You are on page 1of 4

COMMENTARY

Managing Groundwater–Energy with a feed-in tariff would be economi-


cally viable.

Nexus in India Viability Question


The note argues,
What Will Solar Pumps Achieve? Solar irrigation pumps, considered unviable,
are being aggressively promoted with high
investment subsidies by governments and
Meera Sahasranaman, M Dinesh Kumar, Mahendra Singh Verma, Chris J Perry, DISCOMs (electricity distribution companies
Nitin Bassi, M V K Sivamohan of India) to reduce farm power subsidy bur-
den. (Verma et al 2019: 64)

I
The fresh arguments made by n the rejoinder note on the discussion This is an incorrect statement. If solar
Shilp Verma and others in support by Meera Sahasranaman et al (2018), pumps are unviable, what is the logic be-
Shilp Verma et al (2019) awkwardly hind giving high investment subsidies for
of the “SpaRC” model, as a solution
sing the chorus to the arguments made it? Subsidies are desirable, when the tech-
for India’s multiple problems of by Tushar Shah et al (2017) that one way nology is economically viable, that is, it
groundwater depletion, farmer to reverse the trend of depleting ground- generates enough benefits to the society,
distress, poor financial working water and increasing farm power subsidy but is not viable from the point of view of
(which is draining power utilities) is to private benefits and costs. The authors
of the power sector and growing
“promote” “Solar Power as a Remunerative have not produced any data to show that
carbon footprint in agriculture Crop” (SPaRC) among farmers by (i) using the SIPs are economically viable, even when
are misleading, and the analyses solar irrigation pumps (SIPs) to replace the sum of direct and indirect economic
presented to back them are flawed. grid-connected electric tube wells, and benefits is compared against the full cost
(ii) offering SIP owners a buyback guar- of the system. In this case, not only a heavy
antee for their surplus solar energy at a capital subsidy is given to the farmers for
remunerative price. Such a policy would the infrastructure (to the tune of 90%) to
create an incentive for farmers to conserve bring down the financial costs, but price
Meera Sahasranaman (meera.pradeep@gmail. energy and water, curtail grid power incentive (to the tune of `2.5/kilowatt-
com) is an independent consultant. subsidies that burden distribution com- hour [kWh]) over and above the inflated
M Dinesh Kumar (dinesh@irapindia.org) is with panies, reduce carbon footprint of irri- tariff under the power purchase agreement
the Institute for Resource Analysis and Policy. gation and offer farmers a new risk-free of `4.26/kWh, is also offered for the energy
Mahendra Singh Verma (msverma@msn.com) is
income source (Verma et al 2019: 62). produced by them to jack up the revenue.
an advisor to IRAP on projects and partnerships.
Chris J Perry (chrisjperry@me.com) is an Unfortunately, the authors fail to present
independent consultant. Nitin Bassi (bassi43@ any new evidence, wilfully closing their Marginal Cost–Benefit Concept
gmail.com) and M V K Sivamohan eyes and ears to the facts that run con- Verma et al (2019: 65) state in the foot note:
(sivamohanmvk@gmail.com) are with IRAP, trary to their claim that a heavily subsi- The confusion stems partly from a misin-
Hyderabad.
dised solar photovoltaic (PV) system terpretation of marginal cost and marginal

22 march 13, 2021 vol lVi no 11 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
COMMENTARY
returns in irrigation. The first irrigation in water in the farm, the farmer has the electric pump by the most conservative
any crop will yield high marginal returns option of selling the water pumped out estimate is around 50%.1 This means,
on energy use, let us say `100 per kWh.
using the surplus electricity to his neigh- 1 kWp of solar power is equivalent to
This is because the first irrigation generally
provides the highest increment to crop yield, bour at a price of around `40/kWh so 0.33 kW of electric pump in the most op-
compared to a completely rain-fed crop. How- long as the demand persists. The mar- timistic scenario of having an efficient
ever, as the farmer keeps irrigating, the mar- ginal cost and return concept do not solar PV system. Hence, even by the most
ginal returns from each additional irrigation work here. It is the average return against conservative estimate of solar PV system
will decline. By the third irrigation, the mar-
a marginal opportunity cost. cost used by the authors (that is, `50/
ginal returns might be down to `20/kWh
and for the fifth irrigation, the marginal watt-peak), the total cost of replacing
returns might be `7/kWh. When the farmer Cost of Replacing Electric Pumps the 15 million electric pumps works out
gets free or subsidised power at `1/kWh, it The authors provide poor estimates of to be `10.12 lakh crore (15*10^6 ×
makes economic sense for them to irrigate a the cost of replacing 15 million electric 50,000 × 13.5 = 10.12 × 10^5 crore, that
sixth time because marginal cost is `1/kWh
while marginal return is `7/kWh. In fact,
pumps in India. It says: is, 10.12 lakh crore). The annual agricul-
they will continue irrigating till marginal Even if capital costs do not decline any fur- tural power subsidy in India is taken as
returns fall below the marginal cost of ther (which is highly unlikely), solarising `50,000 crore for calculations, while the
pumping. However, this behaviour is neither India’s 15 million electric pumps will cost figure stood at `45,561 crore in 2011–12
efficient nor desirable as the marginal cost of the exchequer only `2.92 lakh crore (as- (Planning Commission 2011). Hence, in
electricity for the society is much higher than suming an average size of 6.5 HP); not the
the private marginal cost. Faced with similar order to recover the capital cost of the
`9 lakh crore estimated by Sahasranaman et
marginal returns, a grid-connected “SPaRC system through the saving in agricultur-
al (2018). Thus, by spending the equivalent
farmer” will stop irrigating after the fourth
of 3.65 years of farm power subsidy, the an- al power subsidy (claimed by Verma and
irrigation because they can earn `7/kWh others in their discussion note), the
nual dead weight of farm subsidies, and the
simply by evacuating it as surplus power. In
perverse incentives that they create, can be farmer would require to keep the system
both cases, the average returns from irriga-
eliminated. (Verma et al 2019: 63) running for nearly 100 years (with a dis-
tion will be the same (close to `50/kWh) but
pumping behaviour will be very different, To replace 6.5 HP or 4.5 kilowatt (kW) count rate of 5%) and not 3.65 years as
leading to efficient outcomes. (6.5*0.746) of average capacity of an claimed by Verma et al (2019). But the
This is incorrect application of the electric pump with a solar PV system of life of the system even under the most
concepts of marginal costs and marginal equal power, we need a solar PV system optimistic scenario is only 25 years.
returns. The price being offered by the of around 13.5 kilowatts peak (kWp) and
utility for the electricity is the opportunity not 4.5 kWp of power. This is because of The Cost–Benefit Claims
cost of using solar power for irrigation. the huge difference in energy conversion Verma et al (2019) contest that the cost
This is `7/kWh. The marginal return is efficiency. Solar cell energy conversion figures considered by Sahasranaman et al
that of the marginal net income from efficiencies for commercially available (2018) for estimating the capital cost
crop production. Yes, as pointed out by solar cells are around 14%–19%, whereas subsidy are very high as it included the
Verma et al (2019), the marginal return the energy conversion efficiency of an old cost of the microgrid (around `20 lakh)
from irrigation will keep declining as
the irrigation dosage increases (Kumar No. A-12011/14/2018-ADM
2005). But the fact remains that adequate Government of India,
number of irrigations have to be given to Department of Personnel & Training,
get the optimum yield, which can range LAL BAHADUR SHASTRI NATIONAL ACADEMY OF
from five–six irrigations (for wheat) to ADMINISTRATION MUSSOORIE
30–40 irrigations (for banana). It is totally Applications are invited for selection of Teaching Associate (Research Intern) on
false to assume that with one irrigation, contract basis with a consolidated remuneration of Rs. 40,000/- per month in Lal
the marginal return will be highest! In Bahadur Shastri National Academy of Administration, Mussoorie in the following
field initially for a period of one year and extendable based on performance
fact, there will be no yield or return for
appraisal.
most irrigated winter and summer crops
in semi-arid and arid regions with one Sl. No. Subject No. of Vacancies
irrigation and therefore the marginal 1. Economics 01
return is zero and not `100/kWh. By the
Willing candidates are required to submit their application in prescribed proforma
time water is pumped out for 30 irriga- within 21 days from the date of publication. Applications received after last date
tions (for banana) of 10–12 for paddy, or found incomplete will not be considered.
the groundwater is already mined. So, Note:
making the distinction between efficiency The details including eligibility of the vacancies and prescribed form of application
and sustainability is very important, and are available on the website of the Academy. (http://www.lbsnaa.gov.in)
is ignored by the authors. The moot point Deputy Director (Sr.)
is sustainability of groundwater use. & I/c Administration
Further, after efficiently using the irrigation
Economic & Political Weekly EPW march 13, 2021 vol lVi no 11 23
COMMENTARY

and that once the same model is used for and as a result, the surplus power which performance report of state power utilities
(PFC 2015) reveals that an average elec-
replacing the existing electric wells, the farmers can sell would reduce to almost
tric pump in central Gujarat consumes 830
cost would go down. In the light of this, nil, if we choose a solar PV system of the kWh/HP/year. Against this, the consump-
their argument is that the subsidy required same capacity. In that case, the only eco- tion of member farmers of the Dhundi solar
is only 40% for replicating this model. nomic benefit of having solar PV system cooperative is only 446 kWh/HP/year. This
shows that they are consuming about 45%
But they missed the fact that Sahasra- connected to the grid is the saving in gov- less energy than they would have if they
naman et al (2018) had essentially com- ernment subsidy for power, plus the pos- had equivalent capacity electric pumps
mented on the economic viability of the itive externality associated with produc- with subsidised farm power. Given that the
Dundi model (where diesel pumps were tion of clean energy (that is, 0.47 × groundwater situation and water levels are
comparable in central Gujarat and that their
replaced by solar PV systems with a mi- 60,000 = 28,200). Then the net income
crop yields are comparable to those of elec-
crogrid) and therefore had analysed the works out to be `2,40,000 + `28,200 = tric pump owners, this is the best proxy in-
viability of that model based on the fig- `2,68,200. If we consider a lifespan of 12 dicator for efficient pumping behaviour and
ures (`50.4 lakh) provided by the au- years, the cost goes up to `4.95 lakh groundwater use in agriculture.
thors in the original article by Shah et al against the same benefit. Here again, In our view, comparing the average en-
(2017). The extent of subsidy does not the cost far exceeds the benefit. ergy consumption for irrigation in a re-
matter. What matters is whether the Another way of looking at the benefit gion with that of a few farmers in a vil-
model is economically viable or not. It and cost is to consider the cost of clean lage from that region does not make
should also be noted that the annualised energy production (or the replacement much sense. First of all, the groundwater
cost considered by Sahasranaman et al cost of fossil fuel-based electric power), in the village is heavily recharged by ca-
(2018) was only `4.4 lakh against `3.59 against its benefit, the latter being the nals (Shah et al 2017) and the return
lakh of the annual return, based on an full economic cost of producing fossil flows from irrigated fields. Second, how
assumed lifespan of 25 years and not “12 fuel-based power. The cost of clean much electricity the farmers use for
years” proposed in the rebuttal. Had it energy production works out to be `5.5 pumping groundwater depends more on
considered a 12-year life, the cost would per kWh (3,30,000/60,000=5.5), which the operational holding, keeping other
be `6.6 lakh as mentioned in the same is nothing but the annualised cost of conditions the same. In this case, all the
rebuttal (Sahasranaman et al 2018). We solar PV system divided by the total en- farmer members of the solar cooperative
would like to point out that we were lib- ergy produced per annum in kWh. The are marginal holders, with less than one
eral in evaluating the benefits of solar, benefit is `4.97 per kWh, for an assumed acre of holding. The average landholding
as the whole intervention was to show life of 25 years. For an assumed life of 12 in Kheda district (where the village falls)
that even with inflated benefits, the sys- years, the cost is `8.25 per kWh, against is 1.14 ha, that is, 2.70 acre (Agricultural
tem is socio-economically unviable. Be- the same benefit. Census, Government of Gujarat 2011).
cause of this reason, the entire energy So, it is incorrect to compare the energy
production by Dundi coop was consid- Efficient Pumping Behaviour? use by these marginal holders with the
ered for estimating the direct benefit of Verma et al (2019: 63) states: average energy use by farmers in central
solar PV,2 while the portion of electricity A simple analysis of data from the Fifth Gujarat, simply because the ground-
produced and used by the farmer mem- Minor Irrigation Census (GoI 2017) and water condition and landholding sizes are
bers was considered for estimating the
subsidy cost saving as the unique advan-
tage of the model. EPW E-books
Now, the nationwide replication of Select EPW books are now available as e-books in Kindle and iBook (Apple) formats.
Dundi experiment results propounded
by the Shah et al (2017) and Verma et al The titles are
(2019) will have to cover farmers already 1. Village Society (ED. SURINDER JODHKA)
having electric power connection, and
(http://www.amazon.com/dp/B00CS62AAW ;
for this the cost of the grid is to be
https://itunes.apple.com/us/book/village-society/id640486715?mt=11)
excluded from benefit cost calculations.
In that case, if we have to go by the new 2. Environment, Technology and Development (ED. ROHAN D’SOUZA)
cost break-up offered by Verma et al (http://www.amazon.com/dp/B00CS624E4 ;
(2019: 62), the annualised cost of solar https://itunes.apple.com/us/book/environment-technology-development/
PV system works out to be `33 lakh for a id641419331?mt=11)
25-year life and `4.95 lakh for a 12-year
3. Windows of Opportunity: Memoirs of an Economic Adviser (BY K S KRISHNASWAMY)
life. But the benefit part of the equation
changes altogether. The energy require- (http://www.amazon.com/dp/B00CS622GY ;
ment of farmers in an electric pump irri- https://itunes.apple.com/us/book/windows-of-opportunity/id640490173?mt=11)
gated area in most parts of India is likely Please visit the respective sites for prices of the e-books. More titles will be added gradually.
to be much higher than that of Dundi,
24 march 13, 2021 vol lVi no 11 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
COMMENTARY

uncomparable. A proper study based on cost of using groundwater (water buyers irrigation pilot from conceptualisation
primary survey involving comparative in diesel well commands) was comparable to micromanagement. If it is so, should
analysis of water use efficiency in crop with that of their water-selling counter- not they get a third party to evaluate the
production of the solar farmers and the parts (Kumar et al 2010). project? Even commercial and corporate
neighbouring farmers (without solar) When an argument like this is made organisations use professional services
should be undertaken by the International against an otherwise sound economic of auditors, internal and statutory. The
Water Management Institute (IWMI) proposition, the onus lies on the authors techno-economic analysis of Dhundi so-
before making any such claim. to provide robust evidence. But they have lar project presented in the original arti-
miserably failed in that. The authors are cle and the discussion note is not based
The ‘Political Economy’ Argument very fond of promoting an idea, which on any norms prevalent in the solar
Verma et al (2019) argue that their model would not do any good to either the power sector.
of solar PV system with a feed-in tariff is groundwater economy or the state ex-
Notes
the second-best solution. They agree that chequer, just because, it will not attract
1 The typical energy conversion efficiency of an
the metering of farm power with pro the farmers’ ire. They say: electric motor that converts electricity into
rata pricing is the ideal solution. But Rather than simply wishing for pro rata
mec hanical energy is 65%, whereas that of
a solar cell that converts solar energy into
their contention is that the second one is tariffs, if Sahasranaman et al (2018) can electricity is 15%. For details of energy conver-
politically unviable. But there is no anal- offer a way for a democratically elected gov- sion efficiency of different energy production
ernment to implement it without attracting systems, https://www.ems.psu.edu/~radovic/
ysis to back these claims. The only argu- Chapter4.pdf.
the farmers’ ire, it would be a great service
ment is that many state governments had 2 Obviously, the benefits of energy production
to the nation. through diesel pump prior to solar PV system
fallen from Andhra Pradesh to Madhya adoption was not factored in the B–C calcula-
Pradesh (Verma et al 2019: 64). Unfortu- We wonder whether the authors consider tions as a cost.
nately, this argument had been paraded the governments in WB and Gujarat as
by one of the co-authors of the rejoinder not democratically elected! References
Kumar, M D (2005): “Impact of Electricity Prices
for nearly one and a half decades (Shah and Volumetric Water Allocation on Energy
et al 2004; Shah et al 2017). Yet, there is Conclusions and Groundwater Demand Management:
Analysis from Western India,” Energy Policy,
not an iota of evidence to this effect, in Finally, there is no Industrial Research Vol 33, No 1, pp 39–51.
the form of studies on this topic. Gov- Assistance Programme (IRAP) proposal Kumar, M D, O P Singh and M V K Sivamohan
ernments fall due to several reasons. on solar power, unlike what is claimed (2010): “Have Diesel Price Hikes Actually Led
to Farmer Distress in India?” Water Interna-
Farm distress can be one of the reasons. by Verma et al (2019) in the discussion tional, Vol 35, No 3, pp 270–84.
But even then, there is no evidence to note. The authors state: Planning Commission (2011): Annual Report 2011–
12 on the Working of the State Power Utilities
suggest that metering would cause farm Table 2 explores three broad alternative and Electricity Departments in India, Govern-
distress. If that is the case, how come policy trajectories: (i) The “IRAP proposal” ment of India, New Delhi, October.
to stop subsidising SIPs, as argued in Sahas- Sahasranaman, M, M D Kumar, N Bassi, A Ganguly
West Bengal (WB) had 100% metering of and M S Verma (2018): “Solar Irrigation Coop-
ranaman et al (2018); (ii) the current model
farm power supply for almost 13 years eratives: Creating the Frankenstein’s Monster
of SIP promotion being implemented by gov- for India’s Groundwater,” Economic & Political
now? The utility in WB charges `4 per ernment agencies; and (iii) IWMI’s “SPaRC” Weekly, Vol 53, No 21, 26 May, pp 65–68.
kWh. In Gujarat, for several years, farm model of promoting grid-connected SIPs Shah, T, C A Scott, A Kishore and A Sharma (2004):
“Energy-Irrigation Nexus in South Asia Im-
power connections are being metered with low capital subsidy and buy-back ar-
proving Groundwater Conservation and Power
and the number of metered connections rangements through FiT and EBI. Sector Viability,” Research Report # 70, Inter-
national Water Management Institute, Colombo,
has increased substantially to two-thirds Contrary to what the authors say, the Sri Lanka.
of the tube well connections. There are a note by Sahasranaman et al is simply a Shah, T, N Durga, G P Rai, S Verma and R Rathod
few other states also that do agricultural rejection, backed by evidence, of the un- (2017): “Promoting Solar Power as a Remuner-
ative Crop,” Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 52,
metering. tenable and unsubstantiated proposal No 45, 11 November, pp 14–19.
In fact, empirical evidence suggests that presented by them in the name of action Verma, S, N Durga and T Shah (2019): “Solar Irriga-
tion Pumps and India’s Energy–Irrigation Nexus,”
once confronted with positive marginal research. Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 54, No 2,
cost of pumping groundwater (in the For a project in alternative energy 12 January, pp 62–65.
case of diesel well owners, and electric production to be evaluated, a minimum
well owners using metered connections) time lapse of three years from the start Permission for Reproduction of
or using groundwater (water buyers), of production is required. Evaluation of Articles Published in EPW
farmers use all crop inputs efficiently Dhundi solar irrigation coop was done No article published in EPW or part thereof
and modify their farming systems (with when it was just 18 months in operation. should be reproduced in any form without
greater allocation of water for water- IWMI is mentioned as the subsidy pro- prior permission of the author(s).
efficient crops) to secure higher net vider. The authors of the original article A soft/hard copy of the author(s)’s approval
income (`/ha) along with higher water (Shah et al 2017) and the discussion note should be sent to EPW.
use efficiency in physical (kg/m3) and (Verma et al 2019), who are reported to be In cases where the email address of the
author has not been published along with
economic terms (`/m3). The average net working for IWMI, have invested person-
the articles, EPW can be contacted for help.
income of farmers who incurred higher ally and professionally in Dhundi solar
Economic & Political Weekly EPW march 13, 2021 vol lVi no 11 25

You might also like