You are on page 1of 11

International Journal of Forecasting 8 (1992) 3-13

North-Holland

Forecasting stock market prices: Lessons


for forecasters *
Clive W.J. G-anger
University of California, Sun Diego, USA

Abstract: In recent years a variety of models which apparently forecast changes in stock market prices
have been introduced. Some of these are summarised and interpreted. Nonlinear models are particularly
discussed, with a switching regime, from forecastable to non-forecastable, the switch depending on
volatility levels, relative earnings/price ratios, size of company, and calendar effects. There appear to be
benefits from disaggregation and for searching for new causal variables. The possible lessons for
forecasters are emphasised and the relevance for the Efficient Market Hypothesis is discussed.

Keywords: Forecastability, Stock returns, Non-linear models, Efficient markets.

1. Introduction: Random walk theory ever, a deeper theory - known as the Efficient
Market Hypothesis - suggests that mere fore-
For reasons that are probably obvious, stock castability is not enough. There are various forms
market prices have been the most analysed eco- of this hypothesis but the one I prefer is that
nomic data during the past forty years or so. The given by Jensen (1978):
basic question most asked is - are (real) price
HC,2:A market is efficient with respect to infor-
changes forecastable? A negative reply leads to
mation set 1, if it is impossible to make
the random walk hypothesis for these prices, economic profits by trading on the basis of
which currently would be stated as:
this information set.
H,,: Stock prices are a martingale.
By ‘economic profits’ is meant the risk-adjusted
i.e. E[ P,+, I I,] = P,, returns ‘net of all costs’. An obvious difficulty
with this hypothesis is that is is unclear how to
where Z, is any information set which includes measure risk or to know what transaction costs
the prices P, _ j, j 2 0. In a sense this hypothesis are faced by investors, or if these quantities are
has to be true. If it were not, and ignoring trans- the same for all investors. Any publically avail-
action costs then price changes would be consis- able method of consistently making positive prof-
tently forecastable and so a money machine is its is assumed to be in I,.
created and indefinite wealth is possible. How- This paper will concentrate on the martingale
hypothesis, and thus will mainly consider the
forecastability of price changes, or returns (de-
Correspondence to: C.W.J. Granger, Economics Dept., 0508, fined as (P, - P,_ , + D,)/P, _ 1 where D, is divi-
Univ. of California, San Diego, La Jolla, California, USA dends), but at the end I will give some considera-
92093-0508. tion to the efficient market theory. A good survey
* Invited lecture, International Institute of Forecasters, New
of this hypothesis is LeRoy (1989).
York Meeting, July 1991, work partly supported by NSF
Grant SES 89-02950. I would like to thank two anonymous By the beginning of the seventies I think that it
referees for very helpful remarks. was generally accepted by forecasters and re-

0169.2070/92/$05.00 0 1992 - Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. All rights reserved


4 C. W.J. Crunger / Forecasting stock market prices

searchers in finance that the random walk hy- The risk is usually measured from the capital
pothesis (or H,,,) was correct, or at least very asset pricing model (CAPM):
difficult to refute. In a survey in 1972 I wrote,
‘Almost without exception empirical studies.. . ’ R, - r, = p (market excess return) + e,,
support a model for p, = log f’, of the form
where the market return is for some measure of
dP,+, =~AP,+ I,-, +~t+l, the whole market, such as the Standard and
Poor’s 500. p is the non-diversifiable risk for the
where 0 is near zero, 1, contributes only to the stock. This is a good, but not necessarily ideal,
very low frequencies and E, is zero mean white measure of risk and which can be time-varying
noise. A survey by Fama (1970) reached a similar although this is not often considered in the stud-
conclusion. The information sets used were: ies discussed below.
I,,: lagged prices or lags of logged prices. Section 2 reviews forecasting models which can
be classified as ‘regime-switching’. Section 3 looks
ZZt: Ilr plus a few sensible possible explanatory at the advantages of disaggregation, Section 4
variables such as earnings and dividends. considers the search for causal variables, Section
The data periods were usually daily or monthly. 5 looks at technical trading rules, Section 6 re-
Further, no profitable trading rules were found, views cointegration and chaos, and Section 7 looks
or at least not reported. I suggested a possible at higher moments. Section 8 concludes and re-
reporting bias - if a method of forecasting was considers the Efficient Market Theory.
found an academic might prefer to profit from it
rather than publish. In fact, by this period I
thought that the only sure way of making money 2. Regime-switching models
from the stock market was to write a book about
it. I tried this with Granger and Morgenstern If a stationary series X, is generated by:
(1970), but this was not a financially successful
strategy. X, = (Y, + ylxI_, + E, if z, in A
However, from the mid-seventies and particu- and
larly in the 1980s there has been a burst of new X, = (Ye+ y*x,_, + Ed if z, not in A,
activity looking for forecastability, using new
methods, data sets, longer series, different time then x, can be considered to be regime switching,
periods and new explanatory variables. What is with z, being the indicator variable. If Z~ is a
interesting is that apparent forecastability is often lagged value of x, one has the switching thres-
found. An important reference is Guimaraes, hold autoregressive model (STAR) discussed in
Kingsman and Taylor (1989). The objective of this detail in Tong (1990), but z, can be a separate
part is to survey some of this work and to suggest variable, as is the case in the following examples.
lessons for forecasters working on other series. It is possible that the variance of the residual E,
The notation used is: also varies with regime. If x, is a return (or an
excess return) it is forecastable in at least one
p, = a stock price, regime if either y, or y2 is non-zero.
PI = log P,,
D, = dividend for period t,
2.a. Forecastability with Low Volatility
Rr = return = (P, + D, - P,_,)/P,_,,
[In some studies the return is calcu-
lated without the dividend term and LeBaron (1990) used R,, the weekly returns of
approximated by the change in log the Standard and Poor 500 index for the period
194661985, giving about 2,000 observations. He
prices.]
= return on a ‘risk free’ investment, used as the indicator variable a measure of the
rr
= excess return, recent volatility
R, -rt
P = risk level of the stock, 10

R, - r, - /3 X market return - cost of transac- &,,’= c Rf_,


tion = risk-adjusted profits. 1=0
C. W.l. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices 5

and the regime of interest is the lowest one-fifth with the corresponding standard errors:
quantile of the observed C? values in the first half Size E/P
of the sample. The regime switching model was
Mean (s.d.) Mean (s.d.)
estimated using the first half of the sample and
smallest 1.79 (0.32) highest 1.59 (0.25)
post-sample true one-step forecasts were evalu-
2nd 1.53 (0.28) 2”d 1.59 (0.22)
ated over the second half. For the low volatility S’h 1.25 (0.24) gLh 1.17 (0.22)
regime he finds a 3.1 percent improvement in 9th 1.03 (0.21) gth 1.11 (0.25)
forecast mean squared error over a white noise largest 0.99 (0.20) lowest 1.19 (0.28)
with non-zero mean (that is, an improvement negative
earnings (1.39) (0.39)
over a model in which price is taken to be a
random walk with drift). No improvement was Source: Keim (1989).
found for other volatility regimes. He first takes
cy (the constant) in the model to be constant It is seen that the smallest (in size) portfolios
across regimes, relaxing this assumption did not have a substantially higher average return than
result in improved forecasts. Essentially the model the largest and similarly the highest E/P portfo-
found is lios are better than the lowest.
The two effects were then combined to gener-
ate 25 portfolios, five were based on size and
R, = cr + 0.18R,_1 + lt if have low volatility
each of these was then sub-divided into five parts
R,=cu+~, otherwise,
on E/P values. A few of the results are given in
the following table as average monthly returns
where LYis a constant. This non-linear model was with beta risk values shown in brackets.
initially found to fit equally well in and out of Size E/P ratio
sample. However, more recent work by LeBaron Lowest Middle Highest
did not find much forecasting ability for the smallest 1.62 1.52 1.90
model. (1.27) (1.09) (1.09)

middle 1.12 1.09 1.52


(1.28) (1.02) (1.06)
2. b. Earnings and size portfolios largest 0.89 0.97 1.43
(1.11) (0.98) (1.03)

Using the stocks of all companies quoted on Source: Keim (1989).


either the New York or American Stock Ex-
changes for the period 1951 to 1986, Keim (1989) The portfolio with the highest E/P ratio and
formed portfolios based on the market value of the smallest size has both a high average return
equity (size) and the ratio of earnings to price and a beta value only slightly above that of a
(E/P) and then calculated monthly returns (in randomly selected portfolio (which should have a
percentages). Each March 31”’ all stocks were beta of 1.0). The result was found to hold for
ranked on the total market value of the equity both non-January months and for January, al-
(price x number of shares) and ten percent with though returns in January were much higher, as
the lowest ranks put into the first (or smallest) will be discussed in the next section. Somewhat
portfolio, the next 10% in the second portfolio similar results have been found for stocks on
and so forth up to the shares in the top 10% other, non-U.S. exchanges. It should be noted
ranked giving the ‘largest’ portfolio. The portfo- that as portfolios are changed each year, transac-
lios were changed annually and average monthly tion costs will be moderately large.
returns calculated. Similarly, the portfolios were The results are consistent with a regime-
formed from the highest E/P values to the lowest switching model with the regime determined by
(positive) values. [Shares of companies with nega- the size and E/P variables at the start of the
tive earnings went into a separate portfolio.] The year. However, as rankings are used, these vari-
table shows the average monthly returns (mean) ables for a single stock are related to the actual
for five of the portfolios in each case, together values of the variables for all other stocks.
6 C. W.J. Changer / Forecasting stock market prices

2.c. Seasonal effects its were achieved for transaction costs at a level
appropriate for larger traders. Thus, after allow-
A number of seasonal effects have been sug- ing for risk and costs, a portfolio based on price
gested but the strongest and most widely docu- reversal was found to be clearly profitable.
mented is the January effect. For example Keim Long term price reversals have also been docu-
(1989) found that the portfolio using highest E/P mented. For example, Dark and Kato (1986)
values and the smallest size gave an average found in the Japanese market that for the years
return of 7.46 (standard error 1.41) over Januarys 1964 to 1980, the three year returns for decile
but only 1.39 (0.27) in other months. A second portfolios of extreme previous losers exceed the
example is the observation that the small capital- comparable returns of extreme previous winners
ization companies (bottom 20% of companies by an average 70 percent.
ranked by market value of equity) out-performed In this case the indicator variable is the ex-
the S&P index by 5.5 percent in January for the treme relative loss value of the share. As before
years 1926 to 1986. These small firms earned the apparent forecastability leads to a simple
inferior returns in only seven out of the 61 years. investment strategy, but knowledge is required of
Other examples are given in Ikenberry and the value taken by some variable based on all
Lakonishok (1989). Beta coefficients are also gen- stocks in some market.
erally high in January.
The evidence suggests that the mean of re- 2.e. Remolsal of extreme values
turns have regime changes with an indicator vari-
able which takes a value of unity in January and It is well known that the stock markets occa-
zero in other months. sionally experience extraordinary movements, as
occurred in October 1987, for example. Friedman
2.d. Price reversals and Laibson (1989) point out that these large
movements are of overpowering importance and
A number of studies have found that shares may obscure simple patterns in the data. They
that do relatively poorly over one period are consider the Standard and Poor 500 quarterly
inclined to perform well over a subsequent pe- excess returns (over treasury bills) for the period
riod, thus giving price change reversals. A survey 19541 to 1988IV. After removal of just four ex-
is provided by DeBondt (1989). For example, Dyl treme values, chosen by using a Poisson model,
and Maxfield (1987) selected 200 trading days in the remaining data fits an AR(l) model with
random in the period January 1974 to January significant lag coefficient of 0.207 resulting in an
1984, each day the three NYSE or AMEX stocks R2 value of 0.036. The two regimes are thus the
with the greatest percentage price loss (on aver- ‘ordinary’ excess returns, which seem to be fore-
age - 12%) were noted. Over the next ten trad- castable, and the extra-ordinary returns which are
ing days, these losers earn a risk-adjusted return not, from the lagged data at least.
of 3.6 percent. Similarly the three highest gainers
lost an average 1.8% over the next ten days.
Other studies find similar evidence for daily, 3. Benefits of disaggregation
weekly and even monthly returns. Transaction
costs will be fairly heavy and a strategy based on A great deal of the early work on stock market
these results will probably be risky. prices used aggregates, such as the Dow Jones or
However, Lehman (1990) considered a portfo- Standard and Poor indices, or portfolios of a
lio whose weights depended on the return of a random selection of stocks or some small group
security the previous week minus the overall re- of individual stocks. The availability of fast com-
turn, with positive weights on previous losers and puters with plenty of memory and tapes with
negative weights (going short) on previous win- daily data for all securities on the New York and
ners. The portfolio was found to consistently pro- American Exchanges, for example, allows exami-
duce positive profits over the next week, with very nation of all the securities and this can on occa-
few losing periods and so with small risk. Trans- sion be beneficial. The situation allows cross-sec-
action costs were substantial but worthwhile prof- tion regressions with time-varying coefficients
C. W.J. Grunger / Forecasting stock market prices I

which can possibly detect regularities that were month ahead forecasts. Once transaction costs
not previously available. For example Jegadeesh are taken into account the potential abnormal
(1990) uses monthly data to fit cross-section mod- returns from using P, are halved, but are still
els of the form around 0.45% per month (from personal commu-
12
nication by author of the original study).

4. Searching for causal variables

for each month. Thus, a lagged average relation- Most of the studies discussed so far have con-
ship is considered with coefficients changing each sidered forecasting of prices from just previous
month. Here R,, is the average return over a long prices but it is also obviously sensible to search
(four or six years) period which exclude the previ- for other variables that provide some forecastabil-
ous three years. [In the initial analysis, R was ity. The typical regression is
estimated over the following few years, but this
Ap, = constant + _p’Kl _ , + E, ,
choice was dropped when forecasting properties
were considered.] Many of the averaged aj were where & is a vector of plausible explanatory, or
significantly different from zero, particularly at causal variables, with a variety of lags considered.
lags one and twelve, but other average coeffi- For example Darrat (1990) considered a monthly
cients were also significant, including at lags 24 price index from the Toronto Stock Exchange for
and 36. A few examples are shown, with t-values the period January 1972 to February 1987 and
in brackets.
achieved a relationship:
_
a1 a,2 aI4
Rf
Ap, = tsTA volatility of interest rates (t - 1)
all months -0.09(18) 0.034(9) 0.019(6.5) 0.108
January -0.23 (9) 0.08 (5) 0.034C2.6) 0.178
Feb. to Dec. -0.08(17) 0.03 (8) 0.017(6) 0.102 - :;::A production index (t - 1)

Source: Jegadeesh (1990).


+ yiE3fA long-term interest rate (t - 10)
There is apparently some average, time-vary-
ing structure in the data, as seen by R: values of - 0.015 A cyclically-adjusted budget
10% or more. As noticed earlier, January has (3.0)
more forecastability than other months and it was deficit (t - 3)) (4.1)
found that a group of large firms had regressions
with higher Rf in February to December than all R2 = 0.46,
firms using these regressions (without the R Durbin-Watson = 2.01,
terms), stocks were ranked each month on their where only significant terms are shown and the
expected forecastability and ten portfolios formed modulus of t-values in brackets. Several other
from the 10% most forecastable (P,), second variables were considered but not found to be
10% and so forth up to the 10% least fore- significant, including changes of short-term rates,
castable (P,,,). The average abnormal monthly inflation rate, base money and the US-Canadian
returns (i.e. after risk removal) on the ‘best’ and exchange rate, all lagged once. An apparently
‘worse’ portfolios for different periods were high significance R2 value is obtained but no
All months January Feb.-Dec. out-of-sample forecastability is investigated.
0.011 0.024 0.009 This search may be more successful if a long-
PI
P 10 - 0.014 - 0.020 -0.017 run forecastability is attempted. For example Ho-
drick (1990) used monthly US data for the period
Source: Jegadeesh (1990).
1929 to December 1987 to form NYSE value-
There is thus seen to be a substantial benefit weighted real market returns, Rr+k, over the
from using the best portfolio rather than the time span (t + 1, t + k). The regression
worst one based on the regressions. Benefits were
also found, but less substantial ones, using twelve log R,tk,t = (Ye+ p,( dividend/price ratio at t )
x C. W.J. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices

found R2 increasing as k increases, up to R2 = able at the time of the forecast was used in
0.354 at k = 48. Thus, apparent long-run fore- making the forecast.
castability has been found from a very simple (ii) If the predictor was negative, the invest in
model. However, again no post-sample evaluation T-bills.
is attempted. The following table shows the rate of returns
Pesaran and Timmerman (1990) also employ achieved by either using a ‘buy-and-hold’ market
simple models that produce useful forecastability portfolio, or the switching portfolio obtained from
and they also conduct a careful evaluation of the the above trading rule or by just buying T-bills.
model. As an example of the kind of model they As the switching rule involves occasional buying
produce, the following equation has as its depen- and selling, possibly quarterly, two levels of trans-
dent variable (Y,> the quarterly excess return on action costs are considered 4% and 1%.
the Standard and Poor 500 portfolio: Investment strategy

Y = - 0.097 + t_T7: dividend yield ( t - 2) Market Switching T-bill


Transaction
- 1.59 inflation rate (t - 3) costs 0 4% 1% 0
(2.8) Interest rate of
- ?$)I T-bill (end, t - 1) returns 9.5 1 13.30 12.39 6.34
Standard deviation
of returns 8.23 5.43 5.41 0.70
+ 0.025 T-bill (begin, t - 2) Wealth at end of
(4.6)
period ” 1394 3736 2961 595
+ 0.066A twelve month bond state (t - 1)
(5.5) ” The period considered from 1960.1 to 1988.IV and the
wealth accumulates from an investment of $100 in Decem-
+ residual, (4.2) ber 1959.
Source: Pesaran and Timmerman (I 990).
Rf = 0.364, Durbin-Watson = 2.02.
Although the results presented are slightly bi-
Here dividend yield at time t is ased against the switching portfolio zero transac-
dividend on S&P index ( t - 1) tion costs are assumed for the alternative invest-
ments, the trading rule based on the regression is
price of S&P index (t) .
seen to produce the greatest returns and as a
T-bill is the one month interest rate ‘end’ means lower risk-level than the market (S&P 500) port-
it is measured at the end of the third month of folio. A variety of other evaluation methods and
the quarter, ‘begin’ indicates that it is measured other regressions are also presented in the paper.
at the end of the first month of the quarter. The It would seem that dividend/price ratios and
two T-bill terms in the equation are thus effec- interest rates have quite good long-run forecast-
tively the change in the T-bill interest rate from ing abilities for stock price index returns.
one month to the next, plus one at the end of the
quarter. As just lagged variables are involved and
a reasonable R: value is found, the model can 5. A new look at old techniques - Technical
potentially be used for forecasting. [It might be trading rules
noted that Rz climbed to 0.6 or so for annual
data.] Some experimentation with non-linear A strategy that is popular with actual specula-
lagged dependent variables produced some in- tors, but is disparaged by academics, is to use an
creases in R:, to about 0.39, but this more com- automatic, or technical trading rule. An example
plicated model was not further evaluated. is to use perceived patterns in the data, such as
A simple switching portfolio trading rule was the famous ‘head and shoulders’, and to devise a
considered: rule based on them. Much technical analysis is
(i) Buy the S&P 500 index if the excess return difficult to evaluate, as the rules are not precise
was predicted to be positive according to enough. The early literature did consider various
equation (4.2), with the equation being se- simple rules but generally found little or no fore-
quentially re-estimated. Thus only data avail- casting value in them. However, the availability of
C. W.J. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices 9

fast computers has allowed a new, more intensive Neftci (1991) investigates a similar moving av-
evaluation to occur, with rather different results. erage trading rule using different statistical meth-
Brock, Lakonishok and LeBaron (1991) con- ods and an even longer period - monthly Dow-
sider two technical rules, one comparing the most Jones Industrial Index starting in 1792, up to
recent value to a recent moving average, and the 1976. Let M, be an equi-weighted moving aver-
other is a ‘trading range breakout’. Only the first age over the past five months. If P, is the price of
of these is discussed here. the index in month t, define a dummy variable:
The first trading rule is as follows:
D,= 1 if P,>M, given P,+, CM,_,
Let M, = average of previous 50 prices, form = -1 if P, <M, given P,-, >&I_,
a band B, = (1 f 0.01) M,, so that the band
= 0 otherwise.
is plus and minus 1% around M,. If P,, the
current price, is above the band, this is a Regression results are presented for the equation
buy signal, if it is below the band, this is a
sell signal. P*+,# = 5 CI~P~_~
+ 5 Y~D,_~ + residual,
j=0 j=0
Using 90 years of daily data for the Dow-Jones
Index (giving a sample of over twenty-three thou- where the residual is allowed to be a moving
sand values) for the period 1897 to 1986, the rule average of order 17, for each of the three sub-
suggested buying 50% of the time giving an aver- periods 1792-1851, 1852-1910 and 1910-1976. In
age return next day of 0.00062 (t = 3.7) and sell- each case the sum of the alphas is near one, as
ing 42% of the time, giving an average return of suggested by the efficient market theory and in
- 0.00032 (t = 3.6). The return on the rule ‘buy if the more recent period the gammas were all
have buy signal and go short on a sell signal’ gave significant, individually and jointly, suggesting
an average daily return of 0.00094 (t = 5.4). The some nonlinearity in the prices. No forecasting
first two t-values are for the return minus the exercise was considered using the models. The
daily unconditional average return, the ‘buy-sell’ use of data with such early dates as 1897 or 1792
r-value is relative to zero. If this buy-sell strategy is surely only of intellectual interest, because of
was used 200 times a year, it gives a return of 20.7 the dramatic institutional changes there have oc-
percent for the year. However, this figure ignores curred since then.
transaction costs, which could be substantial. The Neftci also proves, using the theory of optimal
trading rule was considered for four sub-periods forecasts, that technical trading rules can only be
and performed similarly for the first three but helpful with forecasting if the price series are
less well for the most recent sub-period of 1962- inherently nonlinear.
1986, where the buy-sell strategy produced a daily
return of 0.00049. Other similar trading rules
were considered and gave comparable results. 6. New techniques - Cointegration and chaos
Thus, this rule did beat a buy-and-hold strategy
by a significant amount if transaction costs are Since the early statistical work on stock prices,
not considered. The authors also consider a much up to 1975, say, a number of new and potentially
more conservative rule, with a fixed ten day hold- important statistical models and techniques have
ing period after a buy or sell signal. The above been developed. Some arrive with a great flourish
rule then averages only 3; buy and sell signals a and then vanish, such as catastrophe theory,
year, giving an annual expected return of 8.5% whereas others seem to have longer staying power.
compared to an annual return for the Dow Index I will here briefly consider two fairly new ap-
of about 5%, again ignoring transaction costs. proaches which have not been successful, so far,
These, and the results for the other trading rules in predicting stock prices.
considered suggest that there may be regular but An Z(1) series is one such that it’s first differ-
subtle patterns in stock price data, which would ence is stationary. A pair, X,, Y,, of Z(1) series
give useful forecastability. However, very long are called cointegrated if there is a linear combi-
series are needed to investigate these rules. nation of them, Z, =X, - AY,, say, which is Z(0).
10 C. W.J. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices

The properties and implications of such series are with


described in Granger (19861, Engle and Granger
(19911, and many other publications in economet- 0 < Yo < 1>
rics, macroeconomics and finance. If the series
have developed a great deal of interest and can
are cointegrated there is necessarily an error-cor-
be called ‘white chaos’. These series have the
rection data generating model of the form (ignor-
physical appearance of a stochastic independent
ing constants):
(i.i.d.1 process and also the linear properties of a
,4X, = (Y,Z, _, + lagged AX,, AY, terms white noise such as zero autocorrelations and a
+ white noise, flat spectrum. The question naturally arises of
whether the series we have been viewing as
plus a similar equation for Ax, with at least one
stochastic white noise are actually white chaos
of N.~, tiy,. being non-zero. It follows that either X,
and are thus actually perfectly forecastable - at
must help forecast Y,+ , or Y, must help forecast
least in the short run and provided the actual
X ,+ , or both. Thus, if dividends and stock prices
generating mechanism is known exactly. The lit-
are found to be cointegrated, as theory suggests,
erature on chaos is now immense, involves excit-
then prices might help forecast dividends, which
ing and deep mathematics and truly beautiful
would not be surprising, but dividends not help
diagrams, and also is generally optimistic, sug-
forecast prices, in agreement with the efficient
gesting that these processes occur frequently. In
market hypothesis. However, for the same reason
fact, a clear case can be made that they do not
one would not expect a pair of stock prices to be
occur in the real world, as opposed to in labora-
cointegrated, as this would contradict the effi-
tory physics experiments. There is no statistical
cient market hypothesis. In fact several papers
test that has chaos as the null hypothesis. There
have been produced that claim to find cointegra-
also appears to be no characterizing property of a
tion between pairs of prices or of portfolios, but
chaotic process, that is a property that is true for
the error-correction models are not presented or
chaos but not for any completely stochastic pro-
the forecasting possibility explored, and so this
cess. These arguments are discussed in Liu,
work will not be surveyed. It should be noted that
Granger and Heller (1991). It is true that some
cointegration would be inconsistent with the
high-dimensional white chaotic processes are in-
well-respected capital asset pricing model
distinguishable from iid series, but this does not
(CAPM) which says that the price P,, of the ith
mean that chaos occurs in practice. In the above
asset is related to the price of the whole market
paper, a number of estimates of a statistic known
P,,,, bY as the correlation dimension are made for various
3 log P,, = b,d log P,, + E;, , parameter values using over three thousand
Standard and Poor 500 daily returns. The result-
where err is white noise. Summing over time gives
ing values are consistent with stochastic white
noise (or high dimensional chaos) rather than low
log Pi, = bi log P,,cr + i e,,t_j.
dimensional - and thus potentially forecastable -
j=O
white chaos. A little introspection also make it
As the last term is the accumulation of a station- seem unlikely to most economists that a stock
ary series, it is 1(l) (ignoring trends) and so market, which is complex, involving many thou-
cointegration should not occur between log P,, sands of speculations, could obey a simple deter-
and log P,,,. Similarly, there should be no cointe- ministic model.
gration between portfolios, Gonzalo (1991) has
found no cointegration between three well known
aggregates, the Dow-Jones Index, the Standard
7. Higher moments
and Poor 500 Index and the New York Stock
Exchange Equal Value Index.
A class of processes generated by particular To make a profit, it is necessary to be able to
deterministic maps, such as forecast the mean of price changes, and the stud-
ies reviewed above all attempt to do this. The
y,=4y,-,(I -Y,-,) efficient market theory says little about the fore-
C. W.J. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices 11

castability of functions of price changes or re- as a cumulative distribution function of a contin-


turns, such as higher moments. If R, is a return it uous random variable so that 0 I @ I 1, _X, is a
has been found that Rf and is clearly fore- vector of explanatory variables possibly including
castable and IR, I even more so, from lagged lagged returns and w, is the ‘switching variable’,
values. Taylor (1986) finds evidence for this using possibly a lagged component of & or some linear
U.S. share prices and Kariya, Tsukuda and Maru combination of these components. It has always
(1990) get similar results for Japanese stocks. For been important to discover appropriate explana-
example, if R, is the daily return from the U.S. tory variables &, and with this new class of
Standard and Poor index the autocorrelations for models it is especially important to find the ap-
R, are generally very small, the autocorrelations propriate switching variable, if it exists and is
for Rf are consistently above 0.1 up to lag 100 observable. This class of models is discussed in
and for IR, I are about 0.35 up to lag 100. It is Granger and Terasvirta (1992), where tests and
clear that these functions of returns are very estimation procedures are outlined.
forecastable, but this is not easily converted into The papers also suggest that some sub-periods
profits, although there are implications for the may be more forecastable than others - such as
efficiency of options markets. The results are summer months or January - and this is worth
consistent with certain integrated GARCH mod- exploring. If many component series are avail-
els but this work is still being conducted and the able, then ranks may produce further information
final conclusions have yet to be reached. that is helpful with forecasting. There seems to
be many opportunities for forecasters, many of
whom need to break away from simple linear
8. Lessons for forecasters univariate ARIMA or multivariate transfer func-
tions. It is often not easy to beat convincingly
Despite stock returns once having been thought these simple methods, so they make excellent
to be unforecastable, there is now plenty of opti- base-line models, but they often can be beaten.
mism that this is not so, as the examples given Before the results discussed in previous sec-
above show. Is this optimism justified, and if yes, tions are accepted the question of how they should
what are the lessons for forecasters working with be evaluated has to be considered. Many of the
other data sets? As there is an obvious possible studies in this, and other forecasting areas, are of
profit motive driving research into the forecasta- the ‘if only I had know this at the beginning of
bility of stock prices, or at least returns, one can the period I could have made some money’ classi-
expect more intensive analysis here than else- fication. For a ‘forecasting model’ to be accepted
where. Whereas too many forecasters seem to be it has to show that it actually forecasts, it is not
content with just using easily available data, with sufficient to produce a regression model evalu-
the univariate or simple transfer function fore- ated only in sample. There is always the possibil-
casting techniques that are found on popular ity of small-sample in-sample biases of coeffi-
computer packages, stock market research is more cients which give overly encouraging results, as
ambitious and wide-ranging. It should be empha- shown by Nelson and Kim (1990). The possibility
sized that the above is not a complete survey of of ‘data mining’ having occurred, with many mod-
all of the available literature. els having been considered, and just the best one
The sections above suggest that benefits can presented is also a worry. Only out-of-sample
arise from taking a longer horizon, from using evaluation is relevant and, to some extent, avoids
disaggregated data, from carefully removing out- these difficulties. It is surprising that more of the
hers or exceptional events, and especially from studies surveyed do not provide results of fore-
considering non-linear models. Many of the latter casting exercises.
can be classified as belonging to a regime switch- Not only do the models that are proposed as
ing model of the form providing useful forecasts of price changes or
returns need to be evaluated, to provide prof-
itable strategies the forecast returns need to be
corrected for risk levels and also for transaction
were Q(w) is a smooth monotonic function such costs. Many of the studies discussed earlier fail to
12 C. W.J. Granger / Forecasting stock murket prices

do this, and so, at present, say nothing about the Friedman, B.M. and D.1. Laibson, 1989, “Economic implica-
correctness of the efficient market hypothesis tions of extraordinary movements in stock prices, Working
paper, Ecomomics Department, Harvard University.
(EMH). However, this criticism does not always
Gonzalo, J., 1991, Private communication.
apply, for example for the carefully conducted Granger, C.W.J.. 1972, “Empirical studies of captial markets:
analysis by Pesaran and Timmerman (1990). Does A survey, in: G. Szego and K. Shell, eds., Mathematical
this mean that the EMH should be rejected? One Methods in Investment and Finance (North-Holland. Am-
has to say - not necessarily, yet. If a method sterdam).
Granger, C.W.J., 1986, “Development in the study of cointe-
exists that consistently produces positive profits
grated economic variables”. Oxford Bulletin of Economics
after allowing for risk correction and transaction and Statistics. 48, 213-228.
costs and if this method has been publicly an- Granger, C.W.J. and 0. Morgenstern. 1970, Predictability c~f
nounced for some time, then this would possibly Stock Market Prices (Heath-Lexington).

be evidence against EMH. There are so many Granger, C.W.J. and T. Terasvirta, 1992, Modelling Nonlinear
Economic Relutionships(Oxford University Press, Oxford).
possibly relevant trading rules that it is unrealistic
Guimaraes, R.M.C., B.G. Kingsman and S.J. Taylor, 1989. A
to suppose that investors have tried them all, Rerrppraisal of the Efliciency of Financial Markets (Sprin-
especially those that have only been discovered ger-Verlag, Berlin).
by expensive computation and sophisticated sta- Hodrick. R.J.. 1990. “Dividend yields and expected stock
tistical techniques. Once knowledge of an appar- returns: Alternative procedures for inference and meas-
urement”, Working paper, Kellogg Graduate School of
ently trading rule becomes wide enough, one
Management, Northwestern University.
would expect behaviour of speculators to remove Ikenberry, D. and J. Lakonishok, 1989. Seasonal anomalies in
its profitability, unless there exists another trad- financial markets: A survey. in: Guimaraes et al. (1989).
ing rule the speculators think is superior and thus Jegadeesh, N., 1990, “Evidence of predictable behaviour of
concentrate on it. Only if a profitable rule is security returns”. Joftrtzal of Finance, 35, X81-898.
Jensen M.C., 1978. Some anomalous evidence regarding mar-
found to be widely known and remains profitable
ket efficiency, Journal of Financiul Economics. 6, 95- 101.
for an extended period can the efficient market Kariya, T., T. Tsukuda and J. Maru, 1990, Testing the random
hypothesis be rejected. It will be worthwhile walk hypothesis for Japanese stock prices in S. Taylor
checking in a few years on the continued prof- models, Working paper 90-94. Graduate School of Busi-
itability of the rules discussed earlier. This re- ness, University of Chicago.
Keim, D.B., 19X9, Earnings yield and size effects: Uncondi-
search program agrees with the modern taste in
tional and conditional estimates, in: Guimaraes et al.
the philosophy of science to try to falsify theories (1989).
rather than to try to verify them. Clearly verifica- LeBaron, B., 1990. forecasting improvements using a volatility
tion of EMH is impossible. index, Working paper, Economics Department, University
of Wisconsin.
Lehman, B.N., 1990. Fads, martingales, and market efficiency.
Quarterly journal of Economics, 105 (1) l-28.
References
LeRoy, SF., 1989. Efficient capital markets and martingales,
Brock, W., J. Lakonishok and B. LeBaron. 1991, “Simple Journal of Ecottomic Literature 27, 1583-1621.
technical trading rules and the stochastic properties of Liu, T.. C.W.J. Granger and W. Heller, 1991, Using the
stock returns, Working paper 9022, Social Science Re- correlation exponent to decide if an economic series is
search Institute, Unrversity of Wisconsin, Madison. chaotic, Working paper, Economics Department, Univer-
Dark. F.H. and K. Kate, 1986, “Stock market over-reaction in sity of California. San Diego.
the Japanese stock market”. Working Paper. Iowa State Neftci. S.N.. 1991. Naive trading rules in fincancial markets
University. and Wiener-Kolmogorov prediction theory, Journal of
Darrat, A.F., 1990, “Stock returns, money and fiscal deficits”, Busmess. s49-571.
Journal of Financial and Quantitatiw Analysis, 25, 387-398. Nelson, C.R. and M.J. Kim, 1990, Predictable stock returns:
DeBondt, W.F.M.. 1984, Stock price reversals and over-reac- reality or statistical illusion‘? Working paper, Economics
tion to news events. A survey of theory and evidence, in: Department, University of Washington, Seattle.
Guimaraes et al. (19X9). Pesaran, M.H. and A.G. Timmerman, 1990, The statistical
Dyl. E.A. and K. Maxfield. 1987, Does the stock market and economic significance of the predictability of excess
over-react‘? Working paper, University of Arizona. returns on common stocks, Program in Applied Econo-
Engle. R.F. and C.W.J. Granger, 1991, Long-rmr Ecorlomic metrics Discussion paper #26, University of California,
Relationships; Reading.7 in Cointegrution (Oxford University Los Angeles.
Press. Oxford). Taylor. S., 1986. Modelling Financial Time Serre.s (Wiley,
Fama, E.F.. 1970, “Efficient capital markets: A review of Chichester).
theory and empirical work”. Journal of finance, 25. 3X3- Tong, H.. 1990. Non&war Time Series (Oxford University
417. Press. Oxford).
C. KJ. Granger / Forecasting stock market prices 13

Biography: Clive GRANGER is Professor of Economics at


the University of California, San Diego having moved from a
professorship in Applied Statistics and Econometrics of Not-
tingham University sixteen years ago. His work has empha-
sised forecasting, econometric modelling, speculative markets,
causality and cointegration. He has written and edited nine
books and nearly 1.50 papers. He is a Fellow of the Economet-
ric Society.

You might also like