You are on page 1of 21

American Economic Association

Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand


Author(s): Olivier Jean Blanchard and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 77, No. 4 (Sep., 1987), pp. 647-666
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1814537
Accessed: 24-05-2016 15:42 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Monopolistic Competition and the Effects
of Aggregate Demand

By OLIVIER JEAN BLANCHARD AND NOBUHIRO KIYOTAKI*

How important is monopolistic competition to an understanding of the effects of


aggregate demand on output? We ask the question at three levels. Can monopolis-
tic competition, by itself, explain why aggregate demand movements affect output?
Can it, together with other imperfections, generate effects of aggregate demand in
a way that perfect competition cannot? If so, can it give an accurate account of the
response of the economy to aggregate demand movements? The answers are no,
yes, and yes.

Monopolistic competition provides a con- Section I builds a simple general equi-


venient conceptual framework in which to librium model, with goods, labor, and mon-
think about price decisions, and appears to ey, and monopolistic competition in both the
describe many markets more accurately than goods and the labor markets. It then char-
perfect competition. But, how important is acterizes the equilibrium. Section II char-
monopolistic competition for macroeconom- acterizes the inefficiency associated with mo-
ics? In particular, how important is monopo- nopolistic competition and shows that it is
listic competition to an understanding of the associated with an aggregate demand exter-
effects of aggregate demand on economic nality. It shows that this externality cannot,
activity? This is the question we analyze in however, explain why pure aggregate de-
this paper. mand movements affect output. In particu-
One can ask the question at three levels. lar, it cannot explain why changes in nomi-
First, using perfect competition as a bench- nal money have real effects. The answer to
mark, can monopolistic competition, by the first question is therefore negative. Sec-
itself, explain why aggregate demand move- tion III studies the effects of "menu costs"
ments affect output? Second, can monopolis- when combined with monopolistic competi-
tic competition, together with some other tion. It shows that small (second-order) costs
imperfection, generate effects of aggregate of changing prices may lead to large (first-
demand in a way that perfect competition order) changes in output and welfare in re-
cannot? Third, taking as given that aggregate sponse to changes in nominal money. It
demand movements affect output, can mo- shows the close relation between this result
nopolistic competition give a more accurate and the aggregate demand externality iden-
account of the response of the economy to tified in Section II. The answer to the second
aggregate demand shocks? The paper ana- question is therefore positive. Section IV
lyzes these three questions in turn. takes as given that prices and wages do not
adjust to movements in nominal money, and
draws the implications of monopolistic com-
petition with fixed costs for the behavior of
output, productivity, profits, and entry by
*Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge MA
02139, and University of Wisconsin, Madison, WI 53706,
new firms in response to fluctuations in ag-
respectively. We thank Andrew Abel, Laurence Ball, gregate demand. These implications fit the
Russell Cooper, Rudiger Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, facts and our answer to the third question is
Mark Gertler, Robert Hall, Andrew John, Kenneth
positive. We conclude by discussing how the
Rogoff, Jeffrey Sachs, Lawrence Summers, Martin
Weitzman, and two referees for discussions and sugges-
implications for entry may in turn help ex-
tions. We thank the National Science Foundation and plain the lack of adjustment of prices and
the Sloan Foundation for financial support. wages.
647

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
648 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

Our paper is closely related to three recent good and provides services.1'2 Money is also
strands of research, on general equilibrium the numeraire, so that firms and workers
implications of monopolistic competition quote prices and wages in terms of money;
(Oliver Hart, 1982, and Martin Weitzman, this plays no role in this and the next sec-
1982, in particular), on "menu costs" or tion, but will become important in Section
"near rationality" (N. Gregory Mankiw, III.
1985, George Akerlof and Janet Yellen, The third choice is to make assumptions
1985a, b) and on "coordination failures" about utility and technology that lead to
(Russell Cooper and Andrew John, 1985, in demand and pricing relations, which are as
particular). We shall point out specific rela- close to traditional ones as possible, so as to
tions as we proceed. Our intent is in part to allow an easy comparison with standard
show their relation and macroeconomic im- macroeconomic models. In effect, we follow
plications in the specific context of monopo- Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz (1977) in
listic competition. adopting constant elasticity of substitution
specifications in utility and production.3
I. A Model of Monopolistic Competition These specifications lead to log-linear de-
mand and pricing functions, and rule out
In developing a model of monopolistic potentially important nonlinearities as well
competition, we make four main choices. as a potential source of multiple equilibria.4
Because we want to focus on both wage and Finally, the model is static and we leave
price decisions, we construct a model with the potentially important dynamic implica-
both households and firms, with separate tions of monopolistic competition to future
labor and goods markets. Both labor and work.'
goods markets are monopolistically competi-
tive. The assumption of monopolistic com- A. The Model
petition in both sets of markets is made for
symmetry and transparence rather than for The economy is composed of m firms,
realism. For some purposes, however, the each producing a specific good that is an
model that has both wage and price setters is imperfect substitute for the other goods, and
not the simplest, and we also occasionally n consumer-workers, households for short,
focus on a special case, that can be thought
of as an economy of household-firms, each
producing a differentiated good; in that case,
there is only one set of price setters and the 'A Clower Constraint would lead to similar results.
analysis is simplified. Developing an explicitly intertemporal model to justify
why money is positively valued did not seem worth the
The second choice follows from the need
additional complexity in this context.
to avoid Say's Law, or the result that the 2There are, however, differences between money and
supply of goods produced by the monopolis- a standard nonproduced good that arise from the fact
tically competitive firms automatically gen- that real, not nominal, money balances enter utility; we
shall point out these differences as we go along.
erates its own demand. To avoid this, agents
3The main alternative to product diversification a la
must have the choice between these goods Dixit-Stiglitz, is geographic dispersion. This is the ap-
and something else. In the standard macro- proach followed by Weitzman.
economic model, the choice is between con- 4Our assumptions imply a constant elasticity of de-
sumption and savings. In other models of mand, and a constant markup of price over marginal
cost. Some recent work on the implications of imperfect
monopolistic competition, the choice is be-
competition for macroeconomics has precisely focused
tween produced goods and a nonproduced on why markups may not be constant, either because of
good (Hart, for example). Here, we shall changes in elasticity of demand, or of changes in the
assume that the choice is between buying degree of collusion between firms. See, for example,
Stiglitz (1984), Julio Rotemberg and Garth Saloner
goods and holding money. This is most sim-
(1986), and Mark Bils (1985).
ply and crudely achieved by having real 5Kiyotaki (1985b) studies the implications of mo-
money balances in the utility function. Thus, nopolistic competition for investment and the likelihood
money plays the role of the nonproduced of multiple equilibria.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 649

each of them selling a type of labor which is of firm i, and W4 denotes the nominal wage
an imperfect substitute for the other types. associated with labor type j. The firm maxi-
As a result, each firm and each worker has mizes (2) subject to the production function
some monopoly power.6 We now describe (1). It takes as given nominal wages and the
the problem faced by each firm and each prices of the other outputs. It also faces a
household. downward-sloping demand schedule for its
Firms are indexed by i, i = 1,..., m. Each product, that will be derived below as a
firm i has the following technology: result of utility maximization by households.
We assume that the number of firms is large
enough that taking other prices as given is
(1) Yi = NE N0?- l)/a3 equivalent to taking the price level as given.
j =1 Households are indexed by j, j = 1, .. ., n.
Household j supplies labor of type j. It
where Yi denotes the output of firm i. Nij derives utility from leisure, consumption, and
denotes the quantity of labor of type j used real money balances. Its utility function is
in the production of output i. There are n given by
different types of labor, indexed j, j =
1,..., n. The production function is a CES (3) U = ( m'A'l- )Cj) Y( Mj'1P )1 Y_ N#j
production function, with all inputs entering
symmetrically. Introducing fixed costs would m (OA(@ - 1))
not affect the analysis of the first three sec-
where j = f C,1)/O
tions where we assume the number of firms
to be fixed; we shall, for simplicity, intro-
duce them only in the last section where they 1m 1A(1 - )
matter. and p= ( f pl)- A
The two parameters characterizing the m i=1
technology are a and a. The parameter a is
the elasticity of substitution of inputs in The first term in utility is a consumption
production. The parameter a is the inverse index (basket) that gives the effect of the
of the degree of returns to scale; a -1 is the consumption of goods on utility. C,j denotes
elasticity of marginal cost with respect to the consumption of good i by household j,
output, elasticity of marginal cost for short and C1 is a CES function of the C,,s. All
in what follows. To guarantee the existence types of consumption goods enter utility
of an equilibrium, we restrict a to be strictly symmetrically. The parameter 6 is the elas-
greater than unity, and a to be equal to or ticity of substitution between goods in util-
greater than unity. ity. To guarantee existence of an equi-
The firm maximizes profits. Nominal prof- librium, 0 is restricted to be greater than
its for firm i are given by unity. The constant in front of C), that de-
pends on 6 and on the number of products
n
m, is a convenient normalization with the
(2) Vi=pi I E WjNij, implication that an increase in the number
j=1
of products does not affect marginal utility
after optimization.
where Pi denotes the nominal output price The second term gives the effect of real
money balances on utility. y is a parameter
between zero and one. Nominal money bal-
6Since in equilibrium each labor supplier sells some ances are deflated by the nominal price in-
of his (her) labor to all firms, it is more appropriate to
dex associated with CJ. We shall refer to P as
think of labor suppliers as craft unions, or syndicates as
the price level.
in Hart, rather than individual workers. However, since
we want to analyze labor supply and consumption
The third term in utility gives the disutility
decisions simultaneously, we shall continue to refer to from work, N) is the amount of labor sup-
labor suppliers as "consumer-workers" or "households." plied by household j. The term ,B-1 is the

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
650 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

elasticity of marginal disutility of labor; /3 is and


assumed to be equal to or greater than m \1/(1 - )

unity.7'1 P-(l/m) Ep,l-0


Households maximize utility subject to a
budget constraint. Each household takes
prices and other wages as given. Again we The demand functions for goods and labor
assume that n is large enough that taking are given by
other wages as given is equivalent to taking
n
the nominal wage level as given. It also faces
a downward-sloping demand schedule for its (7) Yi = Y. Cij = KY(PiIP)
j=1
type of labor, which will be derived as the
result of profit maximization by firms. The
m
budget constraint is given by
m

(8) Nj= E Nij= KYa(Wj/W)


m m

(4) QP1Cj+Mj'=WjNj+Mj+ EVj, i =1


i=l i=l

where M. denotes the initial endowment of


money, and Vij is the share of profits of firm where the wage index W is given by
i going to household j.
1 n /-
B. The Equilibrium
(9) W= n j =
The derivation of the equilibrium is given
in the Appendix. The equilibrium can be The price and wage rules are given by
characterized by a relation between real mon-
ey balances and aggregate demand, a pair of
(10) (Pt/P) = [(o/(0-1))Kp
demand functions for goods and labor and by
a pair of price and wage rules.
The relation between real money balances X (W/P) Y ]Af/+e(Gl))
and real aggregate consumption expendi-
tures, which we shall call aggregate demand
i=l,..., m
for short, is given by
(11) ( Wj/W) =[(a(a-1))K
(5) Y=K(M/P)
X (Pl/W) ya(,8-1)] 1(+ 0(#- 1))
where
j= l,...,n
/n m

(6) v = E PI v Dr /D The letters K, Kc, K n Kp, and Kw are


constants that depend on the parameters of
the technology and the utility function as
well as the number of firms and households.
7The assumption that utility is homogeneous of de- We interpret these equations, starting with
gree one in consumption and real money balances, as
the relation between real money balances
well as additively separable in consumption and real
money balances on the one hand, and leisure, on the and aggregate demand. First-order condi-
other, eliminates income effects on labor supply. Under tions for households imply that desired real
these assumptions, competitive labor supply would just money balances are proportional to con-
be a function of the real wage, using the price index sumption expenditures. Aggregating over
defined in the text. It also implies that utility is linear in
households and using the fact that, in equi-
income and this facilitates welfare evaluations.
8For reasons that will be clear below, we exclude the librium, desired money is equal to actual
case where both a and f are equal to unity. money gives equation (5).

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 651

The demand for each type of good relative An increase in the aggregate real wage
to aggregate demand is a function of the (W/P) leads household j to increase its
ratio of its nominal price to the nominal labor supply, thus to decrease its relative
price index, the price level, with elasticity wage (W//W). An increase in aggregate de-
(- 0). The demand for labor by firms is a mand leads, if ,B is strictly greater than
derived demand for labor; it depends on the unity, to an increase in the relative wage. If
demand for goods. The demand for each ,B is equal to unity, if the marginal disutility
type of labor is a function of the ratio of its of labor is constant, workers supply more
nominal wage to the nominal wage index, labor at the same relative wage, in response
with elasticity (- a). to an increase in aggregate demand.
We now consider the price rule. Given the
price level, each firm is a monopolist and C. Symmetric Equilibrium
decides about its real (or relative) price P1/P.
An increase in the real wage (W/P) shifts Equilibrium and symmetry, both across
the marginal cost curve upward, leading to firms and across households, implies that all
an increase in the relative price. An increase relative prices and all relative wages must be
in aggregate demand shifts the demand curve equal to unity. Thus, using Pi = P for all i
for each product upward; if the firm oper- and W4/= W for all j, and substituting in
ates under decreasing returns, the marginal equations (10) and (11) gives
cost curve is upward sloping and the relative
price increases. Under constant returns, the (12) (P7W) = (0/(O-1))KPYa-l;
shift in demand has no effect on the relative
price.
(13) (W1/P) = (a1/(a-1))KWYa(fl-1).
We finally consider the wage rule, equa-
tion (11). We can think of households as Equation (12), obtained from the individ-
solving their utility-maximization problem in ual price rules and the requirement that all
two steps. They first solve for the allocation prices be the same, gives the price wage ratio
of their wealth, including labor income, be- (P7W) as a function of output. If firms
tween consumption of the different products operate under strictly decreasing returns, the
and real money balances. After this step, the price wage ratio is an increasing function of
assumption that utility is linearly homoge- the level of output. Equivalently, the real
neous in consumption and real money bal- wage (W/P) consistent with firms' behavior
ances implies that utility is linear in wealth, is a decreasing function of output. We shall
thus linear in labor income. The next step is refer to equation (12) as the "aggregate price
to solve for the level of labor supply and the rule."
nominal wage. Given that utility is linear in Equation (13), obtained from the individ-
labor income, we can think of households as ual wage rules and the requirement that all
monopolists maximizing the surplus from wages be the same, gives the real wage (W/P)
supplying labor. Formally, if IL denotes the as a function of output. If /3 is strictly greater
constant marginal utility of real wealth, than unity, that is, if workers have increasing
households solve in the second step: marginal disutility of work, an increase in
output, that leads to an increase in the
derived demand for labor, requires an in-
max ,u(Wj/P)ANj - NJ
crease in the real wage. The real wage con-
sistent with households' behavior is an in-
Nj = K,Y( W/W) creasing function of output. We shall refer to
equation (13) as the "aggregate wage rule."
The real wage relevant for worker j is Equations (12) and (13) give (W/P) and
Wj/P, which we can write as the product Y. The value of (M/P) follows from (5).
(Wj/W)(W/P). The demand for labor of The equilibrium is characterized graphically
type j is a function of the relative wage in Figure 1. As (12) and (13) are log-linear,
(Wj/W) as well as of aggregate demand. we measure log(W/P) on the vertical axis

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
652 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

cal to that in Figure 1, except for the fact


wage rule that the aggregate wage rule is horizontal.
This special case is convenient as it allows
- pA sope,aB -) to concentrate on the interactions between
price setters rather than between both price
slope -(a- I) and wage setters. The assumption of con-
stant marginal utility of leisure is unattrac-
tive, but equations (5) and (14) admit an
price rule
alternative interpretation: they can also be
derived as the equations characterizing the
log Y (log (M/P)+constant)
equilibrium of an economy with many
household-firms, each producing a differenti-
FIGURE 1. THE MONOPOLISTICALLY COMPETITIVE
EQUILIBRIUM ated good with a constant returns technol-
ogy and increasing marginal disutility of
work, and deriving utility from the consump-
and log(Y) (or log(M/P) as the two are tion of all goods and money services.9 Under
linearly related) on the horizontal axis. If a that interpretation, (a-1)) stands for the
and /3 are both strictly greater than unity, elasticity of marginal utility of leisure.
the aggregate wage rule is upward sloping,
while the aggregate price rule is downward II. Inefficiency and Externalities
sloping. The equilibrium determines the real
wage and output. Given output, we obtain A. Comparing Monopolistic Competition
the equilibrium level of real money balances and Perfect Competition
and given nominal money, we finally obtain
the price level. To characterize the inefficiency associated
Figure 1 looks like the characterization of with monopolistic competition, we first com-
equilibrium under perfect competition, with pare the equilibrium to the competitive equi-
an upward-sloping labor supply curve and a librium. The competitive equilibrium is
downward-sloping labor demand. What is, derived under the same assumptions about
therefore, the effect of monopolistic competi- tastes, technology, and the number of firms
tion? Before turning to that issue, we briefly and households, but assuming that each firm
consider a special case of the model that will (each household) takes its price (wage) as
be convenient later. given when deciding about its output (labor).
The competitive equilibrium is very simi-
D. A Convenient Special Case lar to the monopolistically competitive one.
The demand functions for goods and labor
In the special case of the model where the are still given by equations (7) and (8). The
marginal utility of leisure is constant so that price and wage rules are identical to equa-
3 = 1, the characterization of the equilibrium tions (10) and (11), except for the absence of
is much simpler. The relation between real O/(O -1) in the price rules and the absence
money balance and aggregate demand is still of a/(a -1) in the wage rules (the K's are
given by equation (5). But, from equation the same in both equilibria). The explanation
(11) and symmetry, the real wage is con- is simple. The term O/(O -1) is the excess of
stant, so that the price rules are now given price over marginal cost, reflecting the de-
by gree of monopoly power of firms in the
goods market; if firms act competitively,
price is instead equal to marginal cost. The
(14) Pji/P =k(M/P)(a-1)A1+(-1)) same explanation applies to households.

where k is an unimportant constant. Equa-


tions (5) and (14) characterize the equi- 9Laurence Ball and David Romer (1987) derive the
librium. The symmetric equilibrium is identi- equilibrium for such an economy.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 653

between goods or between types of labor, the


log(8/( 8 - )) closer is the economy to the competitive
equilibrium. R is an increasing function of a
_ X t ~ / K competitive and /B. If a and ,B are both close to unity, R
X: \aA , wage rule
3 4 , v ~ (labor supply) is small: the existence of monopoly power in
either the goods or the labor markets can
o competitive have a large effect on equilibrium output.10
2 price rule1
" ltog (oJ(o-l)) \ (labor demand)

B. Aggregate Demand Externalities

log Y ( log (M/P)+ constant)


Under monopolistic competition, output
of monopolistically produced goods is too
FIGURE 2. M,ONOPOLISTICALLY COMPETITIVE AND
low. We have shown above that this follows
COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIA
from the existence of monopoly power in
price and wage setting. An alternative way
of thinking about it is that it follows from an
Again, symmetry requires in equilibrium aggregate demand externality.
all nominal and all wages to be the same; The argument is as follows. In the mo-
this gives equations identical to (12) and nopolistically competitive equilibrium, each
(13), but without the terms O/(6 -1) and price (wage) setter has, given other prices, no
-/(a-1). The price wage ratio consistent incentive to decrease its own price (wage)
with firms' behavior is lower in the competi- and increase its output (labor). Suppose
tive case by O/(6 -1) at any level of output; however that all price setters decrease their
the real wage consistent with household's prices simultaneously; this increases real
behavior is lower in the competitive case by money balances and aggregate demand. The
,/(a -1) at any level of output. The mo- increase in output reduces the initial distor-
nopolistically competitive and competitive tion of underproduction and underemploy-
aggregate wage and price rules are drawn in ment and increases social welfare.11
Figure 2. Point A' gives the competitive We now make the argument more precise.
equilibrium; point A gives the monopolisti- By the definition of a monopolistically com-
cally competitive equilibrium. petitive equilibrium, no firm has an incentive
The equilibrium level of real money bal- to decrease its price, and no worker has an
ances is lower in the monopolistic equi- incentive to decrease its wage, given other
librium; the price level is higher. Employ- prices and wages. Consider now a propor-
ment and output are lower. What happens to tional decrease in all wages and all prices,
the real wage is ambiguous and depends on (dP1/Pi)=(dWj/wj)<O, for all i and j,
the degrees of monopoly power in the goods
and the labor markets. If, for example, there
is monopolistic competition in the goods
market but perfect competition in the labor
" Note that, as there are distortions in two sets of
market, then the real wage is unambiguously interrelated markets, the economy is operating inside
lower under monopolistic competition. its production frontier. This point is developed by
Denoting by R the ratio of output in the Rotemberg (1982).
monopolistically competitive equilibrium to llAn alternative way of stating the argument is as
follows: If starting from the monopolistically competi-
output in the competitive equilibrium, R is
tive equilibrium, a firm decreased its price, this would
given by lead to a small decrease in the price level and thus to a
small increase in aggregate demand. While the other
firms and households would benefit from this increase
in aggregate demand, the original firm cannot capture
all of these benefits and thus has no incentive to de-
crease its price. We have chosen to present the argu-
where R is an increasing function of a and ment in the text to facilitate comparison with the argu-
0. The higher the elasticity of substitution ment of Section III.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
654 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

that leaves all relative prices unchanged but shift in the demand for labor increases util-
decreases the price level. ity as the real wage initially exceeds the
Consider first the change in the real value marginal utility of leisure. The third term is
of firms.12 At a given level of output and the real value of the money stock, which
employment, the real value of each firm is increases with the fall in the price level.
unchanged. The decrease in the price level, Thus, utility unambiguously increases."3
however, increases real money balances and The aggregate demand externality implies
aggregate demand. This in turn shifts out- that underproduction is magnified through
ward the demand curve faced by each firm macroeconomic interactions. Consider the
and increases profit: an increase in demand problem faced by an individual firm, with
at a given relative price increases profit as upward-sloping marginal cost and down-
price exceeds marginal cost. Thus, the real ward-sloping demand, taking as given other
value of each firm increases. prices and aggregate demand. Because the
Consider then the effect of a proportional marginal utility of wealth is constant under
reduction of prices and wages on the utility our assumptions, we can measure welfare by
of each household. Consider household j. looking at the sum of consumers' and pro-
We have seen that, once the household has ducers' surplus. If the firm acted competi-
chosen the allocation of his wealth between tively rather than as a monopolist, the price
real money balances and consumption, we would be lower and the surplus would be
can write its utility as larger. This is the familiar partial-equi-
librium effect. But here, in addition, if all
U}=(Ij/P) - NO firms acted competitively and decreased their
prices, aggregate demand would be higher
where ,u is the constant marginal utility of and the demand curve facing each firm would
real wealth and I1 is the total wealth of the shift to the right and welfare would be fur-
jth household. Using the budget constraint, ther increased. This is the additional general
we can express utility as equilibrium effect present here.
Identifying the inefficiency associated with
monopolistic competition as an aggregate
Uj =[ ( Wj/P) Nj - NJ
demand externality does not, however, imply
m that movements in aggregate demand affect
+ tLVij1P +it(Mj/P) output. Aggregate demand changes associ-
i =1 ated with changes in the demand elasticities
facing firms and workers will have real
Utility is the sum of three terms. The effects, and these effects are likely to be
second is profit income in terms of utility; different under perfect and monopolistic
we have seen that each firm's profit goes up competition. These are not, however, the
after an increase in aggregate demand. Thus, effects we want to focus on. For that reason,
this term increases. The first term is the
household's surplus from supplying labor.
At a given level of employment Nj, the pro-
portional change in wages and prices leaves 13 Note that, if we were performing the same experi-
this term unchanged. But the increase in ment in the neighborhood not of the monopolistically
aggregate demand and the implied derived competitive but of the competitive equilibrium, the first
two terms would be equal to zero. The third, however,
increase in employment implies that this term
would still be present. This is one of the implications of
increases: at a given real wage, an outward our use of real money as the nonproduced good. If real
money enters utility, then the competitive equilibrium is
not Pareto optimal, as a small decrease in the price level
increases welfare. This inefficiency of the competitive
12What happens to the real value of firms is obvi- equilibrium disappears if money is replaced by a non-
ously of no direct relevance for welfare. This step is produced good, while the aggregate demand externality
however required to characterize what happens to the under monopolistic competition remains (see Kiyotaki,
utility of households below. 1985a).

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 655

we shall concentrate on changes in nominal the same is true of the utility of a worker
money. But then it is clear that, as equations who does not adjust his relative wage. Thus
(12) and (13) are homogeneous of degree second-order menu costs may prevent firms
zero in P, W, and M, nominal money is and workers from adjusting relative prices
neutral, affecting all nominal prices and and wages. The implication is that nominal
wages proportionately, and leaving output prices and nominal wages do not adjust to
and employment unchanged. Thus some- the change in nominal money. The second
thing else is needed to obtain real effects of part of the argument is to show that the
nominal money. We examine the effects of change in real money balances has first-order
costs of price setting in the next section. effects on welfare; we show that it is indeed
first order, and of the same sign as the
III. Menu Costs and Real Effects of change in money. The argument has very
Nominal Money much the same structure as the aggregate
demand externality argument of the previous
We now introduce small costs of setting section; this coincidence is not accidental
prices, small "menu" costs. Akerlof and and we return to it below.
Yellen (1985a, b) and Mankiw have shown The first part is a direct application of the
how such small costs can lead to large wel- envelope theorem. Consider firms first. Let
fare effects in imperfectly competitive econo- Vi be the value of firm i. Vi is a function of
mies." We apply their argument to the Pi as well as of P, W, and M (Vi=
specific context of monopolistic competition, Vi(Pi, P, W, M)). Let ViJ* be the maximized
derive welfare and output effects as explicit value of firm i, after maximization over Pi;
functions of the underlying parameters, and Vi* =Vi *(P, W, M). The envelope theorem
relate these effects to the externality iden- then says that
tified earlier.
dVl*/dM = aVadM + ( daViaPJ)(dPIydM)
A. The Effects of Small Changes in
Nominal Money = av1/aM.

We start by considering the effects of a To a first order, the effect of a change in


small change in nominal money, dM. The M on the value of the firm is the same
intuitive argument is the following. whether or not it adjusts its price optimally
At the initial nominal prices and wages, in response to the change in M. Exactly the
the change in nominal money leads to a same argument applies to the utility of the
change in aggregate demand, thus to a change household. Thus, second-order menu costs
in the demand facing each firm. If demand is (larger than the second-order loss in utility
satisfied, the change in output implies in or in value) will prevent each firm from
turn a change in the derived demand for changing its price given other prices and
labor, thus a change in the demand facing wages and each worker from changing its
each worker. Unless firms operate under wage given other prices and wages. The im-
constant returns, each firm wants to change plication is that all nominal prices and wages
its relative price. Unless workers have con- remain unchanged, and that the increase in
stant marginal utility of leisure, each worker nominal money implies a proportional in-
wants to change his relative wage. The loss crease in real money balances.
in value to a firm which does not adjust its What remains to be shown is that the
relative price is, however, of second order; increase in real money balances has positive
first-order effects on welfare. However, we
have already shown in the previous section
that the increase in real money balances,
associated with the increase in aggregate de-
14Akerlof and Yellen assume "near rationality" that
is equivalent to rationality subject to second-order costs mand and employment, raises firms' profits
of taking decisions. and the households' surpluses from supply-

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
656 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

ing labor. Thus, it increases welfare in the log (Pi /M)


neighborhood of the monopolistically com- iso profit locus

petitive equilibrium.
There is clearly a close relation between
the aggregate demand externality and the log (Pilog
/M)
(P1 -~~~~~~~~~~th
- price rule
firmof
Pi /M=Ri(P/M)
menu cost argument of this section. This re-
log (Pi/ M) --
lation is most simply shown in the special
case where the marginal utility of leisure is A

constant, where there are no menu costs in


wage setting and where we can concentrate i sing real profit

on the interactions between price setters only.


Equation (14), which gives the individual / ~~~~~~~~I I
price rules in the absence of menu costs, can
A45? I I
log(P/MI) log(P/M) log(P/M)
be rewritten as
FIGURE 3. AGGREGATE DEMAND EXTERNALITIES
(15) Pi/M AND MENU COSTS

= k ( P/M)[' ?(O - 1)(a -1)1/(l+ O(a -1))

Figure 3 plots the price chosen by firm i absent menu costs, each firm would find in
as a function of the price level, both as ratios its interest to increase its price until the
to nominal money. In the presence of mo- economy had returned to point E. In the
nopoly power, the price rule has slope smaller presence of menu costs, however, these menu
than one. We also draw iso-profit loci, giving costs, if large enough, can prevent this move-
combinations of (Pi/M) and (P/M) that ment back to E, so that the economy re-
yield the same level of real profit for the mains at E' and all firms end up with higher
firm.'5 The symmetric monopolistically com- real profits. (A similar argument, although
petitive equilibrium is given by the intersec- slightly more complicated, holds for the gen-
tion of the price rule and the 450 line, point eral model. We shall not present it here.)
E. Point A gives the highest real profit point It is also important to note the specific role
on the 450 line. played by money in this section. The pres-
The aggregate demand externality argu- ence of an aggregate demand externality does
ment can then be stated as follows. Consider not depend on the nature of the nonpro-
a small proportional decrease of prices, keep- duced good, or on the nature of the
ing nominal money constant. The equi- numeraire. The results of this section depend
librium moves from point E to a point like on money being the nonproduced good and
E' along the 450 line. The profit of each firm the numeraire. That money is the numeraire
rises with the increase in aggregate demand. implies that, given menu costs, unchanged
However, in the absence of coordination, no prices and wages mean unchanged nominal
firm has an incentive to reduce prices away prices and wages. That money is the nonpro-
from the equilibrium point E. duced goods implies that, as the government
The menu cost argument considers instead can vary the amount of nominal money, it
a small increase in nominal money. At the can, if nominal prices and wages do not
initial set of prices, real money balances adjust, change the amount of real money
would increase and the economy would move balances, the real quantity of the nonpro-
from point E to a point like point E'. But, duced good.

B. The Effects of Larger Changes in


Nominal Money
15 The figure assumes decreasing returns to scale.
Note also that, as firms take the price level as given
when choosing their own price, iso-profit loci are verti- For larger changes in money, the private
cal along the price rule. opportunity costs of not adjusting prices in

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 657

response to the change in money (private where (0 - 1)/Oa is the initial share of wage
costs, for short) are no longer negligible and income in GNP.
depend on the parameters of the model. We If ,B is close to unity, that is, if the elas-
now investigate this dependence. ticity of the marginal disutility of labor is
The private costs faced by a firm depends close to unity, private costs of not adjusting
on the size of the demand shifts as well as on wages are small; in the limit, if marginal
the two parameters a and 9. As we have disutility of labor is constant, private costs
seen, these costs are of second order in re- are equal to zero. If a is very large, if
sponse to a change in aggregate demand, different types of labor are close substitutes,
thus roughly proportional to the square of private costs of not adjusting wages are high.
the change in aggregate demand. More pre- Table 1, Part a, gives the size of menu
cisely, define L(A; a, 9) to be the private costs as a proportion of the firm's revenues
opportunity cost to a firm expressed as a (GNP produced by the firm) that are just
proportion of initial revenues, associated sufficient to prevent a firm from adjusting its
with not adjusting its price in response to a price in response to a change in demand;
change of 100A% in aggregate demand, when Table 1, Part b, gives the size of menu costs
all other firms and households keep their as a proportion of initial consumption (GNP
prices and wages unchanged. Then, by sim- consumed by the worker) that are just suffi-
ple computation, we get cient to prevent a worker from adjusting his
(her) wage.
L(A; at, 0) = (a-_1)2( _ 1)] Thus, given the unit elasticity of aggregate
demand with respect to real money balances
/[2(1+ 0(a-1))] }A2 +0(A2) and the assumption that all other prices have
not changed, Part a of Table 1 gives the
where 0(A2) is of third order. private costs associated with not changing
The closer a is to one, that is, the closer to prices in the face of 5 and 10 percent changes
constant returns to scale, the smaller the in demand to the firm. The main conclusion
private cost. In the limit, if a is equal to one, is that very small menu costs, say less than
then private costs of not adjusting prices are .08 percent of revenues, may be sufficient to
equal to zero as the optimal response of a prevent adjustment of prices. Results are
monopolist to a multiplicative shift in iso- qualitatively similar for workers. Part b of
elastic demand under constant marginal cost Table 1 gives the private costs of not chang-
is to leave the price unchanged. Thus private ing wages in response to changes of + 5 and
costs are an increasing function of a. They +10 percent in the demand for goods. It
are also an increasing function of 9; the assumes that a is equal to 1.1, so that changes
higher the elasticity of demand with respect in the derived demand for labor are of 5.5
to price, the higher the private costs of not and 11 percent approximately. We expect /B
adjusting prices. to be higher than a so that Part b of Table 1
Exactly the same analysis applies to looks at values of /3 between 1.2 and 1.6. For
workers. The two important parameters for values of ,B close to unity, required menu
them are ,B and a. If we define the function costs are again very small; as /3 increases
L in the same way as above, the private however, required menu costs become non-
opportunity cost to a worker (measured in negligible: for /3 = 1.6 and a 11 percent
terms of consumption and expressed as a change in demand, they reach .45 percent of
proportion of initial consumption), associ- initial consumption, a number which is no
ated with not adjusting the wage in response longer negligible.
to a change of 100A% in aggregate demand, The more relevant comparison, however,
when all other firms and households keep at least from the point of view of welfare, is
their prices and wages unchanged, is given between private costs and welfare effects,
by that is, the change in utility resulting from
the changes in output, employment, and real
[(O _1)/a L(.l r{1 A)a 1. D _) money that are implied by a change in nomi-

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
658 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

TABLE 1-CHANGE IN AGGREGATE DEMAND AND MENU COSTS

(a): Loss in value to a firm from not (b): Loss in utility (in terms of consumption)
adjusting prices (as a proportion to a worker from not adjusting wages (as
of initial revenues)a a proportion of initial consumption)ab

M1 /MD = M1 /M =
a 9 1.05 1.10 ,B a 1.05 1.10

1.0 5 .000 .000 1.2 5 .025 .100


1.1 5 .003 .013 1.4 5 .066 .265
1.1 2 .001 .004 1.4 2 .027 .111
20 .008 .031 20 .105 .418
1.3 5 .018 .071 1.6 5 .112 .451

Note: MO is the initial level of nominal money, M1 the level after the change.
a Shown in percent.
bo =5; a=1.1.

TABLE 2-MENU COSTS AND WELFARE EFFECTS

M1 /MO = 1.05 M1 /MO = 1.10


Menu Welfare Menu Welfare
a /3 Costsa Effectsa Ratio Costsa Effectsa Ratio

1.1 1.2 .03 1.79 60 .11 3.54 32


(=a =5) 1.4 .07 1.83 26 .28 3.60 13
.11 1.91 17 1.6
.46 3.72 8
1.2 .04 1.2
1.82 45 .15 3.57 24
1.4 .08 1.87 24 .33 3.67 11
1.6 .13 1.98 15 .53 3.85 7
1.1 1.2 .03 .94 31 .11 1.86 17
(= a =10) 1.4 .06 1.02 17 .23 1.93 8
1.6 .09 1.11 12 .36 2.05 6
1.2 1.2 .04 .99 25 .16 1.87 12
1.4 .07 1.07 16 .29 2.01 7
1.6 .11 1.27 12 .44 2.24 5

aShown in percent.

nal money at given prices and wages. Welfare adjusting their prices and workers from ad-
effects depend on the size of the change in justing their wages, given other wages and
nominal money as well as on the parameters prices. The second column gives the welfare
a, 1, 0, and a; the dependence is a complex effects of an increase in nominal nmoney at
one and we shall not analyze it here in unchanged prices and wages, expressed in
detail. Table 2 gives numerical examples. It terms of consumption, again as a proportion
gives the required menu costs and welfare of GNP. The third gives the ratio of welfare
effects associated with two different changes effects to menu costs.
in nominal money, 5 and 10 percent, and Welfare effects turn out not to be much
different values of the structural parameters. affected by the specific values of the parame-
For each of the two changes in money, the ters, at least for the range of values we
first column gives the minimum value of consider in the table. Thus, the ratio of
menu costs, expressed as a proportion of welfare effects to menu cost has the same
GNP, that prevents adjustment of nominal qualitative behavior as that of the ratio of
prices and wages; this value is the sum of output movements to menu costs. It is largest
menu costs required to prevent firms from for values of a, /3, 6, and a close to unity,

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 659

and decreases as these parameters increase. text, unambiguous: the relative price effect
In the table, it varies from 60 for low values dominates the aggregate demand effect, so
of a, 13, 6 and a to 5 for high values of these that an increase in P leads to an increase in
parameters. Pi, although less than one for one. Thus, the
model exhibits strategic complementarity.
C. Strategic Complementarities and This is not, however, a robust feature of the
Multiple Equilibria model: if the elasticity of aggregate demand
with respect to real money balances ex-
We have shown that, if menu costs were ceeded one, the aggregate demand effect
sufficiently large, there was an equilibrium could dominate the relative price effect; an
where, in response to an increase in nominal increase in P could lead the firm to decrease
money, nominal prices and wages remained rather than increase Pi and the model would
unchanged and nominal money had real exhibit instead strategic substitutability. It is
effects. What we have not shown, however, is clear that the results derived above on the
that this was the only equilibrium. It turns inefficiency of the monopolistically compe-
out that, if the condition that Cooper and titive equilibrium, the existence of an aggre-
John have called "strategic complementar- gate demand externality and the role of menu
ity" is satisfied, there exists a range of menu costs do not depend on whether the model
costs for which the equilibrium is not unique. exhibits strategic complementarity or sub-
This has been shown by Julio Rotemberg stitutability. But, if the model exhibits stra-
and Garth Saloner (1986a, b) and, in the tegic complementarity however, the equi-
context of this model, by Laurence Ball and librium with menu costs may not be unique.
David Romer (1987). We give a brief sketch Consider what a particular firm should do
of their argument but refer the reader to after an increase in nominal money. If other
those papers for details. firms do adjust their prices, and if prices are
To discuss the existence and the role of strategic complements, the firm's optimal
strategic complementarity in this context, it price, Pi, increases because of both the in-
is again easiest to study the special case crease in M and the increase in P. If, instead,
where the marginal utility of leisure is con- other firms do not adjust their prices, so that
stant and where there are no menu costs in the price level does not change, the optimal
nominal wage setting, so that real wage is price Pi increases, but by less. Put another
constant and we can concentrate on the in- way, the larger the proportion of firms which
teractions between price setters. Following do not adjust their prices, the lower the
Cooper and John's definition, strategic com- opportunity cost to a firm of not adjusting
plementarity corresponds then to the case its price. Thus, for some values of the menu
where an increase in the price level leads a costs, there will be two equilibria, one in
firm, absent menu costs, to increase its own which all firms adjust, making it costly for a
nominal price. Strategic substitutability cor- given firm not to adjust, and the other in
responds to the case where an increase in the which no firm adjusts, making it less costly
price level leads the firm instead to decrease for a given firm not to adjust.
its nominal price. Strategic complementarity can therefore
In the special case we are considering, the lead to multiple equilibria in the context of
price that each firm would choose, absent monopolistic competition with menu costs."6
menu costs, is given by equation (14). An These equilibria are associated with different
increase in P has two effects on Pi. At a levels of welfare, and to the extent that the
given level of aggregate demand, the firm economy ends at a low welfare equilibrium,
wants to keep the same relative price, and
increase Pi in proportion to P. But an in-
crease in the price level also decreases real
money balances and aggregate demand,
16Strategic complementarity turns out to play an
leading the firm to want a decrease in its important role in dynamic models with menu costs. See
relative price. The net effect is, in our con- the surveys by Blanchard (1987) and Rotemberg (1987).

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
660 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

this can be seen as a "coordination failure,"


the term used by Cooper and John.
competitive
D. Demand Determination of Output FL / 0 wage rule

We have until now assumed that increases 0'

in real money balances at constant prices o competitive


and wages led to increases in output and price rule

employment. When analyzing the effects of


small changes in money, this assumption was 0 log Y log (MIP) + constant)
clearly warranted; in the initial equilibrium,
as price exceeds marginal cost, firms will FIGURE 4. DEMAND DETERMINATION OF OUTPUT

always be willing to satisfy a small increase


in demand at the existing price. The same is
true of workers: as the real wage initially
exceeds the marginal disutility of labor, By a similar argument, workers will supply
workers will willingly accommodate a small up to point B'. The shaded area H is the set
increase in demand for their type of labor. of real wage combinations where workers do
When we consider larger changes in money, not satisfy labor demand. The figure makes
this may no longer be the case. Even if firms it clear that an increase in nominal money
do not adjust their price, they have the op- will increase output and employment. It also
tion of either accommodating or rationing makes clear that, no matter how large menu
demand; they will resort to the second op- costs are, it is impossible, unless the compe-
tion if marginal cost exceeds price. The same titive and monopolistically competitive real
analysis applies to workers. From standard wages are equal, to attain the competitive
monopoly theory, we know that firms and equilibrium through an increase in nominal
workers will accommodate relative increases money.
in demand, respectively, of What happens, therefore, as demand in-
creases depends on both menu costs and
supply constraints. If menu costs are large,
(01/(O 9 _ l)) l(a -1)
supply constraints will come into effect first.
If menu costs are small, a more likely case,
and (a/(a - 1))1/G81) prices and wages adjust before supply con-
straints come into effect.
This raises the question of whether, as-
suming menu costs to be large enough, an IV. Fixed Costs and Aggregate
increase in demand can increase output all Demand Movements
the way to its competitive level. The answer
is provided in Figure 4. This figure replicates Until now, we have taken the number of
Figure 2 and draws the aggregate price and firms as given and fixed costs have played no
wage rules under competitive and monopo- role in our analysis. Both the aggregate de-
listically competitive conditions. Point A is mand externality and the menu costs argu-
the monopolistic competitive equilibrium and ments hold, irrespective of the presence of
A' the competitive one. Along the monopo- fixed costs.
listically competitive price rule, price exceeds In this section, we want to study further
marginal cost; thus firms will satisfy de- the effects of aggregate demand on activity,
mand, at a given price wage ratio, until taking as given that, because of menu costs,
marginal cost equals price, that is, until they such movements in aggregate demand affect
reach the competitive locus. In our case, output. It is then essential to introduce fixed
firms will supply up to point B. The shaded costs, as they have important implications
area F is the set of output-real wage at for productivity, profitability, and the poten-
which firms will ration rather than supply. tial for entry by new firms in response to

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 661

movements in output induced by aggregate Together they determine as before equi-


demand. librium aggregate output and real wages.
From the assumption of constant returns in
A. Fixed Costs and the this section, the markup, or its inverse the
General Equilibrium real wage, is independent of the level of
demand and is determined by (12'). Given
To introduce fixed costs, we change the the real wage, (13') determines the level of
specification of the production function to output.
We can now go further and determine the
equilibrium number of firms. For a given
(1) Yi+F= Ni(.a- ')/a number of firms, m, the real profit of each
j =1 firm after profit maximization is given by

where F can be interpreted as being in terms


of the firm's own output, or as overhead (16) VJ/'P=KV(1/m)(W/P) 1-Y
labor requiring all types of labor in the same
proportions as regular production."7 For - Kp (/P)F,
convenience, we also assume that, apart from
the fixed cost, firms operate under constant where Kv and Kp depend on the structural
returns to scale, so that a = 1. parameters but not on the number of firms.
Given this specification of fixed costs, An increase in m has two effects on the
equations characterizing equilibrium are very profit of each firm. Given Y and (W/P), it
similar to equations (5) to (13). The relation decreases the sales of each firm and decreases
between real money balances and aggregate profit: this effect is captured by the term
demand is unchanged. The demand func- (1/m) in (16). But it also affects the equi-
tions for goods are still given by equation librium value of Y; while the constants K
(7), while in the demand functions for labor, and Kw in (12') and (13') do not depend on
equation (8), Y is replaced by (Y+ mF). m, the level of employment associated with a
The price rules are still given by equation given level of output increases with aggre-
(10), which becomes under the assumption gate fixed costs and therefore with m. This
that a is equal to unity: leads to a lower equilibrium value of Y;
given the assumption of constant returns,
(10') (P,/P) = (O,/(0-1))Kp(W/P) and given that K., is independent of m, the
value of (W/P) is unaffected by m; lower
i=l,..., m.
aggregate output in turn decreases profit.
The wage rules are given by equation (11) Assuming that entry takes place until profit
where Y is replaced by (Y + mF). is equal to zero, equations (12') to (16) and
Equations (12) and (13) which give the the zero-profit condition determine the equi-
aggregate price and wage rules become librium number of firms. We shall assume in
what follows that the number of firms is
(12') (P/1W) =(0(-1))Kp initially given by zero-profit conditions but
is going to be fixed in the short run.
(13') (W/P) = (oa/(a-1))Kw
B. Movements in Aggregate Demand,
(Y + mF) 1. Profit, and Entry

Aggregate demand depends on real money


17An alternative is to assume that fixed costs for a balances, the ratio of nominal money to the
given firm are in the form of other goods. A convenient
price level. Under constant retums with a
assumption is to assume that the fixed cost is a CES
function of all goods, with elasticity of substitution 9. fixed markup of prices on wages, aggregate
This assumption insures that the demand functions for demand is therefore a function of the ratio
goods still have elasticity 0. of nominal money to the nominal wage,

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
662 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

money in wage units. We now consider the For a potential entrant to be indifferent to
effects of movements in (M/W). This may entry, this expression has to be equal to zero.
be due to a movement in nominal money, Assuming zero profit for the potential en-
with no adjustment in nominal wages be- trant, we can derive the elasticity of the
cause of menu costs as in the previous sec- relative wage (W*/W) to the money stock
tion. Or it may be due to a change in the in wage units (M/W). Denoting it by q, we
nominal wage given nominal money; the rea- have
son need not concern us in this section.
Movements in (M/W) lead to one for one
movements in aggregate demand and B= (1/0).
employment.
The first obvious implication of fixed costs Equivalently the elasticity of the shadow
is that productivity, given by (Y/(Y+ mF)), nominal wage to the aggregate nominal wage
varies procycically. We focus on a related is given by 1- (1/0).19 Thus, the higher are
implication, the procycical behavior of aggregate nominal wages, the more difficult
profit. From equation (16), profit is, given is entry, the lower the relative wage a new
that nominal wages and prices are fixed, an entrant can offer to its workers. This result
increasing function of output. If profit was depends on both the presence of monopolis-
initially equal to zero, it becomes negative tic competition and fixed costs. Fixed costs
with a decrease in (M/W), positive with an imply that when higher nominal wages de-
increase in (M/W). Both procycical pro- crease aggregate demand, the profit of all
ductivity and profitability seem to be in firms can be negative; the fact that products
accordance with the facts. are imperfect substitutes implies that new
Procycical profitability has interesting im- entrants face downward-sloping demands
plications for entry. Keeping the number of and cannot capture all of demand by simply
firms constant, we examine the return to undercutting the prices of existing firms.
entry as a function of aggregate demand.18 This result has two implications. In the
Consider the effects of a decrease in nominal previous section, we showed that, if the
money in wage units and the associated re- number of firms was given, menu costs could
duction in output. Existing firms make nega- lead firms not to change prices in response
tive profits and thus, if a potential entrant to changes in nominal money. We see that,
has to pay the prevailing wage, it will not with respect to decreases in money, allowing
want to enter. We can go further and derive for entry will not change the result. More
the shadow wage, say W*, which would make generally (and stepping outside our model)
a potential entrant indifferent to entry, as a this result implies that if nominal wages are
function of (M/W). Going back to equation too high, perhaps because of union push,
(5), (12'), and (16), given M and the aggre- and lead to unemployment, new firms will
gate nominal wage W, if a firm can pay its not want to enter, even if they can pay wages
workers W*, it will make profits of to the unemployed that are far below those
paid to the employed.20 Absent fixed costs,

[K(K,/m)((O 1)/K )-2

x (W*/W)1-0(M/W)

"9As 9 is greater than unity, the elasticity of the


- [(e - 1)/el (W*/W)F]. shadow wage with respect to the aggregate wage is
positive. If we had, however, formalized fixed costs in
terms of a basket of goods, the sign of the elasticity
would depend on whether 9 is greater or smaller than 2.
The difference comes from the fact that, in our case, a
18An alternative would be to determine the equi- decrease in the shadow wage decreases the fixed cost
librium number of firms as a function of the level of whereas, under this alternative assumption, it does not.
aggregate demand. This is the route pursued by Robert 20We are indebted to Larry Summers for suggesting
Solow (1984). this argument.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 663

entry would occur and unemployment sub- tending the model to look at the dynamic
side.21 effects of aggregate demand on output in the
presence of menu costs.
V. Conclusion The first is that we have assumed all prices
to be initially equal and set optimally. In a
The results of this paper are tantalizingly dynamic economy and in the presence of
close to those of traditional Keynesian mod- menu costs, such a degenerate price distribu-
els: under monopolistic competition, output tion is unlikely. But, if prices are initially not
is too low, because of an aggregate demand all equal or optimal, it is no longer obvious
externality. This externality, together with that even a small change in nominal money
small menu costs, implies that movements in will leave all prices unaffected. It is no longer
demand can affect output and welfare. In obvious that money, or aggregate demand in
particular, increases in nominal money can general, will have large effects on output.
increase both output and welfare. In the The second is that, even if nominal money
presence of fixed costs, output, productivity, has large effects on output, it must be the
and profitability move in the same direction. case that money is sometimes unantic-
We believe these results to be important to ipatedly high, sometimes unanticipatedly
the understanding of macroeconomic fluc- low. When money is high, output increases
tuations; we want to point out the obvious and so does welfare to a first order. When
limitations of the analysis as it stands. money is low, output decreases and so does
The scope for small menu costs to lead to welfare, again to a first order. These welfare
large output effects in our model depends effects would appear to cancel out to a first
critically on the elasticity of labor supply order. It is therefore no longer obvious that,
with respect to the real wage being large even if menu costs lead to large output fluc-
enough (on (/3-1) being small). Evidence tuations, the welfare loss of those fluctua-
on individual labor supply suggests however tions exceeds the menu costs which generate
a small elasticity. Thus the "menu cost" them.
approach runs into the same problem as the Fortunately, all these issues are the subject
imperfect information approach to output of active research. Recent developments are
fluctuations; neither can easily generate large reviewed in Blanchard and Rotemberg.
fluctuations in output in response to demand
if the real wage elasticity of labor supply is APPENDIX
low. As in the imperfect information case,
the theory may be rescued by the distinction This Appendix derives the market equi-
between temporary and permanent changes librium conditions (5) to (11) given in the
in demand. Another possibility is that unions text. It proceeds in three steps. The first
have a flatter labor supply than individuals, derives the demand functions of each type
or do not represent the whole labor force. of labor and each type of product by solv-
More likely, the assumption that labor ing part of the maximization problems of
markets operate as spot markets (competi- firms and households. These functions hold
tive or monopolistically competitive) will whether or not prices and wages are set by
have to be abandoned.22 workers and firms at their profit or utility
The analysis of this paper is purely static. maximizing level. The second derives price
There are two main issues involved in ex- rules from firms' profit maximization and
wage rules from workers' utility maximiza-
tion. The third characterizes market equi-
librium.
21This is our interpretation of Weitzman's argument
that increasing returns are a necessary condition for A. Demands for Product and Labor
unemployment to persist. Types
22This is indeed the direction taken by Akerlof and
Yellen (1985b) who formalize the goods market as
monopolistically competitive and the labor market using (a) Demand for product of type i. In
the "efficiency wage" hypothesis. order to maximize utility, each household

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
664 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

chooses the optimal composition of con- ney balances:


sumption and money holdings for a given
level of total wealth I, and product prices: (A7) Y = (y/(1-y )) M'/P

m #z/(0)7(01) n

max A E C- where M'= E M1'.


Cij, M/ X ' i=1 Y j =1

(b) Demand for labor of type j. In order


to maximize profit, each firm minimizes its
m
production cost for a given level of output
subject to EPC +MJ' =Ij. and wages:
i=1
n

Solving this maximization problem gives min , WjNij


Nij j=1

(Al) cii= (Pi/P) 6(yIj/mP) / (a/(-1) ) l/ax


subject to N Y. - Wa
(A2) MJ' =(1 - )Ij j =1

Solving this minimization problem gives


(A3) Aj = IIIj1P
where Nij= (nW/(1 j/W) Yi*

and

(A4) P= (l/m) E Pi1- and n


i =1
(A8) WjNij = n
j=l
= yY(l1 -)l-,
where
p can be interpreted as the marginal utility
of real wealth.
The demand for product of type i is there- (A9) W=(lln E W1-
fore given by j =1

n
The demand for labor of type j is there-
(AS) Yi= E Cij = (PiP) (Ylm), fore given by
j=1
m

where (AlO) Nj= Nij= (Wj/W) N/n,


i =1

n m n
where
(A6) Y= E E PI2Ci )/P = ( Y/P) ? I; .
j i j=1
m n

(All) N- WjNij IW
Y denotes real aggregate consumption ex- ij
penditures of households and will be re-
m
ferred to as "aggregate demand." Equation
'Al/l -a) m y
(AS) is equation (7) in the text. Note also n Yi
i =1
that equations (Al), (A2), (A5), and (A6)
imply the following relation between aggre- N can be interpreted as the aggregate labor
gate demand and aggregate desired real mo- demand index.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BLANCHARD AND KIYOTAKI: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 665

B. Price and Wage Rules This gives equation (5) in the text.
Replacing the Yi's in (All) by their value
(a) Taking as given wages and the price from (AS) gives
level, each firm chooses its price and output
so as to maximize profit: (Al8) N [n/l(- a) m-a
n

(A12) Vi = Pry, - E WjNij, X F (Pi/P) - alY.


j =1

subject to the cost function (A8) and the If all firms choose the same (not necessarily
demand function for its product (A5). Solv- optimal) price, this reduces to
ing the above maximization problem gives
(A19) N= [nl/(1 Uml a]ya
(A13) Pi1P= [((01(0#-l))n11(l -?)am1 a
Substituting N from equation (A19) into
X (W/P) Y x-1I1A1 +O(Ca- 1)). (AlO) gives the demand function for labor j,
equation (8) in the text. Note that the de-
Equation (A13) implies that the price is equal mand functions for goods and labor, and the
to 0/(6 -1) times the marginal cost. Equa- relation between aggregate demand and real
tion (A13) is equation (10) in the text. money balances, have been derived without
(b) Taking as given prices and other use of the price and wage rules and therefore
wages, each household chooses its wage and hold whether or not wages and prices are set
labor supply so as to maximize utility. Using optimally.
(A3), Substituting N from equation (A19) into
equation (A16) gives the wage rule, equation
(A14) Uj = ,IjIP-N (11) in the text. This completes the deriva-
tion.
subject to the demand for its type of labor
(AIO) and the budget constraint: REFERENCES

m
Akerlof, George and Yellen, Janet, (1985a) "Can
(A15) Ij=WJNJ E + fj+Mj. Small Deviations from Rationality Make
X-1
Significant Differences to Economic Equi-
Solving this maximization problem gives libria?," American Economic Review, Sep-
tember 1985, 75, 708-21.
and _ _, (1985b) "A Near-
(A16) WjIW= (/(- )(/n-)
Rational Model of the Business Cycle,
with Wage and Price Inertia," Quarterly
X ( PI W) 0,8-1] 1/(1 + a(-1)) Journal of Economics, 1985, Suppl., 100,
823-38.
Equation (A16) implies that the real wage, in Ball, Laurence and Romer, David, "Sticky Prices
terms of utility, is equal to a/(a -1) times as Coordination Failure," mimeo., Prince-
the marginal disutility of labor. ton University, March 1987.
Bils, Mark, "Essays on the Cyclical Behavior
C. Market Equilibrium of Price and Marginal Cost," unpublished
doctoral dissertation, MIT, 1985.
In equilibrium, desired real money bal- Blanchard, Olivier, "Why Does Money Affect
ances must be equal to actual balances. Thus Output?," in Benjamin Friedman and
M = M'. Replacing in (A7) gives Frank Hahn, eds., Handbook of Monetary
Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland,
(A17) Y= (y/(1-y))M/P. forthcoming 1987.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
666 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

Cooper, Russell and John, Andrew, " Coordi- Rotemberg, Julio, " Monopolistic Price Adjust-
nating Coordination Failures in Keynesian ment and Aggregate Output," Review of
Models," mimeo., Yale University, July Economic Studies, October 1982, 44,
1985. 517-31.
Dixit, Avinash and Stiglitz, Joseph, " Monopolis- _ ,"The New Keynesian Microfounda-
tic Competition and Optimum Product tions," NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
Diversity," American Economic Review, Cambridge: MIT Press, Vol. 2, forthcom-
June 1977, 67, 297-308. ing 1987.
Hart, Oliver, "A Model of Imperfect Compe- Rotemberg, Julio and Saloner, Gart, (1986a)
tition with Keynesian Features," Quarterly "A Supergame Theoretic Model of Price
Journal of Economics, February 1982, 97, Wars," American Economic Review, June
109-38. 1986, 76, 390-407.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, (1985a) "Macroeconomics __=__and _ , (1986b) "The Relative
of Monopolistic Competition," unpub- Rigidity of Monopoly Pricing," NBER,
lished doctoral dissertation, Harvard Uni- Working Paper No. 1943, June 1986.
versity, May 1985. Solow, Robert, "'Monopolistic Competition
) (1985b) "Implications of Multiple and the Multiplier," mimeo., MIT, 1984.
Equilibria Under Monopolistic Compe- Stiglitz, Joseph, "Price Rigidities and Market
tition," mimeo., Harvard University, 1985. Structure," American Economic Review
Mankiw, N. Gregory, "A Small Menu Costs Proceedings, May 1984, 74, 350-55.
and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeco- Weitzman, Martin, "Increasing Returns and
nomic Model of Monopoly," Quarterly the Foundations of Unemployment The-
Journal of Economics, May 1985, 100, ory," Economic Journal, December 1982,
529-39. 92, 787-804.

This content downloaded from 200.37.165.17 on Tue, 24 May 2016 15:42:40 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like