in equations (2)
and (3) for the estimation of the impact level (κ0) and slope (κ1):

π 0ij = β 00j + Σ s α sj x sij + κ 0 I ij + u lij π lij = β10j + Σ s α sj x sij + κ1 I ij + u lij (5)

β 00j = γ 000 + Σ s λ r g rj + I ij m 00j β10j = γ 100 + Σ s λ r g rj + I ij m10j (6)


360 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

3. The external efficiency of Italian universities

The proposed methodology was applied to the evaluation of the external effi-
ciency of Italian university education using the data collected by the Bank of
Italy with the Survey on Household Income and Wealth (Banca d’Italia, 2002)
for the years 1998, 2000 and 2002.
The dependent variable is the earned income for each individual in a time
series and the covariates are individual factors (social-demographic-economic
background), university covariates (input, resources, intangible aspects, per-
sonnel) and job market variables (region, province, etc. where the subject is
addressed).
Several indicators concur to identify the individual human capital and
household socio-economical status: Age, Gender, Region of residence, Marital
status, Educational level, Employment status, Type of job, Economic activity
sector, Years of schooling, Age of entrance in the labour market, Number of
children; Years of full-time work, Years part-time work, Household total
wealth, Household total debt, Household income, and Parents’ educational
level.
The outcome of the analysis is the partial disposable earned income (from
here on earned income) composed of earnings of employed and self-employed
people, pensions, transfers and economic assistance.
The sample was composed of subjects belonging to the labour force with
positive earned income for all three years; we identified the graduates as indi-
viduals who had achieved a university bachelor or master degree before 1998.
The panel of income earners is composed of less than 2000 subjects,
whereas the group of graduates of 559 individuals (Table 2). Because of the
reduced number of panel graduates, it is not possible to deepen our analyses
on the external efficiency by university, or type of degree. The analysis is
therefore limited to the effect of the higher education tout court on the income
dynamics (impact analysis that compares the level and the growth rates of
graduates and non-graduates earnings in Italy)3.

Table 2. Composition of the Bank of Italy panel sample


Income earners
Period Families Individuals Income earners
Graduated after 1998
1998 7147 20901 7635 764
2000 8001 22268 8140 825
2002 8011 21148 7313 793
1998 - 2000 – 2002 2591 6953 1978 559

3
Such data moreover prevent the estimation of the short-term university education effect,
because we must select the graduates who have recently acquired a degree, typically go-
ing back three to five years from the first survey.
Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation 361

Table 3. Means of the earned income (in Euro) by degree level and time

Period Graduate Non Graduate


1998 17,959 13,108
2000 20,700 14,269
2002 22,024 15,429

In order to estimate income temporal trend and the between-group differ-


ences, a MGM is specified for evaluating:
a) the temporal correlations for every subject (covariance structure);
b) the existence of temporal dynamics for earned income trajectories
(time effect);
c) if such a trend differs between graduates and non-graduates (bachelor
effect);
d) the individual characteristics that explain the levels and the growth
rates over time.
The specified longitudinal model is therefore a two-level model composed
of equation (1) and (5) describing, respectively, Level 1 (time effect) and
Level 2 (subject effect). We highlight that both level and growth rate for
graduates are larger than for non-graduates (Table 3).
We can state that the hypotheses on which the classical approaches of re-
peated measures (Anova and Contrast Analysis) are based (constancy of co-
variance between couples of measures when the temporal lag varies, and con-
stancy of variances in time) are too rigid. A correct modelling of the covari-
ance structure Σ - representing it as a function of a relatively small number of
parameters - is fundamental for valid inference and estimation of fixed effects
(impact of the bachelor study programme on the level and growth rates of
earned income). For most of the structures, the covariance between two obser-
vations on the same subject depends only on the lag between measurements
with constant variance.
Estimates of between-graduate variances (diagonal elements) and correlations
within groups at each period are shown in Table 4, referring to the MGM speci-
fied with the effects of treatment, time, treatment-by-time interaction, and other
significant covariates (Table 5). The estimated parameters show that variances
between graduates within each group are approximately equal across times and
correlations decrease with increasing interval between observational times.

Table 4. Estimated correlations and variances of incomes over time

Time 1998 2000 2002


1998 0.34 0.50 0.39
2000 0.50 0.32 0.49
2002 0.39 0.49 0.39
362 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

Table 5. Effect of covariates on earned income at 1998 and on growth 1998-2002

Level (Income at 1998) F Value Pr > F Growth rate F Value Pr > F

Intercept 173.61 <.0001 Intercept 123.56 <.0001


Gender 161.90 <.0001 t* Occupation 99.29 <.0002
Occupation 80.29 <.0002 t*Cl_age 66.34 <.0003
Bachelor 58.43 <.0003 t*Sector 23.56 <.0006
Full_job 14.65 <.0005 t*Bachelor 3.83 0.0218
Sector 8.51 <.0006 t*Gender 1.68 0.0932
Marital 4.43 0.0042 t*Full_job 1.65 0.1021
Area 3.85 0.0039 t*Area 1.15 0.1362
Cl_age 3.09 0.0150 t*Marital 1.12 0.1423

Akaike's information criterion and Schwarz's Bayesian criterion are the in-
dices of relative goodness-of-fit chosen for comparing models with the same
fixed effects but different covariance structures. The covariance structure as-
sumed for Σ is the first order autoregressive one (the estimated correlation pa-
rameter for unitary lag is 0.373), which specifies homogeneous variance and
covariances between observations that decrease toward zero with increasing
lag. The test of heterogeneity indicates a common covariance structure for
graduates and non-graduates.
Once Σ is structured, the longitudinal analysis requires the construction of
the Unconditional Means Model (UMM), a model that does not require co-
variates at each level (level 1, level 2). It is useful to both estimate whether a
systematic variability exists in the outcome, and show how the total variance
of the outcome is decomposed between and within subjects, depending on the
time or on individual factors that changed over time.
The estimated intraclass correlation (the ratio of the between and total vari-
ances) shows that the 43% of the total variability of income is attributable to
the differences between the individuals (i.e. individual characteristics) and for
the remaining part to the differences within the subjects, confirming the hier-
archical structure (multilevel) of the dataset.
Inserting the variable time (as a continuous quantitative covariate) in the
UMM we obtain the Unconditional Growth Model (UGM) that explains how
much of the within subject variance is explained by time. We estimated that
28% of the within-subject variability is determined by time and the remaining
part by individual characteristics that change over time (occupation, sector, etc).
Relative to the fixed effects, the overall growth rate of earned income is
positive and highly significant, so indicating a strong dynamic effect on the
income trajectories, while, relatively to random parameters, the variance of in-
Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation 363

come in 1998 (the reference time) and the variance of the growth rates -
between the subjects- are significantly different from zero. The estimated co-
variance between the levels of incomes in 1998 and growth rates is not signifi-
cant, and this implies unstable relations between slopes and initial income.
In order to explain the residual variability between the levels (earned in-
comes in 1998) and between the growth rates (yearly increment of income),
we inserted individual covariates in the 2 level model (equation 5): some of
which, for the sake of simplicity, are kept fixed in time and measured at the fi-
nal year (2002).
The covariates and the significance levels of the associated parameters
(fixed effects)4 are shown in Table 5. The level of earned income at 1998 (left
part of Table 5), gender, type of occupation at 2002 (Occupation), possession
of a bachelor’s degree (Bachelor), years of full-time job (Full_job), occupa-
tional sector at 2002 (Sector), area of residence at 2002 (Area), marital status
at 2002 (Marital), and age at 2002 (Cl_age) are highly significant.
The factors that characterise the evolution of the growth rates are (right part
of Table 5): type of occupation at 2002 (t*Occupation), age at 2002
(t*Cl_age), occupational sector at 2002 (t*Sector) and, to a lesser extent, the
possession of a bachelor’s degree (t*Bachelor), whereas the other covariates
are not significant at 5% level. Relatively to the random parameters (not
shown here), the residual variances in the 1998 level and growth rates remain
significant.
We can conclude that income level at 1998 and income growth rates are
greater and faster increasing (even though close to the limits of the customary
significance levels) for graduates. The selected covariates explain a large
quota (56%) of the UGM residual variance for the level and just a part (21%)
of the between-subject growth rate variability, thus leaving open the search of
other individual covariates that may affect the evolution of income over time.
The trajectories estimated for each group of subjects (after adjustment for the
selected covariates) give a mean growth annual rates of 1,051€ for a graduate
and 426€ for a non-graduate.
Moreover, we estimated the means of growth rates for the two groups for
the more relevant age class. By comparing the growth rates of a graduate
(1507€) and a non-graduate (916€) in the age class less of 30 years it is possi-
ble to quantify how the labour market rewards university education. The im-
pact of a university degree appears highly significant in absolute terms, while
in comparison with the non-graduate rates this difference remains significant,
but constant in the older age groups (606€ for 31-40 year group; 584€ for 41-
50 group).
Finally, we estimated the differences between group income means at every
time and for the income growth rates. The contrast analysis shows that for all

4
The application of QQ plot test for Level 1 and Level 2 residuals shows that normality is
supported by data.
364 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

Graduated (Oss) Not Graduated (Oss)


Graduated (Adj) Not Graduated (Adj)
24000

22000

20000

18000

16000

14000

12000
1998 2000 2002

Figure 1. Observed and estimated income trajectories

three temporal moments the differences between income means are not only
meaningful, but increasing in time (in particular, the difference is 1188€,
2015€ and 2118€, respectively for 1998, 2000 and 2002) and that the income
growth rate of the graduates (estimate: 525€) is larger than that of non-
graduates (p-value=0.0169).
Figure 1 shows the incomes trajectories for graduates and non-graduates,
relatively to the average observed means (Oss) and to the average estimated
means (Adj). The continuous lines, which show the income trends adjusted for
the subjects’ characteristics, confirm our previous results. The adjusted trajec-
tories make it evident the "correction" effect (also called risk-adjustment).

4. Conclusions

The proposed methodology performs “ceteris paribus” comparisons, so allow-


ing a better inference in the sense that the impact of the university degree is
estimated net of the different group characteristics.
In fact, controlling for the possible factors of heterogeneity, the difference
of the two trajectories is reduced, because graduates possess individual charac-
teristics more coherent with the ability to produce high salaries (area of resi-
dence, household context, remunerative occupation, employment sector, etc.),
as illustrated by the fact that the adjusted trajectory for graduates lowered
drastically.
Human Capital Growth for University Education Evaluation 365

References

BANCA D’ITALIA (2002) I bilanci delle famiglie italiane, Supplementi al Bollettino


Statistico.
BECKER G.S. (1964) Human Capital, Columbia University Press and NBER, New
York.
BRYK A.S., THUM Y.M., EASTON J.Q., LUPPESCU S. (1998) Assessing school
academic productivity: The case of Chicago School Reform, Social Psychology of
Education, 2: 103-142.
BRYK A.S., RAUDENBUSH S.W. (1992) Hierarchical Linear Models: Applications
and Data Analysis Methods, Sage Publication, Newbury Park, CA.
COLLINS L.M. (1996) Is reliability obsolete? A commentary on \Are simple gain
scores obsolete?, Applied Psychological Measurement, 20: 289/292.
CNAAN A., LAIRD N.M., SLASOR P. (1997) Using the General Linear Mixed
Model to analyse unbalanced repeated measures and longitudinal data, Statistics
in Medicine, 16: 2349–2380.
CRONBACH L.J., FURBY L. (1970) How should we measure “change” or should
we?, Psychological Bulletin, 74(1): 68-80.
ELIAS G. (2002) L’accreditamento del processo e la misura del risultato. In:
Workshop “Valutazione dell’Università, accreditamento del processo, misurazio-
ne del prodotto”, Franco Angeli, Università Milano Bicocca.
FITZ-GIBBON C.T. (1997) The Value-Added National Project: Final Report. Feasi-
bility Studies for a National System of Value-Added Indicators, SCAA Publica-
tion, Hayes Middlesex.
GAREN J. (1984) The returns to schooling: a selectivity bias approach with a continu-
ous choice variable, Econometrica, 52, 23-54.
GOLDSTEIN H. (1995) Multilevel Statistical Models, II ed., Edward Arnold, London.
GOLDSTEIN H., SPIEGELHALTER D.J. (1996) League table and their limitations:
statistical issues in comparisons of institutional performances (with discussion),
Journal of Royal Statistical Society, 159(5): 385-443.
GOOD T.L., BIDDLE B.J., BRODY J.E. (1975) Teachers Make a Difference, Holt,
Rinehart and Winston, New York.
HANUSHEK E.A. (1997) Assessing the effects of school resources on economic per-
formance, Education Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 19(2): 141-164.
HANUSHEK E.A. (2002) Publicly provided education. In: AUERBACH A., FELD-
STEIN M. (eds) The Handbook of Public Economics, IV.
LAIRD N.M. WARE J. H. (1982) Random effects models for longitudinal studies,
Biometrics, 38: 973-974.
LOCKHEED M.E., HANUSHEK E.R. (1994) Concepts of educational efficiency and
effectiveness, International Encyclopedia of Education, II Edition.
LOVAGLIO P.G. (2004) Efficacia relativa e di impatto di iniziative nell’ambito dei
servizi alla persona di pubblica utilità, Statistica (in press),
MARIS E. (1998) Covariance adjustment versus gain score-Revisited, Psychological
Methods, 3: 309-327.
MEYER D. (1996). The Power of their Ideas: Lessons for America from a Small
School in Harlem. Boston: Beacon Press.
MELLENBERGH G.J. (1999) A note on simple gain score precision, Applied Psycho-
logical Measurement, 23(1): 87-89.
366 P. G. Lovaglio, G. Vittadini

ROGOSA D.R. (1995) Myths about longitudinal research. In: GOTTMAN J.M. (ed),
The Analysis of Change, LEA, Mahwah, NJ: 3-66.
ROGOSA D.R., BRAND D., ZIMOWSKI M. (1982) A growth curve approach to the
measurement of change, Psychological Bulletin, 90: 726-748.
ROGOSA D.R., WILLETT J.B. (1985) Understanding correlates of change by model-
ing individual differences in growth, Psychometrika, 50: 203-228.
SAUNDERS L. (1999) A brief history of educational "value added": how did we get
to where we are?, School Effectiveness and School Improvement, 10(2): 233-256.
SCHEERENS J., BOSKER R.J. (1997) The Foundations of Educational Effectiveness,
Pergamon, Oxford.
SINGER J.D., WILLET J.B. (2003) Applied Longitudinal Data Analysis: Modeling
Change and Event Occurrence, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
THUM Y.M. (2002) Measuring progress towards a goal: estimating teacher productiv-
ity using a multivariate multilevel model for value-added analysis
(http://www.mff.org/pubs/tchprodv3.pdf).
WILLETT J.B. (1988) Questions and answers in the measurement of change, Review
of Research in Education, 15: 345-422.
WILLIAMS R.H., ZIMMERMAN D.W. (1996) Are gain scores obsolete?, Applied
Psychological Measurement, 20: 59-69.

View publication stats

You might also like