You are on page 1of 14

Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Labour Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/labeco

Fathers’ parental leave-taking, childcare involvement and labor market


participation
Marcus Tamm a,b,∗
a
RWI, Invalidenstr. 112, 10115 Berlin, Germany
b
IZA, Germany

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

JEL classification: This study analyzes the effect of fathers’ parental leave-taking on the time fathers spend with their children and
H31 with household duties and on fathers’ labor supply. Fathers’ leave-taking is highly selective and the identification
J13 of causal effects relies on within-father differences in leave-taking for first and higher order children that were
J22
triggered by a policy reform promoting more gender equality in leave-taking. Results show that even short periods
Keywords: of fathers’ parental leave may have long-lasting effects on fathers’ involvement in childcare and housework. Effects
Parental leave on labor supply do not persist over time.
Childcare
Policy evaluation

1. Introduction leave which replaces 67% of pre-childbirth labor income of the parent
who is on leave. Out of the 14 months of paid leave for the family two
There is extensive evidence that women have lower rates of employ- months are reserved for the mother and two months for the father. The
ment than men and lower wages if employed (OECD 2017). These dif- introduction of the two daddy months led to a strong increase of fathers’
ferences are much larger for mothers than for childless women and it leave taking.
has been argued that it is the birth of children and specifically the birth A straight forward strategy to evaluate the impact of leave taking
of the first child which is one of the main triggers for the divergence would be to compare fathers’ involvement in childcare and home pro-
of labor market outcomes of men and women (e.g. Waldfogel 1998a, duction for families with children born shortly before the policy reform
1998b; Bertrand et al., 2010; Angelov et al., 2016). Yet, this may differ and families with children born shortly after the reform in a kind of re-
between countries. At the same time it is well known that within fami- gression discontinuity setting. Such a strategy allows to obtain estimates
lies it is mainly mothers who leave the labor market for the first couple that are not contaminated by selection of specific fathers into leave. Sev-
of months after childbirth and who take care of the child. Even several eral papers on the effects of fathers’ leave taking follow this approach
years after childbirth mothers continue to dedicate more time to child- (e.g. Ekberg et al., 2013; Cools et al., 2015; Kotsadam and Finseraas,
care and housework than fathers (Bianchi 2000; Bianchi et al., 2000). 2011; Patnaik, 2019; Farré and González, 2018). In the German set-
Several studies document that time out of the labor market for childcare ting, however, this identification strategy is problematic because the re-
has long lasting effects on employment, earnings and wages of women form implementing the father quota also changed other aspects of leave-
(Shapiro and Mott, 1994; Lundberg and Rose, 2000). taking. For example, before 2007 the leave benefit was means-tested
In order to achieve a more equal division of childcare, housework and comprised a flat benefit that was unrelated to pre-childbirth labor
and employment between mothers and fathers, several countries intro- income. From 2007 onwards eligibility was not means-tested, and the
duced father quotas for parental leave, e.g. Norway, Sweden, Iceland, benefit replaced 67% of individual pre-childbirth labor income. These
Germany and France. These quotas or daddy months are intended to other aspects of the reform might also influence fathers’ involvement in
incentivize fathers to take leave and to engage more in childcare and the household, and a comparison similar to a regression discontinuity
housework. This paper analyzes whether fathers’ leave-taking actually design would measure the combined effect of all elements of the reform
does influence fathers’ involvement in childcare and home production, and not the isolated effect of the daddy months.
for the case of Germany. In 2007 Germany introduced a new system of Thus, in contrast to the previous literature, the analysis in this pa-
paid parental leave. Overall parents are eligible to 14 months of paid per does not rely on a regression discontinuity approach. Rather, the


Correspondence to: RWI, Invalidenstr. 112, 10115 Berlin, Germany.
E-mail address: tamm@rwi-essen.de

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2019.04.007
Received 8 October 2018; Received in revised form 18 March 2019; Accepted 6 April 2019
Available online 8 April 2019
0927-5371/© 2019 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

analysis looks at the actual take-up of leave of fathers. In order to get leave and that this effect persist almost 15 years after childbirth. Analyz-
rid of selection effects, the analysis relies on within-father differences in ing a reform in Quebec Patnaik (2019) shows that fathers’ involvement
leave-taking that were triggered by the policy reform in 2007. This strat- in childcare and domestic work increases as well as maternal employ-
egy aims at combining the advantages of fixed effects models to remove ment, while fathers’ employment is not significantly affected by the in-
any differences in observed and unobserved factors that are stable over troduction of daddy months. Similarly, Farré and González (2018) show
time between fathers who are taking leave and those who are not taking that the introduction of two weeks of paternity leave in Spain increases
leave (e.g. motivation, beliefs or preferences) and the advantages of nat- maternal employment rates, while leaving fathers’ labor market attach-
ural experiments to provide an exogenous source of variation in fathers’ ment unchanged.
leave-taking. Specifically, we analyze the behavior of fathers with a first Our results indicate that fathers’ leave-taking significantly boosts the
childbirth before 2007, i.e. before the reform, and a second or higher time fathers dedicate to childcare and housework and that this is also
order childbirth in 2007 or afterwards, i.e. after the reform. Because be- the case after fathers’ return from leave. Furthermore, fathers’ working
fore 2007 hardly any father took parental leave, we assume that fathers’ hours are significantly reduced by fathers’ leave-taking, but these labor
behavior for children born before 2007 reflects fathers’ preferences for market effects seem to be rather short-lived.
family involvement. This is captured in the father fixed effect. In ad- The paper is structured as follows. A description of the 2007 re-
dition, the specification includes time trends in a cubic specification. form of parental leave in Germany is provided in the second section.
These are assumed to capture the impact of the other elements of the Section 3 presents the data and discusses the identification strategy. Re-
reform in 2007 and aspects such as the expansion of early child care sults are shown in Section 4. Section 5 presents tests supporting the
facilities. The impact of fathers’ leave taking is thus estimated by the assumptions of the identification strategy and discusses the generaliz-
change in behavior of fathers taking leave after the reform relative to ability of the results. A conclusion is provided in Section 6.
their pre-reform behavior in comparison with the change in behavior
of fathers not taking leave after the reform relative to their pre-reform 2. The policy reform
behavior.
The main identification assumption is that changes in behavior be- In 2007 Germany introduced a new system of paid parental leave.
tween the first and higher order births would have been similar for fa- This reform applied to all parents of children born on 1st of January
thers who take leave when the higher order child is born and for fa- 2007 or later and introduced a father quota. Overall, families were el-
ther who do not take leave if the daddy months had not been intro- igible to 14 months of paid parental leave out of which two months
duced. Among others, this implies that the other elements of the 2007 were reserved for the father and two months for the mother. The fam-
reform do not differ in their impact on fathers’ behavior between both ily would lose the two daddy months if the father did not use them.
kinds of fathers. The robustness section includes several tests that probe Paid leave had to be taken during the first 14 months after childbirth
the identification assumption. For example, we present several specifi- and parents might take leave consecutively or in parallel. Each parent
cations that control for factors that might influence the impact of the taking paid leave would have to take at least two months, i.e. it was
other elements of the reform and the take-up of leave by the father, not allowed that fathers took one month only. This implies that the
such as mother’s and father’s pre-childbirth labor market participation, choice set of fathers was to take either (i) no leave, (ii) exactly two
the pre-childbirth wages or the relative position of father’s labor income months of paid leave or (iii) more than two months of paid leave, up
compared to mother’s labor income. to 12 months at most. The latter required mothers to take less than 12
This paper contributes to the literature on paternal leave and to the months of paid leave. For each month a mother or a father is on parental
more general literature on gender differences in labor market participa- leave the parent receives benefits replacing 67% of his/her individual
tion and home production by asking whether parental leave of fathers pre-childbirth net labor earning. (Note that the amount of the monthly
influences (i) fathers’ involvement in childcare and housework as well as benefit does not depend on whether the other parent takes leave as
(ii) fathers’ employment. The analysis focusses on short and long-term well or on the labor earning of the other parent.) Besides the introduc-
effects, measured up to six years after childbirth. The previous litera- tion of a father quota the reform in 2007 included other changes as
ture estimating causal effects of fathers’ leave-taking is rather small and well: (i) the overall duration of paid leave was reduced from 24 months
inconclusive. For example, Ekberg et al. (2013) analyze a reform in Swe- for either mother or father to 14 months for both parents combined,
den that reserved one month of parental leave for fathers. They do not (ii) means-testing was abolished, (iii) the monthly benefit was changed
find that fathers’ parental leave affects childcare involvement, which from a flat rate unrelated to pre-childbirth labor earnings to a benefit
they measure using leave taken for care of sick children, or fathers’ and replacing 67% of pre-childbirth labor earnings. The latter implied that
mothers’ long-term employment and wages. Cools et al. (2015) analyze for the majority of parents the monthly benefit increased considerably,
reforms in Norway and find that mothers’ labor market outcomes do specifically for those parents with pre-childbirth labor market attach-
not significantly improve due to a father quota. However, fathers’ take- ment. Also note that the job protection period remained unchanged at
up of parental leave improves children’s school performance at the end 36 months.
of lower secondary education. According to Cools et al. (2015) men’s Administrative data reveal that the reform considerably increased
earnings are not affected by leave-taking which is in contrast to find- the share of fathers taking parental leave. Before the reform the share
ings by Rege and Solli (2013) who analyze the same Norwegian reform of fathers on leave was estimated to be no more than 3%. For fathers
and show that parental leave reduces fathers’ earnings significantly.1 with children born in 2007, i.e. the first cohort after the reform, the
With regard to the division of household tasks Kotsadam and Finser- share was 15% and steadily increased to 34% for fathers with chil-
aas (2011) show that fathers are more involved in the task of washing dren born in 2014 (Huebener et al., 2016). This increase in fathers’
clothes but not in other tasks such as cooking or cleaning if they took leave-taking might be due to the father quota but also due to the
other elements of the reform, such as the change from a flat benefit
1
to a replacement rate. Most fathers taking leave decide to take exactly
According to Rege and Solli (2013) the difference between their results and
two months of paid leave and few families share paid leave equally
those in Cools et al. (2015) is due to analyzing different samples of fathers.
between both parents. RWI (2008) and Reich (2011) show that fa-
While Cools et al. (2015) compare fathers with children born shortly before
and after the reform, Rege and Solli (2013) also look at fathers further away thers’ take-up of leave is highly selective. The probability of fathers’
from the reform cutoff. This implies that in Cools et al. (2015) the post-reform leave-taking is higher for highly educated fathers, for older fathers, in
uptake of parental leave by fathers is still relatively low and highly selective, households where the mother was working before childbirth and in
while it is more common and less selective in the sample analyzed by Rege and particular if mothers’ hours of work were higher than fathers’ hours
Solli (2013). of work.

185
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

3. Data and identification strategy RWI (2008) and Reich (2011). A comparison of fathers with children
born shortly before or after the reform in a regression discontinuity set-
The analysis uses data from the Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP v31.1). ting, however, is also unlikely to generate causal estimates of fathers’
SOEP is a representative longitudinal study of households in Germany leave-taking, as the reform in 2007 included other changes as well. Any
running since 1984. On an annual basis individuals provide, among oth- comparison of parents giving birth before and after the reform will also
ers, information on demographic events, lifestyle and labor market par- reflect behavioral changes due to the other elements of the 2007 re-
ticipation of all household members. More than 11,000 households with form.2
more than 30,000 individuals participate in SOEP each year. The anal- If we are interested in separately identifying the effects of fathers’
ysis focuses on information from the years 2000–2015. leave-taking we will, therefore, have to look at the actual take-up but
In the interview, information on parental leave is collected retro- will at the same time have to account for the selectivity of take-up.
spectively on a monthly basis for the entire preceding year. We define The analysis does so by estimating fixed effects models that identify
that fathers took (paid) parental leave for a specific child if they were on the effects of differences in leave-taking between first and higher or-
leave in any of the 14 months following the birth of the child. According der children. In general, such differences in leave-taking within fathers
to the SOEP data, around 3% of all men becoming father in the years might be selective as well. For example, if a father took leave for the
2000–2006 took parental leave, while for all men becoming father after first child but not for the second this might be due to a more demanding
2006 (and up to the year 2012) the rate is 23%. These rates are only job position at the time of second childbirth which might itself have an
slightly smaller than the official statistics based on administrative data impact on fathers’ involvement in childcare and housework. Or it might
(cf. Section 2). be that a father took no leave when the first child was born but since
Column 1 of Table A1 in the appendix shows regression results using the mother was not satisfied with the division of housework he decides
fathers’ leave taking as dependent variable for a sample of fathers with to adjust his contribution to housework and when the second child is
first childbirth between 2000 and 2012. In the first specification in Panel born also takes parental leave. To circumvent the problem of selectivity
A fathers’ leave taking is regressed on a dummy variable indicating all in within-father-differences in leave-taking the analysis resorts to the
births after the reform. In the ensuing specifications (Panels B to I) sev- 2007 reform of parental leave and applies the fixed effects model to a
eral control factors as well as interaction terms with the reform dummy sample of fathers who had a first child before the reform and a higher
are included. Here, we specifically look at factors that are related to the order child after the reform. The analysis argues that the increase in the
amount of the leave benefit or that might influence the intra-household take-up of parental leave for the higher order child is mainly due to the
division of work between parents. The table indicates that after the re- reform. Given the low share of fathers’ taking leave before the reform
form the share of fathers taking leave increased by a significant 21 per- this is plausible.
centage points (Panel A). The interaction term with pre-childbirth work- The regression equation is modeled as follows:
ing hours indicates that the increase is somewhat larger among fathers
whose partner has a higher number of pre-childbirth working hours but 𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖 + 𝛽Paternal leave𝑖𝑡 + 𝑋𝑖𝑡′ 𝛿 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 (1)
does not depend on the number of fathers’ own pre-childbirth work-
where y is the outcome of father i measured at time t. Paternal leave
ing hours (Panel B) nor on the pre-childbirth hourly wage of mother
is a dummy variable indicating whether the father took parental leave
or father (Panel C) or the relative position of father’s pre-childbirth la-
for the child which is his youngest at time t. X controls for factors that
bor income compared to mother’s pre-childbirth labor income (Panel
change over time, specifically the number of children of the father and
D). The latter is measured using an indicator variable for whether fa-
the age of the youngest child. To account for overall changes in fathers’
ther’s pre-birth earning is higher, about equal or lower than mother’s
behavior over time the analysis also controls for time trends using a cu-
pre-birth earning, with “about equal earnings” being defined as those
bic specification. All differences between fathers with and without leave
where mother’s pre-birth labor income is between 90% and 110% of
that are constant over time are captured in 𝛼 i . If, for example, it is mostly
father’s. Panel E shows that the increase in leave taking is smaller by
fathers taking leave after the reform who would have been highly in-
around 5 percentage points for second or higher order births. The addi-
volved in childcare and housework even in the absence of leave-taking
tional three-way interaction terms between the reform ∗ higher-order-
this will be captured in 𝛼 i . The model is able to identify these fixed
birth dummy and pre-childbirth working hours, wages or the relative
effects because before the reform hardly any father took leave. It as-
position of father’s income compared to mother’s are never significant
sumes that fathers who would have been highly involved in childcare
(Panels G–I).
and housework even in the absence of leave-taking already display such
The main variables of interest are fathers’ time dedicated to childcare
high involvement after the birth of their first child when they were not
and housework and their hours of work on the labor market. Information
on leave. 𝛽 measures the causal effect of treatment on the treated, i.e.
on time dedicated to childcare and housework are collected annually. In
the impact on families where fathers actually take parental leave. Any
the interview individuals are shown a list of activities and are asked how
influence of the 2007 reform on behavior of families in general that
many hours per day they spend on these activities on a typical week-
might, e.g., stem from the fact that the government introduced a father
day. The list of activities includes job, education and training, errands,
quota and promoted fathers’ involvement in childcare and that also af-
housework, childcare, care for other persons in need of care, repairs on
fected families where fathers did not take leave are not covered by the
the house/car and garden work as well as hobbies and other free time
estimate. Note that the estimated treatment effect is not able to sep-
activities. Every second year similar questions are asked for activities on
arately identify the impact of the additional time fathers spend with
Saturdays and on Sundays. With respect to labor market participation
their children, rather the decision of fathers to take paid leave might
the analysis focuses on actual weekly hours of work, including possible
simultaneously influence the behavior of mothers to reduce their time
over-time. Note that individuals not working on the labor market are
on leave. Thus, the effects we find represent the impact of the additional
accounted for by having zero hours of work. Fig. A1 in the appendix
time fathers spend with their children, of the (potentially) reduced time
shows how fathers’ time for childcare, for housework and for errands
mothers spend with their children and of the change in income associ-
differs by number of children, by age of the (youngest) child, and by
day of the week. Similarly, Fig. A2 in the appendix shows a graph for
fathers’ average working hours. 2
All analyses relying on such a regression discontinuity setting that ana-
Cross-sectional differences in fathers’ time use between fathers tak- lyze the 2007 reform correctly interpret their findings to reflect the effects
ing leave and those not taking leave (see Fig. A3 in the appendix) are of the entire reform and not of a single element such as the father quota
unlikely to give the causal estimate of leave-taking given the ample (e.g. Bergemann and Riphahn, 2011; Kluve and Tamm, 2013; Schober, 2014;
evidence on selectivity in leave-taking that has been documented in Geyer et al., 2015; Cygan-Rehm, 2016; Kluve and Schmitz, 2018).

186
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

ated with receiving the leave benefit rather than fathers’ full working for fathers in our sample used for the fixed effects analysis separately
income. by leave status in the post-reform period. For these descriptives each
The identification assumptions of this model are that (i) without the father is considered once per child born after 2007. In comparison to
2007 reform and the increased attractiveness to take paid parental leave fathers not taking leave, fathers who take leave are more often highly
time trends in childcare- and housework-related behavior of fathers educated and have a partner who is highly educated, more involved
eventually taking parental leave and those not taking leave would have in the labor market before childbirth and receives a higher wage. This
changed in parallel and that (ii) differences in childcare- and housework- also leads to a higher share of families where mother and father have
related behavior by number of children of fathers taking leave and of about equal labor earnings or where mother’s earning is higher. These
those not taking leave are similar. The identification strategy would be patterns confirm findings in RWI (2008) and Reich (2011). In addition,
violated if, irrespective of the reform, involved fathers displayed an in- in our sample the share of East Germans is higher among fathers taking
crease in childcare time (and eventually take leave) when higher order leave and the share of those with migration background is smaller. In
children are born, while uninvolved fathers decreased childcare time contrast, there are no or only few differences with respect to the num-
(and do not take leave), e.g. as a response to higher specialization of ber of older siblings and the age of mother and father at the birth of the
parents. Another violation would be if the other elements of the 2007 child.
reform had differential effects for fathers taking leave and for those not
taking leave. Section 5 provides evidence that such violations of the 4. Results
identification strategy are unlikely to challenge the results.
Note that the main fixed effects analysis does not consider fathers We start this section by presenting descriptive differences in the de-
who had no child before the reform because gender differences in house- pendent variable between fathers who had a child between 2000 and
hold and market production are much lower before entry into parent- 2006 an those who had a child between 2007 and 2012. The sample is
hood. Thus, for fathers taking leave who had no child before 2007 it is identical to the one used for analyzing the change in the take-up of leave
unlikely that behavior before first childbirth is a good proxy for behav- by fathers in column 1 of Table A1 but uses all available father-child-
ior in the absence of the father quota. This is most evident when looking year observations, not only one per father-child pair. For this sample, a
at men’s time dedicated to childcare which is basically always zero for summary measure which we label as “family time” and which is defined
childless men. A closely related study is Bünning (2015) that also ap- as the sum of hours per weekday for childcare, for housework and for
plies father fixed effects models. In her analysis she includes first-time errands is regressed on an indicator for whether the child is born after
fathers who are observed between childbirth and take-up of parental the reform. In the ensuing specifications several control factors as well
leave. For first-time fathers she assumes that behavior during the first as interaction terms with the reform dummy are included. Furthermore,
few months after childbirth and before leave-taking provides a good all specifications control for the age of the youngest child. The results
comparison for behavior later on when the child is older. In doing so, of this before-after comparison in column 2 of Table A1 in the appendix
Bünning (2015) only considers a selective group of first-time fathers, show that fathers’ family time is higher by around half hour per weekday
namely those taking leave at the end of the 14 months leave period. for children born after the reform (Panel A). This estimate captures the
Other important differences between Bünning (2015) and this paper are impact of the introduction of the daddy months, of all other elements of
that we use a larger set of outcome variables including childcare and the 2007 reform as well as of all other changes taking place during that
housework on weekends and that we look at more long-term effects, time. Interestingly, most of the interaction terms in Panels B–I are not
not only at effects within the first or second year after leave-taking. significant. This might be seen as evidence that mothers’ and fathers’
By design of the comparison and the restriction to a sample of fami- pre-birth hours of work, wages and income, that a priori might be seen
lies who already had a first child, the treatment effect is estimated only as candidates for heterogeneity in the impact of the other elements of the
for families with more than one child and for fathers’ leave-taking with 2007 reform actually do not display significantly different time trends.
higher order children. In principal effects might differ by parity, for ex- This is supportive for the main identification strategy, specifically be-
ample because a smaller share of fathers takes leave for second or higher cause there is little indication of different time trends between first and
order births than for first children and thus selectivity into treatment dif- higher order births. Only for mothers’ wage there is some evidence that
fers (e.g. Sundström and Duvander, 2002). Therefore, Section 5 presents families with a second or higher order birth reacted differently after the
a discussion on the external validity of the findings and on whether these reform (see Panel H).
findings can be generalized to all families with fathers taking leave. Next we present our main results using father fixed effects models
As mentioned above, the sample for the main analysis using father for a sample of fathers who had a first childbirth before 2007 and a sec-
fixed effects comprises fathers who had a first childbirth before the 2007 ond or higher order childbirth after the reform. The fixed effects models
reform and a higher order birth after the reform and who participate in directly control for the take-up of leave by the father, to disentangle its
SOEP both before and after 2007. Overall there are 304 fathers in the effect from the effects of the other elements of the reform. And they con-
SOEP data who meet these restrictions. Around 9% of these fathers are trol for the impact of any observable and unobservable factors that are
low educated (ISCED 2 or lower) and 35% are highly educated (ISCED constant within families over time, to control for selectivity in leave-
5 or higher). 29% of these fathers have a migration background. On av- taking. Table 1 shows results for fathers’ time use during early child-
erage they were aged 29 at the birth of their first child. At the time of hood. Specifically, time use is measured during the first six years after
the last interview covered in the data, these fathers have 2.5 children childbirth. The table shows results for the summary measure family time
on average.3 Less than 2% of the fathers who are used for the fixed and for each of the underlying time use components as well as for time
effects estimation took parental leave for their first child (i.e. born be- us on weekends. The fixed effects estimates indicate that fathers’ fam-
fore the reform). In contrast, 12% of the children born after the reform ily time increases by around 1.2 h per weekday if fathers took parental
who contribute to the fixed effects estimation had a father who took leave. When looking at each of the separate components of the time use
parental leave. Table A2 in the Appendix shows descriptive statistics measure, the results show that on Saturdays and Sundays the increase in
fathers’ time for childcare is 1.4 and 1.6 h, respectively, both of which
are significant. In contrast, on weekdays the point estimate is smaller at
3
The respective descriptive statistics for all fathers who had a child born af- around two thirds of an hour and not significant. The increase in house-
ter the 2007 reform, i.e. including those whose first child was born after the work (washing, cooking, cleaning) is by 0.5 h per weekday and slightly
reform, are: 16% low educated, 34% highly educated, 38% with a migration higher on Saturdays and Sundays. For errands (shopping, trips to gov-
background, on average aged 30 at first childbirth, 2.1 children on average at ernment agencies, etc.) there is also a significant increase on weekdays
the time of the last interview. (by 0.1 h) but not on weekends. Note that the very small and insignif-

187
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

icant estimate for errands on Sundays is not surprising given that most

Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child in years, for the number of children as well as a time trend using a cubic specification. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in
Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007 and higher order childbirth after the 2007 reform. Family time is the sum of childcare, housework and errands.
fathers report zero errand time on that day (compare Fig. A1 in the ap-

(Sunday)

[0.0210]
−0.0229
pendix).

Errands

1101
Compared with average fathers’ involvement in these activities the

yes

69
estimated effects are considerable. These findings suggest that fathers’
parental leave-taking not only influences fathers’ childcare involvement
but also contributes to more gender equality in other household du-
ties. Other activities such as education and training, repairs on the
(Saturday)

[0.1775]
Errands

house/car and garden work as well as hobbies and other free time activ-
0.2188

1145
yes ities are not significantly affected by fathers’ leave-taking (results avail-
69
able upon request). The finding that (at least for weekdays) there is a
larger effect on housework than on childcare is in line with findings in
Patnaik (2019) but in contrast to Farré and González (2018), who find
that only fathers’ childcare involvement is affected. The reason for this
(weekday)

[0.0799]
0.1409∗
Errands

pattern is unclear. Patnaik (2019) mentions that mothers might be less


2326
148

likely to give up the more enjoyable part of household duties, i.e. child-
yes

care in contrast to housework, or that, even though fathers increased


their childcare competences, mothers still have a comparative advan-
tage for childcare versus housework.
Housework

In principle it would be interesting to split down the impact esti-


(Sunday)

[0.2026]
0.4732∗∗

mates by age of the child, especially in order to test whether effects


1136
yes

are restricted to the time when parents are (potentially) still on leave
70

or whether they persist afterwards and for how long. However, the
number of observations for such a detailed analysis is small and one
should caution to put too much emphasis on the single estimates. We
Housework
(Saturday)

present selected results in Table 2 (for reasons of comparison column 1


[0.2531]
0.5730∗∗

of Table 2 always repeats the less detailed estimates from Table 1). The
1148
yes

70

second column shows results for the time when parents might still be on
leave, i.e. up to month 14. The third column shows results for the en-
tire time after potential leave-taking, up to at most when the child turns
age 6. The fourth and fifth column split up this period after potential
Housework
(weekday)

0.4501∗∗∗
[0.1627]

leave-taking into the time up to when the child turns age 3 and the time
2331

afterwards. Most importantly, the increase in overall family time of fa-


150
yes

thers on weekdays, the increase in childcare on Sundays, the increase in


housework on weekdays and the increase in errands on weekdays does
not appear to be restricted to the time when fathers are (potentially)
on leave but also persists afterwards (see column 3).4 In addition, for
Childcare

1.5544∗∗∗
(Sunday)

[0.5620]

childcare on Sundays and housework on weekdays the effects are even


1165

significant several years after fathers’ return from leave (column 5).
yes

71

Having shown that fathers’ leave-taking leads to more involvement


in home production, the question arises whether this is accompanied by
a decrease in labor market participation. Results using hours of work as
dependent variable are presented in Table 3. The first column shows esti-
(Saturday)
Childcare

1.3629∗∗∗
[0.5072]

mates for the entire six years after childbirth and the following columns
1164

show estimates for a more detailed analysis by age of the child. Fathers’
yes

71

leave-taking significantly decreases fathers’ hours of work by 4.1 h per


week. The detailed analyses by age of the child suggest that this change
in labor market participation of fathers is mainly due to changes in the
period when fathers are (potentially) on leave for a couple of months
(weekday)
Childcare

[0.5034]
0.6399

and do not persist after leave-taking.


2385
151
yes

5. Discussion of the internal and external validity


Effects on fathers’ childcare and housework.

This section presents the results of tests questioning the identification


Family time

assumption of the father fixed effects estimates (internal validity) and


(weekday)

[0.5698]
1.2325∗∗

discusses the generalizability of the results (external validity). The father


2295
146
yes

fixed effects model controls for any factors that are constant over time
brackets. Significance levels.

and assumes that the within-father differences in parental leave-taking


are only due to the exogenous policy reform. If there are changes in
family specific observed or unobserved factors that also lead to changes
in fathers’ parental leave-taking and in the outcomes of interest, the es-
Control variables

timates will be biased. We are not able to rule out this case. However,
Paternal leave

p < 0.01.
p < 0.05.
Observations

p < 0.10.
Obs. treated
Table 1

4
Similarly, results are significant in the period after potential leave-taking for
∗∗∗

housework on Saturdays and housework on Sundays (not shown in the table).


∗∗

Point estimates are 0.92 and 0.68, respectively.

188
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Table 2
Effects on fathers’ childcare and housework by age of the child.

Child age 0–14 months Child age 15–71 months


Outcome Child age 0–71 months (“during leave”) (“after leave”) Child age 15–35 months Child age 36–71 months

Family time (weekday) 1.2325∗∗ 1.3632 1.0435∗∗∗ 1.4893∗∗∗ 0.6082


[0.5698] [1.1146] [0.3556] [0.5186] [0.4160]
Obs. 2295 695 1600 843 757
Obs. treated 146 40 106 49 57
Childcare (weekday) 0.6399 1.3244 0.2637 0.6581 −0.5899
[0.5034] [0.9007] [0.3580] [0.4185] [0.4979]
Obs. 2385 722 1663 882 781
Obs. treated 151 41 110 51 59
Childcare (Saturday) 1.3629∗∗∗ 1.4304∗ 1.2455 1.4253∗ 2.0156
[0.5072] [0.7432] [0.7817] [0.7645] [1.2882]
Obs. 1164 343 821 432 389
Obs. treated 71 20 51 26 25
Childcare (Sunday) 1.5544∗∗∗ 0.9039 1.6298∗ 1.4137∗ 2.4696∗
[0.5620] [0.7274] [0.8782] [0.8056] [1.2685]
Obs. 1165 343 822 433 389
Obs. treated 71 20 51 26 25
Housework (weekday) 0.4501∗∗∗ 0.2132 0.5392∗∗∗ 0.4770∗∗∗ 1.0608∗∗∗
[0.1627] [0.2011] [0.1856] [0.1754] [0.3005]
Obs. 2331 706 1625 856 769
Obs. treated 150 41 109 50 59
Errands (weekday) 0.1409∗ −0.0819 0.2196∗∗∗ 0.3234∗∗∗ 0.1473
[0.0799] [0.1419] [0.0846] [0.1075] [0.1619]
Obs. 2326 703 1623 852 771
Obs. treated 148 40 108 50 58

Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007 and higher order childbirth after the 2007 reform. Family
time is the sum of childcare, housework and errands. Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child, dummies for the number of children as
well as time trends using a cubic specification. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels.

p < 0.10.
∗∗ p < 0.05.
∗∗∗
p < 0.01.

Table 3
Effects on fathers’ labor market participation.

Child age 0–14 months Child age 15–71 months


Outcome Child age 0–71 months (“during leave”) (“after leave”) Child age 15–35 months Child age 36–71 months
∗ ∗∗∗
Fathers’ hours of work per week −4.1084 −11.1887 −0.4276 −0.4458 −1.7634
[2.4038] [4.3078] [2.2845] [3.6342] [2.7430]
Obs. 2384 720 1664 881 783
Obs. treated 149 40 109 52 57

Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007 and higher order childbirth after the 2007 reform. Control
variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child, dummies for the number of children as well as time trends using a cubic specification. Standard errors
accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels: ∗ p < 0.10, ∗ ∗ p < 0.05, ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01.

Table A3 presents results that try to control for such changes. Specifi- control for whether the preceding child is of schooling age. This might
cally, Panel A of the table shows results of a specification that controls be important because time for childcare is not reported individually for
for mother’s and father’s hours of work in the year before the birth of each child, rather it refers to all children and, thus, might be affected by
the child which is the youngest at that time. These pre-birth hours of other children being taken care of outside the household. Overall, for
work of mother and father are thus specific for each child, similar to the all five specifications the results in Table A3 are quite similar to those
information on father’s leave-taking. They are supposed to capture situ- of the main specification. The only differences are that fathers’ house-
ations where, for example, a father takes no leave when the first child is work on Saturdays and Sundays and errands on weekdays are smaller
born but because mother or father are not satisfied with the division of and not significant any more in Panels A to D and that the summary
housework they decide to adjust his contribution to housework and also measure turns insignificant in Panels A and B but the point estimates
to take leave when the second child is born. If such a family already dis- are actually larger than in the main specification. Instead in Panels C
plays changes in labor market attachment before the second or higher and D, fathers’ childcare on weekdays turns significant and in Panel D
order birth takes place, controlling for mother’s and father’s pre-birth also errands on Saturdays. In Panel E errands on weekdays and hours of
hours of work should control for such changes in preferences. Panels B work are not significant any more. In summary, these findings do not
and C of Table A3 show results that control for mother’s and father’s pre- challenge our overall message.
birth wages and the relative position of father’s labor income compared One violation of the assumptions of the father fixed effects model
to mother’s, respectively. Panel D controls for mothers’ and fathers’ pre- would be if the other elements of the 2007 reform had differential effects
birth time use, specifically the time for childcare, for housework and for for families with and without leave-taking fathers. We cannot test this
errands on weekdays in the year before the birth of the child which is the directly. However, first evidence that the impact of the other elements
youngest at that time. The reasoning is always similar to controlling for of the 2007 reform is not different for different types of families has
pre-birth hours of work. Finally, Panel E of Table A3 shows results that been discussed at the beginning of Section 4 (cf. column 2 of Table A1).

189
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Second, we can test whether it makes a difference for our findings if Hochberg (1995) and the sharpened false discovery rate adjusted p-
we allow for separate time trends for specific subgroups of the popula- values based on Benjamini et al. (2006). In summary, adjusting the p-
tion. Candidates for subgroup-specific trends are observable factors that values hardly challenges the findings.
on the one hand correlate with the take-up of fathers’ leave and on the As has been discussed in Section 3 the fixed effects model identifies
other hand have been shown to experience heterogeneous treatment ef- treatment effects only for families with multiple children. Because we
fects with respect to the entire reform. Studies analyzing the entire 2007 restrict the sample to fathers who had at least one child before 2007, in
reform, not only the father quota, have shown that treatment effects are order to use exogenous variation in take-up of parental leave, and be-
heterogeneous mainly between East and West Germany and by moth- cause hardly any father took leave before 2007 the effects only refer to
ers’ level of education (Kluve and Tamm, 2013). To account for such leave-taking for second or higher order children. Generally, these may
differential effects by subgroup we repeat the main analyses allowing differ from effects of leave-taking for first children or for one child fam-
for different time trends for those groups. The main model already in- ilies. For example Pailhé et al. (2018) show that in France the effects of
cludes time trends using a cubic specification and we add interactions fathers’ leave-taking on childcare time differ by parity. Reasons for dif-
with mothers’ level of education and with East Germany, respectively ferential impact estimates by parity might be that leave-taking is more
(see Panels A and B of Table A4). Similarly, we control for different common for first than for later born children and thus the selectivity of
time trends for factors that a priori might been seen as candidates for fathers is different (e.g. Sundström and Duvander, 2002). Another rea-
heterogeneity in the impact of the other elements of the reform, such son might be that parents might be more open to define their roles at
as mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth hours of work (Panel C), their wages first childbirth and are less open to changing these roles when second or
(Panel D) and the relative position of father’s labor income compared higher order children are born. There is no way to formally test the ex-
to mother’s (Panel E). In most cases results are not affected by this. Ex- ternal validity of the findings and thus the generalizability of the results
ceptions are that in Panel C family time and childcare on Saturdays and to other groups, instead we provide descriptive evidence making it more
Sundays turn insignificant, even though the coefficient for family time is plausible for some outcomes that estimated treatment effects have exter-
even larger than in the main specification. Furthermore, time for house- nal validity and less plausible for other outcomes. If we look at fathers’
work on Saturdays and Sundays and time for errands on weekdays is no childcare involvement, housework and errands, descriptive statistics do
longer significantly positive in Panels C–E. Overall, this is reinforcing not reveal any major differences by number of children (see Fig. A1 in
the main findings. the appendix). We take this as evidence that estimated treatment effects
Another assumption of the father fixed effects model is that differ- are more likely to be generalizable to all families with fathers taking
ences in behavior between involved and uninvolved fathers are constant leave. Similarly, fathers’ employment hardly differs by number of chil-
for first and higher order children. We test this by looking at a sample dren, except for families with numerous children (see Fig. A2 in the
of fathers whose first and second child were born after the 2007 reform. appendix). This might suggest that effects on fathers’ employment are
We compare changes in behavior between first and second childbirth for similar when taking leave for first children.
fathers who took leave after the first child was born and for fathers who
did not take leave after the first child was born. Results show that the dif- 6. Conclusion
ference in the change in behavior between fathers taking leave with the
first child and those not taking leave is never significant (see Table A5). Investigating a policy reform that introduced two daddy months of
This supports the identification strategy. Yet, admittedly some of the parental leave in Germany and increased benefits for parents with pre-
estimated coefficients are quite large. Thus, this evidence is not very childbirth labor market attachment this paper uses a within-father dif-
strong. ferences estimator and documents several significant changes in fathers’
Cygan-Rehm (2016) and Raute (2019) have shown that the parental behavior. We find that fathers’ parental leave-taking has significant in-
leave reform affected fertility (for evidence on Spain see Farré and fluence on the time fathers dedicate to childcare (yet, mostly on week-
González, 2018). If after the reform only a selected sample of parents ends) and to housework and errands (also during weekdays). Both ef-
decided to have a second or higher order birth, this might lead to bi- fects persist even after fathers return from leave. This documents the
ased estimates. Table A6 presents results that try to avoid using a se- importance of the first few months after childbirth for shaping gender
lected sample. We do so by using information on only those parents roles in childcare and in household production.
with childbirth in 2007, i.e. in the first year after the reform. Parents With respect to employment the effects of fathers’ leave-taking are
who had a second or higher order birth later are dropped from the anal- rather short-lived, i.e. the decrease of fathers’ hours of work is restricted
ysis. Because the reform was announced only shortly before coming into to the period when parents are eligible to parental leave benefits. This is
effect (Kluve and Tamm, 2013), the rational for looking at treated fam- very much in line with the previous literature on fathers’ leave-taking,
ilies who had a childbirth in 2007 is that for them fertility is unlikely which generally does not find that fathers’ employment changes beyond
to have changed due of the reform. The results show that the sign of the parental leave period (e.g. Ekberg et al., 2013; Cools et al., 2015;
the coefficients is always the same as in Tables 1 and 3. In most cases Rege and Solli, 2013; Farré and González, 2018).
the same estimates are statistically significant, even though the sample
size is now considerably smaller. Only for father’ childcare involvement Acknowledgment
on Sundays, father’ errands on weekdays and father’ hours of work the
estimates are not significant any more. But the point estimate for father’ We acknowledge helpful comments and suggestions by two anony-
childcare involvement on Sundays is very similar to the one reported mous referees, by the responsible editor (Eric Maurin) and by conference
in the main analysis and for father’ hours of work the point estimate is participants at ESPE (Antwerp) and EALE (Lyon). This research did not
even larger. Thus, overall, this also reinforces the main findings. receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commer-
In the paper we analyze quite a number of different outcome vari- cial, or not-for-profit sectors.
ables in addition to the summary measure family time. This might
pose a problem of multiple inference (e.g. Anderson, 2008), i.e. be- Declaration of interest
cause there are many outcomes we look at, some of them might turn
significant even though the true effect is actually zero (type I error). None.
Table A7 presents p-values for the parental leave estimates that control
for multiple inference for each of the detailed time use measures. Besides Appendix
the point estimate and the conventional unadjusted p-value the table
shows false discovery rate adjusted p-values based on Benjamini and Figs. A1–A3, Tables A1–A7.

190
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Fig. A1. Average time fathers spend on childcare, housework and errands.
Note: Calculated from SOEP v31.1, years 2000 to 2015 for all parents with children below age 18.

Fig. A2. Fathers’ average working hours after childbirth.


Note: Calculated from SOEP v31.1, years 2000 to 2015 for all parents with chil-
dren below age 18.

191
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Fig. A3. Fathers’ time spent on childcare, housework, errands and work on the labor market by fathers’ leave-taking.
Note: Calculated from SOEP v31.1, years 2007 to 2015 for all parents with childbirth in 2007 or later.

Table A1
Before-after comparison for fathers’ leave taking and fathers’ time use.

Father’s take-up of parental leave Father’s family time on weekdays


(1) (2)

Panel A After the reform 0.2087∗∗∗ 0.5651∗∗∗


[0.0141] [0.1226]
# father-child pairs 2803 2803
# father-child-year observations 9788
Panel B After the reform 0.1079∗∗ 1.5320∗∗
[0.0460] [0.6101]
After ∗ father’s working hours 0.0008 −0.0265∗∗
[0.0010] [0.0132]
After ∗ mother’s working hours 0.0019∗∗ 0.0044
[0.0010] [0.0076]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992
Panel C After the reform 0.1303∗∗∗ 0.8583∗∗
[0.0321] [0.3725]
After ∗ father’s wage 0.0007 −0.0056
[0.0004] [0.0052]
After ∗ mother’s wage 0.0002 0.0030
[0.0005] [0.0035]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992
Panel D After the reform 0.1666∗∗∗ 0.6286
[0.0484] [0.4624]
After ∗ equal earning 0.0351 0.4861
[0.0618] [0.6354]
After ∗ father has higher earnings 0.0208 −0.2436
[0.0514] [0.4765]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992
Panel E After the reform 0.2271∗∗∗ 0.5490∗∗∗
[0.0177] [0.1588]
After ∗ higher order birth −0.0509∗∗ 0.0392
[0.0238] [0.2265]
# father-child pairs 2803 2803
# father-child-year observations 9788

(continued on next page)

192
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Table A1 (continued)

Father’s take-up of parental leave Father’s family time on weekdays


(1) (2)

Panel G After the reform 0.2146∗∗ 1.0067


[0.0894] [1.1530]

After father’s working hours −0.0002 0.0038
[0.0039] [0.0431]
After ∗ mother’s working hours −0.0026 −0.0040
[0.0033] [0.0240]
After ∗ higher order birth −0.1616 0.7467
[0.1009] [1.2595]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ father’s working hours 0.0008 −0.0175
[0.0022] [0.0236]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ mother’s working hours 0.0023 0.0060
[0.0019] [0.0136]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992
Panel H After the reform 0.0850 0.5157
[0.0582] [0.6117]
After ∗ father’s wage 0.0025 −0.0141
[0.0017] [0.0132]
After ∗ mother’s wage 0.0024 0.0288∗∗
[0.0021] [0.0142]
After ∗ higher order birth 0.0213 0.4649
[0.0647] [0.6629]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ father’s wage −0.0010 0.0043
[0.0009] [0.0070]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ mother’s wage −0.0013 −0.0137∗
[0.0011] [0.0071]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992
Panel I After the reform 0.1765∗∗∗ 0.9855
[0.0650] [0.6366]
After ∗ equal earning 0.1196 −2.1135
[0.2086] [1.8734]
After ∗ father has higher earnings 0.1308 −1.3881
[0.1502] [1.2921]
After ∗ higher order birth −0.0487 −0.5162
[0.0780] [0.7033]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ equal earning −0.0542 1.5897
[0.1202] [1.0673]
After ∗ higher order birth ∗ father has higher earnings −0.0616 0.6908
[0.0860] [0.7160]
# father-child pairs 1415 1415
# father-child-year observations 4992

Note: In column 1 the dependent variable is a dummy variable indicating whether the father took parental leave. In column 2 the
dependent variable measures the sum of daily hours for childcare, for housework and for errands on regular weekdays. Results
for a sample of fathers with first childbirth between 2000 and 2012. In addition to the interaction terms indicated in the table the
specifications also control for main effects of the respective variables. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in
brackets. Significance levels.

p < 0.10.
∗∗
p < 0.05.
∗∗∗
p < 0.01.

Table A2
Descriptive statistics by fathers’ leave status.

Fathers taking parental leave Fathers not taking parental leave

Father highly educated 0.516 0.342


Mother highly educated 0.482 0.231
Father has migration background 0.194 0.297
East Germany 0.355 0.216
Father’s age at birth of the child 35.3 36.0
Mother’s age at birth of the child 32.5 32.0
Father’s hours of work before birth of the child 44.1 40.2
Mother’s hours of work before birth of the child 16.5 13.4
Father’s log hourly wage before birth of the child (if employed) 4.08 4.16
Mother’s log hourly wage before birth of the child (if employed) 4.14 3.88
Father’s labor income before birth of the child is lower than mother’s 0.280 0.190
Father’s and mother’s labor income before birth of the child are about equal 0.160 0.133
Father’s labor income before birth of the child is higher than mother’s 0.560 0.677
Number of older siblings 1.5 1.5
Age difference to preceding child (in years) 4.4 5.3

Note: Descriptive statistics are provided for the sample of the fixed effects analysis. Each father is considered once per child (born since
2007). Fathers’ parental leave status refers to the specific father-child pair.

193
M. Tamm
Table A3
Robustness test: controlling for time-varying characteristics.

Family time Childcare Childcare Childcare Housework Housework Housework Errands Errands Errands Hours of
(weekday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) work

Panel A - Controlling for mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth hours of work

Paternal leave 1.4584 1.0816 1.3012∗ 1.3191∗ 0.3347∗∗ 0.2649 0.3368 −0.0012 0.2547 −0.0099 −8.0533∗∗∗
[0.8999] [0.7009] [0.6610] [0.6790] [0.1642] [0.2209] [0.2760] [0.0848] [0.1636] [0.0275] [2.6461]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Observations 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860
Panel B - Controlling for mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth wage

Paternal leave 1.4769 1.0926 1.3535∗∗ 1.3577∗∗ 0.3322∗∗ 0.2487 0.311 0.0062 0.2687 −0.014 −8.3897∗∗∗
[0.8981] [0.6971] [0.6234] [0.6395] [0.1671] [0.2342] [0.2874] [0.0904] [0.1738] [0.0434] [2.5884]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Observations 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860
Panel C - Controlling for fathers’ pre-birth labor income relative to mothers’

Paternal leave 1.5777∗ 1.2082∗ 1.4754∗∗ 1.4531∗∗ 0.3243∗ 0.2596 0.3163 −0.008 0.253 −0.0078 −8.1302∗∗∗
[0.8668] [0.6691] [0.6222] [0.6350] [0.1657] [0.2279] [0.2851] [0.0856] [0.1728] [0.0279] [2.5624]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Observations 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860
194

Panel D - Controlling for mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth time use

Paternal leave 1.8345∗ 1.4076∗ 1.7623∗∗∗ 1.7527∗∗ 0.3678∗∗ 0.2908 0.3399 0.0179 0.3578∗∗ −0.0282 −8.8375∗∗∗
[0.9821] [0.7553] [0.6534] [0.6997] [0.1746] [0.2328] [0.2876] [0.0949] [0.1734] [0.0253] [2.6515]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 1687 1737 849 849 1710 841 836 1705 841 814 1728
Panel E - Controlling for school eligibility of the preceding child

Paternal leave 0.9750∗ 0.4635 1.3856∗∗∗ 1.5713∗∗∗ 0.4003∗∗ 0.5707∗∗ 0.4734∗∗ 0.1217 0.2229 −0.0236 −3.1077
[0.5494] [0.4984] [0.5301] [0.5705] [0.1564] [0.2565] [0.2038] [0.0812] [0.1794] [0.0230] [2.3492]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Observations 2210 2298 1122 1123 2245 1107 1095 2240 1105 1062 2297

Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007. Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child in years, for the number of children as well as
a time trend using a cubic specification. Panel A additionally controls for hours of work of the mother and of the father in the year before the birth of the child which is the youngest at that time. Panel B additionally
controls for the wage of the mother and of the father in the year before the birth of the child which is the youngest at that time. Panel C additionally controls for two dummy variables indicating the relative position
of father’s labor income compared to mother’s labor income in the year before the birth of the child which is the youngest at that time. Panel D additionally controls for hours for childcare, for housework and for
errands on weekdays of the mother and of the father in the year before the birth of the child which is the youngest at that time. Panel E additionally controls for an indicator whether the preceding child is of schooling

Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197


age. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels.

p < 0.10.
∗∗
p < 0.05.
∗∗∗
p < 0.01.
M. Tamm
Table A4
Robustness test: controlling for separate time trends by family type.

Family time Childcare Childcare Childcare Housework Housework Housework Errands Errands Errands Hours of
(weekday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) work

Panel A - Differential trends by mothers’ level of education

Paternal leave 1.2492∗ 0.7383 1.7033∗∗∗ 1.8972∗∗∗ 0.3892∗∗ 0.4717∗∗ 0.4472∗ 0.1124 0.3481∗ −0.0313 −5.0803∗
[0.6635] [0.5599] [0.5709] [0.5856] [0.1557] [0.2247] [0.2272] [0.0850] [0.1897] [0.0197] [2.6511]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 2102 2187 1071 1072 2132 1054 1045 2130 1053 1011 2186
Panel B - Differential trends in East and West

Paternal leave 1.2359∗∗ 0.6414 1.3809∗∗ 1.5730∗∗∗ 0.4497∗∗∗ 0.5737∗∗ 0.4728∗∗ 0.1412∗ 0.2207 −0.0216 −4.0711∗
[0.5683] [0.5028] [0.5330] [0.5864] [0.1641] [0.2530] [0.2051] [0.0799] [0.1700] [0.0208] [2.3628]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 2295 2385 1164 1165 2331 1148 1136 2326 1145 1101 2384
Panel C - Differential trends by mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth hours of work

Paternal leave 1.4413 1.0781 1.0565 1.0889 0.3315∗∗ 0.2326 0.363 −0.0102 0.2553 −0.0167 −8.5640∗∗∗
[0.9207] [0.7175] [0.7288] [0.7401] [0.1622] [0.2141] [0.2748] [0.0874] [0.1644] [0.0291] [2.7369]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
195

Obs. 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860
Panel D - Differential trends by mothers’ and fathers’ pre-birth wage

Paternal leave 1.4951∗ 1.1048 1.1375∗ 1.1535∗ 0.3433∗∗ 0.2548 0.3213 0.0081 0.261 0.0151 −8.4502∗∗∗
[0.8993] [0.6973] [0.6637] [0.6653] [0.1677] [0.2344] [0.2862] [0.0891] [0.1712] [0.0524] [2.6507]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860
Panel E - Differential trends fathers’ pre-birth labor income relative to mothers’

Paternal leave 1.5649∗ 1.1981∗ 1.3010∗∗ 1.2785∗∗ 0.3396∗∗ 0.2598 0.3215 −0.0244 0.2537 −0.0059 −8.4623∗∗∗
[0.8498] [0.6527] [0.6166] [0.6135] [0.1682] [0.2360] [0.2854] [0.0846] [0.1750] [0.0342] [2.6300]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 1785 1855 907 908 1809 893 886 1807 890 855 1860

Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007 and higher order childbirth after the 2007 reform. Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest
child in years, for the number of children as well as a time trend using a cubic specification. Because pre-childbirth hours of work, wages and the relative income position are child-specific the specifications in Panels
C to E also control for the main effects and not only for the interaction terms with the time trends. Instead mothers’ level of education and the region are basically fixed within households and thus the main effect is
already absorbed in the father fixed effect in Panels A and B. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels.

Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197



p < 0.10.
∗∗
p < 0.05.
∗∗∗
p < 0.01.
M. Tamm
Table A5
Robustness test: Difference in behavior between first and second childbirth by fathers’ involvement with the first child.

Family time Childcare Childcare Childcare Housework Housework Housework Errands Errands Errands Hours of
(weekday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) work

Fathers taking leave −0.7989 −0.6384 0.2070 −0.1519 −0.0955 −0.1263 −0.1166 −0.0736 0.0771 −0.0192 1.4481
with first child ∗
second child
[0.5158] [0.4184] [1.0484] [1.0408] [0.1004] [0.1630] [0.1678] [0.0766] [0.1655] [0.0337] [1.9157]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 1415 1439 781 779 1428 773 768 1424 779 762 1430

Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first and second childbirth after the 2007 reform. Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child in years, for the number
of children as well as a time trend using a cubic specification. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels: ∗ p < 0.10, ∗ ∗ p < 0.05, ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01.
196

Table A6
Robustness test: Leaving out families with childbirth after 2007.

Family time Childcare Childcare Childcare Housework Housework Housework Errands Errands Errands Hours of
(weekday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) (weekday) (Saturday) (Sunday) work

Paternal leave 2.7425∗ 1.8614 2.0280∗ 1.4707 0.8446∗ ∗ ∗ 0.8763∗ 0.9145∗ ∗ ∗ 0.0858 0.4227 0.0059 −6.5754
[1.3983] [1.2228] [1.1319] [1.3437] [0.2522] [0.4818] [0.2607] [0.1397] [0.3393] [0.0158] [4.4791]
Control variables yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Obs. 1540 1604 793 795 1560 783 773 1561 784 749 1601

Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197


Note: Results using father fixed effects models for a sample of fathers with first childbirth before 2007 and higher order childbirth in 2007. Control variables include dummies for the age of the youngest child in years,
for the number of children as well as a time trend using a cubic specification. Standard errors accounting for clustering at father level in brackets. Significance levels: ∗ p < 0.10, ∗ ∗ p < 0.05, ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01.
M. Tamm Labour Economics 59 (2019) 184–197

Table A7
Robustness test: p-values adjusted to multiple inference.

Conventional Adjusted p-value based on Adjusted p-value based on


Outcome Point estimate p-value Benjamini and Hochberg (1995) Benjamini et al. (2006)

Fathers’ childcare (weekday) 0.6399 0.205 0.243 0.139


Fathers’ childcare (Saturday) 1.3629 0.008 0.026 0.027
Fathers’ childcare (Sunday) 1.5544 0.006 0.026 0.027
Fathers’ housework (weekday) 0.4501 0.006 0.026 0.027
Fathers’ housework (Saturday) 0.5730 0.024 0.049 0.036
Fathers’ housework (Sunday) 0.4732 0.020 0.049 0.036
Fathers’ errands (weekday) 0.1409 0.079 0.127 0.068
Fathers’ errands (Saturday) 0.2188 0.218 0.243 0.139
Fathers’ errands (Sunday) −0.0229 0.277 0.278 0.145
Fathers’ hours of work −4.1084 0.089 0.127 0.068

Note: The table replicates point estimates from Tables 1 and 3. Conventional p-values account for clustering at father level. Adjusted p-values additionally account for
multiple inference.

References Kluve, J., Schmitz, S., 2018. Back to work: parental benefits and mothers’ labor market
outcomes in the medium-run. Ind. Labor Relat. Rev. 71 (1), 143–173.
Anderson, M., 2008. Multiple inference and gender differences in the effects of early in- Kluve, J., Tamm, M., 2013. Parental leave regulations, mothers’ labor force attachment
tervention: a reevaluation of the abecedarian, perry preschool, and early training and fathers’ childcare involvement: evidence from a natural experiment. J. Popul.
projects. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 103 (484), 1481–1495. Econ. 26 (3), 983–1005.
Angelov, N., Johansson, P., Lindahl, E., 2016. Parenthood and the gender gap in pay. J. Kotsadam, A., Finseraas, H., 2011. The state intervenes in the battle of the sexes: causal
Labor Econ. 34 (3), 545–579. effects of paternity leave. Soc. Sci. Res. 40 (6), 1611–1622.
Benjamini, Y., Hochberg, Y., 1995. Controlling the false discovery rate. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. Lundberg, S., Rose, E., 2000. Parenthood and the earnings of married men and women.
B 57 (1), 289–300. Labour Econ. 7 (6), 689–710.
Benjamini, Y., Krieger, A., Yekutieli, D., 2006. Adaptive linear step-up procedures that OECD (2017), OECD Employment Database. Accessed on 18.01.2017:
control the false discovery rate. Biometrika 93 (3), 491–507. http://www.oecd.org/employment/emp/onlineoecdemploymentdatabase.htm
Bergemann, A., Riphahn, R., 2011. Female labor supply and parental leave benefits. The Pailhé, A., A. Solaz and M. Tô (2018), Can daddies learn how to change nappies? Evidence
causal effect of paying higher transfers for a shorter period of time. Appl. Econ. Lett. from a short paternity leave policy. INED document de travail #240.
18 (1), 17–20. Patnaik, A., 2019. Reserving time for daddy: the consequences of fathers’ quotas. J. Labor
Bertrand, M., Goldin, C., Katz, L., 2010. Dynamics of the gender gap for young profession- Econ. 37 (4) forthcoming in October 2019.
als in the financial and corporate sectors. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 2 (3), 228–255. Raute, A., 2019. Can financial incentives reduce the baby gap? Evidence from a reform in
Bianchi, S., 2000. Maternal employment and time with children: dramatic change or sur- maternity leave benefits. J. Public Econ. 169, 203–222.
prising continuity? Demography 37 (4), 401–414. Rege, M., Solli, I., 2013. The impact of paternity leave on fathers’ future earnings. Demog-
Bianchi, S., Milkie, M., Sayer, L., Robinson, J., 2000. Is anyone doing the housework? raphy 50 (6), 2255–2277.
Trends in the gender division of household labor. Soc. Forces 79 (1), 191–228. Reich, N., 2011. Predictors of fathers’ use of parental leave in Germany. Popul. Rev. 50
Bünning, M., 2015. What happens after the ‘daddy months’? Fathers’ involvement in paid (2), 1–22.
work, childcare, and housework after taking parental leave in Germany. Eur. Sociol. RWI, 2008. Evaluation des Gesetzes zum Elterngeld und zur Elternzeit, Endbericht.
Rev. 31 (6), 738–748. RWI Projekt für das Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend.
Cools, S., Fiva, J., Kirkebøen, L., 2015. Causal effects of paternity leave on children and RWI:Projektberichte, Essen.
parents. Scand. J. Econ. 117 (3), 801–828. Schober, P., 2014. Parental leave and domestic work of mothers and fathers: a longitudinal
Cygan-Rehm, K., 2016. Parental leave benefit and differential fertility responses: evidence study of two reforms in West Germany. J. Soc. Policy 43 (2), 351–372.
from a German reform. J. Popul. Econ. 29 (1), 73–103. Shapiro, D., Mott, F., 1994. Long-term employment and earnings of women in relation
Ekberg, J., Eriksson, R., Friebel, G., 2013. Parental leave – A policy evaluation of the to employment behavior surrounding the first birth. J. Hum. Resour. 29 (2), 248–
Swedish “Daddy-Month” reform. J. Public Econ. 97, 131–143. 275.
Farré, L. and L. González (2018), Does Paternity Leave Reduce Fertility? IZA Discussion Sundström, M., Duvander, A.-Z., 2002. Gender division of childcare and the sharing
Paper #12023. of parental leave among new parents in Sweden. Eur. Sociol. Rev. 18 (4), 433–
Geyer, J., Haan, P., Wrohlich, K., 2015. The effects of family policy on maternal labor sup- 447.
ply: combining evidence from a structural model and a quasi-experimental approach. Waldfogel, J., 1998a. Understanding the “family gap” in pay for women with children. J.
Labour Econ. 36, 84–98. Econ. Perspect. 12 (1), 137–156.
Huebener, M., Müller, K.-U., Spieß, K., Wrohlich, K., 2016. The parental leave benefit: a Waldfogel, J., 1998b. The family gap for young women in the United States and Britain:
key family policy measure, one decade later. DIW Econ. Bull. 49 (2016), 571–578. can maternity leave make a difference? J. Labor Econ. 16 (3), 505–545.

197

You might also like