You are on page 1of 5

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2017, 107(5): 588–592

https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20171004

Heterogeneity and Power Laws in Macroeconomics‡

Aggregate Demand and the Top 1 Percent †

By Adrien Auclert and Matthew Rognlie*

The rise of the top 1 percent of labor income between 1980 and today had been the observed
earners since the 1980s has attracted a consid- fattening of the Pareto tail of the labor income
erable amount of attention in the public debate, distribution, with average income held constant
as well as in academia. The facts are by now (i.e., income had been redistributed in a way con-
­well-established: the top of the labor income sistent with Pareto’s law). What would the conse-
distribution is well described by a power law, quences for savings and interest rates have been?
whose tail appears to have fattened over time Our results are consistent with the view that this
(see, for example, Piketty 2014). However, the change led to a large increase in desired savings,
macroeconomic consequences of this rise in top which in turn may have reduced ­long-run equilib-
income inequality remain unclear. In particular, rium interest rates by 45 to 85 basis points.
since rich and poor have different consumption
and savings patterns, higher inequality may have I.  Fitting the Evolution of the Top Income
affected aggregate demand. But through which Distribution
channels, and by how much?
A large literature on top income inequality The solid black line of Figure 1 shows the
relies on random growth processes to explain the evolution of the top 1 percent of US labor
tail of the income distribution. A recent literature incomes (from data on wages and salaries) since
further argues that changes in the fundamentals the 1980s, according to the World Top Incomes
of this process can explain the observed rise in database. The share earned by the top 1 percent
the top 1 percent since the 1980s (see, for exam- has roughly doubled, from 6.4 percent in 1980
ple, Gabaix et al. 2016). Building on the contribu- to 11.1 percent today.1 It is well known that the
tions of Huggett (1993) and Aiyagari (1994), in upper tail of the income distribution follows a
Auclert and Rognlie (2016)—henceforth, AR— power law; that is, that the fraction of individ-
we develop a framework for mapping changes in uals making more than any given, large enough
income processes, first to changes in aggregate level of income ​y​is given by
demand (a partial equilibrium effect), and then
to interest rates and output (a general equilibrium (1) ​
P​(​yi​​​  ≥  y)​  ∝ ​y​​  −α​​.
effect) depending on assumptions on monetary
and fiscal policy. In this project, we combine these If the entire distribution was Pareto, we could
canonical frameworks to study the consequences infer the tail coefficient ​α​ using the formula
of the rise in the top 1 percent of incomes. To be
precise, we ask: suppose that all that happened
(2) ​
α  = ​ ___________________
   1 
log (top 1 percent share)
 ​​.
________________
1 − ​        ​
log (1 percent)

Discussant: Erzo Luttmer, University of Minnesota.
* Auclert: Stanford University, Landau Economics
Building, 579 Serra Mall, Stanford, CA 94305 (e-mail:
aauclert@stanford.edu); Rognlie: Princeton University, Julis
Romo Rabinowitz Building, Princeton, NJ 08544 (e-mail: 1 
The most widely cited figures for the income share of
mrognlie@princeton.edu). We thank Ben Moll and our dis- the top 1 percent are higher than this, because they also
cussant Erzo Luttmer for helpful comments. include income on capital. (See, for example, Gabaix et
† 
Go to https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20171004 to visit the al. 2016, from whom we take our data). Instead, we take
article page for additional materials and author disclosure the wage distribution as exogenous, and the model endoge-
statement(s). nously generates consequences for capital income. 
588
VOL. 107 NO. 5 Aggregate Demand and the Top 1 percent 589

Panel A. Top labor income shares, data and model Panel B. Wealth/GDP, partial equilibrium

12 6

10

8 5

4
4

k= 0
2 Top 1% share k= 1
Top 0.1% share 3 k= 1
0

1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 1980 2080 2180 2280 2380

Figure 1. Top Labor Income Shares and ­Model-Implied Partial Equilibrium Wealth/GDP Paths

This simple exercise delivers ​​α​1980​​  =  2.48​ and​​ and Violante (2010) suggest ​​σ​​ 2​  ∈ ​[0.01, 0.04]​​
α​today​​  = 1.92​. It turns out that inferring ​α​ in per year as reasonable values. The evidence is
this way also predicts the shape of the income consistent with ​σ​ being either flat or rising mod-
distribution within the top 1 percent extremely estly over time. We therefore set an initial value
well—for example, the top 0.1 percent share, as of ​​σ1980
​  2 ​ ​ = 0.02​ 
, implying a modest negative
shown by the dashed line of Figure 1, panel A. drift in earnings of around ​2.5​percent per year.
We therefore maintain these as our baseline esti- Through the lens of equation (4), we can
mates of the Pareto tail of US wages. interpret the fall in ​α​ from 1980 to today as
It is also widely known (see, for example, some combination of changes in downward
Harrison 1985) that if the process for individual reversion ​μ​ and idiosyncratic volatility ​σ​. Our
incomes ​​yit​ ​​​follows a geometric random walk experiments consider three combinations of μ ​​
with negative drift and ​σ​: we let
​α1980
( ​αtoday
​ ​​ )
k
(3) ​
d log ​y​it​​  = − μ dt + σ d ​Zit​ ​​​, 2
 ​ ​ = ​σ1980
​​σ​ today
​ ​​
​  2 ​ ​​​  ​ _____  
 ​  ​​​  ​  for  k = 0, 1, 2​,
where ​​Z​it​​​is a standard Brownian motion and ​​ _
y  ​​
is a lower reflecting barrier, then the stationary and then let ​μ​ adjust to satisfy (4), adjusting
distribution ​​yit​ ​​​ obeys (1) with the lower reflecting barrier ​​y _​​so as to hold aver-
age income constant in all three cases. When​
2μ k = 0​ , the rise in income inequality comes from
(4) ​
α = ​ ___2 ​​ .
​σ​​  ​ weaker downward drift: high incomes stay high
for longer. When ​k = 1​ , the rise comes instead
To focus on the effects of a rise in tail inequality, from higher volatility: there are more shocks
we use this simple model of the income process to income, even though drift is constant. Our
to conduct quantitative experiments, studying preferred experiment, however, is k​  =  2​  , which
the effect of a decline from ​​ α​1980​​  =  2.48​ to​​ scales up the r­ight-hand side of (3) uniformly.
α​today​​  = 1.92​and the accompanying surge in top This has the natural interpretation of an increase
incomes. in the return to skill: if individual skills e​ ​​ it​​​ follow
​ξ​​​
The large literature on earnings dynamics the process in (3), and income is ​​y​it​​  = ​e​ it​ t​​  , then
delivers useful orders of magnitude for ​​σ​​ 2​​  , the a rise in the “relative skill price” ξ​ ​​ t​​​ by the factor​​
variance of the innovations to the permanent α​1980​​/​αtoday
​ ​​​ delivers our ​k = 2​outcome.
component of log US earnings. Estimates from Starting from the initial stationary distribution
Floden and Lindé (2001) to Heathcote, Perri, in 1980, we progressively phase in the change in
590 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2017

the earnings process in (3) so that the transition Table 1—Main Experiments
is complete today.2 Panel A of Figure 1 plots the ​k​ ​α​ ​μ​ ​​σ​​ 2​​ ​​W​​  PE​​ ​​r​​  GE​*​
resulting paths for the share of top incomes in
our model as dashed lines. Initial SS 2.48 0.024 0.02 2.98 ​4%​
0 1.92 0.019 0.02 4.61 3​ .55%​
1 1.92 0.024 0.026 5.31 ​3.35%​
II.  Consequences for Aggregate Savings 2 1.92 0.031 0.033 5.94 ​3.16%​

In AR, we propose a model that allows us to * Assuming monetary policy targets full employment and
fiscal policy holds government spending and debt fixed.
map the consequences of changes in earnings
processes, such as the one just discussed, onto
changes in macroeconomic aggregates, building
G
spending ​​ __
Y
 ​   = 20.6 percent​and interest on the
on the general equilibrium models of Huggett debt. Firms produce using a ­Cobb-Douglas pro-
and Aiyagari. Our key observation is that the duction function Y ​ = A​K​​  α​ ​L​​  1−α​​  , with capital
change in income process, holding employment depreciating at an annual rate of ​δ = 2.9 percent​.
and interest rates constant, implies a change We assume that monetary policy maintains full
in aggregate demand, that is, in the pattern of employment at all times, and that fiscal pol-
desired consumption and savings over time. icy responds to developments in inequality by
How macroeconomic imbalance between con- maintaining the levels of spending G ​ ​ and debt​
sumption and output is resolved in general equi- B​ ­constant.3
librium, in turn, depends on fundamentals of the We assume that in 1980, agents learn that
economy as well as monetary and fiscal policy top incomes will rise, with the income process
rules, which multiply the initial effect on aggre- changing in the manner described in the previ-
gate demand. We now briefly describe the key ous section. We compute the new ­steady-states,
elements of the model. as well as p­erfect-foresight transition paths,
The economy is populated by i­ nfinitely-lived, implied by each of our experiments. Table 1
­ex ante identical agents with common discount shows that, if employment and interest rates had
rate ​β​and elasticity of intertemporal substitu- remained constant, the increase in top income
tion ​ ν = ​ _12 ​​
 . Their skills evolve stochastically inequality would have resulted in a large rise
according to the process in (3), initially held in aggregate savings W​​  ​​ PE​​. Panel B of Figure 1
at its stationary 1980 distribution. ­Pretax earn- further shows that this increase in aggregate
ings are proportional to skills. We assume that wealth would have taken centuries to material-
a rate ​​τ​r​​  = 17.5 percent​is applied to these earn- ize, reflecting the slow process through which
ings, with proceeds redistributed in a ­lump-sum income inequality accumulates to determine
fashion. Agents face no aggregate uncertainty wealth inequality. Moreover, the magnitude of
and can only trade in an asset delivering a con- this rise depends on the exact underlying driver
stant return ​r​ , subject to maintaining positive of the Pareto tail increase. The more idiosyn-
net worth at all times. We calibrate the model cratic risk increases (the higher ​k​), the higher
to 1980, setting ​ r = 4 percent​ and finding ​β​ the increase in wealth; but note that there is a
such that the ratio of aggregate wealth to overall large increase in wealth increase even if ​σ​ stays
­post-tax labor income is consistent with its ​1980​ constant. This suggests that precautionary sav-
value. This completes the description of the par- ing, although important, is not the only effect at
tial equilibrium model. work; we now dig into this question further.
To compute general equilibrium outcomes,
we further assume that the overall wealth- III.  The Role of Redistribution
income ratio is the sum of government debt
​​  BY ​   =  27.1  percent​ and capital __
__ ​​  KY ​   = 271 percent​. Conditional on aggregate income, a thicker
The government taxes labor income to finance Pareto tail means a rise in incomes at the top, at

3 
Our model, aided by our ­fat-tailed income process, does
2 
As pointed out by Gabaix et al. (2016), with the skill a good job at matching the wealth distribution until close
price interpretation it is possible to target any transition path to the top, but it misses the shape of the tail as well as the
for the top Pareto coefficient. See online Appendix A for dynamics of wealth inequality documented in the data. See
details on our income transition dynamics.  online Appendix C for details. 
VOL. 107 NO. 5 Aggregate Demand and the Top 1 percent 591

Panel A Panel B

3
dy
ϵW, Y
40 MPCY 0.4
Income change, relative to mean

Sensitivity ϵW, Y
20 0.2

MPC
1

0 0

−20
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
Income percentile Income percentile

Figure 2. Redistribution from α


​  : 2.48 → 1.92​ , and Partial Equilibrium Sensitivities

the expense of incomes at the bottom. Panel A Panel B of Figure 2 shows that ​​ϵ​W, y​​​ is mono-
of Figure 2 shows the impact of our experiment, tonically increasing in ​y.​ For low ​y​  , ​​ϵW, y
​ ​​​ is nega-
a decline in ​α​ from ​2.48​to ​1.92​ , for incomes tive: therefore, when income at the bottom of the
at each percentile of the distribution, normalized distribution goes down, individuals in the aggre-
by mean aggregate income. As expected, most gate increase savings for precautionary reasons.
of the rise in income occurs at the very top of For higher ​y​  , ​​ϵW, y
​ ​​​ becomes positive: when income
the distribution. at the top of the distribution goes up, individu-
als also increase savings due to a wealth effect.
A. The Rise in Savings: Precautionary Savings Hence, in our experiment, both effects contribute
and Wealth Effect positively to aggregate savings,4 with the wealth
effect being somewhat more important.
The experiment k​  = 2​in Table 1 has the spe-
cial feature that the transition matrix between B. The Role of MPC Differences
income quantiles is left unaltered, even as those
quantiles become more dispersed. Following It is often argued that the rise of the top 1
our preferred interpretation, we can think of the percent may depress aggregate demand because
experiment as a change in the income implied the rich have lower marginal propensities to
by each state in a Markov process for skills, with consume (MPCs). In AR, we show that this
the process itself being unchanged. argument is correct if the change in income
It is then possible to break down the increase inequality is temporary.5 We derive a sufficient
in aggregate wealth ___ ​​ dW
W
 ​​  in the experiment into statistic for the partial equilibrium effect ​∂ C​ on
contributions from the change in each income consumption in a given year, when an income
level ​y​ , using the ­first-order approximation (see inequality change takes place only in that year,
online Appendix D) which is

(6) ​
∂ C = Cov​(MP​Cy​ ​​,  dy)​. ​
(5) ​​ ____
dW ​  = Cov​ ​ϵ​ ​​,  dy ​ ​,
( W, y )
W

where ​​ϵ​W, y​​​is the proportional increase in aggre-


4 
Observe that both the d​ y​and the ϵ​
​​ W, y​​​lines in Figure 2
cross zero around the same income percentile. 
gate savings that would result if only the income 5 
However, we show that MPCs play no role in explain-
of individuals earning ​y​were raised, normalized ing ­long-run aggregate demand when the change in income
by the fraction of such individuals. inequality is l­ong-lasting. 
592 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2017

We then show that (6) is a key determinant of Appendix B, this decline is p­ rotracted and only
the general equilibrium effect. fully realized after around 100 years. Hence, the
Panel B of Figure 2 shows ­ model-implied full macroeconomic effects of the rapid rise in
average MPCs by income percentile. MPCs income inequality we have observed may take
decline with income, but the decline is much decades to filter through, providing one force
stronger near the bottom of the distribution for depressed equilibrium interest rates going
(where MPCs are reasonably high) than at the forward.
top (where MPCs are consistently low). This While the rise of the top 1 percent is unlikely
brings down the covariance in (6), since the to have affected aggregate demand because of
income changes in our experiment are most dis- MPC differences, it may well have affected
persed at the top of the distribution, where the it because of the resultant increase in desired
variation in MPCs is limited. savings, via a combination of a wealth effect
Evaluating (6), the implied partial equilibrium and higher precautionary savings. In turn, this
consumption effect of a ­year-on-year increase in may have contributed to pushing the economy
income inequality that thickens the Pareto tail to the zero lower bound. In AR, we show that
from ​α = 2.48​to ​1.92​ , as in our experiment, is once the zero lower bound starts binding, fur-
−1.8 percent of GDP. Furthermore, as demon- ther increases in inequality can be extremely
strated in AR, this partial equilibrium consump- damaging, and can potentially lead to secular
tion effect is typically close in magnitude to the stagnation.
general equilibrium output effect.
Note, however, that such a large shift in the References
income distribution is unlikely to be transitory,
or to happen within a single year. More realistic Aiyagari, S. Rao. 1994. “Uninsured Idiosyncratic
transitory shocks to the right tail of the income Risk and Aggregate Saving.” Quarterly Jour-
distribution, like the ­ year-to-year fluctuations nal of Economics 109 (3): 659–84.
in Figure 1, will have commensurately smaller Auclert, Adrien, and Matthew Rognlie. 2016.
impacts. “Inequality and Aggregate Demand.” http://
Clear empirical evidence on the pattern of web.stanford.edu/~aauclert/inequad.pdf.
MPCs by income is lacking, especially at the Floden, Martin, and Jesper Lindé. 2001. “Idio-
very top. Available empirical evidence lends syncratic Risk in the United States and
support to the view that MPCs decline with Sweden: Is There a Role for Government
income, although probably not as strongly as Insurance?” Review of Economic Dynamics 4
what is implied by Figure 2. Hence, our −1.8 (2): 406–37.
percent number is very likely to be an upper Gabaix, Xavier, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis
bound of the consumption effect of a rise in the Lions, and Benjamin Moll. 2016. “The Dynam-
top 1 percent. ics of Inequality.” Econometrica 84 (6): 2071–
2111.
IV.  Macroeconomic Effects Harrison, J. Michael. 1985. Brownian Motion and
Stochastic Flow Systems. Hoboken: Wiley.
The framework in AR allows us to map the Heathcote, Jonathan, Fabrizio Perri, and Giovanni
effect on savings discussed in Section III onto an L. Violante. 2010. “Unequal We Stand: An
effect on output and interest rates, depending on Empirical Analysis of Economic Inequality in
assumptions about monetary and fiscal policy. If the United States, 1967–2006.” Review of Eco-
fiscal policy holds the level of government debt nomic Dynamics 13 (1): 15–51.
and spending constant, and monetary policy low- Huggett, Mark. 1993. “The Risk-Free Rate in
ers interest rates to ensure full employment, then Heterogeneous-Agent Incomplete-Insurance
the effect on equilibrium interest rates is given in Economies.” Journal of Economic Dynamics
Table 1. The l­ ong-term interest rate effect is sub- and Control 17 (5–6): 953–69.
stantial, amounting to somewhere between 45 Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the Twen-
and 85 basis points depending on the source of ty-First Century.  Cambridge, MA: Harvard
the change in the Pareto tail. As shown in online University Press.

You might also like