You are on page 1of 9

Further Considerations on the Methodological Analysis of Segregation Indices

Author(s): Charles F. Cortese, R. Frank Falk and Jack K. Cohen


Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 41, No. 4 (Aug., 1976), pp. 630-637
Published by: American Sociological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2094840
Accessed: 04-03-2015 20:30 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Sociological
Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FURTHER CONSIDERATIONS ON THE METHODOLOGICAL
ANALYSIS OF SEGREGATION INDICES *

CHARLES F. CORTESE, R. FRANK FALK and JACK K. COHEN


University of Denver

American Sociological Review 1976, Vol. 41 (August): 630-637

The process of developing an adequate measure of segregation occupied the literaturefor


over a decade and culminated in the widespread use of the Index of Dissimilarity. The
inadequacies of this index, although identified by the Duncans (1955), remain with us
and largely have come to be ignored. This research further explores the difficulties per-
taining to limitations in the use and interpretationof the Index of Dissimilarity, demon-
strates some of the systematic biases resulting from these inadequacies and provides a
mathematical refinement which overcomes some of the major problems inherent in the
use of this index.

The concept of ecological segregation article was followed by criticism as well


has never been dealt with adequately in as the developmentof differentmeasures
definitionalterms (cf. Duncanand Duncan, (Hornseth, 1947; Jahn et al., 1948; Jahn,
1955:217). Instead of defining segregation, 1950; Williams, 1948; Cowgill and Cow-
most workhas consideredhow the opposite gill, 1951) whicheventuallyled to Duncan
of segregation-often called assimilation- and Duncan (1955) demonstratingthe
should be defined. A clear and proper mathematical relationships between the
definitionof assimilationis especiallyneces- segregationindices previouslypresented.
sary since,in fact, most attempts(including The Duncans suggested that the Index
ours) to measure relative segregation are of Dissimilarity(D) was the most useful
basedon a priori "ideal"distributions.That of these indices (1955:214-5) and it
is, the complicateddetails of geographical has, in fact, achieved preeminencein the
distributionand clusteringare ignored in measurementof segregation.Taeuber and
an effort to get a simple overall index of Taeuber (1965) have presented what is
segregation.Heretofore,the "ideal"distri- probably the most detailed discussion on
bution has usually been taken to be the the measurementof segregation to date.
even distribution.Jahn et al. (1947) were Figure 1, reproducedfrom Duncan and
concernedwith the questions inherent in Duncan (1955), shows a geometricaldef-
such operationalizationof the concept of inition of D as the maximumvertical dis-
"ecologicalsegregation."In that early arti- tance between the "segregationcurve"and
cle, they formulatedtheir index of dissim- the curve Y = X. The segregationcurve
ilarityon the expectedvalue of the central is the plot of the cumulativeproportionof
tendency of a random distribution.They whites versus the cumulativeproportionof
stated: "This means that if there is no nonwhites, where the respective cumula-
segregation,then members of a minority tions are obtained by taking the census
racial group will be distributedrandomly tracts in order of increasingnonwhiteper-
throughoutthe various census tracts of a centages.
city. For example, if ten percent of the The Duncans provideda set of inade-
population of a city is Negro, then each quacies and precautionarycommentsabout
census tract would be expected to have the interpretationof segregation indices.
a Negro populationof approximatelyten Our articlebuilds upon the Duncans'com-
percent" (Jahn et al., 1947:293). Their ments and further explores the "mathe-
maticalproperties[of the indices]of which
* This research was funded in part by a grant
their proponentswere unaware,and which
from N.S.F. through the UndergraduateResearch
Participation Program, Grant Number GY-9959. lead to difficultiesof interpretation" (Dun-
The position of authors' names does not imply can and Duncan, 1955:210). The objec-
ordinal properties. tions to D have resultedin earlierattempts
630

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ANALYSIS OF SEGREGATIONINDICES 631
throughoutthe population. Our research
Figure I
has focused on an examination of the
random fluctuationsaround this expecta-
tion as significantinformation.It is our
argument that the opposite of segrega-
tion is more appropriatelya randomness
D of distributionratherthan an hypothetical
"evenness." It might be natural, there-
fore, to construct an index which takes
the value of zero when the distributionis
0.
random.However,due to the extensiveuse
of D, we preferto accountfor randomness
by computing the expected value of D
o X. Cum. Prop. of Nonwhites ? under the hypothesisthat the distribution
of nonwhites in any census tract is ran-
dom. That is, one could compute a value
to correct the measure (cf. Leasure and for D which would be expected,given that
Stem, 1968), but thus far it seems the the minority population were distributed
major problems are yet to be dealt with randomlythroughoutthe entirepopulation.
adequately. More explicitly,we assumethat for a cen-
sus unit with Ti residents, we randomly
Objectionsto D select without replacement, Ti individuals
from the total populationof the city. To
The major objections to the Index of computethe expectedvalueof D, one needs
Dissimilarityfollow: the probabilitythat the number of non-
1. The expectationof "evenness"as the whites (Ni) has some particular value
oppositeof segregationis not as use- (ni). The assumptionsof samplingwith-
ful in most cases as the concept of out replacementand a populationdivided
"randomness."9 into two categories (i.e., white and non-
2. D is affected by differencesin the white) specifies that this probability is
proportion of the minority in the given by the hypergeometricdistribution
population, thus preventing inter- (see equation (2) below). It is our con-
city comparisons. tention that the comparisonof the actual
3. D is affected by the size (number D for a city with its expected value con-
of households) of the areal unit of tains more informationthan D itself and
analysis. can alleviate some of the limitations of
4. The present interpretationof D as D. This comparisonis most sensibly car-
the proportion of nonwhites who ried out in units of the standarddeviation
would have to change their tract of of D (cf. Bardwell,1971) underthe same
residenceto make the distributionof assumptionsused for the expected value
the minority even throughout the of D. To compute the standarddeviation
city (Duncan and Duncan, 1955: of D, one needs the joint probabilitythat
211) is misleadingsince it does not in two census units with populationsTi
include the concept of replacement and Tj, the numbers of nonwhites (N,
of the relocatedminority. and Nj) in those units have some particular
Some of these objections are obviously values (ni and nj).
interrelated.We will deal with each briefly. In general, anytimethat more than one
The idealof evennesshas been used pre- census unit is involved in the placement
dominatelyas illustratedby the fact that of a given total number of individuals,
the zero point of most of the indices dis- interdependencyexists. This interdepen-
cussed by the Duncans (1955), including dency is accountedfor by the joint proba-
the Index of Dissimilarity itself, occurs bility distributionin the calculationof the
when the minority is distributed evenly standarddeviation.

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
632 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW
The joint distributionwas derived by that the random fluctuationscan make a
conceptuallyselecting Ti plus Tj individ- significantdifferencein the expectedvalue
uals for the two census units and then of D. The pattern is apparent-as q in-
selecting Ti of these for the ith unit. This creases to .5, the expected value of D de-
joint probabilityis given by the product creases. This relationship,of course, re-
of two hypergeometric distributions as verses as q exceeds .5. For example,a city
shownin equation(3) of the appendix. with only 5% of the populationnonwhite
We proposethat the "standardscore"of and a low density, such as 10 households
D, per block, has an expected value of D of
.63 even when the population has been
ZYD
(=1 ) residentiallydistributedwithout regard to
race or any other demographiccharacter-
is more meaningfulthan D itself. istic. An observed D value of .63 easily
An additionalmotivationfor building can be misinterpretedas evidence of a
uponD is that even thoughevennesswould highly segregatedcity when, in fact, it cor-
not occur naturally, evenness is often a respondsto no segregation.In otherwords,
social goal. Examples of this are recent this score is a result of particularvalues
policies and attemptsto distributeminority of q and N and not of any reality of seg-
teachersevenly througha school system. regation.It is thereforemeaninglessto use
The other three objectionsor limitations D to compare the relative segregationof
raised above have been previouslypointed this city to a city, which is 40% black
out but not clearly demonstrated(Dun- and has one hundredhouseholdsper block,
can and Duncan, 1955:216). Jahn et al. which has an expected score of .08 when
(1947:294) stated that "a satisfactory there is an equal lack of segregation.If
measure of ecological segregationshould we were simply to subtractout the effects
... not be distorted by . . . the proportion of proportionand density (accomplished
of Negroes."D is affectedby the propor- by observed D minus expected D), we
tion of nonwhitesin a particularcity and would have a more realisticstartingpoint
is furtheraffectedby the numberof house- than the conventional zero assumption.
holds per unit of analysis (Taeuber and We have suggestedthat the magnitudeof
Taeuber, 1965:231-5). We demonstrate this differenceis most sensibly carriedout
these effects in Table 1 which provides in units of the standarddeviation.Thus the
the expected value of the Index of Dis- scores in Table 1 shouldbe consideredthe
similarityfor computer-generatedrandom zero points under the random assignment
placementwith varyingproportionsof non- of the populationto the census units. By
whites and under the ideal conditions of employingthe standardscore correspond-
many areal units with an equal numberof ing to D for a particularcity with its par-
householdsin each unit. ticular proportionof nonwhites and with
The expected values in Table 1 shows its particularblock structure,we obtain an

Table 1. Expected Value of the Index of Dissimilarity I with Random Placement of Nonwhites
throughout a City
(N) Number of Households in Each Areal Unit (e.g., Block)
10 25 50 100 1000
.01 .914 .786 .611 .370 .127
(q) Proportionof .02 .833 .615 .372 .273 .090
Minority in the .05 .630 .369 .264 .180 .043
City's Population .10 .387 .272 .185 .132 .042
.20 .301 .196 .140 .099 .032
.30 .266 .176 .122 .087 .028
.40 .250 .161 .114 .081 .026
.50 .246 .161 .112 .080 .025
a The range of Index of Dissimilarity may vary from 0.000 to 1.000. The values in this table

were computed by use of the binomial approximation;see Appendix, equation (21).

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ANALYSIS OF SEGREGATIONINDICES 633
improvedmeasure of segregationfor that Z DEEAD
city. Of course, the issue of the proper D
unit of analysis remains moot and our
proposed analysis can be carried out for as an improved measure of segregation.
any choice for which the appropriatecen- Here D is the measure of deviationfrom
sus data are available. evenness employed by the Duncans. The
Despite the fact that the value of D quantity,1D may be interpretedas the value
is affectedby the proportionof nonwhites of D which would be achievedif race had
and the block structure,and thus partially no effect on the residential distribution.
vitiates intercity comparisons,such com- The value of Z gives the degree to which
parisons have often been made in the the actualdistributiondiffersfrom random-
literature (cf. Taeuber and Taeuber, ness as measuredin standardscores.
1965; Bahr and Gibbs, 1967). The Taeu- Since the exact distributionof Z is yet
bers (1965:215) have stated, "Our pur- to be determined,no probabilisticinterpre-
pose in computingsegregationindexes is tation of Z is yet possible. However,what
to permit intercitycomparisons,and there we have providedis a necessaryfirst step
must be some sense in which equal values which does improveD in allowing,appar-
mean equal degrees of segregation."The ently for the first time, the comparisonof
proposedstandardscore measureincreases cities with differentnonwhite percentages.
the validityof such comparisons. In addition, studies of one city over
We have suggested another objection time have always been suspect due to the
which pertainsto the interpretationof the strong possibilitythat q has changed over
index. D is interpretedas the proportion the time period. Our improvementnow
of nonwhites who would have to change allows us to deal with this.
their tract of residenceto make the distri- If our basic idea for improvingD is ac-
butionof the minorityeven throughoutthe ceptable,the next step is the determination
city (Duncan and Duncan, 1955:211). of the distributionof Z exactly or approxi-
Such an interpretationis misleadingin that mately or empirically.By empiricallywe
D gives the proportionof the minoritythat mean a categorizationof cities by their
would have to be moved withoutreplacing Z-scores. For example, the knowledge of
them with whites. In particular,if the cen- which cities have Z-scores between 0 and
sus tract were wholly populated by a 1, between 1 and 2, etc. would, by itself,
minority, the entire tract would have to be valuableinformation.In fact, we believe
be evacuatedin this interpretation.Actu- that such informationis probably more
ally, what is often desiredis the proportion important to sociologists than the exact
of minoritypopulationwhich would have statisticalprobabilitiesof occurrence.These
to be exchangedwhile keepingthe number calculationscould be accomplishedusing
of householdsper unit constant.It will be the formulaein our mathematicalappendix.
shown in equation (9) below that this While the details of computing Z are
"exchange proportion"is, in fact, given left to the appendix,we now make precise
by (l-q)D where q is the proportionof what we mean by the "hypothesisof ran-
the minorityin the population.' domness."Suppose that a given city has
k census units containingrespectivelyT1,
The Standard Score Index T2, . . ., Tk households and suppose that
Our proposalis to computethe expected the city-wide proportion of nonwhites is
value of D (,AD) and the variance of D q. We conceive of each unit of size T1 as
(0f2D) under the hypothesis of random- being a randomsamplefrom the total pop-
ness and to use the standardscore ulation, T. We assume the samples are to
be selected without replacement,that is,
1 Professor Taeuber has reminded us, in cor- we exclude the possibility that the same
respondence, that Duncan had pointed this out person occupies two or more residences.
(see Taeuber and Taeuber, 1965: 30f.) and that Therefore,the distributionof N1, the num-
Farley and Taeuber (1968:955) have used this
formula, identifying it as the "replacement in- ber of nonwhites in unit, is hypergeo-
dex." metric: that is,

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
634 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

qT
{ 8 (l-q)T For our second example,we again con-
T
ni sider a city composedof two census tracts,
Prop (N1 = n )Ti-n 2)
O but now N1 = 0, Wi 150, and N2= 30,
-

(Ti)
W2 = 0 (i.e., a completelysegregatedcity).
Here, to bring about evenness without
We conclude this section by making a replacement,we must close down tract 2
general observationabout indices. If one completelyand move all its Ns to tract 1.
has a useful index and also a theorywhich 30
explainssome of the obvious and less rel- This is a proportion of -3 1 of the
30
evant factors (e.g., random effects), one minority.Fromthe formulafor D, we have:
can alwayspartialout these factorsby con-
structinga Z-score analogousto that pre-
sented above. D= ?/2(l 0 150 30 0

The Exchange Proportion Problem again in agreementwith our interpretation.


To obtain the result,we introduceT=
We now turn to a discussion of the Ni + WI, the total numberof residentsin
interpretationof D as the proportionof tract i; and T = N+ W, the total number
minoritywhich would have to change cen-
sus tracts to bring about evenness. We of residentsin the city; qi N the pro-
asserted above that D actually gives this portion of nonwhitesin tract i; and q
proportion on the assumption that the N
minority residents are not replaced by the city-wideproportionof nonwhites.
majorityresidents.We illustratethis point
with two simpleexamplesbefore passingto Considera census tract i for which we
the general case. If in the ith census tract have too high a proportionof the minority,
there are Ni nonwhitesand WI whites and i.e., qi>q. We must remove enough non-
if in the city there are N E Ni non- whites from this tract to bring this propor-
i tion down to q. Say we remove RI: since
whites and W . WI whites, then (see we do not replace these people we require
-

i -
Duncan and Duncan, 1955) q Ni Ri (4)
k N1 W,
D =1/2 (3) Solving the equationfor RI, we have
| N W
R= Ni -Tiq (5)
(5 T,(qj-q)
1- q 1- -q
Here k denotes the total numberof census
tractsin the city. Thus, from all the census tracts with too
For our firstexample,we considera city large a proportion of nonwhites, we re-
with only two tracts for which N1 = 10, move
W1 150, and N2 30, W2 =150.
Clearly, to bring about evenness without EvRj 1q vTj(q -q).
replacement, we need merely to move
10 Ns from tract 2 to tract 1. This is a qi>q qj>q
10 That is, a proportion
proportion ?1/4of the minority.From
the above formulafor D we have: qj > q
D =1/2 /10-3150 +30 _150 1/4
(6)
40 300 40 300~ (1 q) qT q >q
in agreementwith our interpretation.Note is removed (recall q = N/T). We now
that if tract 1 had only 160 (N1 + W1) claim that the quantityon the right hand
residentialunits, this would not be a prac- side of equation (6) is equal to D. To es-
tical way of achievingevenness. tablish this, we note that

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ANALYSIS OF SEGREGATION INDICES 635

k k Therefore,once we have computedD, the


l Ti (qi -q) E(Ni Tiq) proportion of the nonwhite, white, and
the total population that must exchange
N-Tq=O; places to achieveevenness are respectively
hence, the proportion removed can be writ- given by
ten as (1 - q)D, qD, 2q(1 - q). (9)
1 k
2(1 -q)qT i-1 Conclusion
We feel that the objectionsto D which
1 k have been voiced previouslyby others or
2(1 -q)qT i
>1Ni-TIqJ (7) have been raised by us are not minor in
since theireffecton the use of the index. Table 1
clearly demonstratesthat the effects of q
Ni -Tiq =Ni -(Ni + Wi) q and N are not "loose"but do in fact pro-
(1-q) Ni-qWi, duce a systematicdeviation.
the proportion removed is The corrections suggested here should
go far toward allowing for meaningful
I k Ni Wi intercitycomparisonsas well as providinga
2 i-1 qT (q)T more practicalinterpretationof the index.
The former is made possible throughthe
1 i~~
k JN~~~wJ
Ni _Wi|D (8)
(8 use of the standardscores while the latter
is aidedby the use of the exchangepropor-
tion formulas(9).
as we see by equation (3). Therefore, our
It mustbe pointedout that the qualifica-
interpretation of D as the proportion of the
tions and modifications we have intro-
minority removed without replacement is
duced have equal, if not greater,applica-
established.
bility in the use of D outside the confines
As stated earlier, what is usually desired
of residential segregation. Multivariate
is the proportion of the minority which
analyses have used the index for several
would have to be exchanged with the ma- measures of differentiationor have in-
jority to achieve evenness. Fortunately this cluded the proportionof nonwhitesas an
quantity has a simple expression in terms
independent or intervening variable (cf.
of D as we shall now show. Since we now
Jiobu and Marshall, 1971). Our findings
replace those moved, equation (4) be- stronglysuggestthat there is a high degree
comes of confoundingeffect when q and D ap-
q Ni-Ri pear along with intercity comparisonsin
T1 multivariatemodels.
and in place of (5) we have
MATHEMATICAL APPENDIX
Rt= Ni - qTi Ti (qi - q).
Thus the proportion removed throughout In computingAD and C2D,we assume
the city is: that the Ti residentsof the ith census unit
are a randomsample selected without re-
I
N >iq = Y. Ti (qi -q) placementfrom the total populationof size
qi >q q i> q T. Thus the probabilitydistributionof N1,
(1 - q)D. the numberof nonwhitesin the ith census
unit, is given by the hypergeometricdis-
Here the last equality follows from (7, 8). tribution,
Similarly, the proportion of the majority
that must change tracts to bring about Pi Prob(NI ni)
evenness is qD and the proportion of the JT8(I q)Tj
total population that must move is: ni TVT -n,
(1 - q) D * T + qD yW 2q (1 -q) D. n () T-n * (1)

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
636 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
Furthermore,if we define Turning to the computation of a2D, we
have, from (7)
sij = ni + n; (2)
the joint distributionof the nonwhitepop- 1-f k
a2D= { Var(jNi Aij)+
ulationsNi and Nj on the ith and jth census i 1
units is given by
E Cov (INi -|, INjI- /tjl)}. (12)
Pii Prob(Ni =ni, Nj =nj)- (3) i7j
T, 8 Tj t qTy(l q)T Now
ni sJ
s- ni J sij ATi + Tj -sij Varf jNj ,Aij) =E((Ni /Ai)2)
( T ) -E2(INi-,I) =ai2- el2 (13)
iJ Ti +
Tj)(
and
Since the mean and varianceof a hyper-
geometric distribution are well known Cov(jNi -JIiI, Nj -j I)
=E(INi-iLj NjN-/Lj,)
(Hays and Winkler, 1970), we have at -E(INi /j-11) E(INj-MkjI) (14)
once =eij - ejej.
,ui~_E[NJ = qTi (4)
Thus,
and
1 k
T-T.i ,2D (2
Gr +
ai2 E[(Ni ,Ai)'] Tiq( - q) j-{ _et2)
i=1
(5) V (ejj -eej)) (15)
From equations (7, 8) of the text we
have 1 k k )
-2 { >S2 e( i2 + eij}.
k i 1 i-1 i7&j
D-2q(1 11 i Ni-qT1l. (6)
2q1- q)T -1 Finally,using (11),
Thus from (4), 1 k
a2D= 2 a{ i2D)2.
1 k
D - Y. Ni -All, (7) (16)
Bi 1
Equations (11) and (16) of this ap-
where
pendix constitute theoretical expressions
B 2q(1 -q)T. (8) for ADand a2D. In practice,however,vari-
This is the form of D that we shall use for ous simplifications and approximations
computingtheoretical expressions for /AD would be employed to simplify the calcu-
and a2D. lations. We now briefly indicate some of
We definethe followingexpectations: the most obvious of these.
In general,since E[(Ni -M)] 0, equa-
Ti tion (9) can be replacedby
ei =E[Ni y- il] Y Ini -/ilPi (9)
ni =? INT (i)
eij = E[lNi K-/il INj - /%jl]
ei=2 V (Ai -ni) Pi, (17)
ni=0
Ti+Tj si
- -
Ini AiI(sij ni) -,jI Pij where INT(,Ai)is the greatestinteger less
sij=O nI=O than or equal to Mi.
(10)
We now consider some simplifications
Then, we have at once, arising from approximatingthe hypergeo-
k metric distributioneither by the binomial
I or by the normal distribution.We employ
ID E(D) Y, ei. (11)
i 1 the notation,

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ANALYSIS OF SEGREGATIONINDICES 637
Cowgill, Donald 0. and Mary S. Cowgill
B(n, q; x) (n )qx (1 q)n-x, (18) 1951 "An index of segregation based on
block statistics." American Sociological
for the binomial probabilities. In most Review 16:825-31.
demographicstudies,the census unit popu- Cramer, Harald
1946 Mathematical Methods of Statistics.
lations Ti are all much smaller than the Princeton: Princeton University Press.
total populationT. In this case, it is per- Duncan, 0. D. and Beverly Duncan
missibleto replace (1) by 1955 "A methodological analysis of segrega-
tion indices." American Sociological
Pi Prob(Ni Bni) B(Ti, q; ni). ( 19) Review 20:210-7.
Farley, Reynolds and Karl E. Taeuber
By a result derived by Cramer (1946), 1968 "Population trends and residential seg-
Bardwell (1971) and others, we have in regation since 1960." Science 159:953-
this approximation 6.
Hays, William L. and Robert L. Winkler
ei- 2 Si(1 -q) B(Ti, q; Si), Si 1+ 1970 Statitics, Vol. I. Holt-Rinehart-Win-
INTOAO), (20) ston.
Hornseth, Richard A.
and thus 1947 "A note on 'The measurement of eco-
logical segregation' by Julius Jahn, Cal-
1 k vin F. Schmid and Clarence Schrag."
,a- Y.ESiB (Ti, q; Si), Ti < < T. American Sociological Review 12:603-
qTi 4.
(21) Jahn, Julius A.
1950 "The measurement of segregation: der-
If furtherTi q( 1 - q) is large for all the ivation on an index based on the cri-
terion of reproducibility." American
T,, then the normal approximationto the Sociological Review 15:100-4.
binomialmay be employedin (21) and we Jahn, Julius A., Calvin F. Schmidt and Clarence
obtain Schrag
1947 "The measurement of ecological segre-
1 k gation." American Sociological Review
T\/27rq(1-q) i-1 12:293-303.
1948 "Rejoinder to Dr. Hornseth's note on
Ti<<T, 1<<Tiq(1-q). (22) 'The measurement of ecological segre-
gation.'" American Sociological Re-
Similarly,a topic of further investigation Review 13:216-7.
is the considerationof the analogoussim- Jiobu, Robert M. and Harvey H. Marshall, Jr.
plificationsof Pij and their consequences 1971 "Urban structure and the differentiation
for o2D. between blacks and whites." American
Sociological Review 36:638-49.
REFERENCES Leasure, J. William and David H. Stern
Bahr, Howard M. and Jack P. Gibbs 1968 "A note on housing segregation in-
1967 "Racial differentiation in American dexes." Social Forces 46:406-7.
metropolitan areas." Social Forces 45: Taeuber, Karl E. and Alma F. Taeuber
521-32. 1965 Negroes in Cities. Chicago: Aldine.
Bardwell, George Williams, Josephine J.
1971 Segregation-A Social Account. Den- 1948 "Another commentary on so-called seg-
ver: Colorado Civil Rights Commis- regation indices." American Sociologi-
sion. cal Review 13:298-303.

This content downloaded from 129.108.202.79 on Wed, 04 Mar 2015 20:30:35 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like