You are on page 1of 13

830557

research-article20192019
SGOXXX10.1177/2158244019830557SAGE OpenAsadullah

Original Research

SAGE Open

Quadratic Indirect Effect of National


January-March 2019: 1­–13
© The Author(s) 2019
DOI: 10.1177/2158244019830557
https://doi.org/10.1177/2158244019830557

TVET Expenditure on Economic Growth journals.sagepub.com/home/sgo

Through Social Inclusion Indicators

Muhammad Ali Asadullah1

Abstract
The recent movement of social-investment state encouraged national educational initiatives taken by the policy makers
of developed countries to enhance individual’s social inclusion for national economic gains. Benefiting from human capital
theory, the author has reexamined the indirect effect of nation expenditure of technical and vocational education and training
(TVET) on economic growth through social inclusion by isolating the effective key social inclusion dimensions (employment,
earnings, and multidimensional poverty) from each other. A 15-year data set, ranging from 2000 to 2014, collected from
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) database of 21 OECD member European countries
was used for hypotheses testing. The statistical results obtained through the quadratic indirect effects demonstrate clear
support for the entire hypotheses. However, the results demonstrate that the indirect effects decrease as the values of TVET
expenditure increases, particularly, when the indirect effect is investigated through the wages or when the overall index
value of social inclusion indicators is introduced as a mediator. The study offers some implications for the researchers and
the policy makers who are interested in determining the overall effectiveness of human capital development initiatives in the
welfare-state/social-investment states.

Keywords
economic growth, employment, social inclusion, technical and vocational education and training (TVET), wages,
multidimensional poverty

Introduction not sufficient from the human capital development rather


there is a continuous need for up-skilling the current work-
The global economies have been facing the issue of aging force as well.1
population and labor shortages for a long time, but the recent These increasingly serious challenges led the researchers
financial crisis hampered further economic growth due to to revisit the impact of education on national human capital
increasing unemployment, inequality, poverty, low job cre- (Leuven & Oosterbeek, 2011; Quintini, 2011) for helping the
ation, and restricted immigration policies to protect local governments to find the remedies of rising unemployment at
jobs (Cerna, 2018). The Organisation for Economic the lowest cost (Pilz, 2012). To cope with these challenges,
Co-operation and Development (OECD) statistics indicate an increasing association between the rising unemployment
an increasing gap in the wages and rising inequality in the and the technical and vocational education and training
household income in majority of OECD countries for past (TVET; López-Fogués, 2012; McGrath & Lugg, 2012) has
three decades (OECD, December 2014; Maclean, 2017). In been observed in OECD countries (López-Fogués, 2018).
addition, the recent migration and refugee crisis in Europe, Particularly, there was an increase in national spending on
resulting from the war and insecurity in the Middle East, TVET due to increasing emphasis of international governing
Africa, and Southern Asia (Allen et al., 2018; Niemann & bodies including UNESCO and World Bank, for alleviating
Zaun, 2018) boosted inequality and poverty across immi-
grant and refugee class (Eugster, 2018). Eugster (2018) 1
Emirates College of Technology, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates
found that regulatory institutions are more successful in
reducing the poverty of the immigrants in countries where Corresponding Author:
Muhammad Ali Asadullah, Emirates College of Technology, Millennium
the immigrants have a greater access to the employment and Tower, Sheikh Hamdan Street, Opp. Hamdan Center, Abu Dhabi, United
social benefits. A recent blog on world economic forum Arab Emirates.
highlighted that policies to reform education for youth are Email: muhammad.asadullah@ect.ac.ae

Creative Commons CC BY: This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License
(http://www.creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/) which permits any use, reproduction and distribution of
the work without further permission provided the original work is attributed as specified on the SAGE and Open Access pages
(https://us.sagepub.com/en-us/nam/open-access-at-sage).
2 SAGE Open

the poverty, inequality, and overall economic prosperity Here, we assimilate national TVET expenditure as a mecha-
(Comyn & Barnaart, 2010). Unfortunately, the national nism of developing human capabilities, social inclusion as a
TVET reforms remained limitedly effective for resolving source of enhancing social capabilities of the individuals,
issues of skill development and social inclusion (Fleckenstein while economic growth as a source of enhancing overall
& Lee, 2018) as a significant proportion of population, par- national economic capacity. While testing these assump-
ticularly, the youth is still experiencing social exclusion in tions, the current study has explained the power of educa-
relation to education (Vandekinderen, Roets, Van Keer, & tional investment in developing human capabilities to
Roose, 2018). Thus, there is a need for TVET sector that enhance overall economic capacity of a nation through their
facilitates the economies in fulfilling their skill gaps, enhanc- social capabilities including employability, earnings, and
ing community cohesion, and productivity (Hadawi & poverty elimination.
Crabbe, 2018). Hadawi et al. stressed the need for a measure Second, this study has contributed to the existing stream of
that demonstrates the social value of TVET. One of such literature on TVET by investigating the distinct mediating
measure that can effectively demonstrate the social value of role of each social inclusion indicators that is, employment,
TVET investments is social inclusion. The question arises earnings, and multidimensional poverty index of a country
about the extent to which the government spending on voca- between national TVET expenditure and economic growth.
tional education and training (VET), in OECD member states The empirical testing of these mediating mechanisms using
of European Union, has been effective in overcoming the social indicators as separate explanatory account between
issue of social exclusion resulting from the increasing unem- TVET and economic growth provides an empirical explana-
ployment, income inequality, and poverty and the overall tion about the effectiveness of “Education Strategy 2020”
economic prosperity. The study aims at addressing this (Cobo, Zucchetti, & Rivas, 2011) of World Bank for its part-
research question by examining the mediating role of key ner countries pursuing social-welfare state policy. According
social inclusion dimensions (earning, employment, and pov- to this strategy, World Bank envisioned to set its priorities to
erty) between national TVET spending and economic growth strengthen the education systems of its member countries.
in OECD member states of European Union. The hypothesized relationships tested in the current study
This study has offered some theoretical contribution to provide an explanation about the extent to which the OECD
the existing stream of literature on TVET investment and member countries have been able to achieve the learning goal
economic growth in certain ways. First, the debates about (target of becoming socially inclusive economies) by follow-
the conventional view of the significance of human capital ing the vision of World Bank through TVET investment ini-
in economic growth have augmented due to the limited and tiatives to achieve economic growth. Third, the existing
controversial empirical evidence (Sunde & Vischer, 2015). research on TVET has not provided sufficient empirical evi-
The existing literature on economic growth provides some dence about the mediating role of each social inclusion indi-
explanation about the contribution of human capital in eco- cators separately between TVET and economic growth. This
nomic growth (by complimenting the factors of production; is important for an important reason. Among the social inclu-
Lucas, 1988a, 1988b; Solow, 1956), adopting new technolo- sion indicators used in the current study, poverty may have a
gies (Nelson & Phelps, 1966) and augmenting innovation different explanatory role as compared with employment and
(Aghion & Howitt, 2006; Hanushek & Woessmann, 2008; earnings. For instance, the increase in employment may ignite
Romer, 1990). However, there is still a need for the mecha- the TVET and economic growth relationship, whereas pov-
nisms, which may explain the effect of human capital on erty may have opposite effect. Thus, extending our previous
economic growth (Sunde & Vischer, 2015). The recent work (Asadullah & Zafar, 2018) in which we used aggregate
movement of welfare state (Garritzmann, Busemeyer, & scores to measure the social inclusion, a separate mediating
Neimanns, 2018) or the social-investment state (Busemeyer, analysis provided more robust explanation for each indicator
de la Porte, Garritzmann, & Pavolini, 2018) reforms has separately. Thus, the current study has demonstrated an
attracted the attention of researchers toward the concept of empirical evidence related to the role of TVET expenditure in
social investment policies, which emphasize developing and economic growth through employment, earnings, and poverty
efficiently utilizing human capital to enhance their social reduction (Figure 1) in 21 different OECD economies based
inclusion (Morel, Palier, & Palme, 2012). Particularly, the on 15 years.
researchers are attracted to empirically test the assumption
of educational policy reformists that education can serve as
Theoretical Framework
a crucial driver for overall economic development by reduc-
ing poverty reduction and promoting social inclusion The government, which is responsible for developing human
(Mercer, 2014). Hence, considering social inclusion as a key resources at the national level, devises national educational
target of social-state policies, this study has introduced policies for workforce development to ensure coordination
social inclusion as a channel to empirically test how national of national resources for a strong economic system
investment in TVET has contributed to the overall economic (Wedchayanon & Chorkaew, 2014). This requires the gov-
development of some social-welfare OECD economies. ernments to treat people as a strategic asset, a strategy of
Asadullah 3

Figure 1.  Hypothetical framework.

national human resource development, to sustain competi- (neither in education, employment, or training) also brings
tive advantage of an economy. The governments take invest- our attention toward the concept of social exclusion of indi-
ment decisions to satisfy this responsibility for developing viduals. This represents that the individuals are highly likely
the skills of individuals, ensuring their employability to to withdraw from the education if they do not find expected
avoid their disengagement/exclusion of population. An benefits. Moreover, the individuals also stop working if their
effective national training system guarantees the national wages are low, and hence the return on investment dimin-
human capital development by improving the skills, knowl- ishes (Angel-Urdinola & Mayer Gukovas, 2018). Thus, a
edge, trust and cooperation, motivation, employability, and timely investment in human capital formation is always criti-
productive industrial relations (Docherty, Forslin, & Shani, cal for social inclusion of the citizens to reap the benefits
2002). Among the national investment decisions for devel- TVET at the social level over a long period. One of the key
oping human resources, TVET has remained one of the most hypothesis of the current study is to demonstrate the effec-
prominent national training systems for developing national tiveness of national investment in TVET for social inclusion
human resources. TVET has a significant potential to facili- of the individuals in a society using the human capital theory
tate governments in overcoming the social and economic for theoretical support of national human resource develop-
issues through various means. ment perspective.
The OECD countries developed a wide range of policies The national educational reforms, which emphasize on
to enhance the opportunities for both learning and gaining empowering TVET to develop the learning, competencies,
work experiences (Vanhove, 2017), yet, skill development and qualifications of the citizens for addressing the changing
through TVET still remained a proven way to enhance the labor market requirements have strengthened the strategic
access of youth to the labor market (CEPAL, 2013). However, value of TVET. A greater financial investment in TVET at
mere skill development does not guarantee the economic national level enables the government to take such diverse
growth, rather, it requires policy makers to emphasize more initiatives to improve and monitor the quality of TVET ini-
on job creation. Particularly, high-income OECD countries, tiatives. A higher investment in TVET facilitates govern-
which are facing more of the issue of overeducation, need to ments in diversifying the investment in human resource
create employment opportunities for their overeducated and development by introducing diverse type of TVEt alterna-
highly skilled workers (Handel, Valerio, & Sánchez Puerta, tives (like dual system of apprenticeships, competency-based
2016; McGuinness, Pouliakas, & Redmond, 2017). training, green initiatives) training and allows for a higher
This is challenging for policy makers to demonstrate the involvement of stakeholders in the process of identifying
value of national investment in TVET at the societal level for market required and competency-based training programs to
their claim of building and upgrading the market-required inject quality in TVET initiatives.
competencies, employability, financial benefits (wages), and Human capital theory offers an economic justification to
reducing inequality. Hadawi and Crabbe (2018) stressed the the policy makers for promoting the participation of indi-
need for a measure that demonstrates the social value of viduals in the education (Gale & Molla, 2015). Human
TVET. One of such measure that can effectively demonstrate capital theory (Becker, 1962; Schultz, 1960, 1961) posits
the social value of TVET investments is social inclusion. that developing the skills, knowledge, and attitude of the
TVET facilitates the economies in fulfilling their skill gaps, human capital facilitates them to find and retain appropriate
enhancing community cohesion and productivity (Hadawi & jobs. This prevents social exclusion and promotes the inclu-
Crabbe, 2018). The individuals of a society are highly likely sion of the educationally deprived individuals in the society
to experience economic and social disengagement, if the by providing the opportunity to integrate themselves into
education system does not facilitate in building the market- the labor market (Dean, 2003; Vandekinderen et al., 2018).
based skill set of the individuals (Angel-Urdinola & Mayer According to the human capital theory, the learner, as a
Gukovas, 2018). Particularly, the population not acquiring human capital, is processed through vocational education
any skill with education is more likely to experience disen- and training to actively shape the work and the society
gagement and exclusion. The term disengagement, which is (Bohne, Eicker, & Haseloff, 2017). The TVET systems pro-
described by Angel-Urdinola & Mayer Gukovas as NEET vide the learner an opportunity to practice and learn, which
4 SAGE Open

enhances their skills. Particularly, the recent forms of com- Based on previous arguments discussed in the light of
petence-based VET provide the learners an opportunity to human capital theory, this study has hypothesized that a
practice at different places (Bohne et al., 2017), which higher national TVET expenditure is more likely to enhance
enhances their market-based competencies. TVET is a key employment and earnings, while reducing poverty. Thus, the
source of social inclusion for its capacity of building the economies with a high TVET expenditure experience a high
individuals’ market-relevant skills to enhance the opportu- social inclusion. Similarly, the economies, which experience
nity for the unemployed to access the labor market (Nilsson, a reduction in poverty, experience an increase in their rating
2010). on multidimensional poverty index.
A high rate of unemployment represents a higher social
Hypothesis 1 (H1): A higher national investment in
exclusion of the individuals as unemployed are unable to
TVET is positively associated with social inclusion of the
contribute to the society because of their low level of pro-
individuals in an economy such that
ductivity and income. This represents their social disen-
Hypothesis 1a (H1a): An increase in national investment
gagement, which is linked to negative performance or
in TVET is positively associated with an increase in
lower productivity (Mirick, 2016; Simmons & Thompson,
employment rate.
2013). However, investing in TVET at national level pro-
Hypothesis 1b (H1b): An increase in national investment
vides a skill-building and employability opportunity to a
in TVET is positively associated with an increase in the
wide proportion of the national population. The employ-
wages.
ability is an indicator of social status and achievement
Hypothesis 1c (H1c): An increase in national investment
(Lawy & Biesta, 2006; Lister, 2000) representing the indi-
in TVET is positively associated with the increase in mul-
viduals’ productivity and their social inclusion
tidimensional poverty rating of an economy.
(Vandekinderen et al., 2018).
Due to its significant contribution to skill and employ-
ability, TVET also has a potential to reduce poverty.
TVET and Economic Growth
Poverty is a multidimensional reality consisting of depri-
vations, unmet needs, and limited participation in social The human capital approach is a key economic rationale for
affairs rather than being restricted to the financial condi- the policy makers to enhance the national investment in edu-
tion or an inadequate income (Alcock, 1997). The research- cation to widen individuals’ participation in the education
ers (Hagenaars, 2017; Ringen, Seegal, & England, 1995; (Gale & Molla, 2015). The human capital theory explains
Sen, 1999) attribute poverty to the deprivation of educa- that national investment in education and training for devel-
tion, material resources, and the social exclusion. Poverty oping competent citizens is positively associated with eco-
keeps the individuals in the consistent need of maintaining nomic growth (Dean, 2003; Regmi et al., 2015). The
their moral state and material necessities, which deter their “education” as a strategy of economic revival attracted the
autonomy. Consequently, the poor remain excluded from significant attention of policy makers after the 2008 Global
social practices (Papa, 2018). This can be argued that the Financial Crisis (Antolin & Stewart, 2009). The human capi-
poor are more likely to remain NEET due to their higher tal theory provides a perspective of the education as a capital
material dependence as compared with the rich. On the good for developing human resources to cope with socioeco-
contrary, the research has also shown that unemployment nomic changes (Olaniyan & Okemakinde, 2008; Regmi
rate is lower in more-educated people (Cairo & Cajner, et al., 2015). The human capital outcomes resulting from the
2017). However, a higher national investment in TVET imperative role of educational institutions (Biesta, 2006) as
initiatives is more likely to provide the poor and unedu- the engine for economic growth (Gowlett, 2012) are driving
cated people to have a skill-building opportunity based on the recent educational policies (Walker, 2012). Hence, “the
the government expenditure. Thus, the individuals living human capital approach provides policymakers with an eco-
in economies with high investment in TVET are more nomic rationale for widening participation in education”
likely to secure greater education and reeducation opportu- (Gale & Molla, 2015, p. 819).
nities to develop their market-required skills. Thus, a Based on human capital theory, this study explains how a
national investment in TVET is also more likely to reduce higher level of social inclusion may contribute to the growth
the poverty of the individuals. There is empirical evidence of an economy. Social inclusion enhances sociocultural
available about the significant contribution of TVET in development (Comyn & Barnaart, 2010), which can enhance
enhancing individual’s skill (Jothilakshmi, Krishnaraj, & social expenditure made by individuals and hence, the over-
Sudeepkumar, 2009), productivity (Kijima, Ito, & Otsuka, all economic activity. The high productivity of the individu-
2012; Rosholm, Nielsen, & Dabalen, 2007), income als and the organizations in a high socially inclusive economy
(Mahmud, Parvez, Hilton, Kabir, & Wahid, 2014), and enhances its gross domestic product (GDP; Dearden et al.,
economic well-being (Mahmud, Mohamed, Ismail, 2005). The individuals of a socially inclusive economy are
Shamsudin, & Hilton, 2007). more likely to secure jobs in the international labor market
Asadullah 5

and contribute to the economy through remittances (Nilsson, 2010), and poverty reduction. Human capital theory
(Asadullah & Zafar, 2018). The individuals of a socially advocates maximum utilization of human capital to enhance
inclusive economy are more likely to consumer national economic growth because economic growth is more likely to
products and services, hence, increasing circulation of wealth increase in the socially inclusive national environments,
and the overall economic activity. The increased circulation which ensure equal chances for the individuals to benefit
of money reduces inequality and the equitable social envi- from economic opportunities (Ali et al., 2018). National
ronment contributes positively to the economic situation TVET expenditure conveys a message of higher state-level
(Ali, Egbetokun, & Memon, 2018) because the social inclu- interest in developing national human capital. According to
sion enhances social activities (Rose, Daiches, & Potier, the perspective of neoclassical economists, the human capital
2012). refers to the national stock of knowledge and skills that enable
The social investment, which has received a recent atten- the people to perform work that creates economic value
tion of policy makers in the welfare-state policies (Garritzmann (Nahapiet, 2011).
et al., 2018), emphasizes on developing human capital and A higher national TVET expenditure represents a
their efficient utilization (Morel et al., 2012). However, the greater supply of human resources in the labor market for
development and utilization of human capital may be less the organizations. Particularly, TVET also facilitates a
effective if most of the population are poor. Poverty is a mul- supply of human resources to the small and medium enter-
tidimensional reality and according to the perspective of prises, hence, contributing to the economic growth of a
imperfect credit market (Stiglitz, 1969), the poor are highly country. There is a recent empirical evidence about the sig-
unlikely to repay their loans because of their inability to nificant contribution of small and medium businesses in
invest their loans for some productivity gains. On the con- economic growth and poverty reduction, in Ethiopia,
trary, the people are more likely to utilize their loans and more through TVET, which enhances their creativity and inno-
capable to reimburse if there is a higher opportunity for vation (Mihret Dessie & Shumetie Ademe, 2017). The
employment and earnings in an economy. Similarly, the econ- skilled individuals may secure minimum wages and over-
omies with low poverty ratio are also highly likely to reduce time pay through their employability to sufficiently meet
crime rate, which can facilitate them in avoiding a significant their basic necessities (Jayasinghe, 2016). As the acquisi-
loss of GDP, for example, 7.5% in Latin America (Bennett, tion of skills and knowledge enhances the productivity and
2002). Thus, an economy, which has a higher rating on multi- earnings (Becker, 1962; Kwon & Kim, 2009), a higher
dimensional poverty index, is more likely to experience eco- TVET expenditure should enhance overall national pro-
nomic growth as compared with the economies, which are ductivity and earnings. By combining the micro- and mac-
low in multidimensional poverty index. Thus, we hypothe- roperspectives of human capital theory, it can be argued
sized the following: that higher TVET expenditure enhances the education
level of the citizens, collectively, which enhances their
Hypothesis 2 (H2): Social inclusion and economic employability and achievement as dictated (microperspec-
growth are positively associated such that, tive, Almendarez, 2013) and productivity, which further
Hypothesis 2a (H2a): The employment rate is positively strengthens the growth of an economy (Almendarez, 2013;
associated with economic growth. Blaug, 1976). In other sense, the growth of an economy
Hypothesis 2b (H2b): Wage rate is positively associated resulting from a higher TVET expenditure can also be as
with economic growth. an externality effect of education as stated by Canton
Hypothesis 2c (H2c): The multidimensional poverty rat- (2007), because the whole society benefits from this
ing is positively associated with economic growth. investment by acquiring those skills and knowledge, which
enhance their employability and earnings. Based on the
previous arguments provided in the light of human capital
Indirect Effect of TVET Expenditure on Economic
theory, it can be derived that the economies with high
Growth employability, higher wages, and high poverty index (the
The human capital theory explains the mechanism through rating of a country on multidimensional poverty index rep-
which national investment on TVET contributes to the eco- resents that the poverty ratio is low in an economy) are
nomic growth of a country through the elements of social more likely to achieve economic growth through an
inclusion, that is, employment, wages, and the overall poverty increased TVET expenditure. Thus, based on the human
ranking of a country. The human capital theory is a wide- capital theory, this study hypothesized that social inclusion
spread notion for justifying the association between educa- indicators strengthen the effect of national expenditure on
tion and economic growth (Marginson, 2019; Tanaka, 2018). TVET on economic growth of a country.
Human capital theory justifies the contribution of national
educational investment, as a part of social-welfare state pol- Hypothesis 3 (H3): The social inclusion strengthens the
icy, in the national economic growth through different social effect of national TVET expenditure on economic growth
inclusion indicators including employability, earning of an economy.
6 SAGE Open

Hypothesis 3a (H3a): The increase in the employment for estimating instantaneous indirect effects when the paths
strengthens the effect of national TVET expenditure on between independent, dependent, and mediating variables
economic growth of an economy. are nonlinear.
Hypothesis 3b (H3b): The increase in the wages strength- The index of social inclusion was created using the stan-
ens the effect of national TVET expenditure on economic dardized estimates of employment, wage, and poverty.
growth of an economy. Similarly, the variables were transformed on the same scale
Hypothesis 3c (H3c): The increase in multidimensional using their standardized estimates prior to estimating the
poverty ranking of a country strengthens the effect of mediation curve. This technique also provides another
national TVET expenditure on economic growth of an advantage of using bootstrapping option for calculating indi-
economy. rect estimates. This study used 2,000 bootstrapping samples
at 95% bias-corrected confidence interval. There are several
advantages of using bootstrapping technique over the para-
Method and Measures
metric procedures for testing indirect effects. The researcher
This is a longitudinal study–based panel data obtained can avoid the assumptions of distribution normally required
through secondary sources. This study used standardized for parametric procedures. The bootstrapping is more robust
OECD statistics to measure the independent, mediator, than parametric procedures with respect to their statistical
dependent variables, and the control variables. The data are power and Type-I error rates (Fritz & MacKinnon, 2007;
collected for 21 OECD member states of European Union MacKinnon, Lockwood, & Williams, 2004). Third, boot-
over a period of 15 years ranging from 2000 to 2014. The strap confidence intervals tend to be more asymmetric and
statistics for the remaining OECD member states of European closer to the true sampling distribution (Hayes & Preacher,
Union was not available for the complete 15-year period, 2010).
therefore, the remaining OECD member states of European
Union are omitted. TVET is measured through the percent-
age of public spending on short-term tertiary education in a
Results
country. We used change in real GDP to measure economic The first hypothesis of the study demonstrated that national
growth of a country. The social inclusion is measured using investment in TVET is positively linked to the social inclu-
an index based on employment (Lister, 2000), wage rate sion of the individuals in an economy such that a higher
(income per capita), poverty, and inequality. Poverty is mea- national investment in TVET is positively related to the
sured using multidimensional poverty index and inequality is social inclusion (H1). The statistical output of instantaneous
measured using the most commonly used measure, that is, indirect effect obtained through SPSS mediation curve esti-
Gini-coefficient. The key macroeconomic variables such as mation macro using quadratic direct and indirect paths dem-
national saving, international trade, inflation and foreign onstrated that national investment in TVET was positively
direct investment were introduced as control variables due to and significantly associated with employment (β = .243;
their potential on economic growth (Lucas, 1988a, 1988b; p < .001). This provided statistical support for H1.
Zarsky & Gallagher, 2012). Furthermore, the statistical results demonstrated positive and
significant association between social inclusion and eco-
nomic growth (β = .986; p < .001). This result also demon-
Analytical Procedure strated statistical support for H2. The Table 1, given below,
The mediation or indirect effect is commonly used to quan- contains the values of beta coefficients and the standard
tify an indirect effect of an independent variable on a depen- errors for different paths (i.e., independent to mediating vari-
dent variable through a mediating variable (Hayes & able [Path a], mediating to the dependent variable [Path b]
Preacher, 2010). The majority of existing literature on medi- and the independent to the dependent variable [Path c]) of
ation methods assumes that the direct and indirect paths each mediation model investigated in the study.
between independent, mediator, and dependent variables are Finally, the statistical output also demonstrated that the
linear. However, the phenomena under investigation are less instantaneous indirect effect of TVET on economic growth
linear in nature. This study aimed at investigating the media- through social inclusion was significant across different
tion mechanism through which national investment in TVET values of TVET (i.e., mean, high [one standard deviation
determines the economic growth through social inclusion. above the mean], and low [one standard deviation below
The current study used a panel data for 21 countries over a the mean]). The estimates for instantaneous indirect effects
time period of 15 years ranging from 2000 to 2014. The data of TVET on economic growth through social inclusion
set contains 315 total observations (21 countries ×15 years). across low (–0.7268), medium (0.2110), and high (1.1488)
The longitudinal nature of the data set demonstrated that the are given
hypothesized direct and indirect paths may not be necessar- in Table 3. These values provide evidence that among the
ily linear. Thus, SPSS macro developed by Hayes and countries with the low, medium, or high level of national
Preacher (2010) used ordinary least square (OLS) regression investment in TVET, increasing national investment in
Asadullah 7

Table 1.  Descriptive Statistics for Standardized Values of the Variables.

M SD Emp Wage MPI S1 EG FDI Infl PCI IT Sav


TVET .213 0.928 .500** .491** .644** .525** –.059 .153** –.319** –.147** .129* .624**
Emp .043 1.054 1 .749** .680** .833** –.001 .089 –.11 –.117* .02 .425**
Wage .0146 1.044 1 .810** .675** –.138* .162** –.286** –.274** –.09 .460**
MPI .000 1.000 1 .693** –.216** .220** –.405** –.347** .046 .566**
S1 .011 0.642 1 .436** .144* –.153** .324** .101 .535**
EG –.068 1.0616 1 .024 .173** .965** .094 .098
FDI –.098 0.913 1 –.105 –.032 .131* .144*
Infl .0258 1.065 1 .207** .057 –.305**
PCI –.008 1.095 1 .116* .016
IT .247 0.855 1 .240**
Sav .0918 1.028 1

Note. EMP = employment rate; MPI = multidimensional poverty index; SI = social inclusion; EG = economic growth; FDI = foreign direct investment;
Infl = inflational; PCI = per capita income; IT = international trade; Sav = national saving; TVET = national investment in technical and vocational
education as percentage of GDP; GDP = gross domestic product.
**Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (two tailed). *Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (two tailed).

TVET may function to increase economic growth through The second hypothesis was delineated to examine the
social inclusion. Table 3 provides the values of instanta- positive association of employment rate (H2a) and wages
neous indirect effects of the quadratic mediation models (H2b) with economic growth, while negative association of
investigated in the study along with the information about poverty to the economic growth (H2c). The statistical results
the effect size of indirect effect at different values (mean/ supported the positive and significant association between
medium; low, that is, one standard deviation above the employment rate and economic growth (β = .634; p > .05),
mean; and high, that is, one standard deviation below the while controlling for the effect of per capita income, infla-
mean) of TVET (theta in third column), the upper bound tion, saving, international trade, and foreign direct. This sta-
and lower bound values (at 95% confidence intervals with tistical result demonstrates statistical support for H2a. The
1,000 boot strapping samples) obtained (column 4 and 5) statistical results also demonstrated that MPI (multidimen-
and the simple interpretation of the results (column 6). sional poverty index) is positively and significantly associ-
ated with the economic growth (β = .144; p > .001). This
also demonstrates statistical support for H2c because of neg-
Post Hoc Analysis ative coefficients. Similarly, the results provided statistical
We performed post hoc analysis to further probe the indirect support for H2b describing that wages increase is positively
effect of each of the mediating variables used to create the associated with economic growth (β = .134; p < .01), while
index of social inclusion (employment, wage, and poverty). controlling for the effect of inflation, savings, per capita
The first hypothesis stated that national investment in TVET income, foreign direct investment, and international trade.
is positively related to the social inclusion such that a higher The third hypothesis was defined to examine a significant
national investment in TVET is positively associated with indirect effect of TVET on economic growth through social
employment rate (H1a) and wages (H1b) but negatively inclusion (H3). We also probed individual-level instanta-
associated with poverty (H1c). We tested instantaneous indi- neous indirect effect of three subdimensions of social inclu-
rect effect through employment by constraining the Path b as sion, that is, employment, wages, and poverty using the
quadratic. mediation curve micro in SPSS. The statistical results
The statistical output of instantaneous indirect effect revealed that the instantaneous indirect effect of TVET on
obtained through SPSS mediation curve estimation macro economic growth through employment was insignificant
using quadratic direct and indirect paths (Table 2) demon- across different values of TVET (i.e., medium, low, and
strated that national investment in TVET was positively and high). Hence, H3a was not supported. The interval estimates
significantly associated with employment at 90% confidence for instantaneous indirect effects of TVET on economic
interval (β= .117; p < .10). This provided partial statistical growth through employment across low (–0.7268), medium
support for H1a. But, national investment in TVET is also (0.2110), and high (1.1488) are provided in Table 3. There is
positively associated with wages (β= .347; p < .001) and evidence that among the countries with the low, medium, or
multidimensional poverty index (β = .529; p < .001). This high level of national investment in TVET, increasing
demonstrated statistical support for H1b and H1c. Thus, national investment in TVET may function to increase eco-
overall H1 was supported. nomic growth through employment.
8 SAGE Open

Table 2.  The Statistical Results for the Quadratic Effects of Path a, Path b, and Path c’s Relationships Hypothesized in the Study.

TVET→SI→EG TVET→EMP→EG TVET→Wage→EG TVET→MPI→EG

Model 2: Model 2:
Model 1 Model 2 Model 1: Model 2: Model 1: DV = EG Model 1: DV = EG
DV = SI DV = EG DV=EMP DV = EG DV = Wage (Path b and DV = MPI (Path b and
Variables (Path a) (Path b and c) (Path a) (Path b and c) (Path a) Path c) (Path a) Path c)
Sav 0.227 0.085 0.054 1.0957 0.303 .011 0.260 0.307
(0.039)*** (0.064) (0.057) (0.239)*** (0.048)*** (0.019) (0.051)*** (0.081)***
INF 0.039 0.15 0.218 0.142 –.107 .028 –0.144 0.109
(0.031) (0.047)** (0.044)*** (0.194) (0.038)** (0.014)† (0.039)** (0.056)†
IT –0.037 0.105 –0.049 0.1741 –.127 –.055 –0.162 0.032
(0.039) (0.059)† (0.051) (0.216) (0.048)** (0.018)** (0.050)* (0.070)
FDI 0.036 0.005 — — 0.098 .037 0.101 0.079
(0.031) (0.052) (0.041)* (0.015)* (0.044)* (0.064)
PCI — — — — –.226 .979 — —
(0.036)*** (0.014)***
MPI — — 0.718 –1.800 — — — —
(0.06)*** (0.308)***
SI — 0.986 — — — — — —
(0.089)***
SI × SI — –0.608 — — — — — —
(0.086)***
TVET 0 .243 –0.580 0.117 0.023 0.529 0.026 0.602 –0.003
(0.048)*** (0.079)*** (0.066)† (0.284) (0.060)*** (0.025) (0.063)*** (0.088)
TVET × TVET –0.030 0.125 — — –.168 –.024 –0.188 –0.003
(0.032) (0.050)* (0.039)*** (0.015) (0.042)*** (0.088)
EMP — — — 0.634 — — — —
(0.248)*
EMP × EMP — — — 0.313 — — — —
(0.163)†
  — —  
Wages — — — — — 0.144 — —
(0.022)***
Wage × Wage — — — — — 0.029 — —
(0.012)*
MPI — — — — — — — –0.342
(0.085)***
MPI × MPI — — — — — — — 0.066
(0.049)
R2 .355 .430 .541 .137 .596 .95 .736 .370

Note. Independent variable: TVET (National Investment in Technical and Vocational Education as percentage of GDP); mediating variable: SI = social
inclusion; EMP = employment rate; MPI = multidimensional poverty index; dependent variable: EG = economic growth; control variables: FDI = foreign
direct investment; IT = international trade; INF = inflation; Sav = national saving; PCI = per capita income; GDP = gross domestic product;
DV = dependent variable.

p < .10. *p < .05. **p < .01. ***p < .001.

However, the statistical results revealed that the instanta- the countries with the low, medium, or high level of national
neous indirect effect of TVET on economic growth through investment in TVET, increasing national investment in
wages was significant across different values of TVET (i.e., TVET may function to increase economic growth through
medium [mean], high [one standard deviation above the the wages.
mean], and low [one standard deviation below the mean]). Similarly, the statistical results revealed that the instanta-
Hence, H3b was supported. The interval estimates for instan- neous indirect effect of TVET on economic growth through
taneous indirect effects of TVET on economic growth multidimensional poverty index was significant across dif-
through wages across low (–0.7268), medium (0.2110), and ferent values of TVET (i.e., medium [mean], high [one stan-
high (1.1488) are given in Table 3. This indicates that among dard deviation above the mean], and low [one standard
Asadullah 9

Table 3.  Bootstrapping Results for Instantaneous Indirect Effects of TVET on EG Through Social Inclusion (EMP, Wage, and Poverty)
Using Quadratic Paths Across Different Values of TVET Spending.

95% bootstrapping CI
Instantaneous indirect effects of TVET Instantaneous values
expenditure of TVET θ Upper bound Lower bound Interpretation
1.  Through social inclusion: Low(–1 SD) = −0.727 0.3546 0.1121 0.8000 Significant
TVET→SI→EG Medium (M) = 0.211 0.2165 0.1259 0.3417 Significant
High (+1 SD) = 1.149 0.1231 0.0630 0.2266 Significant
2.  Through employment: Low (–1 SD) = −0.727 0.0696 0.003 0.185 Significant
TVET→EMP→EG Medium (M) = 0.211 0.0776 0.003 0.199 Significant
High (+1 SD) = 1.149 0.0856 0.0009 0.217 Significant
3.  Through Wages: Low(–1 SD) = −0.727 0.067 0.313 0.121 Significant
TVETW→age→EG Medium (M) = 0.211 0.041 0.218 0.066 Significant
High (+1 SD) = 1.149 0.021 0.045 0.047 Significant
4.  Through multidimensional poverty index: Low(–1 SD) = −0.727 –0.354 –0.547 –0.172 Significant
TVET→MPI→EG Medium (M) = 0.211 –0.166 –0.284 –0.061 Significant
High (+1 SD) = 1.149 –0.047 –0.129 –0.009 Significant

Note. TVET = national investment in technical and vocational education as percentage of GDP; EG = economic growth; EMP = employment rate;
SI = social inclusion; MPI = multidimensional poverty index; GDP = gross domestic product.

deviation below the mean]). Hence, H3c was also supported. through which higher economic outcomes of higher educa-
The interval estimates for instantaneous indirect effects of tion spending may be guaranteed. This study has shown
TVET on economic growth through multidimensional pov- empirical support for a possible social mechanism through
erty index across low (–0.7268), medium (0.2110), and high which the economic effects of national educational invest-
(1.1488) are given in Table 3. There is evidence that among ment can be obtained. Particularly, utilizing the notion of
the countries with the low, medium, or high level of national human capital theory, this study has provided clear empirical
investment in TVET, increasing national investment in evidence for the social inclusion as a mechanism through
TVET may function to increase economic growth through which the national investment in TVET is linked to the eco-
multidimensional poverty index. nomic growth in 21 Schengen states.
According to the statistical analysis, 23% increase in
social inclusion was observed as a result of increase in
Discussion national TVET expenditure. Whereas, individually, 12%
This study has analyzed a socioeconomic mechanism to increase in employment, 53% increase in wages, and 60%
explain how the national investment TVET has contributed increase in poverty ratings of a country was found to be a
to the economic growth of 21 European economies. The function of an increase in national spending in TVET. Thus,
author has provided an empirical evidence for the embedded this study demonstrates that by increasing national spending
assumption of the literature in human capital regarding on TVET, the countries are capable of achieving an increase
national investment in technical and vocation education, in the employment, wages, and their poverty ratings.
social inclusion and economic growth. The author developed Particularly, these findings are consistent with the existing
a competing set of theoretically rooted hypotheses in the lit- empirical studies, which demonstrate the positive associa-
erature of human capital that has highlighted the role of tion between vocational qualifications and employment in
TVET in social and economic gains of a nation. In brief, our different European economies including England (McIntosh
analysis of the sample derived from 21 European states pro- & Garrett, 2009), Portugal (Budría & Telhado-Pereira, 2009),
vided empirical support for the hypotheses theoretically and Germany (European Centre for the Development of
based in human capital theory. Vocational Training (Cedefop), 2009). A recent empirical
The governments tend to convey a public message of their evidence from Senegal also pointed toward increased
concern for social and economic responsibility by taking employment as a decrease in the gap between the demand
decisions of developing national human resources through and supply of high-skilled labor resulting from educational
educational investment. There is a prevailing perception that reforms (Boccanfuso, Larouche, & Trandafir, 2015). These
a higher national spending on education may have signifi- findings are consistent with the notion of human capital the-
cant and higher direct effects on national-level economic ory that developing skills of people through education and
outcomes. However, this might not be a necessary case. This training enhances their employability (Docherty et al., 2002;
requires the policy makers to identify the mechanisms Handel et  al., 2016; McGuinness et  al., 2017), which
10 SAGE Open

represents their social status and achievement (Lawy & this finding supports the view that rather than relying on a
Biesta, 2006; Lister, 1997) and their social inclusion sole perspective, the combined micro and macro perspec-
(Vandekinderen et al., 2018). The positive association found tives is more appropriate to use the notion of human capital
between TVET expenditure and wages is also consistent theory for explaining the mechanism through which human
with existing empirical studies, which reported the signifi- capital development initiatives contribute to the national
cant contribution of TVET in enhancing individual’s skill economic gains.
(Jothilakshmi et al., 2009), income (Benhabib & Spiegel, This study found that the indirect effects of TVET on eco-
1994; Mahmud et al., 2014; Mankiw, Romer, & Weil, 1992), nomic growth through social inclusion are positive and sig-
and economic well-being (Mahmud et al., 2007). nificant at low, medium, and high values of TVET, yet, the
Second, 13% increase in the economic growth of a coun- values are decreasing from low to high, as highlighted in
try accounted for an increase in social inclusion. This finding Table 3. A further examination of the indirect effects through
represents a significant economic gain for the countries, each indicator of the social inclusion, separately, demon-
which ensure a high level of social inclusion as compared strated that this downward trend in the indirect effects across
with the countries with less social inclusion. This finding is different values of TVET existed due to the wages. This find-
consistent with the view that an equitable social environment ing was surprising for the researchers, which calls for the
contributes positively to the economic situation (Ali et al., future research to investigate the rationale behind such a
2018). While isolating the effects of social inclusion index negative trend in indirect effects of the wages. In a recent
variables, the study found that 63% increase in economic study, Gehrke and Hartwig (2018) found that public welfare
growth was resulting from employment and 14% increase programs are only preferable if the wages are low. Should
was resulting from the wage increase. This represents that this finding offer similar conclusion that TVET expenditure
countries with employment level and wage rate have the is preferable only if the wages are below minimum? Another
advantage of higher economic growth over the countries possible explanation may be provided regarding this declin-
with lower employment and wages. Similarly, the economies ing mediating effect of wages between TVET expenditure
with good indexing of in multiple poverty dimension experi- and economic growth. As TVET expenditure is primarily
ence a 14% increase in their economic growth. Thus, overall, emphasized on developing the skills and knowledge of the
the social inclusion index and its individual dimensions dem- people to find some employment opportunity while wage
onstrate an increase in economic growth of the economies. increase may be the second priority of the states because the
Thus, the economic gains of the countries addressing basic states are more likely to invest in TVET in the time of higher
economic reforms, which allow them for a socially inclusive unemployment. Thus, a higher TVET expenditure may rep-
economy based on employment opportunities, higher wages, resent a higher unemployment and vice versa. The future
and low poverty ratio may be higher than the countries pay- research may also develop an understanding of the factors
ing less attention to the social inclusion reforms. This also underlying the weaker indirect effect at higher TVET
represents that the countries, which do not emphasize social expenditure.
inclusion policies may not bypass economic advantage. In This study used data set related to 21 OECD member
the absence of social inclusion policies with less employ- countries for 15 years (2000-2014). Unfortunately, the statis-
ment and fewer wage opportunities and high poverty, the tics for some of the variables used in the current study for the
people may perceive the investment in TVET as a mean of years 2015-2018 were unavailable or partially available,
exploitation on behalf of the policy makers and may react which can be incorporated in future studies to replicate the
negatively to such national-level expenditures. findings. Similarly, this study used SPSS macro for investi-
The significant indirect effect of the national TVET gating quadratic indirect effects, which relies on OLS regres-
expenditure in economic growth through social inclusion sion. However, the future research can replicate the findings
indicators (employment wage and multidimensional poverty using other estimation techniques such as Quantile regres-
ratings) found in the current study offers theoretical contri- sion or Proc quantreg using statistical software other than
bution to the existing literature on economic growth. This SPSS.
finding has introduced social inclusion as a mediating mech-
anism through which human capital contributes to the eco-
Conclusion
nomic growth. This finding supports the recent movement of
social investment/welfare-state (Busemeyer et al., 2018; TVET seems to be an effective national investment decision
Garritzmann et al., 2018) reforms in different OECD econo- for the European economies following the paradigm of wel-
mies to develop and efficiently utilizing human capital to fare-state/social-state due to various reasons. First, investing
achieve economic growth through social inclusion (Morel, in TVET enhances social inclusion of the individuals due to
Palier, & Palme, 2013). This finding also supports the notion its potential for enhancing employment, earnings, and the
of human capital theory to gain economic excellence through multidimensional poverty rating of an economy. Second, the
key social inclusion indicators including employability, social inclusion indicators positively contribute to the eco-
earning (Nilsson, 2010), and poverty elimination. Particularly, nomic growth of an economy. TVET expenditure allows the
Asadullah 11

states to obtain economic growth through social inclusion, Bennett, L. (2002). Using empowerment and social inclusion for
particularly, the employment, earnings, and poverty elimina- pro-poor growth: A theory of social change (Working Draft of
tion. The existing research on human capital development Background Paper for the Social Development Strategy Paper).
does not discuss the indirect effect of TVET expenditure on Washington, DC: World Bank.
Biesta, G. (2006). What’s the point of lifelong learning if lifelong
economic growth through social inclusion. The researchers
learning has no point? On the democratic deficit of policies for
and the policy makers may benefit from the empirical evi-
lifelong learning. European Educational Research Journal, 5,
dence about the improved understanding of the effectiveness 169-180.
of the human capital initiatives in the OECD member states Blaug, M. (1976). The empirical status of human capital theory: A
of European Union. Particularly, the human capital theory slightly jaundiced survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 14,
may be contextualized, and the scope of human capital devel- 827-855.
opment initiatives in the OECD countries may be reconceptu- Boccanfuso, D., Larouche, A., & Trandafir, M. (2015). Quality
alized to encompass national human capital development of higher education and the labor market in developing coun-
decisions including TVET and social inclusion. tries: Evidence from an education reform in Senegal. World
Development, 74, 412-424.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests Bohne, C., Eicker, F., & Haseloff, G. (2017). Competence-based
vocational education and training (VET) An approach of
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect shaping and networking. European Journal of Training and
to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. Development, 41, 28-38.
Budría, S., & Telhado-Pereira, P. (2009). The contribution of voca-
Funding tional training to employment, job-related skills and productiv-
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, author- ity: Evidence from Madeira. International Journal of Training
ship, and/or publication of this article. and Development, 13, 53-72.
Busemeyer, M. R., de la Porte, C., Garritzmann, J. L., & Pavolini,
E. (2018). The future of the social investment state: Politics,
Note
policies, and outcomes. Journal of European Public Policy, 25,
1. https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2017/09/what-to-know%20 801-809.
about-work-jobs-human-capital-2017. Cairo, I., & Cajner, T. (2017). Human capital and unemployment
dynamics: Why more educated workers enjoy greater employ-
References ment stability. The Economic Journal, 128, 652-682.
Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (2006). Joseph Schumpeter lecture appro- Canton, E. (2007). Social returns to education: Macro-evidence. De
priate growth policy: A unifying framework. Journal of the Economist, 155, 449-468.
European Economic Association, 4, 269-314. CEPAL, N. (2013). The employment situation in Latin America
Alcock, P. (1997). Understanding poverty. New York, NY: and the Caribbean: Advances and challenges in measuring
Macmillan International Higher Education. decent work. Santiago, Chile: Economic Commission for Latin
Ali, M., Egbetokun, A., & Memon, M. H. (2018). Human capital, America and the Caribbean.
social capabilities and economic growth. Economies, 6(1), Cerna, L. (2018). European high-skilled migration policy. In M. Czaika
Article 2. (Ed.), High-skilled migration: Drivers and policies (p. 87). Oxford
Allen, W., Anderson, B., Van Hear, N., Sumption, M., Düvell, F., University Press.
Hough, J., . . . Walker, S. (2018). Who counts in crises? The Cobo, C., Zucchetti, A., & Rivas, A. (2011). Learning for all:
new geopolitics of international migration and refugee gover- Investing in people’s knowledge and skills to promote develop-
nance. Geopolitics, 23, 217-243. ment—World Bank Group education strategy 2020 (Educación:
Almendarez, L. (2013). Human capital theory: Implications for edu- Recomendaciones de política para la era digital). Washington,
cational development in Belize and the Caribbean. Caribbean DC: World Bank.
Quarterly, 59, 21-33. Comyn, P., & Barnaart, A. (2010). TVET reform in Chongqing:
Angel-Urdinola, D. F., & Gukovas, R. M. (2018). A skills-based Big steps on a long march. Research in Post-Compulsory
human capital framework to understand the phenomenon of youth Education, 15, 49-65.
economic disengagement. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Dean, H. (2003). Re-conceptualising welfare-to-work for people
Antolin, P. P., & Stewart, F. (2009). Private pensions and policy with multiple problems and needs. Journal of Social Policy,
responses to the financial and economic crisis. OECD Journal: 32, 441-459.
Financial Market Trends, 2009, 127. Dearden, A. L., Smith, P. J., Shin, D. Y., Reis, N., Derby, B., &
Asadullah, M. A., & Zafar, U. A. (2018). Social-economic contri- O’Brien, P. (2005). A low curing temperature silver ink for
bution of vocational education and training: An evidence from use in ink-jet printing and subsequent production of conductive
OECD countries. Industrial and Commercial Training, 50, tracks. Macromolecular Rapid Communications, 26, 315-318.
172-184. Docherty, P., Forslin, J., & Shani, A. B. (Eds.). (2002). Creating
Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in human capital: A theoretical sustainable work systems: Emerging perspectives and prac-
analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5, Pt. 2), 9-49. tice. London, England: Psychology Press.
Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1994). The role of human capital in Eugster, B. (2018). Immigrants and poverty, and conditionality of
economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country immigrants’ social rights. Journal of European Social Policy,
data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34, 143-173. 28, 452-470. doi:10.1177/0958928717753580.
12 SAGE Open

European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training Leuven, E., & Oosterbeek, H. (2011). Overeducation and mis-
(Cedefop). (2009). Modernising vocational education and match in the labor market. In E. A. Hanushek, S. J. Machin, &
training: Fourth report on vocational education and train- Woessmann L (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education
ing research in Europe: Executive summary. Luxembourg: (Vol. 4, pp. 283-326). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier.
Publications Office of the European Union. Lister, R. (2000). Strategies for social inclusion: Promoting social
Fleckenstein, T., & Lee, S. C. (2018). Caught up in the past? Social cohesion or social justice. In S. Angus & A. Peter (Eds.), Social
inclusion, skills, and vocational education and training policy inclusion: Possibilities and tensions (pp. 37-54). Basingstoke,
in England. Journal of Education and Work, 31, 109-124. UK: Palgrave Macmillan.
Fritz, M. S., & MacKinnon, D. P. (2007). Required sample size to López-Fogués, A. (2012). The discourses of vocational education
detect the mediated effect. Psychological Science, 18, 233-239. and training: A developmental response from a European
Gale, T., & Molla, T. (2015). Social justice intents in policy: An perspective. European Educational Research Journal, 11,
analysis of capability for and through education. Journal of 558-569.
Education Policy, 30, 810-830. López-Fogués, A. (2018). Universities and global human devel-
Garritzmann, J. L., Busemeyer, M. R., & Neimanns, E. (2018). opment: Theoretical and empirical insights for social change.
Public demand for social investment: New supporting coali- Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 19, 269-270.
tions for welfare state reform in Western Europe? Journal of Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988a). On the mechanics of economic develop-
European Public Policy, 25, 844-861. ment. Econometric Society Monographs, 29, 61-70.
Gehrke, E., & Hartwig, R. (2018). Productive effects of public Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988b). On the mechanics of economic develop-
works programs: What do we know? What should we know? ment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3-42.
World Development, 107, 111-124. MacKinnon, D. P., Lockwood, C. M., & Williams, J. (2004).
Gowlett, C. (2012). Injurious assumptions: Butler, subjectification Confidence limits for the indirect effect: Distribution of the
and gen(d)erational poverty. International Journal of Inclusive product and resampling methods. Multivariate Behavioral
Education, 16, 885-900. Research, 39, 99-128.
Hadawi, A., & Crabbe, M. J. C. (2018). Developing a mission for Maclean, R. (2017). Education and skills for inclusive growth,
further education: Changing culture using non-financial and green jobs and the greening of economies in Asia—Case
intangible value. Research in Post-Compulsory Education, 23, study summaries of India, Indonesia, Sri Lanka and Viet Nam.
118-137. Mandaluyong, Philippines: Asian Development Bank.
Hagenaars, A. J. (2017). The definition and measurement of pov- Mahmud, K. T., Mohamed, Z. A., Ismail, M. M., Shamsudin, M.
erty. In L. Osberg (Ed.), Economic inequality and poverty: N., & Hilton, D. (2007). Perception and attitude of microcredit
International perspectives (pp. 148-170). London, England: borrowers towards effectiveness of agricultural diversification
Routledge. and intensification project in Bangladesh. Asia-Pacific Journal
Handel, M. J., Valerio, A., & Sánchez Puerta, M. L. (2016). of Rural Development, 17, 67-83.
Accounting for mismatch in low-and middle-income countries: Mahmud, K. T., Parvez, A., Hilton, D., Kabir, G. S., & Wahid, I.
Measurement, magnitudes, and explanations. Washington, S. (2014). The role of training in reducing poverty: The case
DC: The World Bank. of agricultural workers receiving microcredit in Bangladesh.
Hanushek, E. A., & Woessmann, L. (2008). The role of cogni- International Journal of Training and Development, 18,
tive skills in economic development. Journal of Economic 282-290.
Literature, 46, 607-668. Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution
Hayes, A. F., & Preacher, K. J. (2010). Quantifying and testing to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of
indirect effects in simple mediation models when the constitu- Economics, 107, 407-437.
ent paths are nonlinear. Multivariate Behavioral Research, 45, Marginson, S. (2019). Limitations of human capital theory. Studies
627-660. in Higher Education, 44, 287-301.
Jayasinghe, M. (2016). The operational and signaling benefits of McGrath, S., & Lugg, R. (2012). Knowing and doing vocational
voluntary labor code adoption: Reconceptualizing the scope education and training reform: Evidence, learning and the pol-
of human resource management in emerging economies. icy process. International Journal of Educational Development,
Academy of Management Journal, 59, 658-677. 32, 696-708.
Jothilakshmi, M., Krishnaraj, R., & Sudeepkumar, N. K. (2009). McGuinness, S., Pouliakas, K., & Redmond, P. (2017). How use-
Empowering the members of women SHGs in livestock farm- ful is the concept of skills mismatch? (No. 10786). Bonn,
ing through need-based trainings. Asia-Pacific Journal of Germany: Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).
Rural Development, 19, 17-30. McIntosh, S., & Garrett, R. (2009). The economic value of interme-
Kijima, Y., Ito, Y., & Otsuka, K. (2012). Assessing the impact of diate vocational education and qualifications. Retrieved from
training on lowland rice productivity in an African setting: https://dera.ioe.ac.uk/id/eprint/11087
Evidence from Uganda. World Development, 40, 1610-1618. Mercer, M. (2014). Donor policies, practices and investment pri-
Kwon, H. J., & Kim, D. C. (2009). Local incentive effect of crite- orities in support of education, and post-2015 prospects: A
rion change in the earning test in 2006. Journal of Insurance review. International Journal of Educational Development,
Studies, 20, 161-199. 39, 23-31.
Lawy, R., & Biesta, G. (2006). Citizenship-as-practice: The educa- Mihret Dessie, W., & Shumetie Ademe, A. (2017). Training for
tional implications of an inclusive and relational understand- creativity and innovation in small enterprises in Ethiopia.
ing of citizenship. British Journal of Educational Studies, 54, International Journal of Training and Development, 21,
34-50. 224-234.
Asadullah 13

Mirick, R. G. (2016). Reactance theory: A model for instructor Rosholm, M., Nielsen, H. S., & Dabalen, A. (2007). Evaluation
communication in the classroom. Scholarship of Teaching and of training in African enterprises. Journal of Development
Learning in Psychology, 2, 219-229. Economics, 84, 310-329.
Morel, N., Palier, B., & Palme, J. (2012). Beyond the welfare Schultz, T. W. (1960). Capital formation by education. Journal of
state as we knew it. In N. Morel, B. Palier, & J. Palme (Eds.), Political Economy, 68, 571-583.
Towards a social investment welfare state (pp. 1-30). Great Schultz, T. W. (1961). Investment in human capital. The American
Britain: The Policy Press c/o Oxford University Press. Economic Review, 51, 1-17.
Morel, N., Palier, B., & Palme, J. (2013). The social investment Sen, A. (1999). On ethics and economics. Oxford, UK: OUP
welfare state in Europe, 1990s and 2000s: Economic ideas and Catalogue, Oxford University Press.
social policies (Governance and Globalization Working Paper Simmons, R., & Thompson, R. (2013). Reclaiming the disen-
Series 33). gaged: Critical perspectives on young people not in educa-
Nahapiet, J. (2011). A social perspective: Exploring the links tion, employment or training. Research in Post-Compulsory
between human capital and social capital. In A. Burton-Jones Education, 18(1-2), 1-11.
& J.-C. Spender (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of human capital Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic
(pp. 71-95). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65-94.
Nelson, R. R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). Distribution of income and wealth among indi-
technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American viduals. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society,
Economic Review, 56, 69-75. 37, 382-397.
Niemann, A., & Zaun, N. (2018). EU refugee policies and poli- Sunde, U., & Vischer, T. (2015). Human capital and growth:
tics in times of crisis: Theoretical and empirical perspectives. Specification matters. Economica, 82, 368-390.
JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 56, 3-22. Tanaka, M. (2018). Changing demand for general skills, techno-
Nilsson, A. (2010). Vocational education and training—An engine for logical uncertainty, and economic growth (Osaka University
economic growth and a vehicle for social inclusion? International Discussion Papers in Economics and Business, Vol. 18,
Journal of Training and Development, 14, 251-272. 1-40). Osaka, Japan: Graduate School of Economics and
Olaniyan, D. A., & Okemakinde, T. (2008). Human capital theory: Osaka School of International Public Policy.
Implications for educational development. Pakistan Journal of Vandekinderen, C., Roets, G., Van Keer, H., & Roose, R. (2018).
Social Sciences, 5, 479-483. Tackling social inequality and exclusion in education: From
Papa, M. (2018). Social inequalities in a time of economic crisis human capital to capabilities. International Journal of Inclusive
in Greece. International Journal of Social Science Research, Education, 22, 1-20.
6, 61-75. Vanhove, N. (2017). The economics of tourism destinations: Theory
Pilz, M. (2012). International comparative research into voca- and practice. London, England: Routledge.
tional training: Methods and approaches. In M. Pilz (Ed.), Walker, M. (2012). A capital or capabilities education narrative in
The future of vocational education and training in a chang- a world of staggering inequalities? International Journal of
ing world (pp. 561-588). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS Verlag für Educational Development, 32, 384-393.
Sozialwissenschaften. Wedchayanon, N., & Chorkaew, S. (2014). The sufficiency econ-
Quintini, G. (2011). Right for the job: Over-qualified or under- omy and people-centered development: The case of the Huay
skilled? (OECD Social, Employment, and Migration Working Sai Royal Development Project in Thailand. European Journal
Papers 120). Paris, France: Organisation for Economic of Training and Development, 38, 822-844.
Co-operation and Development. Zarsky, L., & Gallagher, K. P. (2012). No miracle drug: Foreign
Regmi, P., Deland, T. S., Steibel, J. P., Robison, C. I., Haut, R. C., direct investment and sustainable development. In L. Zarsky
Orth, M. W., & Karcher, D. M. (2015). Effect of rearing environ- (Ed.), International investment for sustainable development
ment on bone growth of pullets. Poultry Science, 94, 502-511. (pp. 26-58). London, England: Routledge.
Ringen, K., Seegal, J., & England, A. (1995). Safety and health in
the construction industry. Annual Review of Public Health, 16,
165-188. Author Biographies
Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Muhammad Ali Asadullah is serving as an assistant professor of
Political Economy, 98(5, Pt. 2), S71-S102. Human Resource Management (HRM) at Emirates College of
Rose, H., Daiches, A., & Potier, J. (2012). Meaning of social inclusion Technology, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates. He obtained his
to young people not in employment, education or training. Journal PhD (HRM) in 2012 from Aix-Marseille University, Aix-en-
of Community & Applied Social Psychology, 22, 256-268. Provence, France.

You might also like