You are on page 1of 10

The Price-Concentration Relationship in Banking

Author(s): Allen N. Berger and Timothy H. Hannan


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71, No. 2 (May, 1989), pp. 291-299
Published by: The MIT Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1926975 .
Accessed: 11/06/2014 04:50

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of
Economics and Statistics.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PRICE-CONCENTRATION RELATIONSHIP
IN BANKING
AllenN. BergerandTimothyH. Hannan*
A bstract-The commonly observed positive correlation be- average concentration is more often due to the
tween market concentration and profitability may be explained
by non-competitive pricing behavior, as argued by the struc-
high market shares of firms that are efficient than
ture-performance hypothesis, or by the greater effiency of firms to the low market shares of firms that are ineffi-
with dominant market shares, as argued by the efficient- cient. Otherwise, profits and concentration would
structure hypothesis. By examining the price-concentration re-
lationship instead of the profit-concentration relationship, this
not be positively related.
paper tests the structure-performancehypothesis in a manner Thus, the structure-performancehypothesis and
that excludes the efficient-structurehypothesis as an alternative the usual form of the efficient-structurehypothesis
explanation of the results. The results strongly support the imply an observationally equivalent relationship
structure-performance hypothesis and are robust with respect
to model specification, measurement of concentration, and between concentration and profits, but differ as to
econometric technique. the structural model creating it. Essentially, the
structure-performance hypothesis takes concen-
I. Introduction tration as exogenous and maintains that high con-
N UMEROUS studies find a positive statistical centration allows for noncompetitive behavior
that results in less favorable prices to consumers
relationship between market concentration
and measures of firm or industry profitability. An and higher profits to firms. The usual form of
important debate has arisen over the underlying the efficient-structure hypothesis, however, takes
causes of this relationship. The traditional struc- firm-specific efficiencies as exogenous and main-
ture-performance hypothesis suggests that this tains that these efficiencies result in both more
finding reflects the setting of prices less favorable concentrated markets and higher profits. Clearly
to consumers in more concentrated markets as a an important public policy question is at stake in
result of collusion or other forms of non-competi- this debate, since the structure-performance hy-
tive behavior. pothesis suggests that antitrust or regulatory ac-
A challenge to this interpretation is the effici- tion may be productive, while the efficient-struc-
ent-structure hypothesis posited by Demsetz ture hypothesis suggests that such actions are likely
(1973), Peltzman (1977) and others. This argument to be counterproductive.
maintains that differences in firm-specific effi- This debate is no less pronounced in the litera-
ciencies within markets create unequal market ture that focuses on the banking industry, where
shares and high levels of concentration. In princi- the existence of geographically limited markets
ple, firms in markets with a large dispersion of offers researchers the advantage of comparing
efficiencies could be either more or less efficient on profitability and concentration across markets
average than firms in other markets. However, without the confounding influences of interindus-
proponents of the efficient-structure hypothesis try differences.' Recent attempts to distinguish
usually assume (explicitly or implicitly) that the empirically between the two competing hypothe-
dispersion of efficiencies within markets that cre- ses by controlling for the effects of market share
ates high levels of concentration also results in on the profit-concentration relationship have not
greater than average efficiency in these markets, met with mutually agreed upon success.2
yielding a positive profit-concentration relation-
1
ship. In effect, it is maintained that higher than For extensive reviews and opposing views of this literature,
see Rhoades (1982) and Gilbert (1984).
2
Received for publication April 8, 1988. Revision accepted for Market share has been included in profit-concentration
publication August 22, 1988. regressions using both banking data (e.g., Evanoff and Fortier
* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (1988) and Smirlock (1985)) and interindustry data (e.g.
We are grateful to Dean Amel, Bob Avery, Michael Bradley, Smirlock, Gilligan, and Marshall (1984)), and its inclusion has
Sally Davies, Doug Evanoff, Alton Gilbert, Dave Humphrey, been found to diminish substantially the effect of concentra-
Nellie Liang, Steve Sharpe, and the anonymous referees for tion on profits. Whether or not this finding supports the
helpful comments, and to Chris Trojan, Oscar Barnhardt, and efficient-structure hypothesis rests on the disputed contention
Roberto Sella for valuable research assistance. The opinions that market share proxies only the effects of the efficiency of
expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily larger firms and not their market power. See Shepherd (1986)
reflect those of the Board of Governors or its staff. and the reply by Smirlock, Gilligan, and Marshall (1986).

Copyright ? 1989 [ 291 1

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
292 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

In this paper, we approach this issue by avoid- j at time t, and xi]t denotes a vector of control
ing the use of profit data altogether and employ- variables that may differ across banks, markets, or
ing in its place the extensive information on prices time periods. These control variables include fac-
collected in Federal Reserve System surveys of tors exogenous to the bank that may affect prices
banking institutions. This allows us to exploit through market conditions or cost considerations.
important differences in the price-concentration Coefficients are represented by a, f8, and -y, while
relationship implied, by the two hypotheses. As cijt denotesthe errorterm.
argued below, the structure-performancehypothe- The structure-performance hypothesis implies
sis predicts that prices will be less favorable to that market concentration results in prices less
consumers in concentrated markets because of the favorable to consumers. Since the prices employed
non-competitive behavior exhibited in such mar- here (deposit interest rates) are paid to consumers
kets. In contrast, the usual form of the efficient- rather than by consumers, this hypothesis implies
structure hypothesis predicts that prices will, if a negative price-concentration relationship, or
anything, be more favorable to consumers in con- /3 <0.
centrated markets because of the greater efficien- The usual form of the efficient-structurehypoth-
cies exhibited in such markets. Thus, the use of esis, however, maintains that because of the domi-
survey price data allows a test of the structure-per- nance of efficient firms in concentrated markets,
formance hypothesis that excludes the usual form production in such markets is more efficient on
of the efficient-structure hypothesis as an alterna- average. To the extent that greater efficiency is
tive explanation of the results. reflected in a lower marginal cost of producing
The empirical results are found to be consistent output of a given quality, firms in concentrated
with the implications of the structure-performance markets should find it in their interests to offer
hypothesis and are robust with respect to model consumers more favorable prices, higher quality,
specification, measurement of concentration, and or both.4 Put into the context of our banking
econometric method.3 The change over time in the application, if banks in concentrated markets are
price-concentration relationship is also briefly dis- more efficient on average in gathering deposit
cussed. funds and transforming them into profitable in-
vestments, the marginal dollar of deposits should
II. Model Specification have more value to them. Thus they should, if
anything, bid more for deposits, implying a posi-
Since the most extensive survey information tive price-concentration relationship, or ,B 2 O.'
available on bank pricing behavior refers to the The choice of an appropriate measure of bank-
interest rates banks offer for retail deposits, the ing market concentration (CONC) is made diffi-
empirical analysis focuses on the role of local cult by the fact that theory provides little guidance
market concentration as a determinant of these in suggesting which measure to employ when the
rates. The tests reported below are relatively type of non-competitive behavior at issue is un-
straightforward. They consist of estimating re-
duced-form price equations of the form:
' We exclude from consideration the possibility that greater
efficiency results in less favorable prices to consumers accom-
rijt = a + 3CONCj, + 7yxij, + Eijt, (1) panied by more than compensating increases in quality. In a
competitive market, this requires either (i) that money income
where rij, represents the interest rate paid at time is an inferior good so that firms find it in their interest to bid
t on one category of retail deposits by bank i for consumer patronage with more quality and less money
income, or (ii) that the gain in efficiency of firms in concen-
located in local banking market j. CONCIt de- trated markets is heavily biased toward quality improvements
notes a measure of concentration in local market as opposed to cost reductions. Neither of these seems particu-
larly plausible for the bank accounts considered here, where
quality differentials are fairly narrowly constrained by law.
3 The few previous studies of the price-concentration rela- SNote that the efficient-structure hypothesis could predict
tionship in banking found support for the structure-perfor- fi < 0 if concentration results from the inefficiency of small
mance hypothesis, although the data used in these studies were firms in the market, rather than the efficiency of large firms. In
usually limited in scope and pre-dated by many years to- this case, however, concentration would be associated with less
day's deregulated pricing environment (see Edwards (1964), efficiency, violating the observed positive profit-concentration
Glassman (1975), Heggestad and Mingo (1976), and Hannan relationship. We therefore rule out this "unusual" form of the
(1979)). A recent exception is Keeley and Zimmerman (1985), efficient-structure hypothesis as an explanation of a finding of
which reported mixed results with a limited sample. A < 0.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PRICE-CONCENTRATION RELATIONSHIP IN BANKING 293

known.6 To determine whether the results are results are based contains 470 banks in 195 local
sensitive to the choice of measure, we employ both banking markets observed quarterly over a 2-1/2
the three-firm concentration ratio (CR3) and the year period. When cross section data from ten
Herfindahl index (HERF) in the empirical analy- quarters are pooled in estimation, roughly 3,500 to
sis. The variables CR3 and HERF are also con- 4,000 observations are employed for each of six
structed both with and without the inclusion of different deposit categories.
savings and loans (S & Ls), which offer similar Table 1 gives the definitions of the variables.
services. All four measures yield qualitatively simi- The dependent variables are retail deposit interest
lar results. rates (expressed in basis points) paid by commer-
Additional variables are included for the pur- cial banks, as reported in the Federal Reserve's
pose of statistical control. The growth rate of Monthly Survey of Selected Deposits and Other
deposits in the bank's market (IYRGROW) may Accounts. Six rates are collected: the Money Mar-
reflect local demand or supply considerations, and ket Deposit Account (MMDA) rate (rmmda), the
its coefficient may have either sign. The variable Super-NOW (SNOW) rate (rs) and the 3, 6,
BANKPROP, defined as the number of bank 12, and 30 month Certificate of Deposit (CD)
branches divided by total bank plus Savings and rates for accounts under $100,000 (rcd3m, rcd6m,
Loan (S&L) branches in the local market, is an rcdl2m, rcd30m). The MMDA and SNOW rates
inverse index of the extent to which S & Ls com- were collected for each of ten quarters from
pete with banks and is predicted to have a nega- September 1983 to December 1985. The CD rates
tive coefficient.7 Local per capita income were collected for the latter nine quarters, since
(PCINCOME) is included to control for factors these rates were not yet deregulated in September
affecting the supply of funds to banks. Its coeffi- 1983.
cient -may have either sign in a non-competitive Banks in the sample were assigned to local
market, since it may reflect either a greater or markets, which are defined as Metropolitan Statis-
lesser elasticity of deposit supply. The local bank tical Areas (MSAs) or non-MSA counties, follow-
wage rate (WAGE) is included as a cost factor. ing previous research (e.g., Smirlock (1985) and
However, since it may also reflect local income Rhoades (1982)). Banks with less than 75% of
differences across markets, the sign of its coeffi- their deposits in one local market were deleted
cient is not predicted. Similarly, the variable MSA from the sample to ensure a close correspondence
reflects the differences in conditions between between the deposit rates banks offer and the
metropolitan and rural markets, and its coefficient characteristics of the markets in which they oper-
may have either sign. The variables UNIT and ate, although virtually equivalent results are ob-
LIMIT indicate whether the state in which the tained in the absence of this restriction.8
bank is located prohibits or limits branch banking,
respectively. To the extent that these variables IV. EmpiricalResults
signal effective entry barriers, negative coefficients
Tables 2 and 3 report results obtained by re-
are predicted.
gressing retail deposit rates on a measure of con-
centration and various control variables. Since all
III. Data Description and Sources four concentration measures (CR3 and HERF,
The data employed in this study are quite exten- each with and without the inclusion of S& Ls)
sive. The refined sample upon which reported yield qualitatively similar results, we report only
those results obtained by using CR3 computed for
6
Dansby and Willig (1979) give the theoretical rationales for
banks only. We focus primarily on the MMDA
various market concentration measures when the type of con-
jectural variations that firms hold are known. The Herfindahl 8 The concentration measures (CR3, HERF) are calculated
index is implied for Cournot competitors, and the m-firm using Summary of Deposits data for banks and (when applica-
concentration ratio is implied when the largest m firms collude ble) Federal Home Loan Bank Board data for S & Ls. Market
and the remaining firms are price-takers. We have no prior growth (1YRGROW) is constructed using the total deposits
grounds for choosing between these types of conjectural varia- (from the Report of Condition) of all banks with at least 75%
tions. of their deposits in one market (as determined from Summary
7 The alternative of using bank and S & L deposits rather of Deposits data). Bank wages (WAGE) and per-capita income
than branches to construct this index was not chosen because (PCINCOME) are computed from County Business Patterns
of the greater likelihood of simultaneous equations bias associ- and Survey of CurrentBusiness, respectively. UNIT and LIMIT
ated with the use of deposit data. are formed using state branching laws as of 1984.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
294 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 1.-VARIABLE DEFINITIONS

Endogenous Variables (r)


rmmda -Money Market Deposit Account rate paid on the largest dollar value of
deposits issued during the 7-day period ending on the last Wednesday of
the quarter, 1983: 09-1985 :12. (basis points).
rsnow -Super-NOW rate for same periods.
rcd3m, rcd6m, rcdl2m, rcd3Om-3, 6, 12, and 30 month CD rates, beginning 1983 :12 (after
deregulation).
Exogenous Variables of Interest (CONC)
CR3 -3-firm deposit concentration ratio computed for commercial banks in the
local market (MSA or non-MSA county). Alternatively computed inclusive
of S & Ls as well as banks. (percent)
HERF -Herfindahl index of bank concentration, defined as the sum of squared
market shares of deposits. Alternatively computed inclusive of S & Ls as
well as banks. (sum of percent squared).
Exogenous Control Variables (X)
T8309-T8512 -Time dummies introduced to account for the interest rate cycle, changes in
minimum balance requirements, and other time-specific factors.
rmmmf -Money Market Mutual Fund rate, included instead of time dummies in
some estimations. (basis points)
1YRGROW -1-year growth in market deposits. (proportion)
BANKPROP -(Number of bank branches)/(Number of bank branches + number of
S & L branches) in the market.
WAGE -Index of local banking wage rate. ($000/quarter)
PCINCOME -Per-capita income in local market. ($ / year)
MSA -Dummy variable indicating location in a Metropolitan Statistical Area.
UNIT, LIMIT -Dummy variables indicating location in a unit banking or limited branch-
ing state, respectively.
Variables of Questionable Exogeneity (Excluded from X in most estimations)
MKTSHR -The bank's market share of deposits. (proportion)
BRANCH -Number of branches of the bank.
TA -Total assets of the bank.

rate, since MMDAs are predominantly local prod- dependent variable. Ten quarterly cross sections
ucts with quite narrowly constrained quality dif- of 470 banks are pooled, with some of the banks
ferences. Over the sample period, MMDAs had having missing data for some time periods. One
standardized minimum balance requirements and estimation problem concerns the possibility of
per-month transactions limits, reducing the possi- correlations among the error terms for banks
bility that differences in service across banks can and/or markets that are included in the survey for
explain differences in deposit rates.9 The SNOW multiple quarters. In addition, the error terms are
accounts had the same minimum balance require- likely to be heteroskedastic over time, since much
ments, but variations in per-check charges and of the variation in retail deposit rates derives from
other fees might distort the regression results. The the interest rate cycle. To solve these problems, we
CD accounts had very uniform service and charges, estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) and
but these accounts may be competed for on a corrected the covariance matrix of the parameter
broader geographic basis than local markets, due estimates by forming an unrestricted probability
to larger denominations and less frequently re- distribution for each of the 470 banks from the
quired contact between depositor and bank. exogenous variables and OLS residuals.10
Table 2 reports results obtained by estimating
equation (1) using the bank's MMDA rate as the 10
Details are available from the authors. In most cases, this
procedure yields standard errors 50% to 100%larger than those
9 The legally binding minimum balance requirement was calculated by the OLS formula. Computation of probability
$2500 through 1984 and $1000 in 1985. Throughout the sam- distribution by market instead of by bank (not shown) did not
ple, MMDAs could have no more than 6 preauthorized, auto- change the significance test results. Correction of the OLS
matic, or other transfers per month, of which no more than 3 coefficient covariance matrix was chosen over use of GLS
could be by check. It is possible that some banks imposed because estimates of the error distribution by bank were judged
stricter limits. to be too tentative to use in altering the coefficient estimates.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PRICE-CONCENTRATION RELATIONSHIP IN BANKING 295

TABLE2.-MMDA RATE REGRESSIONS-POOLED TIME SERIES-CROSSSECTION


(DEPENDENTVARIABLE= rmmdaIN BASIS POINTS)

Exogenous
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

CONSTANT 695.2b 684.8b 685.9b 689.7b 86.6a


(29.9) (28.4) (28.4) (26.2) (2.26)
CR3 0.63b 1.04a
(-5.72) (2.10)
CR3 - T8309 -0.33a 0.42b -0.38a
(-2.56) (-3.01) (-2.31)
CR3 - T8312 0.4ob 0.49 -0.44b
(3.65b (-4.12b (-2.95)
CR3 * T8403 -0.51 -0.61 0.56b
(-3.85) (-4.21) (-3.24)
CR3 * T8406 1.07 -1.17 -1.12
(6.01b (6.21) (- 5.40)
CR3 - T8409 -1.33 L.-1.374b
(-6.74b (-6.80) (- 6.18b
CR3 * T8412 -0.78 -0.87 -0.82
(-4.97) 5.33) (-4.53b
CR3 * T8503 -0.53 0.64 -0.58
(-3.71) (-4.24) (-3.36)
CR 3 * T8506 -0.46b 0.57b 0.50
(-2.92) (-3.48) (-2.802
CR3 * T8509 0.46 0.57b -0.51
(-3.30) (-3.84) (-2.92)
CR3 * T8512 0.45b 0.56b 0.50b
(-3.14) (-3.78) (-2.97)
IYRGROW 41 42.8 44.36 42.69b 49.32b
(3.86) (4.00) (4.14) (3.95) (4.29)
BANKPROP 8.24 8.58 7.91 8.24 9.64
(0.54) (0.56) (0.52) (0.52) (0.62)
WAGE 7.11 7.17 6.98 7.00 7.47
(4.20) (4.23) (4.03) (4.01) (4.23)
PCINCOME -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
(-0.95) (-1.00) (-0.82) (-1.11) (-1.27)
MSA -10.10a -9.98 -10.19a -9.59 -9.89
(-1.98) (-1.96) (-1.98) (-1.86) (-1.86)
UNIT -5.14 -4.94 -3.74 -3.19 -4.53
(-1.31) (-1.26) (-0.93b (-0.23) (-1.15)
LIMIT -11.79 -11.75 -12.01 -19.13 -11.49
(-3.32) (-3.32) (- 3.38) (-1.53) (-3.25)
MKTSHR 29.78a
(2.09)
BRANCH 0.05
(1.29)
CR3* UNIT -0.03
(-0.12)
CR3 * LIMIT 0.12
(0.60)
rmmmf 0.87b
(25.38)
CR3 rmmmf -0.002
(-3.44)
T8309-T8509 c c c c

R2/Num. Obs. 0.80/4047 0.80/4047 0.80/4047 0.80/4047 0.76/4047


a
Significantly different from zero at 5% level (t-statistics in parentheses).
b
Significantly different from zero at 1% level (t-statistics in parentheses).
c Time dummies T8309-T8509 were included in the first 4 regressions (T8512 excluded as base case).

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
296 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE3.-REGRESSIONS FOR OTHER INTERESTRATES-


POOLEDTiMESERIES-CROSSSECTION

Exogenous
Variables rsnow red3m rcd6m redl2m rcd3Om

CONSTANT 663.7b 687.8b 769.7b 776.0b 718.8b


(19.7) (20.0) (34.9) (15.5) (12.4)
CR3 - T8309 -0.39a
(-2.04)
CR3 * T8312 -0.48 0.46b 0.37 -0.55 -0.05
(-2.67) (-2.63) (-2.64) (-1.60) (-0.31)
CR3 * T8403 -0.38 -0.12 -0.10 0.06 0.32a
(-1.86) (-0.612 (-0.64b (0.18) (2.00)
Cr3 T8406 -0.75 0.71 -0.81 -0.68 -0.01
(-3.05) (-2.97) (-4.58) (-1.77) (-0.07)
CR3 * T8409 -0.89b 0.79b -.90b -0.63 -0.35
(-3.35) (-3.05) (-5.01) (-1.67) (-1.84)
CR3 * T8412 -0.84 -0.36 -0.43a -0.41 -0.06
(-4.03) (-1.95) (-2.59) (-1.48) (-0.33)
CR3 * T8503 -0.56 0.05 -0.40 -0.09 0.11
(-2.942 (0.29) (-2.90) (-0.30) (0.67)
CR3 * T8506 -0.61 -0.14 -0.31a -0.28 -0.22
(-3.042 (-0.87) (-2.38) (-1.03) (-1.09)
CR 3 * T8509 -0.51 0.46 0.49 0.36 0.36
(-2.64) (-2.59) (-4.12) (-1.48) (0.65)
CR3 * T8512 0.60b 0.54b 0.59b 0.42 -0.26
(-3.17, (-2.76) (-4.69) (-1.66) (-1.34)
IYRGROW 50.14 39.18a 27.1 13.39 83.04
(2.75) (1.99) (2.81) (0.51) (1.77)
BANKPROP 12.87 34.51 3.24 12.42 38.34
(0.55) (1.48) (0.21) (0.44) (1.40)
WAGE 1.99 3.77 3.53a 9.53a 8.93a
(0.70) (1.07) (2.21) (2.41) (2.07)
PCINCOME - 0.03b 0.0002 - 0.001 - 0.005 0.0009
(-2.61) (0.11) (-1.16) (-1.48) (0.70)
MSA -8.18 -8.03 -12.87 b 14.45 13.24a
(-1.11) (-1.21) (-3.32) (1.31) (2.03)
UNIT 1.81 13.18 6.19 12.43 9.08
(0.31) (1.59) (1.30) (1.43) (1.30)
LIMIT -3.04 -1.19 -3.24 6.09 9.51
(-0.59) (-0.22) (-0.92) (0.74) (1.04)
T8312-T8509 C C c C C

R2/Num. Obs. 0.51/3663 0.68/3436 0.88/3635 0.58/3466 0.33/3572


a
Significantly different from zero at 5% level (t-statistics in parentheses).
b
Significantly different from zero at 1% level (t-statistics in parentheses).
c Time dummies T8312-T8509 (plus T8309 for r were included in all regressions (T8512 excluded as base
case).

The regression reported in column (1) of table 2 expressed in percentage points, the coefficient of
includes as regressors CR3 and seven control vari- -0.63 implies a 47 basis point reduction in r
ables (IYRGROW, BANKPROP, WAGE, PCIN- in moving from the least concentrated market in
COME, MSA, UNIT, and LIMIT). Fixed-effects the sample (CR3 = 25) to the most concentrated
time dummies (T8309 to T8509) are also included market in the sample (CR3 = 100), ceterisparibus
to account for the influence of the interest rate (- 0.63 (25 - 100)= 47).11 Similarly, when
cycle, the change in legal minimum balance re- HERF is used in place of CR3 (not shown), the
quirements for MMDAs (from $2500 to $1000 in predicted reduction is 52 basis points. The coeffi-
January 1985), and other possible changes in the cients of the control variables reported in tables 2
MMDA market over the sample period.
The concentration variable (CR3) coefficient is
11 A one standard deviation increase in CR3 (17 percentage
negative and statistically significant at the 1%level. points) yields an 11 basis point reduction in rmmda, ceteris
With rmmda expressed in basis points and CR3 paribus.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PRICE-CONCENTRATION RELATIONSHIP IN BANKING 297

and 3 are largely unexceptional and will not be The regression reported in column (3) tests the
discussed due to space limitations."2 robustness of our results to the inclusion of two
The finding that banks in more concentrated variables of questionable exogeneity-the bank's
markets pay lower deposit rates is consistent with market share (MKTSHR) and the number of of-
the implications of the structure-performancehy- fices of the bank (BRANCH). Market share has
pothesis, but is not a prediction of the usual form been included in some profit-concentration studies
of the efficient-structure hypothesis. Thus, while as a proxy for firm-specific efficiencies, although it
both efficiency and market structure effects may may also capture elements of market power (see
play roles in explaining profitability, the results Shepherd (1986)). Its use in a price-concentration
presented here suggest the dominance of struc- study is more problematic. Market share may be
ture-performance hypothesis over the efficient- highly endogenous to prices, since firms offering
structure hypothesis in determining deposit rates. more favorable prices to consumers may attract
This same regression equation (without the time customers and gain share. Moreover, if other mar-
dummies) was also estimated by OLS separately ket conditions (including concentration) are prop-
for each of the ten quarters (not shown). The erly controlled for, MKTSHR should only cause
coefficients of concentration were found to be differences in prices to the extent that it reflects
negative for every period and significant at the 1% product quality differentials. Otherwise, con-
level in all but the first period, when rates on sumers in the same market environment would be
competing deposit categories were not yet deregu- paying different prices for a product of the same
lated. The levels of these coefficients also varied quality. For these reasons, MKTSHR is excluded
considerably over the sample, rising from Septem- from most of the regressions. The significant posi-
ber 1983 to peak in September 1984 and then tive coefficient of MKTSHR in column (3) could
falling through 1985. indicate that firms of different sizes provide dif-
A pooled time series, cross section regression ferent levels of quality. However, this coefficient
that allows the coefficients of CR3 to vary over could also reflect the endogeneity of MKTSHR if
time (by including interactions of CR3 with the banks that pay higher rates gain market share."4
time dummies) is reported in column (2) of table Of primary importance, however, is the fact that
2. The CR3 interaction coefficients are all statisti- the inclusion of MKTSHR as a regressor in col-
cally significant and follow the same pattern as the umn (3) or in any of the other regressions (not
separate cross-section estimates. The null hypothe- shown) does not change the finding of a significant
sis that all ten CR3 coefficients are equal is re- negative relationship between concentration and
jected at the 1% level (X2 = 41). The fall in rmmda deposit rates.
in moving from the least to the most concentrated The variable BRANCH is included to control
market, ceteris paribus, rises from 25 basis points for the possibility that local convenience may serve
in September 1983 to 100 basis points in Septem- as a substitute for higher deposit rates, implying a
ber 1984, then falls to 34 basis points in December negative coefficient for this variable. However,
1985. The use of HERF in place of CR3 (not since it is a decision variable for the bank, it is
shown) and the inclusion of squared concentration excluded from most of the regressions to avoid
terms to account for the possibility of non-linear endogeneity. The insignificant positive coefficient
relationships (not shown) does not alter the results is not consistent with the hypothesis that branches
in any material way.13 provide a strong service alternative to higher de-
14
12 The negative coefficient of MSA does not imply that It might be argued that a similar endogeneity problem
metropolitan area banks pay less than rural banks. In fact, applies to the concentration measures (CR3, HERF) or the
banks in MSAs pay higher MMDA rates on average (8.01%vs. market growth variable (IYRGROW), since they are con-
7.91%). The coefficient is hegative because the differences in structed from the output of individual firms in the market.
the other exogenous variables between urban and rural mar- However, any such problems are likely to be small, since
kets, particularly the lower concentration in urban markets, changes in one firm's deposit rate would generally have a small
would predict that an even larger premium be paid by urban effect on the entire market's concentration or growth. More-
banks. over, any biases on the coefficient of the concentration measure
13 When interactions between the square of CR3 and the would tend to cancel each other out, since the change in a
time dummies are included, the derivative of rmmda with firm's market share resulting from a price change would move
respect to CR3 evaluated at the mean remains negative and concentration in the same direction as market share for larger
largely unchanged for each of the 10 time periods. firms and in the opposite direction for smaller firms.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
298 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

posit rates and may instead reflect the endogeneity the time dummies (R2 = 0.80). In addition, plug-
of this variable.'5 The inclusion of another poten- ging the values of rmmmfinto this equation and
tially endogenous variable, bank size as measured solving for estimates of drmmda/dCR3 reveals
by total assets (not shown), was found to make no roughly the same deposit rate-concentration pat-
material difference to the registered effect of con- tern over time as was registered with the time
centration. dummies.16 The inclusion of additional lags for
The regression reported in column (4) includes the MMMF rate and allowing for different re-
interactions of CR3 with both UNIT and LIMIT sponses to upward and downward aggregate inter-
in order to allow the effects of concentration to est rate movements did not change these results
vary across branching environments. The coeffi- substantially."7
cients of these interaction terms are small and not The finding that the price-concentration rela-
statistically significant (X2 = 0.5), and their inclu- tionship is stronger when aggregate rates are rela-
sion does not alter the role of market concentra- tively high may suggest slower price adjustment
tion in any material way. on the part of banks in more concentrated mar-
Table 3 reports the results of regressions in kets, as implied by the "administered price" hy-
which the dependent variables are the five other pothesis.18 This inference, however, is more tenta-
retail deposit rates taken from the survey. Each tive than those drawn above, since the data from
specification is identical to that reported in col- only one interest rate cycle are employed and
umn (2) of table 2 except for the dependent vari- other macroeconomic events affecting the price-
able. Note that the results of the r regression concentration relationship may be correlated with
are very similar to those reported for rmmda, except this cycle. A more extensive examination of the
that the variation over time in the CR3 coeffi- variation in the deposit rate-concentration rela-
cients is less pronounced. The regressions using tionship over the interest rate cycle may provide a
the shorter-term CD rates (rcd3m and rcd6m) have fruitful avenue for future research.
some large and significantly negative CR3 coeffi-
cients, but a few of these coefficients are insignifi-
cant. Regressions using the longer-term CD rates V. Conclusions
(rcdl2m and rcd3om) register mostly negative but
insignificant coefficients of CR3. These results are This paper employs extensive information on
consistent with the notion that CDs, particularly bank deposit prices to test the structure-perfor-
mance hypothesis in a manner that excludes as an
those with longer maturities, are competed for on
a broader basis than that represented by local alternative explanation the form of the efficient-
banking markets. structure hypothesis that is used to explain the
Finally, we consider the possible causes of the positive relationship between profits and concen-
variation over time in the relationship between tration. The empirical results are strongly consis-
deposit rates and concentration. As noted above, tent with the implications of the structure-perfor-
the estimated effect of concentration increases mance hypothesis. Ceteris paribus, banks in the
from September 1983 to September 1984 and then most concentrated local markets in the sample are
falls through 1985. This roughly parallels the found to pay MMDA rates that range from 25 to
movement in aggregate interest rates over the same 100 basis points less than those paid in the least
concentrated markets, depending on the time pe-
period. To examine how closely aggregate rates
track the deposit rate-concentration relationship,
the MMDA rate regression was re-run with the 16 This derivative is the CR3 coefficient (1.04) plus the prod-
Money Market Mutual Fund rate (rmmmf)substi- uct of the interaction coefficient (- 0.002) and the appropriate
tuting for the time dummies. As shown in column value of rmmmf-
17 This approach is similar to that of Domowitz, Hubbard,
(5) of table 2, this equation has almost the same
and Petersen (1986), who use interaction terms to examine how
explanatory power (R2 = 0.76) as the models with the relationship between industry price-cost margins and con-
centration changes over time.
18Consistent with this hypothesis, the 50 banks with the
15
This coefficient could, for example, reflect the possibility highest CR3 values had the same rmmd.a in consecutive quar-
that banks that pay higher deposit rates attract more customers ters 24.2% of the time, while the 50 with the lowest CR3s had
and therefore decide to open additional branches. the same rates in consecutive quarters only 14.8% of the time.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PRICE-CONCENTRATION RELATIONSHIP IN BANKING 299

riod examined. Similar results are found for Su- REFERENCES


per-NOWs and shorter-term CDs. However, the Dansby, Robert E., and Robert D. Willig, "Industry Perfor-
effect of concentration on longer-term CD rates is mance Gradient Indexes," American Economic Review
marginal at best, reflecting the possibility that 69 (June 1979), 249-260.
these may be competed for on a broader basis Demsetz, Harold, "Industry Structure, Market Rivalry, and
Public Policy," Journal of Law and Economics 16 (Apr.
than local banking markets. We note, however, 1973), 1-9.
that these price-concentration results do not rule Domowitz, Ian, R. Glenn Hubbard, and Bruce C. Petersen,
out the possibility that the efficient-structure hy- "Business Cycles and the Relationship between Con-
centration and Price-Cost Margins, Rand Journal of
pothesis also plays a role in the profit-concentra- Economics 17 (Spring 1986), 1-17.
tion relationship. Edwards, Franklin R., "Concentration In Banking and Its
As shown in the tables and text, these findings Effect on Business Loan Rates," this REVIEW 46 (Aug.
1964), 294-300.
are robust with respect to (i) the use of separate Evanoff, Douglas, and Diane Fortier, "Reevaluation of the
OLS cross-section estimates in place of pooled Structure-Conduct-PerformanceParadigm in Banking,"
time series, cross section estimation, (ii) the choice Journal of Financial Services Research 1 (June 1988),
277-294.
of concentration measure (CR3 or HERF), (iii) Gilbert, Alton, "Studies of Bank Market Structure and Com-
the inclusion of firm-specificvariables of question- petition: A Review and Evaluation," Journal of Money,
able exogeneity (market share, bank branches, or Credit, and Banking 16 (Nov. 1984), 617-644.
Glassman, Cynthia A., "The Effects of Mergers on Price and
bank size), (iv) the treatment of concentration Service Performance of Pennsylvania Banks," Ph.D.
under different state branching laws, and (v) the dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1975.
inclusion of an aggregate interest rate in place of Hannan, Timothy H., "Limit Pricing and the Banking Indus-
try," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 2 (Nov.
the time dummies to control for time-series fac- 1979), 438-446.
tors. Also examined, but not shown numerically, Heggestad, Arnold A., and John J. Mingo, "Prices, Nonprices,
are the effects of (i) the modeling of the dependent and Concentration in Commercial Banking," Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking (Feb. 1976), 107-117.
variable as a market premium instead of a rate by Keeley, Michael C., and Gary C. Zimmerman, "Determining
using the difference between the MMDA rate and Geographic Markets for Deposit Competition in Bank-
the Money Market Mutual Fund rate, (ii) the ing," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco (Summer 1985), 25-45.
inclusion of S & L data in the concentration mea- Peltzman, Samuel, "The Gains and Losses from Industrial
sures, (iii) the use of additional variables to take Concentration," Journal of Law and Economics 20 (Oct.
account of differences in state bank holding com- 1977), 229-263.
Rhoades, Stephen, "Structure-Peformance Studies in Banking:
pany laws, (iv) the use of squared concentration An Updated Summary and Evaluation," Staff Study
terms, (v) the exclusion of the control variables # 119, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
that do not have statistically significant coeffi- System (1982).
Shepherd, William G., "Tobin's q and the Structure-Perfor-
cients, and (vi) the inclusion of banks with less mance Relationship: Comment," American Economic
than 75% of their deposits in one market. In no Review 76 (Dec. 1986), 1205-1210.
case are the market concentration results altered Smirlock, Michael, "Evidence on the (Non) Relationship be-
tween Concentration and Profitability in Banking,"
qualitatively. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 17 (Feb. 1985),
This study also investigates why the observed 69-83.
effect of concentration on deposit rates varies so Smirlock, Michael, Thomas Gilligan, and William Marshall,
"Tobin's q and the Structure-Performance Relation-
greatly over the sample period. The difference in ship," American Economic Review 74 (Dec. 1984),
deposit rates paid in concentrated and unconcen- 1050-1060.
trated markets is found to be strongly related to , "Tobin's q and the Structure-Performance Relation-
ship: Reply," American EconomicReview 76 (Dec. 1986),
the aggregate level of interest rates. 1211-1213.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.157 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 04:50:39 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like