You are on page 1of 3

Ed Thorp

A MATHEMATICIAN ON WALL STREET

Inefficient Markets
The markets are far more efficient when change in the index of about 2 per cent.
viewed from the banks of the Charles than Then we have about 18 per cent left over
from the banks of the Hudson. as the sum of the two deviations d(Friday
Fischer Black close) and d(Monday close). The best we
can do from a min max point of view is
to put this 2 per cent band of correct

T
he “crash of ’87” was the pricing midway between the two closing
most extreme stock mar- prices, which allocates a 9 per cent error
ket price jump of the twen- to each closing price. We conclude that
tieth century. The S&P 500 the S&P 500 was mispriced by at least 9
Index fell over 20 per cent per cent at one or both of the two closes.
in one trading day, meas- Since the whole US market and mar-
ured by the change in closing prices kets worldwide behaved similarly,
from Friday, October 16, 1987 to the we’re looking at a minimum aggregate
close the following Monday, October 19. mispricing of $200 bn or so in the US
But if the market were close to efficient and a comparable additional amount
then both these closing prices must be, worldwide.
to good approximation, “correct.” Let’s
see what this implies. Absolute and relative
Suppose that every security, including mispricing
not only individual issues but “portfo- A security is absolutely mispriced at time t
lios,” has at any time t a “correct” or if I(t) = q(t), i.e. d(t) = 0.We’re of
“true” price Q (t), a current market price course only concerned throughout this
P(t), and a deviation D(t) of the market article with “significant” deviations
price from the correct price, satisfying from zero, as everyone accepts the fact
the equation P(t) = Q (t) + D(t). If the bid- that there is a small irreducible ran-
asked spread and transactions costs are dom “chatter” of d(t) around zero and
“small,” then to a good approximation that this doesn’t violate the spirit of
P(t) is an observable number. Since we’ll market efficiency. For an illustration of
be concerned with the relative sizes of how this chatter can violate market effi-
Q (t) and D(t), it will be useful to consider ciency and produce excess returns, see
the true price and deviation as a propor- my “Statistical Arbitrage,’’ Parts I-VI, in
tion of P(t). Dividing through by P(t) gives Wilmott Sept. ‘04–July ‘05. We argued
I(t) = q(t) + d(t), where I(t) is one unit of the secu- Index changed by approximately 20 per cent in one that the market as a whole was absolutely mis-
rity and q(t) = Q (t)/P(t) is the portion correspon- day. Yet an analysis by Shiller (1987) finds no news priced by at least 9 per cent at the close on at least
ding to the true price and d(t) is the difference or information based explanation either ex ante or one of the two days Friday, October 16, 1987 or
between one unit and the true price portion. If a ex post. This implies that the one-day change in the Monday 19. However we can’t tell from our rea-
security is efficiently priced at time t then d(t) is correct price must have been much less than 20 soning on which of the two days this occurred
very small compared to I(t) and q(t). So, assuming per cent. For discussion purposes, suppose that it and how much greater the mispricing might
market efficiency, the correct price of the S&P 500 were “just” a “two sigma event.” This typically is a have been.

36 Wilmott magazine
We used a relative mispricing argument for spot aberrations from micro efficiency can make That covers the first part of the dictum. What
our deduction. A pair of securities is relatively money from those occurrences and, in doing so, about micro efficiency? If Samuelson and Shiller
mispriced if, given Ii (t) = qi (t) + di (t), i = 1, 2, they tend to wipe out any persistent inefficien- and Jung mean relative mispricing, as I believe
we have cies). In no contradiction to the previous sen- they do, then there is no contradiction and what
tence, I had hypothesized considerable macro the dictum is telling us is that nearly all the
I1 (t) − I2 (t)  = q1 (t) − q2 (t)
inefficiency, the sense of long waves in the time absolute mispricing of individual stocks is due to
or, equivalently, d1 − d2 = 0. It follows that if two series of aggregate indexes of security prices the absolute mispricing of the overall market,
securities are relatively mispriced, either d1 = 0, below and above various definitions of funda- with just a minor amount due to relative mispric-
d2  = 0, or both, so at least one of the securities mental values.” ing of individual securities.
must be absolutely mispriced. The relative mis- They add (2005) that this means “the efficient Just how good is this claimed micro efficien-
pricing is d = d1 − d2 hence at least one of d1 or markets hypothesis works much better for indi- cy? We’ve given general examples in this col-
d2 must satisfy |di |≥ |d |/2 so the magnitude of vidual stocks than it does for the aggregate stock umn, such as the stories of statistical arbitrage
the absolute mispricing for one or both of the
pair must be at least |d |/2 . We applied this gen-
eral argument to the crash of ‘87 with one addi-
What about micro efficiency? If Samuelson
tional assumption: there we compared securities
at two different times and had to use informa- and Shiller and Jung mean relative
tional arguments to tie them together. At the end
of this article we’ll give an example without this
additional step. It is similarly extreme but uses
mispricing, as I believe they do, then there
simultaneously priced securities. is no contradiction
Micro versus macro efficiency
If we form a weighted average, e.g. an index, of market.” They then go on to review evidence in and convertible hedging, and the specific exam-
individual securities, we intuitively would expect recent literature and also test stock market data, ple of the COMS/PALM spinoff. For more on this
some “cancellation” of their absolute mispricing both supporting the Dictum and seeming to con- and other mispriced spinoffs, see Lamont and
with the consequence that the absolute mispric- tradict the triangle inequality! Thaler (2003).
ing of the index tends to be less than the absolute I believe this is resolved using the distinction Derivatives theorists will be amused (if they
mispricing of the components. To see this mathe- between absolute and relative mispricing. To don’t believe the EMH) by another example, the
matically, suppose illustrate with an extreme example, if the market price of Redback Networks (RBAK) compared to
were absolutely mispriced (absolutely macro inef- two of its warrants. In an extreme contradiction
Ii (t) = qi (t) + di (t), i = 1, . . . , n
ficient) but pairs of individual securities were not to rational warrant pricing, both warrants trad-

and that we form the index IM (t) = ni=1 ai Ii (t) relatively mispriced (relatively micro efficient) ed at prices substantially above the price of the

where the ai are non-negative weights with ni=1 then each pair of securities would satisfy stock. Details: The terms for RBAKZ were one
n n
ai = 1. Then IM (t) = i=1 ai qi (t) + i=1 ai di (t) di (t) = dj (t) hence di (t) = c, a constant, for warrant + $9.50 can buy one share of RBAK until
 
and if we assume that ni=1 ai qi (t) = qM (t), we have i = 1, . . . , n. Then dM (t) = ni=1 ai di (t) = c as well Jan. 2, 2011. Similarly one RBAKW warrant +
n
dM (t) = i=1 ai di (t), from which the triangle and macro inefficiency holds if c = 0. In other $5.00 can buy one share of RBAK until the same

inequality gives |dM (t) |≤ ni=1 ai |di (t)| , i.e. the words, all securities are mispriced by the same date. For almost all the first four months of 2004,
absolute mispricing of the index is less than or percentage so the market is mispriced but there is the price of RBAKW exceeded that of RBAK. The
equal to the weighted average of the absolute val- no relative mispricing between securities. Absolute same was generally true for RBAKZ as well. On
ues of the absolute mispricing of the individual macro mispricing (macro inefficiency) of markets Feb. 5, 2004, for example, the prices were RBAK
securities. seems evident to the casual observer, such as the $8.30, RBAKW $12.50 and RBAKZ $15.15! As I’ve
This suggests that inefficiencies are greater 1979-81 interest rate and precious metals price made a living for 38 years by exploiting relative
among individual securities than with the mar- spikes, the crash of ‘87, the dot com “bubble,” and micro mispricing, its magnitude and extent are
ket as a whole. On the other hand we have what current housing prices in large parts of both the of great interest to me.
Jung and Shiller (2002), quoting from a private US and the rest of the world. Exploitation?
letter from Samuelson, call Samuelson’s Dictum: Perhaps by asset reallocation. Note that asset real- Arnott’s argument
“Modern markets show considerable micro location exploits the relative mispricing between Arnott, Hsu and Moore (2004) and Arnott (2005)
^
efficiency (for the reason that the minority who asset classes but not their absolute mispricing. develop an idea for estimating the amount of

Wilmott magazine 37
ED THORP

relative micro inefficiency in the market. Here’s E(IA /IM ) = exp(σ 2 (t2 − t1 )), bought 10 million dollars worth of index futures,
the root idea. Suppose that at the start of each realizing a gain of more than a million dollars
period each security has probability 1/3 of being i.e. the expected growth rate of IA per unit time when the relationship returned to nearly normal.
in each of three states: (1) Pi = (1 + a)Qi , (2) exceeds that of IM by σ 2 . Hsu’s derivation One or both of these two securities, by our earlier
Pi = Qi , or (3) Pi = (1 − a)Qi . At the beginning of assumes that di (t), di (t + 1), . . . are independent, argument, had to be absolutely (macro) mispriced
the next period the state is independent of the as does our example. Under these assumptions by at least 5 per cent.
state in the prior period. Securities are on aver- and the measured effect of about 2 per cent per We have developed a framework for thinking
. √
age fairly priced (absolute macro efficiency) but year, σ = .02 = 14%. about market inefficiencies. In addition to the
individually fluctuate randomly around their This is likely to be quite an underestimate. distinctions between absolute and relative mis-
unknown true price. (The idea works just as well Here’s why. It’s intuitive that regression of d(t) pricing, and between macro and micro ineffi-
with absolute macro inefficiency but the details towards the mean ought to have some associated ciency, we see that the total market value and
are more complicated.) Each state transition has characteristic time. Arnott et al. find that the extent of these inefficiencies appears substan-
probability 1/9. If we form an equally weighted mispricing effect doesn’t vary much if rebalanc- tial. However much of this isn’t, and perhaps
portfolio and rebalance to equal weights at the ing is done quarterly, semi-annually or annually. may never be, linked to specific securities, i.e. it
start of each new period, a calculation shows This suggests that for these time intervals there exists but is not “observable.” Further, much of
that we gain G = 2a2 /(3(1 − a2 )) per period. For are substantial positive correlations between suc- what is observable is not exploitable due to mar-
instance, the transition from state (1) to state (3) cessive d(t), d(t + 1), etc. But then it turns out ket defects, costs, and the tendency of the mis-
pricing to diminish as a consequence of the

As Steve Ross observed, the total market trades that exploit it.
As Steve Ross observed, the total market value
of the available alpha is generally far less than
value of the available alpha is generally far the total market value of the alpha that exists.
Nevertheless, fortunes have been and will
less than the total market value of the continue to be made by extracting the alpha that
is available.
alpha that exists
changes an amount 1 + a to 1 − a for a loss per that as ρ increases from zero, a larger σ 2 is
unit of −2a/(1 + a). The variance σ 2 per period required to produce a given effect, hence the
REFERENCES
of d(t) is 2a2 /3 so the gain per period can be writ- implication that the average relative micro mis- ■ Arnott, Robert D. 2005. What cost 'noise?' Financial
ten as σ 2 /(1 − a2 ). If a = 1/6, for instance, we pricing is likely to be considerably larger than Analysts Journal. March/April: 10-14.
have G = 2/105 or about 2%. 14%. I suspect that ■ Arnott, R., J. Hsu, and P. Moore. 2004. Redefining
Arnott finds, under a number of scenarios E(IA /IM ) = exp((1 − ρ)σ 2 (t2 − t1 )) for ρ  = 0, with Indexation. Research Affiliates.
that may exploit this effect – one of which is ρ perhaps of the form ρ = exp(−k(t2 − t1 )). For ■ Hsu, Jason C. 2004. Cap-weighted portfolios are sub-
equal weighting, that he can get historical ρ = 1/2 and t2 − t1 = 1 year, this gives σ 2 = 0.04 optimal portfolios. Research White Paper #WP5401, Draft,
returns of about 2 per cent more than the market or σ = 0.20, up from σ = 0.14 when ρ = 0. December.
index without offsetting increases in risk. The ■ Jung, J. and R.J. Shiller. 2002. One simple test of
Samuelson’s Dictum for the stock market. Cowles
results if due to this cause, suggest that the rela- The Crash of ‘87, Day 2 Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1386, October.
tive micro inefficiency may have order of magni- The day after the 20 per cent drop in the S&P 500, I
■ Jung, J. and R.J. Shiller. 2005. Samuelson’s Dictum and
tude of fourteen percent or more! Clearly the observed the S&P futures contract trading at
the stock market. Economic Inquiry. 43(2): 221-228.
root idea here can be extended to more realistic about 190 and the S&P index trading at about 220, ■ Lamont, O.A. and R.H. Thaler. 2003. Can the market add
probability distributions and transition probabil- for a relative macro mispricing of more than and subtract? Mispricing in tech stock carve-outs, Journal
ities, with essentially the same type of result. Hsu 10per cent. As experienced index arbitrageurs, we of Political Economy. 111(2): 227-268.
(2004) gives a general derivation where di (t) is at Princeton Newport Partners knew that, ordinar- ■ Schiller, Robert J. 1987. Investor behavior in the October
white noise with mean zero and variance per ily, the two should and did satisfy “no arbitrage” 1987 stock market crash: survey evidence. Cowles
unit time σ 2 . He finds in this case the expected conditions to within a fraction of a percent. We Foundation Discussion Paper 853, NBER Working Paper
value of the ratio IA /IM , where IA is an equal therefore shorted a little more than 10 million Series, Working Paper No. 2446, November 1987.
weighted index satisfies dollars worth of a diversified basket of stocks and W

38 Wilmott magazine

You might also like