You are on page 1of 23

29/11/2020

CHAPTER T W O

2 International Economics
Eleventh Edition

The Law of Absolute & Comparative


Advantage
Dominick Salvatore
John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Learning Goals:
 Understand the law of absolute &
comparative advantage.

 Understand the relationship between


opportunity costs and relative commodity
prices.

 Explain the basis for trade and show the gains


from trade under constant cost conditions.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

1
29/11/2020

Introduction

 Basic questions:
 What is the basis for trade?

 What are gains from trade?

 What is the pattern of trade?

 Assume two-nation, two-good world

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Different Trade Theories

1. What is the basis for trade?


Reasons countries trade goods with each other
include:
 Differences in the technology used in each country (i.e.,
differences in each country’s ability to manufacture
products)

 Differences in the total amount of resources (including labor,


capital, and land) found in each country

 The proximity of countries to each other (i.e., how close they


are to one another)

© Palmatier
4

2
29/11/2020

Concerns of Trade Theory

The classical theory of international trade is


concerned with the following three questions:

2. What are the gains from trade?


 In other words, if countries benefit from
international trade, where do the gains
come from, and how are they divided
among the trading countries?

© Palmatier
5

Concerns of Trade Theory

The classical theory of international trade is


concerned with the following three questions:
3. What is the structure/pattern of trade?
In other words, which goods/services are
exported, and which are imported?
What are the fundamental laws that govern
international allocation of resources and the
flow of trade?

© Palmatier
6

3
29/11/2020

Different Trade Theories

Understanding the Gains from


International Trade
Nations (or firms in different nations) trade
with each other because they benefit from it!

We can divide the different trade theories in four


categories...
 Early Trade Theory: Mercantilists
 Classical Trade Theory: Ricardian Model
 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model
 Alternative Approaches to Trade Theory

© Palmatier
7

The Mercantilists’ Views on Trade

 Mercantilism
 Economic philosophy in 17th and 18th
centuries, in England, Spain, France, Portugal
and the Netherlands.

 Belief that nation could become rich and


powerful only by exporting more than it
imported.
 Mercantilism advocates government
intervention to achieve a surplus in the
balance of trade
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

4
29/11/2020

The Mercantilists’ Views on Trade

 Mercantilism
 Export surpluses brought inflow of gold and
silver.
 Trade policy was to encourage exports and
restrict imports.
 One nation gained only at the expense of
another.
 It views trade as a zero-sum game - one in
which a gain by one country results in a loss
by another

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

The Mercantilists’ Views on Trade

 Mercantilists measured wealth of a nation by


stock of precious metals it possessed.

 Today, we measure wealth of a nation by its


stock of human, man-made and natural
resources available for producing goods and
services.
 The greater the stock of resources, the greater the
flow of goods and services to satisfy human
wants, and the higher the standard of living.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

10

5
29/11/2020

International Trade Theory: Absolute Advantage

Adam Smith argued that a country has an absolute


advantage in the production of a product when it is more
efficient than any other country in producing it

According to Smith, countries should specialize in the


production of goods for which they have an absolute
advantage and then trade these goods for the goods produced
by other countries
In 1770s, Adam Smith argued that import restrictions would
reduce the gains from specialization and make a nation
poorer. He used absolute advantage to explain the benefits of
trade.

© Palmatier
11

11

Trade Based on Absolute Advantage:


Adam Smith

 A nation has absolute advantage over another


nation if it can produce a commodity more
efficiently.

 When one nation has absolute advantage in


production of a commodity, but an absolute
disadvantage with respect to the other nation in a
second commodity, both nations can gain by
specializing in their absolute advantage good and
exchanging part of the output for the commodity
of its absolute disadvantage.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

12

6
29/11/2020

Trade Based on Absolute Advantage:


Adam Smith

 Examples:
 Canada is efficient in growing wheat, inefficient
in growing bananas.
 Nicaragua is efficient in growing bananas,
inefficient in growing wheat.
 Canada has absolute advantage in wheat,
Nicaragua has absolute advantage in bananas.
 Mutually beneficial trade can take place if both
countries specialize in their absolute advantage.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

13

Trade Based on Absolute Advantage:


Adam Smith

 Specialization and trade benefit both


countries.
 Adam Smith and other classical economists
advocated a policy of laissez-faire, or
minimal government interference with
economic activity.
 Free trade would cause world resources to be
utilized most efficiently, maximizing world
welfare.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

14

7
29/11/2020

Trade Based on Absolute Advantage:


Adam Smith

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 5

 U.S. has an absolute advantage over U.K. in wheat.


 U.K. has an absolute advantage over U.S. in cloth.
 Both nations can gain from specializing in
production and then trading.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

15

Trade Based on Comparative Advantage:


David Ricardo

 Law of Comparative Advantage


 Even if one nation is less efficient than (has
absolute disadvantage with respect to) the
other nation in production of both
commodities, there is still a basis for mutually
beneficial trade.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

16

8
29/11/2020

Trade Based on Comparative Advantage:


David Ricardo

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 5

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

17

Trade Based on Comparative Advantage:


David Ricardo

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2

 U.K. has an absolute disadvantage in both goods.


 Since U.K. labor is half as productive in cloth but
six times less productive in wheat compared to
U.S., the U.K. has a comparative advantage in cloth.
 U.S. has a comparative advantage in wheat.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

18

9
29/11/2020

The Case of No Comparative Advantage

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 3
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

19

The Case of No Comparative


Advantage
 There is one (not very common) case where there is
no comparative advantage. This occurs when the
absolute disadvantage that one nation has with
respect to another nation is the same in both
commodities.
 For example, if one hour produced 3W instead of 1W
in the United Kingdom (see Table 2.2), the United
Kingdom would be exactly half as productive as the
United States in both wheat and cloth.
 The United Kingdom (and the United States) would
then have a comparative advantage in neither
commodity, and no mutually beneficial trade could
take place.
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

20

10
29/11/2020

REVIEW

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 5

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2

U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 3
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

21

Comparative Advantage and


Opportunity Costs

 The original idea of comparative advantage


was based on the labor theory of value:
 The value or price of a commodity depends
exclusively on the amount of labor used to
produce it.
 Can use the opportunity cost theory to
explain comparative advantage:
 The opportunity cost of a good is the amount of a
second good that must be given up to release just
enough resources to produce one additional unit
of the first good.
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

22

11
29/11/2020

Comparative Advantage and


Opportunity Costs

 Consequently, the nation with the lower


opportunity cost in the production of a
commodity has a comparative advantage in
that commodity (and a comparative
disadvantage in the second commodity).

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

23

Comparative Advantage and


Opportunity Costs
U.S. U.K.
Wheat (bushels/hour) 6 1
Cloth (yards/hour) 4 2
Opportunity cost U.S. U.K.
(Autarky)
Wheat 1W = 2/3C 1W = 2C

 In which country, the opportunity cost of wheat is


lower?
 Which country has a comparative advantage over
the other country in wheat?
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

24

12
29/11/2020

The Gains from Trade

 Both countries can gain from trade by each


specializing in the production and exporting
of the commodity of its comparative
advantage.
 The US gains as long as 6W trade for more
than 4 C.
 The UK gains as long as 2C trades for more
than 1 W.
 Thus the range for mutually beneficial trade
is: 4C < 6W <12C
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

25

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs
 Opportunity costs can be illustrated with the
production possibility frontier, or
transformation curve

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

26

13
29/11/2020

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

27

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs
US UK
Wheat ∆ W Cloth ∆C Wheat ∆ W Cloth ∆C
180 0 60 0
150 20 50 20
120 40 40 40
90 60 30 60
60 80 20 80
30 100 10 100
0 120 0 120

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

28

14
29/11/2020

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs
US UK
Wheat ∆ W Cloth ∆C Wheat ∆ W Cloth ∆C
180 0 60 0
150 -30 20 20 50 -10 20 20
120 -30 40 20 40 -10 40 20
90 -30 60 20 30 -10 60 20
60 -30 80 20 20 -10 80 20
30 -30 100 20 10 -10 100 20
0 -30 120 20 0 -10 120 20

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

29

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs
Opportunity U.S. U.K.
cost
(Autarky)
Wheat 30W = 20C 10W = 20C
=> 1W = 2/3C => 1W = 2C

Constant Constant
opportunitity cost opportunitity cost

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

30

15
29/11/2020

The Production Possibility Frontier


under Constant Costs
 Production Possibilities Frontier
 Slope: downward or upward?
 Line: straight or curve?

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

31

FIGURE 2-1 The Production Possibility Frontiers of the


United States and the United Kingdom.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

32

16
29/11/2020

Opportunity Costs and Relative


Commodity Prices
 We have seen that the opportunity cost of
wheat is equal to the amount of cloth that the
nation must give up to release just enough
resources to produce one additional unit of
wheat.
 This is given by the (absolute) slope of the
production possibility frontier, or
transformation curve, and is sometimes
referred to as the marginal rate of
transformation
Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

33

Opportunity Costs and Relative


Commodity Prices
 Figure 2.1 shows that the (absolute) slope of
the U.S. transformation curve is 120/180 =
2/3 = opportunity cost of wheat in the United
States and remains constant.
 The slope of the U.K. transformation curve is
120/60 = 2 = opportunity cost of wheat in the
United Kingdom and remains constant.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

34

17
29/11/2020

Opportunity Costs and Relative


Commodity Prices
 On the assumptions that prices equal costs of
production and that the nation does produce
both some wheat and some cloth, the
opportunity cost of wheat is equal to the price
of wheat relative to the price of cloth (PW /PC).

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

35

Opportunity Costs and Relative


Commodity Prices
 PW /PC = 2/3 in the United States, and inversely
PC /PW = 3/2 = 1.5. In the United Kingdom, PW
/PC = 2, and PC /PW = 1/2.
 The lower PW /PC in the United States (2/3 as
opposed to 2) is a reflection of its comparative
advantage in wheat.
 Similarly, the lower PC /PW in the United
Kingdom (1/2 as opposed to 2/3 ) reflects its
comparative advantage in cloth.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

36

18
29/11/2020

Comparative Advantage and


Opportunity Costs

 Production Possibilities Frontier


 A curve that shows alternative combinations of
the two commodities a nation can produce by
fully using all resources with best available
technology.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

37

Constant opportunity costs

 Constant opportunity costs arise when:


 Resources are either perfect substitutes for
each other or used in fixed proportion in
production of both commodities, and
 All units of the same factor are homogeneous.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

38

19
29/11/2020

Constant opportunity costs

 the same amount of one commodity must be


given up to produce each additional unit of the
second commodity.
 Although opportunity costs are constant in each
nation, they differ among nations, providing the
basis for trade.
 Constant costs are not realistic, however.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

39

The Basis for and the Gains from Trade under


Constant Costs

 In the absence of trade, a nation’s production


possibilities frontier also represents its
consumption frontier.
 Increased output resulting from
specialization and trade represents nations’
gains from trade, allowing nations to
consume outside production possibilities
frontier.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

40

20
29/11/2020

FIGURE 2-2 The Gains from Trade.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

41

The Basis for and the Gains from Trade under


Constant Costs

 Under constant cost conditions, nations will


completely specialize in their comparative
advantage .
 With complete specialization in both nations,
the equilibrium-relative commodity price of
each commodity lies between the pretrade
relative commodity price in each nation.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

42

21
29/11/2020

FIGURE 2-3 Equilibrium-Relative Commodity Prices with


Demand and Supply.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

43

The Basis for and the Gains from Trade under


Constant Costs

 Suppose that world demand for wheat


intersects world supply in the portion of the
supply curve between zero and B in the left
panel of the previous graph.
 Then trade takes place at the pretrade price in
the U.S., which will not completely specialize,
and all the gains from trade accrue to the U.K.
 This is the small country case, demonstrating
“the importance of being unimportant.”

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

44

22
29/11/2020

 Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

 All rights reserved. Reproduction or translation of this work beyond


that permitted in section 117 of the 1976 United States Copyright Act
without express permission of the copyright owner is unlawful.
Request for further information should be addressed to the
Permissions Department, John Wiley & Sons, Inc. The purchaser may
make back-up copies for his/her own use only and not for distribution
or resale. The Publisher assumes no responsibility for errors, omissions,
or damages caused by the use of these programs or from the use of the
information herein.

Salvatore: International Economics, 11th Edition © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

45

23

You might also like