You are on page 1of 14

Omega 98 (2021) 102104

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Omega
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/omega

Horizontal cooperative advertising with advertising threshold effects ✩


Lili Yu a, Xiuli He b, Juan Zhang c, Chuanyong Xu a,∗
a
School of Management, University of Science and Technology of China, Hefei, Anhui, 230026, PR China
b
Belk College of Business, University of North Carolina at Charlotte, Charlotte, North Carolina, NC28223, USA
c
Business School, Hohai University, Nanjing, Jiangsu, 210098, PR China

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The advertising threshold effect, which implies that advertising has little effect on sales if the level of
Received 20 March 2018 advertising is below a certain level, has seldom been addressed in a modeling context. Inspired by the
Accepted 15 August 2019
practice of horizontal cooperative advertising (HCA), this paper attempts to investigate the advertising
Available online 19 August 2019
threshold effect in a horizontal context and to explore the value of HCA programs. To investigate the ad-
Keywords: vertising threshold effect in a horizontal context, we develop several advertising and pricing models that
Cooperative advertising involve two horizontally related firms, where the advertising threshold effect is formulated by a two-
Advertising threshold effect regime sales function. We first consider the monopoly case and then extend it to a duopoly case. We fur-
Game theory ther consider two HCA programs to explore the value of such programs, in which the firms share adver-
Marketing-operations interface tising expenditures to reduce their advertising cost. The findings include the following: (i) The presence
of an advertising threshold can lead to sub-optimal advertising decisions. (ii) If one firm is influenced
by the advertising threshold, this influence may be passed to its competitor. (iii) Although cooperative
advertising is less cost effective than individual brand advertising, firms can benefit from HCA programs
only when the advertising threshold is neither too high nor too low, and the synergy effect of cooperative
advertising is not too low.
© 2019 Published by Elsevier Ltd.

1. Introduction “regimes” in only one of which advertising is effective, Vakratsas


et al. [29] provided strong support for the existence of threshold
For firms with a product/service to sell, advertising is crucial. effects.
It is widely used for developing brand image [25], building con- However recent studies on advertising decision-making do not
sumer goodwill, or persuading consumers to purchase [9,28]. It is take account for the advertising threshold effect. In this paper, we
especially important for growing firms or firms introducing new investigate the impacts of the advertising threshold effect on firm’s
products, as customers are not familiar with such brands or prod- decisions, especially for small or new firms. Furthermore, we at-
ucts. However, investment in advertising does not always produce tempt to explore the means of alleviating advertising threshold ef-
sufficient return. As Adachi and Liu [1] noted, in their examination fects. Specifically, inspired by industry practice, we propose two
of the relationship between the level of advertising and demand horizontal cooperative advertising (HCA) programs. One is a joint
for generic fluid milk, advertising investment is only effective once advertising program in which two firms invest in one advertis-
it reaches a certain level. ing with two brands, where the two brands share the advertising
The advertising threshold effect, which implies that advertis- space and the advertising effect. The other is a common brand pro-
ing has little effect if it is below a certain level, has been proved gram or brand sharing program in which the firms share a com-
by many marketing researchers and practitioners. For instance, mon brand name. In both scenarios, one firm determines the ad-
based on monthly time-series and cross-sectional data in a con- vertising participation rate first, and then the other determines the
sumer market, Bemmaor [5] utilized an alternative econometric advertising level for the advertising program.
model and proved that the advertising threshold effect does ex- Joint advertising and brand sharing advertising programs are
ist. In another study using a switching regression model with two common approaches in practice. A joint advertising program is
a strategic marketing and advertising partnership between two
brands wherein the success of one brand brings success to its part-

This manuscript was processed by Associate Editor AE M. Fry.

ner brand. It is an effective way to build business, boost aware-
Corresponding author.
ness, and break into new markets. For example, in April 2017,
E-mail addresses: lizi121@mail.ustc.edu.cn (L. Yu), xhe8@uncc.edu (X. He),
hhuzhang@hhu.edu.cn (J. Zhang), xcy@ustc.edu.cn (C. Xu). two competitive retailing platforms, Tmall (tmall.com) and Suning

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2019.08.011
0305-0483/© 2019 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
2 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

(suning.com), jointly invested in an advertising campaign, “Mall- been proven. The literature on the advertising threshold effect is
Ning”, which brought much consumer flow to both platforms. The mainly empirical and focuses primarily on testing and demon-
brand sharing advertising program provides another way to over- strating the existence of the advertising threshold effect. From the
come the advertising threshold, where the firms may or may not perspective of the behavioral psychology, Greenberg and Suttoni
be in the same industry. For example, in 2001, 18 medium-sized [16] suggested that there may be a threshold effect in the sales
taxi companies in Shanghai formed and shared a common “Blue response to advertising. In subsequent works, Lambin [22], Corkin-
Alliance” brand to compete with five other famous companies in dale and Newall [12] and Adachi and Liu [1] proved the existence
the same city. Many fashion apparel companies in Shishi and Jin- of an advertising threshold by using different approaches. Utiliz-
jiang in China have shared a common brand and advertised to- ing the two-regime market share model, Bemmaor [5] tested for
gether to increase their sales over the past two decades. the existence of a cutoff point and found that advertising has little
Based on these observations, we are interested in the following effect when its level is below the cutoff. Addressing the question
questions. First, what is the impact of advertising threshold effect of how to formulate a sales response model when considering the
on a firm’s advertising and pricing decisions? Second, what is the advertising threshold effect, Johansson [20] argues for modeling
impact of advertising threshold effect on horizontal related firms, the advertising sales response function as an “S-curve”. Based on
which may offer substitutive or complementary products? Third, Johansson’s work, Vakratsas et al. [29] proposed a switching re-
what is the value of HCA programs when the advertising thresh- gression model with two “regimes” to revisit this “S-curve” in a
old effect is present? Whether and when can they benefit from probabilistic manner. These studies serve as the basis for this pa-
such programs and how? To answer these questions, we develop per. We adapted Beammor’s model to characterize the sales re-
several advertising and pricing models. In the models, the adver- sponse function.
tising threshold effect is incorporated through a two-regime sales Although the literature has proven the existence of the adver-
response function. To understand the impact of the threshold effect tising threshold effect, few studies account for it. One exception is
in a horizontal context, we consider a monopoly case then extend [15], who considered the advertising threshold effect in their de-
it to a duopoly case. The impact of advertising threshold transfers mand models of a vertical supply chain, using an S-shaped adver-
to the other firm even if the latter is not affected directly. Then, we tising response model. However, it is also important to investigate
explore the value of HCA programs. We consider a joint advertising the impacts of the advertising threshold effect on advertising de-
program with two brands in one advertisement, and a brand shar- cisions when two firms compete in a market, especially for small
ing advertising program where two firms share a common brand. and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) that suffer from the adver-
We identify the value of the HCA programs comparing their out- tising threshold effect. In contrast to [15], we incorporate the ad-
comes with those of the duopoly case. vertising threshold effect into a model involving two competing
The findings reveal the impacts of the advertising threshold and firms and propose HCA programs to alleviate the effect.
the value of HCA programs. First, when the advertising threshold Our paper is also related to the literature on cooperative ad-
effect is present, the level of investment in advertising may be sub- vertising. Vertical cooperative advertising is the most common
optimal in both the monopoly case and duopoly case. Second, in application of cooperative advertising, which describes a finan-
the duopoly scenario, if either firm is affected by the advertising cial agreement whereby a manufacturer offers a subsidy to its
threshold effect, then the other will also be influenced indirectly. retailer by sharing the latter’s advertising costs [6,7,17,18,31,34].
Third, under HCA programs, both firms can benefit from the HCA In this stream, Huang and Li [18] and Li et al. [24] initi-
programs only when the advertising threshold is neither too high ated the framework of national advertising and local advertis-
nor too low, and the synergy effect is not too low. That is to say, ing. Readers can refer to Aust and Buscher [3] and Jørgensen and
a cooperative advertising with brand A+B should be more effective Zaccour [19] for excellent review on cooperative advertising mod-
than advertised separately, otherwise the cooperative advertising els. Recently, researchers have incorporated findings on the sup-
program is less likely to occur. ply chain into the cooperative adverting program, such as fair-
This paper contributes to the literature in the following aspects. ness concerns, channel conflict, reference prices, and accrual rates
First, it is among the few papers that incorporate the advertising [11,32,33,35,36]. In contrast to such vertical settings, we investigate
threshold effect into cooperative advertising programs. Gou et al. cooperative advertising in a horizontal market structure.
[15] proposed the first vertical cooperative advertising model with The literature on HCA programs is closely related to this study.
advertising threshold effects. This paper differs from their contri- HCAs entail collaboration on advertising by firms belonging to
bution by considering the horizontal advertising cooperation. Sec- the same echelon of the supply chain [3]. Generic advertising is
ond, this paper is among the first to reveal the impacts of the ad- an example of HCAs, which are most commonly applied in the
vertising threshold effect on horizontal firms. This paper identifies farming and agricultural sector [10,13]. Generic advertising is not
the value of HCA programs, which suggests that HCA helps to over- intended to promote a particular brand but a particular product
come the advertising threshold. category [4], and any firm’s advertising will also increase the sales
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. of other firms. Thus free-riding becomes a major concern [26].
Section 2 reviews the related literature. We study a monopoly In addition to generic advertising, the literature on horizontal ad-
scenario in Section 3 and then extend it to a duopoly scenario vertising generally employs models with two branches. The first
in Section 4. In Section 5, we investigate two HCA programs and branch considers two or more firms that launch a cooperative
explore their value. In Section 6, we illustrate our results using advertising campaign for their own brands and share the total ad-
numerical analysis. Section 7 concludes our findings and discusses vertising costs. For example, Varadarajan [30] considered a joint
directions for future research. promotions strategy in which two or more firms or brands jointly
conduct promotional activities through advertisements, which lead
2. Literature review to a better promotion effect with lower advertising costs. Karray
and Sigué [21] studied the optimal selection of promotional part-
Our paper has a close connection to two streams of literature: ners in a market with three horizontal firms where two firms sell
those on the advertising threshold effect and those on cooperative complementary products and a third firm sells an independent
advertising programs. product.
Recent works on decision-making in advertising fail to account The second branch considers two or more firms combine
for the advertising threshold effect despite its existence having resources to create a common brand, and advertising decision
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 3

makers use the firms’ advantages to form a advertising content Proposition 1 shows that as the advertising threshold K varies,
to promote the common brand [23]. Samu et al. [27] investigated the monopolist’s advertising decision falls into three different
the effectiveness of advertising alliances involving two brands from regimes, named the “unrestricted regime”, “partially restricted
different product categories and cooperative investment in adver- regime”, and “restricted regime”. Under the “unrestricted regime”,
tising to introduce new brands. Gou et al. [14] considered a sim- where the advertising threshold is very low (K < u0M ), the monop-
ilar scenario with brand extension, and their results showed that olist’s decisions are identical to those when the advertising thresh-
for horizontal advertising cooperation programs, the contractual al- old effect does not exist. Under the “partially restricted regime”,
liance dominates the joint venture for most profit-sharing patterns. where the advertising threshold is moderate, i.e., u0M ≤ K < 2u0M ,
Following works that consider these two branches, our paper ex- the monopolist exerts greater advertising effort than optimal to
tends the literature on HCA programs by considering the advertis- meet the threshold. Under the “restricted regime”, where the ad-
ing threshold effect, and we propose two HCA programs to over- vertising threshold is very high and surpassing the threshold is
come the constraint of the advertising threshold: one is a joint ad- very costly (K ≥ 2u0M ), the monopolist chooses to invest nothing in
vertising program in which two firms cooperate in advertising for advertising.
two brands, and the other is a brand sharing advertising program Thus, a firm influenced by the advertising threshold may over-
in which two firms share a common brand. or under-invest in advertising, relative to the optimal advertising
level when the advertising threshold is absent, depending on the
3. The monopoly scenario level of the advertising threshold. The selling price follows the
same pattern as the advertising level, increasing under the partially
In this section, we consider the situation in which there is only restricted regime and dropping directly to a lower level under the
a monopolist in the market to determine the basic impacts of restricted regime. The inefficiency caused by the threshold effect is
the advertising threshold. The monopolist faces a given advertis- increasing, while the reason for this may vary.
ing threshold K( ≥ 0). That is, the advertising has no effect on sales The impact of the advertising threshold effect on the monopo-
when the advertising effort u is lower than K. To reflect such a list’s decisions is illustrated in Fig. 1. In this figure, K varies from 0
phenomenon, we assume that the sales function is to 100 while the other parameters are fixed at a = 100, b = 2 and
S(u, p) = a − bp + γ δ (u ), (1) γ = 1.
For a given threshold K, the smaller u0M is, the more likely the
where δ (u) is defined as
 monopolist’s advertising and pricing decisions are to be affected
0, if u < K, by the advertising threshold. Noting that ∂ u0M /∂ a > 0, ∂ u0M /∂ γ > 0,
δ (u ) = (2)
u, if u ≥ K. and ∂ u0M /∂ b < 0, we find the following: (i) when the potential
In Eq. (1), a > 0 is the potential market size, p > 0 is the re- market size is smaller or the consumer is more sensitive to price,
tail price, b > 0 measures consumer sensitivity to the retail price, the monopolist is more likely to be affected by the advertising
and γ > 0 is the efficiency of advertisement (when it takes effect). threshold, and (ii) the advertising threshold is more likely to influ-
The expression δ (u) implies that advertising has no effect on sales ence the firm’s decision when advertising efficiency is low. In prac-
when u < K. Note that Eq. (1) not only captures the advertising tice, SMEs usually have a relatively small potential market size and
threshold effect but also reflects the fact the sales decrease in the their sales are sensitive to price. Our results here show that firms
retail price p. with such characteristics are more likely to be influenced by the
We assume the advertising cost has a quadratic relationship advertising threshold effect. This result explains why SMEs usually
with the advertising level u to characterize the decreasing marginal have to spend a larger share of their total cost on advertising com-
effect of advertising, i.e., C (u ) = u2 /2. Such an assumption has of- pared with large enterprises [22].
ten been utilized in previous advertising studies, and readers may Finally, to characterize the extent to which the system is af-
refer to Zhang et al. [37]. For brevity, we normalize the marginal fected by the threshold effect, we define
production cost to zero. Then, the monopolist’s profit function is a2 /4b γ2
σ =1− = ,
u2
a2 /2 ( 2b − γ ) 2b
2
π ( p, u ) = p[a − bp + γ δ (u )] − . (3)
2 which measures the maximum profit loss ratio when the advertis-
The monopolist determines its advertising level u and retail price ing threshold takes effect. Noting that σ increases in γ and de-
p simultaneously
√ to maximize its profit. Note that we assume that creases in b, we know that when consumers are more sensitive to
0 < γ < 2b throughout this paper to rule out the case of infinite advertising but less so to price, the total efficiency loss is higher.
advertising and retail price which is not possible in practice. The
monopolist’s optimal decision is given in the following proposition.
4. The duopoly scenario
Proposition 1. The monopolist’s optimal advertising level and retail
price are In this section, we consider two firms selling substitute prod-
 aγ ucts in the same market, to explore the impact of the advertising
2b−γ 2
if 0 ≤ K ≤ u0M
threshold effect across horizontal firms. Denote the advertising lev-
u∗M = K if u0M < K < 2u0M (4)
els as ui and the retail prices as pi (i = 1, 2). We assume that the
0 if K ≥ 2u0M
sales of the products are given by1
and
⎧ a Si = ai + γ δ (ui ) − bpi + θ ( p3−i − pi ), (7)
⎨ 2b−γ 2 if 0 ≤ K ≤ u0M
p∗M = a+γ K (5)
if u0M < K < 2u0M
⎩ a 2b if K ≥ 2u0M ,
1
An alternative model is Si = ai + γ δ (ui ) − bpi + θ1 ( p3−i − pi ) − θ2 (δ (u3−i ) −
2b δ (ui )). However, we do not consider advertising competition for the following rea-
respectively, where u0M = aγ /(2b − γ 2 ). Its profit is sons. First, a firm’s advertising will not always decrease the sales of its competi-
⎧ a2 tors. Specifically, when the market is far from saturated, advertising competition
⎨ 2(2b−γ 2 ) if 0 ≤ K ≤ u0M can usually be ignored [2]. Second, since our main focus is not advertising com-
petition but the advertising threshold effect, ignoring the former is a useful way
π =
∗ ( a+γ K )2
− 1 2
K if u0M < K < 2u0M (6)
M
⎩ a2 4b 2 to keep the results parsimonious. Moreover, accounting for advertising competition

4b
if K ≥ 2u0M . does not affect our main conclusions.
4 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

(a) Advertising Level (b) Price and Profit

profit

advertising
level

price
0

partially partially
unrestricted restricted unrestricted restricted
restricted restricted

0 uM0 2um0 0 uM0 2um0

advertising threshold K advertising threshold K


Fig. 1. The monopoly case with threshold effect.

where the function δ (ui ) the parameters ai , b and γ have the same Proposition 2. Given the advertising level u3−i and retail price p3−i
meaning as in Section 3. of firm 3 − i(i = 1, 2), the best response functions of firm i are
Noting the symmetric structure of the problem, we assume that
ui (u3−i , p3−i )
a1 ≥ a2 . The newly introduced parameter θ reflects the substitution ⎧
effect between the two products. A high θ implies a high degree of ⎪ γ (ai + θ p3−i ) γ (ai + θ p3−i )

⎪ if K ≤
price competition. The special case of θ = 0 means that the sales ⎪
⎨ 2 k − γ 2 2k − γ 2
γ (ai + θ p3−i ) 2γ (ai + θ p3−i )
of the two products are independent of each other, wherein the = K if <K< (11)

⎪ 2k − γ 2 2k − γ 2
decision of either firm will be the same as in Section 3. The model ⎪
⎪ 2γ (ai + θ p3−i )
⎩0 if K ≥
may also capture the case when the products are complementary, 2k − γ 2
by setting θ < 0. For brevity, we consider only the case of θ > 0 in
this section. and
Despite our implicit assumption that the two firms face the pi (u3−i , p3−i )
same advertising threshold, we should note that such an assump- ⎧
⎪ ai + θ p3−i γ (ai + θ p3−i )
tion is not made simply for brevity. In practice, to guarantee na- ⎪
⎪ if K ≤
⎨ 2k − γ
⎪ 2k − γ 2
2
tional coverage, advertisers need to reach a certain threshold of ai + γ K + θ p3−i γ (ai + θ p3−i ) 2γ (ai + θ p3−i )
= if <K< , (12)
advertising spending. As described by Brierley [8], during the early ⎪
⎪ 2k 2k − γ 2 2k − γ 2

1990s in the United Kingdom, the spending threshold was approx- ⎩ ai + θ p3−i
⎪ if K ≥
2γ (ai + θ p3−i )
imately £70 0,0 0 0 for a TV campaign and £20 0,0 0 0 for a national 2k 2k − γ 2
poster campaign. When two firms belong to the same country or
Then, differentiating ui (u3−i , p3−i ) and pi (u3−i , p3−i ) with re-
area, their advertising thresholds would most likely be the same.
spect to p3−i we have
Let k = b + θ ; then, Eq. (7) becomes  θγ
∂ ui (u3−i , p3−i ) if ui > K
Si = ai + γ δ (ui ) − kpi + θ p3−i . (8) = 2 k 2 −γ 2
∂ p3−i 0 if ui ≤ K
Obviously, θ < k since b is positive. and
As in Section 3, we assume that the advertising cost is quadratic  θ
in the advertising effort ui , i.e., C (ui ) = u2i /2, and the unit produc-
∂ pi (u3−i , p3−i ) 2 k −γ 2
if ui > K
=
tion cost is zero for simplicity. Then, their profits are given by ∂ p3−i θ
2k
if ui ≤ K,

u2i respectively. Then, we have ∂ ui (u3−i , p3−i )/∂ p3−i ≥ 0 and


πi = p i S i − , (9) ∂ pi (u3−i , p3−i )/∂ p3−i > 0. These two expressions indicate that
2
a firm will increase its advertising expenditure and retail price
and the total profit of the two firms is when the retail price of its rival increases.
Simultaneously solving the best response functions of both
u21 + u22
π = p1 S1 + p2 S2 − . (10) firms, we can obtain the Nash equilibria stated in the following
2 proposition.
Since both firms determine their advertising levels and retail
Proposition 3. Under the duopoly scenario, the equilibria are shown
prices simultaneously to maximize their profits in Eq. (9), this is
in Table 1, and for each equilibrium, the necessary conditions are
a non-cooperative game. First, we characterize the best response
given in Table 2.
functions of both firms. Given the decisions of firm 3 − i, i.e., u3−i
and p3−i , the best response functions of firm i (i = 1, 2) are speci- Proposition 3 shows the advertising decision of each firm still
fied by Proposition 2. falls into three regimes: un-restricted, partially restricted, and
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 5

Table 1
The equilibrium solutions under the duopoly scenario.

Firm 1/Firm 2 Un-restricted Partially restricted Restricted


γ )a1 +θ a2
p∗N1 = (2(2k−
2
2ka1 +θ (a2 +K ) 2ka1 +θ a2
k −γ 2 ) 2 −θ 2 p∗N1 = 2 k ( 2 k −γ 2 ) −θ 2
p∗N1 = 2 k ( 2 k −γ 2 ) −θ 2
γ 2 )a2 +θ a1
p∗N2 = (2(2k− (2k−γ 2 )(a2 +γ K )+θ a1
p∗N2 = (22kk(−2γk−γ)a22)+−θθa21
2
k −γ 2 ) 2 −θ 2 p∗N2 = 2 k ( 2 k −γ 2 ) −θ 2
Un-restricted
u∗N1 = γ [((22kk−−γγ 2))a21−+θθ2a2 ] γ (2ka1 +θ (a2 +γ K ) γ (2ka1 +θ a2 )
2

u∗N1 = 2 k ( 2 k −γ 2 ) −θ 2
uN1 = 2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2
u∗N2 = γ [((22kk−−γγ 2))a22−+θθ2a1 ]
2
u∗N2 =K u∗N2 = 0
p∗N1 = 2k(a1 +γ4Kk2)−
+θ ( a2 +γ K )
θ2 p∗N1 = 2k(a14+b2γ−Kθ)2+θ a2
p∗N2 = 2k(a2 +γ4Kk2)−
+θ ( a1 +γ K )
θ2 p∗N2 = θ (a1 4+kγ2 K−)θ+2 ka2
Partially restricted 2

u∗N1 =K u∗N1 =K
u∗N2 =K u∗N2 =0
θ a2
p∗N1 = 24kak12 +
−θ 2
θ a1
p∗N2 = 24kak22 +
−θ 2
Restricted
u∗N1 =0
u∗N2 =0

Table 2
The equilibrium regions by K.

Firm 1Firm 2 Un-restricted Partially restricted Restricted

( γ [((22kk−−γγ 2))a22−+θθ2a1 ] ,
2

( (24kk−γγ((22)(k−4kγ2 −)θa22 −2
+θ a1 )
2
,
[0, γ [((22kk−−γγ 2))a22−+θθ2a1 ] ] γ (2ka1 +θ a2 ) kγ 2 )
2
Un-restricted min{ 4k2 −θ 2 −2kγ 2 −θ γ 2 , γ (2ka1 +θ a2 )
γ (2ka1 +θ a2 ) 4k2 −θ 2 −2kγ 2
]
2k (4k2 −θ 2 −2kγ 2 −θ γ 2 )−θ 2 γ 2
)
[max{ 4γk(22−kaθ 21 −2
+θ a2 )
,
[ 4k2 γ−(θ22ka 1 +θ a2 )
−2kγ 2 −θ γ 2
, kγ 2
4γ k (2ka2 +θ a1 )
Partially restricted 4kγ (2ka2 +θ a1 ) (2k−γ 2 )(4k2 −θ 2 )−4kθ γ 2 },
4k (2k−γ )−4kθ γ 2 −θ 2 (2k+γ 2 )
) 4kγ (2ka1 +θ a2 )
)
2 2

4 k 2 ( 2 k −γ 2 ) −θ 2 ( 2 k + γ 2 )
Restricted [ (44kk2γ−(θ22ka)(12+kθ−aγ2 )2 ) , +∞ )

restricted, as the advertising threshold increases. However, the sit- Table 2 indicates that not all the nine possible combinations can
uation is quite complicated when one jointly considers the two be an equilibrium. Because firm 2 has a smaller potential market,
firms. it is more likely to be affected by the advertising threshold effect.
There are six possible equilibria unde the duopoly scenario. For When the advertising threshold K increases gradually, we can see
convenience, we denote the six possible equilibria as the (U, U), that firm 2 will always enter the partially restricted regime or the
(U, P), (U, R), (P, P), (P, R) and (R, R) equilibrium. Here, the first restricted regime earlier than firm 1. This is why equilibrium re-
letter of each pair is for firm 1, and the second is for firm 2. The sults do not exist for the three cases located in the bottom-left
letters U, P and R indicate that the corresponding firm’s advertising corner of Table 2.
decision is unrestricted, partially restricted and fully restricted by Moreover, we can prove that when the value of K increases
the advertising threshold, respectively. gradually, there are two possible paths that the equilibrium will
From Proposition 3, we have the following remarks on the in- take: one is (U, U) → (U, P) → (U, R) → (P, R) → (R, R), and the other
teractions between the two firms. is (U, U) → (U, P) → (P, P) → (P, R) → (R, R). The former path occurs
when a2 is very small, and the latter arises when a2 is relatively
Remark 1. A firm’s advertising or pricing decision will be affected large. To illustrate how the advertising threshold level will affect
by the advertising threshold when its competitor enters the par- the decisions of the two firms, we plot the equilibrium decisions
tially restricted regime or restricted regime. of the two firms in Figs. 2 and 3, by varying K.
In Figs. 2 and 3, we vary K from 0 to 70 while holding other
This observation reveals an interesting result. Consider the
parameters fixed, i.e., a1 = 100, θ = 0.6, γ = 0.8, k = 2.6 for both
(U, P) regime as an example: firm 1 is not directly affected by
figures, with the only differences being a2 = 20 in Fig. 2 and a2 =
the advertising threshold. However, firm 2 has to over-invest in
60 in Fig. 3. Note that although specific values are used here, the
advertising, which leads to a higher selling price. According to
same patterns remain if the parameters vary.
Proposition 3, due to competition on price, firm 1 also sets a
higher price, which demands a higher level of advertising invest-
(1 ) (2 )
ment. The remark shows that when a firm is directly influenced by Remark 3. (i) ∂ uN0 /∂ θ < 0; (ii) ∂ uN0 /∂ θ > 0 if a1 /a2 > A(b, θ ,
(2 )
the advertising threshold, its competitor will also be affected. γ ), and ∂ uN0 /∂ θ < 0 otherwise. Here, A(b, θ , γ ) = [2(2b − γ 2 )2 +
Furthermore, when we consider the profits under the (U, P) 6 θ ( 2 b + θ − γ 2 )] / [ ( 2 b − γ ) 2 − 3 θ 2 ] .
regime and the (P, R) regime, we find a surprising result.

Remark 2. Under the (U, P) regime, πN1 ∗ is increasing in K, and In this remark, the first result suggests that firm 1, as the larger
under the (P, R) regime, πN2
∗ is increasing in K. firm, always decreases its advertising investment as the degree of
competition θ increases. In contrast, as implied by the second re-
This result implies that a firm may even benefit from the ad- sult, the decision of firm 2 depends on its relative potential mar-
vertising threshold, if its competitor is forced to over-invest in ad- ket size. If the potential market size of firm 2 is relatively small,
vertising. This suggests that the threshold having a horizontal in- then the advertising level of firm 2 increases with θ . However, if
fluence is not necessarily detrimental to a firm. It depends on the the difference between the potential market sizes of the two firms
regime in which the firms operate. is small, then firm 2 makes similar decisions to firm 1. Because
(i )
Further note that although each firm’s advertising decision p∗Ni = uN0 /γ , the degree of competition has a similar impact on re-
could fall into three different regimes, i.e. the U, P, or R regime, tail prices as on the advertising level.
6 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

(a) Advertising Levels (b) Selling Prices


60 40
u1 p1
u2 p2
35
50

30
40

25

30 (P, R)

20

20 (U, R)
15 (U, P )
(U, U)
(U, U) (U, R) (P, R) (R, R)
10 (U, P )
10
(R, R)

0 5
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Advertising threshold K Advertising threshold K

Fig. 2. The advertising levels and prices when a2 is small.

(a) Advertising Levels (b) Selling Prices


60 40
u1 p1
u2 p2

50 35

40 (P, R) 30
(U, P )

30 25 (U, U) (P, P )
(P, P )

(U, U)
20 20
(U, P )
(P, R)

(R, R)
10 15

(R, R)

0 10
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Advertising threshold K Advertising threshold K

Fig. 3. The advertising levels and prices when a2 is large.

5. Horizontal cooperative advertising (HCA) programs advertising, the advertising cost is divided among partners, which
thus reduces the advertising expenditure of one firm.
The previous section shows that even if a firm is not directly In this section we investigate two types of HCA programs, to ex-
affected by the advertising threshold, it may be influenced indi- plore their value when the advertising threshold effect is present.
rectly if its competitor is affected. In this section, we investigate First, we consider a scenario in which two brands share space and
whether it is possible for horizontal firms to cooperate in adver- expenditures in one advertisement, and both brand names appear
tising. In practice, some firms have attempted to cooperate with in the advertisement. Second, we consider a scenario in which two
others in promotion campaigns. These campaigns, which referred brands form an alliance and share a common brand name. Both
to as co-marketing campaigns can take various forms, with several firms invest in the advertising for the common brand and benefit
involving two brand cooperation in advertising. For example, to at- from the advertising in that the common brand is closely related
tract visitors from around China and the world, scenic spot oper- to their products/services. In both scenarios, in addition to adver-
ators in Jiangsu province such as Yunlong lake resort and Hongze tising cooperation, both firms still have the freedom to decide their
resort formed an alliance called ‘Alliance of Scenic Spots of North own selling prices. These settings fit the current industry practices.
Jiangsu’ and they jointly invested in TV advertising to promote There are also cases in which the firms build more closer alliances,
north Jiangsu tourism. Although the individual brands did not ap- and the selling price is also determined jointly. However, this is
pear in the TV advertising, each partner could benefit from the in- not the focus of our paper.
creased visitor flow to Jiangsu. There are also examples in which
two brands jointly advertise their products. Sometimes in one ad 5.1. Scenario I: two brands in one advertisement
you can see more than one brands. Companies, such as Didi, Uber,
and Mobike, have posted many advertisements in which another In this scenario, two brands invest in adverting with both
brand name also appears besides the host brand. In this kind of brand names shown in the advertisement. The advertising space
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 7

is shared, and the advertising expenditure is divided between two Proposition 5 (i) shows that if firm 1 demands a very high APR,
parties according to the allocation of the advertising space. The al- firm 2 will select an extremely high advertising level, which en-
location of the advertising space is uneven, and thus the expen- tails a substantial loss for firm 1. This would thus never happen.
diture allocation is not even either. Similar practices are observed Proposition 5(ii) presents the optimal total advertising level in dif-
in co-branding and ingredient advertising. For example, the “Intel- ferent cases. To clearly show the value of horizontal cooperative
inside” label is actually another brand name that appears in the advertising programs under the advertising threshold effect, in the
advertisements of PC manufacturers, for which Intel pays part of following, we focus solely on the cases in which at least one firm
the advertising expenditure. However, to secure Intel’s support the is affected by the advertising threshold effect.
advertising space for the label is strictly specified. Another issue
must be addressed here. When two brands appear in one adver- Lemma 1. (i) When 0 < < 1 , ∂ uC0 /∂ φ > 0;
(ii) When 1 < < 2 , ∂ uC0 /∂ φ < 0 in (0, φ 0 ) and ∂ uC0 /∂ φ > 0 in
tisement, there could be synergy effect (or conflict effect) when we
2 k+θ θ (2k−θ ) −θ 2
4k2√
consider the interaction of the two brands. A synergy effect might (φ0 , φ˜ ); where 1 = , 2 = , and φ0 = 2k
2k−θ

occur because the advertising content is richer and the delivery of 2k 2k 2k 2k
2 k+θ θ
information may be more effective, as the recall of the advertise- 2k(2k−θ )
.
ment can be triggered by either brand. A conflict effect might also
occur since the advertising content is more complex and may lead This lemma shows that there’s a mapping relation between APR
to confusion. We should take the synergy (or conflict) effect into and advertising level. When the mapping is one to one, we denote
consideration when two brands are shown in one advertisement. the inverse function of uC0 (φ ) by η1 (u ). When the mapping is not
The sequence of events is as follows. Firm 1 determines its ad- one to one, note that each u corresponds to only two φ ’s, among
vertising participation rate (APR), φ1 = φ , for the joint advertising. which only one could bring higher profit for firm 1. In such a case,
Firm 2 then decides the advertising level of the joint advertising denote the best φ as η1 (u).
after learning its APR, φ2 (= 1 − φ ). Given the advertising level and Moreover, regarding the decision of firm 1, we have the follow-
APR, both firms determine their selling prices (p1 , p2 ) simultane- ing lemmas.
ously.
Lemma 2. When firm 1 anticipates the advertising level to be K,
Similar to the Eq. (8), the sales for firm i(i = 1, 2 ) is
he will always set φ just low or high enough, such that either φ =
Si = ai + φi δ (u ) − kpi + θ p3−i , (13) min{φ : K/2 ≤ uC0 (φ ) ≤ K } or K = uC0 (φ )
where = γ · (1 + g). When the synergy effect is positive, we
This lemma establishes the best decision of firm 1 if firm 2
would expect g > 0 or > γ . Note here that firm i will only obtain
should decide to meet the advertising threshold. The next lemma
a portion of the increased customer flow which is equal to the APR
establishes that firm 1 can always find an optimal APR in (0, φ˜ ) if
that the firm undertakes. Then, the profit for firm i(i = 1, 2 ) is
the advertising threshold effect is absent.
φi
πi = p i S i − u2 . (14) Lemma 3. In scenario I, with the advertising threshold effect absent,
2
Solving the problem by backward induction, we first derive the there exists an optimal φ ∗ in the interval (0, φ˜ ) that maximizes the
equilibrium retail prices ( p∗1 , p∗2 ) for both firms given (φ , u), then profit of firm 1.
obtain the optimal advertising level u∗ for firm 2, and finally we Denote uC0∗ as the solution to dπ1 (u, φ (u ))/du = 0, which is
solve the optimal APR for firm 1. The following proposition shows optimal to firm 1 as the advertising threshold effect is absent.
the equilibrium retail prices given φ and u. Let φ = min{φ : K/2 ≤ uC0 (φ ) ≤ K }, φˆ = max{φ : uC0 (φ ) = K }. Given
Proposition 4. Given u and φ , the equilibrium retail prices are given these lemmas, we have the following proposition which gives the
by optimal APR.
2kai + θ a3−i + (2kφi + θ φ3−i ) δ (u ) Proposition 6. Under scenario I the optimal decision of APR by firm
pi ( φ , u ) = , (15)
4k2 − θ 2 1, denoted by φI∗ , is as follows:
and the profits are given by (i) if K < uC0∗ , then φI∗ = η1 (uC0∗ ) and this leads to u∗I = uC0∗ ;
4k(2ka1 +θ a2 )[2kφ +θ (1−φ )]
k{2kai + θ a3−i + (2kφi + θ φ3−i ) δ (u )}2 φi (ii) if K > for φ ∈ {φ , φ}
(4k2 −θ 2 )2 φ −2k[2kφ +θ (1−φ )]2 2
ˆ , then φ ∗ =
I
πi = − u2 , (16)
0, and this leads to u∗I = 0;
( 4k2 − θ 2 )2 2
In the following, we analyze how firm 2 decides the total ad- (iii) otherwise, either φI∗ = φ or φI∗ = φˆ , and this leads to u∗I = K.
vertising level given firm1’s APR. Proposition 6 shows that if K is sufficiently high, the HCA
Proposition 5. The optimal advertising level determined by firm 2 is programs cannot be practiced. When the advertising threshold is
given by: medium, firm 1 will always choose the lowest or the highest APR
(i) when φ ≥ φ˜ , u∗I = +∞, where φ˜ is the positive root of equa- that will induce firm 2 to decide an advertising level exceeding the
tion 2k 2 (2k − 2kφ + θ φ )2 − (4k2 − θ 2 )2 (1 − φ ) = 0, i.e., threshold.

2k ( 2k + θ )2 ( 2k + θ ) (4k2 − θ 2 )2 − 8k2 (2k − θ ) 2
φ˜ = − + ; 5.2. Scenario II: sharing a common brand name
2k − θ 4k 2 4 2 k ( 2 k − θ )
(17) In this scenario, we consider the case in which two brands
(ii) When 0 < φ < φ˜ , form an alliance and advertise through a common brand name. In
 some cases, firms invest in category advertising when they spe-
uC0 if K ≤ uC0 cialize in that category. This kind of advertising can be interpreted
u∗I = K if uC0 < K < 2uC0 (18) as advertising under a common brand name. For example, in early
0 if K ≥ 2uC0 , 2019, the notion of flexible display is clearly associated with Sam-
where sung and Huawei, since they are first movers and easily identifi-
2k [2k(1 − φ ) + θ φ ](2ka2 + θ a1 ) able in this category. As previously mentioned, firms located in a
uC0 = . (19)
(4k2 − θ 2 )2 (1 − φ ) − 2k 2 [2k(1 − φ ) + θ φ ]2 given region also sometimes advertise through a common regional
8 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

brand name. Regardless of whether the products/services are sub- Given the best response of firm 2, we can convert the optimiza-
stitutes or compliments, the firms all benefit from increased cus- tion problem of firm 1 into the following problem,
tomer flows to their region.
k[2ka1 + θ a2 + u(2kϕ1 + θ ϕ2 )]2 η2 ( · )
As the firms share a common brand, the advertising effect max π1 (u ) = − u2 . (26)
comes from the total customer flow of the common brand. Thus,
u ( 4k2 − θ 2 )2 2
the advertising effect is not allocated according to the advertis- The optimal APR decision by firm 1 is given in the following propo-
ing space allocated to each firm. We assume here that the allo- sition.
cation of the advertising effect is exogenously given, independent
of the allocation of advertising expenditure. The sales function of Proposition 9. In scenario II, the firms will not cooperate in adver-
firm i(i = 1, 2 ) is given by tising if $K>K_1$. Otherwise, the optimal decision of APR by firm 1 is
given by,
Si = ai + ϕi δ (u ) − kpi + θ p3−i , (20) (i) if u0S ∗ < K < K1 , then φII∗ = η2 ( K2 ) and u∗II = K;
where ϕ i (ϕ1 + ϕ2 = 1) is the proportion of the advertising effect (ii) if K < u0S ∗ , then φII∗ = η2 (u0S ∗ ) and u∗II = u0S ∗ ;
4k (2ka +θ a )(2kϕ +θ ϕ )
of the common brand borne by firm i, representing how much where K1 = η (K/2 )(4k2 −1θ 2 )2 −2
2 1 2
k 2 (2kϕ1 +θ ϕ2 )2
2
of the customer flow generated by the common brand advertis-


ing goes to firm i. In advertising, a common brand may be either k 2(2ka1 + θ a2 )(2kϕ1 + θ ϕ2 ) + (2ka2 + θ a1 )(2kϕ2 + θ ϕ1 )
more or less effective than an individual brand. We still use the uS0∗ =
.
synergy/conflict effect factor to characterize the difference between
( 4 k 2 − θ 2 ) 2 − 2 k 2 ( 2 kϕ 1 + θ ϕ 2 ) 2 + ( 2 kϕ 2 + θ ϕ 1 ) 2
common brand and individual brand advertising. Then, the profit (27)
for firm i(i = 1, 2 ) is
Proposition 9 demonstrates that it is possible to establish a co-
φi operative advertising program with each firm bearing a portion of
πi = p i S i − 2
u . (21)
2 the total advertising expenditure. Note that φ ∗ should be positive.
Note here that the allocation of advertising expenditure differs If it is not positive, then cooperative advertising cannot happen un-
from that in the scenario with two brand in one advertising sce- der such a case.
nario. It is possible that a firm may pay a larger or smaller fraction However, it is not clear whether such a cooperative advertising
than the portion of effect he obtains. program is beneficial? Thus, we should explore whether HCA pro-
The sequence of events is as follows. Firm 1 decides the APR grams are beneficial and who will benefit from them.
first. Given the APR, firm 2 determines the advertising level of the
common brand. After the adverting level is determined, both firms 5.3. Value of HCA programs
simultaneously decide their selling prices.
Similar to the previous subsection, we solve the problem by In this subsection, we explore the value of HCA programs. By
backward induction. First we solve for the equilibrium selling comparing them with the duopoly case, we will be able to show
prices given the advertising levels. whether HCA programs are beneficial. We also investigate the ef-
fect of factors that would influence the value of HCA programs.
Proposition 7. Given u and φ , the equilibrium retail prices are given
This will shed light on how and when the HCA programs will of-
by
fer the greatest value. We also explore the disadvantages of HCA
2kai + θ a3−i + (2kϕi + θ ϕ3−i ) δ (u ) programs in this subsection.
pi ( φ , u ) = , (22)
4k2 − θ 2 As the solutions under HCA programs are quite complicated,
and the profits are given by comparing the profits with the duopoly case directly leads to ex-
treme complex results. The analytic form doesn’t even exist in sce-
k{2kai + θ a3−i + (2kϕi + θ ϕ3−i ) δ (u )}2 φi
πi = − u2 . (23) nario I. Thus, we only consider the symmetric case for scenario II,
( 4k2 − θ 2 )2 2 and then we verify the general case in numerical analysis. In the
Next we establish the best response function of firm 2 given the rest of this subsection, we assume that a1 = a2 = a. It is straight
decision of firm 1. forward to assume that ϕ1 = ϕ2 = ϕ = 1/2.
We first address the question of whether HCA programs are
Proposition 8. Given φ , the optimal advertising level determined by
beneficial. The following proposition shows that a HCA program is
firm 2 is given by:
beneficial under some condition.
2k(2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )2 2
(i) if φ ≥ φ̄ = 1 − 4k2 −θ 2
, u∗II = +∞;
(ii) otherwise, Proposition 10. When the two firms are symmetric, if the advertising
 threshold is very low and the synergy effect is weak, the brand sharing
u0S if K ≤ u0S program is not beneficial.
u∗II = K if u0S < K < 2u0S (24)
0 if K ≥ 2u0S , This proposition shows that when both firms are not affected
by the advertising threshold, then it is better not to cooperate in
where
advertising.
2k (2ka2 + θ a1 )(2kϕ2 + θ ϕ1 )
u0S = . (25)
(1 − φ )(4k2 − θ 2 )2 − 2k 2 (2kϕ2 + θ ϕ1 )2 Proposition 11. If the advertising threshold is not very low, the brand
sharing program can be beneficial if the following condition satisfies.
Proposition 8 presents the optimal advertising level given the
APR φ . We find that if the advertising threshold level K is too high, k(8aγ + 4γ 2 K − 4a − 2 K ) < (2k − θ )2 K (28)
then firm 2 will not invest any in advertising. In addition, when K
is relatively high, the best strategy for firm 1 is not to invest in As we would expect, when K is too high, HCA programs are not
advertising. The above two cases lead to the breakdown of brand beneficial because too much advertising is required while it is also
sharing program. When K is not high, the optimal advertising level not necessary. Furthermore, when K is too low, HCA programs are
for firm 2 is u0S . Note that the relationship between the u0S and φ not beneficial, either. This is due to the cost effectiveness of adver-
is one-to-one mapping and u0S increasing in φ . Thus, we can define tising. The individual brand advertising is more cost effective than
the inverse function of u0S as η2 ( · ). cooperative brand advertising, if without synergy effect. To realize
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 9

1600 1600

πN
1
πN
1

1400 πN
2 1400 πN
2
I II
π1 π1

πI πII
2 2
1200 1200
Profits

Profits
1000 1000

800 800

600 600

400 400
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Advertising threshold K Advertising threshold K

Fig. 4. The profits of two firms under HCA programs and duopoly case.

Fig. 5. Advertising synergy effect on HCA programs.

an the advertising effect of γ u for each firm, the advertising level Proposition 13. The two-brand-in-one-advertising program is more
should be u under individual advertising and 2u under cooperative valuable than the common brand sharing advertising program when
advertising. This requires a total expenditure of 12 u2 + 12 u2 = u2
under individual brand advertising but 12 (2u )2 = 2 · u2 under co- 2k (2ka2 + θ a1 )
uS0∗ <  .
operative advertising if the advertising effect and cost are shared [4k2 − θ 2 − 2 2kθ (2k − θ )](2k + θ )
evenly.
We next show even if cooperative advertising is not cost effec-
The proposition shows that the two-brand-in-one-advertising
tive as individual advertising, firms will be able to benefit from
program can be more valuable, as it ensures a larger feasible re-
HCA programs. The next question we would like to tackle is Who
gion of cooperative advertising and higher profits. The reason is
will benefit more from HCA programs?
that in Scenario I, the advertising cost are allocated according to
a fair mechanism that entails greater incentives for both firms to
Proposition 12. The initiator of an HCA program benefits more from
participate.
it.

Although the two HCA programs we consider above differ in Proposition 14. Under scenario II, when two firms are symmetric, we
their advertising effects and cost allocation mechanisms, we would have
∂ u∗ ∂π ∂π
want to know which is better? Thus, the question is when and (i) ∂θII ≤ 0, ∂θ1 < 0, and ∂θ2 < 0;
∂ u∗ ∂π
which HCA program we have explored is more valuable? (ii) ∂ II ≥ 0, ∂ i ≥ 0.
10 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

Fig. 6. Impact of decision sequence on firms’ profits.

Fig. 7. Impact of θ on HCA programs.

These two propositions shed some light on when firms should u = K, the profit of frim 1 decreases with increases of K and the
seek horizontal advertising partners and what kinds of partners firm2’s profit increases with increases of K. In summary, without
they should consider. To develop some intuitions, we would illus- advertising synergy effects, two firms can barely benefit from HCA
trate the results in numerical analysis. programs.
In the following, we explore how advertising synergy affects the
6. Numerical analysis value of HCA programs.
In Fig. 5, we only consider the advertising synergy effect under
Based on the previous results in this paper, in this section we the case where advertising level exceeds the advertising thresh-
study how the value of HCA varies with different settings and fac- old, and under other cases, the results are similar to this case.
tors. Our analysis uses the following parameter values: a1 = 100, The sub-figure on the left of Fig. 5 shows the advertising levels
a2 = 60, b = 2, γ = 0.8, and θ = 0.6. of two HCA programs increase with the increase of g, which sug-
To investigate the value of HCA programs, we compare the two gests that advertising synergy effects helps firms to overcome ad-
vertising threshold effects easily. Let πi (i = 1, 2 and j = I, II) de-
j
HCA programs with the duopoly case under the condition of g =
0. By varying the value of K while keeping other variables fixed, note the benefits of firm i from HCA program j, and we find that
we get the Fig. 4. From Fig. 4, we find that (i) under scenario I, the greater the synergy effect of advertising, the more profits the
the profit of both firms does not exceed that of duopoly case; (ii) firms earns from HCA programs. In addition, we find uI > uII and
under scenario II, the profit of firm 1 is less than that of duopoly π1I + π2I > π1II + π2II from Fig. 5, which indicates that the
case, but when K is not too high or too low, the profit of firm 2 two brands in one advertising program is more valuable than the
more than that of duopoly case. In addition, we find that when common brand sharing advertising program.
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 11

Trying to describe how decision sequence affects two firms’ Acknowledgment


profits under two HCA programs, we change the firm2’s market
size a2 while keeping other variables fixed. We consider two cases: The authors thank two anonymous reviewers and the Asso-
(i) firm 1 moves first and decides the APR, and then firm 2 deter- ciate Editor for their helpful comments and suggestions in improv-
mines the advertising level; (ii) firm 2 moves first and decides the ing this paper. This work was supported by the National Natu-
APR, and then firm 1 determines the advertising level. Using su- ral Science Foundation of China (Grant nos. 71671170, 71501059,
perscript ‘F’ to represent the case where firm 2 moves first. Then 71571174, 71171182) and the Funds for International Cooperation
the results are presented in Fig. 6. and Exchange of the National Natural Science Foundation of China
Fig. 6 presents the profit of each firm under two different se- (Grant no. 71110107024).
quences of decisions, and we find that who moves first will get
more profits. Moreover, the profits of two firms are increasing with Appendix A. Proofs
the increase of a2 , which suggests that firms tend to look for hori-
zontal cooperative partners that have little difference in the size of Proof of Proposition 1
their markets.
Varying the value of θ from −0.3 to 0.3 while keeping other Because π (u, p) is a piece-wise function, we utilize the divide-
parameters fixed, we try to study the effect of competition or com- and-conquer approach to solve the optimization problems. For any
plementary, and the results are shown in Fig. 7. given u, the first and second derivatives of π (p, u) in Eq. (3) with
When two firms are competing (θ > 0), with the increase of respect to p are
competition intensity, the advertising level of two HCA programs ∂π ( p, u )
= a − 2bp + γ δ (u ) (A.1)
decreases, the profit of firm 1 decreases, and the profit of firm 2 ∂p
increases. This suggests that the leader of the HCA programs are
and
more likely to cooperate with firms that are less competitive. Sim-
ilarly, when two firms are complementary (θ < 0), the leader of ∂ 2 π ( p, u )
= −2b < 0. (A.2)
the HCA programs are tend to cooperate with firms that are more ∂ p2
complementary. Thus, π (p, u) is a concave function with respect to p. The first-
order condition gives the optimal price for any u, i.e., p∗ (u ) =
a+γ δ ( u )
2b
. Substitute p∗ (u) into Eq. (3), so the optimization problem
7. Conclusion is converted to
[ a + γ δ ( u )] 2 u2
The advertising threshold effect implies that advertising has lit- max π (u ) = − . (A.3)
u 4b 2
tle influence on sales if it is below a certain level. Although the
Since δ (u) is a piece-wise function, we discuss the optimal so-
advertising threshold effect has been proven, few models have in-
lutions under the two cases u < K and u ≥ K.
vestigated its impacts on advertising decisions, especially in a hor-
(i) When u < K, we have δ (u ) = 0 and Eq. (A.3) becomes π (u ) =
izontal context. a2 2
To fill this research gap, we propose an advertising and pricing 4b
− u2 . It is easy to get the optimal solution u∗ = 0 since π (u) is
model that includes horizontal related firms in which the advertis- decreasing in u (u > 0). The corresponding profit is given by π ∗ =
a2
ing threshold effect is incorporated by through a two-regime sales 4b
.
function. We first explore the impacts of the advertising thresh- (ii) When u ≥ K, we have δ (u ) = u and Eq. (A.3) becomes
( a+γ u )2 u2
old in a monopoly scenario and a duopoly scenario. We find that π (u ) = 4b
− The first derivative of π (u) with respect to u
2 .
γ ( a+γ u )
(i) a firm may over- or under-invest in advertising, depending on is dπdu(u ) = 2b
− u .
the level of the advertising threshold; (ii) if one firm is influenced It can be observed that π (u) is increasing in the interval
γa γa
by the advertising threshold, that influence will be passed on to (0, 2b− γ2
] and decreasing in the interval ( 2b−γ 2 , +∞ ), and also
its competitor, which surprisingly, might benefit a firm if its com- 2γ a aγ
petitor is forced to over-invest in advertising. We then investigate π ( 2b−γ2
) = π (0 ). Thus, when 0 < K ≤ 2b−γ 2
, the optimal adver-
aγ aγ 2γ a
two HCA programs—a joint advertising program and a brand shar- tising level is u∗ = 2b−γ 2
; when 2b−γ 2
<K< 2b−γ 2
, u∗ = K; and
ing advertising program. Specifically, in the joint advertising pro- 2γ a
when K ≥ 2b−γ 2
, the optimal advertising effort is u∗ = 0.
gram, the two firms invest in an advertising campaign with two
brands, while in the brand sharing advertising program, the two In summary, the optimal advertising level is given as follows:
⎧ aγ aγ
firms share a common brand and jointly determine their adver- ⎨ 2b−γ 2 , if K ≤ 2b−γ 2
;
tising. The results shed light on the value of HCA programs. We aγ 2aγ
u∗M = K, if 2b−γ 2
< K < 2b− γ2 ; (A.4)
also provide some insights into when and how to initiate HCA pro- ⎩ 2aγ
0, if K ≥ 2b− γ .
grams. 2


Future directions for the research addressed in this paper in- Denoting u0M = 2b−γ 2
and substituting u∗ in Eq. (A.4) into p∗ (u)
clude the following. First, we assume that the firms do not face
and π (u), we get the optimal solutions shown in Proposition 1.
budget constraints, which is a simplification of reality. Taking bud-
get constraints into consideration would lead to a more realis- Proof of Proposition 2
tic but complicated model. Second, in practice, it is more likely
that two firms with complementary products will cooperate in ad- Given the decisions of firm 3 − i, i.e., advertising level u3−i and
vertising. Although the present model can accommodate the case retail price p3−i , we utilize the divide-and-conquer approach to
in which the two products are complementary by setting θ < 0 determine the optimal decisions of firm i. The first and second
in Eq. (7), we did not discuss this case analytically, which en- derivatives of π i (u1 , u2 , p1 , p2 ) in Eq. (9) with respect to pi are
tails greater mathematical complexity but would be an interesting ⎧
problem to address. Third, there are several types of advertising ⎪ ∂π (u , u , p , p )
⎨ i 1 2 1 2 = ai + γ δ (ui ) − 2kpi + θ p3−i
with different objectives. When firms need to allocate advertising ∂ pi
∂ 2 πi ( u 1 , u 2 , p 1 , p 2 ) . (A.5)
expenditure among these types, the advertising threshold may im- ⎪
⎩ = −2k.
pose a different impact, and this question demands further study. ∂ pi 2
12 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

Thus, π i (u1 , u2 , p1 , p2 ) is a concave function. From the first- Proof of Proposition 5


order condition we can get the optimal retail price for any ui , i.e.,
a + γ δ ( u )+ θ p Given φ , firm 2 tries to find the best u to optimize his own
pi (ui , u3−i , p3−i ) = i i
2k
3−i
. Substituting pi (ui , u3−i , p3−i ) into
Eq. (9), the problem becomes profit. When u < K, π 2 is decreasing in u, thus u = 0 is optimal in
this interval. When u ≥ K, the first and second derivatives of π 2
[ai + γ δ (ui ) + θ p3−i ]2 u2
max πi (ui , u3−i , p3−i ) = − i . (A.6) with respect to u are
ui 4k 2

Since δ (ui ) is a piece-wise function, we discuss the optimal so- ⎨ ∂π2 = 2k [2k(1 − φ ) + θφ ]{2ka22 + θ a2 1 2+ [2k(1 − φ ) + θφ ] u} − (1 − φ )u

∂u ( 4k − θ )
lutions under the two cases ui < Ki and ui ≥ Ki . Referring to the ⎪ ∂2π 2k 2 [2k(1 − φ ) + θφ ]2
γ (ai +θ p3−i ) ⎩ 22 = − (1 − φ )
proof of Proposition 1, let uNi = and we can derive the ∂u ( 4k − θ )
2 2 2
2k−γ 2
equilibrium advertising level ui (u3−i , p3−i ) of firm i as follows. (A.9)

uNi if K ≤ uNi It can be seen that if φ˜ < φ < 1, π 2 (u) is convex and
ui (u3−i , p3−i ) = K if uNi < K < 2uNi (A.7) lim π2 → +∞. Consequently, the optimal advertising level is
u→+∞
0 if K ≥ 2uNi
u∗I = +∞. When this happens, π1 = −∞.
Substituting ui (u3−i , p3−i ) in Eq. (A.7) into expression We have ∂ 2 π 2 /∂ u2 < 0 when φ < φ˜ . The first order condition in
a + γ δ ( u )+ θ p
pi (ui , u3−i , p3−i ) = i i
2k
3−i
, the equilibrium retail price Eq. (A.9) gives us
of firm i is as shown in Proposition 2.
2k [2k(1 − φ ) + θ φ ](2ka2 + θ a1 )
uC0 = .
Proof of Proposition 3 (4k2 − θ 2 )2 (1 − φ ) − 2k 2 [2k(1 − φ ) + θ φ ]2
The structure of the solution is similar to Proposition 1.
According to the proof of Proposition 2, we know that
ui (u3−i , p3−i ) is a function of p3−i and pi (ui , p3−i ) is a function of
ui and p3−i , so pi (ui , p3−i ) is also a function of p3−i . Thus, there is Proof of Lemma 1
a mapping relationship between p1 and p2 . For any K and consid-
ering the constraints of ui ( p3−i ) in Eq. (A.7), we first divide p3−i From Proposition 5, we can obtain
(2k−γ 2 )K−2γ ai (2k−γ 2 )K−2γ ai
into three conditions: p3−i ≤ 2γ θ
, 2γ θ
< p3−i <
(2k−γ 2 )K−γ ai (2k−γ 2 )K−γ ai
∂ uC0 2k (2ka2 + θ a1 )(2k − θ ) f (φ )
, and p3−i ≥ . Then, the optimal advertis- = ,
γθ γθ ∂φ [(1 − φ )(4k2 − θ 2 )2 − 2k 2 (2k(1 − φ ) + θ φ )2 ]2
ing level ui and retail price pi for firm i are given by
(Ai ): u∗i =
γ (ai +θ p3−i ) a +θ p
, pi = i2k−γ32−i , when p3−i ≥
(2k−γ 2 )K−γ ai
; where f (φ ) = (2k + θ )2 (2k − θ )θ − 2k 2 [2k(1 − φ ) + θ√
φ ]2 . Note
2k−γ 2 γθ 4 k2 − ( 2 k+θ ) 2kθ (2k−θ )
∗ ai +γ K+θ p3−i (2k−γ 2 )K−2γ ai that f (φ ) is concave with two zeros, φ1 = 2k(2k−θ )
(Bi ): ui = K, pi = 2k
, when 2γ θ
< p3−i < √
4k2 +(2k+θ ) 2kθ (2k−θ )
(2k−γ 2 )K−γ ai and φ2 = 2k(2k−θ )
> 1. This implies that f (φ ) < 0
γθ ;
when φ < φ1 , and f (φ ) > 0 when φ > φ1 .
∗ a +θ p (2k−γ 2 )K−2γ ai
(Ci ): ui = 0, pi = i 2k 3−i , when p3−i ≤ ; 2 k+θ θ (2k−θ )
2γ θ Furthermore when < 1 = 2k 2k
, then φ1 < 0, other-
According to the constraints of p1 and p2 , we can find 9 equi-
libria, one for each of the cases (A1 , A2 ), (A1 , B2 ), (A1 , C2 ), (B1 , A2 ), wise φ1 > 0. Note also that in order to ensure that uC0 > 0 we need
−θ 2
4k2√
(B1 , B2 ), (B1 , C2 ), (C1 , A2 ), and (C1 , B2 ), (C1 , C2 ). Consider the solu- < 2 = 2k 2k
.
tion under the case (A1 , C2 ) as an example. Thus when < 1 , f (φ ) > 0 for φ ∈ (0, φ˜ ), consequently
γ ( a +θ p )
Firstly, we have u1 = 2k1−γ 2 2 and u2 = 0. Then we solve ∂ uC0 /∂ φ > 0 since it has the same sign with f (φ ). When 1 < <
a1 +θ p2 a2 +θ p1 2 , f (φ ) < 0 for φ ∈ (0, φ1 ) and f (φ ) > 0 for φ ∈ (φ1 , φ˜ ), conse-
the two equations p1 = 2k−γ 2
and p2 = 2k
, and get p1 =
2ka1 +θ a2 (2k−γ 2 )a2 +θ a1
quently we have ∂ uC0 /∂ φ < 0 for φ ∈ (0, φ1 ) and ∂ uC0 /∂ φ > 0 for
and p2 = . Secondly, we can get the
2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2 2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2 φ ∈ (φ0 , φ˜ ).
γ (2ka1 +θ a2 )
u1 = 2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2 and u2 = 0. Finally, we substitute the p1 and
p2 into the constraint under the case (A1 , C2 ) and obtain
4kγ [(2k−γ 2 )a2 +θ a1 ] γ (2ka1 +θ a2 ) Proof of Lemma 2
[2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2 ](2k−γ 2 )
≤K≤ 2k(2k−γ 2 )−θ 2
. Due to a1 > a2 , the equi-
librium solutions for cases (B1 , A2 ), (C1 , A2 ) and (C1 , B2 ) do not When firm 1 anticipates the advertising level to be K, the profit
exist. We can determine the other equilibrium solutions shown in function of firm 1 is
Proposition 1 by methods similar to that used to get the equilib-
rium for (A1 , C2 ). k{2ka1 + θ a2 + (2kφ + θ (1 − φ )) K }2 φ
π1 = − K2, (A.10)
( 4k2 − θ 2 )2 2
Proof of Proposition 4
The first and second derivatives of π 1 with respect to φ are
For any given φ and u, both firms determine their retail prices ⎧
⎪ ∂π 2kK (2k − θ )[2ka1 + θ a2 + (2kφ + θ (1 − φ ) K )]
simultaneously and the equilibrium of selling prices is a Nash Equi- ⎨ 1 = − K 2 /2
∂φ ( 4k2 − θ 2 )2
librium. It can be obtained by solving the system of first order con- ∂ 2π 2kK 2 2

⎩ 21 =
ditions as follows:
∂φ ( 2k + θ )2
∂πi
= ai + φi δ (u ) − 2kpi + θ p3−i = 0, (A.8) (A.11)
∂ pi
∂ 2 π1
since ∂ 2 πi /∂ p2i = −2k < 0 ensures the concavity. Solving the sys- Since ∂φ 2
> 0, π 1 is a convex function. Thus, the optimal φ is
tem of equations leads to the equilibrium prices and then we get either the left or the right boundary of the interval of φ which
the profit functions as shown in Proposition 4. induces the advertising level in (K/2, K).
L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104 13

Proof of Lemma 3 Proof of Proposition 9

When the advertising threshold effect is absent, we substitute (i) When firm 1 anticipates u∗II = 0, he will not invest in adver-
∂π1 (φ ) tising. Consequently, the profit of firm 1 is π 1 (0);
u = uC0 into π 1 , and we get ∂φ |φ =0+ > 0 and π 1 (0) > 0. As φ →
(ii) When firm 1 anticipates u∗II = K, π1 (φ )|u=K is a decreas-
φ˜ , π1 → −∞. Since π 1 is continuous, there exists at lease one opti-
ing function with respect to φ . From Proposition 8, the constraint
mal φ ∗ that maximizes the profits of firm 1 which can be obtained
of K is u0S < K < 2u0S . Because of ∂ u0S /∂ φ > 0, the optimal APR of
through FOC.
firm 1 is φ ∗ = η2 (K/2 ) under this case, and the profit of firm 1 is
π 1 (η2 (K/2)).
Proof of Proposition 6
(iii) When firm 1 anticipates u∗II = u0S ∗ , the unconstrained
∂π1
optimal advertising level, we can get from ∂ u = 0, u0S ∗ =
Though the analytic form of the profit function of firm 1
is too complicated to optimize, the solution procedure is quite k 2(2ka1 +θ a2 )(2kϕ1 +θ ϕ2 )+(2ka2 +θ a1 )(2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )
. Then we get φ ∗ =
straight forward and give us the structural properties shown in (4k2 −θ 2 )2 −2k 2 (2kϕ1 +θ ϕ2 )2 +(2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )2
Proposition 6. We only need to discuss the following three cases: η2 (u0S ∗ ) and the profit of firm 1 is π1 (η2 (u0S ∗ )).
u = uC0∗ , u = K, and u = 0. Comparing profits under these cases leads to the result.
(i) u = uC0∗
If the advertising threshold is very low, i.e., uC0∗ > K, then the Proof of Proposition 10
optimal decision of firm 1 may be in feasible region. Since it is the
unconstrained optimal decision for firm 1, he will always prefer To prove this we need to compare the brand sharing case
this rather than u = K. with the duopoly case under the unrestricted regime. Note that
(ii) u = K when the firms are not restricted by the advertising thresh-
If the advertising threshold is medium such that K > uC0∗ . It is old, for the brand sharing case, uS = 2(2k−3θk) 2 a−2k 2 and πS =
not possible for firm 1 to choose the first best decision uC0∗ . Under ka2 [16(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ] aγ
this case, firm 1 have to choose an APR such that u = K. According 8(2k−θ )2 [(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ]
. For the duopoly case, uN = 2k−θ −γ 2 and

πN = (a2k−(2θk−−γγ 2 ))2 . When = γ > 0, we have πS < [(2k−2θka


2 2 2
to Lemma 2, when this happens, the best APR for firm 1 is either .
)2 −k 2 ]
the lower or the upper bound of φ which induces firm 2 to choose πS 2k(2k−θ −γ 2 )2
u = K. Thus π < [(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ](2k−γ 2 ) < 1, since 2k(2k − θ − γ ) − [(2k −
2 2
N
(iii) u = 0 θ )2 − k 2 ](2k − γ 2 ) = −γ 2 (2k2 − θ 2 − kγ 2 ) < 0. Since πS is in-
Since marginal return of advertising is decreasing, it follows creasing in and πN is increasing in γ , we have for any given
that if K is sufficiently large, advertising at level K is not profitable. γ > 0, when ≤ γ , πS < πN always holds.
In such a case it is better not to participate in the HCA program.
Thus firm 1 should set u = 0 when π 1 (u = 0)>π 1 (u = K). Proof of Proposition 11

Proof of Proposition 7 Under partially restricted regime, we have u∗ = K for both the
duopoly case and the brand sharing case. The difference of the
The proof is similar to Proposition 4 and thus is omitted. profit under the two cases is:

kK K2
Proof of Proposition 8 π = π S − π N = (4a + 2 K − 8aγ − 4γ 2 K ) +
2 ( 2k − θ )2 2
Given the advertising participation rate φ , we solve the opti- (A.15)
mal advertising level u in the following. Since δ (u) is a piece-wise After rearranging the terms, we can obtain the result.
function and it is easy to find that the firm 2 will not invest in
advertising when u < K. When u ≥ K, according to the profit of firm Proof of Proposition 12
2 in Proposition 7, the first and second derivatives of π 2 with re-
spect to u are Since the two firms are symmetric, we need only to consider
⎧ two cases: (U,U) and (P,P). According to Proposition 8, we divide
⎨ ∂π2 = 2k (2kϕ2 + θ ϕ1 )[2ka22 + θ a2 1 2+ (2kϕ2 + θ ϕ1 ) u] − (1 − φ )u
⎪ our discussion into two cases: u = u0S and u = K.
∂u ( 4k − θ ) (i) u = u0S
⎪ ∂ 2π 2k 2 (2kϕ2 + θϕ1 )2
⎩ 22 = − ( 1 − φ ). Substituting u = u0S into the profit function of firm 1, and we
∂u ( 4k2 − θ 2 )2
get the first and second derivatives of π 1 are
(A.12) ⎧
⎨ ∂π1 = 24kφ (k − θ ) − k 2 + 6φθ − 2(223k − θ )
⎪ 2 2 2
∂2π
From the above equation, we have ∂ u22 < 0 when 0 < φ < ∂φ ( 2 ( 2k − θ ) ( φ − 1 ) + k ) (A.16)
⎩ ∂ π21 = − 24k a (2k − θ2 ) [2(2k − θ ) 2 −4 k ] .
⎪ 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
∂2π 2k 2 (2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )2
φ̄ and ∂ u22 > 0 when φ̄ < φ < 1, where φ̄ = 1 − (4k2 −θ 2 )2
.
∂φ ( 2 ( 2k − θ ) ( φ − 1 ) + k )
Furthermore, π 2 (u) is a convex function when φ̄ < φ < 1, and
∂2π
Since ∂φ 21 < 0, π 1 is concave and we get φ ∗ = 13 + 6(2kk −θ )2 . Since
2
thus lim π2 → +∞. Consequently, the optimal advertising level
u→+∞
is u∗II = +∞. two firms are symmetric, the profits under duopoly scenario are
Given φ ∈ (0, φ̄ ), π 2 (u) is a concave function. From the same. Let = π1 − π2 denote the profit difference between
equation ∂ π2 /∂ u = 0 in Eq. (A.12) we get u = u0S = the initiator and the follower of the program. Substituting φ ∗ into
two firms’ profits functions, we get = (2k−θ )23[k(2 k−aθ )2 −k 2 ] > 0.
2 2 2
2k (2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )(2ka2 +θ a1 )
(4k2 −θ 2 )2 (1−φ )−2k 2 (2kϕ2 +θ ϕ1 )2
. Similar to Proposition 1, we get
the optimal advertising level as follows, (ii) u = K
4ak −[(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ]K
 Similar to case (i), we get = 2(2k−θ )2
. Since the
u0S if K ≤ u0S 3 k a 3 k a
u∗II = K if u0S < K < 2u0S (A.13) condition of u = K is 2[(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ]
< K < (2k−θ )2 −k 2 , then we get
0 if K ≥ 2u0S . > 0.
14 L. Yu, X. He and J. Zhang et al. / Omega 98 (2021) 102104

In summary, under scenario II, the initiator of HCA programs [11] Chatterjee P, Karray S, Sigué SP. Cooperative advertising programs: are ac-
benefits more from the HCA programs. crual constraints necessary?. International transactions in operational research;
2017.
[12] Corkindale D, Newall J. Advertising thresholds and wearout. Eur J Mark
Proof of Proposition 13 1978;12(5):329–78.
[13] Crespi JM, James JS. Bargaining rationale for cooperative generic advertising.
Aust J Agric Resour Econ 2007;51(4):445–57.
The value of an advertising program depends on the system ef- [14] Gou Q, Zhang J, Liang L, Huang Z, Ashley A. Horizontal cooperative programs
ficiency it can achieve. We should prove the advertising level under and cooperative advertising. Int J Prod Res 2014;52(3):691–712.
scenario I is higher, which implies a higher system efficiency, than [15] Gou Q, Zhang J, Zhang J, Liang L. Nash equilibria of co-operative advertis-
ing programs with advertising threshold effects. Int J Inf TechnolDecis Making
that under scenario II, given the stated condition. From Lemma 1
2015;13(1):1–24.
the lower bound of uC , denoted by uC , can be obtained at φ = φ1 . [16] Greenberg A, Suttoni C. Television commercial wearout. J Advert Res
2k (2ka2 +θ a1 ) 1973;13(5):47–54.
Thus we have uC = √ . A necessary condi-
[4k2 −θ 2 −2 2kθ (2k−θ )](2k+θ ) [17] He X, Prasad A, Sethi SP. Cooperative advertising and pricing in a dynamic
tion for <u0S ∗
is uC∗ u0S ∗ < uC since uC ≤ uC holds
for any uC . From stochastic supply chain: feedback stackelberg strategies. Prod. Oper. Manage
2009;18(1):78–94.
our numerical analysis this condition is quite loose. [18] Huang Z, Li SX. Co-op advertising models in manufacturer–retailer supply
chains: a game theory approach. Eur J Oper Res 2001;135(3):527–44.
Proof of Proposition 14 [19] Jørgensen S, Zaccour G. A survey of game-theoretic models of cooperative ad-
vertising. Eur J Oper Res 2014;237:1–14.
[20] Johansson JK. Advertising and the s-curve: a new approach. J Mark Res
From the proof of Proposition 12, the optimal solutions and cor- 1979;16(3):346–54.
responding profits are as follows. [21] Karray S, Sigué SP. A game-theoretic model for co-promotions: choosing a
complementary versus an independent product ally. Omega 2015;54:84–100.
(i) When K < 2[(2k−3θk )2a−k 2 ] , we have u∗II = 2[(2k−3θk )2a−k 2 ] , π1 = [22] Lambin JJ. Advertising, competition, and market conduct in oligopoly over
· [8((22kk−−θθ))2 −k
+k ]
· [4((22kk−−θθ))2 −k
−k ]
2 2 2 2 time. New York: American Elsevier Publishing Company; 1976.
ka2 2
8(2k−θ )2 2
, and π2 = 4(2ka
k−θ )2 2
. [23] Leuthesser L, Kohli C, Suri R. 2+ 2= 5? A framework for using co-branding to
3 k a 3 k a
(i) When 2[(2k−θ )2 −k 2 ] < K < (2k−θ )2 −k 2 , we have u∗II = K, leverage a brand. J Brand Manage 2003;11(1):35–47.
[24] Li SX, Huang Z, Zhu J, Chau PY. Cooperative advertising, game theory and man-
k(2a2 +4a K+ 2 K 2 ) K2 2
π1 = 2(2k−θ )2
− 2 and π2 = (2kka
−θ )2
. ufacturer-retailer supply chains. Omega 2002;30(5):347–57.
[25] Meenaghan T. The role of advertising in brand image development. J Prod
∂ u∗ ∂π ∂ u∗
Note that k = b + θ . Then we can get ∂θII ≤ 0, ∂θi < 0, ∂ II ≥ 0, Brand Manage 1995;4(4):23–34.
[26] Roma P, Perrone G. Generic advertising, brand advertising and price competi-
∂π
and ∂ i ≥ 0. tion: an analysis of free-riding effects and coordination mechanisms. Rev Mark
Sci 2010;8(1).
[27] Samu S, Krishnan HS, Smith RE. Using advertising alliances for new product
Supplementary material introduction: interactions between product complementarity and promotional
strategies. J Mark 1999;63(1):57–74.
Supplementary material associated with this article can be [28] Sutherland M, Galloway J. Role of advertising: persuasion or agenda setting. J
Advert Res 1981;21(5):25–9.
found, in the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.omega.2019.08.011. [29] Vakratsas D, Feinberg FM, Bass FM, Kalyanaram G. The shape of advertising re-
sponse functions revisited: a model of dynamic probabilistic thresholds. Mark
References Sci 2004;23(1):109–19.
[30] Varadarajan PR. Joint sales promotion: an emerging marketing tool. Bus Horiz
[1] Adachi K, Liu DJ. Estimating threshold effects of US generic fluid milk adver- 1985;28(5):43–9.
tising. Am J Agric Econ 2010;92(3):727–39. [31] Xie J, Wei JC. Coordinating advertising and pricing in a manufacturer–retailer
[2] Anderson ET, Simester D. Advertising in a competitive market: the role channel. Eur J Oper Res 2009;197(2):785–91.
of product standards, customer learning, and switching costs. J Mark Res [32] Xie J, Liang L, Liu L, Ieromonachou P. Coordination contracts of dual-chan-
2013;50(4):489–504. nel with cooperation advertising in closed-loop supply chains. Int J Prod Econ
[3] Aust G, Buscher U. Cooperative advertising models in supply chain manage- 2017;183:528–38.
ment: a review. Eur J Oper Res 2014;234(1):1–14. [33] Yang J, Xie J, Deng X, Xiong H. Cooperative advertising in a distribution chan-
[4] Bass FM, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP. Generic and brand advertising nel with fairness concerns. Eur J Oper Res 2013;227(2):401–7.
strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Mark Sci 2005;24(4):556–68. [34] Yue J, Austin J, Wang MC, Huang Z. Coordination of cooperative advertising in
[5] Bemmaor AC. Testing alternative econometric models on the existence of ad- a two-level supply chain when manufacturer offers discount. Eur J Oper Res
vertising threshold effect. J Mark Res 1984;21(3):298–308. 2006;168(1):65–85.
[6] Berger PD. Vertical cooperative advertising ventures. J Mark Res [35] Zhang J, Gou Q, Li S, Huang Z. Cooperative advertising with accrual rate in a
1972;9(3):309–12. dynamic supply chain. Dyn Games Appl 2017;7(1):112–30.
[7] Berger PD. Statistical decision analysis of cooperative advertising ventures. J [36] Zhang J, Gou Q, Liang L, He X. Ingredient branding strategies in an assembly
Oper Res Soc 1973;24(2):207–16. supply chain: models and analysis. Int J Prod Res 2013;51(23–24):6923–49.
[8] Brierley S. The advertising handbook. London: Routledge; 1995. [37] Zhang J, Gou Q, Liang L, Huang Z. Supply chain coordination through coopera-
[9] Bucklin LP. The informative role of advertising. J Advert Res 1965;5(3):11–15. tive advertising with reference price effect. Omega 2013;41(2):345–53.
[10] Chakravarti A, Janiszewski C. The influence of generic advertising on brand
preferences. J Consum Res 2004;30(4):487–502.

You might also like