You are on page 1of 17

Original Research

SAGE Open
October-December 2023: 1–17
Ó The Author(s) 2023
The Happiness-Economic Well-Being DOI: 10.1177/21582440231199659
journals.sagepub.com/home/sgo
Nexus: New Insights From Global Panel
Data

Yok-Yong Lee1 and Kim-Leng Goh1

Abstract
This paper explores whether happiness-led growth policies implemented in some countries are viable for achieving better
economic well-being proxied by GDP per capita using a panel dataset covering 104 countries from 2006 to 2018. While past
studies showed that economic growth promotes happiness, this paper applied the panel Granger causality test to show that
GDP per capita is also determined by happiness. Accordingly, the pooled ordinary least squares, random-effects model,
fixed-effects model, and two-step generalized method of moments were employed to estimate the effect of changes in happi-
ness on economic growth. The empirical results suggest that economic growth of 1% to 3% can be obtained by increasing
happiness. The positive effect of happiness is about four times greater in developed countries than in developing countries.
This paper reveals that happiness should be included in conventional economic growth models to achieve a holistic approach
in designing development policies.

Keywords
economic growth, economic well-being, generalized method of moments (GMM), Granger causality, happiness

Introduction Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) associated with


169 targets and 232 indicators (United Nations, 2015).
The global financial crisis in 2007 to 2008 has led to To date, 193 countries worldwide have agreed and
reconsider the adequacy of adopting gross domestic adopted the SDGs framework that captures economic,
product (GDP) as an all-encompassing yardstick of eco- social, and environmental sustainability. Therefore, the
nomic performance and societal progress (Pillay, 2020). equilibrium between economic, social, and environmen-
This resulted in the establishment the ‘‘Commission on tal sustainability is focal to sustainable development
the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social (Aksoy & Bayram Arlı, 2020). Following this, the notion
Progress’’ led by the Nobel laureates Joseph Stiglitz and of ‘‘Economy of Well-Being’’ that underscores the
Amartya Sen and facilitated by Jean-Paul Fitoussi. They mutually reinforcing relationship between well-being and
have prompted efforts to develop metrics that reflect the economic growth is proposed by Llena-Nozal et al.
essence of the good life (E. Stiglitz et al., 2009). Stiglitz-
(2019). Nevertheless, the ‘‘Economy of Well-Being’’ does
Sen-Fitoussi report is a significant ‘‘Beyond GDP’’ sti-
not deny the importance of GDP as one of the relevant
mulus (J. Stiglitz et al., 2018). It encourages complement-
measures of economic performance and societal prog-
ing growth-oriented policies with happiness (Noll, 2011).
ress. Instead, the ‘‘Economy of Well-Being’’ policy needs
Happiness is a societal progress indicator that ensures
to be guided by a broader metric that can capture the
economic growth does not exceed the limit of social sus-
complexity of the relationship between economic growth
tainability and planetary boundaries (Masaki, 2022;
Rogers et al., 2012).
1
Apart from that, the ‘‘Beyond GDP’’ agenda has been University of Malaya, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia
integrated into the global policy agenda, as demon-
Corresponding Author:
strated by the agenda of the United Nations on Kim-Leng Goh, Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Malaya,
‘‘Transforming Our World: The 2030 Agenda for Kuala Lumpur 50603, Malaysia.
Sustainable Development.’’ It consists of the 17 Email: klgoh@um.edu.my

Creative Commons CC BY: This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License
(https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/) which permits any use, reproduction and distribution of
the work without further permission provided the original work is attributed as specified on the SAGE and Open Access pages
(https://us.sagepub.com/en-us/nam/open-access-at-sage).
2 SAGE Open

and societal progress and the channels through which Additionally, according to the Sustainable Development
they are connected. Report 2021, subjective well-being is one of the metrics
The ‘‘Economy of Well-Being’’ proponents pointed of SDG 3 on ‘‘Good Health and Well-Being’’ (Sachs
out that growth-oriented policies that solely rely on et al., 2021). Hence, implementing happiness-led growth
GDP are associated with three major constraints. First, policies contribute to sustainable economic growth and
‘‘the welfare of a nation can be scarcely inferred from a sustainable development. Moreover, happiness-led
measurement of a national income (Kuznets, 1934, p. growth policies enable comprehensive evaluations of the
7).’’ An economy-centrism GDP captures the tangible impact of policies on people’s conditions and
material living standards but does not capture social experiences.
sustainability, such as happiness and social inclusion Since ‘‘growth, prosperity, and inclusion are comple-
(Kalimeris et al., 2020; Wang, 2015). Meanwhile, mentary, not contradictory, goals for meaningful eco-
human-centrism happiness captures tangible and intan- nomic development’’ (Liu, 2016, p. 8), economic growth
gible dimensions that matter to people, including mate- should not come at the expense of social inclusion and
rial living standards, education, environment, health, well-being. In other words, economic growth alone is not
insecurity, institutional quality, jobs, and social sufficient for promoting overall well-being and happi-
connections. ness. On the other hand, Figure 1 shows a strong associ-
Second, ‘‘If ever there was a controversial icon from ation between happiness (using life ladder obtained from
the statistics world, GDP is it. It measures income, but World Happiness Report as a measure) and real GDP
not equality, it measures growth, but not destruction, per capita (in natural logarithm) for 104 countries.
and it ignores values like social cohesion and the envi- Happiness explains 66.71% of the variation in real GDP
ronment. Yet, governments, businesses and probably per capita. Kenny (1999) suggested a bidirectional rela-
most people swear by it (OECD Observer, 2004).’’ GDP tionship between happiness and economic growth is
sidesteps the social costs of income disparity and the plausible. Kenny (1999, p. 19) argued further that ‘‘if
benefits from informal economic activities. Besides, there is any causal relationship in rich countries, it
GDP provides false information by capturing the recon- appears to run from happiness to growth, not vice-
struction activities but ignoring the corresponding eco- versa.’’ While it may be disputed that higher income pro-
nomic destruction. Moreover, social cohesion involving motes happiness, happiness may be positively associated
cooperation, social capital, and trust between individuals with increased income. However, this opinion remains to
is not factored into GDP. Also, the changes in climate, be tested.
depletion of environmental assets or natural resources, Several developments highlight the growing attention
and loss of biodiversity are overlooked in GDP. to happiness in development planning (Exton &
Third, ‘‘distinctions must be kept in mind between Shinwell, 2018). In 2004, Australia developed a well-
quantity and quality of growth, between its costs and being framework incorporating five well-being elements.
return, and between the short and long term. Goals for The Prime Minister of the United Kingdom decided to
more growth should specify more growth of what and include subjective well-being as an input to development
for what (Kuznets, 1934, p. 7).’’ Three commonly used policies from 2010 onward (Diener et al., 2015). The
approaches to quantify GDP (for instance, expenditures, United Nations Sustainable Development Solutions
income, and production approaches) and various mea- Network (UNSDSN) published the first World
sures of GDP (such as GDP growth, GDP per capita, Happiness Report in 2012. In 2013, the OECD distribu-
and GDP rankings) downplay the vital role of happiness ted guidelines on implementing global measures of sub-
as social capital to achieve sustainable development. jective well-being (Diener et al., 2015). Effective April
However, GDP are used not only as economic health 2015, the Government of France submitted an annual
indicators but also as societal development and welfare report on economic, social, and environmental condi-
indicator (Boo et al., 2016). tions to the Parliament (Exton & Shinwell, 2018). Since
Despite the foregoing omissions of GDP, minimal 2016, the Government of Italy has annually reported 12
monetization is necessary for a high level of happiness indicators grounded on the ‘‘measures of equitable and
(Miñarro et al., 2021). Therefore, Target 8.1 under the sustainable well-being’’ to the Parliament. In 2017, the
Sustainable Development Goal (SDG) 8 on ‘‘decent Swedish Ministry of Finance introduced new measures of
work and economic growth’’ is that, ‘‘Sustain per capita well-being complement to GDP in the Budget Bill. The
economic growth following national circumstances and, same year, the United Arab Emirates proposed incorpor-
in particular, at least 7 per cent gross domestic product ating happiness in policy-making by executing the
growth per annum in the least developed countries.’’ On National Program for Happiness and Positivity.
the other hand, happiness is a foundation for sustainable Scotland launched the new National Performance
economic growth (Llena-Nozal et al., 2019). Framework in 2018, focusing on national well-being,
Lee and Goh 3

Figure 1. Relationship between happiness and economic growth, 2018.


Source. Authors own work, data source World Development Indicators and World Happiness Report.
Note. A higher life ladder indicates a higher level of happiness.

mainly economic, environmental, health, and social Nevertheless, implementing happiness-led growth
facets (Wallace, 2019). On 30th May 2019, New Zealand policies is not without challenges. Hitherto, the vast
released the first well-being budget to promote happiness literature on fundamental determinants of economic
as the country’s national agenda (Anderson & Mossialos, growth is restricted to tangible dimensions, such as
2019). Recently, Iceland has suggested well-being initia- capital formation, entrepreneurship, financial devel-
tives because GDP is prone to underestimate the quality opment, labor force, natural resources, technology,
of life and sidestep inequality, which results in social and innovation (Paun et al., 2019). Nonetheless, it is
damage (Frijters & Krekel, 2021). observed that these fundamental determinants are
4 SAGE Open

inadequate to explain differences in economic growth 2011). Thus, happiness is not merely a function of posi-
across countries. Additionally, the literature regard- tive feelings but living a good life (Rasheed et al., 2011).
ing the effect of happiness on economic growth and Happiness is often used interchangeably with other
the economic consequences of happiness is under- comparable terms, such as life satisfaction (Gonza &
explored (Kenny, 1999; Li & Lu, 2010; Llena-Nozal Burger, 2017), quality of life (Veenhoven, 2017), and
et al., 2019; Rasheed et al., 2011; Rasiah et al., 2019). well-being (Veenhoven, 2017). Nonetheless, the compa-
The primary reason for this limited literature is that rable terms can be clearly distinguished from one
conventional economic growth models do not incor- another. Broadly, well-being is an umbrella term cover-
porate happiness as an explanatory variable of eco- ing: (1) objective well-being (Voukelatou et al., 2021),
nomic growth (Rasiah et al., 2019). Therefore, with (2) subjective well-being (Chen et al., 2013), and (3)
more countries taking happiness into account when psychological well-being (Chen et al., 2013). Objective
devising policies, it becomes critically essential to well-being is external well-being, which evolves from
thoroughly examine the effect of happiness on eco- one’s evaluation of human society (Alatartseva &
nomic growth, and not just from economic growth to Barysheva, 2015). It reflects people’s material living
happiness, as done by many past studies. conditions and the quality of their lives (Voukelatou
This paper contributes to the literature in four-fold. et al., 2021).
First, it sheds light on happiness’s role in advancing eco- On a separate note, subjective well-being and psycho-
nomic growth. If there is clear evidence that happiness logical well-being are internal well-being (Alatartseva &
spurs economic growth significantly, policymakers Barysheva, 2015). Internal well-being is interpreted as
should propose measures that improve happiness. human spiritual well-being associated with one’s per-
Second, the newly developed panel Granger Causality sonal characters and features (Alatartseva & Barysheva,
test by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) is adopted to show 2015). Subjective well-being is happiness’s scientific term
that while economic growth leads to a higher level of or synonym (Yang & Srinivasan, 2016). Happiness refers
happiness as commonly reported in the literature, the closely to hedonism, so subjective well-being is also
causal relationship is not one way, but a feedback rela- synonymous with ‘‘hedonic well-being’’ (Chen et al.,
tionship exists between the two variables. Third, consid- 2013) or self-reported happiness.
ering the bidirectional relationship between happiness Subjective well-being encompasses of an affective
and economic growth, this paper applied the generalized component and a cognitive component (Gata ulinas &
method of moments (GMM) to deal with endogeneity Banceviča, 2014). The affective component is experiential
and simultaneity biases. Fourth, this paper includes a in nature, whereby pleasure is a feeling. The cognitive
comprehensive sample of countries worldwide to the component involves rational evaluative assessment of
extent of data available. lives as a whole, by which pleasure is an attitude (van
This paper comprises five sections. After this introduc- Hoorn et al., 2010). The cognitive component of subjec-
tory section, a literature review is conducted in Section 2. tive well-being is equivalent to life satisfaction (Lucas &
Section 3 includes the empirical model, description of Diener, 2008). On the other hand, psychological well-
data and econometric methods. The discussions of the being consists of six dimensions: (1) autonomy, (2) envi-
empirical results are provided in Section 4. Finally, ronmental mastery, (3) personal growth, (4) positive rela-
Section 5 concludes the study by providing policy recom- tions with others, (5) purpose in life, and (6) self-
mendations and suggestions for future research. acceptance (Ryff & Singer, 2008).
In tandem with more governments’ concern regarding
happiness, various measures of happiness are made
Literature Review known, including Cantril’s Self-Anchoring Ladder (also
known as the Cantril Ladder of Life), Gross National
Concept of Happiness Happiness, Quality of Life Index, Satisfaction with Life
Since 1794, public happiness (also known as the ‘‘pub- Scale, Positive and Negative Affect Schedule, Personal
blica felicita’’) has been the ultimate goal in economics, Well-Being Index, Subjective Happiness Scale, Happy
as pointed out by the Italian philosopher, Ludovico Planet Index, Legatum Prosperity Index,
Antonio Muratori (Rasheed et al., 2011). Generally, Environmentally Responsible Happy Nation Index,
happiness is defined as the subjective enjoyment of one’s Social Progress Index, etc. The development of globally
life as a whole or overall ‘‘life satisfaction’’ (Veenhoven, comparable data on happiness has contributed to the
2017). It is the sense of contentment and gratification in possibility of conducting in-depth research into the rela-
all facets of life (Rasheed et al., 2011). It is also a state of tionship between happiness and economic growth
mental health associated with harmony, free from anxi- (Mikucka et al., 2017). Figure 2 illustrates the concept of
ety and other emotional disturbance (Rasheed et al., happiness.
Lee and Goh 5

Figure 2. Concept of happiness.


Source. Authors own work.

Relationship Between Happiness and Economic condition for happiness but economic growth is not a
Growth sufficient condition for happiness. It was noted that in
developed countries, the marginal utility of absolute
Much of the literature has mainly focused on the impact
income is less significant than that of relative income. He
of economic growth on happiness, and the empirical concluded that the economic growth model should take
findings are controversial. For instance, some findings happiness into account. Nevertheless, Kenny’s (1999)
demonstrated that higher economic growth raises happi- study used panel data for a small number of developed
ness (Veenhoven & Vergunst, 2014). However, the oppo- countries, limiting the generalizability of the findings.
nents disputed that economic growth is insignificant in In the same vein, Li and Lu (2010) studied the impact
improving happiness (Bartolini & Sarracino, 2015). of happiness on economic growth. They demonstrated a
Instead of focusing on the compatibility between hap- significant positive correlation between happiness (prox-
piness and economic growth, Mikucka et al. (2017)
ied by life satisfaction) and economic growth. On the
pointed out the importance of specific conditions that
other hand, they found a significant negative correlation
influence their relationship. The development status is
between sex ratio imbalance and happiness. According
one of these conditions, where the impact of economic
to them, happiness is strongly associated with the part-
growth on happiness diminishes as a country becomes
nership. Hence, an imbalanced sex ratio leads to diffi-
more affluent (Bartolini et al., 2017). The time span also
culty finding a life partner and is anticipated to result in
matters. The positive effect of economic growth on hap-
piness exists in the short run but vanishes over the long unhappiness. Accordingly, they used the sex imbalance
run due to the decline in the marginal utility of income ratio as an instrument of unhappiness in a Two-Stage
on happiness (Easterlin, 2005). Least Squares estimation. They found that happiness has
On the other hand, the literature on the effect of hap- a significantly positive causal effect on economic growth.
piness on economic growth is scarce and indicates a large They also employed Three-Stage Least Squares and con-
gap in the ‘‘Economy of Well-Being’’ (Kenny, 1999; Li & cluded that happiness lengthens life expectancy and
Lu, 2010; Llena-Nozal et al., 2019; Rasheed et al., 2011; attracts investment, which in turn spurs economic
Rasiah et al., 2019). Kenny (1999) is among the pioneer- growth. Li and Lu (2010) used sex ratio imbalance as a
ing researcher to raise the possibility of a bidirectional proxy for one aspect of happiness and life satisfaction as
relationship between happiness and economic growth. a broader measure of happiness. However, they did not
He surveys the empirical evidence in 10 developed coun- consider the dynamic feature of economic growth. While
tries over the period 1952 to 1989. Kenny found that the the study provides evidence for the positive relationship
relationship between happiness and economic growth is between happiness and economic growth, it does not
complex and not easily generalizable, with some coun- offer insights into the mechanisms through which this
tries exhibiting a positive relationship, some a negative relationship operates.
relationship, and some no relationship. He explained Using the panel data of 10 countries over the period
that a minimum level of economic growth is a necessary from 1961 to 2005, Rasheed et al. (2011) employed a
6 SAGE Open

Solow Growth Model incorporated with happiness to Nevertheless, there is a dearth of studies regarding the
observe the effect of happiness on economic growth. effect of happiness on economic growth. Many studies
They employed the Cobb-Douglas function-based total assume that economic growth is necessary to achieve
factor productivity (TFP) as a proxy for GDP growth happiness but neglect the possible economic growth
and three happiness indices which are ecological foot- channel through happiness. To fill the lacuna, the paper
print, life expectancy and life satisfaction. Ecological examines the existence of a feedback relationship
footprint has a significantly positive effect on TFP in between happiness and economic growth and further
four countries but a significantly negative effect in analyses happiness’s effect on economic growth.
another four countries. In comparison, life expectancy Limitations in past studies are the inclusion of a small
has a significant positive effect on TFP in two countries sample of countries or limited control variables. This
but a significant adverse effect in another country. Life paper fills in the gap by using a dataset that includes 104
satisfaction is not significant in all 10 countries except countries to enable robust conclusions to be drawn on
the USA. They summarized that happiness is an intangi- happiness as an engine of growth by controlling the
ble capital that explains TFP in the Solow Growth effects of a larger group of variables that potentially
Model. However, Rasheed et al. (2011) have not system- affect economic growth.
atically distinguished the impact of the different happi-
ness indices on TFP. Besides, the empirical findings from
the analysis of 10 developed countries cannot be general- Theoretical Framework
ized worldwide, especially in developing and transition Based on a critical and extensive literature review, the
economies. primary aim of this study is to examine the effect of
Accordingly, Llena-Nozal et al. (2019) devoted atten- changes in happiness on economic growth. The relation-
tion to the fact that well-being has gradually overtaken ship between happiness and economic growth can be
GDP as a measurement agenda for budgetary and pol- explained through economic and psychological theories.
icy-making. They developed the notion of the ‘‘economy The theoretical framework is grounded in the
of well-being.’’ They defined the ‘‘economy of well- Endogenous Growth Theory. Endogenous Growth
being’’ as the mutually reinforcing relationship between Theory posits that economic growth is not only driven
well-being and economic growth. In other words, none by external forces (particularly capital formation and
of the OECD countries can achieve moderate economic population growth), but also dependent on internal
growth without doing well on well-being. As such, effec- forces, such as human capital, innovation and knowledge
tively leveraging happiness for economic growth is creation.
imperative to achieve a sustainable economy of well- Coinciding with the Broaden-and-Build Theory of
being. They outlined the potential channels through Positive Emotions, happiness entails positive emotions
which well-being reinforces economic growth. These that spark a broad and expansive thought-action reper-
include educational attainment, skills, longevity, absence toire. Positive emotions fuel novel, flexible, creative
of physical and mental health problems, gender equality, thinking and problem-solving approaches (Fredrickson,
and social protection and redistribution. Nevertheless, 2001). Besides, positive emotions promote advancement
the bidirectional relationship between well-being and in personal growth by acquiring competence develop-
economic growth is established based on opinion rather ment (Newman et al., 2011) and catalyzes creativity and
than extensive evidence. innovation (Mao & Weathers, 2019). In this sense, hap-
Applying the dynamic panel estimation of piness can promote economic growth by increasing crea-
Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM), Rasiah tivity and productivity.
et al. (2019) evaluated the effect of happiness on eco- Herzberg’s Two Factor Theory also offers insights
nomic growth on a panel dataset from 2000 to 2013. into the relationship between happiness and economic
They found that happiness has a positive and statisti- growth. According to this theory, two factors contribute
cally significant impact on economic growth after con- to job satisfaction: hygiene and motivators. Hygiene fac-
trolling for other factors such as human capital, capital tors, such as salary and working conditions, are neces-
formation, and population. Furthermore, they sary but insufficient for job satisfaction. Motivators,
reported that a low level of happiness hampers eco- such as recognition and opportunities for growth, genu-
nomic growth by lowering labor productivity and ferti- inely contribute to job satisfaction and happiness. The
lity rate (below the replacement levels) but increasing ‘‘Happy-Productive Worker Thesis’’ also proposed that
suicides. However, they used panel data consisting of happy employees are believed to have higher productiv-
50 countries with a limited set of four explanatory vari- ity and better performance. Happiness is operationalized
ables (i.e., capital formation, population, human capi- as job satisfaction (Wright, 2005). ‘‘Subjective well-being
tal and happiness). is associated with good success in the workplace. Happy
Lee and Goh 7

workers are productive, satisfied workers, and their posi- Lit = labour,
tive affect is associated with good organisational citizen- i = country,
ship, good relations the well-known (Pavot & Diener, t = time,
2004, p. 685).’’ When these motivators are present, a = elasticity of real output with respects to the physi-
employees are more likely to be productive and innova- cal capital, and
tive, leading to economic growth. b = elasticity of real output with respects to the
Finally, the PERMA Theory of Well-Being offers a human capital.
comprehensive framework for understanding the compo- Nonetheless, Ait also denotes labor-augmenting factor
nents of well-being. PERMA stands for Positive (Fethi & Imamoglu, 2021). In this paper, we argue that
Emotions, Engagement, Relationships, Meaning, and happiness is a labor-augmenting factor. Happiness not
Accomplishment (Seligman, 2011). This theory suggests only stimulates labor productivity at the macro-level
that when individuals experience positive emotions and (DiMaria et al., 2020) but also promotes creativity and
are engaged in meaningful work, they are more likely to innovation (Mao & Weathers, 2019), as well as improves
form positive relationships and achieve a sense of accom- life expectancy (Straume & Vittersø, 2015), which in turn
plishment. These components of well-being can contrib- spurs economic growth. In addition to technological
ute to increased creativity, productivity, and innovation, progress and happiness, there are also other variables
leading to economic growth. In agreement with the that affect economic growth, which could be included in
PERMA Theory of Well-Being, the engagement element Ait . Let Ait represent the factors that potentially affect
of happiness reflects the sense of belonging to the organi- economic growth other than labor, physical capital and
zation. It induces intrinsic motivation/satisfaction, which human capital. The variables Ait and Lit are assumed to
raises productivity (Oswald et al., 2015). The generaliz- grow exponentially at the exogenous rate of gi and ni as
ability of the happiness-productivity relationship at the depicted in Equations 2 and 3, respectively.
aggregate level has been proven by DiMaria et al. (2020).
Overall, these theories suggest that happiness and Ait = Ai0 egit + uHAPit + Zit p ð2Þ
well-being are desirable outcomes and have important
economic growth implications. By fostering positive Lit = Li0 enit ð3Þ
emotions, providing meaningful work and growth
opportunities, and promoting positive relationships and where,
accomplishments, individuals can contribute to eco- Ai0 = initial technological level,
nomic growth and prosperity. Li0 = initial labor,
HAPit = happiness,
Methodology Zi = a vector of other factors that affect economic
output,
This section explains the empirical model, data, and gi = the exogenous growth rate of technological prog-
econometric methods used for subsequent analysis. ress, and
ni = the exogenous growth rate of labor.
Following the argument presented by Law and
Empirical Model Habibullah (2006), the steady-state of output per worker
The empirical model for examining the effect of happi- derived from Equations 1–3 can be represented by:
ness on economic growth is grounded on Mankiw et al.’s      
(1992) Augmented Solow Model. Following Mankiw Yit a b
ln = lnsk, it + lnsh, it
et al. (1992), the model is derived from the Cobb- Lit 1ab 1ab
Douglas production function of the Augmented Solow  
a+b
Model that relates real output, Yit to physical capital, Kit ,  lnðgit + nit + dit Þ + lnAi0
1ab
human capital, Hit . and labor, Lit in Equation 1 as
follows: + git + uHAPit + Zit p
ð4Þ
Yit = Kita Hitb (Ait Lit )1ab ð1Þ
where,
where, sk = share of physical capital in output,
Yit = real output, sh = share of human capital in output, and
Kit = physical capital, dit = depreciation rate of capital.
Hit = human capital, Due to data limitations, we assume that the growth
Ait = technological progress, rate of technological progress and capital depreciation
8 SAGE Open

rate remain unchanged over time in each country. This paper transforms the non-index variables and
Rearranging terms, Equation 4 can be summarized as: non-ratio variables into natural logarithms. This facili-
  tates the interpretation of the regression coefficients as
Yit elasticities.
ln = b0 + b1 lnsk, it + b2 lnsh, it  b3 lnðgi + nit + di Þ
Lit
+ uHAPit + Zit p
Data
ð5Þ
This paper employed a panel dataset of 104 countries for
Equation 5 states that the steady-state of real output the period 2006 through 2018. The sample countries were
per capita is driven by physical capital, human capital, chosen worldwide to the extent of data available. A total
labor, happiness and other variables that affect output. of 1,352 observations were considered.
This provides the basis for the empirical model as The data on happiness were collected from the World
follows: Happiness Report (WHR) published by the United
ln yit = g0 + g1 kit + g2 hit + g3 lit + uHAPit Nations Sustainable Development Solutions Network
Xp ð6Þ (UNSDSN). Happiness at the micro-level (also known as
+ p z + eit
j = 1 j jit self-reported happiness) was measured by Cantril’s Self-
Anchoring Ladder (Cantril, 1965) through the Gallup
where, World Poll. The poll reads, ‘‘Please imagine a ladder,
yit = real GDP per capita in country i at time t, with steps numbered from 0 at the bottom to 10 at the
kit = capital formation in country i at time t, top. The top of the ladder represents the best possible life
hit = human capital in country i at time t, for you and the bottom of the ladder represents the worst
lit = labour force in country i at time t, possible life for you. On which step of the ladder would
HAPit = happiness in country i at time t, you say you personally feel you stand at this time?’’ Since
zjit = p fundamental variables determining economic the reliability of the self-reported happiness by the indi-
growth in country i at time t, and vidual respondents is subject to contextual bias, happi-
eit = error term or disturbance term. ness at the macro-level is calculated by using the mean
Other studies supported the inclusion of capital for- happiness of the individuals in a country. Happiness at
mation (Pasara & Garidzirai, 2020; Topcu et al., 2020), the macro-level is proven to be less vulnerable to mea-
human capital (Matousek & Tzeremes, 2021; Sulaiman surement bias (Veenhoven, 2010). Previous works recog-
et al., 2021) and labor force growth (Raghutla, 2020; nized the high congruent validity of the Cantril’s Self-
Yıldırım & Akinci, 2021) in the real output per capita Anchoring Ladder as demonstrated in the consistency in
function. These three variables together with zjit are the responses to the question, irrespective of how the ques-
control variables in this study. We include labor produc- tion is admitted (Oswald & Wu, 2010).
tivity (Martı́n-Retortillo & Pinilla, 2015; Rozkošová & The data on real GDP per capita (constant 2010
Megyesiová, 2018) and life expectancy (He & Li, 2020; USD) were obtained from the World Development
Kunze, 2014) to improve the estimation of labor and Indicators (WDI) made available by the World Bank. It
human capital effects on output. The fundamental vari- was computed from the real GDP divided by the mid-
ables zjit encompass other economic growth determi- year population. Similarly, capital formation, financial
nants. These include financial development (Doumbia, development, government expenditure, household expen-
2016; Nyasha & Odhiambo, 2018), government expendi- diture, inflation, labor force growth, labor productivity,
ture (Chen & Xu, 2022; Chu et al., 2020), household life expectancy and trade openness were gathered from
expenditure (Radulescu et al., 2019; Tran, 2022), infla- the WDI. Capital formation, financial development, gov-
tion (Baharumshah et al., 2016; Dinh, 2020), and trade ernment expenditure, household expenditure and trade
openness (Keho, 2017; Raghutla, 2020). openness were expressed as ratios to GDP. Inflation was
Meanwhile, to take into account the dynamic feature represented by the annual growth in Consumer Price
of economic growth, whereby the past economic growth Index (CPI).
is influenced by the current economic growth, Equation The labor force covered individuals aged 15 years old
6 is extended with a lagged real output per capita as pre- and more who are currently: (1) employed, (2) first-time
sented in Equation 7. jobseekers, and (3) unemployed but pursuing a job. In
ln yit = g0 + g1 kit + g2 hit + g3 lit + g4 lnyit1 + uHAPit this paper, the labor force growth rate in year t was cal-
Xp culated as the percentage change in the labor force from
+ p z + eit
j = 1 j jit year t21 to year t. Labor productivity was measured by
ð7Þ real GDP (constant 2017 PPP $) divided by total employ-
ment in a country. The life expectancy at birth was based
Lee and Goh 9

on the number of years a newborn would have lived if The Breusch-Pagan Lagrangian Multiplier (LM) test
the prevailing mortality rate at the time of birth remained was used to distinguish between the Pooled OLS Model
the same throughout his or her life. The human capital and REM (Breusch & Pagan, 1980). Rejection of the null
index was gathered from the Penn World Table (PWT) hypothesis suggests that the country-specific effects are
maintained by the University of California and the heterogeneous, and the REM model is preferred. The
University of Groningen. According to PWT, the human Hausman test was conducted to determine the appropri-
capital index was constructed from both average years of ateness between REM and FEM (Hausman, 1978). The
schooling and Mincer’s assumed rate of return to null hypothesis stipulates no correlation between the
education. country-specific effects and the regressors, suggesting
that REM is more suitable than FEM.
Additionally, a dynamic panel data model was also
Econometric Methods considered, whereby the dynamic relationship is charac-
terized by including a lagged dependent variable, as
Equation 6 was first estimated and the Cook’s Distance
stated in Equation 7. GMM is widely acknowledged for
Outlier Test was applied to identify the outliers.
its robustness in alleviating endogeneity (Lahouel et al.,
Consequently, 71 observations identified as outliers were
2019). The lagged dependent variable can be used an
excluded from the subsequent estimations in the
internal instrument in the GMM estimator (Roodman,
analysis.
2009) to address endogeneity. Endogeneity is eliminated
This paper used the Fisher-type test based on
through an internal transformation, whereby the past
Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test for panel data to
value of the variable is deducted from its current value
ascertain the stationarity properties of the variables. The
(Roodman, 2009). Internal transformation also enhances
p-values of the test were obtained using four methods,
the efficiency of the GMM estimator (Wooldridge,
namely inverse chi-squared, inverse normal, inverse logit,
2012). This paper used the Two-Step Difference GMM
and modified inverse chi-squared (Choi, 2001). The null
with robust standard errors proposed by Arellano and
hypothesis conjectures that the variable under consider-
Bond (1991) and further improved by Windmeijer
ation contains unit-roots.
(2005). The forward orthogonal deviations were applied
Upon establishing the stationarity properties of the
whereby the mean of all future available observations of
variables, this paper employed an improved Granger
the variable is subtracted from its current value
Causality Test in panel data proposed by Dumitrescu
(Roodman, 2009; Ullah et al., 2018). This approach
and Hurlin (2012). The test involves testing for causality
transforms the equation into first difference to eradicate
between two stationary variables under consideration
the country-specific effect. To remove simultaneity bias,
across all the cross-section units (countries in this case)
lagged levels of the regressor were used as instrument.
in Equations 8 and 9.
Two-Step Difference GMM with robust standard errors
XK XK has the advantage of avoiding downward biased stan-
Yit = ai1 + k =1
bik Yi, tk + k =1
dik Xi, tk + ei, 1t dard errors and instrument proliferation (Law, 2018).
ð8Þ The Arellano-Bond Test was conducted as a diagnostic
check for first- and second-order serial correlation.
XJ XJ In addition, Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) estima-
Xit = ai2 + l X
j = 1 ij i, tj
+ gij Yi, tj + ei, 2t
j=1 tions were performed as a robustness check that the
ð9Þ empirical models were not affected by endogeneity,
whereby lagged happiness was used as an instrumental
with i = 1, .., N and t = 1, .., T. The regression variable for happiness.
coefficients differ across countries but are constant over
time.
The null and alternative hypothesis of the panel
Empirical Results and Discussions
Granger causality, the Wald Test for non-causality and Table 1 displays the empirical results of the Fisher-based
approximated standardized statistic, Z̃ are explained in Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to assess the sta-
Appendix A. tionarity of real GDP per capita and happiness. The null
Accordingly, the static and dynamic panel data mod- hypothesis of all the four tests is consistently rejected (at
els were considered to examine the effect of happiness on .1% significance level) for both real GDP per capita and
economic growth. Three static panel data models, happiness. These two variables are stationary without
namely the Pooled Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) further differencing.
Model, Random Effects Model (REM), and Fixed The results of the Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012)
Effects Model (FEM) were fitted for Equation 6. Granger causality test on the relationship between
10 SAGE Open

Table 1. The Results on the Stationarity Tests.

Methods Real GDP per capita Happiness

Inverse chi-squared 533.7477*** 376.7622***


Inverse normal –11.3473*** –9.4947***
Inverse logit –11.9371*** –9.3544***
Modified inverse chi-squared 15.9711*** 10.2083***

Note. The test statistics of the Fisher-based Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test are reported.
***p\.001.

Table 2. The Results on the Causality Relationship Between Happiness and Real GDP per Capita.

Happiness causes real GDP per capita Real GDP per capita causes happiness
Approximated Approximated
Optimal Standardized Optimal standardized
Information criterion number of lags Statistic, Z̃ number of lags statistic, Z̃

Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) 1 2.4607* 2 5.5883***,#


Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) 1 2.4607* 2 5.5883***,#
Hannan-Quinn Information Criterion (HQIC) 2 2.8119**,# 2 5.5883***,#

Note. The Dumitrescu and Hurlin’s (2012) Granger-causality test was employed.
*p\.05. **p\.01. ***p\.001 (based on asymptotic distribution). # p\.05 (based on bootstrap critical values).

happiness and real GDP per capita are reported in Table standard errors and the empirical results are reported in
2. The null hypothesis of real GDP per capita does not Model 5. Model 6 is an extension to Model 5 by incor-
Granger-cause happiness is consistently rejected in all the porating lagged happiness as an additional explanatory
tests. This finding is consistent with the well-documented variable.
evidence in the literature that the real GDP per capita The Breusch-Pagan Lagrangian Multiplier (LM) Test
affects happiness. The results also provided evidence that was conducted to detect the presence of the country-
happiness Granger-causes real GDP per capita. This specific effect. The null hypothesis of homogeneity is
empirical finding is under reported in the literature. The rejected at the .1% significance level. Since the heteroge-
test was repeated with a bootstrapping of 1,000 replica- neity problem attributable to the country-specific effect is
tions to obtain the empirical distribution of the test sta- present, REM (Model 2) is more appropriate than Pooled
tistic. The test based on lag length selected using the OLS (Model 1). The Hausman Test was performed to
Hannan-Quinn Information Criterion continues to indi- detect the presence of endogenous regressors. The test sta-
cate a bidirectional relationship between real GDP per tistic is significant at the .1% level, suggesting that FEM
capita and happiness. These empirical findings indicate (Model 3) is more favorable than REM (Model 2).
that the determinants of economic growth must not only Upon ascertaining the most appropriate static panel
focus on macroeconomic factors but also recognized the model, diagnostic checks were conducted. VIF was com-
neglected impact of happiness on economic growth. puted to detect multicollinearity. The mean of VIF is
Hence, the inclusion of happiness in the conventional 2.79, suggesting that the dataset does not have a severe
economic growth model is crucial to achieve a holistic multicollinearity problem. The modified Wald and
understanding of economic growth for policy designs. Wooldridge tests were performed to detect heteroscedas-
Table 3 presents the empirical results to examine the ticity and serial correlation, respectively. The null
effect of happiness on real GDP per capita in 104 coun- hypothesis of the modified Wald test is homogeneity. In
tries. Equation 6 was estimated using Pooled Ordinary contrast, the null hypothesis of the Wooldridge test is no
Least Squares (OLS), Random Effects Model (REM), first-order autocorrelation. Therefore, both the null
Fixed Effects Model (FEM), and FEM with clustered hypotheses are rejected at the 0.1% significance level.
standard errors. The results are given in Model 1, Model Since the problem of heteroscedasticity and first-order
2, Model 3, and Model 4, respectively. Meanwhile, autocorrelation are present, FEM with clustered stan-
Equation 7 was estimated using the Two-Step Difference dard errors is estimated to provide country-clustered
Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) with robust standard errors.
Lee and Goh 11

0.06460*** (0.01106)

0.18570*** (0.02021)

0.93023*** (0.02086)

21.90080*** (0.16587)

Note. The VIF, modified Wald test, and Wooldridge test are for checking the presence of multicollinearity, heteroskedasticity, and serial correlation, respectively. The values in parentheses are standard errors.
Two-stage least squares

0.00131** (0.00038)

0.30572** (0.09734)
To deal with any endogeneity problem, Two-Step

0.00318* (0.00159)
0.00014 (0.00014)
0.00113 (0.00107)
–0.00071 (0.00039)

–0.00022 (0.00042)

20.00017 (0.00012)
Difference GMM with robust standard errors was

.8797
(7)

employed to estimate Equation 7 and reported as Model

-
-
-
-
-
-
-
5. In addition, Model 6 includes lagged happiness as one
of the regressors. In both Model 5 and Model 6, the null

104

hypothesis of no first-order serial correlation in first dif-


Two-step different GMM with
robust standard errors and

ferences is rejected using the Arellano-Bond test.


0.25503*** (0.06033)
0.01084*** (0.00313)

0.00118*** (0.00038)

0.15660*** (0.04350)

0.32348*** (0.05011)
0.75890*** (0.05347)

21.82795*** (0.27070)
–0.00049** (0.00021)
–0.00305** (0.00137)
0.00479**(0.00241)

Meanwhile, the null hypothesis of no second-order serial


0.00062 (0.00044)

0.00005 (0.00030)

0.00047 (0.00266)
0.00022 (0.00014)
lagged happiness

20.47468
correlation is not rejected.

104
(6)

-
-
-
-
-
-
2.37850*
The estimated results for all the models consistently
indicate that happiness is a statistically significant deter-
minant of real GDP per capita at the 0.1% significance
level. Based on the appropriateness of the empirical
with robust standard errors

models above, this paper focuses on interpreting the


Two-step different GMM

0.26522*** (0.05694)
0.00988*** (0.00300)

0.00123*** (0.00038)

0.14233*** (0.04067)

0.29967*** (0.06294)
0.74722*** (0.05423)

21.65586*** (0.24808)
–0.00052** (0.00019)
–0.00275* (0.00135)

results of the FEM with clustered standard errors


0.00002 (0.00040)

0.00008 (0.00027)

0.00018 (0.00294)
0.00025 (0.00015)

20.24363

(Model 4) and the Two-Step Difference Generalized


104
(5)

2.97760**

-
-
-
-
-
-
Method of Moments with robust standard errors (Model
5 and Model 6). Consistent with Kenny (1999), Li and

Lu (2010), Rasheed et al. (2011), Llena-Nozal et al.


(2019), and Rasiah et al. (2019), the three models consis-
0.03039*** (0.00622)

0.39328*** (0.10029)
0.86733*** (0.03040)
0.00184** (0.00064)

0.12690** (0.04011)

20.00061** (0.00020)
20.94261** (0.29203)

tently indicate that happiness is a statistically significant


FEM with clustered

0.00020 (0.00023)
–0.00090 (0.00172)
–0.00064 (0.00084)

–0.00057 (0.00072)

0.00467 (0.00297)
standard errors

determinant of real GDP per capita. One unit increase in


.8980
104
(4)

happiness leads to economic growth of between 1%


-
-
-
-
-
-
-

(Models 5 and 6) to 3% (Model 4). A unit increase in


happiness in the previous year adds to an additional

growth of 0.5% (Model 6). The total positive effect of


0.03039*** (0.00326)

0.00184*** (0.00030)

0.12690*** (0.01657)

0.39328*** (0.08295)
0.86733*** (0.01618)
0.00467*** (0.00115)
20.00061*** (0.00010)
20.94261*** (0.14072)

happiness on growth estimated in Model 6 is 1.5%. The


0.00020 (0.00011)
–0.00090 (0.00087)
–0.00064 (0.00035)

–0.00057 (0.00041)

41,910.56***

other explanatory variables that are consistently signifi-


898.53***

736.48***
.8980
FEM

2.79

104
(3)

cant in the three models are lagged real GDP per capita,
-
-
-

capital formation, human capital, labor force growth,


and labor productivity. Financial development, govern-

ment expenditure, household expenditure, inflation, life


Table 3. The Results on the Effect of Happiness on Real GDP per Capita.

0.03398*** (0.00383)

0.00126*** (0.00036)

0.15097*** (0.01870)

0.47952*** (0.09777)

20.00037*** (0.00011)
21.84975*** (0.14679)
0.96168***(0.01671)
0.00038** (0.00013)

–0.00128** (0.00041)

expectancy, and trade openness are insignificant.


0.00034 (0.00101)

–0.00020 (0.00048)

0.00240 (0.00130)

2,381.12***

Equation 6 is repeated with the 2SLS using lagged happi-


.8956
REM

104
(2)

-
-

-
-
-
-

ness as the instrument to show further that the results


are not affected by the endogeneity of happiness.

Happiness has a significant positive effect on economic


growth.
0.19680*** (0.01069)

–0.01502*** (0.00121)
0.00346*** (0.00020)
0.00793*** (0.00180)
–0.01305*** (0.00086)
0.22408*** (0.02092)

0.77401*** (0.01810)
0.00865*** (0.00182)

20.61727*** (0.17941)
–0.00582** (0.00205)

20.00043** (0.00014)

The models were also estimated for two sub-samples


0.39465 (0.44696)
Pooled OLS

consisting of 35 developed countries and 63 developing


.9780
104
(1)

-
-
-
-
-
-
-

countries. The country classification is according to the


United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

(UNCTD) definition. Table 4 reports the results for the


FEM with clustered standard errors (Model 1a and 1b
Breusch and Pagan Lagrangian multiplier test

for the developed and developing countries, respec-


tively), the Two-Step Difference Generalized Method of
*p\.05. **p\.01. ***p\.001.

Moments with robust standard errors (Model 2a and


Model 2b), and the same method repeated with the inclu-
Arellano-Bond test for AR(1)
Arellano-Bond test for AR(2)

Variance inflation factor (VIF)


ln lagged real GDP per capita

sion of lagged happiness in the model (Model 3a and


Government expenditure
Household expenditure
Financial development

Number of countries

Model 3b). The empirical results in all the models consis-


ln labor productivity
Labor force growth

Modified Wald test


Capital formation
Lagged happiness

tently illustrate that happiness is a statistically significant


Wooldridge test
Trade openness
Life expectancy
Human capital

Hausman Test

determinant (at a 0.1% significance level, except for


Happiness

R-squared
Constant
Variables

Inflation
Models

Model 1b at a 5% significance level) of real GDP per


capita for both developed and developing countries.
12 SAGE Open

robust standard errors and lagged happiness


The Arellano-Bond tests are for checking the presence
Two-step different GMM with of autocorrelation of order one and two. The values in

0.000228*** (0.00003)
parentheses are standard errors. Comparing the two sub-
0.29013*** (0.01593)
0.00640*** (0.00072)
0.00373*** (0.00084)
0.00069*** (0.00011)

–0.00199*** (0.00021)

0.09613*** (0.01493)

0.19300*** (0.01999)
0.72943*** (0.01882)

–1.82891*** (0.08324)
0.000075 (0.00006)
–0.00003 (0.00009)

0.00012 (0.00010)

0.00137 (0.00098)
samples shows that the effect of happiness is larger for
(3b)

the developed countries. A unit increase in happiness


brings about a growth of between 3% to 7.5% for devel-

0.9908
0.9847
oped countries and 0.6% to 1.3% for developing coun-

63

tries. Considering the lagged effects of happiness, the
impact is 4.4% for developed countries and 1.0% for
developing countries (Model 3a and 3b, respectively).
The empirical results for the control variables suggest
Two-step different GMM with

0.29357*** (0.02054)
0.00572*** (0.00078)

0.00052*** (0.00011)

–0.00224*** (0.00021)
–0.00039*** (0.00008)
0.09773*** (0.01487)

0.20695*** (0.01206)

0.00034*** (0.00005)
–1.71237*** (0.08680)
robust standard errors

that real GDP per capita is also contributed by lagged


0.7224*** (0.01998)
0.00021* (0.00008)

0.00001 (0.00005)

0.00095 (0.00088)

real GDP per capita, capital formation, human capital,


(2b)

labor force growth, labor productivity, and trade open-


ness. Meanwhile, household expenditure is a significant
0.9798
0.9403

determinant for developed countries only, and financial


63

development is a significant determinant for developing


countries only. The positive effect of happiness on real
0.83012*** (0.03887)
Table 4. The Results on The Effect of Happiness on Real GDP per Capita in the Developed and Developing Countries.

0.00138** (0.00049)
FEM with clustered

GDP per capita in developed countries is about four


0.01281* (0.00509)

–0.00059* (0.00028)
–0.76721* (0.37236)
0.00054 (0.00056)

–0.00080 (0.00186)
–0.00033 (0.00090)
0.09388 (0.05596)
–0.00027 (0.00101)
0.23911 (0.12021)

0.00520 (0.00282)
standard errors

times greater than in developing countries. When viewed


(1b)

from the perspective of Maslow’s hierarchy of needs


.9306

(Maslow, 1943), the basic needs of individuals in devel-


63


oped countries were fulfilled, and they achieved the con-


sumption threshold (Victor, 2010). They are more
robust standard errors and lagged happiness

concerned about psychological needs and self-fulfilment


Two-step different GMM with

than individuals in developing countries. Consistent with


0.28374*** (0.03228)
0.03000*** (0.00221)
0.01425*** (0.00158)
0.00294*** (0.00041)

–0.00505*** (0.00032)

0.30833*** (0.06750)
0.67870*** (0.03198)
–0.00357** (0.00113)

0.10619** (0.04062)
0.00125** (0.00038)

the Broaden-and-Build Theory, happiness sparks an


–0.00036* (0.00016)
–0.00006 (0.00010)

–0.00060 (0.00127)

–0.55228 (0.43430)

expansive thought-action repertoire, which builds long-


(3a)

term psychological, physical, and social resources


0.0064
–0.0282

(Conway et al., 2013). As such, happiness catalyzes crea-


tivity and innovation (Mao & Weathers, 2019) and fos-
35

ters the absorption capacity of technological progress


(Teixeira & Queirós, 2016). Consequently, it promotes
advancement in personal growth by acquiring compe-
with robust standard errors

tence development (Newman et al., 2011) and improves


Two-step different GMM

0.32016*** (0.02762)
0.02712*** (0.00149)

0.00292*** (0.00040)

–0.00394*** (0.00047)

0.38207*** (0.03236)
0.72917*** (0.02630)

–0.00044*** (0.00011)
–1.24177*** (0.30901)
–0.00343** (0.00102)

0.11161** (0.03373)
0.00073* (0.00033)

labor productivity (DiMaria et al., 2020), a crucial stimu-


–0.00013 (0.00009)

–0.00307 (0.00163)

lant of economic growth (Rozkošová & Megyesiová,


(2a)

2018). These arguments support the findings of a larger


–0.0146
0.0076

impact of changes in happiness on economic growth in



35

developed countries.
0.07469*** (0.00532)

0.00667*** (0.00104)

0.63497*** (0.13276)
0.79675*** (0.08763)
–0.00517** (0.00188)
0.12541** (0.04314)
FEM with clustered

–0.00055* (0.00026)
0.00022 (0.00029)
0.00243 (0.00424)

0.00084 (0.00120)

0.00890 (0.00497)

–0.18519 (1.01123)
standard errors

Conclusions and Policy Recommendations


(1a)

The literature documents rich evidence that higher eco-


.8835

nomic growth often leads to higher happiness. This


*p\.05. **p\.01. ***p\.001.

paper highlights a bi-directional relationship between


35


happiness and economic growth. In other words, happi-


ness can be an engine for economic growth, and its
Arellano–Bond Test for AR(1)
Arellano–Bond Test for AR(2)
ln lagged real GDP per capita

impact on economic growth is under-researched. The


Government expenditure
Household expenditure
Financial development

Number of countries

Granger Causality test found that happiness spurs eco-


ln labor productivity
Labor force growth
Capital formation
Lagged happiness

nomic growth. Accordingly, various panel models were


Trade openness
Life expectancy
Human capital

employed to determine the effect of happiness on eco-


Happiness

R-squared
Constant
Variables

Inflation

nomic growth. Generally, economic growth of between


Models

1% to 3% can be obtained by increasing happiness.


Lee and Goh 13

However, the marginal return to increased happiness is economic growth and the mediator through which hap-
higher in developed than in developing countries. piness stimulates economic growth would be beneficial.
Further estimation suggests that the positive effect of Future research should use objective measures of happi-
happiness is about four times greater in developed coun- ness from big data to supplement self-reported happiness
tries than in developing countries. and mitigate social desirability bias. Additionally, future
The theoretical implication of the findings in this research should explore the effect of subjective well-being
study is that the economic growth model should not and psychological well-being on economic growth and
overlook the inclusion of happiness. It is crucial to examine how they could be fostered through policy inter-
include some measures of well-being in the model to ventions. Future research also should investigate the
avoid under-specification and variable omission bias. potential trade-offs and synergies between happiness and
In terms of policy implication, policymakers should economic growth to enable policymakers to identify win-
consider placing happiness with economic growth as
win policy solutions that maximize multiple objectives.
the central tenet of government policy. The findings
This way, policymakers could devise a policy focusing
support the rationale for countries such as Scotland,
on happiness and economic growth to achieve sustain-
New Zealand, and Iceland to consider the citizens’
able economic growth.
well-being in their national development agenda.
Policymakers should focus on policies that are geared
toward fostering happiness. This can include improving Appendix A
the quality of life, providing social support, promoting
work-life balance, and investing in education and The null hypothesis that X does not Granger cause Y
healthcare. According to the ‘‘Economy of Well- given by Equation A.1 indicates no causality across all
Being,’’ policymakers should not use growth-led poli- the countries.
cies as a single compass. Moving beyond GDP by con-
H0 : d1 = . . . . . . = dk = 0, 8i = 1, . . . . . . , N ðA:1Þ
sidering happiness is imperative to ensure long-term
sustainable economic growth. This is owing to the sig-
However, causality may exist in some isolated coun-
nificant positive spill-over effect of happiness that
tries, but not in other countries. Say causality does not
encourages human capital development, innovation,
exist in a sub-group of N1 countries. The alternative
and labor productivity. Additionally, policymakers
hypothesis is given below:
should further explore the conditions that enhance the
impact of happiness on economic growth and the
H1 : d1 = . . . . . . = dk = 0, 8i = 1, . . . . . . , N1 andd1 6¼ 0
mechanisms through which happiness fosters economic
growth. This will enable policymakers to devise policies or . . . . . . or dk 6¼ 0, 8 i = N1 + 1, . . . . . . , N
tailored to specific contexts and promote sustainable
economic growth. Furthermore, policymakers should Similarly, the null and alternative hypotheses to test if
recognize that the positive effect of happiness on eco- Y Granger causes X are expressed in Equation A.2.
nomic growth is greater in developed countries than in
developing countries. Therefore, policies that promote H0 : g1 = . . . . . . = gk = 0, 8i = 1, . . . . . . , N ðA:2Þ
happiness and well-being in developing countries
should be tailored to meet the specific needs and chal- H1 : g1 = . . . . . . = gk = 0, 8 i = 1, . . . . . . , N1 and g1 6¼ 0
lenges of these countries. or . . . . . . or gk 6¼ 0, 8 i = N1 + 1, . . . . . . , N
While the positive direct effect of happiness on eco-
nomic growth is confirmed, the limitation of this study is
that we have not examined the conditions that boost the The Wald Test for non-causality was computed for all
effect of happiness on economic growth and the channels the countries, and the average Wald statistic was
that facilitate the mechanism. In addition, this study obtained as Equation A.3.
relies on the subjective measure of happiness, which may 1 XN
be subject to social desirability bias and may not reflect W= i=1
Wi ðA:3Þ
N
actual happiness. Furthermore, this study focuses on
subjective well-being without considering psychological Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) proposed the approxi-
and objective well-being. Moreover, this study did not mated standardised statistic, Z̃ with corrections for rela-
examine the potential adverse effects of over-focusing on tively large N but small T panel datasets as specified in
happiness as a policy goal and neglecting important eco- Equation A.4. This paper used Z̃ to test for causality
nomic objectives. Therefore, studying the potential mod- based on a block bootstrap procedure to estimate the
erator of the relationship between happiness and bootstrapped critical values.
14 SAGE Open

rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi  
d
~ = N : T  3K  5 T  3K  3 :W  K :
Z Nð0, 1Þ
economic boom. World Development, 74, 333–351. https://
2K T  2K  3 T  3K  1 ! doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.05.010
N !‘
Boo, M. C., Yen, S. H., & Lim, H. E. (2016). A note on happi-
ðA:4Þ ness and life satisfaction in Malaysia. Malaysian Journal of
Economic Studies, 53(2), 261–277.
where, Breusch, T. S., & Pagan, A. R. (1980). The Lagrange multiplier
K = lag order. test and its applications to model specification in econo-
metrics. The Review of Economic Studies, 47(1), 239–253.
Cantril, H. (1965). The pattern of human concerns. Rutgers Uni-
Acknowledgments versity Press.
Not applicable. Chen, F. F., Jing, Y., Hayes, A., & Lee, J. M. (2013). Two con-
cepts or two approaches? A bifactor analysis of psychologi-
cal and subjective well-being. Journal of Happiness Studies,
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
14(3), 1033–1068. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-012-9367-x
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with Chen, Q., & Xu, X. (2022). Stabilizing economic growth:
respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this Growth target and government expenditure since World
article. War II. China Economic Quarterly International, 2(2),
98–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ceqi.2022.05.003
Funding Choi, I. (2001). Unit root tests for panel data. Journal of Inter-
national Money and Finance, 20(2), 249–272. https://doi.org/
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial sup- 10.1016/s0261-5606(00)00048-6
port for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this Chu, T. T., Hölscher, J., & McCarthy, D. (2020). The impact of
article: This publication is partially funded by the Faculty of productive and non-productive government expenditure on
Business and Economics, Universiti Malaya Special Publication economic growth: An empirical analysis in high-income ver-
Fund. sus low- to middle-income economies. Empirical Economics,
58(5), 2403–2430. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1616-3
Conway, A. M., Tugade, M. M., Catalino, L. I., & Frederick-
ORCID iDs son, B. L. (2013). The broaden-and-build theory of positive
Yok-Yong Lee https://orcid.org/0000-0003-2924-8264 emotions: Form, function, and mechanisms. In S. David, I.
Kim-Leng Goh https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2367-8303 Boniwell & A. Ayers (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of happi-
ness (pp. 17–34). Oxford University Press.
Diener, E., Oishi, S., & Lucas, R. E. (2015). National accounts
References of subjective well-being. The American Psychologist, 70(3),
Aksoy, F., & Bayram Arlı, N. (2020). Evaluation of sustainable 234–242. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0038899
happiness with sustainable development goals: structural DiMaria, C. H., Peroni, C., & Sarracino, F. (2020). Happiness
equation model approach. Sustainable Development, 28(1), matters: Productivity gains from subjective well-being. Jour-
385–392. https://doi.org/10.1002/sd.1985 nal of Happiness Studies, 21(1), 139–160. https://doi.org/10.
Alatartseva, E., & Barysheva, G. (2015). Well-being: Subjective 1007/s10902-019-00074-1
and objective aspects. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Dinh, D. V. (2020). Optimal inflation threshold and economic
Sciences, 166, 36–42. growth: Ordinal regression model analysis. The Journal of
Anderson, M., & Mossialos, E. (2019). Beyond gross domestic Asian Finance, Economics and Business, 7(5), 91–102. https://
product for New Zealand’s well-being budget. The Lancet doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2020.vol7.no5.091
Public Health, 4(7), e320–e321. https://doi.org/10.1016/ Doumbia, D. (2016). Financial development and economic
S2468-2667(19)30109-4 growth in 43 advanced and developing economies over the
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for period 1975–2009: Evidence of non-linearity. Applied Econo-
panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to metrics and International Development, 16(1), 13–22.
employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, Dumitrescu, E. I., & Hurlin, C. (2012). Testing for Granger non-
58(2), 277–297. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968 causality in heterogeneous panels. Economic Modelling, 29(4),
Baharumshah, A. Z., Slesman, L., & Wohar, M. E. (2016). 1450–1460. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.014
Inflation, inflation uncertainty, and economic growth in Easterlin, R. A. (2005). Feeding the illusion of growth and hap-
emerging and developing countries: Panel data evidence. piness: A reply to Hagerty and Veenhoven. Social Indicators
Economic Systems, 40(4), 638–657. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Research, 74(3), 429–443. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-
ecosys.2016.02.009 004-6170-z
Bartolini, S., Mikucka, M., & Sarracino, F. (2017). Money, Exton, C., & Shinwell, M. (2018). Policy use of well-being
trust and happiness in transition countries: Evidence from metrics: Describing countries’ experiences (OECD Statistics
time series. Social Indicators Research, 130(1), 87–106. Working Papers 2018/07). OECD Publishing.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-1130-3 Fethi, S., & Imamoglu, H. (2021). The impact of rent-seeking
Bartolini, S., & Sarracino, F. (2015). The dark side of Chinese on economic growth in the six geographic regions: Evidence
growth: Declining social capital and well-being in times of from static and dynamic panel data analysis. International
Lee and Goh 15

Journal of Finance & Economics, 26(4), 5349–5362. https:// No. 2019/02). OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/
doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.2069 18152031
Fredrickson, B. L. (2001). The role of positive emotions in pos- Lucas, R. E., & Diener, E. (2008). Personality and subjective
itive psychology: The broaden-and-build theory of positive well-being. In O. P. John, R. W. Robins, & L. A. Pervin
emotions. The American Psychologist, 56, 218–226. (Eds.), Handbook of personality: Theory and research
Frijters, P., & Krekel, C. (2021). A handbook for well-being pol- (pp. 795–814). The Guilford Press.
icy-making: History, theory, Measurement, implementation, Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribu-
and examples. Oxford University Press. tion to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly
Gata ulinas, A., & Banceviča, M. (2014). Subjective health and Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407–437.
subjective well-being (the case of EU countries). Advances in Mao, C. X., & Weathers, J. (2019). Employee treatment and
Applied Sociology, 4(9), 212–223. firm innovation. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting,
Gonza, G., & Burger, A. (2017). Subjective well-being during 46(7-8), 977–1002.
the 2008 economic crisis: Identification of mediating and Martı́n-Retortillo, M., & Pinilla, V. (2015). On the causes of
moderating factors. Journal of Happiness Studies, 18(6), economic growth in Europe: Why did agricultural labour
1763–1797. productivity not converge between 1950 and 2005? Cliome-
Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. trica, 9, 359–396.
Econometrics, 46(6), 1251–1271. https://doi.org/10.2307/ Masaki, K. (2022). Exploring the ‘partial connections’ between
1913827 growth and degrowth debates: Bhutan’s policy of Gross
He, L., & Li, N. (2020). The linkages between life expectancy National Happiness. Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics,
and economic growth: Some new evidence. Empirical Eco- 34(1), 86–103. https://doi.org/10.1177/02601079211032103
nomics, 58(5), 2381–2402. Maslow, A. H. (1943). A theory of human motivation. Psycho-
Kalimeris, P., Bithas, K., Richardson, C., & Nijkamp, P. logical Review, 50, 370–396.
(2020). Hidden linkages between resources and economy: A Matousek, R., & Tzeremes, N. G. (2021). The asymmetric
‘‘Beyond-GDP’’ approach using alternative welfare indica- impact of human capital on economic growth. Empirical
tors. Ecological Economics, 169, 1–14. https://doi.org/10. Economics, 60(3), 1309–1334. https://doi.org/10.1007/
1016/j.ecolecon.2019.106508 s00181-019-01789-z
Keho, Y. (2017). The impact of trade openness on economic Mikucka, M., Sarracino, F., & Dubrow, J. K. (2017). When does
growth: The case of Cote d’Ivoire. Cogent Economics & economic growth improve life satisfaction? Multilevel analysis
Finance, 5(1), 1332820. of the roles of social trust and income inequality in 46 coun-
Kenny, C. (1999). Does growth cause happiness, or does happi- tries, 1981–2012. World Development, 93, 447–459. https://doi.
ness cause growth? Kyklos, 52(1), 3–25. https://doi.org/10. org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.01.002
1111/1467-6435.00072 Miñarro, S., Reyes-Garcı́a, V., Aswani, S., Selim, S., Barring-
Kunze, L. (2014). Life expectancy and economic growth. Jour- ton-Leigh, C. P., & Galbraith, E. D. (2021). Happy without
nal of Macroeconomics, 39(PA), 54–65. https://doi.org/10. money: Minimally monetized societies can exhibit high sub-
1016/j.jmacro.2013.12.004 jective well-being. PLoS One, 16(1), e0244569. https://doi.
Kuznets, S. (1934). National Income, 1929-1932. National org/10.1371/journal.pone.0244569
Bureau of Economic Research. Newman, A., Thanacoody, R., & Hui, W. (2011). The impact
Kuznets, S. (1962), How to judge quality. The New Republic, of employee perceptions of training on organizational com-
147, 29–32. mitment and turnover intentions: A study of multinationals
Lahouel, B. B., Gaies, B., Zaied, Y. B., & Jahmane, A. (2019). in the Chinese service sector. The International Journal of
Accounting for endogeneity and the dynamics of corporate Human Resource Management, 22(8), 1765–1787. https://
social – Corporate financial performance relationship. Jour- doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2011.565667
nal of Cleaner Production, 230, 352–364. https://doi.org/10. Noll, H. H. (2011). The stiglitz-sen-Fitoussi-report: old wine in
1016/j.jclepro.2019.04.377 new skins? Views from a social indicators perspective. Social
Law, S. H. (2018). Applied Panel Data Analysis: Short Panels. Indicators Research, 102(1), 111–116.
University Putra Malaysia Press. Nyasha, S., & Odhiambo, N. M. (2018). Financial development
Law, S. H., & Habibullah, M. S. (2006). Financial develop- and economic growth nexus: A revisionist approach. Eco-
ment, institutional quality and economic performance in nomic Notes, 47(1), 223–229.
East Asian economies. Review of Applied Economics, 2(2), OECD Observer. (2004). Is GDP a satisfactory measure of
201–216. https://doi.org/10.22004/ag.econ.50150 growth? OECD Observer No. 246/247, December 2004–Jan-
Li, B., & Lu, Y. (2010). Is happiness good for economic growth? uary 2005.
chrome-extension://efaidnbmnnnibpcajpcglclefindmkaj/ Oswald, A. J., Proto, E., & Sgroi, D. (2015). Happiness and
https://profile.nus.edu.sg/fass/ecsluyi/happiness_sub.pdf productivity. Journal of Labor Economics, 33(4), 789–822.
Liu, A. (2016). Remaking economic development: The markets Oswald, A. J., & Wu, S. (2010). Objective confirmation of sub-
and civics of continuous growth and prosperity. The Brook- jective measures of human well-being: Evidence from the
ings Institution. USA. Science, 327(5965), 576–579. https://doi.org/10.1126/
Llena-Nozal, A., Martin, N., & Murtin, F. (2019). The econ- science.1180606
omy of well-being: Creating opportunities for people’s well- Pasara, M. T., & Garidzirai, R. (2020). Causality effects among
being and economic growth (OECD Statistics Working Paper gross capital formation, unemployment and economic
16 SAGE Open

growth in South Africa. Economies, 8(2), 26. https://doi.org/ Stiglitz, J., Fitoussi, J., & Durand, M. (2018). Beyond GDP:
10.3390/economies8020026 Measuring what counts for Economic and Social Perfor-
Paun, C., Musetescu, R. C, Topan, M. V., & Danuletiu, D. mance. OECD Publishing.
(2019). The impact of financial sector development and Straume, L. V., & Vittersø, J. (2015). Well-being at work: Some
sophistication on sustainable economic growth. Sustainabil- differences between life satisfaction and personal growth as
ity, 11(6), 1713. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11061713 predictors of subjective health and sick-leave. Journal of
Pavot, W., & Diener, E. (2004). Findings on subjective well- Happiness Studies, 16(1), 149–168. https://doi.org/10.1007/
being: Applications to public policy, clinical interventions s10902-014-9502-y
and education. In P. A. Linley & S. Joseph (Eds.), Positive Sulaiman, N. F. C., Saputra, J., & Muhamad, S. (2021). Effects
psychology in practice (pp. 679–692). Wiley. of human capital and innovation on economic growth in
Pillay, D. (2020). Happiness, wellbeing and ecosocialism – A selected ASEAN countries: Evidence from panel regression
radical humanist perspective. Globalizations, 17(2), 380–396. approach. Journal of Asian Finance Economics and Business,
https://doi.org/10.1080/14747731.2019.1652470 8(7), 43–54. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2021.vol8.no7.0043
Radulescu, M., Serbanescu, L., & Sinisi, C. I. (2019). Consump- Teixeira, A. A. C., & Queirós, A. S. S. (2016). Economic
tion vs. investments for stimulating economic growth and growth, human capital and structural change: A dynamic
employment in the CEE countries – A panel analysis. Eco- panel data analysis. Research Policy, 45(8), 1636–1648.
nomic Research, 32(1), 2329–2353. https://doi.org/10.1080/ https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.04.006
1331677x.2019.1642789 Topcu, E., Altinoz, B., & Aslan, A. (2020). Global evidence
Raghutla, C. (2020). The effect of trade openness on economic from the link between economic growth, natural resources,
growth: Some empirical evidence from emerging market energy consumption, and gross capital formation. Resources
economies. Journal of Public Affairs, 20(3), e2081. https:// Policy, 66, 101622. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.
doi.org/10.1002/pa.2081 101622
Rasheed, F., Rauf, S. A., & Ahmad, E. (2011). Happiness in Tran, N. V. (2022). Understanding household consumption
Solow growth model. Journal of Business Economics, 3(2), behaviour: What do we learn from a developing country?
127–144. The B E Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 22(4),
Rasiah, R., Guptan, V., & Habibullah, M. S. (2019). The 801–858. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2022-0036
impact of happiness on economic growth and community Ullah, S., Akhtar, P., & Zaefarian, G. (2018). Dealing with
development: A dynamic panel estimation. Dilemmas Con- endogeneity bias: The generalized method of moments
temporáneos: Educación, Polı´tica y Valores, 6, 45. (GMM) for panel data. Industrial Marketing Management,
Rogers, D. S., Duraiappah, A. K., Antons, D. C., Munoz, P., 71, 69–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010
Bai, X., Fragkias, M., & Gutscher, H. (2012). A vision for United Nations. (2015). Transforming our world: The 2030
human well-being: Transition to social sustainability. Cur- agenda for sustainable development. United Nations General
rent Opinion in Environmental Sustainability, 4(1), 61–73. Assembly.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cosust.2012.01.013 van Hoorn, A., Mabsout, R., & Sent, E. M. (2010). Happiness
Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many and capability: Introduction to the symposium. The Journal
instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, of Socio-Economics, 39(3), 339–343.
71(1), 135–158. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008. Veenhoven, R. (2010). Greater happiness for a greater number.
00542.x Journal of Happiness Studies, 11(5), 605–629. https://doi.org/
Rozkošová, A., & Megyesiová, S. (2018). Linkage between eco- 10.1007/s10902-010-9204-z
nomic growth and labor productivity in Slovakia by using lin- Veenhoven, R. (2017). Measures of happiness: Which to
ear econometric model. In J. Wallner (Ed.) Proceedings of choose? In G. Brulé & F. Maggino (Eds.), Metrics of subjec-
EDAMBA 2018: International Scientific Conference for Doc- tive well-being: Limits and improvements (pp. 65–84).
toral Students and Post-Doctoral Scholars-Capacity and Springer.
Resources for Sustainable Development. University of Eco- Veenhoven, R., & Vergunst, F. (2014). The Easterlin illusion:
nomics in Bratislava. Economic growth does go with greater happiness. Interna-
Ryff, C. D., & Singer, B. H. (2008). Know thyself and become tional Journal of Happiness and Development, 1(4), 311–343.
what you are: A eudaimonic approach to psychological well- https://doi.org/10.1504/ijhd.2014.066115
being. Journal of Happiness Studies, 9(1), 13–39. Victor, P. (2010). Questioning economic growth. Nature,
Sachs, J., Kroll, C., Lafortune, G., Fuller, G., & Woelm, F. 468(7322), 370–371. https://doi.org/10.1038/468370a
(2021). Sustainable Development Report 2021. Cambridge Voukelatou, V., Gabrielli, L., Miliou, I., Cresci, S., Sharma,
University Press. R., Tesconi, M., & Pappalardo, L. (2021). Measuring objec-
Seligman, M. E. P. (2011). Flourish: A new understanding of hap- tive and subjective well-being: Dimensions and data sources.
piness and well-being and how to achieve them. Nicholas Brea- International Journal of Data Science and Analytics, 11(4),
ley Publishing. 279–309.
Stiglitz, E., Sen, A., & Fitoussi, J. P. (2009). The measurement Wallace, J. (2019). Scotland: Well-being as performance man-
of economic performance and social progress. Revisited reflec- agement. In I. Bache, K. Scott, & P. Allin (Eds.), Well-being
tions and overview. Commission on the Measurement of Eco- and devolution, well-being in politics and policy (pp. 45–71).
nomic Performance and Social Progress. Palgrave Pivot.
Lee and Goh 17

Wang, J. H. (2015). Happiness and social exclusion of indigen- Perrewe & D. C. Ganster (Eds.), Research in occupational
ous peoples in Taiwan-a social sustainability perspective. stress and well-being (Vol. 4, pp. 221–264). JAI Press.
PLoS One, 10(2), e0118305. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal. Yang, C., & Srinivasan, P. (2016). Life satisfaction and the pur-
pone.0118305 suit of happiness on Twitter. PLoS One, 11(3), e0150881.
Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the var- https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0150881
iance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal Yıldırım, D. C x., & Akinci, H. (2021). The dynamic relation-
of Econometrics, 126(1), 25–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. ships between the female labour force and the economic
jeconom.2004.02.005 growth. Journal of Economic Studies, 48(8), 1512–1527.
Wooldridge, J. (2012). Panel data models with heterogeneity and https://doi.org/10.1108/jes-05-2020-0227
endogeneity. Institute for Fiscal Studies.
Wright, T. A. (2005). The role of ‘happiness’ in organisational
research: Past, present and future directions. In P. L.

You might also like