You are on page 1of 29

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.

3
YMCA Library Building, Jai Singh Road, New Delhi 110001

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.


It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in

Oxford New York


Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto

With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam

Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press


in the UK and in certain other countries.

Published in India
by Oxford University Press

© Oxford University Press 2006, 2010

The moral rights of the authors have been asserted.

Database right Oxford University Press (maker)

First published 2006


Second edition 2010

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,


stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above.

You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose this same condition on any acquirer.

ISBN-13: 978-0-19-806111-3
ISBN-10: 0-19-806111-0

Typeset in Baskerville
by Le Studio Graphique
Printed in India by Radha Press, Delhi 110031
and published by Oxford University Press
YMCA Library Building, Jai Singh Road, New Delhi 110001

© Oxford
Managerial Economics, Second Edition University Press. All rights reserved.
Contents

Preface to the Second Edition v Why is the Demand Curve


Preface to the First Edition vii Negatively Sloped? 29
Exceptions to the Law of Demand 30
PART ONE 2.3 Shifts in Demand 31
2.4 Market Demand and
The Foundation Its Interpretation 32
2.5 From Individual Demand
1. Foundations of 3
to Market Demand 32
Managerial Economics 2.6 Slope and Elasticities 34
Introduction 3 2.7 Price Elasticity and
1.1 What is Economics? 4 Total Expenditure 39
1.2 Definition and Scope of Price Elasticity: Some Applications
Managerial Economics 6 and Solved Problems 41
1.3 Typical Decisions Handled Determinants of Price Elasticity
by Managerial Economics 7 of Demand 41
1.4 Opportunity Costs 9 Price Elasticity—Special Cases 43
1.5 Positioning Managerial Price Elasticity along a
Economics in the Big Picture 10 Linear Demand Curve 43
1.6 The Theory of the Firm Price Elasticity, Marginal Revenue,
and the Role of Profits 11 and Average Revenue 45
1.7 Why do Economic 2.8 Income Elasticity of Demand 46
Profits Exist? 13 2.9 Cross-price Elasticity
1.8 The Invisible Hand 13 of Demand 49
1.9 Microeconomic Problems Case Study 1 54
in Managerial Economics 14 Case Study 2 54
1.10 Supply–demand Analysis 15 Case Study 3 55
1.11 Total, Average, and
Marginal Magnitudes 17 3. Household as a Consumer: 56
1.12 The Concept of Margin 21 Behind the Demand Curve
Introduction 56
PART TWO 3.1 The Decision-making
Process of the Consumer 57
The Household and the Firm
Assumption of Completeness 58
2. Demand 27 Assumption of Transitivity 58
Assumption of Non-satiation 58
Introduction 27
3.2 Utility—Concept and
2.1 Meaning of Demand 27
Measurement 58
2.2 Law of Demand and
Cardinal and Ordinal Utility 59
Exceptions to the Law 28

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


xii Contents

3.3 Optimization— 5. Firm as a Producer 135


The Cardinal Approach 60
Introduction 135
3.4 Deriving the Demand Curve—
5.1 Existence of Firms 135
The Cardinal Approach 65
5.2 Profits—The Motive
3.5 Optimization—
behind Existence 137
The Ordinal Approach 66
5.3 Determination of the
3.6 Indifference Curves 66
Profit-maximizing Level
3.7 Properties of
of Output 139
Indifference Curves 67
Total Revenue 140
3.8 Other Types of
Total Economic Cost 141
Indifference Curves 70
Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost 143
3.9 Budget Constraints 72
3.10 The Consumer’s Equilibrium 5.4 Do Firms Really
and Optimal Combination 74 Maximize Profits? 146
Consumer Equilibrium Internal Control Mechanisms 148
Expressed in Utility 76 External Control Mechanisms 150
3.11 Changes in Equilibrium Profit Maximization over Time 151
When Prices Change 77 5.5 Goals of Non-profit Firms
3.12 Deriving the Demand and Public Sector Firms 151
Curve—The Ordinal Approach 78 5.6 Global Firms 152
3.13 Changes in Equilibrium What Characterizes an MNC? 153
When Income Changes 81 What is Attractive about
3.14 Income and Substitution being an MNC? 153
Effects of a Price Change How can Firms Become MNCs? 153
and Giffen Goods 83 Are There no Complications at all? 156
3.15 Exception to the Law of Case Study 159
Demand—The Case of
Giffen Goods 85 6. Analysis of Production: 160
3.16 Applications of Theory and Estimation
Indifference Curves 86 Introduction 160
Welfare Effects of a Direct Tax 6.1 Production Decisions 160
vs an Indirect Tax 87
Decisions Bringing Together Inputs
4. Demand Estimation 95 to Produce the Product or Output 161
and Forecasting Variety in the Decisions—
Short Run and Long Run 162
Introduction 95 Production Function 164
4.1 Demand Estimation Using 6.2 Production Function with
Qualitative Research Techniques 96 One Variable Input (A Short-run
4.2 Statistical Estimation of Production Function) 164
Demand Function 97 Production Elasticity 168
Step 1: Identification of Variables 98
Three Stages of Production 168
Step 2: Collecting Historical Data 98
Three Stages of Production
Step 3: Specification of the Model 98 and Decision-making 169
Step 4: Simple Linear Regression Model 101 6.3 Optimal Input Levels
4.3 Forecasting 117 with One Variable Input 169
Forecasting Techniques 118 6.4 Production Function Where
Case Study 1 133 All Inputs are Variable—
Case Study 2 134 Case of Two Variable Inputs 173

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Contents xiii

Properties of Isoquants 176 7.7 Relationship between Average


Relationship between Marginal Cost Curves—Long Run and
(Physical) Product and Marginal Short Run 222
Rate of Technical Substitution 177 Using LRAC in Decision-making 226
Relationship between MRTS and 7.8 Statistical Estimation of Cost
Elasticity of Substitution 179 Functions—Short-run Function 226
Appreciation of the Isoquant Model 180 Polynomial Function 227
6.5 Determination of Optimal Logarithmic Function 228
Combination of Inputs Problems of Data Measurement
When All Inputs are Variable 181 and Data Availability 228
6.6 Returns to Scale 184 Examples of Statistically Estimated
Source of Returns to Scale 185 Short-run Cost Functions 230
Graphical Representation of 7.9 Statistical Estimation of Cost
Returns to Scale 187 Functions—Long-run Function 231
6.7 Statistical Estimation of Case Study 1 236
Production Function 188 Case Study 2 237
Cobb–Douglas Production Function 189 Case Study 3 238
Euler’s Theorem 190
Example of Estimation of 8. Supply 241
Production Function 191 Introduction 241
Problems of Data Specification in the 8.1 Deriving the Supply Curve
Estimation of Production Functions 192 of a Firm—Short Run 241
Empirical Studies of the Marginal Output Rule 242
Production Function 193 Shut Down Rule 242
6.8 Isoproduct Curves and 8.2 Supply Curve of a Firm—
Production Frontiers 194 Long Run 245
Case Study 1 199 8.3 Elasticity of Supply 246
Case Study 2 200 Time Period 247
7. Analysis and Estimation 202 8.4 Individual Supply to
Market Supply—
of Costs
Industry Supply Curve 247
Introduction 202 Downward Sloping Industry
7.1 The Economic Concept Supply Curve 248
of Cost 203 8.5 Shifts in Supply Curves 248
7.2 From Production Function to
Cost Function—Long-run PART THREE
Total Cost 204
7.3 Relationship between Cost Price and Output Decisions
and Output in the Long Run 206 in Product Markets
7.4 Cost and Output Relationship
in the Short Run 208 9. The Competitive and 255
7.5 Average and Marginal Cost Monopoly Model
Curves in the Long Run 212 Introduction 255
Sources of Economies of Scale 213
9.1 Equilibrium in Competitive
7.6 Average and Marginal Markets—Price Takers’
Cost Curves in the Short Run 217 Equilibrium 256
Relationship between SRMC Characteristics of a Perfectly
and SRAVC Curves 219 Competitive Market 256

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


xiv Contents

9.2 Interference with Equilibrium 261 10.6 Barriers to Entry 318


9.3 Output Decisions for a Firm in Sources of Barriers to Entry 318
a Perfectly Competitive Market 262 10.7 Some Basic Concepts of
9.4 Some Uses of the Game Theory 319
Competitive Model 264 Dominant Strategies 322
9.5 Normative Analysis of Dominated Strategies 323
Perfect Competition 270 Maximin Strategies 324
9.6 The Monopoly Model 272 Pure and Mixed Strategies 325
9.7 Pricing and Output Decisions 10.8 An Entry Game 325
in a Monopoly 274
10.9 Games of Imperfect and
9.8 Monopoly vs Incomplete Information 326
Competitive Solution 278
10.10 Sequential Games—
9.9 Taxing a Monopolist 280 First-mover Advantage 329
9.10 Normative Analysis 10.11 Repeated Games 330
of Monopoly 281
10.12 Finitely Repeated Games 331
9.11 Public Policy and Case Study 1 336
Regulation of Monopoly 282
Case Study 2 337
Antitrust Policy 283
Case Study 3 337
Antitrust Legislations in India 283
Patent Policy 284 11. Alternative Pricing Practices 339
9.12 Price Discrimination 285 Introduction 339
9.13 Breakeven Analysis 289 11.1 Pricing of Multiple Products 340
Case Study 1 296 Products with Interdependent Demands 340
Case Study 2 296 Products Related in Production
Case Study 3 296 (Joint Products) 341
Fully-distributed Costs and
10. Monopolistic Competition 298
Incremental-cost Pricing 346
and Oligopoly An Example 346
Introduction 298 Ramsey Pricing 347
10.1 Monopolistic Competition— Transfer Pricing 348
Assumptions and Features 299 11.2 Price Discrimination 351
10.2 Determination of Short-run Numerical Example to Show that
and Long-run Equilibrium 300 Price Discrimination is Profitable 352
Optimal Level of Selling and Two-part Tariff 353
Promotional Outlays 302
Peak-load Pricing 354
10.3 Normative Analysis of
Product Bundling 354
Monopolistic Competition 302
Full Cost Pricing 355
10.4 Features of Oligopoly 303
Other Pricing Practices 356
10.5 Equilibrium in Oligopoly 304
Numerical Example of 11.3 Marginalism in Practice 359
Cournot Equilibrium 306 Case Study 1 362
Bertrand Model 308 Case Study 2 362
Stackelberg Model 309 12. Markets for Factor Inputs 365
The Kinked Demand Model 310
Introduction 365
Collusion 313
12.1 Competitive Factor Markets 365
Price Leadership 316
Demand for a Single Variable Factor 366

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Contents xv

Demand for Several Variable Factors 370 Purchasing Insurance 409


Industry Demand for Factors 372 Controlling the Operating Environment 409
Supply of Inputs to a Firm 373 Restricted Use of Firm-specific Assets 410
Market Supply of Inputs 374 13.6 Production of Depletable
Equilibrium and the Concept Resources—Intertemporal
of Economic Rent 375 Aspects 410
Economic Rent 375 The Production Decision 410
12.2 Monopsony in the Expected Market Price 411
Factor Market 377 13.7 Interest Rates and
Minimum Wage Laws 378 Their Determination 413
12.3 Factor Markets with Case Study 1 417
Monopoly Power 380 Case Study 2 418
Bilateral Monopoly 382
12.4 Land as a Factor of PART FOUR
Production 383
Rent 383
Market Failures
12.5 Capital as a Factor of 14. Economics of Information 421
Production 384
12.6 Profit 385 Introduction 421
Case Study 1 389 14.1 Asymmetric Information 422
Case Study 2 389 14.2 Signalling 423
14.3 Adverse Selection 426
13. Long-term Investment and 391 Market Responses to Adverse Selection 428
Risk Analysis Government Responses to
Introduction 391 Asymmetric Information Arising
from Hidden Characteristics 431
13.1 The Capital-budgeting Process,
Basic Framework and Stages 14.4 Hidden Actions 431
in the Process 392 Moral Hazards in the Insurance Market 432
Generation of Capital Efficiency Effects of Moral Hazards 434
Investment Projects 393 Ways of Mitigating Moral Hazards 434
Estimation of Cash Flows 393 Moral Hazards in Product Markets 438
Evaluation of Investment Projects 395 Brand Name Reputations as Hostages 439
Comparison of NPV and IRR— Guarantees and Warranties 439
Do They Give the Same Rankings? 402 Case Study 1 447
Ex-post Evaluation/Review of Projects 403 Case Study 2 447
13.2 Economic Cost-benefit
Analysis 403 15. Externalities and 449
13.3 Risk and Adjustments for Risk 405 Public Goods
13.4 Decision-making under Introduction 449
Uncertainty 407 15.1 Externalities 450
Maximin Criterion 407 Private vs Social Cost 451
Minimax Regret Criterion 407 15.2 Government Responses
13.5 Managing Risk and Uncertainty 408 to Externalities 452
Seek More Information 408 Taxes 452
Diversification 408 Regulation 453
Hedging 409 Effluent Fee 453

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


xvi Contents

Transferable Emission Permits 454 16.4 Level of Investment 487


Recycling 456 16.5 Inflation and Unemployment 489
15.3 Market Reponses 16.6 Balance of Payments 494
to Externalities 457
17. Fiscal, Monetary, and 502
Mergers 457
Social Conventions 457
Exchange Rate Policies
Property Rights and Introduction 502
Bargaining—Coase Theorem 457 17.1 Business Cycles 502
A Legal Solution 460 17.2 Fiscal Policy 505
15.4 Public Goods 460 17.3 Monetary Policy 510
Efficient Provision of Public Goods 462 17.4 Exchange Rate Policies 517
Public Goods and Market Failure 462 Devaluation 520
Private Preferences for Public Goods 463 Prediction of Movements in
Impure Public Goods 463 Exchange Rates 522
15.5 Public–private Partnerships 464 Relationship between Domestic
Monetary and Fiscal Policies and
Definition of Public–private
Exchange Rate Policies 523
Partnerships 464
Scope of Public–private Partnerships 465 18. The New Economy 528
Contracting Out 465 Introduction 528
Private Financing 466 18.1 The New Economy—
Application of Public–private Definition and Characteristics 528
Partnerships 467 The Internet and the World Wide Web 529
Case Study 1 469 18.2 Network Industries in
Case Study 2 470 the New Economy 530
18.3 Impact on Industry Structure 533
PART FIVE 18.4 The Rise and Fall of Dot-coms 534
Macroeconomic Environment 18.5 Fundamental Laws and
Concepts of Old Economy 535
16. Macroeconomic Aggregates 473 18.6 Internet Service Providers
in India 537
Introduction 473
18.7 Internet Pricing Models 538
16.1 Aggregate Output 474
Flat-rate Pricing 538
Gross Domestic Product and
Usage-sensitive Pricing 538
Gross National Product 476
Transaction-based Pricing 539
16.2 Aggregate Price Level—Price
Indices 479 Priority Pricing 539
Consumer Price Index 479 Charging on the Basis of Social Cost 539
Wholesale Price Index 481 Precedence Model 539
GDP Deflator 481 Smart Market Mechanism Model 539
16.3 Aggregate Consumption 482 18.8 Government and the
Irving Fisher’s Hypothesis 485 New Economy 540
Life Cycle Hypothesis 485
Appendices 543
Duesenberry’s Hypothesis 486
Random Walk Hypothesis 487 Index 584

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


C HAPTE R 1
Foundations of
Managerial Economics

OBJECTIVES Introduction
After reading this chapter, the
readers will be able to
l understand the definition
E conomics is a subject that ranks high on familiarity. In a survey
conducted in Japan amongst lay persons, one of the questions
asked was: ‘What would the respondent associate with the
and scope of economics
word “high”?’ The survey results revealed that a relatively large
l gain an insight into the
proportion of respondents associated the word with ‘inflation’,
basic concepts and
analytical methods of an unadulterated economic term, and a much smaller portion
economics associated the word with the volcano, Fujiyama.
l understand the basic The scope of economics is also very wide. It includes micro-
supply–demand analysis, economics, macroeconomics, welfare economics, development
the working of the market
mechanism, the theory of economics, mathematical economics, and a lot more. With
the firm, the theory of ‘management’ having spun off as an independent discipline in
consumer behaviour, and academics, the applicability of tools of microeconomics to mana-
marginal analysis
gerial decision-making was popularized. The subject which
l have clarity on the scope
and definition of
focuses on the application of microeconomic tools to the special
managerial economics context of managerial decision-making is called ‘managerial eco-
l comprehend the nomics’. This chapter will focus on the definition and scope of
fundamental questions managerial economics.
that economics, in general,
After defining the subject and its scope, this chapter will
and managerial economics,
in particular addresses. elaborate on the analytical tools used in managerial economics,
l appreciate the role of borrowed from microeconomics. Managerial economics borrows
economics even in contexts two important analytical techniques from microeconomics,
where markets fail ‘optimization’ and ‘determination of equilibrium’. There are also

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


4 Managerial Economics

Inflation is the rate of other techniques, which have been borrowed from other decision
increase in prices. sciences. This chapter will focus on these two techniques, with which a
bulk of managerial economics problems can be solved. Optimization
occurs at the micro level of decision-making, wherein the decision-maker’s
objective is to arrive at the best combination of goods to be consumed or
produced, or of inputs to be employed.
The determination of equilibrium is at a slightly higher level of
aggregation at the level of markets, and is the outcome of the interaction
of the different economic agents in the market.

1.1 What is Economics?

Economics is all pervading and makes its presence felt when various
economic agents take decisions. In each of these contexts, economics
gives us techniques, rooted in sound logic, with which the decision can
be assessed in terms of the pros and cons, the advantages and disadvan-
tages, and the benefits and costs. So much so, the head of a country once
said, ‘I want a “one-handed” economist to advise ...’ because economists’
assessment will most often say ‘on the one hand ... but on the other hand
...’ Listing out outcomes, both favourable and unfavourable, makes the
final decision a well-informed one. Buying goods through a smuggler
has its own benefits and costs. Advocating heavy tax cuts may mean less
burden on individuals, but it also means less resources available to spend
on public goods; curbing imports may protect domestic industry, but it
also cuts off avenues for exports; a wage hike announcement by a leading
steel producer may ward off potential entrants into the industry, but it may
also add to overall inflation. The decision-makers using the methodology
of economics will take a decision dictated by the need of the hour, well
aware of both the favourable and the unfavourable consequences.
The whole gamut of issues addressed by economics is traditionally
classified into the following three categories of questions:
1. What to produce?
2. How to produce?
3. How to distribute?

Three critical questions These critical questions are addressed at different levels of aggregation
addressed by the in an economic system. The subject matter which addresses these
subject matter of
economics—what to
questions at the lowest degree of aggregation, which happens to be that of
produce, how to the individual as a decision-maker is called microeconomics. Managerial
produce, and how economics borrows heavily from this. The subject matter which addresses
to distribute.
these questions at the highest level of aggregation, which happens to

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 5

be that of the decision-maker being the ‘economy’ itself, is called


macroeconomics.
These questions are difficult to answer because of scarcity of resources,
which is a fundamental characteristic of the resource base. Therefore,
decisions regarding utilization of resources that are scarce have to be
taken carefully, and economics provides the methodology to answer these
fundamental questions.
How does economics make such comprehensive assessments at the
micro level? Economics makes a simplifying assumption—that of a
rational behaviour amongst individuals—that individuals as both con-
sumers and producers seek to maximize satisfaction and profits, respec-
tively. With this rational behaviour, individuals interact and negotiate,
and arrive at the best possible solution through a very powerful mecha-
nism called the market. The solution is arrived at through the interaction
of two prominent forces in the market, demand and supply. Let us take a
real situation. You, along with 10 others from your class, decide to buy
calculators. You have in your mind a certain value attached to it and are
willing to buy so long as the price that you have to pay is less than this
value. The sellers of calculators also have in their mind a certain value
attached to the calculators and are willing to sell only when the price is
above this value. These two forces of demand and supply meet, interact,
and negotiate in a market, which enables the buyers and sellers to arrive
at a situation wherein both are able to achieve their goals. An economy
that encourages the free working of these forces in a ‘market’ and relies
on solutions arrived by the market is a ‘free market’ economy.
Later in this chapter, the reader will be exposed to a more detailed
discussion on the analytical tool of the supply–demand analysis, which is
used extensively in managerial economics.
Economics examines in detail the behaviour of individual decision-
making units, which constitute the forces of demand and supply. Since
consumers constitute the demand side of the market, economics analyses
the behaviour of the consumer (dealt with in detail in Chapters 2 and 3);
and since the producer (the firm) constitutes the supply side of the market,
the behaviour of the firms as producers is also analysed in economics
(dealt with in Chapters 5 and 6). A thorough understanding of these
market forces is important for a manager whose success or ‘failure’ is
measured by how well he ‘plays’ in the marketplace to maximize the
goals of the firm.
While providing solutions to the individual players in the marketplace,
the analytical approach suggested by economics is the marginal approach.
In this approach, problem situations are assessed by looking at the impact

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


6 Managerial Economics

Marginal approach on cost and benefits at the margin. That is the impact on cost and ben-
involves using the efits of a unit change in the decision-making variable; for example, the
impact of a change to
impact on costs and benefits of a decision to increase or change quantity
take decisions.
produced by an additional unit. This ‘marginal approach’ is one of the
most significant contributions made by economics to decision-making.
Managerial economics is built on the concept of marginal analysis. This
is dealt with in greater detail later in this chapter.
While economics shows how the market mechanism provides solutions,
there are some market solutions that are not desirable from the society’s
point of view. Economics’ concern extends also to the society. For example,
if the outcome of the working of market forces is the emergence of one
large supplier, such as Microsoft in the computer software industry,
economics analyses its flip side—will the supplier then exploit the market;
or will the supplier become complacent about efficiency because there is
no one to compete with? Therefore, economics, quite naturally, enters
the area of regulation—directing the market forces to move along a
desirable direction so that society’s welfare is also maximized. Managers
ought to be aware of these aspects of regulation so that they do not break
these rules while ‘playing’ in the market.
There are also situations where markets fail to provide solutions. For
example, let us take the case where the government decides to build a
lighthouse. How much should the users be charged, and if charged, how
can non-payers be prevented from using the light emanating from the
lighthouse? The market will not provide solutions because users will not
reveal their preferences and the value attached to the services of the
lighthouse, because they can continue to use the light from the lighthouse
without revealing its worth to them. This effectively means that the
demand force is non-existent and so the market mechanism, which relies
on the interaction between demand and supply, fails. Once again,
economics comes to the rescue of the decision-makers in such situations.
This is dealt with in later chapters.

1.2 Definition and Scope of Managerial Economics

The decision-making problems addressed by economics include both


problems faced by individuals as consumers and producers and those
faced by the economy as a whole. This wide range of issues is classified
under two broad heads—those that deal with the individuals’ choice (the
individual as a consumer and as a producer), and those that need to be
addressed at the aggregate level of the economy as a whole. The former

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 7

Microeconomic Macroeconomic Decision constitutes the subject matter of microeconomics,


Theory Theory Sciences while the latter constitutes the subject matter of
macroeconomics.
Managerial economics draws heavily from
Constitutes managerial economics microeconomic theory to provide tools and tech-
when applied to provide solutions niques to facilitate decision-making in the mana-
to decision-making situations faced
by managers gerial context. It also draws on other decision
sciences, such as operations research, to enable
Fig. 1.1 Definition, Scope, and Functions well-informed decision-making. Managerial eco-
of Managerial Economics nomics, unlike microeconomics, does not assume
the ‘aggregate’ picture as given. The manager can-
not afford to ignore the macroeconomic environment while taking rational
decisions for the firm.
The definition, scope, and functions of managerial economics have
been depicted in Fig. 1.1.
The contribution of managerial economics as a subject to managerial
decision-making has been best put by Joel Dean (1951), one of the earliest
authors on the subject. In the preface to his book, Managerial Economics,
he says, ‘The purpose of this book is to show how economic analysis can
be used in formulating business policies ... the big gap between the
problems of logic that intrigue economic theorists and the problems of
policy that plague practical management needs to be bridged in order to
give executives access to the practical contributions that economic
thinking can make to top-management policies ....’

1.3 Typical Decisions Handled by Managerial Economics

More often than not, young managers are asked to look into the economic
validity of an expansion or diversification plan. For example, if Barista, a
chain of coffee shops, decides to diversify into corner bookshops, the
first task is to economically justify this diversification, that is, if it is in the
interest of Barista to diversify. This requires the application of tools offered
by managerial economics. All readers are aware of the rivalry between
Pepsi and Coke in the soft drink market. The rationale of strategies
adopted by them to become the market leader can be found in managerial
economics. The movement in the price of petrol as a result of the
behaviour of the crude price set primarily by OPEC is not at all baffling
when the situation is analysed using the analytical frameworks provided
by managerial economics.
Coming across firms that have built capacity far in excess of what is
being effectively used seems apparently irrational, but the reader will

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


8 Managerial Economics

realize that it is not so after gaining familiarity with managerial economics.


Firms often face problems regarding optimum resource allocation on
the shop floor. Questions, such as what the size of the production run
should be; which is the least cost combination of inputs the production
engineer needs to employ in order to minimize costs; what should the
product be priced at; should a new production process be adopted? etc.,
are addressed by managerial economics.
These typical managerial problems can, in one way or the other, be
categorized under the three fundamental economic problems addressed
by economics. These are:
1. What to produce?
2. How to produce?
3. How to distribute?
These three fundamental questions arise and need to be addressed by
The economic
decisions assume a decision-makers because of the scarcity of resources. Had resources been
high degree of plentiful, with no perceivable limits, there would not be a decision-making
criticality because they
are to be taken in the
problem. We could then have all that we wished for. For instance, you, a
context of scarce college student, would be allowed by your parents to spend any amount.
resources which have You can have all you want—ice cream, movies, music, books, weekend
alternative uses, and
in the context of getaways, and so on. As against this, put yourself in a position where you
growing wants. are given only Rs 500 per month by your parents. You will now have to
decide how much to spend on ice cream, movies, etc. It is in this latter
situation that economics comes to your help by providing tools and
techniques with which well-informed decisions can be made. The situation
is complicated by the fact that there is a constraint on the resources that
you possess and you want to get the best out of this constrained resource.
Economics helps deal with such situations where the decision-maker is
seeking a solution which maximizes in the presence of constraints, which
is called constrained maximization.
The decision-making in a situation with resource constraints could
still be easy if the uses to which the resources could be put had been
specified. For instance, if you had been told that out of Rs 500, Rs 200
should be spent on books, Rs 100 on movies, and the rest on food, the
decision-making would be less complex. However, in reality, resources
have more than one use to which they can be put; the Rs 500 can be used in
a thousand different ways. This possibility, of putting resources to more
than one use, makes decision-making difficult, and the application of
economic logic eases the process.
We could still have gotten away if, as human beings, we were a
contented lot with a well-defined fixed need set, which could be

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 9

methodically fully satisfied. However, human beings, by nature, have a


continuously growing and constantly changing need set, which at no
point is fully satisfied, thereby only adding to the complexity. Therefore,
we have no choice but to resort to economics to provide us with tools
and techniques to enable us take the right decisions in all economic
activities, be it consumption, production, sale, or distribution.
A manager’s primary responsibility is the allocation of scarce resources
(financial, human, machines, etc.) amongst alternative uses in order to realize
the objective of profit maximization or other objectives. The link between
economic logic, tools, and techniques, and the managers’ responsibilities
could not be more obvious. Economists began focusing on and magnifying
this link, and thus, emerged the new suffix ‘managerial’ to economics
and the subject ‘managerial economics’. Thus, the suffix ‘managerial’ is
more than justified, and hence, the subject ‘managerial economics’.

1.4 Opportunity Costs

Scarcity of resources, besides imposing a constraint on the choice set,


also makes us realize that there are ‘trade offs’. Putting a resource to one
use means that you are foregoing the other uses to which you could have
put it to had you not used it in the present use. Amongst the other uses
that you could have put it to, the concern is only on the next best use. So
what you are foregoing is what you would have got had you put the
resource to its next best use. The benefits foregone by not putting it to
the next best use is therefore the cost of putting the resource to the present
use. This cost of putting the resource to the present use is nothing but
what is foregone and so, what is foregone is called the ‘opportunity cost’
of this resource being put to the present use.
In the context of consumption, this concept is used to evaluate choices.
Suppose a consumer decides to take a loan to buy a car and so has to pay
up his EMIs. He has to evaluate this decision after considering the
opportunity cost of taking the loan in terms of what he will have to forego
if he took a loan to buy a car. In the context of production, a resource is
valued at its opportunity cost, that is, at what one could have got by
putting it to the next best use or, what one is foregoing by putting it to the
present use. In the context of exchange too, this concept is used. When a
country has to decide on what it should produce and what it should trade
in, the rule is to concentrate on the production of those goods for which
it has a lower opportunity cost. The theory of comparative advantage in
the context of international trade is based on this concept. This concept
of opportunity cost is dealt with in detail in the chapter on costs.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


10 Managerial Economics

Definition: Opportunity cost is defined as what the resource would have


yielded in the next best alternative, which has to be foregone if the
resource is put to its current use.

1.5 Positioning Managerial Economics in the Big Picture

In the previous section, we saw that the answers to the three fundamental
questions are made difficult because all economies face the problem of
scarcity of resources. Economics seeks to answer these questions for
individuals at the micro level and for the nation at the macro level through
the mechanism of the market. In a market system, consumers and
producers make their own decisions and macroeconomics and managerial
economics address these issues. However, in a market system, all these
Decisions addressed by
managerial economics players take decisions simultaneously. In order to understand this
are all taken in two complexity, it is inevitable for the economists to resort to model building,
markets—factor
‘abstracting’ from the detailed reality to understand and conceptualize
market and product
market. Factor market the complex reality.
is the market where One model which fits together all these players and their activities,
factors (resources used
for production but
and helps us understand the concept of markets is the circular flow model.
owned by the This model visualizes the economy as consisting of two sectors or institu-
households) are tions—the household and the firm. The household sector owns productive
exchanged. Product
markets are those resources, such as labour, capital, and land, which can be used for pro-
where the products duction by the firms. Therefore, the household indulges in selling these
produced are
resources to the firms through a market called the factor market (Fig. 1.2).
exchanged.
The resources owned by the households are the inputs, also referred to
as factors of production, and hence, also
Product termed ‘the factor market’. With the income
Income Markets Revenue earned from the sale of factors of production,
Spent Earned the households lay a demand on goods and
Goods Goods services, which are produced by the firms and
Demanded Supplied sold to the households in a market called the
product market. The two institutions of
House households and firms get together in both the
Firms
Holds
markets and the markets throw up the fol-
Inputs Inputs lowing solutions; the quantity produced (and
Supplied Demanded sold), the cost at which it is produced (de-
pends on the price at which households sell
Income Factor
Earned Factor Costs their productive resources), and the price at
Markets (Input) which the products are sold. Microeconomics
examines these outcomes in detail and
Fig. 1.2 Circular Flow Model provides the economic logic behind these

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 11

outcomes. This logic is used by managerial economics to provide the


decision-makers with the techniques to arrive at the desirable outcomes.
In microeconomics and managerial economics the focus is on the
aspects within these two markets of factors and products—the players,
the decision-making processes of these players, the markets, and their
dynamics.

1.6 The Theory of the Firm and the Role of Profits

Any decision is taken and evaluated in the perspective of the objective.


So is a managerial decision; it is taken and can be evaluated in the context
of its objective. The objective of the decision has to be clearly stated. For
an individual who is a consumer, the objective is to maximize satisfaction,
or what is called utility in economics. For a producer the objective is to
maximize profits or other objectives. The decision-maker as a producer
operates in an entity called the ‘firm’. The firm is an entity that brings
together resources required to produce a product. It is therefore appro-
priate at this juncture to look into the theories that would explain the
existence and working of the firm.
The theory of the firm should explain the behaviour of a firm in the
light of its objectives. Given the complexity of the working of firms,
economic and behavioural theorists have resorted to model building.
One of the earliest basic models says that the firm’s behaviour is dictated
only by its desire to maximize profits. This theory seems commonsensical
because the first objective that would come to the reader’s mind is also
profits. However, a closer look at the reality makes one realize that the
firm’s behaviour is dictated by various other considerations, such as
minimizing risk, maximizing sales, etc.
A richer version of the fundamental theory of profits is a theory that
says that the firm wishes to maximize its wealth or value. This is also the
version adopted by managerial economists and, therefore, we will
examine it in detail.
A firm’s value is defined as the present value of its expected future
cash flow. The reader will be exposed to the concept of cash flow in courses
relating to accounting/finance, but for now, we will treat cash flow as
synonymous to profits.
Present value of expected future profits
n
P τ1 Pτ2 Pτ3 P τn Pτt
= + + + ... + = ∑ t
1 + i (1 + i ) t =1 (1 + i )
2 3 n
(1 + i ) (1 + i )

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


12 Managerial Economics

Economic profit is where P τ t is the profit in time period t, and i is the discount rate used to
defined as the bring the future value to the present. This method of discounting (as
difference between against compounding, which the reader may be familiar with) will be
total revenue and
total economic costs. dealt with in detail in Chapter 13.
What is profit? The reader would be able to say quite easily that profit
is the difference between total revenue and total cost. In order to maximize
profit, it is important to maximize total revenue and minimize total cost.
Therefore, every employee working for a firm has a role to play in
maximizing profits, and the behaviour of every entity in the firm can be
dictated by this objective. The shop floor producers can take measures
to increase efficiency, thereby reducing costs; the marketing managers
can take measures to increase revenue through increased sales; the
research division can develop substitutes and complements, which could
further contribute to the minimization of costs and to the maximization
of the total revenue.
Reality, again, dictates that this profit maximization cannot be an
unconstrained maximum. Many a time, managers and decision-makers
are faced with situations wherein they are stuck with some inputs, such
as a specific piece of machinery, or a contractual employment, which
they cannot tamper with even if that would lead to minimization of costs.
The decision-makers may have little flexibility in the production process
also—inputs availability may be limited. Even if economies of scale dictate
installation of large plants, limited availability of inputs may restrict the
size of the plants to be installed.
Given this fact, the techniques used to maximize profits are, therefore,
constrained optimization techniques which the reader will be exposed to
in later chapters.
Economic cost is the
Economists advocate a concept of profit called economic profit,
value of what is given wherein profit is defined as the difference between total revenue and
up or foregone total economic cost. Economic costs are what economists consider as
because of putting the
resource to its present relevant costs estimated using the principle of opportunity costs. These
use. concepts are explained in detail in the chapter on costs, suffice for now to
say that when economists speak of profit, they define total cost as inclusive
of the cost of capital and labour provided by the owner of the entity called
firm. Let us take a simple situation where Mr Chris runs a grocery store
from one room in his house (the grocery store is the firm here). He could
have taken up employment for Rs 60,000 per year, and the capital that
Firm is an entity which he has invested in the shop, if put in the bank, would fetch him a return
brings together
resources/factors for of Rs 12,000 per annum. So if Mr Chris’s venture, the grocery store, has
production of finished to be profitable, it has to earn at least Rs 72,000 per annum. Any earning
goods.
greater than Rs 72,000 is what the economists would call economic profit.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 13

Definition: Economic profit is defined as the difference between the total


revenue and the total economic costs. Economic cost is defined as ‘relevant’
cost. The ‘relevance’ is defined in the context of ‘run’—short run or
long run.

1.7 Why do Economic Profits Exist?

Economic profits, as defined in the previous section, arise under many


circumstances, and each of these circumstances emerges as a theory of
profit. The first situation conducive to economic profit is one where an
innovation has been made by a courageous innovator. The innovation
of the microprocessor by Intel is a classic example of the role played by
innovation in profit generation.
The second factor that explains differences in behaviour and differences
in performance, as indicated by economic profit, is the ability to take
risk, and profit is seen as a reward for risk bearing. The ability to take on
the risk of innovation, such as, the Intel chip, is to be rewarded, and that
is called economic profit.
Many a time, imperfections in the market give rise to economic profit.
A market with a single seller or a few large sellers will have greater power
and this shows up as economic profit. This is in contrast with the situation
of perfection in the market where there are a large number of sellers, so
large that no single seller has any power to influence the price in the
market. In such situations, economic profits are non-existent.
There are other theories of firms, which are discussed in detail in
Chapter 5.

1.8 The Invisible Hand

No introduction to economics in general is complete without exposing


the reader to the concept of the invisible hand. This concept is to
economics what Darwin’s principle of natural selection is to biology or
what Newton’s principle of gravitation is to astronomy.
This unifying principle is the contribution made by Adam Smith (1776)
in his book, Wealth of Nations. Adam Smith argued that even if individuals
behave selfishly and pursue their own interests, they will be indirectly
promoting the interest of the society. To quote Adam Smith:
But it is only for the sake of profit that any man employs his capital in
the support of industry; and he will always, therefore, endeavour to
employ it in the support of that industry of which the produce is likely to
be of the greatest value, or to exchange for the greatest quantity either of

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


14 Managerial Economics

money or of other goods ... he is in this, as in many other cases, led by


an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.
Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By
pursuing his own interests, he frequently promotes that of the society
more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.
This was conceptualized by Adam Smith more than two centuries ago
and holds good even today. Millions of transactions take place between
two ends of the world, each working with a purely selfish interest, and
yet, in the process, furthering the welfare of the nation.
Adam Smith’s conceptualization of the economy as one big market
working under some laws like the law of the invisible hand is the corner
stone of micro and managerial economics. It is from this that we derive
the concepts of the market and market economy.
Having gained familiarity with the definition and scope of managerial
economics, let us now move on to elaborate on the analytical techniques
used in managerial economics.

1.9 Microeconomic Problems in Managerial Economics


As mentioned in the introduction to this chapter, the two analytical
techniques of optimization and determination of equilibrium help bring
order in an otherwise gigantic and complex set of economic problems
by enabling the classification of the relevant economic problem as
amenable for the use of one or the other technique. When the decision-
maker wants to arrive at the best choice of goods to be produced or
consumed, it is an optimization problem. Mathematically, the process of
optimization is equivalent to finding the maximum (of a desirable variable)
or minimum (of an undesirable variable). This is what calculus deals
with. This is the reason why mathematics enters the realm of managerial
economics in a big way.
When we are interested in ascertaining the price of a good, say, onions,
in the market, from which it has little or no tendency to change, then we
are trying to arrive at an equilibrium price. This equilibrium price level
is a crucial input for fixing ceiling or floor prices in regulating markets,
and for decisions regarding entry and exit of firms.
To arrive at equilibrium solutions, the working tool used is the supply–
demand analysis, and to solve optimization problems the reader must
have an understanding of the concepts of total, average, and marginal
magnitudes and the relationship amongst these.
We will examine the supply–demand analysis in the following section,
and the total, average, and marginal magnitudes in the subsequent section.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 15

1.10 Supply–demand Analysis

In economics, we often resort to graphs to facilitate comprehension of


abstract phenomena, such as markets. Supply–demand analysis also can
be best understood through graphical representations. We will, therefore,
keep the graph represented in Fig. 1.3 as the reference.
In the figure, the horizontal axis represents quantities of a good per
month, per week, or per any other unit of time. The vertical axis represents
the price expressed in monetary terms, and is stated as Rs/unit of the
good. That we plot price on the Y-axis is a matter of convention (although
we will see later that price is an independent variable, and therefore,
ought to be plotted on the X-axis). The curve DD is the demand curve.
Every point on this curve shows the quantity that the consumer is willing
to demand at that price. Let us take any price, say Rs 8. The demand
curve shows the quantity Q D , which is what the consumer is willing to
buy at Rs 8. In other words, it captures the relationship between the
quantity demanded and the price, that is, what the consumer is willing to
buy at different prices. Normally, the demand curve slopes downward,
showing an inverse relationship between price and quantity. While we
will be examining the reasons for this inverse relationship in-depth later,
it is sufficient at this point to offer a commonsensical explanation to this,
that we, as consumers, tend to buy more at lower prices and less at higher
prices. The reader can relate to the discount sales offered by sellers to
attract buyers. The curve SS is the supply curve. Every point on this shows
the quantity that the seller is willing to supply at that price. For example,

Rs/Unit
(Price) SS

P=8

P′
E
P*

P ′′ DD

Quantity
QD Q S′′ QD′ Q* Q S′ QS QD′′ Q

Fig. 1.3 Basic Demand–Supply Model

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


16 Managerial Economics

if the price is equal to Rs 8, the SS curve will show the quantity Q S that
the seller is willing to supply at the price, Rs 8.
In other words, the supply curve captures the relationship between
the quantity supplied and the price, that is, what the supplier is willing to
sell at different prices. Normally, the supply curve slopes upwards, show-
ing a positive relationship between the price and the quantity supplied.
While we will be examining the derivation of the supply curve in detail
later, suffice it to say that it reflects the normal tendency of the seller to
be willing to supply more only at higher prices.
It can be seen in Fig. 1.3 that the two curves, DD and SS, intersect at
point E, and the corresponding price and quantity are P * and Q *,
respectively. This point of intersection is called the equilibrium. The
equilibrium state is a state of balance (state of balance between demand
and supply), from which there is no tendency to change. Even if the
price or the quantity deviate from this equilibrium price or equilibrium
quantity, the forces of DD and SS will make it unsustainable, and
eventually, it tends to get back to the equilibrium level. In the figure, if P
were to drift upwards from P * to P ′, the situation would be one of
imbalance, with the imbalance showing up as an excess of SS (Q S′ ) over
DD (Q ′D ). What happens to price if there is an excess supply of a good in
the marketplace? The price has to come down; it will tend back to P *.
Let us take a situation where the price falls below the equilibrium level
to P. At this price, the situation is one of imbalance, with the imbalance
showing up as an excess D (Q ′′D ) over supply (Q S′′ ). The reader must be
able to see that if the demand for a good exceeds its supply, the price will
go up, and tend back to P *. It is not difficult for the reader to visualize a
situation where the consumer, caught up in a shortage, bids up the price
and triggers off an upward pressure on price.
Thus, the point of intersection is the point of equilibrium, since it is a
state of balance from which, if either P or Q deviates, it will sooner or
later tend back to the equilibrium level. This inherent characteristic
of tending back to equilibrium automatically from any point of disequi-
librium is called stable equilibrium. The supply–demand model described
above with the demand and supply curves sloped the way they are is a
model which gives a stable equilibrium solution.
Such a solution is possible and acceptable only if the market is a level
play field with no one individual or group capable of distorting either of
the two forces. Such a solution is acceptable if the ‘market’ includes the
entire relevant population. If the market excludes the low income group
simply because they cannot afford to pay the high price which may be
arrived at by the market mechanism, then the solution may not be

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 17

acceptable. A solution can be arrived at only if the buyers reveal their


preferences and reveal the value that they are willing to attach to the
consumption of a commodity. If they choose not to reveal, then the market
mechanism fails.
There are many situations in which the solution offered by the market
are not accepted and the regulator chooses to tinker with them. Such
situations are described in Chapter 9 in the sub-section titled ‘Interferences
with the equilibrium’.
Further, there are situations where the market mechanism’s solution is
inefficient and further still, situations where the market mechanism fails
to provide an equilibrium solution. These situations are dealt with in
Chapters 14 and 15 where situations of asymmetric information and
situations of externalities are discussed.
Definition: Equilibrium is defined as a state of balance between two
forces. Stable equilibrium is one where the forces tend towards this point
of balance constantly despite slipping off from the equilibrium.
The next related question which we need to answer is: Can equilibrium
price or quantity change to another level, or can an equilibrium shift?
This will be answered in Chapters 2 and 8 where these aspects will be
dealt in detail.

1.11 Total, Average, and Marginal Magnitudes

We now address the second analytical technique, that of optimization,


Total magnitude is the
cumulative marginal and the working tools associated with it. With the help of these working
magnitude. Marginal tools, it is possible to solve optimization problems without any in-depth
magnitude is the knowledge of calculus.
contribution made by
the last additional We will understand the concept of total, average, and marginal in rela-
unit to the magnitude tion to one magnitude—revenue. The concept, principles, and relation-
in question. Average
magnitude is the
ships amongst these will not change with the changes in magnitude. For
magnitude per unit. instance, the magnitude could be utility, product, or cost. Whatever be the
magnitude, the underlying concept and relationships will be the same.
We start by taking a hypothetical linear demand relationship for a
good, Q . The schedule of data corresponding to the hypothetical linear
demand equation given as P = 10 – Q , is listed in Table 1.1. The first two
columns of the table show the values of Q and P derived from the
hypothetical equation.
If the first two column entries are multiplied, that is, if price is multiplied
by quantity, it would give us the total magnitude which, in this case, is
the total revenue. If the seller sells two units of Q at Rs 8 per unit, he gets

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


18 Managerial Economics

Table 1.1 Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue

1 2 3 4 5 6
Quantity Price Total Revenue MR MR MR
(AR) (TR) (upward (downward (better
approximation) approximation) approximation)
Average of 4 and 5

0 10 0 9 – –
1 9 9 7 9 8
2 8 16 5 7 6
3 7 21 3 5 4
4 6 24 1 3 2
5 5 25 –1 1 0
6 4 24 –3 –1 –2
7 3 21 –5 –3 –4
8 2 16 –7 –5 –6
9 1 9 –9 –7 –8
10 0 0 – –9 –

a TR of 16. It must be noted that the price is always expressed per unit.
The third column in Table 1.1 gives us the TR, which is PQ .
If PQ is the total magnitude, the revenue per unit is the average
magnitude, which will be called average revenue. So average revenue is
nothing but TR /Q or PQ /Q ≡ P . Price is, therefore, average revenue.
Column 2 of Table 1.1 is also the column corresponding to average
revenue. In terms of geometry, the relation between total magnitude
and average magnitude can be seen in Fig. 1.4. Total revenue assumes an
inverted U-shape. The average revenue is the slope of the line from the
origin to the relevant level of Q. The slope of this line is the height
TR reached along the curve divided
Total by the horizontal length represented
Revenue 25
24 24 by the distance Q. If we want to find
(TR)
21 21
AR for Q = 3, the height reached
16 16
along the TR curve is 21 and the
horizontal length represented by the
distance Q is 3. Therefore, slope of
9 9 the line from the origin to Q = 3
ΔTR along the TR curve is 21/3 = 7. The
MR ≡ limit AR thus derived is plotted in Fig. 1.5.
(as Δ →0) ΔQ
That takes us on to the definition
of marginal magnitude. Conceptu-
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Q
ally, marginal magnitude is a change
Fig. 1.4 Total Revenue Function in the total magnitude due to the

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 19

Rs/Q smallest possible change in the independent variable,


which here is Q . This, the reader would realize, is noth-
10
ing but the slope of the total revenue curve. Therefore,
the marginal magnitude, which here is marginal rev-
enue, is geometrically the slope along the TR curve.
To algebraically approximate the slope of the TR
curve at Q = 3, we can see what happens to TR when Q
increases by one unit from Q = 3.
0 5 10 Q The ΔTR and ΔQ are the horizontal and vertical
Fig. 1.5 MR and AR (Derived from legs of the small triangle shown between Q = 3 and
Fig. 1.4) Q = 4 in Fig. 1.4, and the slope ΔTR / ΔQ between
Q = 3 and Q = 4 is an approximation of the slope at
Q = 3, an upward approximation. We could also approximate the slope
at Q = 3 as that between Q = 2 and Q = 3. This would be a downward
approximation. The marginal revenue approximated using upward
approximation is given in Col. 4 of Table 1.1, and the downward
approximation in Col. 5. A third approximation, which is better than the
first two, is the average of the two approximations. This is given in Col. 6
of the table. In general, the approximation becomes better as we reduce
ΔQ , to get closer to the slope at a particular Q . In the limit, ΔQ has to
tend to zero. Therefore, a precise estimation of MR can now be defined
as the following:
ΔTR
MR ≡ limit
(as Δ → 0) ΔQ
This is nothing but the concept of ‘derivative’ in calculus, and thus,
marks the entry of calculus into micro and managerial economics.
To summarize, marginal magnitude is a slope measure of the total
magnitude. To get a precise measure of the slope at a particular Q , the
variation in Q has to be as small as possible, with the variation tending to
zero; this is nothing but the concept of derivative.
Now we are ready to make inferences about the values that a marginal
magnitude takes at various levels of Q and its relationship with the aver-
age magnitude.
Inference 1 When a total magnitude is rising, the corresponding
marginal magnitude is positive. This is evident from Fig. 1.4, wherein we
can see that as along as TR is increasing, the slope along the TR curve
must be positive. Using calculus, when dTR/dQ > 0, the total revenue
function is increasing, and dTR/dQ is nothing but the marginal revenue
function.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


20 Managerial Economics

Inference 2 When the total magnitude is falling, the corresponding


marginal magnitude is negative. In calculus terms, when dTR/dQ < 0,
that is, the marginal magnitude is negative, the total magnitude is
decreasing.
Inference 3 When the total magnitude reaches a maximum or a mini-
mum, the corresponding marginal magnitude is zero.
Each of these inferences can be verified with the data provided in
Table 1.1.
Inference 4 When the average magnitude falls/rises, the marginal
magnitude falls/rises at a rate faster than the average, and so will lie
below/above the average magnitude.
At this point, it is necessary to clarify the distinction between average
and marginal magnitude. The average is a per unit magnitude, while the
marginal gives the change in the total magnitude due to the smallest
possible change in Q. In other words, the ‘marginal
Rs magnitude’ gives the contribution made by the last
additional unit (called marginal unit) to the total magni-
tudes. The average magnitude distributes the contribu-
TC
tion made by the marginal unit amongst all units. Let
Point of us take a series of three numbers, say, 3, 4, 2. The average
Total Cost

Smallest
Slope of this series is 3. Now we add a marginal unit, say, 5, to
this series. The marginal unit contributes 5 to the total
and the consequence of this on the average is that the
average is now (3 + 4 + 2 + 5)/4 = 3.5.
What if the marginal unit had been 3? The new
0 Q average would have remained 3. Therefore, the aver-
age magnitude increases only when the marginal unit’s
contribution to the total is greater than the previous
Rs/Q
average. Similarly, the average magnitude falls only
Cost Per Unit (AC or MC)

when the marginal unit’s contribution is less than the


MC
previous average. It is the contribution made by the
marginal unit which pulls up or pulls down the average,
AC and hence, the fourth inference.
Inference 5 When the average magnitude is neither
rising nor falling, the marginal magnitude must be equal
to it. Figure 1.4 and the corresponding average magni-
tude captures only a part of Inference 4, since the average
Q magnitude is a declining function throughout.
Fig. 1.6 Total, Average, and Figure 1.6, where the total magnitude is the total cost,
Marginal Functions has in it both a decreasing slope and an increasing slope,

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 21

and so captures both Inferences 4 and 5. The reader can see that when the
average cost is rising, the marginal unit lies above the average cost.
Definition: Average magnitude is the total magnitude divided by the
number of units, or it is the magnitude per unit. Marginal magnitude is
the change in the magnitude due to a change in the units.
The working tools learnt here will be used extensively in later chapters.

1.12 The Concept of Margin

The demonstration of the concept of margin for use in managerial


decision-making is a significant contribution made by microeconomics
borrowed by managerial economics.
In the face of scarcity, allocation of resources assumes great importance.
In order to maximize the benefits, satisfaction, or profit, the proponents of
the concept of margin advocate that the decision-maker should, at various
points in the decision-making process, ask whether the contribution to
the total revenue (marginal revenue) or the contribution to the total utility
(marginal utility) exceeds the contribution made by the marginal unit to
cost. Basically, the additional cost incurred is compared with the additional
benefits, and as long as the latter exceeds the former, there is an increase
in the net benefit. There are numerous situations in real life when we are
faced with situations requiring decision-making, such as whether to eat
the third cup of ice cream, whether to devote an extra eighth hour to the
study of a subject, whether to further increase the number of TV spot
advertisements, whether to produce an additional block of 100 units of
electricity, etc. All of these can be successfully tackled using the concept
of margin.
The concept of margin is, thus, the foundation of all managerial
decision-making processes. As we proceed, the reader will understand
the importance and relevance of this concept in various situations. The
reader will also be exposed to situations where ignorance of this concept
actually results in wrong decisions.
Definition: Marginal unit is the last additional unit, and the cost, utility,
or product associated with it is the ‘marginal cost’, ‘marginal utility’, or
‘marginal product’, respectively.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


22 Managerial Economics

SUMMARY
l Managerial economics draws heavily from micro l The invisible hand concept of Adam Smith
and macroeconomics and other decision sciences. explains how society’s welfare is maximized even
l It applies these techniques to provide solutions when individuals behave selfishly to further their
to decision-making situations faced by managers. own economic interests.
l The three fundamental economic problems of l The concept of opportunity cost is central to
what to produce, how to produce, and how to managerial economics. This concept emerges
distribute are also the decisions that managers from the thesis that since resources are scarce,
have to take at the firm level. there is always a trade off. The opportunity cost
of a resource is therefore defined as what has to
l The basic model of the theory of the firm
be given up in order to put a resource to the
states that the objective of the firm is profit
current use.
maximization. There are other theories, such as
the satisficing theory. l The problems of microeconomics and managerial
economics can be classified into two broad
l The circular flow model captures the working of
categories—those requiring use of optimization
a simplified economic system, and enables us
techniques, and those requiring supply–demand
to see the role of the consumer, the producer,
analysis to arrive at equilibrium solutions.
and the markets.
l Equilibrium is defined as a state of balance
l Market mechanism provides solutions to the
between supply and demand, which is graphically
choice problem faced by the consumer and the
represented by the point of their intersection.
producer.

KEYWORDS
Average Magnitude: It is the magnitude per unit. Invisible Hand: It is a mechanism that ensures maxi-
It is computed by diving the total magnitude by mization of social benefit even when individuals
quantity. behave and take decisions independently, to maxi-
Equilibrium: It is a state of balance from which there mize the individual benefit.
is no tendency to change. Marginal Magnitude: It is the change in the total
Firms: Firms produce goods using the resources magnitude due to a unit change in quantity.
provided by households. Optimization: Optimization means arriving at the
Households: The members of this institution are best possible state within a given set of constraints.
owners of resources, which they provide to the Profits: This is the difference between total revenue
firms. Households also lay a demand on the goods and total cost.
produced by the firms.

CONCEPT REVIEW QUESTIONS


1. Distinguish between microeconomics, macroeco- 4. Explain the concept of invisible hand in your own
nomics, and managerial economics. words.
2. Explain the theory of the firm. 5. Bring out the role of the market in the circular
3. Why do economic profits exist? flow model.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.


Foundations of Managerial Economics 23

6. Classify the following examples of managerial l When the total function is rising, the marginal
economic decisions under the three fundamental function is rising.
economic problems—what, how, or for whom: l When the total function is rising, the marginal
l Decision by an auto manufacturer to buy out function is positive.
engines l When the total function is rising, the marginal
l Decision by an oil refinery to get into oil explo- function lies above it.
ration l When the marginal function is rising, the
l Decision by Xerox whether to offer service average function is also rising.
facilities l When the average function is falling, the
lDecision by a bank to computerize its operations marginal function lies below it.
7. Explain the concept of equilibrium in economics. l When the marginal function is neither rising
8. In terms of the general relations among total, nor falling, the average function is constant.
average, and marginal quantities, which of the 9. Distinguish between marginal and average
following statements are necessarily true: magnitude.

NUMERICAL PROBLEMS
1. Mr Chris, belonging to a family whose business revenue of Rs 20,00,000. Determine the economic
has been real estate, is contemplating establishing profit/loss of this venture.
an independent real estate agency. He estimates 2. Compute the marginal and average utilities on
the expenditure on the salaries of employees to the basis of the following total utilities:
be Rs 15,00,000, and on rent, supplies, and
X 1 2 3 4 5 6
utilities to be Rs 2,50,000. He would also require
Rs 50,000 initially to be invested in assets. While TU 10 18 25 30 33 35
he is making this new business plan, he is an 3. Compute the marginal and average cost on the
employee of Leo Realtors, where his annual basis of the following total cost:
income is Rs 1,00,000. The market rate of interest X 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
is 12% per annum. He expects to generate a TC 10 18 24 29 36 45 57

REFERENCES
1. Berle, A. and Means, C.G., 1932, The Modern 5. McGuigan R.J., Moyer, R.C. and Harris, F.H., 1999,
Corporations and Private Property, Macmillan, Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategy and
New York. Tactics, International Thomson Publishing.
2. Hirshleifer, J., 1983, Price Theory and Applications, 6. Simon, H., Theories of Decision-making in
Prentice-Hall India. Economics and Behavioural Science, reprinted in
3. Keat, P.G. and Young, P.K.Y., 1996, Managerial Mansfield, E., 1985, Microeconomics: Selected
Economics—Economic Tools for Today’s Decision Readings, Fifth Edn, Norton, New York.
Makers, Prentice Hall.
4. Mansfield, E., Allen, W.B., Doherty, N.A., and
Weigelt, K., 2002, Managerial Economics—Theory,
Applications and Cases, W.W. Norton & Company.

© Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.

You might also like