You are on page 1of 4

SCHOLARLY COMMUNICATION

Open access in the real world


Confronting economic and legal reality

by Rick Anderson

pen access to scholarly information is a hot­ they created. Then there is the question of whether
O button issue that quickly triggers heated dis­
cussion— especially if the topic arises in a mixed
access to information that has been created with
the support of public funds should be restricted
group of librarians and publishers. Sometimes the at all.
discussion ends up generating useful ideas and prac­ These and other issues surrounding open ac­
tical solutions to real-world problems; too often, cess are important, and they deserve serious con­
it leads to nothing more than facile phrasemaking sideration. Serious consideration however, requites
or spluttering accusation. the recognition of certain legal and economic re­
Open access has become an increasingly im­ alities. While choices made by authors, publishers,
portant and potentially divisive issue in recent and librarians do have an effect on the informa­
years as journal inflation rates have increased. For tion marketplace, their choices and actions have
many librarians and scholars, journal price infla­ little or no effect on the deeper economic reality
tion is itself the central problem and open access in which that marketplace exists. That reality is
is the solution. According to this view, the fact determined in fundamental ways by two simple
that libraries have to pay for access to some schol­ facts over which the human players in the infor­
arly information is acceptable, but prices are too mation economy have little control, and a produc­
high and are increasing at an insupportable rate; tive and intelligent conversation about open access
the establishment of competitive open-access jour­ must proceed from a recognition of these facts.
nals will force commercial publishers to moderate In addressing them here, it will seem to some
their profit-seeking behavior.1 readers that I am belaboring the obvious, and to
Some believe that scholarly information is a them I apologize—but I think a careful treatment
public good and ought to be available to the pub­ of these points is necessary, because while many
lic at little or no charge.2 Others believe that all in the library profession recognize them as self-
information is inherently free and no one ought to evidently true, there are some who regard them as
have to pay for access to it.3 For still others, the blasphemous.
primary problem lies in the fact that academics are
producing most of the scholarly articles in the The m yth o f free in fo rm atio n
journal marketplace, and that those articles are First, there is no such thing asfree information. Most
then being sold back to the very institutions that people (including most proponents of open ac­
produced them; 4according to this view, the prob­ cess) understand this implicitly, but it might be
lem is not that journals cost money, but that the worthwhile to discuss why this is so. Information
institutions that provide the content are having to is not the same thing as ideas or concepts. Ideas
pay excessively for access to the very content that may be free, but they do not become information
A b o u t the author
Rick Anderson is director o f resource acquisition at the University o f Nevada-Reno, e-mail: rickand@unv.edu
© 2004 Rick Anderson

206 / C&RL News ■ April 2004


until a person creates a symbolic representation of of robust and long-term archiving (which is inte­
them. Doing so is a process of labor, and the cre­ gral to the open access concept and not an issue
ator who undertakes that labor is incurring a cost. with which publishers typically concern themselves
The creator may then choose to distribute the in the print realm), the cost of hiring a Web mas­
information at no charge to others, but that does ter and other content maintenance staff, and the
not mean that the information is fr e e —it means costs of acquiring and maintaining servers. A jour­
that its creator has chosen to absorb the costs of nal publisher that employs its own editorial staff
creation and distribution rather than try to re­ has even greater costs to recover.
cover them. W hen information can be generated One more complicating factor in the scholarly
and distributed very cheaply, or when unrestricted information economy is the fact that many jour­
distribution of it will benefit the creator in some nals, particularly those published by nonprofit so­
way, he or she might choose to make it freely cieties, bear the weight of recovering other costs
available to others, and, in fact, people do so ev­ in addition to those incidental to their ow n cre­
ery day (on the open Web, in casual conversation, ation and distribution. Often subscription rev­
via e-mail, etc.). But the costs o f producing and enues support legitimate organizational activities
distributing that information have not magically that have nothing to do with the journals them­
disappeared in these cases; they have been ab­ selves, such as annual conferences or member ser­
sorbed by the author. vices. For-profit publishers have legitimate costs
Authors are less likely to give away informa­ that must b e met as well, though in some cases
tion that requires a great deal o f time and effort they could lower their prices significantly and still
to create. One way or another they will usually try recover those costs with revenues to spare. (What
to recover their costs or even realize a profit, as kinds of activities nonprofit societies ought to be
will the middlemen who turn the raw informa­ funding from subscription revenues and to what
tion into a publishable product and then distrib­ degree commercial publishers should be allowed
ute that product. Freelance authors usually re­ to seek profit in the scholarly-information mar­
coup their costs by trading copyright for money. ketplace are contentious topics best suited to an­
Scholars (most o f whom are paid a salary to cre­ other essay.)
ate information) usually try to trade their copy­
rights for enhanced reputation or professional ad­ The m yth o f in fo rm a tio n as a p u b lic
vancement by submitting their writings to presti­ good
gious publishing houses or journals. Either way, There is a second basic reality of the information
those who produce labor-intensive, high-quality economy that bears on the open-access question,
information usually try to get something in return and this one is more controversial than the first:
for their labor. Information is nota p ublicgood. Too often, commen­
The cost o f creating information, the cost of tators on the economics o f scholarly information
preparing it for publication, and the cost of dis­ seem to confuse the concept of “a public good”
tributing it are all quite distinct from each other, (meaning something that is owned by the public)
and each type o f cost may ri se or fall independent with “the public good” (meaning the general wel­
o f the other. W hen information was published fare). The fact that something is good for people,
primarily in print format, distribution costs were or the fact that its broad distribution would be
very high; in the electronic realm, they are rela­ beneficial to the general public, does not make it a
tively low. But even in a publishing system in­ public good. What makes something a public good
creasingly characterized by online distribution, is legal public ownership. A municipal park is one
the cost of preparin g information for distribution example of a public good; it is paid for and main­
remains significant.5In the case of many scholarly tained with public funds, and belongs equally to
journals, it is true that editorial tasks are performed all citizens. Most o f the information in scholarly
by contributors at no cost to the publisher. How­ journals does not fit this definition.
ever, even when articles and editorial services are Is it possible for information to b e a public
provided at no charge, the remaining costs of pre­ good? Yes, if it is created and owned by the pub­
paring information for publication are consider­ lic. The information contained in a government
able. These include a publisher’s staffing and over­ document is a public good, which is why govern­
head costs, which are often substantial and may ment documents are exempt from copyright. In­
actually increase when a journal moves from print formation produced by private individuals and
to online. Consider, for example, the added costs organizations, however, is not a public good.

C&RL News ■ April 2004 /207


W hatever its potential benefits to the world at lication can be undertaken without significant cost,
large, however much the public might benefit from will not work in the real world because both of
its free distribution, most information is never­ those premises are demonstrably incorrect. If we
theless the intellectual property of those who cre­ do not bear in mind the intrinsic costliness of
ate it. We can object to that fact if we wish, but it information, we will have a very hard time dis­
is still a legal fact. cussing intelligently the intractable economic re­
This begs a question, o f course, and it is one alities that govern its creation and distribution, let
that bears heavily on the open access issue: What alone formulating pricing and distribution strate­
about information that is produced with govern­ gies that will provide maximum public benefit.
ment funding? If the public is underwriting the Nevertheless, the problems that have led to
creative costs o f that information, should it be the current controversy over journal pricing and
freely available to the public, as som e have ar­ open access are real and need to be solved in some
gued?6 Like all “should” questions, this is one that way. Clearly the status quo is insupportable; if the
has more than one possible answer. One reason­ price of scholarly journals continues to rise at the
able answer is, “It depends on how much govern­ present rate, research libraries will quickly lose
ment funding was involved.” Information created the ability to meet the needs o f their patrons. At
at just about any university or college (public or the same time, it is not reasonable to expect all
private) can be said to have been supported to journal publishers (even nonprofit ones) to move
some degree by public funds— does it follow that immediately into an open-access model simply
every physics professors research article and every because the Internet has lowered the cost of dis­
English instructor’s short story collection should tribution. We w ho are trying to act in the best
pass immediately into the public domain? Perhaps interests o f the public and maximize access to
a certain threshold of government funding should quality information must balance zeal with rea­
be set, such that information created with the son. Most journal publishers are operating in good
substantial support of public funds becomes pub­ faith and need our patience and support, as well as
lic property by definition (as Congressman Martin our exhortations, as they work through the diffi­
O . Sabo has proposed in H.R. 2613, the Public cult process of moving from the old information
Access to Science Act, which is still in committee world into a new one.
as o f this writing). Until such a proposal becomes
law, however, there is a legal reality within which Notes
w e must work: most information created with 1. “Why is SPARC Needed?,” in the Frequently
the support o f governm ent funding is, in fact, Asked Questions section o f the SPARC Web site
copyrightable, and the copyright in most publicly at www.arl.org/sparc/core/index.asp?page=eO
funded information is held by the author. (accessed March 4, 2004).
2. Richard Edwards and David Shulenberger,
Im p lica tio n s fo r open access “The High Cost of Scholarly Journals (and What
Both o f these facts— that information is inher­ to Do About It),” C hange 35, no. 6 (November/
ently costly, and that information is not usually a December 2003): 10.
public good—pose challenges for the idea of open 3. John Perry Barlow, “The Economy of Ideas,”
access. For information to be made freely and per­ W ired 2, no. 3 (March 1994): 84.
manently available to the public, the costs of cre­ 4. Academic Senate Committee on Libraries,
ation, publication, and distribution must be absorbed Columbia University, “Crisis in Scholarly Commu­
by someone other than those who wish to use it. nication: Motion re Stanford’s Reaction to the Seri­
The Internet eliminates most distribution costs, but als Crisis.” Version referred to is dated February 19,
not all of them, and does not affect creative costs 2004, library.cpmc.columbia.edu/hsl/scholcom/
or publication costs to any appreciable degree. clibresolution.html (accessed March 4 , 2004).
Do these inconvenient facts mean that open 5. Donald W. King and Carol Tenopir, “Eco­
access is not desirable or that it cannot work? No. nomic Cost Models of Scientific Scholarly Jour­
But they do define some limits to our options, and nals,” paper presented at the ICSU Press Work­
a recognition o f those limits should lead us to shop, Kebl College, Oxford, UK, April 1998,
have patience with publishers that are moving www.bodley.ox.ac.uk/icsu/kingppr.htm (ac­
more slowly towards that model than we might cessed March 4, 2004).
like. Any proposal that is built on the premise that 6. Edwards and Shulenberger, “The High Cost
information is inherently free, or that online pub­ o f Scholarly Journals.” ■

208 /C&RL News ■ April 2004


C&RL News ■ April 2004 / 209

You might also like