You are on page 1of 10

Organizational Impacts of Information

Technology
Balaji Parthasarathy, International Institute of Information Technology, India
Ricardo Lage, International Institute of Information Technology, India

Introduction 289 Similarities in the Adoption of IT:


The Significance of Contemporary Conquering Space and Time 294
IT and Its Adoption 289 IT Adoption in the United States:
Misconceptions about the Organizational The Cases of G. F. Swift and
Impacts of IT 290 Company and Dell Computer 294
The Argument 290 IT Adoption in Developing Contexts:
Productivity Improvements and the The Fisheries Industry in
Adoption of IT 291 Kerala, India 296
Spatial Unevenness and Social Differences Conclusion: IT a Necessary Tool but Not a
in the Adoption of IT 292 Strategic Differentiator 296
The Digital Divide 292 Glossary 297
The Selective Globalization of IT Services Cross References 297
and Outsourcing to India 293 References and Suggested Readings 297
Differences among Developed Countries:
E-commerce in the United States and Japan 293

INTRODUCTION earlier centuries means that microelectronics is just one


more in a sequence of forces transforming IT, there are at
The Significance of Contemporary IT and Its least two reasons why this transformation is considered
Adoption significant enough to be the basis of a third industrial
Drawing on Shapiro and Varian (1999, 3), this chapter revolution (Castells 2000).
uses information to mean anything that can be digitized First, advances in microelectronics ÎÎmake it possible
or encoded as a stream of bits. However, unlike in formal to obtain and deliver information from and to any corner
information theory, in which “ . . . the semantic aspects of of the world, in real time, on a scale unparalleled in his-
communication are irrelevant to the engineering aspects” tory. Although the importance of information has long
(Shannon and Weaver 1964, 8), not every bit stream qual- been recognized, the historical relevance of such possi-
ifies as information: following Bell (1999), there must be bilities is heightened by concurrent economic and social
a context to understand its structure and meaning. The transformations. The acceptance of economic globaliza-
importance of a social context for information is cap- tion, for example, has increased the demand for infor-
tured in the widely held truism that knowledge is power. mation about distant markets. Similarly, as the virtues of
Knowledge is information that is used to present “ . . . political democracy are emphasized, access to informa-
a reasoned judgment or an experimental result, which tion is viewed as a fundamental right.
is transmitted through some communication medium Second, as with other technologies, the adoption of
in some systematic form” (Bell 1999, 175). The work of IT has been driven by the desire to improve productivity
economists such as Stigler (1961) and Akerloff (1970) has and aggregate standards of living. This is especially the
more formally established the importance of informa- case with general-purpose technologies like IT that not
tion, especially for the functioning of efficient markets. only improve productivity in their own sector, in this case
The Information Technology Association of America information processing, but also have the potential “ . . .
defines Information Technology (IT), as “the study, design, to transform an economy by finding new applications and
development, implementation, support, or management fusing with existing technologies to rejuvenate other, pre-
of computer-based information systems, particularly soft- existing sectors of the economy” (David 2000, 75). Indeed,
ware applications and computer hardware” (ITAA n.d., advances in microelectronics have made IT increasingly
30). Although, as the definition suggests, IT has become more powerful, affordable, and versatile. As a result, it is
closely identified with microelectronics-based comput- no more than a broad and fuzzy term to describe various
ing and networking since the mid-twentieth century, it activities, ranging from issues connected with the tech-
has existed ever since there has been information and nology, such as computer hardware and software, to the
the means to represent information, such as language, deployment of the technology for information processing
graphics (including scripts), and number systems, were in application domains as distinct as design, cartography,
invented. While the invention of writing or telegraphy in and medicine.
289
290 ORGANIZATIONAL IMPACTS OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY

Misconceptions about the Organizational 2008a). While e-books are likely to be used for text-only
documents with a linear narrative, such as fiction, a wide-
Impacts of IT spread switch to e-books, at the expense of p(aper)-books,
The potential impact of adopting IT manifests itself not is unlikely (Clark et al. 2008). This is because of techno-
only in direct and measurable productivity improvements. logical advances, which, for example, make the publish-
It also manifests itself in changes in organizations, or the ing of print-on-demand (PoD) titles economically feasible
“ . . . patterns of communications and relations among a for even a tiny readership. This commercial opportunity
group of human beings, including the processes for mak- is lost even on Amazon, which has announced it will print
ing and implementing decisions” (Simon 1997, 18–19). all the PoD books it sells (Clark et al. 2008).
Yet, while information and IT have had a long and impor- In the late 1980s, business process reengineering was
tant role in various guises in human history, Brown and offered as a means of overcoming organizational incon-
Duguid (2000) lament the limited understanding of the sistencies and inertia in firms to enhance their produc-
organizational changes that accompany the introduc- tivity (Brown and Duguid 2000). As consultants advised
tion of contemporary IT. They fear that a temptation to managers to obliterate organizational structures, and to
vest hope in the explosion of bit streams alone, to help start afresh by setting aside old practices, reengineering
overcome the challenges posed by working with incom- was widely adopted. By the mid-1990s, however, reengi-
plete information, is a case of 6-D vision, that empha- neering was viewed with much skepticism as it failed to
sizes disintermediation, disaggregation, demassification, deliver the improvements it promised. Its reliance on tech-
decentralization, denationalization, and despatialization nology was seen merely as another means of downsizing.
(Brown and Duguid 2000, 22). However, by overlook- Claims about the “death of distance” (Cairncross 2001),
ing the need for concomitant social changes, 6-D vision and about city downtowns being “leftover baggage from
reduces the bit stream explosion to a glut of data rather the industrial era” (Gilder 1995) followed as inexpensive
than viewing it as a proliferation of information. bandwidth became available in the 1990s with the spread
A consequence is what Brown and Duguid term end- of a fiber optics–led digital network infrastructure. But
isms, which proclaims the end of various social organiza- Townsend (2003) shows that the new infrastructure did
tions, including mass media, brokers and intermediaries, not lead to the urban dissolution envisaged by the techno-
firms and bureaucracies, universities, government, cities utopians because they mistakenly treated telecommuni-
and regions, and the nation state. Although many of these cation and transportation as substitutes. Instead, digital
organizations may well undergo changes, most proc- infrastructure witnessed the emergence of new elements
lamations focus almost entirely on the organization as that only reinforced existing physical, social, and economic
an economic entity, and the changing transactions costs networks within the urban fabric, but in a highly uneven
that the introduction of new technology brings. But they fashion. These elements included info-highways (providing
ignore that organizations are also social and psychologi- fiber connectivity from the global to neighborhood scales),
cal entities, characterized by informal practices and flows info-factories (located in urban financial and cultural
of information, with the possibility of individual goals centers to produce the content for the information age),
diverging from organizational goals (Simon 1997). As a info-warehouses (secure, climate-controlled data stor-
result, endisms typically lack empirical basis as the fol- age centers, akin to industrial warehouses, located close
lowing examples attest. to urban areas for access to metropolitan data networks),
Despite claims about the imminent arrival of the and info-ports (interconnecting various data networks and
paperless office as the use of electronic documents spread located in urban centers).
since the 1970s, Sellen and Harper (2001) make a com-
pelling case for the importance of paper. They point
to certain physical properties of paper (it is thin, light, The Argument
porous, opaque, and flexible) that facilitate such human It is against this backdrop of the (mis)understanding of
actions as grasping, carrying, folding, and writing, in contemporary IT that this chapter makes three interre-
a way that digital devices do not. The rise in the use of lated arguments. First, aggregate improvements in pro-
paper, along with the growing use of e-mail, for example, ductivity will not automatically follow the introduction of
suggests a complementary role for both, rather than the IT. That is, changing the technical division of labor will
end of paper. More recent predictions about the end of lead to noticeable productivity improvements only when
paper have accompanied the arrival of e-book readers. accompanied by changes to the social and spatial divisions
However, such predictions ignore problems with ergo- of labor. Similarly, at a firm level, Teece (2006, 1133) argues
nomics, interfaces, incompatible standards, and digital that “ . . . managerial choices, the nature of knowledge,
rights management, which plague these devices (Clark et intellectual property protection, and the asset structure
al. 2008). Clark et al. report a study of the usage of Kindle of the firm impact the business enterprise’s ability to cap-
(the e-book reader from the online retailer Amazon), at ture value from innovation.” But changes to the division
Texas A&M University, in which users appreciated many of labor, and the ability of firms to profit from innovation,
technical features of the product, such as the wireless can neither be taken for granted, nor are they instantane-
download of content. But concerns with page navigation, ous. This argument is made in the section “Productivity
graphics, and screen display, made them rule out regular Improvements and the Adoption of IT” by discussing the
use. It is likely that many problems currently plaguing e- productivity paradox in the late twentieth century and
book readers will be addressed over time, and they will no comparing it with a similar paradox that followed the
longer “remain crude simulacra of books” (The Economist introduction of the dynamo in the late nineteenth century.
PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS AND THE ADOPTION OF IT 291

Second, despite economic globalization and the emer- dent to the early adopters, the process was slow. Thus,
gence of an increasingly unitary global economy that oper- the productivity effects of this substitution were not felt
ates in real time at a planetary scale, the organizational until the 1920s, when the electrification of mechanical
impacts of IT suffer from sociospatial unevenness. Indeed, drives crossed the 50 percent mark, thanks in part to
capitalism has historically been characterized by such falling prices (David 2000, 356). It was then that grad-
unevenness and informational capitalism is no different ual diffusion led to widespread use triggered by network
(Castells 2000). This argument is made in the section on externalities.
the digital divide by pointing to the international divide David explains the sluggishness in substitution as a
that exists in the adoption of IT. The divide is not merely a technological and organizational regime transition, or
case of the poor versus the rich. The section “The Selective a set of technological and organizational adjustments
Globalization of IT Services and Outsourcing to India” that must be made when a new technology is introduced.
describes how India, despite being poor, has managed Teece (2006, 1139) is in agreement with David when
to become one of the largest non-OECD exporters of IT he says that “many technologies today are systemic.
services. The section immediately after that compares the Successful commercialization requires bringing together
different approaches to e-commerce in the United States complementary technology as well as complementary
and Japan to show how differences are manifest even patents. . . . Of course, many innovations require com-
among developed countries. Furthermore, even within a plementary infrastructure investments (for the automo-
country like the United States, the adoption of IT need not bile, roads and service stations; for electricity, long-life
have a uniform impact across firms, reflecting differences lightbulbs plus generators, transmission lines, and stand-
in organizational approaches. ards).” In the case of the dynamo, factories designed to
Third, although its technical characteristics and the run on steam power had to depreciate their assets before
context for its adoption have changed, the organizational it became profitable to turn to electrical power. More
means of adopting IT have not changed over time. The crucially, it took until the 1920s to understand that the
section “IT Adoption in the United States: The Case of substitution was more effective when accompanied by
G. F. Swift and Company and Dell Computer” compares redesigning factory layouts that supplied machines and
the adoption of the telegraph in the mid-nineteenth cen- tools with power from separate secondary electric motors
tury by the Swift meatpacking company in the United instead of relying on centralized transmission. In addition
States, and the use of the Internet by the computer maker to energy efficiency that came with the switch to easy-to-
Dell in the late twentieth century to illustrate how they distribute electrical power, factories could be better laid
shared the goal of conquering space and time to boost out to accommodate redesigned workflows. Furthermore,
their competitiveness and profitability. A similar goal is infrastructure investments (for example, the establish-
also evident in the adoption of mobile telephony by fish- ment of transmission networks) contributed to many
ermen in the Indian state of Kerala, as discussed in the quality changes, such as improvements in lighting equip-
section that immediately follows the section on Swift ment and urban transit systems, which were unmeasured
and Dell. at the time, resulting in depressed productivity.
The chapter closes by pointing to a feature in the adop- A similar bias was noted from the 1980s when, with
tion of a general-purpose technology like IT. While those falling prices in the 1970s, there was an expansion in
who deploy the technology productively profit, aggre- investment in IT to utilize its “ . . . broad power to reduce
gate benefits are realized only as others learn and imi- the costs of coordination, communications, and informa-
tate them. In other words, as the advantages of deploying tion processing” (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2000, 24). But
technology become evident to more actors, any advantage economists did not find such investments necessarily
from its deployment will remain less with possessing the translating into productivity improvements—a phenome-
technology than with the unique organizational means of non that has been referred to as the productivity paradox.
deploying IT (Carr 2004). This point is made by drawing This paradox was succinctly captured by Solow (1987)
on the different routes to operational efficiencies taken when he said, “We can see the computer age everywhere
by Cisco Systems, a pioneer in the deployment of IT, and but in the productivity statistics.”
the manual system of delivering meals by the dabbawal- By the 1990s, however, evidence began to emerge from
las (the lunchbox men, in Hindi) of Mumbai. firm-level studies about the contribution of IT to produc-
tivity (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2000). The gap between the
firm-level findings and those at the macrolevel was due to
PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS measurement problems (caused by lags, redistribution,
and the like). Conventional productivity measures focus
AND THE ADOPTION OF IT only on observable aspects of output such as price and
To understand why improvements in productivity will not quantity, neglecting intangible gains such as improved
automatically follow the introduction of IT, it is worth quality, new products, customer service, and speed.
examining the spread of the dynamo, a general-purpose Furthermore, measurement also neglected complemen-
technology from an earlier era. Like IT, the dynamo tary investments in business processes and work prac-
witnessed many technical improvements after it was tices that were crucial to ensuring the intangible gains.
first developed in the 1880s (David 2000). Although As Cortada (2004, 37) puts it, “The direct contribution of
dynamos began to substitute for water power and steam the computer is difficult to quantify because when com-
engines as prime movers soon after electrification began panies and government agencies were investing substan-
in 1881 in the United States, and its benefits became evi- tially in computers, they were also acquiring other types
292 ORGANIZATIONAL IMPACTS OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY

of technology, all in the spirit of leveraging new tools to well networked with older forms of IT, including radio,
improve operations.” In other words, IT was used as part televisions, and telephones, will prevail in the digital
of a process to bring about more profound organizational economy, especially in the absence of initiatives to over-
changes. come social stratification. In other words, the optimists
Drawing on their study of various performance indi- believe that technological and economic characteristics
cators of all publicly traded firms in the United States of IT will ensure that absolute differences will narrow
between the 1960s and 2005, McAfee and Brynjolfsson over time, whereas the pessimists believe that relative
(2008) point to the consequences of the organizational inequities will persist.
changes. They argue that a new competitive dynamic, Norris’s analysis of the global divide across 179 coun-
akin to Schumpeterian creative destruction, has emerged tries shows that economic factors, especially per capita
since the mid-1990s, especially in those industrial sectors gross domestic product (GDP), is the most important
that have invested the most in IT. This dynamic is char- predictor of cross-national differences in access to the
acterized by “ . . . greater gaps between the leaders and Internet. Since the same factors are also the best pre-
laggards in an industry, more concentrated and winner- dictors of access to older forms of IT, she argues that
take-all markets, and more churn among rivals in a sec- Internet access is limited less by the particular charac-
tor” (McAfee and Brynjolfsson 2008, 100). teristics of the technology, such as lack of Internet con-
nections or fewer non-English language web sites, than
by more entrenched socioeconomic conditions that also
SPATIAL UNEVENNESS AND SOCIAL deny access to telephones and televisions.
DIFFERENCES IN THE ADOPTION OF IT Kraemer and Dedrick (2001) share Norris’s conclusions
about “new technologies, old inequalities” when address-
The Digital Divide ing the question of the payoffs from investments in IT at
In her work on the digital divide, Norris (2001) highlights a national level. They find evidence of a relationship with
the widespread unevenness in the diffusion and adoption increased productivity and economic growth, although
of the Internet. Although the diffusion of many technolo- that result is influenced by the extent of complemen-
gies has tended to follow an S-shaped pattern (slow initial tary investments. They present a conceptual framework
adoption, a substantial surge that peaks when penetration wherein four factors drive investments in IT—national
levels reach saturation point, followed by a slowdown in wealth, wage rates, IT infrastructure, and the price-to-
demand), whether the S will be flat and elongated, or performance ratio of IT products. These investments
whether it will be upright, requires empirical investiga- offer a stimulus for greater national wealth and higher
tion (Figure 23.1). Similarly, there is no a priori reason to wages through the formation of new IT-related industries
believe that all organizations, groups, and locations will and higher skills. This relationship is clearer for devel-
be a part of the diffusion process. oped countries that have a longer history of investment in
In the case of the Internet, Norris points to a debate IT, in human resources, and in telecommunications. With
between cyberoptimists, who believe that even as those each of these investments reinforcing one another, there
with the resources, knowledge, and skill to take advan- is a virtuous cycle established between investment in IT
tage of digital technology will have an early advantage, and productivity growth.
extensive diffusion will inevitably follow as the costs of More recently, Andres et al. (2007) use data between
connectivity and access devices decline rapidly, and net- 1990 and 2004 to explain differences in Internet diffu-
work effects make the Internet too valuable to ignore. The sion between 199 countries. Their findings confirm that
cyberpessimists, on the contrary, argue that those already per capita GDP is the most relevant factor in explaining
cross-country divergence. GDP per capita is followed by
telecommunication infrastructure, as measured by the
Twentieth-Century American Technology
number of phone lines, and the cost of a local call. Higher
100
cost makes it less likely that users will adopt the Internet.
Other factors include the degree of competition between
Internet service providers: The greater the competition,
75
the lower the prices of Internet access, which, in turn,
% of Households

Phones
Radio
encourages diffusion.
TVs Andres et al. also explain Internet diffusion by relat-
50
Cable TV ing it, like Norris (2001), to an S-shaped curve defined by
VCR network effects. When the authors introduce the number
PCs of Internet users in a year in their regression model, the
25
Net variable becomes the most significant explanation for
the number of users in the following year, irrespective of
national income level. Network effects are more significant
0
in developed countries (high-income and upper- middle-
1900
1905
1910
1915
1920
1925
1930
1935
1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000

income countries, as defined by the World Bank), where


a 10 percent increase in the number of Internet users in
Figure 23.1: The Diffusion of Various Technologies in the
a year leads to an increase of 8 percent in the number of
United States in the Twentieth Century
users the following year, 2 percent more than in devel-
Source: Adapted from Norris (2001, Figure 2.3). oping countries, that is, low- and lower-middle-income
SPATIAL UNEVENNESS AND SOCIAL DIFFERENCES IN THE ADOPTION OF IT 293

countries (Andres et al. 2007, 16). The authors argue improved the overall productivity and quality of software
that this is because information-intensive services and projects, especially in large firms developing software for
Internet-based jobs are in greater demand in developed stable markets, wide variations in programmer productiv-
economies. ity and quality have meant that the practices are less effec-
When Andres et al. compare two different time peri- tive for the vast majority of firms that develop software
ods, 1985 to 1998 and 1999 to 2004, they find that Internet with innovative features under tight budgets. In short,
diffusion in developed countries in the first period was quality and productivity improvements delivered by soft-
steep and similar to the diffusion in developing countries ware engineering have thus far been limited, supporting
in the second period. In the second period, however, the Brooks’s (1995) point that there is no silver bullet for the
growth curve in developed countries flattened. They esti- bottleneck. Thus, overcoming the bottleneck has required
mate that, by 2015, developing countries will catch up to the deployment of more software professionals.
90 percent of the diffusion rates in developed countries. The inability of software producers in North America
But absolute differences will remain stark, and “a sim- and Europe to deploy enough software professionals to
plified simulation indicates it would take low-income ensure cost-effective development provided an opportu-
countries more than fifty years to close the digital divide” nity that India, with its relatively large pool of English-
(Andres et al. 2007, 10). In this context, the authors argue speaking engineers who were available to work at
that language “ . . . as a proxy of network externalities of comparatively low wages, capitalized on (Parthasarathy
users speaking and sharing contents” matters, by showing 2004). The opportunity also came in the 1980s just as the
that a 10 percent increase in the number of users shar- Indian economy, which until then was stifled by autarkic
ing the same language in other countries increases the import-substitution-led industrialization policies, began
number of users in that country by 2.4 percent (Andres to emphasize greater private initiative, trade, and foreign
et al. 2007, 21). investment. Initially, software exports meant little more
than bodyshopping, or “ . . . providing inexpensive onsite
(that is, at customer locations overseas) labor on an hourly
The Selective Globalization of IT Services basis for low value-added programming services such as
and Outsourcing to India coding and testing” (Parthasarathy 2004, 669). It was not
Despite the contrasts between developed and developing until the early 1990s, when reliable and affordable data
countries, the unevenness of IT and its organizational communication facilities became available, that firms
impacts cannot be reduced to any simplistic distinc- could establish offshore development centers (ODCs)
tion between the rich and the poor. An example of this in India. As the ODCs took independent responsibility
is how India, despite having a relatively high proportion for the quality and productivity of their work, they also
of its population living in poverty and illiteracy (World began to undertake turnkey projects, which involve all
Bank 2008), exported $31.3 billion of IT services in 2007 aspects of development, instead of just low value-added
(NASSCOM 2008). The trajectory of India’s software programming services (Cusumano 2004). Thus, with the
industry illustrates the integration of India into the glo- establishment of IT infrastructure, India took advantage
bal IT outsourcing network. of its human capital and the opportunities offered by the
An independent global software industry grew fol- global software industry to contribute to the organiza-
lowing IBM’s decision in 1969 to sell software separately tional transformation of the industry.
instead of bundling it with hardware (Campbell-Kelly One cannot underestimate either the economic signifi-
2003). The decision was crucial, as it gave customers the cance of software exports and IT outsourcing to India’s
option of buying their software and hardware from dif- GDP growth, or the demonstration effect it has had on
ferent vendors, since IBM, at that time, commanded two- other sectors of the Indian economy (Arora and Athreye
thirds of the world’s computing market. Subsequently, 2002). Opportunities in the industry, however, have thus
the invention of the microprocessor in 1972 facilitated the far been limited to select urban areas and to those with
availability of increasingly more powerful and inexpen- education in a country where social deprivation abounds
sive hardware to trigger the personal computer (PC), (Parayil 2006). Although India has emerged as a major
networking, and the Internet revolutions of the 1970s, IT producer, enhancing the quality of life of the socially
1980s, and 1990s, respectively. These revolutions led to deprived will demand a transformation of various seg-
a proliferation of computing usage in various economic ments of the economy, to improve aggregate productivity,
sectors, creating a huge demand for software. However, by raising the relatively low levels of consumption and
while automated, capital-intensive operations permit the use of IT (The World Bank 2006). The section on the fish-
mass production of high-quality hardware, software pro- eries industry in Kerala discusses an example of how this
duction, in comparison, has remained a craft-like, labor- might happen.
intensive affair, plagued by uneven productivity and
quality, relying more on trial and error to achieve its goals
(Brooks 1995). The result is that software development is
Differences among Developed Countries:
notoriously prone to bugs, delays, and cost overruns. E-commerce in the United States and Japan
To overcome this software bottleneck, there has Arguments against simplistic rich-versus-poor distinc-
evolved a discipline of software engineering, along the tions are reinforced by contrasts among and within
lines of industrial engineering, to simultaneously auto- developed countries. For example, Norris (2001) points
mate and rationalize software development (Cusumano to a social divide manifest in Internet usage within
2004). While the adoption of engineering practices has Europe. Analyzing data from the fifteen nations of the
294 ORGANIZATIONAL IMPACTS OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY

European Union in 1999, she says that although educa- the U.S. model of e-commerce, since “ . . . the wireless web
tion and occupation are more strongly associated with was conceived to function much like Japan’s convenience
computer-related IT than with older forms of IT, demo- stores, providing a limited yet essential array of products
graphics (age and gender) are the significant predictors and service with instant access” (Aoyama 2003, 1214).
of Internet usage after controlling for resources such Thus, as the evolution of m-commerce in Japan has also
as household income, education, and occupation levels. taken a path-dependent trajectory, it is used to primarily
National variables are significant even after controlling deliver information goods and digital services (such as
for social background, highlighting the importance of the banking and travel reservations), time-sensitive informa-
macrocontext, including policy factors such as initiatives tion (such as news and weather), entertainment (such as
to widen Internet use through training, connectivity, and games and fortune telling), and text-messaging, rather
hardware prices. than nondigital goods.
The evolution of business-to-consumer (B2C) e- Even within a country, at a firm level, the adoption of
commerce in the United States and Japan highlights the IT does not deliver uniform results. Based on their survey
significance of national context in the adoption of IT. In of firm-level literature in the United States, Brynjolfsson
2005, there were 65.7 users of the Internet per 100 inhab- and Hitt (2000) argue that making investments in IT
itants in the United States, while the corresponding fig- without organizational change, or only partially imple-
ure for Japan was 66.8 (UNCTAD 2007, 70). Despite the menting organizational changes, can lead to significant
similarity in Internet penetration, Aoyama (2001) helps productivity losses as any benefits from the introduction
us understand why U.S. e-commerce revenues in 2005 of IT are outweighed by existing organizational practices.
reached $186 billion (U.S. Department of Commerce These organizational changes must lead to greater decen-
2008, 2), whereas they were only $35.6 billion in Japan tralization. Thus, while programmable equipment offers
(OECD 2007, 10). Since the nineteenth century, the rapid versatility in the form of flexible production, it simul-
expansion of railroads, a reliable postal system, and taneously demands greater delegation of authority and
improvements in printing technologies in the United decision rights to the shop floor than was the norm
States helped the growth of nonretail stores. Mail-order when equipment was less flexible. This, in turn, requires
operations using catalogs were launched by firms such a better-educated workforce that displays commensu-
as Sears, Roebuck and Company to meet the demands of rate versatility to respond to a wider variety of tasks.
a population spread across a vast territory with enough Decentralization will also alter the incentives, depending
space in their houses to stock large quantities of prod- on circumstances, for either vertical integration or disin-
ucts. Thus, long before e-commerce was conceived, tegration, as connecting to and tracking external supply
suppliers and consumers gained experience in dealing chains becomes easier.
with the nonretail store. For example, retailers’ policies
and practices to deal with customer refunds, returns, and
exchanges only reinforced the business operation. Against
SIMILARITIES IN THE ADOPTION OF IT:
this historical backdrop, the arrival of Internet-based e- CONQUERING SPACE AND TIME
commerce was but a new medium for nonretail stores, IT Adoption in the United States:
and another distribution channel for retail stores.
In Japan, on the other hand, the concentration of pop-
The Cases of G. F. Swift and Company
ulation within a much smaller area, not to mention a rela- and Dell Computer
tively inefficient postal system and undeveloped printing Ironically, even as intranational and international differ-
technologies, discouraged the growth of nonretail stores ences are noticeable in IT adoption in any given time, the
(Aoyama 2001). Besides, the stores that did emerge lacked organizational means of adopting IT have not changed
the commitment to ensure the quality of delivery and war- over time despite its changing technical characteristics.
ranties to win the trust of customers. Subsequently, the This is evident in the comparison by Fields (2004) of how
U.S. model of e-commerce did not work. What emerged the G. F. Swift and Company from the nineteenth cen-
instead was the use of IT in Japan’s dense network of tury, and Dell Computer from the late twentieth century,
convenience stores, which thrive by providing accessible, used IT and other technologies in their respective eras, to
one-stop shops for a range of daily necessities that must profitably conquer time and space.
be frequently restocked in smaller houses, and for a vari- In the mid-nineteenth century, the markets for cattle
ety of services. The convenience stores used IT to improve slaughter and the consumption of beef, a perishable com-
delivery efficiencies and to identify and match customer modity, were characterized by a highly localized struc-
demand and product offerings. Thus, in a country where ture. The business also had many intermediaries: The
personal checks and credit cards are seldom used, and beef went from cattle grazers and stockers, to cattle com-
home use of PCs is not as widespread as in the United mission houses, to cattle shippers, to wholesale butch-
States, these stores have become e-commerce access ers, and to retail butchers before reaching the customer.
points in a manner not observed in the United States. When Swift entered the business in 1855, there were two
Mobile phones, rather than PCs, are used more widely transformations taking place that helped the new firm
in Japan to access the Internet: By September 2004, transform the meatpacking business to its advantage and
94.1 percent of mobile phone subscribers had Internet- become the largest meatpacking firm in the United States
connectable devices, in contrast to 33.5 percent in the by the end of the century.
United States (OECD 2007, 11). But Internet access over First, between 1850 and 1900, the percentage of the
mobile telephone (3G) networks did not lead to mimicking population living in urban areas grew from 11.3 to 39.6,
SIMILARITIES IN THE ADOPTION OF IT: CONQUERING SPACE AND TIME 295

as cities became the centers of factory industrialization combined with a demand that IBM alone could not meet,
to complement their roles as commercial centers; sec- provided the opportunity for producers, such as Compaq,
ond, connecting these urban centers was a network of among others, to assemble PCs by globally sourcing com-
two innovations. There was the telegraph network, which ponents and selling it to customers through an indirect
expanded from 12,000 miles to 1,307,000 miles during channel, typically distributors and computer resellers or
those 50 years, and the railroads, which expanded from dealers. In 1987, selling PCs through an indirect chan-
9,000 miles to 206,600 miles (Fields 2004, 85). To cater nel accounted for 80 to 90 percent of all the shipments,
to the opportunity offered by the demand for fresh meat in a system that forced the PC makers to forecast mar-
in growing urban areas, Swift took advantage of the ket demand and build accordingly, while waiting for the
decreasing transactions costs offered by technological customers’ purchases (Fields 2004, 176). Any delays or
innovation. Swift converted the localized beef business biased forecasts were exacerbated by the short shelf life
to a national business by introducing a new product— of PCs.
dressed beef—which meant slaughtering and butchering Dell entered the business in 1983 with two notions that
beef in one location and selling it in another. were in contrast to the business model of the time—direct
There were four components to the success of Swift’s selling and customization. To that end, the firm began to
strategy. First, the firm based its operations on custom- assemble PCs by taking orders directly from customers,
ers’ orders for specific cuts and grades of beef transmit- which allowed it to tailor PCs to customer needs and to
ted over telegraph lines. That created a pull system with minimize inventory. The firm also created a supply chain
which supply could be matched with the exact demand that incorporated the least expensive computer compo-
instead of relying on demand forecasts. Swift used nent sources from around the world, using overnight air-
the telegraph to balance supply from the cattle farms of the freight. Dell’s goal was to assemble PCs quicker and at
Midwestern states with demand in the urban centers lower costs, especially targeting corporate customers who
in the East. Second, a distribution network was built would regularly require upgrades and additional sales.
over the railway system to directly reach retail butch- Like Swift, Dell also bypassed existing intermediaries and
ers. As a standardized, nationwide railway infrastructure placed itself between the suppliers and the final customer.
grew, Swift made critical complementary investments by The success of the strategy was evident in the growth in
designing refrigerated railroad cars to ensure that the beef net sales from $6.2 million in 1985 to $388.5 million
did not spoil when transported over long distances. In the in 1990 (Fields 2004, 181). But a steep fall in profit in 1990
absence of such cars, live cattle used to be transported to showed that Dell’s custom-direct model was reaching a
their final destinations, adding considerably to the cost. saturation point as volumes grew. Remedial measures to
Thus, trains with refrigerated cars allowed larger vol- address this problem were taken by complementing the
umes of shipments, which could be moved faster, more direct sales model with sales through indirect channels.
reliably, and less expensively than by any other means of Although these efforts made Dell the world’s tenth-largest
transportation at the time. PC maker in 1994, it did not help profitability.
Third, the firm adopted a vertically integrated struc- It was then that Dell turned to the Internet and, in
ture to build scale and national reach, eliminating the June 1996, it became the first PC maker to sell systems
often locally focused independent firms. Not only did its online. After a period of trial and error, in 2001, Dell real-
model of directly buying cattle and slaughtering them ized 57 percent of its sales revenue online to become the
eliminate the need for cattle commission houses and cat- world’s largest online retailer (Fields 2004, 188). It also
tle shippers but, when its strategy of supplying dressed became the world’s largest PC maker, thanks to formida-
beef ran into opposition from wholesale butchers unwill- ble advantages over its competitors. For example, by 2001
ing to invest in refrigerated warehouses, Swift set up its Dell held just four days of inventory compared to 42 days
own branch houses to sell to retail butchers. Essentially, at Compaq, its nearest competitor (Fields 2004, 190).
Swift established itself as a new intermediary in the beef Such advantages were facilitated by Dell’s Internet-based
business by obliterating the older hierarchy of beef distri- information platform for demand and supply planning,
bution. Finally, these three elements combined to create a parts procurement, build-to-order production schedules,
new form of organization that benefited from economies customer order intake, and product delivery processes.
of scale nationally, while concentrating production in Although Dell undertook long-term production and pro-
centers such as Chicago, which was also a railroad hub. curement planning, its advantage came from separating
Fresh beef was delivered from these centers over long planning and execution. Dell balanced demand and sup-
distances across the United States according to customer ply by producing PCs at its factories around the world
demand. only as orders came in. It also set up a supply chain that
In the 1980s and 1990s, Dell took advantage of the required suppliers to invest in an information system
advent and development of the Internet, and improve- compatible with Dell’s platform, and to locate supply
ments in intermodal transit and airfreight, using them logistics centers adjacent to its factories so they could
as a platform to reconfigure the supply chain of the PC feed the assembly line at two-hour intervals.
industry. In the 1980s, the IBM standard was increas- Although separated by a century, both Swift and Dell
ingly dominant, thanks to IBM’s decision to build the PC took advantage of new technologies in their respective
to a modular and open architecture and to decentralize eras to reconfigure the organization of the meatpacking
production by outsourcing even essential parts, notably and the PC manufacturing industries. They were able to
from Intel and Microsoft, and from other suppliers in effectively use the telegraph and the Internet, respectively,
Taiwan, Singapore, and South Korea. This architecture, to manage information flows and to transform industries
296 ORGANIZATIONAL IMPACTS OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY

by relying on a pull instead of a push system to balance thereby reducing price fluctuations. “The data showed
demand with supply. In addition to using IT to ensure that merchants, owners, and agents making a large chunk
they delivered their products, each of which had a limited of their business-related calls outside their local calling
shelf life, quickly to the customer, they took advantage areas, which can be interpreted as a sign that they are
of transportation advances in new ways—railroads with monitoring prices at distant markets, providing further
refrigerated cars and overnight airfreight. The conquest evidence of greater market integration” (Abraham 2007,
of space and time by Swift and Dell was not just a con- 11). The newly available information also allowed them
sequence of their deployment of technology. It also had to save fuel and to reduce the time spent traveling on
to do with attendant organizational changes: both elimi- poor roads searching for lower prices. As risk and uncer-
nated middlemen to create a vertically integrated organi- tainty were reduced for all parties involved, on average,
zation in one case (Swift), and a virtually disintegrated profits of fishermen rose by 8 percent; wastage, instead of
organization in the other (Dell). averaging 5 to 8 percent of the catch, was eliminated; and
consumer prices fell by 4 percent, while the coefficient of
variation of price across markets fell from 60 to 70 per-
IT Adoption in Developing Contexts: cent to less than 15 percent (Jensen 2007, 883).
The Fisheries Industry in Kerala, India
The adoption of IT to conquer space and time, even when
locations are both literally and metaphorically thousands CONCLUSION: IT A NECESSARY
of miles apart, is evident from the impact of the introduc- TOOL BUT NOT A STRATEGIC
tion of mobile phones on the fisheries industry in Kerala.
The fisheries industry was long affected by information DIFFERENTIATOR
asymmetries across local markets where fishermen sold After making the points that it set out to, this chapter
their catch. Although fish forms part of the staple diet in concludes by arguing that even if technological diffu-
Kerala, and the fisheries industry offers a major source sion does occur over a period of time, taking advantage
of employment, poor information flow across local fish of the productivity benefits that IT can deliver will even-
markets meant that there was wide variation in prices tually depend on conscious organizational efforts. That
and wastage of fish (Jensen 2007). is, organizational advantage must provide the means to
Fishermen returning from sea often relied only on deploy IT rather than relying on IT to bring about organi-
their local markets to sell their catch. This was because zational impacts.
of the potential cost and risk involved in traveling longer This point is perhaps best illustrated by the fortunes
distances to another market, with a highly perishable of Cisco Systems, the router manufacturer that, like Dell,
product, especially if prices there happened to be lower. established a business model that relied on IT to connect
Therefore, depending on the amount of fish caught in a its customers, suppliers, partners, and employees in a vir-
particular region, a specific market would have either tually integrated supply chain. Apart from being a tech-
abundance or scarcity of fish, pushing prices down or up, nological pioneer of the Internet era, Castells (2000, 182)
respectively (Abraham 2007). Furthermore, since each credits Cisco with pioneering “probably the most self-
market operated for only a limited duration, the uncer- conscious model of the networking form of organization,”
tainty also affected wholesale and retail merchants, and and compares it with the role played by Ford in introduc-
commission agents, who formed part of a long supply ing standardized production in the industrial era. Cisco
chain. Lacking reliable information from the fishermen at proposed a “global networked business model,” arguing
sea, merchants had to almost randomly choose a particu- that it is not enough to be only connected to other firms,
lar market where they often found no fish to buy, while in but that there must exist a “networked fabric” between
other markets fish would be dumped because there were business relationships and the communication channels
no merchants. The problem was aggravated by poor road that support them. The idea, therefore, was that the firm’s
quality and high transportation costs. “If fishermen had network had to give it competitive advantage.
price information for all locations, the market should As Cisco put its ideas into practice, revenues grew
achieve an outcome where price dispersion is reduced, from $69 million in 1990 to over $12.2 billion in 1999,
fish are allocated across markets more efficiently, waste outperforming all competitors in a rapidly growing mar-
is reduced or eliminated, and total welfare is increased” ket (Castells 2000, 181). In less than a decade, the firm
(Jensen 2007, 883). ensured transformations in all relationships, using the
The verification of Jensen’s hypothesis began with the Internet as the means for automated interaction. For
deployment of mobile telephony in Kerala in 1997. example, with access to a network of suppliers online, by
The installation of base towers in the coastal areas allowed 1999, Cisco reduced its own production facilities from 30
service signals to reach over 25 kilometers out to sea, to 2. In this model, Cisco was simply getting the payment
enough for fishermen to use mobile phones while fish- “for R&D, technology, design, engineering, information,
ing. Thus, by 2001, 60 percent of fishing boats were using technical support, and business savvy in building a reli-
mobile phones to share information about the location able network of suppliers, and in marketing to custom-
of swarms, saving fuel required for such a search, and ers. This is a manufacturing company that does almost no
to inform agents about their exact time and location of manufacturing” (Castells 2000, 182). In addition, as with
return, reducing waiting times on both sides (Jensen Dell, Cisco’s web site played a crucial role in support of its
2007, 883). Agents and merchants were also able to interactions with customers and suppliers. Cisco handled
share information regarding prices and fish availability, 83 percent of its orders and 80 percent of customer-service
REFERENCES AND SUGGESTED READINGS 297

issues online, resulting in an estimated saving of $500 mil- entire society in all of its aspects of economic and
lion between 1997 and 1999 (Castells 2000). social life.
Notwithstanding the success it enjoyed in the 1990s, Information Asymmetries: Manifest themselves when
Cisco suffered losses in 2001. Unable to foresee an immi- one party to a transaction has better or more complete
nent reduction in the demand for network equipment, information than the other.
despite a powerful real-time forecasting system, the firm Intermediaries: Third parties that act as conduits for
had to write off $2.5 billion and fire 8,500 workers (Carr goods or services offered by a supplier to a consumer,
2004, 110). Aside from any cyclical reasons attributable usually by adding some value to the transaction that
to the fortunes of Cisco, Carr argues that any advantages may not be possible with direct trading.
that IT might confer on a first mover are limited. Although Network Effects: Signify the increase in the value of a
IT gives firms the potential to rearrange business, “If a unit of a good to a user with the number of units used.
company is unable to hold on to a technological advan- Outsourcing: The process of subcontracting a produc-
tage for a substantial period, its early-mover strategy can tion process, such as design or manufacturing, to a
backfire. Competitors won’t just catch up; they’ll leapfrog third party.
the first mover, introducing more powerful systems” (Carr Productivity Paradox: The discrepancy between
2004, 77). As technology evolves to become more afford- measures of investment in productivity-enhancing
able and more easily accessible, leading to its widespread technology and measures of output that result from
adoption, the systems deployed by firms such as Cisco, such investment.
or even Dell, become standardized infrastructure, that is, Supply Chain: The system of organizations, people,
simply another component of the cost of doing business. technology, activities, information, and resources
In other words, what were once unique systems become involved in moving a product or service from producer
appropriable by other firms as generic complementary to consumer.
assets (Teece 2006). Technology Diffusion: The process by which an inno-
To Carr, as IT becomes a prerequisite to compete in the vation is communicated through certain channels over
market, the organizational means of adopting IT is not dif- time among the members of a social system.
ferent from previous infrastructural developments such Transactions Costs: Incurred in making an economic
as railroads and electric power. Carr is echoing Simon exchange, and include search and information costs,
(1997) who argued that, with the introduction of contem- bargaining costs, and contract policing and enforce-
porary IT, working with limited information is no longer ment costs.
a concern. An unlikely source of support for this argu-
ment comes from the 5,000 dabbawallas of Mumbai who
collect 170,000 homemade meals from across the city for CROSS REFERENCES
delivery to workplaces in various locations every day (The Click-and-Brick Electronic; Groupware; IT Economics;
Economist 2008b). Modern IT does not play any role in Site Selection in the Supply Chain; Virtual Organizations
the 99.9999 percent efficiency with which this operation Commerce
is carried out. Instead, the information to coordinate a
supply chain that relies on manual collection, for delivery
by bicycle, trolley, and commuter trains, is encoded in REFERENCES AND SUGGESTED
the colored numbering system on special boxes holding the
meals. If the exclusive reliance on human and social inge- READINGS
nuity to coordinate effective meal delivery has attracted Abraham, R. 2007. Mobile phones and economic devel-
the attention of management scholars, it is only because opment: Evidence from the fishing industry in India.
even in the age of informational capitalism designing Information Technologies and International Development
organizational structures is far more crucial to business 4(1):5–17. www.itidjournal.org/index.php/1111/article/
success than technology per se. view/241/111. (accessed December 3, 2008).
Akerloff, G. 1970. The market for “lemons”: Quality uncer-
tainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of
GLOSSARY Economics 84(3):488–500.
Complementary Investments: The assets and infra- Andres, L., D. Cuberes, M. A. Diouf, and T. Serebrisky.
structure required to facilitate the socialization and 2007. Diffusion of the Internet: A cross-country analysis.
spread of a technology. Policy Research working paper WPS4420. The World
Digital Divide: The gap between people with the Bank. www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/
resources and the skills to access and use digital and WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2007/12/03/000158349_
information technology and those without. 20071203114216/Rendered/PDF/wps4420.pdf
Division of Labor: The specialization of cooperative (accessed December 3, 2008).
labor in specific, circumscribed tasks and roles, to Aoyama, Y. 2001. Structural foundations for e-commerce
increase aggregate labor productivity. adoption: A comparative organization of retail trade
E-commerce: The buying and selling of products or between Japan and the United States. Urban Geography
services over electronic systems and computer net- 22(2):130–153.
works such as the Internet. ———. 2003. Sociospatial dimensions of technology adop-
General-Purpose Technologies: Innovations that are tion: Recent m-commerce and e-commerce develop-
general enough in their characteristics to affect an ments. Environment and Planning A 35(7): 1201–1221.
298 ORGANIZATIONAL IMPACTS OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY

Arora, A., and S. Athreye. 2002. The software industry Kraemer, K. L., and J. Dedrick. 2001. Information tech-
and India’s economic development. Information nology and economic development: Results and policy
Economics and Policy 14:253–273. implications of cross-country studies. In Information
Bell, D. 1999. The coming of post-industrial society: A ven- technology, productivity and economic growth:
ture in social forecasting. New York: Basic Books. International evidence and implications for economic
Brooks, F. P. 1995. The mythical man-month: Essays on development, ed. P. Matti, 257–279. New York: Oxford
software engineering 2nd ed. Reading, MA: Addison University Press.
Wesley Longman. McAfee, A., and E. Brynjolfsson. 2008. Investing in the IT
Brown, J. S., and P. Duguid. 2000. The social life of infor- that makes a competitive difference. Harvard Business
mation. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Review 86(7/8):98–107.
Brynjolfsson, E., and L. M. Hitt. 2000. Beyond compu- National Association of Software and Service Companies
tation: Information technology, organizational trans- (NASSCOM). 2008. www.nasscom.in/upload/5216/IT%
formation and business performance. Journal of 20Industry%20Factsheet-Aug%202008.pdf (accessed
Economic Perspectives 14(4):23–48. December 3, 2008).
Cairncross, F. 2001. The death of distance: How the com- Norris, P. 2001. Digital divide: Civic engagement, informa-
munication revolution is changing our lives. Boston: tion poverty and the Internet worldwide. Cambridge:
Harvard Business School Press. Cambridge University Press.
Campbell-Kelly, M. 2003. From airline reservations to Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Sonic the hedgehog: A history of the software industry. Development (OECD). 2007. Mobile commerce. OECD.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. www.oecd.org/dataoecd/22/52/38077227.pdf (accessed
Carr, N. G. 2004. Does IT matter? Information technology December 3, 2008).
and the corrosion of competitive advantage. Boston: Parayil, G. ed. 2006. Political economy and information
Harvard Business School Press. capitalism in India. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Castells, M. 2000. The rise of the network society. Volume Parthasarathy, B. 2004. India’s Silicon Valley or Silicon
I of the information age: Economy, society and culture Valley’s India? Socially embedding the computer soft-
2nd ed. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers. ware industry in Bangalore. International Journal of
Clark, D. T., S. P. Goodwin, T. Samuelson, and C. Coker. Urban and Regional Research 28(3):664–685.
2008. A qualitative assessment of the Kindle e-book Sellen, A. J., and R. H. R. Harper. 2001. The myth of the
reader: Results from initial focus groups. Performance paperless office. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Measurement and Metrics 9(2):118–129. Shannon, C. E., and W. Weaver. 1964. A mathematical
Cortada, J. W. 2004. The digital hand: How computers theory of communication. Champaign: University of
changed the work of American manufacturing, trans- Illinois Press.
portation, and retail industries. New York: Oxford Shapiro, C., and H. R.Varian. 1999. Information rules:
University Press. A strategic guide to the network economy. Boston: Harvard
Cusumano, M. A. 2004. The business of software: What Business School Press.
every manager, programmer, and entrepreneur must Simon, H. A. 1997. Administrative behavior: A study of
know to thrive and survive in good times and bad. New decision-making processes in administrative organiza-
York: The Free Press. tions 4th ed. New York: The Free Press.
David, P. A. 2000. Understanding digital technology’s evo- Solow, R. M. 1987. We’d better watch out. New York Times
lution and the path of measured productivity: Present Book Review, July 12, 36.
and future in the mirror of the past. In Understanding Stigler, G. J. 1961. The economics of information. The
the digital economy, eds. E. Brynjolfsson and B. Kahin, Journal of Political Economy 69(3):213–225.
49–98. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Teece, D. J. 2006. Reflections on profiting from innova-
Dewan, S., and K. L. Kraemer. 1998. International dimen- tion. Research Policy 35:1131–1146.
sions of the productivity paradox: Don’t blame IT. Townsend, A. M. 2003. Wired/unwired: The urban geog-
Communications of the ACM 41(8):56–62. raphy of digital networks. Unpublished PhD diss.
The Economist. 2008a. Unbound: Book publishing in Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
America, June 5, 68. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
———. 2008b. The cult of the dabbawalla, July 12, 69. (UNCTAD). 2007. Information economy report 2007–
Fields, G. 2004. Territories of profit: Communications, 2008: Science and technology for development: The new
capitalist development, and the innovative enterprises of paradigm of ICT. UNCTAD. www.unctad.org/en/docs/
G. F. Swift and Dell Computer. Stanford, CA: Stanford sdteecb20071_en.pdf (accessed December 3, 2008).
University Press. U.S. Department of Commerce. 2008. 2006 E-commerce
Gilder, G. 1995. Forbes ASAP. February 26, 56. multi-sector report. www.census.gov/eos/www/2006/
Information Technology Association of America (ITAA). 2006reportfinal.pdf (accessed December 3, 2008).
n.d. Information technology definition aggregation. The World Bank. 2006. Information and communica-
www.itaa.org/es/docs/Information%20Technology%20 tions for development 2006: Global Trends and Policies.
Definitions.pdf (accessed July 30, 2008). The World Bank.
Jensen, R. 2007. The digital provide: Information (tech- ———. 2008. World development indicators 2008.
nology), market performance, and welfare in the The World Bank.
South Indian fisheries sector. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 72(3):879–925.

You might also like