You are on page 1of 250

INFORMATION TO USERS

This manuscript has been reproduced from the microfilm master. UMI films
the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and
dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of
computer printer.

The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the


copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations
and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper
alignment can adversely affect reproduction.

In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript
and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized
copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion.

Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are reproduced by


sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing
from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps.

Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced


xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6* x 9” black and white
photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing
in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order.

ProQuest Information and Learning


300 North Zeeb Road. Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA
800-521-0600

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
B2B: Supplier Management,
Investments in Information
System s, and Codifiability

M ordechai Levi

A Dissertation

In

Operations and Information Management

for the Graduate Group in Managerial Science and Applied Economics

Presented to the Faculties of the University of Pennsylvania in Partial

Fulfillment of the Requirements of the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy

2002

Graduate Group Chairperson

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
UMI Number 3043905

Copyright 2002 by
Levi, Mordechai

All rights reserved.

UMI’
UMI Microform 3043905
Copyright 2002 by ProQuest Information and Learning Company.
All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against
unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.

ProQuest Information and Learning Company


300 North Zeeb Road
P.O. Box 1346
Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
© [2002] by [Mordechai Levi]
All rights reserved.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Dedicated to my Parents, Avraham and Yehudit Levi

to my wife, Adva Dinur-Levi

and

to Shira, my daughter

in

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank Morris Cohen, Howard Kunreuther, Eli Snir, and

Dennis Yao for many helpful comments on earlier drafts of the material in

this dissertation. I am very grateful for Lorin H itt’s comments on all of the

material and especially his invaluable assistance on the empirical part. I

have been helped by Kate Fang and the rest of the administrative staff of

the Operations and Information Department at The Wharton School. I am

highly indebted to my wife, Adva Dinur-Levi, who throughout my studies

and the years it took to reach here helped me with support, advice, and

provided me with the insight to the key idea of codifiability, without which

this dissertation would not be as it is. More them anyone, I am forever

indebted and thankful to my advisor, Paul Kleindorfer for his multi-faceted

support, guidance, knowledge, and wisdom, which have carried me through­

out my graduate studies and the completion of this manuscript. All errors

and omissions are solely my responsibility. This dissertation was supported

in part by the Institute of Supply Management (ISM, formerly NAPM).

iv

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Abstract
B2B: Supplier Management, Investments in Information
Systems, and Codifiability
Mordechai Levi
Paul R. Kleindorfer

B2B e-commerce requires substantial investments by suppliers and buyers

in information systems find related infrastructure. As has become evident re­

cently, generating trade via e-Marketplaces and exchanges is not easy. More

than 1,000 exchanges were built in the past few years and B2B trade through

those is expected to reach trillions of dollars. However, more than 90% of

these exchanges and marketplaces have generated very low trade activity

and many have had to close down. Contradicting early predictions, suppli­

ers have not rushed to join these exchanges, for various reasons, the most

salient of is fear of margin erosion. In order to analyze supplier management

strategy in this context I build an analytical framework. This framework

allows analysis of both the selection and control questions. In Chapter 2

the questions of incentives (control) for suppliers’ investments in informa­

tion systems is solved, while in Chapter 3 I analyze the question of how

many, and which, suppliers should a buyer use to generate optimal invest-

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ments by suppliers in the resulting relationship. Out of this investigation

emerges an important factor in determining strategy, namely the codifiabil­

ity of transaction knowledge. Codifiability, some level of which is necessary

for electronically mediated transactions, is shown to determine how many

suppliers can be used. While the concept of codifiability is not new, its ap­

plication to inter-firm relationships is novel. To examine the framework and

the hypotheses generated in Chapter 3, an empirical study on a procurement

department of a leading chemical firm is performed. I find that the model

is strongly supported and that codifiability and transferability of transac­

tion knowledge are important factors in determining supplier management

strategy and performance. Building on these findings, chapter 4 uses an

analytical model to examine how codifiability affects the mix of contract and

spot-market procurement. I find lower codifiability to shift the mix towards

contracts, which allow an orderly negotiation process on the details of the

transaction, thus strengthening Chapter 3’s results. Details of the resulting

market equilibrium arising from various degrees of codifiability are presented

as one important implication of this modeling framework.

vi

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Contents

1 Introduction 1

1.1 Historical Perspective.................................................................... 3

1.2 Supplier Management in P e rs p e c tiv e ........................................ 10

1.3 Dissertation O u t l i n e .................................................................... 13

2 Incentives for Suppliers’ Investm ents in Information System s 25

2.1 Introduction........................................ 25

2.2 Supplier Management:An Overview of the Issu es.......................... 32

2.3 Modeling Fram ew ork........................................................................ 47

2.3.1 The C o n te st........................................................................ 48

2.3.2 The Buyer’s P ro b le m ............................................................54

2.3.3 In c e n tiv es........................................................................... 59

2.4 D iscussion....................................................................................... 64

vii

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
2.5 Appendix A ...................................................................................68

3 T he O ptim al Num ber o f Suppliers and Codifiability 71

3.1 Introduction ........................................................................................71

3.2 Modeling F ram ew ork....................................................................... 80

3.2.1 Assumptions.......................................................................... 85

3.2.2 Time L in e ..............................................................................86

3.2.3 N o ta tio n s ..............................................................................87

3.3 A n a ly sis............................................................................................. 88

3.3.1 Version 1: Contractible Investm ents.................................. 91

3.3.2 Version 2: Unobservable In v e stm e n ts ................................97

3.4 C odifiability..................................................................................... 102

3.5 The Empirical S t u d y ......................................................................107

3.5.1 H y p o th e se s......................................................................... 109

3.5.2 The D a t a ............................................................................ 120

3.5.3 Part I: The Case of the Missing S tra te g y ........................ 124

3.5.4 Part H: Regression R esu lts.................................................135

3.6 D iscussion......................................................................................... 150

3.7 Appendix: List of V a ria b le s .......................................................... 153

viii

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
4 O ptim al Contract and Spot-M arket M ix for Buyers in the

Presence o f Uncodiflable Transaction Knowledge 158

4.1 In troduction ..................................................................................... 158

4.2 Model and Notation ......................................................................164

4.3 Basic R e s u l t s ...................................................................................172

4.4 Multiple B u y ers............................................................................... 191

4.5 Summary .........................................................................................197

4.6 A p p e n d ix .........................................................................................199

5 Conclusions and Future Research Directions 212

5.1 Practical C ontributions....................................................... 213

5.2 Theoretical C o n trib u tio n s .............................................................216

5.3 Future R esearch............................................................................... 222

ix

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
List of Tables

3.1 Design of Analysis ............................................................................90

3.2 Descriptive S ta tis tic s ...................................................................... 123

3.3 CorrelationsT a b le l.......................................................................... 126

3.4 CorrelationsT a b le 2 .......................................................................... 127

3.5 CorrelationsT a b le 3 .......................................................................... 128

3.6 CorrelationsT a b le 4 .......................................................................... 129

3.7 CorrelationsT a b le o ...........................................................................130

3.8 Number of Suppliers: Main E f f e c ts ..............................................138

3.9 Number of Suppliers: U n iq u en ess................................................. 139

3.10 Defects Performance - Main E ffe c ts ..............................................145

3.11 Quality Performance - Main E ffe cts..............................................147

3.12 Performance - Learning and C odifiability.....................................149

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
List of Figures

*2.1 Relationship Structures as a function of Transaction Attributes 38

3.1 Time L i n e .......................................................................................... 86

3.2 Number of Suppliers vs. Annual Monetary V o lu m e ..................132

xi

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Chapter 1

Introduction

With the advent of the world-wide-web (WWW) as a transaction medium

for Business-to-Business trade (B‘2B) supplier management has become the

focus of industry and research alike. This new medium, the WWW, of­

fers a fundamentally different platform than any that existed before. By

drastically reducing some types of transaction costs and supplying a more

plug-and-play environment, the W WW is supposed to allow a move towards

markets, with a substantial increase in the number of participating suppliers.

Predictions of the volume of trade facilitated by the WWW are now routinely

estimated to be trillions of dollars in trade activity per annum. However, as

the past two years witnessed, this proposition is not so easily fulfilled, and it

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is not clear that it can be fulfilled across all transactions domains. Indeed,

while there is substantial volume of trade over the W W W in some transac­

tion categories such as steel and plastics, trade projections in other sectors

had to be lowered from their levels a year or two ago. The problem is clear.

For any progress to be made in this domain, firms have to get their suppliers

to join the exchanges, e-Marketplaces, and other such web based platforms.

Those suppliers, however, are not eager to do so for many reasons, one of

which is the fear of eroding margins due to increased competition. This and

other concerns has given rise to a renewed interest by suppliers and buyers

alike in the terms that will govern their longer-term relationships, especially

if these are to be electronically mediated. Thus, rather them reducing the

importance of relationship management, the WWW has underlined supplier

management as a key determinant of any firm in moving towards web based

procurement. This is especially true for buyer-supplier relationships for

which large idiosyncratic investments, and specifically investments in infor­

mation systems, or the integration of long-term contracting and spot market

purchases are of concern. This dissertation focuses on supplier management

where these tire key underlying factors of buyer-supplier relationships. For

this context, I note specifically the central role of codifiability as a driver of

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
both idiosyncratic investments and resulting supplier management strategies.

In so doing, I address some of the fundamental concerns and issues behind

B2B e-commerce, its development and its future.

The rest of this chapter starts with a historical perspective on supplier

management in section 1.1. I then discuss briefly the core of this dissertation

in section 1.2 and continue with a discussion of supplier management, which

as mentioned above is my focus in this study. Section 1.3 outlines the rest

of the dissertation and summarizes the approach and results of chapters 2,

3, and 4.

1.1 H istorical P erspective

Before we put forth a theory or a model to explain some of the drivers of B2B

and its interaction with the WWW, we have to understand the challenges

faced by firms in today’s global market place. In order to do so, however,

we first have to understand the history of supplier management, since that

history shapes current practices and strategies, and therefore the challenges

faced by firms.

Around the mid eighties, Total Quality Management (TQM) had started

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
to influence U.S. business thinking after a 1980 special NBC program “If

Japan C an ... Why Can’t We?” brought W. Edwards Deming’s ideas to U.S.

executives (see Evans and Lindsey, 1999 for an extensive discussion of TQM).

The program highlighted Deming’s role in the development of Japanese qual­

ity. By emphasizing quality, TQM pushed organizations to evaluate their

internal processes to ensure high quality. The reasoning is simple: it is more

costly to fix something than to do it correctly the first time around. How­

ever, zero defects or six-sigma are not easy to achieve. Organizations had to

change complete processes and embark on continuous self-evaluation. It was

not long before this process of self-evaluation came to recognize that a key

ingredient for quality are the products, materials, and services procured from

outside. Unless those are of high quality the organizational effort towards

high quality cannot be effective. Enter supplier management. Economic

th inking at the time emphasized creating competition as opposed to estab­

lishing relationships. Since quality was a driver, monitoring of quality and

thus monitoring of suppliers became key elements of supplier management.

While this trend carried on into the nineties, with the confluence with

process re-engineering, two other theories started to take root and influence

business thought. The first was Transaction Cost Economics (TCE), which

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
owed its early development to Williamson’s seminal book, Markets and Hi­

erarchies, in 1975. In this book Williamson suggested that firm boundaries

are determined by the relative costs of conducting a transaction internally

compared to conducting it through an external source. Williamson postu­

lated that firms and groups of firms (read entire value chains) choose the

least costly alternative. Thus, if it is cheaper to conduct the transaction

internally, the firm will vertically integrate and if it is cheaper to conduct it

externally the firm will procure the item from outside suppliers. However,

underlying this observation was an idea that is as critical. The idea is that

there are multiple factors determining transaction costs and as those change,

so would the organizational structures and inter-firm relationships observed.

At one extreme, firms may choose to vertically integrate, and at the other

extreme firms may choose to purchase in the spot market. Intermediate

solutions may constitute long-term relationships, small number outsourcing

among others. The TCE idea was powerful since it made the observation

that there is not one solution to supplier management strategy. Rather it

argued that efficient strategy choice depends on finding a fit between trans­

action specifications and the structure of (supplier) relationships. However,

only when enough supporting empirical evidence had started to accumulate,

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
towards the late 80s, this idea became accepted and supplier management

w£is considered not just as quality monitoring and cost reduction but as re­

quiring complex, context-based, strategy.

The second theory was Michael Porter’s value added chain approach

(Porter, 1985). Porter observed that the process by which firms add value to

a good or service consists of several subprocesses, each of which contributes

both cost Eis well as potential attributes of the product or service valued by

end customers. At the same time, each firm is a link in a value-adding

chain, which stEirts with raw materials and ends with a finished consumer

product. The more value a firm adds, the stronger its Position in the value

chain. The key to Porter’s Einalysis was to use overEill value chain margin as

the scorecEird Eind to look for opportunities across the entire value chain for

improving this scorecEird, either through reduced cost or through enhancing

those attributes of the product or service VEilued by customers. Naturally,

the first reaction by firms was to try to cut costs. When the gains from pure

cost cutting Eire exhausted, firms have to think about value adding and not

just quality and cost. Value adding, e.g. through reduced cycle time or

through improved customization of the product, requires close relationships

sind collaboration with other links in the supply chain and mainly with sup-

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
pliers. When such is the case, a value chain can compete with other value

chains supplying the same goods. Such very close relationships, or strategic

partnerships as they have come to be termed, are costly to establish in time

and personnel. Thus, to achieve such partnerships a firm must reduce its

supplier base and cultivate only few suppliers in each domain. As a result,

beginning in the early nineties and continuing throughout the nineties, the

trend was towards a reduction of the supplier base and a move towards close

partnerships in domains where value-added logic dictated closer relationships

between buyers and suppliers.

As a result of this type of thinking, the field of operations management

assimilated the idea of strategies focused on the entire value chain. Opera­

tions management coined its own terminology, supply chain management, to

better match its operational perspective. But the idea behind supply chain

management is clearly the same as the one behind value chain management.

Firms are links in a chain leading from raw materials to consumer or in­

dustrial goods. The emphasis is on linking and matching operations and

processes to facilitate a more efficient supply chain. One direct consequence

of this evolution has been the huge growth in interest in Enterprise Resource

Planning (ERP) software. In order to link outside, a firm must first link

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
and match its internal operations and processes. This requirement gave rise

to ERP software such as SAP’s. Given the cost and complexity of ERP

implementation, many firms stopped far short of implementing a complete

package of ERP software. However, even partial implementation, focused

on material management and production planning, has allowed firms to start

shifting their focus to external interactions with other firms and suppliers.

At the same time, the mid-nineties, the WWW had started to become

common. Firms that had invested in Electronic Data Interchange (EDI) in

the past could only do so with their big suppliers or customers or the invest­

ment could not be justified. The WWW, however, offers a different type of

system. EDI is one-to-one link so that each connection requires a new in­

vestment. The WWW, on the other hand, is many-to-many or one-to-many

at the least. When a third party creates an e-Marketplaces, the investment

in essence is spread over many buyers and suppliers. Furthermore, each con­

nection is not unique, thus allowing for even bigger savings. Investments,

mostly in information systems (IS) are, therefore, less relationship specific.

At the same time, they are supposed to be less idiosyncratic in that the

platform should apply to multiple transaction types.

To support this evolution towards ERP-based or platform-based interac-

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
tions between buyers and sellers in the B2B world, a number of other data

management and sophisticated supply chain management tools were created,

including those of companies like i2 and Manugistics. The idea behind these

supply-chain software tools is to optimize the material and information flows

along the supply chain. Since, presumably, firms have reasonable control

over internal flows, and due to the common platform offered by the web,

those firms can now link and start operating as a coordinated supply chain.

Naturally, in practice this idea is far from being implemented and supply-

chain software mostly coordinates two “adjacent” firms on the supply-chain,

the standard buyer-supplier model.

W ith such opportunities, supplier management has become even more

important. A firm now has, in theory, an ability to interact seamlessly

with more suppliers across more product lines. Rather than simplify, such

ability actually complicates supplier management since now a firm cannot

look at each supplier or product in isolation and has to manage the full

matrix. The importance of matching strategy to transaction types is even

more critical since no longer can a “one approach fits all” strategy be used

successfully. More over, firms have to manage suppliers on multiple fronts.

While cost and quality are still and always will be a critical factor, firms have

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
to get suppliers to invest in inter-firm systems and processes of various types

in order for these firms and their supply/value chain to interact efficiently.

On the transaction level, firms have to figure out which transactions can

be conducted via electronic channels and what has to be done to facilitate

electronic transactions, from standardizing and digitizing the product offering

to agreeing on contract and transactional terms sufficiently precisely to allow

electronic order fulfillment.

1.2 Supplier M anagem ent in P erspective

Notwithstanding all of these very positive developments, and as noted ear­

lier, the early growth predicted for electronic B‘2B activity did not materialize

in many sectors. In order to understand why B‘2B activity has not picked

up as fast as forecasted, we have to understand supplier management and

its interaction with the WWW. This is the primary focus of this disserta­

tion. Supplier management research in the past three decades has included

multiple research questions, researched with different methodologies and has

been discussed in several disciplines, mostly in economics, management, and

operations management. In the next few paragraphs I give a short review

10

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of approaches to the problem. I start with the questions asked within sup­

plier management, explain the differing approaches of different disciplines

and which methodologies have been used. Broadly defined, these questions

can be divided into the following categories:

1. How many suppliers to have? This question arises from economics and

mostly compares the nature of incentives one versus multiple sources

offer. Multiple sources are considered broadly without examination

of the differences between having, for example, four or five suppliers.

This issue is usually also linked to the “Spot market vs. long term

relationship” question discussed below.

2. Make or Buy? When a firm is interested in using only a single source,

it may want to consider vertical integration. There axe advantages and

disadvantages to either make or buy decision. Sometimes the decision

to buy may be from multiple sources (vs. from a single source), but

that is not usually the case examined. The literature is concerned with

analyzing the trade-offs between make and buy strategies.

3. W hat should be the nature of relationship with suppliers? There are

many types of relationships a firm can establish with its suppliers,

11

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ranging from strategic partnership bordering on vertical integration to

an opportunistic one with no commitments or any other relationship-

enhancing mechanisms. As mentioned before, this question and the

number of suppliers question are tied since to create strategic partner­

ship with a supplier a firm cannot have more than a few suppliers for

the specific item in question. Often this question is posed as follows:

(a) Should a firm buy through long-term relationships or through spot

markets? Posing the question as such allows for starker differences

and for analytical modeling. Many of the •‘middle ground” con­

figurations are difficult to model analytically since benefits and

costs are not clearly defined and measurable monetary value or

costs associated with alternative designs are difficult to identify.

4. How should contracts be written? As Coase (1937) and Williamson

(1975) observed, contracts may be difficult and costly to write due to

transaction costs, bounded rationality and other factors. Furthermore,

even when contracts are costless it can be still difficult or even impossi­

ble to structure contracts that induce optimal behavior. The contract

literature is vast but as I show later, much has yet to be achieved. A

12

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
more focused question often asked is:

(a) W hat incentives should be given via contracts to suppliers? The

idea is to use specific incentives (for the transaction in question)

to align suppliers’ objectives with the buyer’s own objectives to

induce a desired behavior.

All these questions Eire tied together and answers to one affect what can be

done to Einswer others. However, anEilyzing these questions in conjunction

is often difficult, especially for analytical modeling which is the research

focus here. Each question is explored using a different level of Einalysis

and isolates different interactions among firms. In this research I try to

link these different questions, and specificEilly questions 1, 3, and 4, eis the

following outline describes.

1.3 D issertation O utline

Therefore, I start by ansdyzing the incentives problem in chapter 1. In­

centives are designed once the decisions regsurding number of suppliers and

purchasing institutions and markets (spot vs. long-term) have been made.

Only when a buyer knows the way it is going to purchEise Eind how msiny

13

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
suppliers are to be used, can it consider the question of incentives and tailor

them appropriately. Incentive questions have been analyzed extensively in

the Principal-Agent literature, contract theory, game theory and in numer­

ous other streams of literature and research paradigms, including economics,

marketing, operations, management, accounting, and law. These have also

been applied to IT investments for supply-chain improvements (Clemons and

Kleindorfer, 1993), (Wang and Seidmann, 1995). In analyzing incentives

for investments to improve supplier-buyer transactions, it is important to

reflect the impact of such investments on the cost and quality of the ulti­

mate transactions leveraged by these investments. To be specific, I focus on

investments in information systems, but the same arguments developed for

IT will apply more generally. In the model developed, the buyer is able to

observe supplier investments but cannot mandate them (in the usual sense

of principal-agent modeling), in contrast to the assumption of Wang and

Seidmann (1995). Rather than rely on incentives that rely on ex post mon­

etary transfers, depending on the level of the supplier investment, a different

approach is required that is compatible with the context of supplier manage­

ment involving competing suppliers. The framework developed foresees two

incentive instruments, both in the hands of the buyer. The first instrument

14

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is based on the natural assumption that suppliers compete for the buyer’s

business and, in the contest model developed, the “best” supplier wins the

business. Here, “best” will be defined as an observable function of the sup­

plier’s investment in IT. The second instrument is that the buyer itself can

invest in the supplier, thus assuring some additional performance from the

supplier but also affecting the supplier's further incentives to invest. The

trade-offs between the cost and effectiveness of these two instruments is the

central object of the analysis.

As Williamson (1975) established, investments are a key factor in deter­

mining the nature of relationships between firms. To support idiosyncratic

investments, long-term relationships have to be established. Williamson and

the whole stream of TCE that followed have tried to identify the types of

relationships likely to form as a function of several key variables, such as

complexity and frequency of transactions. I build on that insight and use

it to extend standard supplier relationship models by considering a segmen­

tation of transactions as a function of transaction attributes. Chapter 2

analyzes the segmentation problem in terms of the nature of optimal incen­

tives for alternative transactions, described by volume, revenues, complexity

of the buyer-supplier interactions, as well as required investment costs and

15

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
effectiveness.

In chapter 2 and chapter 3 transactions axe modeled as being of different

types relative to supplier capabilities. The “type variable” for new projects is

modelled as a random variable taking values in the [0,1] interval. The unit

interval represents a measure of transaction attributes on which suppliers

are measured, such as quality and cost. Supplier capabilities are located

on this same interval. The buyer cares about the distance between the

transaction and the suppliers, and chooses the supplier who is closest to the

transaction, given a preselected list of approved suppliers. Investments in

supplier capabilities, and the screening and qualification of suppliers, are

decisions undertaken before the "locations” (i.e., specific requirements) of

any new projects are known.

Such modeling provides both advantages and disadvantages in analysis.

The key advantage is, of course, the ability to incorporate and analyze spe­

cific transaction attributes, such as frequency, monetary volume, variability,

and complexity, as drivers of supplier management strategy. The key disad­

vantage is the need to specify functional forms more strongly. I argue that

the functional forms chosen here are reasonable on several dimensions. The

key intuitive property of these functional forms is that investments in buyer-

16

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
supplier compatibility improve this compatibility by providing a better fit

between future projects of the buyer and supplier capabilities. We will see

that this has profound effects on the nature of feasible and optimal incentives

and other characteristics of the supplier management problem. The analysis

of these effects, given a set of suppliers, is indeed the main contribution of

chapter 2.

The results of Chapter 2 also contribute to the theory of contests by

complementing existing literature as best exemplified by Nalebuff and Stiglitz

(1983). Existing literature has concentrated on agents’ output that is linear

in effort with risk-averse agents. In this research the assumption is that

output (here it is A* and not R(A*) since agents are chosen based on A*)

is non-linear in effort/investment and agents axe risk neutral. Nalebuff

and Stiglitiz, generalizing previous papers (e.g., Lazear and Rosen, 1981;

Holmstrom, 1982), have shown that under assumptions of linear output,

risk-neutral agents, and individual randomness effort is increasing in prize

(Theorem 2). The results in this paper axe the same. Similar to the

behavior of agents in their model, agents (suppliers) in this model invest in

order to increase their probability of winning the contract only to end up

with the same probability of winning the contract with which they started

17

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
(in the symmetric case, 0.5). Nalebuff and Stiglitz also showed that, under

non-linearity, a contest does not achieve first best even under risk neutrality.

Here the result is strengthened and it is shown that adding an individualistic

component will improve results under the right conditions. In doing so it

adds to the fundamental discussion of Nalebuff and Stiglitz regarding how

contests and individualistic incentive schemes compare. Lastly, Nalebuff

and Stiglitiz showed that individual randomness is required for equilibrium

to exist. In this work, individual randomness in not present and is not

required to generate interesting results since the nonconvexities identified by

Nalebuff and Stiglitz do not occur here.

In chapter 3 ,1 use the same framework and extend it in order to solve for

the optimal number of suppliers to be used for a set of transactions, the scope

of whose characteristics are defined ex ante, with individual projects realized

randomly in the fashion described above. The analysis generates testable

hypotheses about the factors that drive supplier management strategy, in­

cluding investment levels, numbers of suppliers and performance for various

types of market environment and transactions characteristics. I test these

hypotheses in the empirical part of chapter 3 using data from the purchasing

department of a leading Fortune 500 chemical company.

18

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
A key aspect of the analysis of Chapter 3 is the identification of transac­

tion knowledge codifiability as an important factor in determining supplier

management strategy, especially when e-commerce is concerned. Codifiabil­

ity (Zander and Kogut, 1992) is the ability to take the knowledge embedded in

the transaction and its related processes and codify it in manuals and explicit

instructions for the purpose of communicating requirements for products or

projects involved in the transaction. Codifying transaction knowledge is

necessary for electronic interchange since only codified inputs can be trans­

ferred electronically. In the context of the modeling framework of Chapter

3, codifiability (or more correctly uncodifiability of transaction knowledge)

is modeled as lack of knowledge regarding the transaction or project loca­

tion on the unit interval AFTER the transaction has realized. This lack

of knowledge could apply for both buyer and suppliers. Thus, the buyer

has to form its supplier management strategy knowing it may not be able to

recognize the most able supplier without error or maybe not even at all in

the extreme case.

While knowledge codifiability has been examined in a very limited way

in the management literature (Kogut and Zander 1993; Szulanski, 2000;

Inkpen and Dinur 1998) it has not been examined as a driver for inter-firm

19

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
relationships, supplier management strategy and e-commerce related strate­

gies. Furthermore, using codifiability for analyzing inter-firm relationships

gives rise to interesting new categories of information ‘"asymmetry” effects.

Previous models, based on moral-hazard and adverse selection, have placed

the information asymmetry on only one side of a relationship, mostly placing

the principal at a disadvantage. Uncodifiability of transaction knowledge,

however, may affect both parties similarly. In the case of new technology,

for example, it is sometimes not clear what the specifications are, how to

produce it, or how to support the development and deployment of the tech­

nology. Under conditions of complete uncertainty about such requirements,

the model in Chapter 2 predicts that only one “good overall” supplier will be

used. Thus, in line with intuition, when faced with new technology develop­

ment under high uncertainty on product specification, firms will employ one

supplier for externally sourced requirements. In less extreme circumstances,

increasing uncodifiability results in fewer suppliers used.

Part II of Chapter 3 is an empirical study of a leading Fortune 500 chem­

ical company to examine the several hypotheses generated from this frame­

work. As explained in Chapter 3, multiple reasons exist as to why a single

company is an appropriate focus for such a study at this stage of research

‘20

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
knowledge. The results strongly support the analytical model and the hy­

pothesis that codifiability is a key driver of supplier management strategy.

These results extend the analytical model by showing that indeed, as pointed

above, it is not codifiability itself that matters, but the ability of the buyer to

communicate or transfer its transaction knowledge to its suppliers. In many

instances, the buyer in question knew the transaction and was able to codify

it but was not able to transfer that knowledge to its suppliers, who were

unable to learn the transaction well and efficiently. The result of this lack of

communicability was a decrease in the number of suppliers used, matching

the model’s prediction. Naturally, such instances represent a tremendous

improvement opportunity for the buyer.

Building on the codifiability results and insights, I examine in chapter 4

the integration of various market types for procurement. Given the centred

role of e-Marketplaces in the B2B area, the emphasis here is on the inte­

gration of spot markets and long-term contract procurement choices. We

will see that codifiability is again a central aspect of the nature of this in­

tegration; increased codifiability makes the good in question more amenable

on multiple dimensions to spot market transactions involving arms-length

participation by a number of buyers and sellers. Exactly how this occurs,

21

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
both in single supplier-buyer transactions and in market equilibrium among

competing buyers and sellers requires that we abstract from the details of

individual contracts and focus on more general types of interactions between

buyers and sellers in the markets in question. The framework developed to

analyze this problem builds on work by Wu, Kleindorfer, and Zhang (‘2000,

2001) that examines the spot vs. contracting question but in less general

settings and without treating codifiability effects.

The model developed in chapter 4 adopts the following perspective. One

or more buyers face a decision as to how to source an intermediate product

from one or more suppliers. They can do so either by setting up longer-term

contracts, with specialized suppliers, or through one-time (spot) purchases

from generalized suppliers. In the case of contracts, systems and procedures

are established ahead of time to support the execution of transactions, and

these procedures may be embodied in an exchange with restricted member­

ship. In the case of generalized suppliers, procurement occurs through a

■’spot exchange", where the exchange can be either an established electronic

exchange or something as simple as the Yellow Pages.

The key difference between these types of procurement is that contract

procurement is negotiated in advance, and can accommodate virtually any

22

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
customization in product or delivery features desired by the buyer(s), while

generalized (or "spot”) procurement is constrained by the rules of the market,

and typically allows much less customization. The benefits of contracting

are assumed to be lower variable production and transactions cost, including

the costs of poor quality and off-spec product, and a higher probability of

order fulfillment in the face of demand volatility. Spot purchases from gen­

eralized suppliers provide access to a broader competitive market, and allow

fine timing of demand and supply, but possibly at higher unit costs associated

with the poorer matching of product specifications and delivery features with

the buyer’s requirements. While these benefits favor contracting, it must be

done in advance, and sometimes well in advance, of physical delivery require­

ments so that investments in capacity or customization required of suppliers

to support contract execution may face increased uncertainty relative to spot

market transactions. The trade-offs between these costs and risks depends

fundamentally on the codifiability of transactions and the volatility of de­

mand. If transactions are completely codifiable, and unit costs are identical

between these two sourcing alternatives, there would be no reason (for ei­

ther competing suppliers or buyers) to set up long-term contracts. But cost

differences can arise for both suppliers and buyers. I use this framework

•23

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
to synthesize a host of previous results on the incentives for contracting in

supply chain management.

To summarize, this dissertation examines all stages of supplier manage­

ment from control, selection and screening, to the choice of long-term con­

tracting and spot market mix. This dissertation has formulated a framework

allowing segmentation of supplier relations, into which a number of previous

findings have been integrated. Building on this framework, a fundamental

contribution, shown both analytically and empirically, is the role of codi­

fiability as a driver of all aspects of supplier management strategy. The

analysis and results take on special importance against the significance and

growth of B2B e-commerce activity and resulting restructuring of procure­

ment strategies.

24

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Chapter 2

Incentives for Suppliers’

Investm ents in Information

System s

2.1 Introduction

As the World-Wide-Web (WWW) increases in importance for B‘2B transac­

tions, supplier management becomes more critical for success. At the same

time, buyers’ demands from suppliers are changing. In the past, cost and

quality were the important factors driving supplier management and the key

‘25

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
measures of successful relationships. In a complex and global competitive

world the WWW brings about, cost and quality are not enough. Firms that

cannot create value-adding relationships with their suppliers will not be able

to compete. Given the rise of the WWW and increasing B‘2B activity, such

relationships hinge on investments in ever more complex information systems

(IS), mostly geared towards inter-firm transactions. Until several years ago,

conducting transactions via electronic channel meant doing it through an

EDI connection. Today, it means conducting it either through EDI, or

through a variety of different and new e-Marketplaces. At the same time,

supply-chain software, building on enterprise resource planning (ERP) sys­

tems has emerged to offer even more competitive tools to optimize supply

chain operations.

The result is that for firms to compete successfully, they must get their

suppliers to invest in information systems of different types. While such

systems are typically highly idiosyncratic investments, they may be more or

less relationship specific, i.e. some of these investments may be useful in

general in allowing buyers or suppliers to integrate their operations with the

new realities of e-Markets. The broad purpose of all of these information

systems, whether operational, transactional, or information sharing oriented,

26

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is improving interactions between buyers and suppliers along the range of

products traded between them.

In order to get suppliers to invest in such information systems, a buyer

must set up an environment conducive to supplier investments. Interestingly,

the WWW is the exact opposite of what one usually takes to be the prop­

erties of an "investment inducing environment”. In particular, the W WW

stresses easy access to many suppliers, thus promising higher competition on

the supply side and therefore lower margins for suppliers. However, unless

suppliers believe they can recuperate the investment, they will not invest.

Thus, firms face a sort of catch-2‘2. They want suppliers to invest in sys­

tems that by their very nature may weaken the ability of these suppliers to

recuperate these investments. This may be one of the several reasons that

B‘2B has not grown as fast as forecasted a few years back. A key objective

of this dissertation is to create a framework for designing incentives for to

motivate suppliers to invest in inter-firm IS when it is efficient to do so. In

this chapter I use the framework to analyze incentives for such investments

while in the following chapter I analyze the related question of screening and

selecting suppliers (the so-called "selection problem”), including the optimal

number of such. Thus, as we will see, the framework established allows

27

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
analysis of both selection and control within a single framework.

The framework developed draws upon and extends the transaction cost

economics (TCE) literature on intermediate production relationships (which

has come to be dubbed as B2B), as developed originally by (Coase, 1937)

and (Williamson, 1975). Williamson (1975, 1996) has argued in detail that

the nature of inter-firm relationships changes when various attributes of the

transaction, such as risk and frequency, change. These relationships can

vary from close partnerships with one supplier to spot market purchases in

an open market among several buyers and sellers. However, in the area of

supplier management, TCE has not been successfully formalized analytically.

This paper lays a foundation for such a formalization based on the theory of

contests (Nalebuff and Stiglitz, 1983) and Principal-Agent modeling (Holm-

strom, 1982). A buyer who is the principal has to structure incentives for

suppliers to make inter-firm, relationship strengthening, investments. The

suppliers compete on getting orders or projects from the buyer. By investing,

a supplier makes its fit with any project better. As Clemons et. al (1993)

observed, IS have such an effect. Regardless of the transaction executed

information systems should improve its efficiency and performance. In this

chapter I model this feature of IS and it is the reason why the buyer is trying

28

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
to incent supplier to invest in IS. Suppliers’ investments in IS improve their

performance for any given project transacted with the buyer, which in turn

improves the buyer’s revenues. Such relationship enhancing investments are

akin to establishing a strong relationship. As shown later, the buyer may

invest in the relationship as well, which is akin to selecting those suppliers it

invests with. Thus, part of the ’selection of suppliers’ problem is answered

here as well. However, due to the one-period nature of the model, this paper

does not claim to fully answer it or analyze implications of such selection.

Further work is required to build a multi-period model with more them one

buyer to analyze the full spectrum of the selection and relationships question

?ind is outside the scope of this paper.

To fully use TCE as a basis for analysis economic tools are not enough for

two reasons. The first is that economics neglects operational variables that

are important and critical for understanding relationships with suppliers.

Furthermore, in economics demand is price dependent and such a framework

applies more to market or consumer market situations. In buyer-suppliers

context, demand is generated not by suppliers’ prices but on the buyer’s side

independently of suppliers’ prices and should therefore modeled as stochas­

tic, which is an Operations Management perspective. In this work I use

29

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
stochastic demand generated on the buyer side.

As Williamson (1975) observed, investments are a key factor in estab­

lishing relationships. Wang and Seidmann (1995) explored the question of

incentives for investments in EDI but assumed suppliers must participate,

which mutes the relationship building aspect of the investment. Other mod­

els based on PA have looked at cost reduction rather than investment induce­

ment. As a result, this work finds that the classic solution to PA problems,

of conditional transfers, used in Wang and Seidmann (1995) as well, does not

work in this context. Rather, a more novel approach is required.

This work also contributes to the theory of contests by complementing

existing literature as best exemplified by Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983). Ex­

isting literature has concentrated on agents’ output that is linear in effort

with risk-averse agents. In this research the assumption is that output (here

it is A* and not f?(A*) since agents are chosen based on A*) is non-linear in

effort/investment and agents are risk neutral. Nalebuff and Stiglitiz, gen­

eralizing previous papers (e.g., Lazear and Rosen, 1981; Holmstrom, 1982),

have shown that under assumptions of linear output, risk-neutral agents,

and individual randomness effort is increasing in prize (Theorem 2). The

results in this paper are the same. Similar to agents behavior in their model,

30

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
agents (suppliers) in this model invest in order to increase their probability

of winning the contract only to end up with the same probability of winning

the contract with which they started (in the symmetric case, 0.5). Nale­

buff and Stiglitz also showed that, under non-linearity, a contest does not

achieve first best even under risk neutrality. Here the result is strength­

ened and it is shown that adding an individualistic component will improve

results under the right conditions. In doing so it adds to the fundamental

discussion of Nalebuff and Stiglitz regarding how contests and individualis­

tic incentive schemes compare. Lastly, Nalebuff and Stiglitiz showed that

individual randomness is required for equilibrium to exist. In this work,

individual randomness in not present and is not required to generate inter­

esting results since the nonconvexities identified by Nalebuff and Stiglitz do

not occur here.

The rest of the paper is as follows: Section 1 discusses relationship specific

investments and long-term relationships. Section 2 discusses IS investments

in particular. Section 3 deals with supplier management and control. Sec­

tion 4 surveys briefly some of the selection and control literature. In section

5 we describe the analytical model. In part I (of section 5) we analyze

the case of two asymmetric suppliers and without special incentives towards

31

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
investments. That creates a base model to compare to and establishes suppli­

ers expected behavior with regard to investments when they are not offered

investments based incentives. In Part II I analyze investment dependent

incentive schemes for two symmetric suppliers and demonstrate the impor­

tance of the type of incentives provided to suppliers. I also solve for the

optimal linear scheme, which is both a common assumption in literature and

a practical necessity for implementation.

2.2 Supplier M anagem ent: An O verview o f

the Issues

During the past decade there has been a marked and continuing trend to re­

duce the number of suppliers used (Dyer 1995; McMillan 1990). In a recent

survey covering 27 U.S. industries, all but the government and transporta­

tion sectors reported that in 1997 the mean decrease in number of suppliers

was 6.1%, as a percentage of the 1996 supplier base. Given the growing

economy in 1997, this decrease is quite large, especially against the backdrop

of significant previous decreases in the supplier base during the early ’90s.

At the same time, mean percentage of sales revenues procured from suppliers

32

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
was 35% and in some industries it reached 60% (averaged across the sampled

companies). Thus, on one hand firms are reducing their supplier base and

on the other they are outsourcing more.

As companies increasingly try to focus on core competencies, outsourcing

becomes critical for successful competition in the global marketplace. If a

firm does not manage its suppliers effectively, its operations, product quality,

time to market and overall strategy will clearly be adversely affected.

Previous research aimed at understanding supplier management and inter­

firm relationships have typically concentrated on only one of the four stages

of supplier management:

1. Selection and screening. In order to ensure quality and smooth

transactions, firms have to select and screen suppliers to establish a

list of qualified suppliers.

2. R elationship formation. After suppliers have been selected and

screened, the buyer forms relationships with them. Those relation­

ships may range from arm-length to strategic partnerships and al­

liances. Each relationship type carries a different nature and level

of interaction.

33

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3. Relationship developm ent. Once those relationships have been

formed, they have to be maintained and strengthened, especially when

they are close, long-term relationships.

4. Control and incentives. At the operational level of supplier man­

agement, firms have to write contracts, establish control mechanisms,

and offer the correct incentives to supports the buyer’s goals for a given

relationship.

The thrust of the present work is to examine the challenges of integrat­

ing the above stages. While these four stages are typical of most supplier

relationships, there are significant differences across industries, buyers, and

suppliers in the nature and intensity of each of these stages. A general

framework will need to represent the factors that might affect these dif­

ferences. As Seshadri (1995) notes, selection and control Eire increasingly

considered as strategicEilly linked stages, but except for his theoretical paper

there is little other evidence to suggest that this notion has influenced the

research literature. SimilEirly, early on Macbeth (1987) predicted that just-

in-time and other advanced manufacturing technologies would bring about

the integration of supplier selection with long-term contracts, but very little

34

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
research has been accomplished until recently to examine this subject.1

Like Seshadri (1995) and Wang and Seidmann (1995), I solve simulta­

neously the joint problem of screening an appropriate number of suppliers

and investing in the resulting longer-term relationships with those suppliers.

As in Seshadri (1995), I analyze the dual-sourcing problem using a contest

embedded in a principal agent problem. Seshadri examined the cost contain­

ment contest between two suppliers and derives the optimal cost-plus contest.

The suppliers are drawn from several vendors through a bidding competition.

The winner of the bidding competition, the supplier with lower cost, wins a

larger share of the contract. Wang and Seidmann (1995) analyzed adoption

of EDI by suppliers find showed that EDI externalities influence the adopter

value. The reward for adopters is increased market share and sales volume.

They also show that under certain conditions the buyer may want to subsi­

dize suppliers. Similar to Wang and Seidmann (1995) I analyze idiosyncratic

investments in IS by suppliers. However, unlike both Seshadri (1995) and

Wang and Seidmann (1995) in our model demand cannot be split between

lThis is not to say that the area of contracting in supply chain management has not
been a very active area of research over the past decade, e.g., Cohen and Agrawal (1999)
and many other works reviewed in the recent survey by Cachon (2001). The point here
is simply that this literature has not yet integrated the subjects of selection and control
within a unified framework.

35

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
suppliers. The winner gets all of the profits for any single project (of course,

the buyer may, and in our model does, distribute the benefits of projects

over time among all suppliers on the approved list) . Furthermore, while in

Wang and Seidmann (1995) suppliers are mandated to adopt EDI, suppliers

in this model invest in IS only if they find it profitable to do so. I also

explore the structure of incentives in more detail and show that certain in­

centive schemes have very dysfunctional consequences. Specifically, I show

that conditional transfers, the classic solution in PA and also used by Wang

and Seidmann (1995), are not feasible for ex ante investment incentives in

supplier management. The structure of reasonable incentives is clarified in

this paper.

Concerning general frameworks for supplier management, Christy and

Grout (1994) divide the relationships and the associated theory or models

of supplier management into 4 quadrants. On one axis is process specificity

and on the other is product specificity. When product specificity is high and

process specificity is low, they argue that principal-agent models apply. In

the ’’opposite” quadrant, when product specificity is low and process speci­

ficity is high, transaction cost economics and long-term contracting are ar­

gued to be the suitable theoretical approach. However, in the middle ranges

36

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of product and process specificity they provide no clear answer regarding

which model should be used. I am interested in exactly this middle area and

through combining transaction cost economics and a principal-agent models

I aim to develop a framework that applies to a broader range of supplier

management settings.

Arguably, the central foundation during the past decade for general frame­

works for studying supplier management and inter-firm relationships derives

from transaction cost economics (TCE, see Williamson 1996). The goal of

TCE is to understand and explain the nature of supplier relations in terms

of the factors driving the nature of these relationships. Williamson (1975,

1996) argued that the key factors to consider are: risk, complexity, monetary

volume, and frequency of transactions. These factors determine, according to

Williamson, the nature of relationships and efficient mechanisms for govern­

ing these. These governance mechanisms include long-term contracts, spot

markets, and other arrangements for planning and executing transactions.

The basic logic of Williamson’s approach, applied to supplier management,

is illustrated in Figure 2.1 below.

Located at the lower left corner of the transaction space in Figure 2.1, or

at low levels of risk, complexity, and impact but with high monetary volume

37

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Figure 2.1: Relationship Structures as a function of Transaction A ttributes

c
o Sole Sourcing
m
Long-term Alliances
*
s
t
k

Annual $ Volume
Strategic Impact

and frequent transactions, are standardized transactions. For such transac­

tions, the buyer knows the exact specifications, and products are essentially

commodities; here the emphasis is on low unit cost and low transaction costs.

The market as the trading system is the most common structure, and the

relationship is mostly adversarial. Although investments are made, these are

not relationship-specific investments, but jure geared towards lowering trans­

action costs (e.g., EDI, web-based systems) and better monitoring (tracking

shipping progress, etc.).

At the extreme right upper comer, at high levels of risk, complexity, mon-

38

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
etary volume of transactions (a function of both S/transaction and frequency

of the transaction), and strategic impact are the very close relationships,

resulting in either vertical integration or sole sourcing with long-term con­

tracting. The range of such "strategic partnerships” can itself be large.

Examples are found in automotive and high technology manufacturing. A

parts supplier may supply only one manufacturer, both because of the high

cost and complexity of designing parts and tools for a specific manufacturer

and by reason of the large strategic risks for the automotive manufacturer

(the buyer) should quality problems result. For such transactions where

relationship-specific investments are extremely high and the dollar volume

of transactions makes it worthwhile, efficient supplier management requires

that work processes be aligned, with supporting IT and organizational mech­

anisms to facilitate sharing and coordinating production scheduling and ful­

fillment. These requirements lead naturally to a small supplier base.

When not all the dimensions are either high or low, relationships become

more difficult to establish and analyze. For example, large engineering con­

struction projects are very complex and carry high risk, both for the buyer

and the contractor. Monetary value and strategic and financial impact are

u su a lly high. However, the number of transactions is low. In this case,

39

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
vertical integration may not be feasible since the bought firm would lose its

ability to trade with other buyers and the number of transactions with any

one buyer is not high enough. Sole sourcing, on the other hand, is also

typically infeasible for the buyer, given the geographic dispersion of such

engineering projects. However, the buyer is still interested in relationship-

specific investments on the part of its suppliers since these allow mitigation

of the risks and complexity involved.

As these examples illustrate, at the middle ranges of the dimensions dis­

cussed above, we see various structures, from alliances and strategic partner­

ships to closed e-Markets. These formations are solutions spanning the mid­

dle ground between market mechanisms and full integration or sole sourcing.

In the middle-ground of Figure 1, buyers would still benefit from suppliers’

making relationship-specific investments. However, providing appropriate

incentives to promote such investments is difficult. Among other factors,

relationship duration may complicate matters. Unless suppliers Eire guaran­

teed a long enough relationship they will hesitate to invest since buyers can

eiIways walk away after investments have been made.

Before analyzing market structure using transaction cost economics in

em analytical model, we have to understand how idiosyncratic investments

40

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
are linked to selection and control. In order to benefit over the long term,

a firm has to select suppliers that can improve over time. However, such

improvements usually require idiosyncratic investments, for which suppliers

want to be compensated. To compensate suppliers for such investments,

buyers often promise suppliers who invest that they will enjoy a bigger wal­

let share as an incentive. As a result, selection and control issues are fre­

quently tied to relationship-specific investments. Thus, only an analytical

apparatus that includes both selection and control in conjunction with idio­

syncratic investments will sufficient scope to deal with the basic issues raised

by the transaction cost economics paradigm that has come to dominate as

the foundational framework for analyzing efficient supplier management.

Williamson (1975, 1996) in his analysis of transaction cost economics es­

tablished that a key to understanding market structure lies with relationship

specific investments. These investments are at the core of forming close

relationships such as alliances. However, at the same time, such invest­

ments create a hold-up problem to one or both parties involved. Joksow

(1987) found that buyers and sellers make longer commitments to the terms

of future trades and count less on repeated bargaining as the importance

of relationship-specific investments increases. Therefore, in order to under-

41

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
stand long-term relationships, we first have to understand the mechanisms

underlying the creation of specific investments.

First, let us recall the historical trends noted above towards reduced sup­

plier base. A firm that reduces its supplier base is more exposed to hold-ups

by suppliers as they become more critical to the buyer’s operation and not

as easily replaceable. To counteract such exposure, a firm has to establish

stronger relationships with its existing suppliers. Therefore, accompanying

the reduction in supplier base, we have witnessed a growth in strategic al­

liances for procurement. When vertical integration is not feasible or not

desirable, such alliances serve to secure valuable resources, technologies and

knowledge and usually entail long-term relationships that allow firms to cap­

italize on improved congruency and trust. The benefits to both sides are

many. Kalwani and Narayandas (1995) found that suppliers in long-term

relationships do not experience a lower sales growth than their competitors

who prefer a more transactional approach and at the same time axe able

to reduce cost through better inventory utilization. These cost reductions

are transferred to the buyers through lower prices, which implies that firms

involved in long-term relationships with their suppliers might enjoy cost ad­

vantages. However, Kalwani and Narayandas (1995) also show th at supplier

42

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
firms in long-term relationships enjoy higher profitability by having lower

discretionary expenses such as selling, general, and administrative overhead

costs. At the same time, buyer firms in long-term relationships were found

to benefit from improved quality, process performance and continuous cost

reductions (Newman 1988; TVevelen 1987; Liker and Wu *2000).

Gassenheimer et. al. (1995) found relationship-specific investments to

be the key variable explaining differences in a supplier’s share of a buyer’s

purchases. Such investments include training, process alignment, specialized

information systems, specific equipment and other investments that are only

valuable in a specific relationship. Gassenheimer et. al. found that the

higher the supplier’s investments, the higher the share of the buyer’s wallet

they get. Similarly, Stump (1995) found specific investments to be associated

with greater purchasing concentration. This evidence suggests that suppliers

should want to invest in relationship-specific investments and that buying

firms should try to incent suppliers to invest. However, often firms do

not or cannot sign long-term contracts in advance. Thus, the question

arises: how do buyers motivate suppliers to invest in specific investments

even when future contracts are not guaranteed? This is the central focus

of the analytical framework developed below.

43

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The second key issue in the framework developed is the integration of

selection and control, an issue to which I now turn. In addition to the work

of Seshadri (1995) and Wang and Seidmann (1995), discussed above, some

work on this produced in the literature on managing bidding, awarding and

control of public procurement. A key paper in this regard is Anton find Yao

(1989), who analyze a split-award model and show that it leads to collusive

behavior that in turn leads to increased prices by preventing competition.

Seshadri et. al. (1991) analyze a bidding model without collusion and find

that when the number of bidders is endogenously determined it leads to more

bidders but with higher prices. As Seshadri (1995) points out, both streams

of research into bidding, collusive or competitive, find (p. 563) that: "The

generally obtained result in the cited studies is that multiple agent selection

schemes lead to higher prices them if just one agent were selected.”

Principal-agent theory on the other hand examines contests or tourna­

ments as a means for motivating suppliers. Lazear and Rosen (1981) use

rank-order tournaments as such a mechanism. Holmstrom (1982) generalizes

their mechanism through sufficient statistics analysis. In both models the

principal is faced with a hidden action problem since agents have two sources

of cost uncertainty, common and private. Using a contest, the principal is

44

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
able to outperform an individualized incentive scheme since the contest al­

lows the principal to extract the common cost information. Extraction of

the common cost information allows the principal to extract rents from the

agents. This result depends on the common uncertainty, and as Holmstrom

(1982) observes, "competition per se is worthless” (p. 324). Only compe­

tition that allows extraction of common factors supplies benefits. Nalebuff

and Stiglitz (1983) also use a contest in a slightly different way but with

comparable results. When a common source of uncertainty exits, compe­

tition is mostly preferred over individualistic reward schemes as a means of

extracting the common information rents from the agents. Thus, in contrast

to the selection literature, principal-agent research finds competition to be

better than, or at least equal to, individualistic compensation schemes.

In this paper I integrate the above two streams of research and apply the

integrated model to the realm of idiosyncratic investments. I use a contest

with two suppliers but with a different structure than either that of Seshadri

(1995) or Wang and Seidmann (1995). The agents and principal face the

same common uncertainty. However, although the principal can observe the

investments made by the agents, she cannot contract on these investments

directly because of the nature of the environment in which only one of the

45

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
agents can execute the work. The principal, due to the uncertainty involved,

does not know ex-ante which agent is best suited for the work. Only the

winner gets ”a prize”, which is actually the payment associated with the

contract. While the promise of winning the project may be enough for agents

(suppliers) to invest, the buyer may find it useful to offer stronger, investment

specific, incentives. I find that monetary transfers, fixed or conditional, are

not enough and in effect do not change suppliers’ effective investments, since

such transfers do not affect their marginal returns. The principal (buyer)

has to invest in the relationship. In my two-stage model, such incentives are

akin to a selection of the supplier in a multi-period model since they establish

a "strong” relationship with a supplier and give that supplier some preferred

status. In the model here, this translates to higher probability of winning

a contract ceteris paribus. We show below that when the two questions

of selection and control are tied together there is no clear answer to how

many suppliers the principal (the buyer) should select. Depending on the

technology of the idiosyncratic investment and other factors, the principal

might select both, one, or none of the suppliers.

46

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
2.3 M odeling Framework

We assume two suppliers competing for the business of a single buyer. Sup­

pliers can be asymmetric on two attributes. The first is their type or spe­

cialty, which we represent by a type parameter p{, for suppliers i = 0 , 1 , where

p{ takes values on the [0,1] interval. Projects (or transactions) are assumed

to arrive stochastically and to have attributes that can also be positioned

on this same [0, 1] interval. Indeed, we think of the location of project a t­

tributes as describing the ideal type supplier for that project, whereby actual

suppliers will be chosen as suppliers depending on the distance of their type

from this ideal type or project location. The details of the selection process

are described below.

We place the two suppliers on the extremes, one supplier at pQ = 0 and

one supplier at px = 1. However, having asymmetry by placing one closer

to the middle than the other would not change results in any fundamental

manner. Such asymmetry would only serve to shorten the [0,1] effective

interval over which competition for projects occurs to the interval between the

two suppliers. Any area between a supplier find the interval end is controlled

by that supplier alone and therefore does not affect the competition between

the suppliers.

47

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The second source of asymmetry is a technology factor, a*. I start by

assuming technology asymmetry (qo a i) but I consider the results for the

special case of symmetry in some detail.

I begin with a simple pure contest model that does not have any specific

incentive mechanism designed to incent investments by suppliers. I limit the

analysis to two suppliers; the N-supplier case is a straightforward extension.

I consider in Chapter 3 of this dissertation the optimal number of suppli­

ers, thus complementing the present analysis to solve the dual questions of

selection and control.

2.3 .1 T h e C ontest

Each supplier faces the same situation. It wants to maximize its profits

given the incentive scheme declared by the buyer. Thus, supplier i faces the

following problem:

MaxUi = T x Ti - Xi for i = 0,1 (*)


Xj> 0
T is the average transfer suppliers receive from a given transaction . 2 is

2In the more general framework proposed in Chapter 3 we multiply the term TxT, by
the arrival rate of projects/transactions that would be enabled by the single investment Xj.
In this more general framework, the supplier is thus making investments with an eye on
cashflows generated by a stream of projects that it might thereby win. For the moment,
we focus on a single-shot contest, i.e., a single transaction.

48

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
supplier i’s probability of winning any given order or project, and Xi is sup­

plier i’s relationship-specific investment directed towards winning this order.

Such investments might include specialized equipment, tooling or informa­

tion systems. To solve the supplier’s problem, Ti has to be specified. As

noted above, we assume th at the probability of winning the order for sup­

plier i is determined by the distance between the supplier’s type (p0 = 0 and

p, = 1) and the realized project characteristics p, where p is assumed to be

a uniform random variable on [0, 1]. The distance between supplier i and

the realized project type before investments effects axe taken into account is

A, := |p —p j. Supplier i’s investment is assumed to reduce the ”effective

distance” between the supplier and the project. We model the effective

distance as A f^ = Av x A/, where M : = ---- , which we term the ” tech-


1 + otiXi

nology function” with the technology factor a* determining the impact of Xi

on Mi and therefore on Aj.

Using the above notation and assumptions, To = (1— Ti) is determined

as follows:

To = Pr[Supplier 0 wins the project]

=Pr[SupplierOhasthesmallesteffectivedistance]

=Pr[|p - Pol x iV/ 0 < |p - pj| x Mi\

49

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
=Pr[pM0 < (1 - Pj) x Mi]
or „ Mi , Mi
=Pr[p <
(Mo + Mi) (M0 + Mi)
where the fineil equality results from the assumption that projects are drawn

from a uniform distribution. Similarly we get Ti = , . , .


(M0 + Mi)
Given To and Ti, there is a unique point p*, which divides the [0,1]

interval into two parts. To the left of p* supplier 0 wins eind to the right of

it supplier 1 wins. Substituting T* into the profit function (*), we obtain

the suppliers’ problem:


,. _ T x Mj . n , ,
MaxIIj = 7— r— - Xi t = Q, 1 j = I -1
-vt>0 M (Mi + Mj)

T h e o re m 1 For the game with profit functions Ilj, i — 1,2, there exists a

unique, Nash Equilibrium:

Xi = Max < 0, QtQj t —L\ i = o ,l j = 1 —i


I (<*« + < * j) Cti J

Proof.

Existence

Since H is concave in Xi I consider the first-order condition while ignoring

the non-negativity constraint. To simplify presentation I use the fact that


At #
d ‘ = —QiMf. The F.O.C.s are therefore:

g jl.a WM j=oa j ml-i


dxi (Mi + Mj)

50

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Combining the two F.O.Cs for the two suppliers and solving for M q and Mi

results in atoMo = a i Mi and therefore,

Mi = ^Q,2+Q^ - i = 0 ,1 j = 1 - i
<Aa i T
Solving for X*:

Xi =
QiQj
t J aT T
- —1
i = 0 ,1 j = 1 - *
(a* + atj)2 at
Since I!,- is strictly concave in x* it is easily seen this implies the solution

proposed.

Uniqueness

I follow the discussion in EViedman (1986) which summarize both Gale-

Nikaido (1965) and Rosen (1965) and thus allow to show that uniqueness

follows from both those papers but through using one notation system. The

following conditions hold and can be easily verified:

1. Si, the strategy space of each player is compact and convex for each

player i. A strategy for player i is simply Xj (corresponds to As­

sumption 2.1 in EViedman.)

2 . H is continuous and bounded for all strategy combinations s = (sot Si)

and Jill i (corresponds to Assumption 2.2 in EViedman.)

3. H is strictly concave in x,.(corresponds to Assumption 2.3 in EVied-

51

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
man.)

4. Players cannot have binding agreements (corresponds to Rule 2.1 in

Friedman.)

5. Strategy choices by the players (suppliers) axe made prior to the game

(corresponds to Rule 2.2 in Friedman.)

6 . T = (N, S, FI) is a strictly smooth game. N is the set of players, S the

strategy space and II is the set of H . (corresponds to Definition 2.13

in EViedman.)

Given the above conditions both Theorem 2.6 in FViedman which follows

the Gale-Nikaido (1965) univalence theorem and Rosen’s uniqueness theorem

are satisfied if the Jacobian of the implicit form of the best reply function is

negative quasi-definite. To show that last condition the following deriva­

tions are provided:


tfU j —2 a j T M j M f
dx? (Mi 4- M j)3
FUi Q jCtjTM jM f (M j - Mj)
dxidxj (Mi + M j)3

Since the diagonal elements of the Jacobian are negative and the deter­

minant | J + J 7"! is positive the Jacobian is negative quasi-definite and the

proof is complete. Q.E.D. ■

52

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
From Theorem 1, we see that under symmetry, Qo = = a , the solution
f T 1)
is Xi = M ax < 0 ,--------- >. Note for the symmetric case that if a T < 4 then
I 4 aj
xq = X\ = 0. Thus, the combination of project revenues and the unit im­

pact of investment on buyer-supplier fit should be above a certain threshold

in order for supplier investment to occur. In other words, expected revenues

for the supplier and investment impact should be high enough to make it

profitable for suppliers to invest in information systems and other idiosyn-

cractic systems to improve supplier-buyer performance. The incentives for

supplier investment are sharpened somewhat by the nature of the prisoners’

dilemma type of competition embodied in this contest. Notwithstanding

this sharpening, if the cumulative effect on efficiency is not sufficiently high,

no investment will occur. Note that, as expected, investments increase in ex­

pected revenues, T. Investments increase in the technology factor ct*, which

drives investment effectiveness in terms of improved fit. Given the declining

marginal effectiveness of investments on overall fit as well as supplier prof-


T
itability, such investments are bounded above, in the symmetric case by —.
4

Note that under symmetry, suppliers still have the same probability 0.5 of

winning the project after equilibrium investments have occurred, and thus

they are worse off than before investments occurred, having lost the invest-

53

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ment. This outcome is the natural and intended consequence of the structure

of the contest set up by the Buyer to push suppliers towards processes and

technologies exhibiting better fit.

2.3.2 T he B uyer’s P rob lem

As a base model I assume the buyer is not offering any specific incentives

for suppliers’ investment. Thus, suppliers would invest only if ex-ante, they

perceive the investment to be profitable. I note that from discussions we

had with purchasing managers, firms mostly do not offer specific incentives

towards investments in information systems or other idiosyncratic invest­

ments, but rather require such as the normal course of business interactions.

However, as experience for example with B‘2B related investments, suppli­

ers would not necessarily invest. As Stump (1995) found, when suppliers

do make relationship specific investments, they have a higher likelihood of

winning projects or orders and both the buyer and supplier enjoy lower trans­

action costs because of a decrease in repeated bargaining (Joksow, 1987).

I model investment effects as follows. Assume any given project or order

would generate some ideal revenues r on the buyer’s side. However, r can

be achieved only if the supplier matches perfectly with the project. In

54

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the model, such match translates to supplier attributes or location p{ being

the same as the the project attributes or location p. Under any other

configuration of supplier location and project location there will be some

distance, A* = \p{ —p\, between the supplier and the project, which will

lower revenues achieved. I define the revenue function as R — /i(A*) =

1~—— where
1+0A *
0 6 [0,oo) is the ’impact of fit’ coefficient. For different firms, and even

for different project types within the same firm, the importance of supplier-

project fit is different. For example, when a highly strategic project such as

a new manufacturing plant is considered, the importance of supplier-project

fit is high. On the other hand, when an order of desks for employees usage is

considered, the importance of fit is very low or practically zero. Thus, when

0 = 0 , which would match the desk example, the buyer always achieves the

ideal results or revenues associated with it and therefore would not require

its suppliers to make relationship enhancing investments. As 9 increases,

the importance of fit, or A*, goes up and the only way to offset the increase

in 6 is for suppliers to invest.


r
Note that 0 < A* < 1 and therefore < R < r. Therefore, changes
1+ 0 - - °

in 0 will affect not onlv the mean but also the variance of R.

oo

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
I assume the following on r : r > (Q° a 0 ^ This assumption assures
a 0Qi
feasibility of prize and non-negative revenues for the buyer. Theoretically,

this assumption may not be satesfied, but then contracting does not happen.

Thus, this is a regularity condition on the relationship between r and the fit

paramteres in the model.

The buyer’s problem is to maximize profits, assuming he uses only project

based incentives or the ” prize” awarded to the winner, and is therefore:

MralIU = r ? W " r < a ’‘i)


In order to solve this maximization problem A* has to be calculated first.

Theorem 2 A t the optimal solution to the buyer’s problem, A* = (Q° ^


atoctii
for any a, and any prize T. The optimal prize maximizing the Buyer’s

expected profits is T* = - <*±*11


aoai ao£*i

Proof. A* is the expected distance between the chosen supplier and the

project and therefore A* = E min ^Aq^, A * ^ where A ^ is as defined

above, the ”net distance” between supplier and a project accounting for

investment effects. As shown above, there exists a unique equilibrium point,

p'. To the left of p ’ supplier 0 wins and to the right of it, supplier 1 wins.

Using this fact, the solution for A* is obtained as follows:

56

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
A* = E m i n ^ ^ A f ' ) =

= Pr (Supplier 0 wins) x Aq^ + Pr (Supplier 1 wins) x A ^ ^ =

= J f pModp + (1 - p) M«ip =
MqM i
(Mo + M t)
(a , 4- Qj) 2
Substituting Mi = —^ — ■£— supplies the desired result. To determine T*,
a f a jT
given A*, we note that the buyer’s problem is:
w _tt a0a xr T
Maxiih — _ . .
7* a o ctiT 4- (oio -F Q i ) ®

Since lit is concave in T, we use the F.O.C to find the maximum, which is

achieved at:
r . _ /(q, + a,)r(J _ (°. + o,)0 Q ED u
V ao<*i ttoOt

2
Corollary 1 Under symmetry a 0 = ai = 0, A* = —= and the optimal prize
al
/ 2r0 20
is T = J ------------.
V a a

From these results, we note that as the revenues for the Buyer increase,

so too does the optimal prize T*. In the symmetric case, T is convex in

q and is maximized at a = 80 jr . There is a level of impact of investment

at which transfers to suppliers provide the buyer with the highest returns

for its money. When a is too low, investments do not have enough effect

and therefore the buyer does not give as high a transfer. However, if a

57

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is sufficiently high, the buyer knows the suppliers are going to invest and

therefore the buyer can and does lower its transfer payments. Below we show

the profit function that embodies this discussion. Note in the symmetric case

that T is always increasing in 9 near the origin. Thus, some attention to fit

is always appropriate in setting the level of the prize.

1
Corollary 2 A* =

/ Q0a xrd _ Q
(Qo +Oti)

Corollary 3 A* = , under symmetry. As should be, A* in-


y /0 J ri§ -6
creases in r, a , and 9.

= r _ y ( a o 4- a i ) r 0
Corollary 4 R(9)
QoQi
Given the assumption, (Q° < r a^ot,gj R{9) is positive and con-
aoOi
tracting is feasible.

Corollary 5 II6 = R(9) - TT == r - 22 ^/ (Q° + Ql) rg + ^Q° + ? l)0 and given


w a 0a i a 0 a!
the assumption above it is positive.

/ 2r0 20
Corollary 6 Under symmetry: Ub = r —2 \ ------ 1---- and therefore profits
V a a
are convex in a.

58

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
2.3.3 In cen tives

As I observed earlier, using only project dependent transfers may not be

enough to support supplier investments. Furthermore, it may be beneficial

to the buyer to offer investment related incentives, other them T. In most

cases it is not feasible to condition T on supplier investments Xi since T in

this context represents expected revenues from a stream of future transac­

tions. In the following section I analyze when it is profitable for the buyer to

offer investment related incentives, what form should these incentives take,

and how suppliers would respond to them. I examine three types of incen­

tives and show the classic solution to Principal-Agent problems, conditional

transfer, does not work in this context and a more sophisticated conditional

incentive is required. The analysis is restricted to linear schemes since non­

linear schemes would not be practical in this problem context and thus I

do not solve for the optimal incentive scheme. I solve only for symmetric

suppliers in order to show insights clearly. For asymmetric suppliers the

analysis does not yield qualitatively different results.

59

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
D irect Transfers: Fixed Transfers

The first incentive to consider is the trivial fixed transfer. However, as easily

observed, such a transfer would not change supplier investments. It would

only increase suppliers’ profits while lowering buyer’s profits.

D irect Transfers: C onditional Transfers

This is the classic solution to Principal-Agent problems. However, under this

paper’s problem it does not work. If the conditional transfer is K(Xi) the
QiOtj
analysis will show the optimal investment to be x< = --------- -a---------—T —
(ai + ctj) (1 - K )
— where K' is the derivative with respect to xt. If we assume a linear scheme

K(Xi ) = kxi it is easy to see that x, is indeed increasing in k. However, it

is essentially the same as offering the supplier a higher transfer T, but T is

solved to optimality to begin with. The main difference in this paper from

classic Principal-Agent papers is the problem here is of incenting investments

and not inducing cost reductions. In cost reduction problems the suppliers’

objective function fundamentally changes when such incentives are used due

to a change in the marginals. Such an effect does not take place when

investments are concerned. Wang and Seidmann (1995) had shown condi­

tional transfers to work for inducing investments but under the assumption

60

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
that suppliers must participate, which allows conditional transfers to work

in their settings. However, the present work does not assume, as is realistic

in many situations, that buyers can force suppliers to invest.

Investm ents in the R elationship

Given the above analysis of transfers it is clear that for an incentive scheme to

work it should be more them a mere transfer from the buyer to its suppliers.

Indeed, where investments in relationships are concerned, a buyer can invest

in the relationship as well. Such investments translate to a better fit between

the buyer rind the specific supplier supported by such an investment. As was

shown previously, higher fit induces higher investments by suppliers.

Such a scheme, of a buyer investing in its relationship with a supplier, is

akin to the buyer selecting this supplier for long-term relationship. Given

the one-period nature of the model in this paper it is not feasible to analyze

the broader and temporal effects such investments would have and is outside

the scope of this paper.

Fixed Support

If the buyer invests a fixed amount yt- in the relationship then

Mi = --------- and yi is guaranteed and known to the suppliers in


1 + q (xi + yi)

61

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
advance. The analysis of suppliers’ contest does not change and the solution

is still Mq — Mi = - 7 - . Using the new we solve for Xj to get x» =


ctT
T 1
— j/f. This solution is the same solution as before except that the
4 Q

supplier now invests y* less. Clearly the buyer gains nothing and only loses

Ih. Interestingly, this scheme has the same effect as the direct fixed transfer

incentive had.

Quid Pro Quo Support

An improvement on the fixed support scheme would be to offer condi­

tional support, i.e. iji = 2/»(Xj). Intuitively, such an incentive should increase

suppliers’ incentives to invest by improving fit. The trade-off for the buyer

is between the costs of the support find the benefits incurred due to a smaller

A*. As mentioned before, I concentrate on a linear scheme = 0Xi since

nonlinear schemes are not practical for implementation. As in the analy­

sis under no incentives, I start with the contest and then solve the buyer’s

problem.

The C ontest

Since the analysis follows exactly the analysis for no incentives the proofs

are the same and I will only report the changes. The first change is that now

—_ a (1 4. p ) Xi_ 1 define a ’’new” technology factor a ' = a (1 + 13


uXj

62

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
a ia j 1
and oget X;» ------
(I — ------ r,> i = 0.1, j = 1 —i. Note that this solution is
(Q« + a i)
exactly like the asymmetric solution reported earlier but with the new factor

replacing the previous one o^. As expected, Xf increases in /3{. Note th at

now the buyer’s investment in the relationship induces higher investment by

the supported supplier(s) because the more the buyer invests, the more it

pays the supplier to invest.

The Buyer’s Problem The buyer’s profit function is now slightly dif­

ferent and is:

M ax Ilfc = -— T
~ T - f3x
T.t3 1 + 0A*
with (3 = (/?o,/?i) a n d x = (x0 ,x i). However, when y(x) or (3 is optimized,

it is assumed that T is fixed or given. The reasoning is as before th at T

is a stream of payments and project dependent and therefore the buyer is

trying to optimize incentives for investment given those payments. Therefore,


(qo + a'.)
and using the solution A* = - —■,—rzr~ an<i the solution for xt the buyer’s
Qoa i ^
problem is:
n _______ a'0a [r T _______ ^ {0O+ 0 X) aoa'l m . 0 O , (3l
* Al6 _ a ' a ; r + ( a ; + Q; ) 0 ( a '+ a 'O + + a',

Theorem 3 The solution to the buyer’s problem is:

I- A> ~ = P

63

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
2a0 rT T 2
2. 3 is determined by the equation 7 ——-H------------ =• =
^ ( a ( l + 0 ) T + 20) 2 a (1 + /3)
2 a 0 rT T 2
0 in the region w here ------------ , —— H— > 0 and 3 = 0 outside this
(a T + 29)2 2 a
region.

3. Unique

Proof. In the appendix we show 0 Q = 0 { = 0. Therefore, the buyer’s


,, . „ a(l+ /S )rT „ /S„ . 2/3 c .
problem «: M ax II. = q ( 1 + ^ - T - -T + The f a t
2 ck0 rT T 2
derivative w.r.t. /? is -----------------------r —— H ---------r. At 0 = 0 it
( a ( l + 0 ) T + 20) 2 a(l+0)2
. 2a 6 rT T 2 . , , . - 4 a 29rT 2
is------------- s —— H— . Since the second derivative---------------------- t —
(a T + 20) 2 a (a (1 + 0 ) T + 29)
4
----------- 3 < 0 V/3, Ilf, is unimodai in /?. Thus to have a positive solution
a (1 4- 0)
for 0 the first derivative must be positive at 0 which defines the region as in

2. Then we get the solution to 0 by the equation defined in 2. Otherwise,

if at 0 = 0 the first derivative is not positive, 0 = 0 is the optimal solution.

Q.E.D. ■

2.4 D iscussion

I have demonstrated that suppliers should invest in relationship specific in­

vestments to enhance the likelihood of winning projects because of their

en h a n ced relationship with the buyer. Suppliers find such investments ben-

64

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
eficial when their revenues from the contract are high enough, and when the

impact of the investment on the relationship is strong enough. Such in­

vestments are induced by suppliers’ competition over the contract. When

suppliers enjoy asymmetric returns from such investments one may invest

while the other may not.

I have also demonstrated that a buyer has several ways to motivate sup­

pliers but only one of those actually works. Contrary to practice, but in

accordance with standard principal-agent analysis, the buyer should not of­

fer any type of fixed support to the supplier. However, when a buyer does

support suppliers through fixed transfers she may fail to understand that

such fixed support is not optimal. The reason is that while such support

does not change suppliers’ investments, the buyer still enjoys profits and

therefore misinterprets the investment effects. However, the buyer’s profits

are not optimal but only the same profits she would have enjoyed without

the transfer minus the transfer. When linear reward schemes are considered,

only conditioned support is optimal. Thus, the buyer should invest directly

in the relationship instead of using monetary transfers to the supplier, which

result in the supplier reducing its own investment by at least the amount

transferred to it.

65

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
This work also adds insight to the economic literature on contests. The

model used here has the suppliers investing despite the existence of only

environmental randomness and no individual based randomness. This result

contrasts with the classic result (theorem 4) of Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983) in

which they prove individual randomness to be a necessary condition for effort

by the agents (suppliers in our case.) Thus, we Eire able to structure a new

type of contest where individual randomness is not required while the prize

system is still ordinal as in Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983). This chapter offers

further insight on Nalebuff and Stiglitz’s (1983) theorem 1, which states that

some dependence between agents’ outputs is needed for the optimEil incentive

scheme not to be individualistic. Theorem 2 in this chapter states that when

suppliers are symmetric the incentives should be the sEime to both. Given

the perfect correlation between the two suppliers’ ’’output," I have proved

the complement of Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983) theorem 1.

The model Einalyzed here applies to cases where a contract can be awEirded

to only one supplier, while most of the literature has been concerned with

contracts that can be split among suppliers (e.g. Anton and Yao 1989; Se-

shadri, 1995;Wang and SeidmEinn, 1995). The model exEimined in this paper

adds another dimension to the literature and allows a better investigation of

66

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the various types of contracts. Indeed, as discussed in the introduction, con­

tracts and supplier relations exhibit considerable variety in terms of the risk,

complexity, and impact they present to the buyer. A worthy goal, for future

research is to integrate the various possible models for each combination of

conditions on the above dimensions into one general framework.

As discussed in the introduction, this paper is only the first step in estab­

lishing a framework for analysis of supplier management across its life-cycle.

I was able to analyze both selection and control, the two extreme phases

of the cycle, in conjunction. To analyze questions relating to long-term

relationships, multiple periods must be introduced into the model. Corre­

spondingly, in order to analyze the full question of supplier selection, ” pre­

ferred supplier” status, alliances and partnerships, more than two suppliers

should be assumed to exist. Combining these two extensions would allow

us to examine how long-term relationships and strategic alliances, or other

types or relationships, interact with contract structure, interorganizational

idiosyncratic and specific investments, and the nature of the transactions

and products involved. Another possible extension is to add suppliers’ pri­

vate information regarding their production function. This paper’s model

generates an interesting conflict even without the use of private information.

67

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Finally, I am aware of modeling limitations in this paper due to the

specific functional forms we used. However, in order to generate the insights

which are the main focus of this paper, specific functions had to be used.

Because of the model’s complexity, having a contest embedded in a principal-

agent model, generalizing the functional forms would have limited our ability

to derive meaningful results.

2.5 A ppendix A

Summery of Notations

Xi :=Relation specific investment made by the supplier.

y { —Relation specific investment, in supplier i, made by the buyer.

ai :=Technology factor determining the impact of x, and on A/,, a , > 0.

Mi : = -------- ,technologyfunction determining the impact of x, and iji


1 + OjXj

on the distance between a project and supplier i.

r —Location of a project, r is distributed uniformly on [0, lj.

p{ —Location of a supplier on the [0,1] interval.

^ := |p - Pi\

A /c f —A,-x Mi, the effective distance between a supplier and a project

68

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
given Xi and y,.

A* := min(Aj), the minimum of the distances between the suppliers and

the project. Supplier i, which achieved this distance is the winner.

T :=The fixed transfer or prize the buyer gives the winning supplier.

R := R( A*) the revenue function of the buyer as a function of the distance

between the winning supplier and the project.

H := Profit function of supplier i.

lib := Profit function of the buyer.

Proof, o f Theorem 1: We want to show that /30 = ,8i . For simplicity of

presentation I define
2 + 0Q + 0 X /? ,) + /? ! J D L
A = — --- , . -,i—“ -r and B ——r-— - ——— . Let Ai and B, be
Q ( 1 + A>) ( 1 + $i) a.{2 + 0 Q+ 0 X)
the first derivatives w.r.t.. to /3iof A and B respectively. Then
-1 2
Ai = ------------ 7 and Bi = --- ——-- — for i = 0,1. The buyer’s
q ( 1 + Pi) Q( 2 + P o + f a )
objective function can now be rewritten as follows:
w__ r-r _ rT _ B_T _____ 0o_________ 0i
M ax lift T + AQ a T q(1 +) 3oj +

The F.O.C. are:


dnb rT 1 (BiA - B A ) T 1 Q
80, T + A6 a (1 + f3,)2 A2 a(l+,^)2
Multiplying by a (1 + 0,)2 , equating the F.O.C for i = 0 and i = 1 and

simplifying we get:

69

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
(B qA — BA q) a (1 + 0 Q)2 = ( B \A —B A i) a (1 -I- A ) 2- Substituting Ao,

Ax, Bo, B\, A, and B the condition is:

1 + A) = 71 7+-A j r a a
7 - 7 - 5- 3 - and therefore, A = Pi-
1 + Pi i + Po
It is easy to check the second order conditions and as I showed in the proof

given in the body of the paper, those axe satisfied when ,P0 = fix-Q.E.D. ■

TO

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Chapter 3

The Optimal Number of

Suppliers and Codifiability

3.1 Introduction

In chapter 2 of this dissertation I have analyzed the question of control

through incentives by a buyer to its supplier for idiosyncratic investments,

such as investments in Information Systems (IS). The focus of this chapter

is to solve the complementing problem of supplier selection, and it is done

via the analytical framework developed in chapter ‘2. I then examines em­

pirically the hypotheses generated by the analytical model. Selection is the

71

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
first stage in supplier management and thus affects the nature and specifics

of later stages in the supplier management process. Supplier selection is both

a strategic and an operational decision, which makes it more complex to an­

alyze. While supplier management strategy has to align with the buyer’s

overall supply-chain strategy and allow its execution, supplier management

strategy also has to satisfy operational requirements when products and ma­

terials are procured.

In the new world of B2B e-commerce, when e-Marketplaces and ex­

changes are increasingly becoming a medium through which to conduct trans­

action, having the right supplier management strategy becomes even more

critical for firms. Even more so, buyers now must consider the right sup­

plier base for supplier investments in IS. As the last two years have shown,

suppliers are highly hesitant to join e-Marketplaces and exchanges for fear

of eroding margins due to increased competition (see Helper and MacDuffie,

2001). The only successful (or partially so) exchanges are these cater to com­

modities (e.g. steel) or are led by a strong buyer or consortium of buyers (e.g.

Covisint). In most other instances suppliers either do not join exchanges or

put high obstacles to prevent successful operation of the exchange in ques­

tion. As an International Data Corporation study found, only 10% of 1,000

72

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
exchanges launched in a span of 18 months had any activity by May, ‘2001

(cited in The Economist, 5/19/2001). One potential explanation is sug­

gested by the analytical framework, which shows that limiting the supplier

base (as in Covisint) is required for suppliers’ investments.

Even more critical for any electronic transaction is the issue of codi­

fiability (Kogut and Zander 1992), which is the level at which a transaction

can be described by a written description and manuals. Naturally, unless a

transaction can be codified it cannot be executed electronically. However,

as this chapter shows, it is not just a requirement but also a critical and

important driver of supplier management strategy. Management literature

(Kogut and Zander, 1992 and 1993; Szulanski 1996; Inkpen and Dinur 1998)

examined codifiability in intra-firm activities and context and find it to be

an important factor in knowledge transfer. I take the idea of codifiability

and apply it in inter-firm relationships context and specifically as a driver of

supplier management strategy. The analytical model shows the extent to

which transaction codifiability may determine the optimal number of suppli­

ers. As codifiability decreases, fewer suppliers can be used. The empirical

analysis extends the concept and examines transaction transferability (Szu­

lanski 1996; Inkpen and Dinur 1998). Inkpen and Dinur found contextual

73

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
elements (e.g. culture) to be an important factor in determining transferabil­

ity. In this study the focus is how transaction transferability affects supplier

management strategy and specifically how it determines the number of sup­

pliers used. Therefore, both codifiability and suppliers’ ability to learn the

transaction are measured.

Operations management literature (Helper and MacDuffie, 2001)

concentrated on product standardization and complexity as a driver of sup­

plier management strategy and recently B2B e-commerce strategy. Com­

plexity, also identified by Williamson (1975), and standardization are indeed

important factors in supplier management. Novak and Eppinger (2001)

have found product complexity and vertical integration to be complements.

However, a key observation is that both standardization and complexity are

directly related to codifiability and transferability of transactions. The more

complex a product is, the less codifiable it is and the more difficult it is for the

supplier to learn. The more standardized a product the easier and cheaper

it is to codify. Moreover, suppliers have to invest much less in learning

since learning a product once serves all buyers who procure that product.

Therefore, I focus on codifiability and transferability as drivers and in the

empirical analysis measure them directly.

74

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Codifiability, when applied to inter-firm relationships, gives rise to in­

teresting new categories of information “asymmetry” effects. Previous mod­

els, based on moral hazard and adverse selection, have placed the information

asymmetry on only one side of a relationship, mostly placing the principal

at a disadvantage. Uncodifiability of transaction knowledge, however, may

affect both parties similarly. In the case of new technology, for example, it

is sometimes not clear what the specifications are, how to produce it, or how

to support the development and deployment of the technology. As such, it

gives rise to many questions (and outside the scope of this study) such as

what investments should be made in codification, whom should make them

(buyer or suppliers) and how codifiability level and related investments af­

fect the overall industry structure. Under conditions of complete uncertainty

about such requirements, the model in this chapter predicts that only one

“good overall” supplier will be used. Thus, in line with intuition, when faced

with new technology development that implies high uncertainty on product

specification, firms will employ one supplier or develop it in house. In less

extreme circumstances, increasing uncodifiability results in fewer suppliers

used.

The selection of suppliers is an ongoing process composed of first

(0

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
screening suppliers in order to ensure acceptable quality, adequate capacity,

and in general to screen out (or screen in) suppliers that do not have the

capabilities to satisfy the buyers requirements on multiple dimensions. Those

suppliers who pass the screening process become part of a qualified supplier

list. The critical questions for this stage are how many suppliers to use

and which ones should be chosen to constitute the qualified suppliers list.

Previous research on these questions, especially analytical modeling, centered

on two variants of the number of suppliers question:

1. Pros and cons of multiple suppliers compared to a single source.

2. Pros and cons of dual sourcing compared to sole sourcing.

This analysis tackles the broader question of optimal number of suppli­

ers for a given product and market attributes. By doing so, it takes the

Williamsonian framework of TCE a step further. TCE stipulated that dif­

ferent supplier relationships configurations should exist for different product

attributes, specifically risk, complexity, monetary volume, and frequency of

transactions. This paper supplies an analytical framework to solve for the

optimal number of supplier given those factors when idiosyncratic invest­

ments axe of concern.

76

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The second stage is selecting, usually from the pre-qualified suppliers list,

the supplier who is to supply a specific order. The process may vary and

may include an auction, request for proposal, or more screening for specific

capabilities. As explained in chapter 2, in this framework the supplier who

is best fit to execute the transaction gets selected to do so. In doing so, the

study takes a different approach and focus than auction related literature or

split-award research (Anton and Yao, 1989), which emphasizes the selection

of the most appropriate supplier or the correct way to divide the work be­

tween two winning suppliers. Given the most fit supplier selection criteria,

and the assumption of uniform distribution of transactions, suppliers selected

to be on the qualified supplier list are uniformly distributed throughout the

attributes space represented by the [0, 1 ] interval. Of course, the uniform dis­

tribution assumption is only for analytical tractability. The insight derived

is that buyers should select suppliers to match the distribution of attributes

of future transactions. In doing so, the buyer maximizes the expected fit be­

tween the chosen supplier and project/transaction. Such a supplier selection

strategy will also balance competitive forces and likelihood of winning future

transactions (by a supplier.) For example, if the distribution of arriving

transactions for a certain product line is skewed towards high quality and

77

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
sophisticated engineering products, then more suppliers with those capabili­

ties should be chosen and fewer of lower sophistication. The result is strong

competition in the high quality/sophisticated engineering product domain,

and as chapter 2 shows, leads to high investments in IS for competitive ad­

vantage while ensuring high enough volume for each supplier. At the same

time, the lower concentration of low quality suppliers ensures that they will

have enough volume (given the lower frequency of such projects) to provide

them with an incentive to invest in idiosyncratic investments.

As shown with this example, the analytical framework developed in this

dissertation allows segmented supplier management strategy. For a differing

set of conditions, a different strategy should be used. In the empirical work

this hypothesis is examined as well as whether the factors identified in the

analytical part of this chapter are drivers of supplier management strategy

and if so, how do the supplier management strategy as determined by these

factors influences performance.

The empirical investigation had been conducted on the procurement de­

partment of a leading, Fortune 500, chemical company (XChem). Specifically,

for reasons explained in detail in the empirical section of this chapter, data

collection focused on equipment purchasing. Severed findings have emerged.

78

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
First, XChem does not have a supplier management strategy as it relates to

factors used in the analytical model. Except monetary volume, other fac­

tors are not systematically considered in strategy formulation. Despite that,

when a multi-factor regression is run, the model is confirmed. Practically

all hypothesized effects are supported. Since some of those factors are well

grounded in economic theory, the ability to replicate results is important.

Indeed, even the effects of transaction knowledge codifiability and transfer­

ability are strongly supported. Given the small data set of 35 observations,

such results are quite encouraging.

The model is also an optimization model, which implies that when the

suggested supplier management strategy is not followed, performance should

suffer. To examine performance related hypotheses two performance mea­

sures, defects and quality, are used. These specific measures are used since

they most aptly capture the essence of suppliers’ performance in the model

and have proven time and again to be a critical, if not the most critical,

factor in determining overall performance (of the buyer in this case). While

the model’s performance is buyer’s revenues, these are not measurable in this

context. Most factors are found to affect performance through interaction

with the number-of-suppliers strategy in the hypothesized direction. The

79

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
one exception is suppliers’ ability to learn. It seems that rather than being

a complement of the strategy it is a substitute. While the effect may be

firm specific, it suggests that further study is required to understand the

interactions of learning and performance in supplier management.

The rest of the chapter is as follows. Section 2 introduces the model.

Section 3 analyzes under two different assumptions about information visibil­

ity. Section 4 discusses codifiability and the results of incorporating it into

the model. Section 5 discusses the empirical study, describes the hypotheses

generated by the analytical model and the results. I conclude in section 6

with a discussion of both the analytical and empirical parts.

3.2 M odeling Framework

This study examines supplier management by a buyer who is interested

in its suppliers investing in intra-firm information systems. To model this

setting I use a principal-agents framework (see figure 2 in appendix A). The

suppliers (agents) compete for projects that arrive stochastically. In each

period, only one supplier can win a project. Unlike previous work (Anton

and Yao, 1989; Wang and Seidmann, 1995), split awards are not used since

80

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the focus is on the selection of the optimal number of suppliers, which can

be any, and is not limited to two as in Anton and Yao. The winner takes

all assumption, however, does not prevent splitting the total volume between

multiple suppliers, which is exactly the case in this study. It crystallizes,

though, the importance of fit between a supplier and a transaction, which

would be masked under split awards. Comparing different types of trans­

actions (e.g. large, complex projects such as building a new plant versus

procuring office supplies) requires that monetary volume would not have en­

dogenous effects, which is the case in split awards. Furthermore, while one

can model splitting an order to two suppliers as two separate orders (of simi­

lar characteristics), it is not common to observe a complex project being split

into two. Therefore, to be able to analyze across transaction characteristics

a winner takes all approach is required.

Not all projects of similar type (say, ordering a spark plug or order­

ing a valve) necessarily require the same type of supplier in terms of quality,

cost and other such considerations. In order to capture that, suppliers are

modeled as distributed along the [0 , 1 ) interval, with their location, p£, rep­

resenting a measure of their overall characteristics. One could consider 0

location to be low cost and low quality supplier where the T ’ location would

81

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
be a high cost, high quality supplier. In essence, the [0,1] interval is a

mapping of the efficient frontier and dominated suppliers are not considered.

Projects that arrive, although of similar type, may have different require­

ments (e.g., high quality, fast delivery, low cost, etc.) modeled as a location,

r, on the [0, l] interval. Projects’ locations are distributed uniformly on the

[0 , 1 ] interval, with the uniform distribution assumed for analytical tractabil-

ity. When a project arrives the buyer observes the project’s location, p, and

chooses the best-fit supplier. In this model fit is measured as the Euclidean

distance, Ai, between a supplier and the project. Thus, only the two closest

suppliers actually compete on a specific project. As we have observed in

a case study and in current work reported in the empirical section of this

study, buyers often limit the final decision to a decision between two suppli­

ers even if the list of possible suppliers and bidders includes more than two.

This screening stage is not modeled here but could be considered the stage in

which the buyer learns of the suppliers’ exact locations and eliminates those

that are dominated by the “n” best suppliers.

Suppliers, however, can influence their fit with projects through in­

vestments. Idiosyncratic, relationship specific investments have the effect of

improving a supplier’s capabilities with regard to the transaction to which

82

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the investments apply. There could be two types of such idiosyncratic invest­

ments. First, transaction specific investments, which are investments that

apply only to a specific type of project. Second, investments which apply

to the relationship in general and therefore are valuable to all transaction

types. Investments in intra-firm information systems are mostly of the sec­

ond type (but information systems may be developed in support of specific

transactions as well). These investments improve supplier performance for

any project and not only for a specific transaction due to better coordination

between firms. In the model developed, we focus on a particular type of

transaction in the landscape. We assume that suppliers may invest, x<, in in­

formation systems and therefore improve their fit, i.e. decrease the distance,

with any project that arrives of this general type. The effect of this invest­

ment is Mi, and is a function of the investment, Xj. By comparing the results

derived for a specific type of transaction across the transaction landscape,

we are able to generate hypotheses about differences in efficient governance

structures that might be expected to be observed in different parts of the

landscape.

The buyer requires a certain level of investment by suppliers in order

for the relationship to achieve a minimum performance level. However, in-

83

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
vestments may or may not be observable to the buyer. Thus, the incentives

given by the buyer may or may not depend on the investment made. This

study analyzes both cases. Interestingly, results for the observable case still

hold under unobservability but are augmented with additional conditions.

All else being equal, the buyer would prefer more suppliers to fewer

since as the number of suppliers increases, the expected project-supplier fit,

E (A '), improves. However, each additional supplier requires a fixed cost, F,

associated with establishing the relationship. Suppliers incur relationship-

specific fixed costs as well, denoted J\. As to be expected, the Buyer has

to compensate suppliers for fi in order to enlist their participation. There­

fore, the Buyer pays F directly and fi indirectly for each additional supplier.

Unless suppliers are guaranteed to at least break even in expectation, they

would not participate and therefore the buyer would not be able to execute

projects. As Wang and Seidmann (1995) observe, the buyer may need sup­

pliers to participate even when they invest less than the required investment

level X i. We call that requirement a "strong participation constraint” since

it is a tighter constraint for the buyer. Alternatively, it may only need those

suppliers investing at least X \ (denoted the "weak participation constraint”).

We analyze both scenarios.

84

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Next, we list all the assumptions, show the time line and supply a

summary of notation used in the development of the modeling framework.

The plan of analysis, i.e. the different combinations of assumptions analyzed,

is then described, followed by the main results with a short discussion. Since

proofs are straightforward and follow the proofs in Appendix B, we omit these

for a cleaner exposition.

3.2.1 A ssu m p tion s

• Suppliers can invest in the relationship, which makes them better

fit for any project arriving.

• Buyer and suppliers are risk neutral and maximize expected profits.

• Common knowledge - suppliers and buyer know all parameters in­

volved: cost functions, locations, technology and fit parameters). They

also know that the others know ad infimum.

• Two types of supplier investments are modeled:

— Contractible

— Non-observable

85

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
• Codifiability - Project location may range between being perfectly ob­

servable to non-observable. I concentrate on the two extreme cases for

clarity of insights.

• Suppliers’ locations: it is assumed that suppliers are chosen to be lo­

cated at equal distances along the [0,1] interval. This assumption is

actually a result that can be proven in the event that the Buyer can

choose which Suppliers to include in the supplier base. This result is

shown in Appendix B for the case of two suppliers.

• Suppliers have identical cost structure and may be one of the following

two:

- Q = q(Xi) + K s f E

- C t = q(Xi) + K

3 .2.2 T im e Line

Figure 3.1: Time Line

Incentive Screening Suppliers —► Project Money


Scheme Invest Realized Transfers

86

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.2.3 Notations

• p:= Location of a project, r is distributed uniformly on [0,1].

• pi := Location of a supplier on the [0,1] interval.

• Ai := |p —Pi\ = ~ 7 rrr^ The distance function of each supplier from the

project. jL. js the mean distance given a uniform distribution of project

location and even spacing of the suppliers along the [0 , lj interval

• Xi := Relationship-specific investment made by the supplier.

Axiom 1 • Qj := Technology factor determining the impact of x, and

tjion Mi with a,- > 0.

• Mi := M (xi) technology function determining the impact of Xi on A,-.

• := Aj x Mi, the effective distance between a supplier and a project

given Xf and yi.

• A ’ := m in (A i), the minimum of the distances between the suppliers

and the project. Supplier i, which achieved this distance is the winner.

• Ti := Transfer or prize the buyer gives the winning supplier.

87

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
• R := i?(A*) the revenue function of the buyer as a function of the

distance between the winning supplier and the project.

• X = Projects arrival mean rate

• N — Number of suppliers

• F = Fixed investment by the buyer

• f = fixed investment by a supplier

• Cost function:

- Ci = q {X i ) + k Va

- C i = q{Xi) + k VE*

• H ;= Profit fi unction of the buyer. Buyer optimizes profits and would

not participate unless profits are not negative.

3.3 A nalysis

We analyze the model under two major assumptions. The first assumes

investments are contractible and therefore, incentive plans and contracts can

be and are written on the investment itself. The second model assumes

88

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
investments are unobservable and contracts cannot written on them. How­

ever, a noisy signal, the revenues resulting from investments, exists and con­

tracts can be written on that signal. Interestingly, results of the contractible

investments model hold under unobservability. Additionally, under unob­

servability error variance matters in determining the number of suppliers to

be used, a result that is completely new to principal agent literature.

I also analyze two types of cost functions for each of the models, one

being concave and the other convex. This is done to examine whether the

nature of the cost function determines the results. Again, all results hold.

Furthermore, we also examine two types of participation constraints, which

again examine sensitivity to modeling assumptions. As before, the model

shows robustness and results are the same.

As summarized below, our analysis has a 2 x 2 x 2 design, which is

composed of two fundamental models, each with a 2 x 2 design. Note th at

while the incentive scheme is different for contractible versus unobservable

investments, it is fundamentally the same but adjusted to take into account

the difference in assumptions. Table 3.1 below summarizes the design.

89

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Version 1: Contractible Version 2: Unobservable
Case 1: Case 2:
Cost Function
C i= q iX J + K yfR C i = 9(X;) + K V A3
Strong Participation:
V1C1S / V2C1S V1C2S / V2C2S
n i(xi= x 0) = o
Weak Participation:
V1C1W / V2CIW V1C2W / V2C2W
ni(x,.= A:1) = o

£o Sd
A IV
Si if Xi>Xi
Incentive Scheme

II
So if Xi<Xi
Distance Function: A* M(JCi+ii)
f»V2 8V3
Table 3.1: Design of Analysis

Note:

1. The technology function, A/*, has an error term in order to create an

unobservable investment environment for version ‘2 of this model.

'2. Participation could be required, i.e., guaranteed, under all investment

levels, whether at Xq or X \. Alternatively, payments to suppliers could

be made that would guarantee participation only if they invest at least

X i > X q. Clearly, the former is a stronger constraint on the structure

of the design of Buyer incentive structures.

3. It turns out that strong or weak participation does not m atter for the

results since forcing the equality sign in the participation and incentive

90

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
compatibility constraints mutes that issue.

In this model we assume the Buyer ensures suppliers participation.

Thus, given the incentive scheme and assuming the Buyer solves the appro­

priate “problem” (detailed below), suppliers invest X \. Suppliers invest at

this level, since the buyer ensures, via T), that it is the suppliers’ preferred

option.

3 .3 .1 V ersion 1: C ontractible In vestm en ts

T he B uyer’s Problem

The buyer wants to maximize profits. It has revenues f?(A*) that are a

function of the distance between the chosen, closest supplier and the arriving

project. Those revenues arrive at a rate of A. However, the buyer incur costs
N
of 52 Ti which are the average transfer costs as a result of the incentive
i=l
scheme T* it uses to incent suppliers to participate and invest in the required

information systems. The buyer also incurs fixed relationship costs of F with

each supplier it chooses. The buyer also has to make sure suppliers partici­

pate and that investing is their preferred action, or incentive compatible.

Therefore, the buyer’s problem is:

91

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Strong Participation (SP): A^ —C (X o) —/ > 0

Incentive Compatibility (IC): —C( Xi ) > A ^ —C ( X o)

Where T is the vector (T0,T i, ...T \r) and N is the number of suppliers

selected to have a relationship with.

Theorem 4 For the above problem and case 1 with the cost function

Ci— q{Xf) + K \f K , the solution is Ti = Si Vi with S0 = ^ and

„ N { f + Cx) ^ L , „ J -A R ^ M (X i)
Si = — The number of suppliers is given by N = . / — ---- .
A y 4(r +

Proof. If we denote Co = C (X 0) and Ct = C (X i) and solve the above

„ . N (f-h C o ) , e W (/ + C,)
constramts we get: So ------ and Si = ------ -------
A A

Given SP, suppliers pay the fixed cost / to have a relationship. Further­

more, given IR, suppliers choose x* = and therefore the buyer pays

Ti = Si for all i.

After substitution of the above solution and Si the buyer’s problem is:

max lib = Ai*(A‘) - N ( f + Ci + F)


N

Substituting C j= q iX J 4 - F n/A and given A* := problem is:

max lib = AJJ(A') - N ( f + q(X i) + F) -


N

92

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
dA ' M (XA
Solving for the F.O.C and denoting -7 7 7 = — - we get the solution:
dJy —lDiY'*

N = (I The second order conditions are as required


V ^ f + z + ^ o) ^
and are easy to check. Q.B.D. ■

Corollary 7 A !=>■ N f Higher demand results in more suppliers used.

Corollary 8 \R&\ !=► N ] As the fit between a supplier and a project

becomes more important (stronger effect on revenues) the buyer will use more

suppliers and thus reduce the average distance.

Corollary 9 X \ f = > N [ (since M( Xi ) J, and q(X 1 ) f ) Higher required

investment implies a smaller supplier base.

Corollary 10 F f or f f ==>• N J, Higher fixed cost on either the buyer or

supplier side results in a smaller supplier base since the buyer ends up paying

both.

Corollary 11 q (X 1 ) t= ^ N I irrespective of changes in Xy as the variable

costs of investments increase the supplier base shrinks. Since the buyer has

l For this analysis to hold, cannot be a function of N. However, that is a reasonable


condition if for example, R = When A approaches 0, R approaches infinity, which
might create a problem. To solve that, R could be modeled as min{R , ^ } . This would
not change the results or analysis except to introduce an upper bar on the number of
suppliers to be chosen, which is the case for other reasons such as supplier pool, strategic
reasons, and coordination costs to name a few. Thus, we are choosing to forgo this
unnecessary complication in modeling and analysis.

93

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
to ensure all suppliers invest X i, it has to take into account the resulting

variable costs.

Theorem 5 When costs are as in case 2, i.e., C i= q { X() + K \ J A^,

N= —y/SXR^M(Xi) + k M 3(Xi)
V 4V 8(F + /+< *(* ,))
Proof. Following the analysis in theorem 1 but using Ci— q ( X {) + K n/A^

as a cost function generates the desired result. Q.E.D. ■

Corollaries 7-11 hold with corollary 12 below as an additional one.

Corollary 12 k f=> N f Stronger effect of A on the variable costs result

in more suppliers since more suppliers reduce A thus reducing variable costs.

Discussion

We can see that most if not all of the results are intuitive. As demand in­

creases, we do expect to see more suppliers used for several reasons. First,

as demand increases, the pie is bigger, and the buyer can afford to use more

suppliers while still being able to incent them to invest in the costly in­

formation system. That investment can only pay off to suppliers if their

expected share of the pie is big enough. Furthermore, considerations outside

the model, such as meeting demand volatility by having multiple suppliers to

94

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ensure availability of production capacity, dictate that as demand increases

more suppliers will be used.

Sim ila rly, as the investment required increases, the supplier base size

is reduced. This reduction allows suppliers to recuperate the associated

investments. An increase in the variable costs associated with supplier’s

investments results in areduction of supplier’s expected profits, thus the buyer

has to reduce the number of suppliers it uses to ensure suppliers invest at the

required level, X%. In the case of an increase in the fixed costs associated

with the relationship on either the buyer’s or the supplier’s side, the buyer

finds that those costs weigh more than the decreasing margined benefits of

having more suppliers and thus uses fewer suppliers.

Corollary 8 is the one that is not seen in the literature and thus may

be less intuitive. It states that as the impact of supplier’s fit with a project

type on revenues is stronger, the buyer will use more suppliers. This result

seems to contradict prevalent wisdom to reduce the number of suppliers as

projects increase in strategic importance (which partially translates to in­

crease in importance of supplier-project fit.) However, the analysis here is

a simple-factor sensitivity analysis with all factors (e.g. codifiability) but

the one examined being held constant. In reality, as strategic importance

95

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
increases, codifiability (see below for extensive discussion and analysis) be­

comes lower and other factors change as well. As shown in the codifiability

section, a reduction in the codifiability level reduces the number of suppliers.

If the codifiability effect is stronger than the project-supplier fit effect, the

number of suppliers will decrease.

Corollary 12 is straightforward. Since more suppliers reduces the average

distance, as that distance has stronger effect on variable costs the number of

suppliers will increase.

As discussed above, we treat these results on two dimensions. While

these are recommendations stemming from an optimization model, we view

these as hypotheses with regard to firms’ strategy. Certainly, firms may not

behave optimally at any given point in time for many reasons. They may be

in the process of learning, they may be exhibiting bounded rationality and

not able to ” compute” optimal behavior in face of complex dynamic world.

Regardless of the reason for such suboptimal behavior, we do expect to see

performance affected in those instances. Through performance we expect

to see the two views of the model meet.

96

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.3.2 V ersion 2: U nobservable In vestm en ts

The assumption about contractibility of investments changes to:

• X i is unobservable. Furthermore, A; = -—^ with E(£i) = 0

and ci has the pdf g and cdf G.

Definition .1 R\ = ECiR ( A(X t)2

Now the incentive scheme cannot depend on x< but has to use the revenues

as a signal. Thus,
S\ if R > Ri

{ Sq i f R < R\

Definition .2 p* = p(x<) = P(Ri > R \) = P ( A f < Ai) =

= P [ M ( x i + ei) < M ( X i)] =

= P [(x< + et) > X i ] = l - G (X t - Xi)

We therefore have pi = p(Xi ) = 1 —G(0) and po = p(Xo)

Under the assumption of unobservability the SP and IC constraints change

to become probabilistic and buyer’s problem is:

m a x n 6 = AP(A*) - £ £ Ti - iV x F
TJ* t=l
2 While using ER(A{Xi) instead of R(E( A(A'i))) is not precise, it does not change the
fundamental nature of the model while allowing analytical tractability.

97

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
(SP) poA^ + (1 —Po)A^ —C(Xo) —/ > 0

(IC) PiA^- + (1 —Pi)A^ —C(Ao) > PoA^ + (1 —Po)Xjfr —C(X0)

T h e o re m 6 Given the buyers problem, and the case 1 cost function,

C i= q ( X{) + K \f K , the solution to the buyer's problem is:


N PoCi + P iC 0
S0 =
(pi - Po )
N f + (1
andi cSi = —
— po)C i + (1 — P \)C q
A (Pi - P o)

y 4 ( F + f + q{Xi))

P ro o f. As in Theorem 1 we solve the SP find. IC conditions and get So and

Si- Given that, we can restate the buyer’s problem as follows:

max lift = A \p\R\ + (1 -pi)Ho] - A[pi7\ + (1 - p i) T 0J - N x F =


N
= A \piRi + (1 - pi)Ro] - N ( F + f + Ci)

Again solving for the F.O.C results in:


i-X [ptMCX,) + (1 - Pi ) M( X q)]
N =
4(F + / + 9(JC0)
• Corrolaries 7-12 of Version 1 Case 1 still hold. In addition due to

uncertainty, the magnitude of X 0 influences N as follows:

C o ro lla ry 13 X 0 f=>- N ]. (since M ( X 0) I) Now the buyer has to take

into account the lower investment since she cannot know which one has been

actually invested.

98

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
C o ro lla ry 14 Since M { X x) < M ( X 0) [ X x > X 0J i f p x ± 0.5 , i.e. E(si) ± 0

[and assuming a distribution in which the mean=median], then we have two

cases:

1. E(Si) > 0 =*■ pi = 1 —G(0) > 0.5

If Var(ei) t [without changing E(ct)] then N f (since C(0) f and

therefore pi |)

Intuition: The LEFT tail of R xs distribution gets bigger (i.e., supplier’s

probability of reaching f?i when investing X x decreases) and therefore

the buyer hedges by having more suppliers (The buyer wants Var(£i) =

0). Thus, what we see here is a hedging strategy, by the buyer, against

the likelihood of getting sub-par results. When the expectation is for

an above par result, then higher variance results in a higher likelihood of

having a sub par result, even as the expectations stays constant. Given

that the buyer is interested not in expectations per se, but in getting

above par (i.e., above iii results), the buyer hedges by increasing the

the number of suppliers, countering the effect of the higher variance.

2. E(si) < 0 ==> pi = 1 —C(0) < 0.5

If Var( cj) f [without changing f?(cj)] then N f (since C(0) J. and

99

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
therefore pi | )

Intuition: The RIGHT tail of R x's distribution gets bigger (i.e., sup­

plier’s probability of reaching R\ when investing A-! increases) and

therefore the buyer can reduce the number of suppliers. In this case,

the buyer can reduce its hedging and use fewer suppliers. By doing

so, the buyer increases the strength of incentives to invest for the re­

maining suppliers. As before, it is driven by the threshold objective

the buyer is interested in.

Theorem 7 When costs are as in case 2, Ci— q i X J -I- K y/&*,

J k M*{ X\ ) ~ y/8AflA[piM (A 1) + (1 - fb)M(Xo)]


V 4v/8(F + / + g(A,))
Proof. Similar analysis to the above will generate that result ■

Corrolaries 7-12 hold in this case.

D iscussion

It is interesting to note that all the results generated under the assumption

of contractibility are replicated under unobservability. This is not the usual

case in the literature. Unobservability and contractibility are often used as

alternate assumptions to generate different if not contradictory results. In

100

R e p ro du ced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
this study, it is the fundamental nature of interaction between buyer and

suppliers that drives results regardless of whether the buyer can or cannot

contract or observe supplier investments. This claim is strengthened by the

fact that using a weak or strong participation constraint does not matter.

Under unobservability we would normally expect such differing requirements

(i.e., strong vs. weak constraints) to matter, even when the differing re­

quirements do not affect results under contractibility. Under information

asymmetry regarding investments, the type of investments required to en­

sure profitability would affect the results. However the exception would be

when the nature of factors examined is more fundamental than the informa­

tion asymmetry involved. Such is exactly the case in this study, where the

factors examined dominate the information assymetry issue.

I also note that corollary 13 is unusual. I have not seen in the litera­

ture any indication about importance of variance of measurement error to

supplier management strategy, and specifically on the number of suppliers

to use. Indeed, the standard assumption, which usually is not examined, is

that E(Si) = 0. Only when not assuming that as the default such an effect

is revealed. W hen we do so, we find that assumptions on E(si) matter!

Different results take place depending if it is positive or negative. In one

101

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
case, when E(si) > 0, an increase in error variance forces the buyer to use

more suppliers to compensate for it. In the other case, when E(ei) < 0,

an increase in error variance allows the buyer to reduce the number of sup­

pliers without losing. This result is achieved even though everyone is risk

neutral in our model. Again, as before, this shows that our model examines

fundamental interactions and can generate results that usually require risk

aversion on one of the sides, buyer or suppliers.

3.4 Codifiability

Knowledge can be more or less codifiable. Codifiability of a transaction

knowledge is the ability to take all aspects of the transaction and the required

knowledge to perform those and list it in written form (Zander and Kogut,

1995). As such, it is a critical factor in B‘2B e-commerce interactions that

are to be done through electronic channels. Unless transaction knowledge

can be codified the transaction cannot be completely executed electronically.

The less codifiable a transaction is, the less are the gains from moving to an

electronic means of transaction. As shown below, codifiability is not just

a requirement for successful electronic transactions but also affects supplier

102

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
management strategy.

In order to make the concept more vivid, one can think about two trans­

actions. The first is a buyer who is interested in buying desks. Naturally, the

buyer can specify the physical requirements and even the engineering specifi­

cations such as materials if so required. Usually, the process of buying desks

in organizations is quite routine and therefore the associated procedures, ac­

counting and otherwise, are quite clear and well specified. Therefore, this

type of transaction is highly, if not completely, codifiable. The second trans­

action is the development of new technology. Almost by definition, the

knowledge associated with this transaction can hardly be specified, if at all.

At best, and even that may be questionable, operating specifications can be

spelled out, and maybe cost and time for development. Associated processes

are not routine and may or may not be well specified or even known. Even if

the buyer or the supplier have knowledge pertaining to this new technology, it

mostly cannot be written and communicated easily, but is embedded in peo­

ple, skills, and organizational capabilities, processes, and culture. Therefore,

such a transaction is highly uncodifiable, if at all.

In this study’s model, one could think of the location of the project as

more or less accurately known . In the previous sections the project location

103

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
was known without any error, which translates to perfect codifiability. The

buyer can figure out and explain the specifications of the project without any

error.

On the other hand, we think about a project as highly uncodifiable if it

would result in the inability of the engineers to specify requirements. That

leads to significant difficulty or impossibility of the procurement department

to match a supplier with the project without significant, informal interactions

with prospective suppliers. If the project is completely uncodifiable, it could

be translated in our model to a project with an error that masks the realiza­

tion of the project location completely (below I explain how to construct tin

error term to fit the model), thus ex post the buyer is facing a project that

is distributed uniformly on the [0,1] interval. In this case, it is obvious that

the optimal number of suppliers is one, with that supplier located precisely

in the middle of the [0,1] interval. The simple reason is that more suppliers

are not going to improve the expected revenues since the expected project

fit with suppliers (the expected A in the above model) remains constant.

That happens since regardless of the project, the optimal selection criterion

is to select the middle supplier (located at 0.5). However, more suppliers

result in higher costs due to the fixed costs associated with establishing the

104

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
relationship. One could think of those fixed costs as including search costs

as well.

Formally, we model the error term representing codifiability as follows:

r —* r + e £~U[—b, +a]3, where a + b = c < 1

b = mi n{ r, c/ 2}

a = m in{ 1 —r, c/2}

This modeling ensures that boundary effects are not present since the

error ’’bounces” from the edge and is always of the same length regardless of

where the project is located4. Note that since the buyer makes its decision

ex-ante and the error exists ex-post, it cannot use a point location but rather

a whole interval with length equal to error length.

Following the above reasoning, if the error term results in a project loca­

tion that is distributed uniformly on half an interval, the optimal strategy is

to have 2 suppliers. That ensures the buyer does not have suppliers between

3Error term modeling: Assume an error of length I. A project location is then dis­
tributed uniformly over a distance of I. A project that is too close to the extremes of the
[0,1] interval still gets the same distribution but it is not symmetric around its location
but takes into account the "border'’.
Example: if the error term is 0.5 than if a project falls between [0.25,0.75] we have no
problem. If the project is realized at 0.1 than the buyer (and supplier) can only know it
is distributed uniformly between [0,0.5]. This renders all projects that fall in the interval
[0,0.25] as same.
4An alternative model would have used a circle instead of a line, eliminating the problem
of boundary effects and simplifying the modeling. That would not have changed results
in any fundamental manner.

105

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
which it cannot differentiate. If it were to choose more, the expected ex-post

distance would not decrease but the fixed costs associated with selecting more

supplier would increase. Similarly with an error of j , the optimal solution

is 3 suppliers.

Codifiability in effect puts a limit on the number of suppliers that can be

chosen (essentially by flattening the revenue curve after the relevant number

of suppliers is reached). If the optimal number is below that limit, then

codifiability doesn’t come into play in that decision. However, if the opti­

mal number is above the limit, codifiability truncates it at the appropriate

number.

This result has an intuitive appeal since we would expect the number of

suppliers to be affected by the level of codifiability and in the same direction

as found here. In particular, intuitively it seems clear that the less codifiable

a project is, the less you want to go through the process of interacting with

a larger number of suppliers to explain the details of the project.

106

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.5 T he Empirical Study

In order to test the above results or hypotheses, data was collected from a

leading, Fortune 500 company, which I will call XChem. The company is

a leader in the chemical industry and purchases about $15 billion worth of

products from its suppliers. The bulk of those purchases is done through

its corporate headquarters purchasing department but some of it is done

through local divisions. For severed reasons we have chosen to concentrate

on the central purchasing department. First, corporate procurement is sup­

posed to have a more structured supplier management strategy compared to

local procurement departments. Second, Local divisions usually purchase as

needed and are highly constrained due to low volumes and geographical and

information limitations.

Within the corporate procurement the focus is on the equipment pur­

chasing department. The other part of corporate procurement, the MRO

department has much less variability in its purchases due to the inherent

nature of the products it procures. Specifically, the MRO department pur­

chases products that are highly codifiable and mostly are described either

by catalogue number or can be completely and easily specified (e.g. office

supplies). Since in the context of this work, I am first and foremost inter-

107

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ested in examining codifiability as a critical factor in supplier management

strategy, the absence of variance on it would prevent such examination.

Empirical research on transaction cost economics (TCE) tends to focus on

an industry and often on one firm. Many of the variables measured change in

definition dramatically from firm to firm. Furthermore, firm specific factors,

such as historical practices tend to change results strongly between firms and

more so between industries. Thus, while firm specific work suffers from the

potential limitation of insufficient generality, it allows for better understand­

ing of the factors and models examined and is not without precedent. Even

when done at the industry level, previous TCE related research has concen­

trated on highly concentrated industries such as the U.S. automobile or aero

space industry. Examples are Monteverde and Teece (1982) who used Ford

and GM only, Masten (1984) for the U.S. auto industry, Masten (1989) in the

aerospace industry. Novak and Eppinger (2001) examined eight auto firms

in the global industry but concentrated on the luxury-performance market

and on eight vehicles in total. As Novak and Eppinger indicate by quot­

ing Joksow, measuring many of TCE variables, such as asset specificity, or

performance, is very difficult, especially when trying to compare across firms

and industries.

108

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
While there are several studies examining TCE, none have examined an

analytical model that draws on TCE and none have looked into codifiabil­

ity. Research using codifiability has a construct is new, sparse, and never

been done in the context of supplier management. Examples are Kogut and

Zander (1992), Szulanski (1996) and Inkpen and Dinur (1998). Further­

more, TCE studies (e.g., Joksow, 1987, Walker and Weber, 1987, Helper and

Levine 1992)) have concentrated on examining either long-term relationship

or make versus buy decisions (Monteverde and Teece, 1982;Novak and Ep­

pinger, 2001). This study’s broader question of optimal number of suppliers

combined with the complexity of measuring codifiability and transferability

of transaction knowledge between separate firms calls for concentrating on

one firm. Results, therefore, would serve to show future research as well as

to provide insightson underlying theory.

3.5.1 H yp oth eses

The model above allows us to generate severed hypotheses about how trans­

action attributes affect suppliers management strategy and resulting perfor-

memce. In hypotheses H1-H6 the dependent variable is number of suppliers.

H7 takes into account the optimization nature of the model eind is therefore

109

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
about performance as a result of following the recommended strategy as put

forth by the model and hypotheses H1-H6. The hypotheses are discussed

separately to clarify the logic, theory, and model behind each factor but this

is not to suggest any factor may be affecting results by itself. Rather, it is the

combination of factors that affects the dependent variable (Number of Sup­

pliers or Performance), with each factor working in the direction suggested

by the relevant hypothesis.

A unique contribution of this study to economic and management liter­

ature discussing strategy regarding supplier management is the concept of

codifiability. The model suggests that the more codifiable an item is, the

easier it is to use more suppliers and the gains from it are higher. During

the initial interviewing phase a case study about water tanks procurement

helped highlight the codifiability idea behind hypothesis 1. In the case of

water tanks, XChem has split the procurement continuum into three regions.

The two extremes had either low specifications (standard tanks) or high spec­

ifications (customized tanks with well understood final requirements) and as

a result were relatively codifiable. The ” middle region” had products that

were of uncertain and unclear nature and had to be tailored as the develop­

ment occurred. Thus, the middle region is relatively uncodifiable. Indeed,

110

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
XChem’s strategy is to use one supplier per geographical region in the middle

region while using the regular multi supplier strategy in the other two. This

strategy is as predicted in my analysis.

However, codifiability by itself is not enough to allow for transfer of trans­

action knowledge from buyer to supplier (Inkpen and Dinur, 1998). For suc­

cessful, efficient, frictionless transfer to occur, the receiving unit (suppliers in

this context) should be able to learn it easily ( Szulanski, 1998; Inkpen and

Dinur, 1998). Therefore, I define transferability as the combination of trans­

action codifiability and suppliers’ learning ability of the specific transaction.

Transferability is increasing in both codifiability and specific learning ability.

Measuring codifiability or transferability of knowledge is not an easy task.

Since, has been discussed, knowledge is embedded in people, processes, and

culture among others, each transaction, even in the same organization, may

have very different set of measures that are applicable. Measuring the actual

number and size of manuals pertaining to a specific transaction may not

reflect codifiability, because some transaction would require only few pages

for complete codification (e.g. desks), while others may require thousands of

pages and still may not be completely codified (e.g. building a new plant.)

The newness and how often the transaction is being executed would greatly

111

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
affect the number and size of manuals associated with it. At the same time,

the inherent level of codifiability may be higher or lower but not reflected

by the number and size of manuals. Therefore, I have chosen to ask the

buyers in charge of a transaction about its level of codifiability. Since they

intimately know the transaction, they know exactly how difficult it is to

codify it and can assess all the intangibles that affect codifiability, and be

less effected (than the actual manuals) by its newness and frequency.

The hypotheses regarding codifiability are therefore:

HI: Higher transferability will results in more suppliers.

Hlb: Higher codifiability will result in more suppliers.

Hlc: Higher learning ability will result in more suppliers.

The analytical model suggests that when investments required to estab­

lish a relationship (either F or fi] go up, the number of suppliers used should

become lower. While the model cannot examine the specificity of investment

as a factor5, it is specific (to buyer and commodity combined) investments

that should make a difference. Specific investments are an important part of

TCE, which postulates a similar direction. However, TCE mainly empha­

5This limitation is due to the single buyer model used. However, given that the only
revenues that may cover such an investment for suppliers are derived only from this buyer,
it is akin to modeling that investment as a specific one.

112

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
sizes the hold-up problem resulting from specific investments. As a result,

an argument could be made that the way for a buyer to countereffect the

hold-up problem is to increase the number of suppliers, thus putting more

competitive pressures. This study utilizes a different logic. A buyer trims

down its supplier base in order to incent remaining suppliers to invest in the

relationship. Therefore, hypothesis 2 is as follows:

H2a: Higher specific investments will result in fewer suppliers.

Buyers often make investments in aligning suppliers’ practices to

their own practices and invests in training of suppliers’ personnel. These are

also specific investments and thus the logic above holds.

H2b: Higher investments in practices alignment will result in fewer sup­

pliers.

H2c: Higher investment in training will result in fewer suppliers.

After a relationship has been established firms have to maintain it. The

costs associated with doing so can be due to required investments in in­

frastructure, continuing training, and realignment of processes as firms change.

While not paid up-front, these costs axe part of the investments in a rela­

tionship modeled as F and /*. Therefore, the logic of hypothesis 2 holds.

H3: On-going costs will be negatively correlated with the number of

113

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
suppliers.

The model shows that as volume increase more suppliers can and should

be used, all else being equal. While the revenue associated with the commodi­

ties purchased cannot be measured, the actual annual transaction monetary

volume data was collected. It is reasonable to assume that on average, more

expensive inputs (i.e. higher annual transaction monetary volume) are part

of products that result in higher revenues. If this relationship holds than we

have the following hypothesis:

H 4: Monetary volume for a given transaction will be positively correlated

with more suppliers.

Related to investment specificity is the ability to substitute a supplier

and the level of the supplier uniqueness. Substituting a supplier can be

difficult due to a lack of substitutes or because of negative quality and cost

implications. While not necessarily a driver of supplier management strat­

egy, it should be correlated with the number of suppliers used. Lack of

substitutability may constrain firms from having more suppliers or could be

a result of a close relationship with one or few suppliers. Similarly, sup­

plier’s uniqueness should be correlated with the number of suppliers. Higher

uniqueness would either drive a firm to stick with one supplier or could result

114

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
from having a close relationship with a supplier.

It is important to note that uniqueness and substitutability do not mea­

sure the same latent attribute, and should not be colinear. A supplier may be

unique in offering some specialized equipment, but substituting it by another

supplier may not result in significant consequences. Similarly, a supplier may

be not unique, but hardly substitutable since the buyer had tied itself to this

specific supplier by aligning processes and making specific investments on its

side.

H 5: Substitutability will be positively correlated with the number of

suppliers used.

H6: Uniqueness will be negatively correlated with the number of suppli­

ers used.

Finally, the model is an optimization model and thus implies that fol­

lowing the recommended/hypothesized strategy should lead to higher per­

formance. Specifically, the model suggests that this performance should

be along dimensions associated with a better fit between a supplier and a

project. While the overall objective is higher profits, this study cannot ex­

amine it since there is no direct link between commodities purchased and

revenues generated from products using these commodities as inputs. How-

115

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ever, a better fit should translate to higher quality, lower defects, and better

on-time delivery, for all of which data had been collected.

H7a: When hypotheses 1-4 are being supported, higher quality results.

I will use H7al to H7a4 to indicate how H7a relates to each hypothesis.

H7b: When hypotheses 1-4 are being supported, fewer defects result. I

will use H7bl to H7b4 to indicate how H7b relates to each hypothesis.

H7c: When hypotheses 1-4 are being supported, better on-time delivery

performance results. I will use H7cl to H7c4 to indicate how H7c relates to

each hypothesis.

To further corroborate the above, the survey asks about production time

compared to other supplier of the same commodity and also compared to

production time of comparable commodities. The level of suppliers’ im­

provement (for a specific commodity) and performance compared to XChem

goals had been collected as well. However, the link between these perfor­

mance measures and the recommended strategy is not straightforward or

necessarily implied by the model and thus hypotheses about that link are

not constructed.

116

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
D ata C ollection

Our d ata collection took place in three stages. The first stage included in­

terviews with the purchasing director, the managers of equipment and MRO

departments, and product managers. In these interviews severed objec­

tives were accomplished. First, better understanding of XChem’s specific

processes and business practices was achieved. Second, the underlying ana­

lytical model was found to apply to XChem’s way of doing business in that

XChem uses a pre-qualified list of suppliers of whom they may require rela­

tionship enhancing investments. Third, data sources were identified. How­

ever, due to idiosyncrasies in data management processes at XChem, we were

able to retrieve only annual purchasing volume per supplier and commodity6.

To supplement this data a questionnaire was designed. XChem’s exec­

utives find managers helped us in building the questionnaire and fine tun­

ing questions to their firm specific vocabulary. After the questionnaire was

deemed satisfactory we pilot tested it with them. Four commodities were

chosen as representatives of different commodity types that may exist in their

purchasing mix. The questionnaire was administrated to the executive in

charge of equipment and a few product managers.

6In XChem terminology, they call products they purchase commodities.

117

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
As we analyzed the results of the pilot, it was clear that they consider

the cost/price for one of the commodities was well below par. It was also

clear that this commodity in questions should have many suppliers on the

authorized supplier list but had only a few. This discrepancy held resulted

in subpar cost/price as compared to market price and the price they believed

they should face. The one factor that seemed odd was the fact that the

commodity was considered to be highly codifiable by the firm but suppliers

were having difficult time learning to produce it to acceptable levels. The

buyer had or could easily provide manuals, specifications lists, requirement

lists, etc. and despite this its purchasing managers knew suppliers were

having difficulty learning the commodity. The reason became clear imme­

diately in a follow up interview with the equipment department manager

who attributed it to the safety requirements for that commodity. Given the

buyer’s emphasis on safety, those requirements are extensive and complicated

to learn. Thus, the solution was clear, to simplify and clarify the safety re­

quirement, without lowering standards in order to make it feasible to train

suppliers easily and cheaply. Embarking on such strategy would allow the

buyer to move from a limited relatively small supplier pool to a much larger

one and would result in competitive prices.

118

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
This shows not only the importance of codifiability, but also that codifia­

bility includes multiple dimensions. It first must encompass the transaction

as a whole, and not just the product or commodity by itself. While the

product may be highly codifiable, parts of the associated transaction may be

less so, thus lowering overall codifiability. In addition, codifiability includes

not just the ability to supply manuals and such, but also the ability of the

’’other side” to understand and utilize those efficiently.

After fin alizin g the questionnaire, we conducted it via the web. The

questionnaire was put online on a secure web site. As product managers

filled and submitted it, the data was automatically downloaded to a database.

Once the process started, it took 10 days to finish. Although it is extremely

short time for such a process, we lost two commodities since one of the

managers left the division in the middle of the process and could not complete

it.

During the analysis it was found that few questions were not understood

in the way intended. Those questions were reworded and discussed with

XChem’s executives and managers who were responsible for answering them.

The questions that were misunderstood were about investments in inter-firm

systems, either by suppliers or XChem. The product managers interpreted

119

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the question as pertaining to procurement systems only and not to all sys­

tems. These questions were re-administered and the data were then final­

ized. The discussions that took place during this stage helped clarify and

contexualize the results and conclusions derived from the study.

3.5.2 T h e D a ta

The resulting data has 94 data points on the commodity-supplier unit of

analysis and 36 on the commodity unit of analysis. The reason for the

two types of unit of analysis is that some variables in the study pertain

only to the commodity and are by definition the same for all suppliers of a

given commodity while other variables may have different scores for different

suppliers of the same commodity. One commodity observation, and therefore

all of its associated commodity-supplier observations, was dropped off. This

commodity was an outlier on the general codifiability scale, but for reasons

exogenous to the transaction and therefore did not represent the study well.

The resulting data set had 35 commodity observations and 90 commodity-

supplier observations.

Table 1 below provides summary statistics for all variables based on the

35 commodity observations. Those variables that are on the commoditv-

120

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
supplier scale would not have observable differences in mean and standard

deviation because only in very few instances did XChem’s buyers rank sup­

pliers differently when supplying the same commodity. Several observations

can be made on the data.

The first is th at performance measures were truncated at a score of 6

(out of 7), except defects, which was not truncated above but truncated

below a t 2, indicating that XChem buyers are never ” fully satisfied” with

the performance the get from their suppliers. However, this is a common

result with Likert scale based questionnaires and does not indicate anything

of real importance.

The second observation is that general codifiability is ranked at 4-7 (7

being complete codifiability), while requirement and engineering codifiabil­

ity were ranked between 1 or 2 (correspondingly) to 7, with 7 being com­

plete. This indicated that the general measure of codifiability does not

capture the actual codifiability and its answers are more biased by subjec­

tive perceptions. Requirement and engineering based questions directed the

respondents towards more observable and explicit measures and thus were

less biased. Supporting that were interviews with the managers and buyers

in XChem’s equipment procurement area who believed they "always know”

121

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the commodities they buy. Thus, general codifiability was not used in the

analysis.

Another observation is that XChem hardly make any investments in the

relationship. The scores for that measure ranged between 1 to 3, indicating

zero or very low investments. The complete lack of variation rendered this

variable meaningless to analyze and the XChem’s investments variable was

therefore dropped.

XChem tend to use 3 or fewer suppliers. While the mean (2.85) and

standard deviation (1.86) indicate it, examining the raw data makes it vivid.

Out of 35 observations, in seven cases XChem uses more than 5 suppliers, in

one case it uses 5 suppliers, in two cases it uses 4, and the rest have 3 or fewer

suppliers. It also highlights that XChem either uses 3 or fewer suppliers (few

in its language) or more than 5 (many in its language), indicating a tendency

for extreme strategies. As the next section discusses, it is indeed XChem

approach to its supplier management.

122

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Variable Mean Std Minimum Maximum
Quality 4.86 1.11 1 6
Defects 2.68 1.28 1 5
Number1 2.86 1.86 1 6
Cod 6.03 0.86 7
EngCod 5.97 1.58 7
ReqCod 6.28 1.38 1 7
Learning 5.11 2.19 1 7
Screening 3.4 1.19
ProdUnique 3.83 1.65 1 7
OrgUnique 3.77 1.61 1 7
MgmtUnique 4.31 1.49 7
GenSub 4.05 1.92 1 7
MnfqrSub 4.37 2.00 1 7
Qsub 4.57 2.06 1 7
CostSub 4.23 1.97 1 7
Practices 4.25 1.38 1 6
Training 4.26 1.38 1 6
Eqlnvest 4.08 1.56 1 7
TotalAnnualSpend2 6.35 1.49 0.1 35
EqUniqlnvst 1.51 1.27 1 6
DuPEqUniqlnvst 1.06 0.34 1 3
OnGoingCosts 2.06 1.88 1 7

Table 3.2: Descriptive Statistics

• Represents a transaction with a given supplier for a given commodity.

Measured in millions of US dollars.

• Number was ranked on a 1-6 scale with 1-5 being the actualy number

of suppliers used and 6 representing more than 5 suppliers.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.5.3 P art I: T h e C ase o f th e M issin g S trategy

The correlation table shown below, together with knowledge of XChem’s

procurement gained during the interviews, indicate that XChem does not

have a formal supplier management strategy that links the variables this

study measured and the number of suppliers they use. As can be seen,

only two variables have a significant correlation. TotalAnnualSpend has a

0.4 correlation with BinNum at a p-value of 0.017. Learning, as our model

predicts, has a 0.326 correlation at a p-value of 0.056. However, XChem, at

the time of the study, was not aware of learning or codifiability as pertaining

to its supplier management strategy. Learning operated as a constraint

and forced XChem to limit the number of supplier it used but not as a pre­

determined strategy. The total annual spend on a commodity, when high

enough, allowed XChem to increase the number of suppliers it was using.

Furthe more, as shown in the previous section, XChem either uses few

(less than 3) or many (more than 5) suppliers. Such a behavior indicate

that only a global strategy exists with regard to supplier management and

that strategy is not dependent on quantifiable parameters.

Discussions with XChem procurement executives confirmed that while

XChem does have a general supplier management strategy, they do not have

124

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
a systematic approach to segmenting its strategy per the factors considered

in this study. As one executive stated: ”We have a strategy in that we

make decisions on how many suppliers we should use for a commodity, but

certainly do not have any strategy that is based on quantitative analysis of

data.”

Note: In the corrleation tables below correlations are calculated on stan­

dardized variables, except for BinNum, which is binary.

* = p<0.1 ** = p<0.05 *** = p<0.01

1. P=0.0161 2. p=0.056 3. p=0.1007 4. p=0.0173 5. p=0.0169

125

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
QualityPerf DefectsPerf BinNum

QualityPerf 1 0_4**i -0.26

DefectsPerf 0.4** 1 -0.26

BinNum -0.26 -0.26 1

AvgCod 0.18 0.06 0.01

MinCod 0.13 0.05 -0.02

Learning -0.34 -0.11 0.33*2

Screening o.l5 0.28 -0.16

AvgUnique 0.17 0.00 -0.25

MinUnique 0.1 -0.12 -0.25

AvgSub 0.26 0.24 -0.05

MinSub 0.07 0.05 0.11

Practices 0.04 0.10 0.07

Training 0.04 0.10 0.07

Eqlnvst 0.31* -0.21 -0.283

TotalAnnualSpend 0.009 -0.17 0.40**'1

EqUniqlnvst 0.01 0.08 0.09

OnGoingCost 0.13 0.03 -0.05

Table 3.3: Correlations Tablel

126

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
AvgCod MinCod Learning Screening

QualityPerf 0.19 0.13 -0.34** 0.15

DefectsPerf 0.06 0.05 -0.11 0.28

BinNum 0.01 -0.02 0.32*2 -0.16

AvgCod 1 0.91*** -0.09 0.26

MinCod 0.91*** 1 -0.04 0.29**

Learning -0.09 -0.04 1 0.00

Screening 0.26 0.29* 0.00 1

AvgUnique -0.08 -0.11 -0.31** -0.22

MinUnique -0.19 -0.22 -0.30** -0.35**

AvgSub 0.04 0.04 -0.05 0.68***

MinSub 0.09 0.16 0.13 0.58**

Practices 0.24 0.20 0.14 0.24

Training 0.24 0.20 0.14 0.24

Eqlnvst -0.12 -0.18 -0.37** -0.33**

TotalAnnualSpend -0.28* -0.32* 0.21 -0.04

EqUniqlnvst 0.03 0.06 0.04 -0.31*

OnGoingCost -0.15 -0.11 0.03 -0.02

Table 3.4: Correlations Table2

127

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
AvgUnique MinUnique AvgSub MinSub

QualityPerf 0.17 0.11 0.26 0.07

DefectsPerf 0.00 -0.13 0.24 0.05

BinNum -0.25 -0.25 -0.05 0.11

AvgCod -0.08 -0.19 0.04 0.08

MinCod -0.11 -0.22 0.05 0.16

Learning -0.31* -0.30* -0.05 0.12

Screening -0.21 -0.35** 0.68*** 0.56***

AvgUnique 1 0.93*** -0.50*** -0.51

*
##
b\
0.93*** 1 -0.61***

-" I
MinUnique

O
I
AvgSub -0.50*** -0.61*** 1 0.87***

MinSub -0.51*** -0.57*** 0.87*** 1

Practices 0.00 -0.05 -0.01 -0.11

Training 0.24 -0.05 -0.01 -0.11

Eqlnvst 0.80*** 0.79*** 0.50*** -0.64***

TotalAnnualSpend -0.03 0.03 -0.08 -0.10

EqUniqlnvst -0.31* 0.43*** 0.56*** -0.46***

OnGoingCost -0.02 0.40**6 0.31* -0.39**

Table 3.5: Correlations Table3

128

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Practices Training Eqlnvst

QualityPerf 0.04 0.04 0.31*

DefectsPerf 0.10 0.10 0.20

BinNum 0.07 0.07 -0.283

AvgCod 0.24 0.24 -0.12

MinCod 0.20 0.20 -0.19

Learning 0.14 0.14 -0.37**

Screening 0.24 0.24 -0.34**

AvgUnique 0.00 0.01 0.80***

MinUnique -0.04 -0.05 0.79***

AvgSub -0.01 -0.01 -0.50***

MinSub -0.11 -0.10 -0.64***

Practices 1 -0.01

Training ^*** 1 -0.01

Eqlnvst -0.01 -0.01 1

TotalAnnualSpend 0.33** 0.33** -0.03

EqUniqlnvst 0.07 0.07 0.36**

OnGoingCost 0.44*** 0.44*** 0.34**

Table 3.6: Correlations Table4

129

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
TotalAnnualSpend EqUniqlnvst OnGoingCost

QualityPerf 0.01 0.01 0.13

DefectsPerf -0.18 0.08 0.03

BinNum 0.40** 0.09 -0.05

AvgCod -0.28* 0.03 -0.15

MinCod -0.32* 0.06 -0.11

Learning -0.37** 0.04 0.03

Screening -0.33 -0.31** -0.02

AvgUnique -0.02 0.45*** 0.35**

MinUnique 0.03 0.43*** 0.40**

*—**
CO
AvgSub -0.08 -0.56*** oi

MinSub -0.10 -0.46*** -0.39**

Practices 0.33** 0.07 0.44***

Training 0.33** 0.07 0.44***

Eqlnvst -0.03 0.36** 0.40**

TotalAnnualS pend 1 0.09 0.53***

EqUniqlnvst 0.09 1 0.44***

OnGoingCost 0.53*** 0.44*** 1

Table 3.7: Correlations Table5

130

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
I consider this lack of formulated strategy as making the test of the model

even more difficult and conservative. When a firm has a strategy based on

factors studied, finding a relationship between the factors and the measure

of strategy (in this case, the number of suppliers) is not surprising and may

not teach us much. However, when despite a lack of strategy, a relationship

between a factor and the number of suppliers used is found, it indicates a

strong support for the underlying model. Therefore, the relationship between

BinNum find Learning indicates a strong support to the idea of codifiability

and transferability as critical factors in supplier management. Similarly,

the correlation between TotalAnnualSpend and BinNum shows that XChem

responds strongly to what in the analytical model was called R . In this case,

R works as an enabler. The bigger the pie, the more suppliers XChem can

use without losing its power over the supplier.

However, even here the relationship is not straightforward. Prom the

scatter plot below it seems that low monetary volume does not carry any

recognizable strategy with regard to the number of suppliers used, while

relatively high monetary volume ($15 million and above) does entail using

more suppliers. It actually follows the "No Strategy” idea discussed above.

131

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Figure 3.2: Number o f Suppliers vs. Annual Monetary Volume

Number 'Annual Monetary Volume

2 6

s 0
£ 4
O „
-t ro c
Num ber

1 , -■, - _
o

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
Annual Monatrary Volume
in $ millions

When the annual monetary volume is low, the lack of strategy shows. When

the volume is high, XChem reacts to it by spreading it over many suppliers,

because it can do so.

The framework and theory do not assume that any one factor would solely

or strongly influence the strategy, but some influence is expected. As the

regression results in the sections below show, XChem does respond to the

collection of forces resulting from the combined effect of multiple factors.

However, if XChem had a strategy or would respond to any variable in a

systematic way, then some significant correlation (between that factor and

132

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
number-of-suppliers alone), even if a low one, should have been present. The

reason for the lack of such one-to-one correlation is as the title suggests:

XChem does not have any systematic strategy with regard to the number of

suppliers it uses.

The premise of the framework is that a firm that does not follow the

model-based recommendations would suffer in its performance. The model

uses profits to measure performance. However, firms’ complex processes

usually prevent linking procurement of specific items to profits generated by

products using those items. Thus, performance is best measured through

quality and related measures. I have collected survey data both on quality (of

supplier for a given commodity) and on defects, as well as other performance

related measures (e.g. on-time delivery). Defects is the better measure to

use since it has higher variance (than quality). Furthermore, the data is

managers’ evaluations of suppliers. In the case of defects those evaluations

are based on a measurable (even if not systematically tracked) and relatively

clear signal. Furthermore, in the model, profits are a result of a fit between

the chosen supplier and the transaction. As the fit improves, so do profits’.

The best way to capture fit between a supplier and the transaction is the

’ in the stochastic version, profits are stochastically improving with fit.

133

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
quality and number of defects. Thus, defects and quality capture the essence

of the model better than any indirect measure of performance such as profits,

which might be affected by numerous other factors.

Three main observations are gained in the study of performance measures.

First, gained from discussion with the executive in charge of equipment pro­

curement, is that XChem performs worse than what he would have expected.

Secondly, the factors hypothesized do correlate with performance, mostly in

the hypothesized direction. Thirdly, learning and codifiability are important

and their interaction affects performance as would be expected but the inter­

action with the number of suppliers as it affects performance is surprisingly

opposite to the hypothesis. This result warrants a further study to examine

whether it is a result of XChem’s lack of strategy, an arbitrary effect due to

the nature of the data and study, or a fundamental relationship.

The rest of this chapter is as follows. First each hypothesis is examined

separately and scatter plots are provided to show the lack of one-to-one

relationship between factors and the number of suppliers. Then I present

regression results for the number of suppliers and discuss them. Lastly, I

examine performance related results and discuss these.

134

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3 .5 .4 P art II: R egression R esu lts

Num ber o f Suppliers

It is evident that despite the lack of formal strategy by XChem with regard to

the variables discussed in this study, these same variables do affect its choice

of supplier base size as can be seen in Model 1 below. The coefficients, even

if not always significant due to the size of the data set, are almost always in

the right direction. Thus, the results suggest that the model is capturing

important factors and correctly analyzes these factors’ influence on supplier

management strategy .

M odel 1: M ain Effects The regression was run on the ’’small” data set,

which is limited to the 35 commodity based data points. Since the number

of suppliers is a commodity-based measure, the commodity based data set is

the one to use.

The first take from the regression results is that most of the variables have

the correct sign, even if significance, probably due to data set size, exists only

for TotalAnnualSpend and Learning. Such results serve both to show that

the empirical study concurs with previous research, which supports the study,

and to support the analytical framework as a basis for supplier management

135

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
analysis.

The main innovation of the framework in terms of factors that may predict

strategy and performance is the idea of transaction knowledge transferability

and its parts, codifiability and learning. The correlation table supported

learning as a significant factor and at the right direction, i.e. higher learning

on the supplier side is positively correlated with more suppliers used. The

regression results support this as well, even though learning is only bordering

on significance at a p-value of 0.102. Given the size of the data set, it

is not surprising to see significance disappear when more factors are used.

Noticeably, codifiability is not significant, even if it is in the right direction.

The more important role of learning as compared to codifiability is a direct

result of XChem’s knowledge of its own needs.

As with the correlation results, TotalAnnualSpend is found to be posi­

tively correlated with BinNum and significant at the 0.05 level. As with

Learning the significance level is reduced from the correlation analysis to the

multi-factor regression. It is therefore clear that H4 is supported.

An interesting pattern appears with regard to expenses and investments

associated with a transaction. Both types of investments measures, which

axe either supplier investments in equipment that is unique to the commod-

136

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ity but not to XChem (Eqlnvst) and investments that are unique to both

commodity and XChem (EqUniqlnvst) have a positive correlation with the

number of suppliers used. Such a finding contradicts the usual findings and

expected results. However, the correlation table show Eqlnvst to be neg­

atively correlated with BinNum with a p-value of 0.1. Furthermore, the

correlation between the two investments measurers and measures of unique­

ness and substitutability goes in the right direction, negative for the former

and positive for the later. It is therefore not clear what drives the regression

results in this case and further examination is required. Discussion with

XChem executives suggests that suppliers are not incented to make those

investments but do them on a need to basis. These investments are either

required or not. If they are a necessity to working with XChem on a spe­

cific transaction, in the case of EqUniqlnvst, and the supplier finds them

worthwhile to make, those investments are made. However, XChem does

not change its strategy because such an investments had been made.

At the same time, a measure of transaction costs, OnGoingCosts, shows

up in the right direction as negative with a p-value of 0.06. Therefore, as

transaction costs go up, XChem uses fewer suppliers. The analytical model

concurred with TCE that this should be the effect and this result, therefore,

137

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Parameter Estimate p-value
Intercept -1.98 0.028
MinCod 0.40 0.55
Learning 1.66 0.102
Screening -1.47 0.096

cq
r—
MinUnique 0.28

1
4
MinSub *2.07 0.16
Eqlnvst 2.1 0.3
TotalAnnualS pend 4.9 0.04
EqUniqlnvst *2.37 0.17
OnGoingCosts -4. *20 0.06

Table 3.8: Number of Suppliers: Main Effects

supports the model’s applicability.

M odel 2: H6 revisited Uniqueness shows in the right direction and sig­

nificant both in the main effects model, which includes Screening and Spend,

or in an interaction model with spend alone. It is interesting to note that

average uniqueness does not hold as well in the model and has a lower co­

efficient and is at a lower significance level, which suggests that the idea of

uniqueness as a constraint has some validity. Thus, H6 is supported with

this model.

138

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Parameter Model i Model ii Model iii
-1.21 -0.34 -1.13
Intercept
(0.013) (0.58) (0.014)
-0.89 -0.67
Screening -
(0.11) (0.199)
-1.03 -1.49
MinUnique -
(0.041) (0.065)
-0.74
AvgUnique - -
(0.083)
1.03 2.82 0.92
TotalAnnualSpend
(0.03) (0.035) (0.04)
-2.53
MinUnique*Total - -
(0.08)

Table 3.9: Number of Suppliers: Uniqueness

A lternative Explanations

One alternative explanation, to replace the codifiability story, that could be

raised is moral hazard. It could be argued that a firm faces the possibility

of knowledge being copied by its suppliers and transferred to other buyers.

Indeed, codified knowledge is more easily copied and learned by suppliers and

competitors alike (Nonaka, ****). As Anton and Yao (***) observe, it may

be beneficial to a firm to hold back information and suffer in performance,

in order to prevent being imitated. While to my knowledge there is no

discussion of how such issues would affect the number of suppliers used, it is

logical that exposure is reduced when fewer suppliers are used. At the same

time, it is logical to argue that less codifiable transactions, thus not protected

139

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
by patents, would have a higher moral hazard. The reason being that for

such transactions, the knowledge is protected by its lower codifiability and

not by formal means of patents. Therefore, moral hazard related problems

should result in fewer supplier used and at the same time lower codifiability

would be observed.

The answer to this is two-fold. In this study, XChem does not have pro­

prietory information regarding the commodities it purchases. Suppliers are

the ones who hold the real knowledge of the commodity. While the transac­

tion may be more or less codifiable, it is not because XChem has some tacit

knowledge of the commodity itself, but rather because XChem may not know

some aspects of the transaction or the commodity. Codifying these transac­

tions more would not expose XChem to moral hazard as discussed, since its

suppliers already have the technological knowledge required. Neither would

codifying related processes expose XChem to imitation by competitors since

these processes are ingrained in larger organizational processes and structures

and cannot be, and most likely should not be, copied by competitors, at least

not without major organizational changes. This point is strengthened by the

result that suppliers’ ability to learn the transaction and not codifiability was

the key driver of the number of suppliers. Given that suppliers do know the

140

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
technologies related to the commodities they supply to XChem it is apparent

that their inability to learn is of other attributes of the transaction. As was

pointed out, those attributes are not imitable by XChem’s competitors.

On a more general level, codifiability (or lack of) and moral hazard are

treated via different means. Lack of codifiability should suggest a firm may

use pilot projects and staged development in order to develop the codification.

An organization may use internal studies to make explicit what it tacitly

knows. It would not have a need, though, to have confidentiality related

sections in contracts, as moral hazard would require. Codifiability would be

alleviated through process related means while moral hazard would mostly

be alleviated through contractual means.

An interesting question to investigate is how the two relate and combine

to affect vertical integration. When a transaction is uncodifiable or has a

low level of codifiability it may be suggested that vertical integration would

alleviate the problem by increasing transferability. However, as empirical

evidence shows (Szulanski 1996, Dinur, 2002) transferring knowledge within

an organization is not an easy task. Currently there is not evidence that

a transfer between organizations is more difficult than a transfer within an

organization but between two different department. On the other hand, it

141

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is clear that moral hazard is controlled by vertical integration. Thus, what

may be observed is that low codifiability absent of moral hazard would result

in sole sourcing (external or internal) but low codifiability combined with a

moral hazard would result in either sole sourcing with ’’strong” contracts or

more vertical integration. At the same time, high codifiability but with moral

hazard present should still result in sole sourcing with ’’strong” contracts or

in vertical integration.

Perform ance Regressions

The model generates performance related hypotheses only for interactions of

factors with the number of suppliers. However, examining main effects pro­

vides insight to XChem’s performance with respect to the factor in question.

Performance regressions are done on the 90 data points set since performance

measures are given for each commodity-supplier combination8. I use the bi­

nary form of ‘Number of Suppliers’ in the interaction term following the

discussion in the previous section. All other variables are standardized.

I examine measures of defects and quality since these are the measures

that best match the spirit of the model and relate the most to codifiability. I

8In effect, the number of points in the actual regression may be lower due to missing
data.

142

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
note when there are differences in results. Differences in signs of coefficients

should not exist theoretically and when they do, it could be a result of either

perceptions of the concepts involved or instability in the data. The cor­

relation between defects and quality is 0.5 with significance level of 0.0001.

Examination of the data reveals that Quality scores are in the range of 4-6

while Defects scores have more variability. Since quality is based on subjec­

tive assessment of multiple dimensions while defects is based on subjective

assessment of one dimension and “hard numbers” it is likely that the defects

measure is a better reflector of actual performance.

M ain Effects: D efects’ Performance regressions I provide both the

regression with all the variables included and then a more optimized version.

Signs do not change, only levels of significance but not substantially. Higher

score for defects means better performance on that measure (fewer defects)

and is therefore “good”.

• Codifiability and Learning both affect performance negatively (same

result as for Quality measure). The model does not predict how they

should affect performance but higher scores on either should make it

easier to manufacture the product and thus have fewer defects. How-

143

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ever, if XChem is not using the correct strategy, a negative sign could

result.

• Screening affects defects related performance positively as it should.

• Specific investments, made by suppliers, affects defects related perfor­

mance positively as it should.

• The more unique suppliers are, the better the performance. This result

makes sense since one expects that part of what makes suppliers unique

is a good fit with the transaction/product, thus leading to fewer defects.

• Higher Substitutability results in lower performance. That could well

be a result of the hold-up problem. Less substitutable suppliers might

be utilizing their power.

• The more XChem spends on a commodity (annual monetary volume)

the lower the performance it sees. That could be a result of the fact

that when they spend more they also use more suppliers, which might

have lower fit. Interaction effects between BinNum, TotalSpend, and

Uniquelnvest are highly insignificant and therefore prevent more in­

sights into the reasons.

144

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Parameter Estimate p-value
-1.98 -2.06
Intercept
(0.0001) (< .0001)
0.13 0.122
Intercept2
(0.75) (0.52)
0.72 0.78
Intercept3
(0.105) (0.03)
2.95 2.99
Intercept4
(< .0001) (< .0001)
5.09 5.33
Intercept5
(< .0001) (< .0001)
-0.49 -0.47
BinNum
(0.5) (0.38)
-0.71 -0.75
MinCod
(0.019) (0.007)
-0.22 -0.43
Learning
(0.46) (0.108)
1.34 1.46
Screening
(0.0002) (< .0001)
0.58 0.48
MinUnique
(0.14) (0.096)
-0.7 -0.92
MinSub
(0.066) (0.006)
0.06
Practices -
(0.82)
0.22
Eqlnvst -
(0.65)
-0.825 -0.71
TotalAnnualSpend
(0.033) (0.014)
-0.136
HHI -
(0.72)
0.69 0.71
EqUniqlnvst
(0.04) (0.018)
-0.005
OnGoingCosts -
(0.99)

Table 3.10: Defects Performance - Main Effects

145

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
M ain Effects: Q uality Regressions

• Different variables come out significant compared to defects perfor­

mance results.

• Unique investments factor comes out negative. However, when Eqln-

vest, which is suppliers’ investments specific to the commodity but

not to XChem is removed unique investments changes sign (and many

other variables lose significance), which implies that the negative sign

is a result of the non XChem-specific investments picking up the effect.

• Uniqueness and Practices may be significant or not (and alternate)

depending on the model examined. Given the small data set it signals

that they could be important and would have both come out significant

in a bigger data set.

• Investments in practices alignment (by XChem) or in commodity re­

lated equipment (by supplier) have the right, positive, sign.

Learning-Codifiability Interactions The best model for examining how

either codifiability or learning affects performance when interacting with the

number of suppliers should be a model that includes both measures. Indeed,

146

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Parameter Estimate p-value
Intercept -21.75 <.0001
Intercept‘2 0.42 0.26
Intercept3 3.28 <.0001
Intercept4 4.91 <.0001
BinNum 0.97 0.085
Screening 1.36 <.0001
MinUnique 0.48 0.186
Practices 0.44 0.087
Eqlnvst 1.38 0.0009
TotalAnnualS pend -0.72 0.006
EqUniqlnvst -0.25 0.34

Table 3.11: Quality Performance - Main Effects

actual regression models with only either codifiability or learning (BinNum

included) are inferior to the model that includes both, confirming the notion

of transferability as the key issue.

• The interaction between learning and codifiability is significant and has

the right sign. When both agree (both high/both low) the performance

is higher than when they disagree. It is more difficult to identify the

problem and figure out the correct strategy when one is high and the

other low. Furthermore, examination of the data shows that codifi­

ability tends to be high while learning tends to be low. Interviews

with XChem’s executives confirm that XChem has not paid attention

to the problem when codifiability is high. However, when codifiability

147

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is low XChem is aware of the inherent problem and devotes resources

to solving it. Thus, the cumulative effect is that when codifiability is

high but learning is low performance is low, but when both are high

or both are low, performance is high. Given that low codifiability and

high learning do not happen, the positive coefficient results.

• The interaction of either with the number of suppliers is surprisingly

negative (only significant for learning). The model-based hypothesis is

that when there is high learning and high codifiability more suppliers

should be used and that would result in higher performance (and low

should go with low).

— XChem does not match the number of suppliers to learning or

codifiability levels knowingly. As discussed earlier the interaction

of codifiability and learning implies that when the two do not have

the same level more suppliers are used, a result which could be ei­

ther random (small sample issue), due to the low-low outweighing

High-High combination. However, why it would imply higher per­

formance when the number of suppliers do not agree with learning

or codifiability is not clear and warrants further investigation.

148

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Parameter Estimate p-value
Intercept -1.42 <0.0001
Intercept2 0.52 0.091
Intercept3 0.99 0.002
Intercept4 2.88 <0.0001
Intercepts 5.13 <0.0001
BinNum -1.05 0.026
MinCod -0.29 0.36
Learning 0.25 0.38
BinNum*Learning -1.1 0.028
BinNum*MinCod -27 0.958
Learning* MinCod 0.45 0.109

Table 3.12: Performance - Learning and Codifiability

— It is also important to remember that in the main effects model,

both learning and codifiability showed as affecting performance

negatively, which was also contrary to intuition.

Thus, it shows the importance of codifiability and learning as part of

supplier management strategy but also indicates that further investigation is

required to understand the reasons behind the counter-model effect and to

examine whether it is unique to XChem or an actual pattern that contradicts

the model.

149

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.6 D iscussion

In this chapter the aim was to analyze the problem of segmented supplier

management within the context of B2B e-commerce environment when idio­

syncratic investments in systems and procedures are required. Specifically,

this study used the framework established in chapter 2 to analyze that ques­

tion under varying assumptions. The analytical results showed that re­

gardless of assumptions on information visibility or on the cost function, the

proposed factors always influence the strategy in the same manner and as

described above. Furthermore, the idea of transaction knowledge codifiabil­

ity was introduced and for the first time incorporated into a discussion about

inter firm relationships and firm boundaries. I have shown codifiability to be

a necessary and critical factor in determining supplier management strategy,

especially when electronic transactions are concerned.

This dissertation and specifically this chapter is the first to suggest that

segmented supplier management strategy is required. While TCE posits

that inter firm relationships are affected by a set of variables and other man­

agement literature have supported that view, the idea of tailoring a firm’s

supplier management strategy to transaction, market, and firms’ (buyer and

suppliers) attributes have not been put forward in such a manner. The

150

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
analytical model of this chapter serves to formalize this concept and TCE’s

notions about the nature of relationships. Thus, the model suggests hypothe­

ses about the nature of supplier management strategy as should be practiced

by ” Darwinian” firms that adapted and learned from the marketplace.

The second, empirical, part of this chapter serves to underscore this dis­

sertation’s agenda. I have found the XChem’s procurement unit to have no

consistent strategy with regard to the number of suppliers it uses in the con­

text of factors considered in this research. As a result XChem’s performance,

as viewed by itself and compared to its competitors, suffers. However, since

no data is tracked and kept, XChem’s ability to deduce and thus change its

behavior is extremely limited. Indeed, from my interviews with the exec­

utives and managers in question, I have learned that a ’’global” strategy is

formed with the objective to lower costs either by going towards a smaller

supplier base (and thus close relationships) or towards a bigger supplier base

(and thus stronger supplier competition). As a confirming side note I will

point out that XChem has not invested in electronic systems, or any other

system, in order to foster suppliers’ investments, not even when suppliers

make such investments in order to work with XChem.

T hat said, the multi-factor regression does support the model and shows

151

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
that XChem responds to the suggested factors as hypothesized. Given the

lack of formal strategy (per those factors) and the small d ata set, such results

strongly support the framework and its underlying assumptions and theory.

Furthermore, the concept of transaction knowledge transferability is found to

affect supplier management strategy as hypothesized. The counter hypothe­

sis finding that learning and number of suppliers are substitutes rather than

complements could well be due to XChem lack of strategy and its complete

unawareness of the issue. However, it does warrant further study to better

understand the reasons behind such effect.

Given these findings, it is clear that a cross firm and possibly cross in­

dustry study is the next step. While strong implications for strategy must

await more detailed field studies and testing of the framework prposed the

results do underscore the need for segmented supplier management strategy

basedon codifiability and other transactions variables.

152

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
3.7 Appendix: List o f Variables

1. PricePerf: The performance in terms of price they get from suppliers.

Higher score means better performance.

2. ComProdTimePerf: The performance in terms of productions time

(compared to other commodities) they get from suppliers. Higher score

means better performance.

3. SupProdTimePerf : The performance in terms of productions time

(compared to other suppliers of the same commodity) they get from

suppliers. Higher score means better performance.

4. OnTimePerf : The performance in terms of on-time delivery they get

from suppliers. Higher score means better performance.

5. QualityPerf: The performance in terms of quality they get from sup­

pliers. Higher score means better performance.

6. DefectsPerf: The performance in terms of defects rate they get from

suppliers. Higher score means better performance.

7. ImprovePerf: The performance in terms of improvement they get from

suppliers. Higher score means better performance.

153

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
8. GoalsPerf: The performance, compared to their goals, they get from

suppliers. Higher score means better performance.

9. Number: Number of suppliers.

10. BinNum: The number of suppliers categorized as few (category = 0)

or many (category = 1). When the number of suppliers is 3 or below it

is categorized as few. When the number of suppliers is 4 or more it is

categorized as many. Since there were only 2 cases of 4 and one case of

5, and the scale was 1-6 with 6 being more than 5, this categorization

is reasonable. Furthermore, including the two observations of 4 in the

few would not change results and neither would a further inclusion of

the ‘5’. This categorization allowed much cleaner analysis due to the

nature of the data but helped only to enhance significance without

changing signs of coefficients.

11. Cod: Level of general codifiability of the commodity. Higher score

means more codifiable commodity.

12. EngCod: Level of engineering codifiability of the commodity. Higher

score means more codifiable commodity.

13. ReqCod: Level of requirements codifiability of the commodity. Higher

154

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
score means more codifiable commodity.

14. MinCod: The minimum of all the codifiability measures. Captures the

notion that codifiability level is dictated by the lowest of the measures

and is a constraint on increasing the number of suppliers.

15. Learning: Suppliers ability to learn the commodity. Higher score means

better ability to learn.

16. Screening: The amount of supplier screening that was required for this

commodity. Higher score means more screening.

17. ProdUnique: How unique is the supplier in terms of its production

capabilities. Higher means the supplier is more unique.

18. OrgUnique: How unique is the supplier in terms of its organizational

capabilities. Higher means the supplier is more unique.

19. MgmtUnique: How unique is the supplier in terms of its management

capabilities. Higher means the supplier is more unique.

‘20. MinUnique: The minimum of all the uniqueness measures. Captures

the notion that uniqueness level is dictated by the lowest of the mea­

sures and is a constraint on increasing the number of suppliers.

155

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
21. GenSub: How easy it is to substitute the supplier. Higher scores mean

it is easier to substitute.

22. MnfqrSub: How easy it is to substitute the supplier in terms of manu­

facturing consequences. Higher scores means it’s easier to substitute.

23. Qsub: How easy it is to substitute the supplier in terms of quality

consequences. Higher scores means it’s easier to substitute.

24. CostSub: How easy it is to substitute the supplier in terms of cost

consequences. Higher scores means it’s easier to substitute.

25. MinSub: The minimum of all the substitutability measures. Captures

the notion that substitutability level is dictated by the lowest of the

measures and is a constraint on increasing the number of suppliers.

26. Practices: How much XChem invested to align supplier’s business prac­

tices with its procurement practices. Higher means higher investment

was required.

27. Training: How much XChem invested to train supplier’s personnel with

its procurement practices. Higher means higher investment was re­

quired.

156

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
‘28. Eqlnvest: Level of investment by supplier in non XChem specific equip­

ment to produce the specific commodity. Higher score means more was

invested.

‘29. SpendRank: Annual monetary volume of transaction between XChem

and the specific supplier, ranked. Higher means XChem transacts more.

30. HHI: Supplier concentration (internal market concentration). Higher

means more concentrated procurement. Not normalized for market

supplier pool.

31. EqUniqlnvst: Level of unique investments made by XChem to be able

to procure the specific commodity with the specific supplier. Higher

means more investments were made.

32. OnGoingCosts: Level of on going costs associated with the transaction

of the specific commodity with the specific supplier. Higher means

higher costs.

• All variables except BinNum have been standardized.

157

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Chapter 4

Optimal Contract and

Spot-M arket M ix for Buyers in

th e Presence of Uncodifiable

Transaction Knowledge

4.1 Introduction

The last few years have seen an explosion in the number of e-Marketplaces,

including a variety of electronic exchanges in the B2B arena. Third party

158

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
solution providers (e.g., Vertical Net), infrastructure companies (e.g., Ariba,

i2), and big buyers (e.g., the Big 3-Covisint) jumped into this arena in order

to capture a share of the forecasted trillions of dollars expected to material­

ize through e-trade1, overall totaling approximately 1500 different exchanges

existing at the end of 2000. As a result, B2B e-trade is vibrant in selected

areas such as steel, plastics, chemicals, and energy. However, the closing of

Chemdex and other such exchanges indicates that there may be significant

problems in establishing sustainable e-Markets for certain transactions. The

question addressed in this paper is what are likely to be the underlying factors

that affect which transactions are likely to be supportable by e-exchanges.

We focus here on a setting that allows both long-term contracting and short­

term spot markets and attem pt to determine which suppliers and buyers will

participate in each of these forms of market relationship. For both types

of relationship, of course, exchanges may be valuable as a means of mediat­

ing transactions. However, the form of the exchange is likely to be quite

different for transactions that are dominated by spot transactions than for

those dominated by contractual relationships. The key element we analyze

l The reader can open tiny publication by Forrester Research, Merill Lynch, PriceWa-
terhouseCoopers and the likes, to see a range of, typically very high, forecasts of expected
trade volumes in the online B2B sector.

159

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
that seems the fundamental determinant of which form of relationship will

dominate for a particular transaction is the codifiability of the transaction.

Kogut and Zander (1992, 1993) define codifiability as the ability to create

an explicit document detailing all aspects of a product, process or procedure,

so that this document would be understandable to relevant parties concerned

with this product, process or procedure. In the inter-firm context, codifiabil­

ity is the ability of either or both of the trade partners to create a commonly

understood document listing everything about the transaction. Chapter

3 applied the codifiability concept to inter-firm transactions and the opti­

mal structure of supplier relations. A central result of Chapter 3 is the

empirical corroboration that codifiability of transactions is a critical factor

determining the optimal structure of supplier relations. This paper argues

that “codifiability” is a central and defining factor for how transactions are

organized in markets, including the nature of the B2B systems, investments

and institutions that support a particular transaction.

Many factors, as identified by Williamson (1975, 1996), may determine

the contracting and management structures governing how particular trans­

actions occur. The Williamsonian approach focuses primarily on the nature

of planning and investment activities preceding actual transactions. This

160

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
analysis builds on this, but is also concerned with the manner in which these

transactions can be integrated with an e-Commerce framework. The analyt­

ical framework developed extends that of Wu, Kleindorfer and Zhang (2000,

2001) in investigating the integration of contracting and spot markets as al­

ternative types of supplier relations. Consistent with recent developments in

e-Commerce, the model developed shows that certain transactions will natu­

rally give rise to governance mechanisms dominated by contract, while others

will be dominated by spot purchases, and still others may use both forms of

procurement. We show that the primary factor underlying the equilibrium

outcome of transactions governance structure is codifiability, appropriately

defined in the context of the model developed.

The model developed adopts the following perspective. One or more

buyers face a decision as to how to source an intermediate product from

one or more suppliers. They can do so either by setting up longer-term

contracts, with specialized suppliers, or through one-time (spot) purchases

from generalized suppliers. In the case of contracts, systems and procedures

are established ahead of time to support the execution of transactions, and

these procedures may be embodied in an exchange with restricted member­

ship. In the case of generalized suppliers, procurement occurs through a

161

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
“spot exchange”, where the exchange can be either an established electronic

exchange or something as simple as the Yellow Pages. The key difference be­

tween these types of procurement is that contract procurement is negotiated

in advance, and can accommodate virtually any customization in product or

delivery features desired by the buyer(s), while generalized (or “spot”) pro­

curement is constrained by the rules of the market, and typically allows much

less customization2. We model the underlying choice here for a single buyer

by considering the cost and timing of these competing sourcing strategies.

We assume that contracting requires time, and leads to fixed costs to estab­

lish the buyer-seller systems and procedures that underlie contract execution.

The benefits of contracting are assumed to be lower variable production and

transactions cost, including the costs of poor quality and off-spec product,

and a higher probability of order fulfillment in the face of demand volatility.

Spot purchases from generalized suppliers provide access to a broader com­

petitive market, and allow fine tuning of demand and supply, but possibly

2Spot markets that are run through exchanges are designed to allow a specific scope
of product features to be specified as delivery or purchase options in advance. For these
features, and these features alone, frictionless transactions are accommodated. Yellow
Pages, on the other hand, allow a much broader range of features to be negotiated, but
the Buyer has to incur search and negotiation costs. The tension between what products
are offered in various types of “spot market'’, and what investments are incurred and by
whom to standardize offerings, is rather interesting in its own right but one that we will
leave for future research. We provide below a framework for undertaking such an analysis.

162

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
at higher unit costs associated with the poorer matching of product speci­

fications and delivery features with the buyer’s requirements. While these

benefits favor contracting, it must be done in advance, and sometimes well in

advance, of physical delivery requirements so that investments in capacity or

customization required of suppliers to support contract execution may face

increased uncertainty relative to spot market transactions. The trade-off

between these costs and risks depends fundamentally on the codifiability of

transactions and the volatility of demand. If transactions are completely

codifiable, and unit costs are identical between these two sourcing alterna­

tives, there would be no reason (for either competing suppliers or buyers) to

set up long-term contracts. But cost differences can arise for both suppliers

and buyers. On the supplier side, as Helper and Sako (1995), Srinivasan et

al. (1991) and Wang and Seidmann (1995) point out, shared schedules and

EDI links can significantly reduce supplier costs by promoting better pro­

duction planning through more precise requirement and delivery schedules.

On the buyer side, the advantages of contract procurement and strategic

partnerships with suppliers have been widely recognized (Walker and Weber,

1984; Helper and Seiko, 1995). On the other side, the advantages of open

and transparent markets are the underlying paradigm of modern economics.

163

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
However, as we note in the framework that follows, a mix of contracting and

spot purchases can have fundamental advantages over either contracting or

spot markets in isolation, and this is especially true when codifiability is less

than perfect and demand volatility is high.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 outlines the mode and notations.

Section 3 provides the basic results and analysis applied to the one buyer

one supplier case. Section 4 analyzes the multiple buyers case. Section

5 summarizes and the Appendix provides proofs not included in the main

body.

4.2 M odel and N otation

Our modeling framework is based on Wu, Kleindorfer and Zhang (2001),

specialized to identical suppliers, but extended to include differences in cost

under contract and spot market procurement, as well as the inclusion of fixed

costs for establishing a contract relationship between a buyer and a supplier3.

We focus on a single buyer with options to purchase a particular intermediate

3Tlie results are easily extended to the case where Suppliers have heterogeneous cost
functions as in Wu, Kleindorfer and Zhang (2001). However, the increased notational
burden associated with doing so, when coupled with the more general problem framework
here, would mask the basic insights derived here.

164

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
product from multiple, identical suppliers in the contract market or from a

spot market .4 The process by which price in the spot market is determined

is not modelled here, i.e., it is exogenous to the analysis5.

We use the following notation.

N = { 1 ,... n}: Suppliers, with number of Suppliers = n

Pa: spot market price, with cumulative distribution function F(Pa) and

density function f { P a), where /x is the mean of the spot market price.

a : Additional costs to the Buyer per unit for purchases made in the spot

market, e.g. because of imperfect codifiability of the product. Given a, the

’’full spot price” to the Buyer of purchasing on the spot market is P3 + a.

/?: Suppliers’ unit capacity cost per period.

bc: Suppliers’ short-run marginal cost of providing a unit under contract

procurement.

b„: Suppliers’ short-run margined cost of providing a unit under spot

market procurement; we assume that bc < bs so that variable cost under

contract is no higher than variable cost under spot procurement. Indeed the

1Extensions to multiple buyers are also briefly discussed. They appear to be


straightforward.
5This price will depend on the co6ts and number of suppliers, on delivery options, on
the structure of the exchange through which spot purchases are made, and many other
factors.

165

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
difference b3 —bc is one measure of the lack of codifiability of the purchased

product in question. However, if adaptation on the supplier side is not

required (probably leading to a higher a on the Buyer’s side) then bc > b 3.

I: Suppliers’ required investment in specific systems and procedures in

order to participate in the contract market.

K: Suppliers’ total capacity.

Li'. Supplier i ’s posted capacity to the contract market, i € N. Li can

only be non-zero if the Supplier pays the required investment costs I ex ante.

Si: Supplier i’s reservation price per unit of capacity if the contract is

signed. Let s = (st , . . . , sn)

gii Supplier i ’s execution price per unit of output actually used from the

forward contract. Let g = (gi , . . . , gn)

Q i : Buyer’s contract market demand for Supplier i ’s output.

<7i: Buyer’s actual contract market consumption of Supplier i’s output,

where < Qi, Vi

x : Buyer’s actual spot market purchase

Dt = x + Qi- Buyer’s total consumption.

F (v,a) = CDF of full spot price P3 + a, so that F(v,a) = P r {Pa + a <

u} = F ((v —a )+,0), where F (t\0 ) is the CDF of the underlying spot price

166

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
p a.

G(v,a) = "effective price function” defined as

G(v,a) = E{min(Pa + a,u)} (4.1)

It is easily seen that G is an increasing concave function of (v, a) that ap­

proaches fj. as v approaches oc. We refer to G as the effective price function

because if a buyer has purchased an option to buy the good in question at

execution price v, then the expected price paid for the good on the day will

be the minimum of the price of purchasing that unit under contract (at price

v) and purchasing it from the spot market (at price Ps -I- a). We denote

G ~l (-,a) as the inverse function of G(-,a) for any fixed adaptation cost a.

The reader will note the following relationship between G{v, 0) and G(v, a) :

G (v,a) = M in[v,G ((v —a)* ,Q) 4- a].

U(z): Buyer’s aggregate Willingness-To-Pay for output level z

D s(p): Buyer’s normal demand function, i.e., Ds(p) — argmaxD>Q{U (D) —

p D }, so that D,{p) = U'~l {p). [We note below assumptions on U that as­

sure D* is well defined; the reader will note that one can start either from

properties of U or properties of D s since the one determines the other.]

167

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
D(p,a) = Ds(G- l (p,a)).

m(P3,a) is the probability that any Supplier i can find a last-minute buyer

on the spot market when the realized spot price is P3 and the adaptation

cost is a. As codifiability decreases (reflected in increasing a), one would

expect this access probability function m(P3,a) to also decrease, reflecting

the fact that decreased codifiability means greater difficulty in finding an

appropriate spot market supplier with whom the buyer can communicate

precise requirements. We will typically suppress the dependence of m on P3

and a in what follows.

Define c = s + G(b c), in which s — E {m(P3,a)(P3 + a —b3)*} is a lower

bound on the reservation fee for any Supplier i to profitably participate in

the contract market.

Let M C N be any set of Suppliers bidding in the contract market. For

every k 6 M C iV, we define the following sets depending on the Suppliers’

168

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
bids {s,g):

M l{ s ,g ) = {i e M\si + G(gi) < sk + G { g k)}; (4.2)

M t(s,g) = {* e M\si + G{gi) < s k + G(gk)}; (4.3)

Mk(s,g) = {i € M\si + G f a ) = sk + C( 3 fc)}; (4.4)

M£{s,g( = {i € M\ai + C(&) > sk + G{gk)}\ (4.5)

We will usually suppress the dependence of the sets M3k on {s,g) whenever

(s,g) is fixed and clear from the context.

We make the following assumptions, which we assume to hold throughout

the paper. Further discussion of these assumptions and conditions is in Wu,

Kleindorfer and Zhang (2001).

A l: In keeping with decreasing marginal utility of consumption (i.e.,

assuming the normal demand curve Daj is downward sloping), we will assume

that the Buyer’s W TP U(z) is strictly concave and increasing so that

U'{z) > 0, U"(z) < 0, for z > 0. (4.6)

Concerning A l, these are standard assumptions on the Willingness-to-

169

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Pay function. EYom A l and the fact that G Ms increasing, it follows that

D{p) is monotonously decreasing.

A2: pEf^p) + 2D's(p) < 0, Vp > 0

A2 requires that the Buyer’s demand curve not be ” too convex” , so that

the gross profit function pD a(jp) is concave. Clearly, A2 is satisfied if Da

is linear or concave, since D'(p) is negative in any case. A2 is a standard

assumption in the financial economics literature (e.g., Rothschild find Stiglitz

1971).

A3 (N o Excess Capacity Condition): Let Suppliers’ offers be indexed

so that <7i < g 2 < ■■■< gn- Then the No Excess Capacity Condition is said

to hold if and only if

i
Qi[D3(gi) ° ’ *= (4.7)
i= i

This No Excess Capacity Condition implies that Buyers will not contract

for more than what they are sure they will use if they buy under contract

on the day, i.e., if Qi > 0 then Da{gi) > Y a = i Q i - P ut another way, this

condition says that if Qi > 0 then the sum of fill contracted capacity with

170

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
execution fees less than or equal to ft must not exceed D ,(ft). By way of jus­

tification for this condition, we note that, on the day, the optimal execution

order of contracts is to use all contracts available in order of increasing ft up

to the point at which the next such execution fee exceeds Pa, satisfying all

additional demand from the spot market. Thus, if the No Excess Capacity

Condition were violated, it would mean that the Buyer had contracted for

some capacity that would guaranteed never be used on the day. This fol­

lows since the Buyer would have to be willing to pay at least the execution

fee ft per unit of output in order to make use of contract capacity. This

non-optimal behavior is ruled out by the condition stated.

T he von Stackelberg Game: Supplier i bids the following information

(e.g., via an electronic bulletin board): [reservation price, execution price,

capacity]=[sit ft, Li\, i = 1 ,..., n. The Buyer decides how much Qi to re­

serve from each Supplier i. Given a common knowledge distribution F(Pa, a)

of the spot price P3, given a, Suppliers and the Buyer adjust their bids and

offers until equilibrium is reached. The adjustment process and resulting

equilibrium will be described in more detail below.

Below we show that when Suppliers properly anticipate the Buyer’s de-

171

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
raand to their bids, [a^ gi, Lj\, i = then the contract execution

price should be set equal to the Suppliers’ variable contract cost, i.e., = bc,

with reservation fees a, determined by Suppliers to trade off the risk of under

utilized capacity against unit capacity costs. The Buyer’s optimal portfolio

is shown to follow a merit order (or greedy strategy) shopping rule, under

which contracts are signed following the index (si + G(bc)) that is an increas­

ing function of both the Suppliers’ reservation fee (a*) and execution fee (bc).

Our assumption that bc < bs will be important in determining the scope of

contracting relative to spot purchasing.

4.3 Basic R esults

The problem confronting the Buyer is to choose an optimal portfolio of con­

tracts from those available from the n identical, competing Suppliers. Some

of the contract offers may carry high subscription rates a* but low execution

fees These must be compared to other offers carrying lower subscription

fees but higher execution fees. Following Wu et al. (2001), we obtain the

result that the Buyer’s optimal solution is to rank contracts in increasing or­

der of the index a* -fC(g»). This index reflects the cost of reserving capacity

172

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
at price s* plus the ccet of maintaining the option to execute the contract at

price gi rather than utilizing the spot market.

Define the Buyer’s utility as :6

n n
V (D t , q, x,4>) = U (D t ) - ^ 2 ~ Y l 9iqi ~ (Pa + a)x ' ^4'8)
i= l

where <j> = (Ps + a,Qi (i = 1 ,... ,n)) is the spot price and the vector of

contract capacities, q = (<ji,. . . , qn) is the vector of purchases under contract

from Supplier i = 1 ,... ,n, x is the amount purchased in the spot market,

and D t is the total consumption of the Buyer, so that

(4.9)
t=i

Because the Buyer’s problem in this paper is identical to the Buyer’s

problem in Wu et al. (2001), Lemma 1 and Theorem 8 below follow directly

from Wu et al. (2001).

6Note that this quasi-linear form of utility is rather standard and implies that the Buyer
is, in fact, risk neutral, since V(-) below is linear in money. The consequences of risk
aversion by the Buyer would be to encourage more contracting to avoid exposure to spot
market volatility. The assumed decreasing marginal utility in consumption (U"(z) < 0)
simply means that the Buyer’s normal demand curve D, is downward sloping, since as
noted earlier Ds — U'~l.

173

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
L em m a 1 Let ft = (Pa + a,Qi (i = l , . . . , n ) ) be given. W.o.Lg., assume

that Suppliers’ offers are indexed so that gi < g<i < .. . < gn. Let the Buyer’s

optimal total demand be given by the solution Drift) 1° ^ie following problem:

MaximizeDT,,^ V{D T,q,x,ft), (4.10)

subject to:

n
DT = x + ' ^ q i , x>0, q> 0 , DT > 0 . (4.11)
i=l

Then (under A 3 , the No Excess Capacity Condition) the solution Drift) 1°

(110)- (4-U ) is

k
Drift) = {DsiP* + a) - max{x(P, + a - gk) ^ Qi I 1 ^ k ^ n l ) +- (4.12)
i= i

and optimal purchases under contract from Supplier i = 1 ,..., n and from

the spot market are given by

n
Qiift) = QiXiPs + a - g i) , xift) = Drift) ~ ^2<nift)- (4-13)
i= I

174

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
where x(') *3 the. indicator function (which takes the value of 1 if its argument

is positive and 0 else).

Alternatively D t (4>) may be expressed as ) = max[Ds(Ps + o), £ f = 1 Qi],

where Supplier k = k{4>) provides the last unit of contract output to the Buyer.

Defining g0 = 0 and gn+i = oc, Supplier k is determined as the first Supplier

(in the indicated order of increasing gi) satisfying gk < P3 a < n• U

k = 0 , no contract capacity whatsoever is used.

The optimal quantities (4.13) purchased under contract from Suppliers

follow the normal "merit order” indicated by the execution fee rank order

in the Lemma. Contracts are executed in order up to the point at which

the spot price dominates any further available contracts. This implies also,

as seen in (4.13), that either all units of a contract or none are executed on

the day, depending on the spot price. We note from Lemma 1 that when

facing dual sources (spot market and contract market) for procurement, the

Buyer’s demand curve is kinked, as captured in (4.1*2). Given the definition

of G(-), we have the following Theorem 8 .

We will see immediately below that the ” price” in the contract market is

determined by the contract index s< -F C(<fc, a), which we also call Supplier’s

i’s ”bid” and we denote it by p. When there is a bid-tie among a set

175

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of Suppliers M C N, then the Buyers’ demand for Supplier i’s output is

proportionally allocated to the Suppliers according to their bid capacity,

thus if pf = p, Vi e M, then Qi = D(p)[Li/X(M)\, where X( M) = Y,kcM Lk

is the total capacity bid in the contract market. For example, suppose

two Suppliers have the same bid, and their bid capacities are 40 and 60.

If the Buyer demands a total of 50 units from both Suppliers, then this

assumption indicates that the demand for Supplier I will be ’20 and the

demand for Supplier 2 will be 30. This would be the expected outcome

of a process in which random selection of Suppliers with the same bid were

undertaken, with visibility of capacity proportional to bid capacity. In the

present context, we will see that Suppliers will bid either all their capacity

into the contract market (if they have incurred the idiosyncratic investment

costs I to participate in this market) or none. Since we are dealing with

identical suppliers here, this tie-breaking assumption implies that the Buyer

will allocate contract capacity equally among all suppliers who participate in

the contract market, i.e., Qi = D(p)/nc. The results given on the demand

side below Eire not very sensitive to the manner in which bid ties cire broken,

but Supplier equilibrium conditions can be Eiffected by varying assumptions

in this regard.

176

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Theorem 8 (Buyer’s Optimal Contract Portfolio):

Let (s,g ,L ) = {(si,gi, Li), i = 1 ,... ,n } , be posted bids by the Suppliers.

W.o.l.g. assume that Supplier bids are ranked in order of the index s< 4-

G(gi,a), so that Si 4- G{gu a) < s2 + G(g2,a ) < .. . < «/ 4- G (gi,a). If

G(U'(0),a ) < S i+ G (g i,a ), then the Buyer’s solution will be to setQ i = 0, Vi,

i.e., no contracting is optimal. Otherwise, Greedy Contracting in order of the

given index is optimal for the Buyer, i.e., the optimal Portfolio of contracts

has the form: Vi 6 A/*, Qi = Li; Vi 6 M£, Qi(s,g, L) = 0; and f o r i €

Qi(s,g,L) = ^ ■■■i D3( G - \ s i + G ( g i,a))) - Lf). (4.14)


L‘ seui

where h € { 1 ,..., n} is any Supplier (there may be more than one in the case

of tied bids) with the largest value of the index Si + G(gi) satisfying

sh + G(gfl, a ) < G ( U ' ( Y , L i )) ( 4 -15)

The structure of the optimal portfolio captured in Theorem 1 is relatively

simple. It calls for the Buyer to rank all offers in terms of a single index

Si + G(gi,a ) and then to pull off as much capacity as allowed by Supplier

i, proceeding in rank order of the contract index until the marginal W TP

177

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is exceeded by the contract index. Since G (and therefore G -1) is strictly

increasing (G'(x, a) = 1 —F(x, a) > 0), and since by concavity (see A l) Da is

(strictly) decreasing, and therefor Qi is decreasing in the contract index for all

i = 1 ,n. Before W TP is exceeded, the Buyer takes all capacity offered

by Suppliers from whom it contracts. Of course, W TP may be exceeded with

the first Supplier and the Buyer may, in fact, sign no contracts whatsoever

(if G(C/'(0),a) < si + G(gi,a)).

We now turn to the Suppliers’ optimal bidding strategies for («<,<&, Li).

We assume throughout that Suppliers are risk neutral and maximize expected

profits from both contracting and spot markets .7 We assume throughout

that Suppliers face stringent penalties for non-performance under contract so

that they will, in fact, post no more than Li < K as available capacity and

that they will set prices (si, 5 i) so that contracted amounts will not exceed

Li.

Lem ma 2 (Optimal Suppliers*Bidding Capacity): Li(Li-K) = 0, Vi.

7If Suppliers were risk-averse, th e tradeoffs becom e m ore interesting. O n th e one h and,
th e co n tra ct m arket would allow lower variable costs an d som e hedge against th e volatility
o f sp o t prices. However, to take advantage o f these benefits, th e Supplier would have to
invest I in fixed system s costs in o rd er to p articip a te in th e co n tract m arket. T h e outcom e
of th is tradeoff could go eith er way in th e presence o f risk aversion. We follow sta n d a rd
finance th eo ry here in assum ing th a t Suppliers, except for issues o f financial distress an d
bankruptcy, a re risk neutral.

178

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Thus, if a Supplier chooses to participate in the contract market, then the

Supplier will offer its entire capacity K in this market.

Proof. The profit of Supplier i is given by

IL(sf, Li, P3) = SiQi + M i “ (PiK + bcqi)+

+ (P3 + a - b3)+m(P3,a )( K - qi) - I x( Li )

= SiQi + (gi - bc)qi - (P3 -f a - b3) f m(P3, a)?,—

- f c K + (P3 + a - b3) v m(P3, a ) K - I X(U) ,

where, from Lemma 1, q, = Qi x(Pj _ 3 i)- Ekpected profit is therefore given

by

EIL(si,gi, Li) = SiQi + (gt ~ bc)( 1 - F(ffi,a))Q i+

+ (K-Q i) f
Jb.
(v —b3)m((v —a)+,a )d F (v ,a )+

+ Q iX ( 9i ~ b 3) [ (v - b 3) m ( ( v - a ) + , a ) d F ( v , a ) - 0 i K - I x ( L i ). (4.16)
Jb.

Supplier i’s problem is to maximize its overall profit from both the contract

market and the spot market by deciding how much to bid (Li) into the

contract market, i.e. MaXg,igtiLi EIL(st, r/it Li). Assuming Qi > 0 , bidding a

179

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
larger capacity into the contract market relaxes the constraint region (since

Qi < Li is required). Thus, if the Supplier chooses to participate in the

contract market at all (i.e., Sj, <7, and Li are chosen such that Qi > 0 ), then

setting L\ = K cannot decrease Supplier i’s profit. □ ■

Lem ma 3 (Optimal Execution Fee Bids by Suppliers): g'= bc, Vi.

Proof. Prom Theorem 1, we know that the Buyer’s optimalcontract

Q i(s,g) will remain unchanged as long as Si + G(gi,a) remains constant. To

prove the Lemma, we therefore show that for any fixed value of s* 4- G(gi, a),

the optimal solution for gi is bc. To see this, note that along any iso-quant

of Si + G (g i,a ) = c, we must have:

dgi = ~ agi
^ L = ~ ( 1 - F ( S i ’ o ) ) - ( 4 1 7 )

Thus, assuming a constant level of contract capacity Qi(s,g) along the iso­

quant Si + G(gi,a) = c, we compute from (4.17) and (4.16) that

dEiii dETii „ „ li

~(9i - bc)f{gi, a)Qi, g{ < b3,

-{(1 - m(gi,a))gi + (bs - bc)\f(gi} a)Qu gt > bs.

180

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
where /(•) is the probability distribution density of spot market price, given

a. Prom this, m(gi, a) < 1 and b3 > bc, we see that E H is increasing for

gi < bc and decreasing for g3 > bc. Therefore, the F.O.C. implies gi = bc. □


Lemma 3 establishes that E H is a strongly unimodal function along any

bid iso-quant of Si -I- G(gi,a) = c for which Qi > 0 (except in the degenerate

cases where m(<fc, a) = 1 or a) = 0 ), with a global maximum at gt = bc

(unique except in the noted degenerate cases). Thus, we will refer to gi = bc

as a g-dominant bidding strategy for Suppliers, since it is optimal no m atter

what total effective bid is made, i.e., no m atter what the value of st +G(gi, a)

is. The rationale for Lemma 3 is that there is a trade-off for Suppliers

between charging higher a* and higher gt. Charging higher gi erodes the

options value (recall the contract index 3i + G(gi,a)) of the benefit Buyers

see from contracting more quickly than the marginal benefits associated with

increases in The lowest level for gi, namely bc, the price associated with

contract production, is therefore the result. Note that it is the contract

market cost rather than the spot market cost that determines the execution

fee in the contract market. In particular if codifiability decreases and this

is manifested in a significant difference between b3 and bc, then there will

181

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
be greater advantages to contracting. These must be balanced against the

fixed costs of supplier screening and the costs of establishing systems and

procedures to allow contracting. The next Lemma establishes the necessary

conditions for contracting to be feasible.

L em m a 4 (Conditions fo r Supplier Participation in the Contract

Market): Let gi = bc, Vi. Then a necessary and sufficient condition for any

Supplier i to participate in the contract market is the following:

(Si - E {m (P3,a)(P , + a - bs)*})Qi > /*(£*). (4.18)

Proof. Since gi = bc, the expected profit of Supplier i is given from (4.16)

as

E l U s i , bc, K ) = (Si - E {m (P „ a)(Ps + a - 6 ,) +})(?<+

+ (E {m (P „a)(P . + a - 6 ,) + } - ft] )K - I X(Li). (4.19)

We see from (4.10) that no contracting (Qi = 0) would be preferable to any

positive contract unless expected contract revenues axe superior (per unit of

capacity committed) to the expected revenues available on the spot market,

182

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
i.e., (4.18) must hold. □ ■

The rationale for Lemma 4 is that the Supplier does not want to make any

less per unit of capacity than it could by committing to sell its capacity into

the spot market (although access to the spot market is imperfect and occurs

on the day only with probability m(P3,a)). Equating the two possibilities,

taking into account the fixed cost of contract market participation spread

over the contract quantity Qi, leads to Lemma 4. Note that the Supplier is

not concerned in this break even analysis with whether or not they actually

sell the contracted units, since the execution price for these is bc, equal to his

unit contract production cost. Recall that we are dealing with the short-run

problem here in which capacities are not variable, so that negative profits

are indeed possible if investments are sunk and capital costs sufficiently high

relative to what the contract and spot market will bear.

The implications of codifiability Me present in Lemma 4 in severed ways.

First, of course, as I increeises because of difficulties in codifying the systems

and procedures for contracting, then participation in the contract market

is clearly negatively impacted. On the other hemd, for the same reason,

the difference in cost b, —bc between spot and contract procurement may

increase as well. To clarify the effect, fix bc. The increase in 6 a over

183

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
bc would reflect the increased cost, to the supplier, of meeting the Buyer’s

requirements. The result, therefore, of lower codifiability, would be to lower

the supplier’s threshold for participation in the contract market. Thus, we

see that as codifiability decreases, there is a trade-off between contracting

and spot market transactions from the supplier perspective. Note also that

decreasing codifiability on the buyer side will also likely imply that m(P3, a)

will decrease, which, together with increased sourcing cost P3 + a, makes the

spot market a less viable alternative to contracting for Buyers.

We are now in a position to derive market equilibrium prices in the short­

term contract market. Several definitions of market equilibrium might be

used. The approach we take is to assume that Suppliers all know the to­

ted demand function of the Buyer, consistent with sophisticated Suppliers

and well-developed markets. This assumption is explicit here in that Sup­

pliers’ expected profit functions depend on the anticipated Buyer demand

functions Qi(s, g, L) as derived from Theorem 8 . Suppliers adjust their bids

until they achieve a Nash equilibrium in this market. Since there are fixed

costs (namely I) for Suppliers, there are several possibilities for defining the

”industry equilibrium”. We follow the Wilson approach to this problem .8

8See the extended discussion of industry equilibrium in the presence of fixed costs in
Baumol, Panzar and Willig (1989).

184

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Under this approach, Suppliers enter as long as, at equilibrium, they all

make positive profits in the contract market, i.e., as long as (4.18) holds at

the resulting (symmetric) Nash equilibrium to their contract pricing game.

In a bit more detail, the normal form game of interest is as follows. The

players are the Suppliers. The strategies are the triples {(s’, <?*, L’) \ i =

1,..., n} and the utility functions of the players are the expected profit func­

tions (4.10). For m y fixed set M C N of Suppliers bidding into the contract

market, the game just described is played to equilibrium. We show below

that this equilibrium, if it exists, is symmetric and unique. We call such

a contract market equilibrium for fixed M simply an equilibrium or an M-

equilibrium if we wish to emphasize the set M involved. Additional suppliers

enter the contract market if and only if they are to do so profitably. Since

Suppliers have identical co6 t and profit structures, there Eire multiple equilib­

ria in terms of Supplier identities, but all of these will have the saime number

of Suppliers participating in the contract market and (as we will show) at the

same price. We characterize below the equilibrium number nc < n of Sup­

pliers that can be supported in the contract market. After demonstrating

the conditions for existence of a Wilson equilibrium, we will investigate how

nc varies as a function of problem pcirameters, including factors reflecting

185

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
codifiability.

Noting th e definition

a = E {m (P „ a)(Ps + a - 6 S) + } (4.20)

we have, from (4.10), the following profit functions (in the short run, i.e.,

neglecting adjustments in capacity):

Etri(s> 6 , K ) = [* - slQiis, bc,K ) + \ s - f t] K - /*(£*). (4.21)

We are interested in short-term pricing strategies satisfying Lemmas 1-4.

From Theorem 8 , for such strategies, the only interesting parameter is the

“price” index. From Lemma 4 and Theorem 8 , we know that pi = Si +

G(bc,a) > c with c = s + G ( b c,a) with s. Using this notation, we can express

the profit functions for Suppliers (given in general by (4.10)) in the following

form:

Etu(p) = [pi - c]Qi(p) + [c - 0 - G(bc,a )\K - I X(Lt), (4.22)

where, for any vector of bids p — (pi, Qi(p) = Qi(s,bc, K ) is given

186

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
by our Theorem 8 . We will characterize contract equilibria of interest in

p- vector space.

For notational simplicity, define D{z) = D s(G~l (z, a)), Vz > 0. As noted

previously. From Theorem 8 find Lemma 2, we have:

K, D (P*) > EieA/2

Q *(p )= ( K / YlicM* K )(D(pk) - *0- * < 0 (l* ) <

0 , D(pk) <

D efinition .3 For any potential equilibrium set M C N and any k 6 M,

define f k{pk) = {pk - c){D(pk) - £ <eWo A"), where = A/ \ {fc} and where

Pk — sk + G(bc).

L em m a 5 If there exists an equilibrium, then it must be symmetric for all

Suppliers providing positive capacity in the contract market. That is, every

equilibrium p must be of the form Pi = x, Vi € M C N , where Qi(p) > 0,:

i € M and Qi(p) = 0,: i 6 N \ M.

P ro o f. Take any supposed equilibrium p and let M be the subset of Sup­

pliers at this equilibrium supplying positive capacity in the contract market.

Suppose that the equilibrium p is not symmetric, so that pi = M infe | i 6

M } < Max {pi | i 6 M} = p 2 , and such that Qi > 0 and Q i > 0. Then, as an

equilibrium strategy for player 1 , pi must be a best response, and moreover

187

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Q i = K . But consider the new bid for player 1: p/x = (pi 4 -p 2 ) / 2 which

is now strictly greater than pi and strictly less than p 2 - Now Q\ = K still

obtains, but clearly profits are strictly higher for player 1 at p'1 than at p\,

keeping all other players’ strategies fixed at their equilibrium values. Thus,

the original p-vector cannot have been an equilibrium. This contradiction

obtains as long as the lowest bid is lower than the highest bid for Suppliers

in M. □ ■

Given Lemma 5, we know that if there is an M-equilibrium price, it is

unique. We will see immediately below that this price must be such that

every Supplier bidding into the contract market contracts all of its capacity

there. To state our main theorem, define the price p ( M ) as the contract

price that would drive the Buyer to exactly exhaust capacity available from

Suppliers in M in the contract market, i.e.,

D( p (M)) = ' £ k = \M \K, (4.23)


ieM

We first state the main Theorem covering the case in which M is non­

singleton, reserving for Corollary 16 the case in which M is singleton.

T heorem 9 (Equilibrium Conditions): Let K , p *, M be any M-equilibrium,

188

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
where M C N is the equilibrium set of all Suppliers having positive capac­

ity contracts, i.e., Qi(pm) > 0 ,i € M and Qk(p *) = 0, Ar € N \ M . If

s+ G (bc) > G(U'( 0)), then no Supplier will participate in the contract market.

Assume M is non-singleton such that |A/| > 1 and s + G(bc,a) < G(U'(0)).

Then the necessary and sufficient conditions for an M-equilibrium p* to exist

are

C l: p* = p(M)

C2: < 0 if pk > p \ where f k(pk) is defined as f k{pk) = ipk -


OPk
c)[D{pk) - £ ,.6Mo K \ = (pk - c)[D{pk) - (|A/1 - 1)K\, where A/° = M \ {*}

and

C3: p* > s + G(bc, a).

For such an M-equilibrium to be a Wilson equilibrium, the following ad­

ditional condition must be satisfied:

C4: p{M) > -j? + s + G{bc,a) > p (M + {i}), Vi e N \ M

P ro o f. See Appendix. □ ■

Condition C l, noted as the “symmetric condition” in Lemma 5, says that

in the short-term equilibrium, for any Supplier “in the money”, i.e., for any

k £ M, its entire capacity will be contracted in the forward market. Condi­

tion C2 might seem a bit technical to begin with, but it is a standard regu-

189

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
laxity assumption on the demand function D to assure quasi-concavity of the

profit function in prices. See, for example, Friedman (1988) for a discussion

of this and stronger regularity conditions typically imposed in price-based

equilibrium analysis. Ours is a special case of the Friedman (1988) assump­

tion for the behavior of the profit function. In Friedman (1988), it is assumed

to be strictly concave, here we only require the function to be non-increasing

to the right of the equilibrium price p, where p > argmax fk(Pk)-

Corollary 15 (Short-Term vSLFE for Single-Element Equilibrium

Group): The necessary and sufficient conditions for a single-Supplier equi­

librium p to exist are (i) : p = \la x {p 11, x 11} > c, where pu as the solution

to Maximize/!(pi) = (pi —c)D(p\), a n d x 11 as the solution to D(x") = K \,

and (i i ) : p < c < G(U'(Q),a).

Theorem 10 (Computation of set M ): M can be computed in the fol­

lowing way.

(i) Let h be the smallest integer that satisfies

G (U \{h - 1)K)) < c = s + G{bc, a). (4.24)

/ V

(ii) For any k e M, if ——— < 0 when pk > p m, then M is an equilibrium


OPk

190

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
group M ; otherwise, there does not exist any equilibrium subset of N .

Proof. EYom (i) of Theorem 2 we have D(p) = £ ieAf K, which is

equivalent to Ds(G~1(p,a)) = U'~l (G~l (p,a)) = 5Zt€M A', therefore p =

G(U'(Yli=i K ), a). Prom (tii) of Theorem 2 , we know that Vfc 6 H \ A/,p <

ck, since Supplier h does not belong to M , we have p < C/, = a* + G(bh).

Hence we obtain G(U'($2iZi K)) < Ch = £h + G(bh), and identify set M.

If every member in this set passes the test of condition (ii) of Theorem 2,

then it satisfies all necessary conditions of theorem 2 ; thus it is the unique

equilibrium group M. □ ■

4.4 M ultiple Buyers

Now we consider multiple Suppliers and multiple Buyers and derive the most

general results in this paper. These results will be seen to follow very

closely the structure of previous results, so we will spare the reader the full

development of the arguments. However, the assumption that a all buyers

face the same codifiability related costs a, which translates to a common shift

to P3, is required.

Prom the point of view of a particular Buyer, the existence of other Buyers

191

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
does not affect its own demand. Thus, on the day, each Buyer’s problem

remains the same as in the Multi-Supplier-Single-Buyer case. Hence the

following Lemma 6 is a direct consequence of Lemma 1.

L em m a 6 Let <f>j = (P3, Q tj (i = 1 , . . . , / ) ) , j € {1,..., J } be given, where

Qij is contracted capacity by Buyer j with Supplier i. Define Buyer j ’s de­

mand function Dj(4>j) as the solution to Maximize{Vj(Dj,qj,Xj,<$>j) |Dj >

Q,qj > 0, Xj > 0}, where and Xj are purchases by Buyer j under contract

and from the spot market, respectively, and where

i i
Vj( Dj,Qj, xj , ) = Uj(Dj) —^ "SiQij —^ ' giQij ~ B3Xj. (4.25)
1=1 i=i

Then Dfifyf), qij and Xj are given by Lemma 1 (with obvious adjustments

for the subscripts j).

Although the presence of other Buyers will not affect the structure of de­

mand, a key issue when multiple Buyers are present is who will have prece­

dence for the more preferable Suppliers (those for which the shopping index

Si -(- G(gi) is lowest). As we note below, this will not be an issue in equi­

librium, since just as in Theorem 9, so too here the shopping index of all

Suppliers in the money will be set equal to the “market index”. But clearly

192

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the operation of the market can depend on how competing Buyers are allo­

cated among Suppliers. We follow the standard economic assumption that

whenever two or more Buyers compete for the same Supplier contract, the

Buyer with the highest W TP will be the Buyer awarded the Supplier’s ca­

pacity, at least up to the point at which some other Buyer does not have a

higher W TP [For a discussion of W TP and other rationing mechanisms un­

der conditions of excess demand, see Crew and Kleindorfer (1986).] Under

this allocation procedure, the Supplier offering capacity at (s,-,#) will sell

just as much as he would to a single Buyer with aggregate demand equal to

the sum of the demands of all the Buyers. Thus, the consequence of this

standard economic allocation procedure is the following Corollary.

C o ro lla ry 16 (Buyer’s Optimal Consumption Portfolio): Given the

demand functions Daj(p),p > 0, j = 1 , . . . , J, define the aggregate Retail de­

mand as Ds(p) = YlJj=i D*j(p) an(l aggregate marginal WTP as U'fiQj) =

D “ 1 (Qj), Qj > 0 . Greedy Contracting is optimal for every Buyer j , as spec­

ified in Theorem 1, in the sense that Buyers will pick off contracts from Sup­

pliers offered to them in the order of the Shopping Index Si+G(<7<). Moreover,

if Buyers are offered contracts in order of their WTP, then total demand for

each Supplier i will be the same as when the Supplier faces a single Buyer

193

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
with demand D s(p) and marginal WTP U'(z) = D3 l (z).

In a similar fashion, Lemmas 2, 3 and 4 in the previous sections hold since

the Suppliers’ problems all remain the same, where now Qi is to be under­

stood as aggregate supply to all Buyers by Supplier i. In particular, from

Lemma '2 and Lemma 3, Li = K and gi = bc continue to be, respectively,

dominating and ^-dominating strategies for the Suppliers. Most importantly,

Corollary 16 implies that the game among Suppliers, and its equilibria fol­

lowing the von Stackelberg model assumed here, is given by Theorem 9, with

aggregate Retail demand, as specified in Corollary 16, with the inverse ag­

gregate marginal W TP specified by U~l (z) = Ds(z). The remaining logic

of Theorem 9 and its proof are then identical. The result is the following.

C orollary 17 (von Stackelberg Leader-Follower Equilibrium (vSLFE)

fo r the Multi-Buyer, Multi-Supplier Case): Consider the Multi-Buyer,

Multi-Supplier Case in which competing demands by Buyers for a particu­

lar Supplier are allocated in order of Buyer WTP. For this case, the condi­

tions for the existence of a vSLFE to the Multi-Buyer, Multi-Supplier Case

{{s ’,g ,, L‘) | i = 1,...,/} are identical to those specified in Theorem 2, with

D(p) = Ds(G~l (p)), where Ds(p) is given in Corollary 18.

194

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Thus, under the assumption that competing Buyer demands for the same

Supplier contract are rationed in order of Buyer WTP, the solution to the

general network case is solved. This general solution results from using

the demand and equilibrium contracting building blocks of Buyer contract

demand and of the market equilibrium results for the Multi-Supplier, Single-

Buyer case. The equilibrium characterized in both Theorem 9 and Corollary

19 has important prescriptive properties that should be mentioned in con­

cluding our discussion. The 5 -strategy is 5 -dominant for the contract capac­

ity provided, the capacity strategy is a dominant strategy, and the s-strategy

is the transparent outcome of the pivot Supplier h who is the price setter in

the contract market. Whether this equilibrium is stable or has other impor­

tant properties behaviorally than the dominance properties noted remains to

be seen through further theoretical and experimented work. The key m atter

to note here is that once the game is understood to be completely specified

in terms of the shopping index s*+C( 6 c), considerable degrees of freedom axe

removed from the problem. Most importantly, the above results establish

this index as the critical focal point for rational strategies for a particular

Supplier, whatever strategies are played by other Suppliers.

195

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
C o ro lla ry 18 An increase in a, the uncodifiability costs associated with spot-

market procurement and incurred by the buyer, would shift demand towards

the contract market, without changing the nature of equilibrium or the allo­

cation of demands to suppliers. However, such a shift may lower overall

demand and result in some suppliers driven out of the market.

As uncodifiability and therefore a increases, it amounts to an increase

in the spot market price. Such an increase raises the effective price and

therefore reduces total demand. While the basic allocation mechanism for

awarding contracts does not change and suppliers "win” contracts according

to their index, the effect of increased spot prices shows up in two ways. First,

suppliers cannot sell the same amount of excess capacity in the spot market.

Second, last-minute demand fulfillment for buyers is also higher. The result

is that both the number of suppliers participating in the contract market

is reduced and the overall level of demand supplied by the contract market

relative to the spot market increases. These results suggest that for less

codifiable items we would see more contracting and fewer suppliers, which is

precisely what the theory of chapter 3 suggests from a different perspective,

and of course also what we corroborated empirically in chapter 3.

196

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
4.5 Sum mary

This chapter has provided a general solution to the Multi-Supplier, Multi-

Buyer supply chain contracting problem for non-storable goods. The key

question addressed is the structure of the optimal portfolios of contracting

and spot market transactions for these Suppliers and Buyers, and the pricing

thereof in market equilibrium and how transaction knowledge uncodifiabil­

ity affects these. The framework developed by Wu, Kleindorfer and Zhang

(2 0 0 1 ) is generalized here to the case when contracts and spot markets have

different unit production costs. Furthermore, costs associated with less than

perfect codifiability of transaction knowledge are incorporated and their ef­

fects analyzed. These costs may be incurred on the suppliers’ side, the

buyer side, or both. The issue of codifiability is critical for electronic chan­

nels based transactions as shown in Chapter 3. In so far as contracts are

less (then spot market transactions) negotiated and executed electronically,

codifiability may be an important determinant of B2B e-commerce activity.

I show that when Suppliers properly anticipate demands to their bids,

then a 3 -dominant strategy for the contract execution price is to truthfully

reveal the Suppliers’ variable cost, with reservation fees determined by Sup­

pliers to trade off the risk of under utilized capacity against unit capacity

197

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
costs. I further show that lower codifiability may result in a shift, under

certain conditions, towards contracts.

This solution has important applications in a number of industrial and

service sector contexts where capital intensity and non-storability are essen­

tial characteristics of supply chain operations. Non-storability (including

cases of JIT delivery) is important to our analysis as is the implicit assump­

tion throughout of capital intensity of the production process. Absent either

of these and inventory or rapid scale-up of production would be suitable sub­

stitutes for long-term contracting or spot market purchases.

A number of future research topics Eire evident. It would be interesting

to explore the opportunities for both mEirket reseEirch and Supplier/Buyer

contracting support systems based on these results in sectors of interest. As

noted, on the theoretical side, severed areeis Eire potentially interesting. Con­

cerning the present model, analyzing how investments in information systems

may change the balemce between contracts and spot markets would be highly

useful. It would even be more interesting to examine how such investments

may interact with investments in codification of trsmsaction knowledge and

the relationship between the two types of investment (i.e., information sys­

tems Eind codification). As was noted at the beginning of this dissertation,

198

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
90% of the presently existing e-exchanges and marketplaces do not have any

transactions. As this dissertation showed, an important factor behind it

may well be the uncodifiability of may types of transactions that were sup­

posed to take place through those exchanges. The investigation proposed

would help suggest some answers to how and when to make investments

towards creating e-exchanges and marketplaces, which already see trade of

several hundred billions dollars and is expected to reach several trillions in

few years. Such solutions may foster a more rapid, less wasteful, process

towards a more optimal B2B e-commerce market structure.

4.6 A ppendix

P r o o f o f L em m a 1

Take tiny i = 1 , . . . , / and any fixed total demand D t • Contract purchases

will be in order of increasing execution fees gi as long as < Pa. We can

therefore assume that, for any I < i, all capacity under contract I will be

used prior to taking any output under contract i.

Now let fc > 0 be the Supplier providing the last unit of contract output,

so that k satisfies gk < Ps < gk+1 - Under A 3 (the No Excess Capacity

199

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Condition), the Buyer will never contract for more than needed, so that

for every k = 1 , Qk = 0 unless 53*=1 Qi < Da(gk) or equivalently,

since Da = U'~l , gk < Qi)- Thus, on the day, depending on the

spot market price, the Buyer faces only the following two cases under which

qk > 0 and qi = 0 for i > k:

1. 9 t< P .< u \Y L x Q i)>

2
• . gk< v ,(Y!LiQi)<P-
Using the fact that Supplier k provides the last unit of contract capacity,

we have = Qi for i < k, qt = 0 for i > k and qk < Qk. Thus, noting that

Pa > max{5 0 , • • •, <7*}, we obtain the following expression for Buyer’s utility

V after substituting the derived expressions for optimal qrf and x = Di — ^3 Qi

as functions of D r -‘

V {D t , q (D r ), x (D t ) , <i>)

i t 1
= U { D t ) ~ 5 3 *iQi ~ ^ S i Q i ” p *(D t ~ 5Z *)
t=l t=l t=l
1 * —1

= U ( D t ) - p aD T - 5 3 SiQi + 5 3 ( p * - Si)Qi
t=l i=l
fc-1
+ (P , - 9k) rn in [DT - 5 3 Q i ’ Q*\- (4 -26 )
i=i

•200

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
To determine Dr{<t>) we need to maximize this concave function V ( D t, q, x, <t>)

over D t > 0. We do this in two steps. In step I (which corresponds to case

1 above), we solve this problem where the minimum is the second quantity

in the [•] in (4.26). This leads directly to Dt(4>) = Da(Pa). In step 2 (which

corresponds to case 2 above), we solve this problem where the minimum is

the first quantity in the [•] in (4.26), i.e., subject to D t < 52?= i Qk- Since in

any case gk < C/'(52?=i Q*)> this leads to DT(4>) = 52?= i Qi- Combining these

two cases, shows the validity of the alternative characterization of Dt(4>) in

the statement of Lemma 1. The characterization (4.12) is easily seen to be

equivalent to this, so that Lemma 1 follows. □

P roof o f Theorem 8

The reader should keep in mind in this proof that the order assumed in

this Theorem, implied by non-decreasing values of the index 4-G(gi), may

be a different order them the order assumed in Lemma 1 in terms of non­

decreasing values of g*.

Assume sj + G(gi) < G(U'(Q)) since otherwise the Buyer is not willing

to pay the effective price of even the lowest cost Supplier (i.e., otherwise the

Buyer will have no incentive to accept any contracts). We first note that since

3{ + G(gi) is non-decreasing in i (by assumption) and since G(U' ( 52!=! £/))

201

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is non-increasing in i (by the properties of G and U'), then if Supplier h has

the largest value of the index + C(gt) satisfying (4.15), then every i < h

will also satisfy the following condition:

i
Si + G{gi) < sm + C(5 m ) < C { V { Z W h (4-27)
i=i

with the left inequality following from the assumed ordering in terms of the

shopping index. For suppose the right inequality in (4.27) did not hold at

some i < h. Then again by the ordering of the index and the monotonicity

of U' and G, we would have:

t /> -1

+ G(gh) > ai+l + G(gi+1) > C ( t / '( E Ll» * G (U' ( 5 2 L'))’ (4/28)
i=i i=i

contradicting the definition of h in (4.15). We note, in particular, from

(4.27) and the monotony of G that the optimal Qi, * = 1 , . . . , /, given in the

Theorem statement satisfy the No Excess Capacity Condition.

Now for any 4> = (Pa,Si,gi,Qi (i = 1 , . . . , / ) ) , we can substitute the

optimal contract and spot purchases and x from Lemma 1 to obtain the

202

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
following simplified form of the Buyer’s utility (4.8) as a function of 0

/ i
V(<(>) = U(D t {4>)) - PsD t {4>) ~ Y , s& + " * ) +^ > (4-29)
i=l t=l

where Dx(0) is given by (4.12). Define EV(Q) as the expected value w.r.t.

Pa of V(4>)- Clearlythere exists an optimal solution to the problem of max­

imizing the EV{Q) since V{4>) iscontinuous in its arguments and we can,

w.o.Lg., restrict attention to the compact set of non-negative contract levels

Qi for which the No Excess Capacity Condition is satisfied. To characterize

the optimal contract amounts, we derive F.O.C.S by considering the deriva­

tives of V(4>) for a fixed realization of P3 and then take the expected values

of these derivatives w.r.t. Pa.

From (4.29) we obtain for any i 6 {1, ... , / } that

= (U'(DtW ) - - * + ( a - S i )*, (4.30)

where D t {4>) is given by (4.12). We wish to evaluate dDr(4>)/dQ{.

Let k be the index of the Supplier with the highest execution fee for which

contract capacity is non-zero, i.e. g-k = max{<fc | 1 < i < I;Q i > 0}. Then

203

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the following relation holds for any k such th at Qk > 0:

I k

9k<9k< tf'E ^ U' ( Z <&)• (4-31)


(=1 1=1

The first inequality follows since g-k is the maximum execution fee for non­

zero callable capacity. The middle inequality is essentially equivalent to the

No Excess Capacity Condition since, by definition of k, Qi = 0 Vi > k, so that

Ilf=i Qi = Hi=i Qi- The final inequality in (4.31) follows since U' = D ~x is

monotone decreasing.

Prom Lemma 1 we know that DT{4>) = max(Da(P3), £ f = 1 Qi), where k is

the last contract executed given <p. Thus, D t {4>) depends on Qt if and only if,

for some k > i , £ f = 1 Qi < DS(P„) and gk < Ps < g k n • Using the Non Excess

Capacity Condition, we further note that if Qk > 0 , then D3(gi) > 52?= i Qi-

We conclude from this and (4.31) that

dDrifi) 1 iff 3 A: with Qk > 0 and & < 0 * < U'{Ya =i Q‘) <
dQi
0 e ls e .

204

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
B ut, given the definition of k and (4.31), this is equivalent to the following:

d D rtt) 1 iff i < k and U ' { Z L i Qi ) < ft-


dQi
0 else.

We also note from (4.31) that precisely when d D r if y /d Q i = 1, we have

Dt {4>) = J2i= i Qi* s™ce ^ f t > ^(52?= i Qt) f°r any * ^ * with Qk > 0 , then

f t > U 'iH U iQ i)- Thus, substituting DT(<j>) = Y^Li Qi ^ interchanging

expectation and differentiation, we finally obtain from (4.30)

= r ( V ( £ q i ) - P.)dF(P.) + / “ (ft - g,)dF(P.) -


Ju'G :lt=lQ,) ^ hi
(4.34)

Since G(p) = Etmintp.P,]} = E {P , - (P3 - p )+}, the first two terms

in this expression reduce to G(U'(Yli= l Qi)) — E {P ,} and E {P a} — G(gi),

respectively, yielding

^ P = C ( y ' ( ^ Q , ) ) - ( » i + C te))- (4.33)

Now note that since the first term is independent of i in (4.35), d E V /d Q i

is monotonic decreasing in s, + CQfc). Thus, if for some k 6 {1,...,/},

205

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
dE V /dQ k > 0 , then dE V /d Q i > 0 for any i such that Si+G(gi) < Sk+G(gk).

Finally, note that for the contract with the maximum such index, say h, with

Q h > 0, we must have dEV/dQ-h > 0 with inequality unless Q-h = L-h. It

follows that every contract with a value of the index s{ 4 - G(gi) no greater

than h will have dE V /d Q i > 0 so that for such contracts Qi = Li. From

this, we see that, in fact, h = h as defined in (4.15). The Theorem follows.


Proof o f Theorem 9

We first note that if the assumption Min{ci|i 6 5} < G(U'(Q)) is not satis­

fied, then there would be no positive contract equilibrium since, as noted in

Theorem 8 , in this case no Supplier would be able offer a profitable contract

that would attract non-zero Buyer demand.

Sufficiency. First we show that if there is a set M that satisfies (i) and

(ii), then VA: € M, the optimal contract price for k is to charge Pk — P

as computed via (i). Furthermore, denote p.* as the price vector of other

players in set M. Given p_* = p, k has no incentive to either decrease or

increase its price pk from p.

Case (a): Choose any k € A/, and suppose, pk < p. We see immediately

that all A;’s capacity will be used, i.e., Qk(pk,P-k) = Kk, that gives him

206

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
a profit of Eiric(pk,p-k) = (Pk — ck)Kk- By definition, we have E 7T*(p) =

(p - ck)D (P)z * * k ' by (*)» we Set D(p) = 5ZieAf K , therefore, Ett*(p) =

(p —Ck)Kk■ Thus we obtain

E 7rk(Pk,P-k) = {pk ~ ck) K k < ( p - ck) K k = Eirk(p), (4.36)

which shows that Supplier k has no incentive to decrease its price given that

other players are charging p.

Case (6 ): Choose any A: € M, and suppose, pk > p. Since pk > p and

from (i ) we have D{p) = YUzm K , since the demand function D(-) is strictly

decreasing, we get D{pk,p - k) < D{p) = 5ZieAf K, therefore, Supplier fc’s

capacity cannot be fully used, i.e., Qk{pk) < Kk- We see,

limPJk~.pEnk{pk,P-k) = { p ~ ck)Qk{p) = (p - ck) K k = E/rfc(p). (4.37)

If we take limits on both sides of equation (4.36), we get

limp*~pE'rfc(Pfc,P-fc) = (p ~ ck) K k = Eirfc(p). (4.38)

207

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Hence, Effk(j>k,P-k) is continuous at p. Since Pk > p, we have

E7Tk{pk,P-k) = fk(Pk,P-k) = {Pk~ Ck)Qk{Pk,P-k) =

= (Pk ~ ck)(D(pk,p-k) (4-39)

Take derivatives of w.r.t. pk in the above equation, we have

dfk{Pk,P-k)
g- nt_
= D f e .p_- O, y - ,, +, , - \&D(pk,P-k)
C„)----- g - -----
ieiW® y
yi / \ . i \dQk(jPkiP-k)
= Qk(j>k,P-k) + (Pfc —Cfc) jr- .
0Pk

From (ii), we have f'k(pk) < 0 if Pk > p, we obtain

d^k(Pk,p-k) d f k(pk,p-k)
< 0. (4.40)
dpk dpk

We conclude that, E n k(j)k,P-k) = fk(j>k,P-k) decreases if pk > p. Hence

Supplier k has no incentive to increase its price given other players’ charge

P-k = P-

Condition C 3 insures that no one outside group M would have any in­

centive to charge a price < p, since doing so will lead to negative profits by

208

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Lemma 4.

N ecessity. Assume there exists an equilibrium set, M, of positive contract

Suppliers. By Lemma 5, we can further assume all Suppliers in M charge an

identical price p. Consider any Supplier k 6 M, since M is sin equilibrium,

k has no incentive to deviate from the equilibrium price p. That is to say, if

we fix other Suppliers’ strategy at p, k does not want to decrease or increase

his contract price pk. We discuss these two cases accordingly.

Case (a): Supplier k does not want to decrease its price by charging pk <

p. If he decreases his price, then he would either extract all the demand from

the Buyer by being the first and last unit provider (Qk(Pk,P-k) = D(pk,p_k)),

leaving nothing for other Suppliers in A/, or still be able to sell all its capacity

(Qk(Pk,P-k) = Kk)- Clearly he has incentive to do so in the former case, since

Kk
limpk-.pEx k(pk,p-k) = ( p - ck)D (p ,p -k) > ( p - ck)D (p ,p -k) = =
luieM K

= Eirk(p ,p -k).

The fact that he does not decrease his price indicates that the latter is true,

209

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
i.e., Qk(Pk,P-k) = Kk, and Eirk(pk,P-k) < Etfk(p,P-k)- Therefore

Ettjk(pk,P-k) = (Pk~ ck) K k < E j k{p,P-k) = (p ~ Ck)D(p,p-k )-^ —


Isiex'r K
(4.41)

If we let pk —* p on both sides of the above equation, we obtain, Kk <

D{p,p-k) r K or equivalently, D(jp) > £ igJV> K .

Case (6 ): Supplier fc does not want to increase price by charging pk > p-

If he increases his price, then he would either be able to sell all its capacity

(QkiPk,P-k ) = Kk) or fulfill the residual demand from other Suppliers in

group M at Qk{pk,P-k) = D{pk,P k) - E ieAio K > 0. Clearly he has incen­

tive to do so in the former case since he enjoys more profit by increasing his

price and selling the same output, the fact that he does not increase price

indicates that the latter is true, i.e., Qk{pk,p~k) = D{pk,P-k ) — E j eA/o K ,

and Eirk{pk,p-k) < Enk(p,P-k)- Therefore

Eirk{pk,P-k) = {Pk ~ ck)[D(pk,P k) “ 5 Z < E?rk{p,p-k) =


ieiw°

= (p - ct )0 ( p ,p -t ) Kk . (4.42)

If we let pk —* p in both side of the above equation, we obtain, D{p,p-k) —

210

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
£ . ^
K ^ ^(p.p-0 r ^ i c or «iuivalently>d(P’P-‘) i ^ f ^ £*«« k ,
or D(p) < £ t6Ay /C.

If we combine the results of case (a) and case (6), we obtain C l in the

Theorem 9, i.e., D(jp) = YlieM ^ - Furthermore, the above reasoning shows

that E7rfc(p*,p_fc) is continuous at p, and decreases if p* > p, so that it

is straightforward to obtain C2. Condition C 3 holds since if 3 j € 5 \

A/,p > cj, the Supplier j has an incentive to join in M , which contradicts

our assumption that M is an equilibrium group. □

‘211

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Chapter 5

Conclusions and Future

Research D irections

This dissertation has achieved multiple interrelated objectives, both on the

theoretical front and on the practiced side. While the practical and theoretical

aspects of this research are highly interlinked, I present these contributions

separately. I start with a discussion of the practiced implications in section

1 and continue with a discussion of the theoretical innovations and contri­

butions to existing knowledge put forward in this dissertation. I conclude in

section 2 with a discussion of future reseeuch directions and cheillenges.

212

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
5.1 P ractical C ontributions

First, as suggested in the introduction, this dissertation provides insights and

a deeper understanding of the nature of supplier management in the impor­

tant context of B2B e-commerce, especially when significant investments in

information systems are required. Chapter 2 showed that traditional incen­

tive systems would not work when such investments are required and offered

an alternative incentive mechanism that is shown to incent suppliers to make

investments when these are efficient. The incentive system offered, namely

buyer’s matching investments in the relationship and supporting systems, is

easily implemented and has an intuitive appeal to firms who are interested

in close relationships with their suppliers. Chapter 3 complements this by

showing what the optimal supplier base should be in the same context, using

the same framework put forward in chapter 2. Thus, chapter 2 and chapter 3

combine to provide insights on implantable solutions for the linked questions

of supplier selection and control.

Even more important is the idea of segmented supplier management that

underlies the framework offered in chapter 2 and 3. Managers and firms,

as became evident in the empirical study, which is part of chapter 3, are

educated to form an overall supplier management approach. That approach

213

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
may be one of creating close, long-term relationships with a small number

of suppliers or of operating in a more adversarial mode with a larger num­

ber of suppliers. However, as the results of Chapter 2 and 3 show, supplier

management strategy should be segmented according to the combination of

product and market attributes, as well as the context in which the strategy

takes place; hence, segmented supplier management strategy. As the empir­

ical results show, the factors put forward by the framework affect supplier

management strategy and more importantly, combine with the strategy to

affect performance. The advent of the Internet as a B2B activity platform

only serves to accentuate the performance implications of not following such a

strategy since the tensions between spot-markets and contracts only increase

when technology improves one or the other or both.

Indeed, out of chapter 3 an important factor for B2B e-commerce arises,

the codifiability of transaction knowledge. Codifiability, which is at some

level a necessary condition for electronic transactions, is found in this disser­

tation to be a critical factor in determining supplier management strategy. I

find that the higher the codifiability, the more suppliers can and should be

used and thus electronic trading (i.e., e-Marketplaces and exchanges and not

EDI) becomes a more viable and appropriate mechanism. This result cor-

214

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
roborates what is evident in the marketplace; that the only e-Marketplaces

and exchanges that have any transactions are those that deal with highly

codifiable transactions (e.g., steel, plastics, office products and MRO). The

emphasis is on transaction codifiability and not product codifiability since

even if the product itself may be highly codifiable, business process and pro­

cedures associated with it may make the overall transaction less codifiable.

The issue of codifiability as a driver and factor of B2B e-commerce activ­

ity and associated supplier management strategy has enormous implications

for the economy, the marketplace, and firms. If the codifiability thesis, put

forward by chapter 3’s analytical model and results and corroborated in the

empirical analysis, is true, then many firms would have to reconsider their

B2B e-commerce strategy. The implications are significant both for would

be trading firms (i.e., buyers and suppliers at all levels) and for the whole set

of firms that create the B2B e-commerce infrastructure (e.g., SAP, Ariba, i2,

Vertical Net, Covisint.)

Chapter 4 complements Chapter 2 and 3 by examining how codifiability

affects the mix of contracts and spot-market transaction buyers would choose.

Corroborating and complementing Chapter 3’s codifiability results, chapter

4 show codifiability to be a driver of the contracts and spot-market mix. It

215

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is shown that, in general, as codifiability improves, spot-markets become a

more attractive option. Such a result has, again, important implications for

firms considering the nature of such a mix, especially when technology brings

the issue to the forefront and may alter the balance in the relative merits of

contracts and spot markets.

Given the forecasted future size of B2B e-commerce trading activity

(which may be as large as $4 trillion within the next few years according to

some industry pundits), the insights and results discussed above may carry

significant economic impact. While further research has to be conducted to

fully support these results, the empirical research and anecdotal observations

of the developing B‘2B e-commerce space, suggest that these results hold and

may be of fundamental importance for practice.

5.2 T heoretical C ontributions

This dissertation provides numerous theoretical contributions, from funda­

mental and basic to more topic specific. Given the detailed discussions in

the preceding chapters, I limit the discussion in this chapter to the more

fundamental and consequential contributions, even when topic-specific con-

216

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
tributions may be significant.

By uniting several research streams, ideas and modeling approaches, from

economics, operations management, and management, it became feasible to

put forward an analytical framework to investigate the idea of segmented sup­

plier management strategy. Previous research such as transaction cost eco­

nomics (TCE), agency theory, and supplier management, identified drivers

of both supplier management strategy and market configurations. Thus,

TCE, as the major proponent of such an approach, showed which factors

may determine market structure and inter-firm relationships. At the same

time, the management and operations management literature focused on sup­

plier management strategy (e.g., Helper and Sako, 1995). This dissertation

suggests that the two should be combined, resulting in segmented supplier

management strategy. The basic approach to segmentation is this. Each

transaction is categorized according to levels of a set of factors identified to

matter, including unit value of transactions and aggregate level of same. The

buyer then determines a number of segment-specific strategies, including the

size of the supplier base, investments in this base and appropriate procure­

ment incentives. The resulting segment-specific strategies unite the economic

t hinking of market Darwinism determining efficient configurations with the

217

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
management approach to proactively choosing optimal configurations and

investments.

Notably, the segmented supplier management strategy study presented

here is grounded in an analytical framework. Previous attempts at analyti­

cally modeling TCE have not succeeded because the pure economic modeling

mechanisms (e.g., game theory, principal agent modeling, industrial organi­

zation modeling) do not offer enough detailed information. This detailed

transaction information is required in order to analyze the interdependency

between transaction and market structure. By combining economic modeling

tools (principal-agent and game theory) with the operations management em­

phasis on the details of the transaction, the framework developed in Chapters

2 and 3 provides a workable and realistic framework for developing insights

on the optimal segmented supplier management strategy.

In doing so, Chapters 2 and 3 solve the dual question of selection and

control of suppliers. Such analysis have been conducted only once before

(Seshadri, 1995) at a lower level of complexity. As Seshadri notes and Chap­

ters 2 and 3 show, the two questions are linked and influence each other.

Chapter 2 and 3 demonstrate that both the supplier base size (selection)

and the type of incentives given (control) influence suppliers’ decisions about

218

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
investments in inter-firm information systems and associated systems and

infrastructure. If both the supplier base size strategy and incentives given

by the buyer do not concur, the result would be contradictory forces (on

the supplier to invest) and some degree of inefficiency. Thus, the analytical

model of Chapters 2 and 3 allow analysis of the selection and control ques­

tions within the same framework but segmented according to transaction and

market attributes rather them according to a one-strategy-fits-all approach.

In Chapter 3 I introduce the idea of transaction knowledge codifiability

as a factor in supplier management and inter-firm relationships. Codifiability

had been discussed previously in both economics and the management liter­

ature (Pelikan 1979; Kogut and Zander 1992) but in intra-firm context and

transfers. This dissertation uses codifiability to analyze inter-firm transac­

tions and specifically supplier management. The analytical part of Chapter 3

show that codifiability is a critical factor in determining supplier management

strategy. Codifiability determines the range of strategic options available to

the buyer. The higher the codifiability, the greater the range.

The idea of transaction knowledge codifiability allows a new type of infor­

mation deficiency m odel. Game theory and principal-agent models assume

one or more of the players (alternatively, principal or agents) may lack some

219

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of information the other player(s) have. Codifiability, however, suggest a new

model in which both sides lack the same type of information since this lack

is embedded in the transaction itself. Less then a perfectly codifiable trans­

action implies all participants face the same type of information deficiency

or lack. The ability to place the information deficiency on the transaction

itself provides an ability to conduct richer and more complex analysis of in­

teractions between transaction participants and seem to be a methodological

innovation.

To complete the analytical investigation conducted in Chapters 2 and 3,

Chapter 3 examines the question of optimal mix of contracts and spot-market

transactions when transactions are not perfectly codifiable. To do so, I utilize

a framework developed by Wu, Kleindorfer and Zhang (2001). I generalize

their model by allowing differing production costs between contracts and spot

markets and introducing codifiability-related cost effects. Lack of codifiabil­

ity is found to shift buyers’ demand towards contracts and may even lower

overall demand and thus trade, resulting in some suppliers being driven out

of the market. This result corroborates Chapter 3’s result that showed lack

of codifiability to reduce the number of suppliers selected. Thus, codifiability

is shown to be a driver of both the supplier base size as well as the nature

220

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
and intensity of contracting.

Last, but certainly not least, an empirical study was conducted to examine

Chapter’s 3 results (hypotheses). While studies of TCE and related theories

have been conducted in the past, only a few empirical studies exist and

these have been primarily directed towards examining the nature of contracts

signed and not their relationship to supplier base and supplier management

issues. Furthermore, the empirical study examined the concept of transaction

codifiability and transferability, which has not received much attention in the

empirical literature until now. Despite a small data set of 35 or 90 data points

the model’s hypotheses are strongly confirmed. Specifically, the concept of

codifiability is shown to be a factor in both supplier management strategy

and related performance. These results are striking since it is also shown

that the firm in question does not follow any pre-conceived strategy based

on the model’s factors, except for the trading volume. However, the study

replicates results concerning certain classic variables and corroborates for the

present study the nature of their influence on supplier management strategy.

The consistency of these findings with multiple past studies thus provides

additional corroboration of the empirical study’s validity.

In conclusion, this dissertation has provided multiple theoretical contribu-

221

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
tions. These contributions include foremost the introduction of new concepts

into existing research streams and a comprehensive and supporting analytical

framework. The results for supplier management strategy in the unfolding

era of B2B e-Commerce could be significant, and taken together they seem

to provide a fertile ground for future research in multiple directions.

5.3 Future Research

While many future research directions are possible, I highlight only a few

that are more fundamental and constitute a significant examination of this

dissertation’s models and results.

First, given the strong results of the empirical study, a larger, less firm

specific study is required. The study, which would preferably be a cross­

industry study, would serve to examine whether the results are firm specific,

industry specific, or indeed more general. Given the nature of XChem’s lack

of supplier management strategy as pertaining to the factors examined, the

results and hypotheses must be confirmed in other settings. Lessons learned

in this study will be utilized to enhance such a study, both in broad concept

as well as in the definition of survey instruments and measures.

222

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Secondly, a codifiability based information model could be developed.

Such a model would serve to enrich the study of interactions among trans­

acting entities (players, firms). Building a general model in which informa­

tion deficiency is placed on the transaction rather than on one of the players

would enhance and complete existing information based models and can be

used to examine various types of situations and their implications for mar­

kets, exchanges and supporting systems.

Thirdly, the framework developed in Chapter 2 uses some specific func­

tional forms, some of which are generalized in Chapter 3. While the complex­

ity of the model may limits the ability to generalize functions and still get

meaningful significant results, it is important to determine the robustness of

the results obtained to more general assumptions on these functions.

Fourthly, the framework of Chapter 2 and 3 can be expanded to examine

even a broader range of factors. By extending the framework to multiple

buyers and/or multiple suppliers, issues such as transaction specificity and

its effects could be studied. This would also allow examination of result­

ing market structure, thus fully combining the management and economics

approaches. The latter are mostly interested in a bird’s eye view of the mar­

ket to examine equilibrium based market structure and the former is more

223

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
concerned with the implications for firms’ strategies. When multiple buyers

and suppliers are part of the model, both the participants strategy can be

analyzed and the resulting structure. Futher more, with such a construct,

the important factor of switching costs and its interaction with codifiability

could be examined. High codifiability should reduce switching costs and

thus allow even a stronger tendency to use markets than was shown in this

research. On the other hand, high switching costs may result in longer-term

relationships, which would result in higher transferability of knowledge from

one partner to the other, but not to other partners. It is not clear how

performance would be affected, and it offers an exciting venue for research.

Finally, Chapter 4’s framework could be used to investigate how invest­

ments in information systems affect the balance between contracts and spot-

market transactions. Specifically, such investments may affect and interact

with transaction codifiability, which has been shown to drive the mix of con­

tracts and spot-markets.

These future directions seem to indicate, together, the promise of a fruit­

ful and deep research program that may provide both an inspiration to its

author and continuing contributions of practical relevance in improving sup­

plier management in industry.

224

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Bibliography

[1] Abel, A. 1983. Optimal Investment Under Uncertainty. American Eco­

nomic Review. 73, ‘228 - ‘233.

[2] Abel, A. 1990. Consumption and Investment. In Handbook of Monetary

and Economics, B. Friedman and F. Hahn. North-Holland, New York.

[3] Abel, A., A. Dixit, J. Eberly AND R. Pindyck. 1996. Options, The

Value of Capital, and Investment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics

A u g u st, 753-777.

[4] Allaz, B. 199*2. Oligopoly, Uncertainty and Strategic Forward Transac­

tions. International Journal of Industrial Organization 10, 297-308.

[5] Allaz, B., AND J.-L. Vila. 1993. Cournot Competition, Forward Markets

and Efficiency. Journal of Economic Theory 59, 1-16.

225

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[6] Anton, J. J. and Yao, D. A., 1989. Split Awards, Procurement, and

Innovation. Rand Journal of Economics Vol. 20 No. 4, 538-552.

[7] Bailey, E. 1972. Peak Load Pricing with Regulatory Constraint. Journal

of Political Economy 80, 662-679.

[8] Bailey, E., AND L. White. 1974. Reversals in Peak and Offpeak Prices.

The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5(1), 75- 92.

[9] Bames-Schuster, D., Y. Bassok AND R. Anupundi. 1998. Coordina­

tion and Flexibility in Supply Contracts with Options. Working paper,

J.L. Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University,

Evanston, IL.

[10] Bertsimas, D., I. Popescu and J. Sethuraman, 2000, “Moment Prob­

lems and Semidefinite Optimization” Working Paper, Sloan School of

Management, MIT, April.

[11] Birge, J. 2000. Option Methods for Incorporating Risk into Linear Ca­

pacity Planning Models Manufacturing & Service Operations Manage­

ment 2:1.

226

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[12] Black, F., AND M. Scholes. 1973. The Pricing of Options and Corporate

Liabilities. Journal of Political Economics 81, 637-654.

[13] Brown, A. 0 ., AND H. Lee. 1997. Optimal ’Pay-to-Delay’ Capacity

Reservation with Application to the Semiconductor Industry. Working

paper, Department of Industrial Engineering and Engineering Manage­

ment, Stanford University, Stanford, CA.

[14] Buckley, P., AND J. Michie. 1996. Firms, Organizations and Contracts.

Oxford University Press, New York.

[15] Chambers, M.J., AND R.J. Bailey. 1996. A Theory of Commodity Price

Fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy 104(5), 924-957.

[16] Chao, H., AND H. Huntington. 1998. Designing Competitive Electricity

Markets. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

[17] Christy, D. P., and Grout, J. R., 1994. Safeguarding Supply Chain Rela­

tionships. International Journal of Production Economics 36, 233-242.

[18] Clark, J. 1961. Competition as a Dynamic Process. Brookings Institu­

tion, Washington, D.C.

227

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[19] Clemons, Eric K. and Kleindorfer, Paul R. 1992. An Economic Analysis

of Interorganizational Information Technology. Decision Support Sys­

tems. 8(5) 431-446.

[20] Clemons, Eric K., Reddi, Sashidhar P. and Row, Michael C. 1993. The

Impact of Information Technology on the Organization of Economic Ac­

tivity: The ‘Move to the Middle’ Hypothesis. Journal of Management

Information Systems. 10(2) 9-35.

[21] Crew, M., AND P. Kleindorfer. 1976. Peak Load Pricing with a Diverse

Technology The Bell Journal of Economics 7(1), 207-231.

[22] Crew, M., AND P. Kleindorfer. 1986. The Economics of Public Utility

Regulation. The MIT Press, Cambridge.

[23] Deaton, A., AND G. Lazoque. 1996. Competitive Storage and Commod­

ity Price Dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 104(5), 896-923.

[24] Dixit, A. K., AND R. S. Pindyck. Investment under Uncertainty. Prince­

ton University Press.

[25] Dunn, K., AND C. Spatt. Forthcoming. Call Options, Points and Dom­

inance Restrictions on Debt Contracts. Journal of Finance.

228

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[26] Dyer, J. F., 1995. Specialized Supplier Networks as a Source of Com­

petitive Advantage: Evidence from the Auto Industry. Strategic Man­

agement Journal 17(4) 271-291.

[27] Erhun, F., P. Keskinocak AND S. Tayur. 2000. Spot Markets for Ca­

pacity and Supply Chain Coordination. Working paper, GSIA, Carnegie

Mellon University.

[28] Friedman, J. W. 1986. Game Theory with Applications to Economics.

New York: Oxford University Press.

[29] Friedman, J. W. 1988. On the Strategic Importance if Prices versus

Quantities. RAND Journal o f Economics 19(4).

[30] Gale, D., and Nikaido, H., 1965. The Jacobian Matrix and the Global

Univalence of Mappings. Mathematisch Annalen 159 81-93.

[31] Gassenheimer, J. B., Calantone, R. J., and Scully, J. I., 1995. Supplier

Involvement and Dealer Satisfaction: Implications for Enhancing Chan­

nel Relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing. 10(2)

pp. 7-19.

229

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[32] Helper, S., and MacDuffie J. P., 2002. B2B and Modes of Exchange:

Evolutionary and Transformative Effects, to appear in The Global In­

ternet Economy. Kogut, B., Editor.

[33] Helper, S., and Sako, M., 1995. Supplier Relations in Japan and the

United States: Are They Converging?” Sloan Management Review ,

36(3) 77-84.

[34] Hiebert, L.D., 1989. Cost Flexibility and Price Dispersion. The Journal

of Industrial Economics 38, 103-109.

[35] Holmstrom, B., 1982. Moral Hazard in Teams. Bell Journal of Eco­

nomics 13(2) 324-340.

[36] Huchzermeier, A., AND C. H. Loch. 2001. Project Management Under

Risk: Using the Real Options Approach to Evaluate Flexibility in R&D.

Management Science 47(1), 85-101.

[37] Inkpen, Andrew C., and Dinur, A., 1998. The Transfer and Management

of Knowledge in the Multinational Corporation: Considering Context,

Carnegie Bosch Institute Working Paper 98-16.

230

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[38] Joksow, P. L., 1987. Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Invest­

ments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets. The American Economic

Review 77(1) 168-185.

[39] Kalwani, M. U., and Narayandas, N., 1995. Long-Term Manufacturer-

Supplier Relationships: Do They Pay Off for Supplier Firms? Journal

of Marketing. 59 1-16.

[40] Kawai, M. 1983. Spot and Futures Prices of Nonstorable Commodi­

ties Under Rational Expectations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics

M ay, 235-254.

[41] Kleindorfer, P., D.J. Wu AND C. Fernando. 2001. Strategic Gaming

in Electric Power Marktes. European Journal of Operational Research

130(1), 156-168.

[42] Kogut, B., 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of

the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Stud­

ies, Fourth Quarter.

[43] Kreps, D., AND J. Scheinkman. 1983. Quantity Precommitment and

Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes. Bell Journal of Eco­

nomics 14, 326-337.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[44] Lazear E., and Rosen, S., 1981. Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum

Labor Contracts. Journal of Political Economy. 89(5) 841-864.

[45] Macbeth, D. K., 1987. Supplier Management in Support of JIT Activity:

A research Agenda. International Journal of Operations and Production

Management 7(4) 53*63.

[46] McMillan, J., 1990. Managing Suppliers: Incentive Systems in the

Japanese and US Industry. California Management Review 4(32) 38-55.

[47] Merton, R. 1973. The Theory of Rational Option Pricing. Bell Journal

of Economics and Management Science 4, 141-183.

[48] Nalebuff, B. J., and Stiglitz, J. E., 1983. Prizes and Incentives: Towards

a General Theory of compensation and competition. Rand Journal of

Economics. 14(1) 21-43.

[49] Newbery, D., AND J. Stiglitz. 1981. The Theory of Commodity Price

Stabilization: A Study in the Economics of Risk. Oxford University

Press, New York.

[50] Newman, R. G. (1988). Single Source Qualification. Journal of Purchas­

ing and Materials Management, 24(Summer) 10-16.

232

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[51] Rosen, J. B., 1965. Existence and Uniqueness of Equilibrium Points for

Concave n-person Games. Econometrica 47 1353-1366.

[52] Rothschild, M. AND J. Stiglitz. 1971. Increasing Risk: II. Its Economics

Consequences. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 66-84.

[53] Schwartz, E.S. 1997. The Stochastic Behavior of Commodity Prices:

Implications for Valuation and Hedging. Journal of Finance L 11(3),

Ju ly , 923-973.

[54] Serel, D., M. Dada AND H. Moskowitz. 2001. Sourcing Decisions with

Capacity Reservation Contract. European Journal of Operational Re­

search 131(3), 635-648.

[55] Seshadri, S., 1995. Bidding for Contests. Management Science. 41(4)

561-576.

[56] Spinier, S., A. Huchzermeier AND P. R. Kleindorfer. 2000. Capacity

Allocation and Pricing of Capital Goods Production. Working Paper,

W harton Risk Management and Decision Processes Center, The Uni­

versity of Pennsylvania, November.

233

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[57] Stigler, G. 1939. Production and Distribution in the Short-Run. Journal

of Political Economy 305-327.

[58] Stump, R. L., 1995. Antecedents of Purchasing Concentration: A Trans­

action Cost Explanation. Journal of Business Research. 34 145-157.

[59] Szulanski, G., 1996. Exploring internal stickness: Impediments to the

transfer of best practice within the firm. Strategic Management Journal,

17; pg. 27-43

[60] Tayur, S., R. Ganeshan AND M. Magazine. 1999. Quantitative Models

for Supply Chain Management Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

[61] 2001. Time to Rebuild: B2B Exchanges. The Economist. May 19, 55-56.

[62] Tobin, J. 1969. A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory.

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking February, 15-29.

[63] Trevelen, M., 1987. Single Sourcing: A Management Tool for the

quality Supplier. Journal of Purchasing and Materials Management.

23(Spring) 19-24.

[64] Trigeorgis, L. 1997. Real Options. MIT Press.

234

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
[65] Varian, H. 1992. Microeconomic Analysis 3rd edition. W. W. Norton &:

Company, Inc.

[66] Wang, E. T. G., and Seidmann, A. 1995. Electronic Data Interchange:

Competitive Externalities and Strategic Implementation Policies. Man­

agement Science. 41(3).

[67] W atts, C. A., and Hahn, C. K., 1993). Supplier Development Programs:

An Empirical Analysis. International Journal of Purchasing and Mate­

rials Management, Spring, 10-17.

[68] Williamson, O. 1966. Peak Load Pricing and Optimal Capacity under

Indivisibility Constraints. The American Economic Rewew 56(4), 816-

827.

[69] Williamson, O. E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and An­

titrust Implications. New York: The Free Press.

[70] Williamson, O. E., 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York:

Oxford University Press.

[71] Wu, D.J., P. Kleindorfer AND Y. Sim. 2001. Optimal Capacity Expan­

sion in the Presence of Capacity Options. Working Paper, Department

235

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of Operations and Information Management, The Wharton School, Uni­

versity of Pennsylvania.

[72] Wu, D.J., P. Kleindorfer, Y. Sun AND J. E. Zhang. 2001. The Price

of a Real Option on Capacity. Working Paper, Department of Opera­

tions and Information Management, The Wharton School, University of

Pennsylvania.

[73] Wu, D.J., P. Kleindorfer AND J. E. Zhang. Forthcoming (2001). Op­

timal Bidding and Contracting Strategies for Capital-Intensive Goods.

European Journal of Operational Research.

[74] Wu, D.J., P. Kleindorfer AND J. E. Zhang. 2001. Optimal Bidding and

Contracting Strategies in the Deregulated Electric Power Market: Part

II. In Proceedings of the Thirty-fourth Annual Hawaii International Con­

ference on System Sciences (CD ROM), R.H. Sprague, Jr. IEEE Com­

puter Society Press, Los Alamitos, California.

[75] Zander, U., and Kogut, B., 1995. Knowledge and the speed of the trans­

fer and imitation of organizational capabilities: An empirical test; ;

Organization Science, Jan/Feb.

236

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like