You are on page 1of 17

International Journal of Management Reviews (2009)

doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2370.2008.00252.x

T he development of the
resource-based view of
the firm: A critical
appraisal
Andy Lockett,1 Steve Thompson and
Uta Morgenstern

Over the last 20 years, the resource-based view (RBV) has reached a pre-eminent position
among theories in the field of strategy, but debate continues as to its precise nature. This
paper contributes to the debate by critically reviewing the development of the RBV to date.
The critical appraisal examines the development of the RBV in terms of theory, method,
empirical evidence and practical insights. It is contended that the permeable and eclectic
nature of the RBV stems from its being a theory about what firms are and how they function,
and that its popularity is due to an absence of limiting behavioural assumptions. Finally, the
authors provide their own subjective views on where they think RBV scholars should focus
their efforts in the future.

Introduction Wernerfelt 1984).


The RBV views the firm as a historically
In this paper we examine the body of theoret- determined collection of assets or resources
ical and empirical work that encompasses the which are tied ‘semi-permanently’ to the firm
resource-based view of the firm (henceforth the (Wernerfelt 1984). Some users of the RBV
RBV). Over the last 20 years, the RBV has risen distinguish resources which are fully appro-
to a pre-eminent position in strategy research. priable by the firm, such as physical capital or
Although the relative weight attri- buted to brand names, from less tangible assets, such as
different scholars’ contributions may be subject organizational routines and capabilities (Teece et
to debate, it is clear that, over time, a series of al. 1997). Similarly, distinctions may be drawn
papers have laid the intellectual foundations for a between static and dynamic resources. The
body of thought relating to the relationship former are those that, once in place, may
between the opportunity set facing the firm, the
strategic behaviour to be implemented by
managers and the outcome in terms of
competitive advantage or performance (e.g.
Barney 1986, 1991; Collis 1994; Dierickx and
Cool 1989; Peteraf 1993; Rumelt 1984;
© 2009 The Authors
Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600
Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA

International Journal of Management Reviews Volume 11 Issue 1 pp. 9-28


be considered to represent a stock of assets to be paper unfolds by examining each of the facets in
The resource-based view of the
used as appropriate firm
over a finite life (e.g. Barney turn.
1986, 1991; Peteraf 1993; Rumelt 1984).
Dynamic resources may reside in capabilities,
such as an organization’s capacity for learning, The Resource-based View: Theory
which generate additional opportunities over time In this section we examine the theoretical
(e.g. Collis 1994; Teece etal. 1997). Here, we development of the RBV. The central tenets of
follow Combs and Ketchen (1999) in noting that the RBV are path dependence and firm heter-
the crucial requirements of the RBV are that the ogeneity (Lockett 2005; Lockett and Thompson
relevant resources, whatever their nature (i.e. 2001). The RBV is a theory about the nature of
resources, capabilities or dynamic capabilities), firms, as opposed to theories such as trans- action
are specific to the firm and not capable of easy cost economics which seeks to explain why firms
imitation by rivals (Barney 1991). Therefore, exist (see Coase 1937). As such, the RBV
such resources constitute the source of Ricardian requires minimal limiting assump- tions about the
rents that comprise a firm’s com- petitive nature of strategic behaviour. In effect, the RBV
advantage and, to the extent that their replication is a statement about how firms actually operate.
by others is problematic, imply a sustainable The minimalistic nature of the RBV’s
advantage over the longer term. Because each assumptions (i.e. its two central tenets) makes
firm’s resource bundle is unique, being the formalization difficult. Ultimately, the RBV’s
consequence of its past managerial decisions and message that firms’ performance differs because
subsequent experience, it follows that so is each of different resource endow- ments is probably
firm’s opportunity set. incapable of falsification. However, theoretical
As empirical evidence relating to the decom- insights have been developed from these central
position of firm performance (e.g. McGahan and tenets. Below, we provide an overview of the
Porter 1997) typically finds that firm-specific main theoretical insights, employing the game of
effects are at least as important as industry poker (where relevant) as an illustration.
characteristics, the RBV offers an obvious
framework for analysing inter-firm variations in
performance. As such, it acts as a natural Resources and Performance: Sustainable
complement to the external, market-based Competitive Advantage
approach to competitive advantage that is The sustainable competitive advantage (SCA)
grounded in industrial organization economics approach to the RBV is exemplified by the work
(IO) and synthesized in, for example, the work of of Barney (1986, 1991), Peteraf (1993) and
Porter (1980). Rumelt (1984). Employing the resource as the
The prominence of the RBV as a core theory unit of analysis the theory seeks to explain the
in the area of management suggests that the time extent to which a firm may be able to sustain a
is right to reflect on its development. Given that a position of competitive advantage. Sustainable
number of reviews on the RBV have already competitive advantage is based on the ownership
been published, which have either been focused of firm-specific resource(s) that, following
towards descriptive ac- counts of the Barney (1991), has the follow- ing attributes: (1)
development of the RBV (e.g. Ambrosini 2007; it must be valuable; (2) it must be rare; (3) it must
Barney 1995; Barney 2001b; Barney and Arikan be inimitable; (4) it must be non-substitutable.
2001; Barney et al. 2001) or have provided a These conditions are what Barney (1991) terms
summary of empirical approaches and evidence VRIN - valuable, rare, inimitable and non-
on the RBV (e.g. Armstrong and Shimizu 2007; substitutable. Valuable resources can be used to
Newbert 2007), we focus our attention on exploit opportu- nities and/or neutralize threats in
providing a critical reflection on the state of a firm’s environment. Rare resources are those
health of the RBV research. Our intention is not that are limited in supply and not equally
to provide an exhaustive interpretation of all distributed across a firm’s current and potential
papers that have been written about the RBV; competi- tion. Inimitability refers to the extent to
rather, we reflect on how the core elements of the which resources are difficult to replicate by other
theory and its application have developed over firms, which may be due to factors such as social
time, to explain how we have arrived at the complexity (Dierickx and Cool 1989), causal
position we have today. In doing so, we examine ambiguity and specific historical circumstances
five interrelated facets of the RBV: (i) theory, (ii) (Barney 1991). Non-substitutability of resources
method, (iii) empirical evidence, (iv) practical implies that one resource cannot be simply
1 insights and (v) the © 2009 The Authors
RBV looking forward. The replaced
0 Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing (orAcademy
Ltd and British substituted) by another one.
of Management
Other authors writing on this issue have the broad conditions necessary for a resource’s
highlighted the importance of limits to com- comparative scarcity to elevateMarchit to 2009
strategic
petition - both ex ante and ex post - in resource significance. Peteraf and Barney (2003), among
markets as a necessary condition for SCA (see others, begin with the assumption of resource
Peteraf 1993), and the importance of isolating heterogeneity and then consider which (if any) of
mechanisms as a necessary condition for SCA a given collec- tion of resources satisfy the VRIN
(see Rumelt 1984). conditions outlined above. They point out that
The RBV is in essence a theory of rents based resources differ in their impact on the firm’s
upon resource market imperfections (Amit and ability to generate cost or differentiation
Schoemaker 1993). At one level it may be advantages, and hence performance. Moreover, if
considered both tautological and even trivial. the cost of a resource reflects the full potential
Consider a firm earning rents it may generate, it cannot, by definition, be
a source of a competitive advantage.
n = PQ - zpr A resource market imperfection may be
exogenous, in the sense that it results from the
Where n,, the profit of the firm on product j, is firm’s possession of some superior physical,
defined as the difference between the revenue organizational or intangible resource that has
received (price of product j [P,] multiplied by the been accumulated as a result of the firm’s unique
quantity of product j [Q,]) and the sum of the historical evolution. Alternatively, it may be
resource inputs consumed in producing product j endogenous, in the sense that it results from a
[r;,] multiplied by their actual or shadow prices conscious strategic decision by the firm’s
[pij]. managers. Such a decision might apply to the
If we assume for simplicity that there is either acquisition of a resource to facilitate the firm’s
no product differentiation or, equivalently, that own production and/or to secure its advantage
differentiation is completely determined by the over a rival. For example, a depart- ment store
resource inputs, non-zero n, (i.e. a competitive corporation’s decision to become the ‘anchor’ for
advantage) in the face of com- petitive rivalry in a new shopping mall complex is both a move to
the market for j indicates that our firm has access secure a resource (market access) for the firm and
to at least one resource input on more favourable a means of pre-empting a rival. This parallels the
terms than its rivals. If it is also the case that n, > distinction between structure and conduct in the
0 persists in the longer term (i.e. that a SCP paradigm in industrial economics. Here
competitive advantage is sustainable), this market structure has been traditionally treated as
resource advantage must also persist over time. exogenously determined by the underlying
Viewed in this light, any SCA is simply a rent industry charac- teristics. Firm conduct, on the
conferred by one or more imperfections in the other hand, is the endogenous outcome of
resource market that pre- vents at least one input managerial decision- taking, albeit within bounds
being available on equal terms to all actual or set by structural characteristics. Thus, collusion,
would-be competitors. for example, which is usually considered to be
Thus, the RBV at its most basic offers an facilitated by high concentration, is imperfectly
interpretation of the existence of profits in predictable without further modelling.
equilibrium based on firm heterogeneity. If that In acknowledging that resources are tied
were all it offered, it would be essentially trivial. ‘semi-permanently’ to the firm, in the phrase of
It would amount to a statement that firms differ Wernerfelt (1984), the RBV recognizes that, in
in performance because they dif- fer in attributes. the short run, the resource set confronting
True but hardly informative! It is scarcely particular managers is largely exogenously
surprising that critics of the RBV (e.g. Priem and determined. However, it also concedes a role for
Butler 2001a,b) have accused its proponents of the manager in perceiving opportunities,
tautological reasoning by attributing the matching these to the available resources and,
generation of competitive advantage to within limits, augmenting the latter with such
possession of those resources whose own value additional resources as are necessary to imple-
reflects these scarcity rents. However, ment its strategy. Thus, the role of a manager in
contributors to the RBV literature have sought to the RBV is akin to that of a card player. The
generate testable hypotheses con- cerning those player is provided with a dealt hand of cards,
characteristics of such inputs that are likely to with the value of each card being broadly
render them strategic resources in the sense of determined ex ante by the rules of the game.
being a source of sustainable rents. Barney’s Success depends upon the relative skill with
© 2009 The Authors
(1991) VRIN framework, outlined above, sets out which that hand, augmented by any cards 1
Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management 1
subsequently acquired, is played in competition opportunity set imposes a limit on its growth. She
The resource-based view of
against rivals. the firm
However, whereas each hand of defined the productive opportunity set of the firm
cards starts out with a completely new deal, as ‘all of the productive possibilities that its
managers are typically engaged in an evolving “entrepreneurs” see and can take advantage of ’
game in which over time the resource base, and (Penrose 1959, 31, our italics). That is, the
hence the opportunity set, can be shifted. effective set of productive opportunity is
determined by both managerial perceptions and
the resources at their disposal. Penrose further
Resources and the Role of Managers suggested that the search for novel uses of
Viewing the RBV as we have outlined above existing resources may expand the firm’s
enables us to gain a better understanding of how opportunity set. Where a firm’s resources are
managers may be able to exploit market incompletely used and there is always some
imperfections, in both resource and product slack, there is a potential oppor- tunity for firm
markets, to advance firm performance. Not growth. In order for any excess capacity of
merely does it cede a substantial role to existing resources to be exploited, the resources
managers, but it also links the internal and may need to be combined with other available
external environments in which they operate. In resources in order to generate productive
this way, it also distinguishes the academic study services; we return to this issue below. Penrose
of strategic management from that of industrial also highlights that firms attempt to discover
organization economics. The latter has made more about the potential uses of their existing
considerable progress in analysing the firm’s resource via research and other types of proactive
optimal response to its external environment, searches. She represents this by arguing that
including the behaviour of its rivals, but it tends managers frequently reflect: ‘there ought to be
to retain its traditional characterization of the some way in which I can use that’ (Penrose 1959,
firm’s internal workings as a ‘black box’ beyond 77). Penrose, in effect, raises the issue about what
scrutiny. Moreover, managers are largely treated the func- tionality of a resource is.
as optimizing algorithms. Under the RBV, The issue of what resources actually do was
managerial responsibilities include the need to revisited by Wernerfelt (1984), who employed
reposition the firm as opportunities change and the concept of duality to discuss the relation- ship
its resource set evolves. By contrast, industrial between resources and the products and services
organization economics sees the managers’ role that result from their usage. Accord- ing to
as responsive. Thus, managers in the RBV are Wernerfelt, firms can be defined either in terms
both adaptive and proactive, i.e. they are of products/services or in terms of resources. The
‘enactors’ (Lado and Wilson 1994), while their two are the different sides of the same coin.
counterparts in industrial organization economics It is not the resource type per se that matters, it
have a role analogous to that of managers in a is the functionality of the resource and how the
regulated utility, whose decisions largely concern resource is employed (Penrose 1959; Peteraf and
marginal adjustments to output and input levels. Bergen 2003; Wernerfelt 1984). Resources may
It is the sources of market imperfections, have a number of different functions, which may
allied to the roles managers play, which makes enable them to be employed across a number of
the RBV an interesting theory. Managers, different markets over time. An important role
through the decisions they make, change the for managers is to determine the most profitable
nature of competition in markets. The deci- sions usage for the resources at their disposal.
that managers take are inextricably linked to their Consequently, resource usage is influenced by
perceptions about the internal characteristics of the subjective perceptions of managers. Further-
their own firms and also of the external more, resource usage shapes the competitive
environment in which they com- pete (Penrose landscape. It is the managers of firms who
1959). Managerial perceptions become important employ their resources in similar ways to their
in relation to three central elements of the RBV: competitors that determine the boundaries of
resource functionality, resource recombination industry membership. If we take the example of
and resource creation, which we discuss next. the manager (landlord) of a public house, he/she
will view their premises as a key resource for the
retailing of their drinks and other consumables.
Resource Functionality The building, however, could have multiple uses.
The issue of resource functionality has a long For example, the building could be used as a pet
tradition in the RBV literature. Penrose (1959) shop. It is how the resource is used that
1 © 2009 The Authors
determines the industry to which the business
2 proposed that the Journal
size of a firm’s
compilation pro-
© 2009 ductive
Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management
belongs. we can attribute the success of a firm (and hence
As outlined above, an important role of SCA) to one specific resource. March 2009 it
Consequently,
mangers is the search for the most profitable use may be more fruitful to consider combinations of
of the resources at their disposal. A bundle of resources. By com- bining resources firms may
resources will have different values accord- ing be able to add value if they are: complementary
to their usage across different markets. Revisiting (Harrison et al. 1991), related (Dierickx and Cool
our analogy of the game of poker, this makes the 1989) or co-specialized (Lippman and Rumelt
rules of the game much more permissive and 2003) in nature. The concepts of
hence the game much more complex. If we complementarity, relatedness and co-
permit resources to be employed across a range specialization all speak to the issue as to how
of different markets, this is akin to a poker player resource combinations can create value. The idea
being able to take his hand of cards and play of resource com- binations (and recombinations)
across a number of different games on different is central to the literature on capabilities. A
tables. The rules of the game will vary between capability is defined as the firm’s ability to
tables, and so the value of the poker players’ undertake a productive activity, which is created
cards will vary accordingly. The role of the poker through the simultaneous deployment of
player is quickly to assess which games he/she resources and factors of production (Teece et al.
wants to play in, i.e. to assess where their cards 1997). The literature on dynamic capabilities
can be deployed most effectively. should be viewed as a complement to the RBV
The problem facing managers, therefore, is (Ambrosini and Bowman 2009; Wang and
how to understand the functionality of the Ahmed 2007).
resources that are under their control, and also to In addition to the productive opportunity set of
understand those that are under the control of the firm being influenced by resource usage,
other firms. This will aid managers in not only Penrose (1959) argues that the opportunity set is
detecting present competitors but also in also influenced by the way in which managers
anticipating future competitors. Peteraf and are able to combine resources to produce
Bergen (2003, 1029), however, argue that productive services (or capabilities). At any given
managers may be poor at understanding the range point the known productive services arising from
of potential functions from their resource-bases a given bundle of resources are unlikely to
for a number of reasons. These include: a lack of exhaust its full potential. There is always the
time and attention; bounded rationality (e.g. potential for firm expansion. Based on the
Williamson 1975); cognitive biases; and framing
discovery of changes in customer preferences and
limitations (Amit and Schoemaker 1993). The
innovation, man- agers choose to engage in the
limitation of managers to perceive competition
from outside their narrowly defined industries recombination of existing resources to satisfy this
dates back to the work of Levitt (1960) and the perceived demand. Hence, opportunities for
problems associated with managers’ myopia. expansion are limited to the extent to which the
Not only must managers understand the managers of a firm perceive there to be
functionality of their resources, they must also opportunities, are willing to act on them and are
comprehend the capacity for usage their able to capitalize on them with their own
resources permit. Some resources may have resources (Penrose 1959, 84). Thus, the growth
multiple functions, and also a capacity that of the firm involves discovering new market
enables them to be used in a number of different opportu- nities and changing and using existing
ways simultaneously. That is, a resource may resources to match these opportunities.
have a high capacity for usage so that its use on Sirmon et al. (2007) offer a more detailed
one market does not preclude it from being used conceptualization of resource recombination,
in another market. In the case of intangible focusing on the nature of resource recombina-
resources, especially in the form of knowledge, tions and their effect on capabilities. In doing so,
there is no real limit to the extent to which the they draw a distinction between the activities of
resource can be shared. Conversely, physical stabilizing, enriching and pioneering. Stabilizing
resources may be easily exhausted, as their use involves making minor incremental
on one market precludes it being used in another. improvements in existing capabilities through
minor improvements to existing resources. A
Resource Recombinations strategy of stabilizing may be a way of
maintaining a current position of competitive
Penrose (1959) argues that resources are seldom
© 2009 The Authors advantage in conditions of low environmental 1
valuable in isolation.
Journal compilation In effect,
© 2009 Blackwell it isLtdunlikely
Publishing and British that
Academy of Management 3
uncertainty. Enriching involves extending and of resources over time. The firm’s resources,
The resource-based view
elaborating of the
current firm through activities
capabilities therefore, will be directly related to the past
such as learning or adding a complementary activities of the firm, i.e. the resource base of the
resource. Pioneering is a more advanced process firm will be path dependent. Although Penrose
of resource recombination which entails ‘the highlighted that resources may be created
integration of completely new resources that through the process of competing in markets,
were recently acquired ... and added to the firm’s little attention has been focused on the issue of
resource portfolio’ (Sirmon et al. 2007, 282). resource creation (Bowman and Collier 2006). A
This process involves creativity and exploratory notable excep- tion is the Management Science
learning in order to create novel capabilities. paper of Dierickx and Cool (1989).
Dierickx and Cool (1989) attempted to
If managers are able to recombine their
summarize the growth and decay processes
resources in a range of different ways, they may
affecting those intangible assets that form the
be able to produce new outputs for the firm. For
core of the RBV. Barney (1991) examined the
example, revisiting our pub landlord above, we
consequences of firm heterogeneity (for a given
find out that in addition to owning a public house
set of resources), whereas Dierickx and Cool
he/she also owns a pet shop. In order to attract
(1989) examined the causes of firm
people into the pet shop, the manager buys a
heterogeneity. The genesis of Dierickx and
large snake, which he/she can also sell if
Cool’s (1989) argument is that, given that factor
required. The snake, however, is only employed
markets for intangible assets are incomplete,
in the pet shop during the opening hours of 9 to 5
critical resources are accumulated rather than
Monday to Saturday. As the snake does not have
acquired in ‘strategic factor markets’. Further-
to work hard for its keep, and given that it is
more, they argue that the immobility of a
under-utilized outside the shop opening hours,
resource position is linked to the characteristics
the manager starts to think how he/she can make
of the asset accumulation process. Their
a more profitable use of the resource. The
terminology has been widely followed, and their
manager then has an idea of combining the snake,
typology of asset accumulation may be
with one of the bar maids, and hey presto a
summarized briefly thus:
resource recombination leads to the creation of an
Asset mass efficiency describes Dierickx and
exotic dancer to perform during the evenings
Cool’s (1989) proposition that the marginal cost
and/or on Sundays. The manager of the pub has
of specific asset accumulation falls with the size
diversified into offering entertainment through a
of the existing relevant asset base. This is seen
resource recombination.
most clearly where activities such as R&D
Invoking our poker analogy again, the issue of
exhibit (at least locally) increasing returns with
resource recombination, like the issue of usage,
obvious benefit to established research-intensive
makes the rules of the game more permissive. By
companies.
recombining a bundle of cards, a person may be
Time compression diseconomies relate to the
able to make a series of different hands that can
observed tendency of the costs of asset
be played in different games. Furthermore, if we
accumulation to rise within a given time interval.
relax the assumption that the recombined cards
The more a firm tries to reduce the time horizon
have to be controlled by one player only, we
associated with asset accumulation, ceteris
open up the potential for players to collaborate in
paribus, the more costly the process will be.
recombining their cards. The potential for
Again, R&D is a good example where there is a
collaboration substantially increases the number
well-established trade-off between the time and
of potential recombinations that may be possible.
cost associated with accelerating the rate of
problem-solving.
Resource Creation and Decay Causal ambiguity, as described by Barney
(1991), relates to the difficulty faced by out-
The issue of resource creation was first dealt with siders - and perhaps even insiders - in isolating
by Penrose (1959) through her attempts to the particular factors responsible for a firm’s
theorize the growth process in firms. She argued competitive advantage.
that firms develop resources through their Asset interconnectedness implies that the cost
productive activities and, over time, firms will of adding an increment of resource A to the
generate an excess capacity in their resource- firm’s stock may be related to its existing stock
bases. It is the excess capacity in a resource base of resource B. Dierickx and Cool’s (1989) own
that presents the basis for firm expansion. The example is of a manufacturer whose product
1 activities of the firm willThe
© 2009 lead to the development development costs are lowered by feedback
Authors
4 Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management
benefits derived from the same firm’s customer limit the generation and testing of direct
service department. hypotheses. March 2009
Asset erosion refers to the shrinkage of the First, and perhaps most fundamental, is the
firm’s stock of intangible assets, as these are issue of tautology. Perhaps unsurprisingly, for an
destroyed by exhaustion, obsolescence and approach that ultimately ascribes differences in
rivals’ innovation. It is the intangible asset firm performance to intrinsic differences in the
equivalent of balance sheet depreciation for firms themselves, the RBV is certainly prone to
tangible assets. It both afflicts the firm in circular reasoning. Priem and Butler (2001a,b) in
isolation and arises through the actions of its an exchange with Barney (2001a), debate this
rivals. In effect, the firm is a bundle of resources point at length. Priem and Butler (2001a,b)
whose value is in constant flux. reduce the RBV to the following statement: ‘only
The work of Dierickx and Cool (1989) has valuable and rare resources can be a source of
important parallels with Barney’s (1986) bad competitive advantage’, where rarity and value in
news message, which was that, if resource turn depend upon the use to which such resources
markets are perfect, the costs of acquiring may be put. More generally, they argue that the
resources will be approximately equal to the problem of tautology lies in the relationship
value of those resources once they are used to between the general and the specific in the RBV.
implement product market strategies. Competitive advantage is considered to be rooted
Consequently, if a firm acquires resources, and in firm-specific circumstances that are
continues to use them in the same way that they themselves, at least in part, imperfectly
were previously employed, SCA will be difficult observable.
achieve in the absence of resource market Second, if one assumes (as does Barney
imperfections. Denrell et al. (2003) provide a 2001a) that the RBV may be specified in a
more nuanced understanding of resource testable form, any empirical assessment of its
acquisition, which is consistent with the work of predictions requires the identification and
Dierickx and Cool (1989), by outlining two measurement of relevant resources. Unfortu-
conditions under which SCA may be possible. nately, this has often proved problematic,
First, you may be lucky and acquire the resources because the resources of central concern are often
below their full market value because of a seller’s those associated with organizational learning etc.
ignorance. Second, you may own, or have access and are commonly unobservable (see Ambrosini
to, other idio- syncratic resources that are not and Bowman 2001; Godfrey and Hill 1995;
available to other firms and which augment the Rouse and Daellenbach 1999). Resources which
value of the resources. can easily be identified and measured are
The Resource-based View: Methodological unlikely to be of great interest to RBV
and Practical Difficulties researchers. Such resources, however, are
commonly the focus of empirical studies largely
The RBV has developed as a series of related because they can be measured, not because they
propositions that seek to explain the relation- ship are necessarily important. Consequently, a
between a firm’s resource endowment and its significant body of empirical research on the
performance and growth. However, it has not RBV has parallels with the proverbial drunk
generated clear unambiguous hypotheses in the looking under the street light for his keys. When
manner of more narrowly conceived theories of asked where he had lost his keys he responded,
firm behaviour or even transaction cost ‘somewhere over there in the dark, but can’t see a
economics (TCE), an approach with which the thing over there so I’m looking under the light
RBV is frequently compared (e.g. by Newbert instead.’ A further consequence of the resource
2007). For example, TCE contends that identification problem is that researchers have
transaction costs rise with certain (relatively) used an extremely varied set of proxies for key
well-defined market attributes, especially asset capabilities and resources, making systematic
specificity, and that vertical integration comparisons across the empirical literature more
dominates outsourcing where transaction costs difficult.
are sufficiently high. Together, these hypotheses Third, firm heterogeneity creates problems for
have suggested a simple reduced form equation researchers who are interested in generat- ing a
test: namely, that vertical integration will homogeneous sample of firms for testing specific
increase with asset specificity. Variants of such RBV hypotheses. Recall that the central thrust of
an equation have been estimated by many the RBV is that any firm’s competitive advantage
researchers. By con- trast, the RBV has a number is rooted in its unique attribute set. If each firm is
of methodological
© 2009 The Authors and practical difficulties that unique, any sample of firms is heterogeneous 1by
Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management 5
definition. This clearly makes it difficult to different business models which presumably
The resource-based view of the
derive meaningful firm about the causes of
inferences require differing resource bundles such that a
competitive advantage across the sample. To performance-resource model indiscriminately
reduce sample heterogeneity, some researchers estimated across airlines is unlikely to yield
have focused on single-industry studies, often strong results.
using exogenous changes in the industry Finally, best practice firm-level empirical
environment, e.g. deregulation (see Ingham and work now generally uses first-differenced panel
Thompson 1995), as ‘natural experiments’. data sets, usually unbalanced to minimize
Fourth, identifying and explaining causal selection/survivor biases. However, in empirical
relationships in large firms is problematic. The work on the RBV it is the fixed effects, discarded
sheer complexity of large organizations makes it in differencing, that contain most of the interest.
very difficult to isolate the performance effects of It follows that much empirical work in the field
specific resources. Birger Wernerfelt recently still tends to use the (otherwise discredited)
argued that, if you take a firm like Wal-Mart, single equation, cross-sectional design. This
there are probably 10,000 little ideas there that raises inevitable problems of causality. For
each might be worth $100,000 or less in annual example, if a study of pharma- ceutical
profits. Therefore, the complexity of the companies reports a positive corre- lation
organization means that a whole range of small between performance and R&D spend, the
initiatives may influence the performance of the researcher cannot, without further tests, rule out
firm, but each in a very small way (Lockett et al. the possibility that R&D depends upon
2008). Moreover, Barney’s (1991) argument that performance rather than the reverse. Furthermore,
causal ambiguity sustains competitive advantage, multicollinearity of explanatory variables, often
by restricting rivals’ ability to isolate and hence size related, is common in cross-sectional firm-
replicate rent-generating resources, itself suggests level work. This reduces the efficiency of
limited potential for empirical work. If rivals, i.e. estimates, leading to what Swann (2006) terms
competitors within the same strategic group, the noise-signal ratio. Many cross-sectional
cannot fathom a firm’s key resources it appears studies do not address these difficulties.
unlikely that models using externally measurable
variables will achieve strong explanatory power,
particularly since these are often estimated across The Resource-based View: Empirical
broad industries to allow viable sample sizes. Evidence
Fifth, not merely is agreement on a working Empirical testing of elements of the RBV has
definition of ‘competitive advantage’ itself focused on two main issues. First, scholars have
controversial (Foss and Knudsen 2003; Powell examined the relationship between firm
2001), but such a concept is directly unobserv- performance and the possession of identifiable
able so that empirical tests normally involve and imperfectly imitable resources/capabilities/
seeking to explain inter-firm differences in competences. Second, researchers have examined
performance (see Peteraf and Barney 2003) with whether the prior possession of such resources
respect to observable differences in the firms’ shapes the subsequent development of the firm in
identifiable resource endowments. Equating ways the RBV predicts.
performance and competitive advantage in this
way strictly tests the joint hypothesis that
resources and not other factors (see Ray et al. Resources and Firm Performance
2003) generate a competitive advantage, and that As suggested above, the overarching proposition
the firm is effectively managed to harvest this of the RBV suggests that a firm’s possession of
competitive advantage. specialized resources may permit it to enjoy a
Sixth, the logic of the RBV does not predict a competitive advantage over its rivals which,
universal relationship between firm per- given suitable management, is converted into an
formance and any particular resource. On the observable performance advantage. Furthermore,
contrary, the value of a resource to the firm will where this resource bundle is imperfectly
depend upon the specifics of its use, including the imitable the competitive advantage is sustainable
deployment of co-specialized assets. Therefore, in at least the medium term. Testing this
even at the industry level, there may be no relationship presents difficulties, some of which
discernible relationship between firm have been outlined in the pre- vious section.
performance and the possession of resource X. Among these are problems in both specifying
For example, within the airline industry, full testable hypotheses and measuring dependent and
1 service carriers and © 2009 The Authors
low-costs operate very explanatory
6 Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing variables.
Ltd and British Academy of Management
In the case of the dependent variable, it is literature, going back to the pioneering work of
noted above that difficulties in defining and Penrose (1959), is concerned withMarchthe 2009
way in
measuring comparative advantage have ensured which the firm’s current resource bundle shapes
that a variety of performance variables have been its future development. This work implicitly
used in the literature. These have included both assumes that in a competitive environment
accounting and stock market- based measures. decisions concerning the firm’s activity set will
The choice of resource measures as explanatory reflect managers’ attempts to use the resources at
variables is necessarily even wider. This is not their disposal in the interest of advancing the
simply a reflection of the availability of data to firm’s performance. This leads to predictions
particular researchers; it also reflects the specific about shifts in the boundaries of the firm
nature of any hypoth- esized link between conditional upon its current resource set. Among
resources and competitive advantage. However, boundary decisions analysed in this way are
an overall consequence of the diversity of the issues concerning diversification, modes of entry
available empirical literature on the RBV and the to new markets and refocusing. The diversity of
range of variables it uses is that formal meta- these issues has thus far precluded any
analyses are pre- cluded, and even summary quantitative survey of which we are aware. The
statistics are difficult to compute. literature review that follows is based on an
The most comprehensive treatment of the updating of that in Lockett and Thompson
RBV performance literature is that of Newbert (2001). We depart from David and Han (2004),
(2007), who performed a semi-quantitative Newbert (2007) and Armstrong and Shimizu
analysis of the studies identified via a formal (2007) in our approach to reviewing the empirical
search procedure. Newbert (2007) used a key literature, which employs a keyword search for
word search across the management literature to RBV papers, because we feel that such an
identify papers appearing to offer a test of the approach omits empirical studies that may be
resource-performance linkage. After the RBV in nature, but do not explicitly mention the
application of relevance criteria, he was left with RBV. Our survey includes papers that test
55 studies from which he generated the following hypotheses congruent with the RBV, even if they
conclusions: First, only 53% of the papers he do not explicitly mention it.2
examined offered positive support for the link
between resources (broadly defined) and Product/Service Market Diversification
performance. This figure, he suggests, is broadly
One of the most explicit and implicit empiri- cal
consistent with other theories of strategic
application of the RBV has been in the literature
management such as transaction cost economics
examining patterns of diversification via new
(see David and Han 2004). Second, he found
market entry. Econometric studies by Lemelin
evidence that resource combinations, and/or
(1982), MacDonald (1985), Montgomery and
capabilities/competences, are more likely to
Hariharan (1991) and Ingham and Thompson
explain performance differ- ences rather than
(1995) have shown that diver- sification is not a
single resources in isolation. As with the drunk
purely random process, driven by idiosyncratic
looking for his keys under the light, many RBV
managerial decisions, but instead follows a
scholars (including the authors) have focused on
pattern consistent with the exploitation of
resources that can be easily measured, e.g. simple
existing identifiable resources (see Montgomery
measures of human capital.
1994, for a review). Lemelin (1982) found that
Given the methodological problems in
diversification tended to occur across industries
designing general tests of the resource-
using similar resources. MacDonald (1985) and
performance relationship, discussed above, the Montgomery and Hariharan (1991) used US
relatively modest empirical support revealed by firm-level data to demonstrate a similar outcome,
Newbert’s survey is generally unsurprising. whereas Montgomery and Wernerfelt (1988)
Perhaps more worrying for those of us work- ing identified that specific resources may only be
in the field is that even this level of support is transferred into a small number of industries and
probably inflated by publication bias: that is the that firms with more specific resources could
tendency of journal editors to disproportionately generate higher rents with less diversification.
reject insignificant findings. Ingham and Thompson (1995) used financial
services deregulation in the UK as a ‘natural
experiment’ to show that diversification into
Resources and Firm Development
previously prohibited, but nonetheless related,
As noted
© 2009 above, an important strand of the RBV
The Authors financial product markets followed the firms’ 1
Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management 7
resource endowments at the time of deregulation. receiver market from the 1950s to the 1970s.
The resource-based
Whileview
the of the has
RBV firmbeen explicitly and Furthermore, the advantage conferred by radio
implicitly used in analysing firms’ diversify- ing experience con- tinued to exert a statistically
expansions into new product markets, the firm’s significant effect, even after 1965 when colour
decision to expand its operation by pro- ducing TV began to dominate the market. Greenstein
its existing products in new regions or national (2000) demonstrates that, although entrants to the
markets involves directly analogous reasoning. ISP sector have come to a completely new
Here the dominant internalization paradigm (see industry, their prior experience, commercial
Caves 1996, for a survey) used to explain the background and local market characteristics
internationalization of business, suggests that determine their subsequent development and
firms choose to become multi- national when the specialization. Thompson (2007) reaches a
specific assets they possess are more similar conclusion with respect to entrants to the
economically transferred across international digital camera business, while Mitchell (1991)
boundaries within the firm rather than by using and Carroll et al. (1996) report com- parable
markets. Internalization theory’s focus is upon results from the diagnostic imaging and early US
the role of comparative levels of transactions car industry, respectively.
costs in determining the optimal form of Scott Morton (1999) shows that, among the set
expansion, and therefore, it might be considered of generic pharmaceutical producers, prior
an application of TCE. However, since the technological, scientific and marketing
transactions costs usually considered to drive this experiences determine which new product
decision are those attached to intangible assets markets, created by compound discovery or
and firm-specific attributes, where replication is patent lapse, individual firms choose to enter.
also problematic, there is an obvious relevance Thus, prior expertise with a particular class of
for the RBV. Non-specific resources pose far compounds, delivery mechanism or disease
fewer problems for market contracting but, treatment market will increase the probability of
conversely, since activities depending upon them entry. Interestingly, she notes how different firm
alone can be easily replicated, offer little resources, the result of divergent experiences,
opportunity for sustaining a competitive assist the industry by preventing the simultaneous
advantage. entry of large numbers of producers with
The evidence on foreign direct investment, at inevitable widespread losses (Scott Morton 1999,
industry and firm levels, is generally con- sistent 436). This confirms the classic argument of
with the internalization perspective (see Caves Richardson (1972) on the importance of firm
1996). It points to concentrations of multinational heterogeneity in the orderly diffusion of
activity in R&D-intensive industries (where innovations.
proprietary technology is important) and
advertising-intensive industries, where marketing
and brand name issues are important. Of Mode of Market entry (Product and
particular relevance to the RBV is the firm-level Geographic)
evidence (e.g. Caves 1996; Grubaugh 1987) that Firms seeking to extend their profitable activities
confirms the effect of proprietary assets and typically require assets to com- plement their
relative R&D and advertising outlays on the existing resource bundles and frequently need to
probability of a large firm having multinational obtain these from existing firms. Mergers and
operations. acquisitions, joint ventures and other
Inter-industry differences in firm organiza- collaborative associations have been analysed
tion constitute a potential difficulty for firm-level quite extensively as alternative mecha- nisms for
work in this field. In consequence, single- the acquisition of complementary assets for
industry studies generally allow a more detailed domestic and foreign expansions alike. In some
specification of relevant resource vari- ables than instances, for example, in obtain- ing access to
would be possible in inter-industry work. Recent specific assets in countries with poorly developed
examples include case studies of the US TV capital markets or with restrictions on private
receiver industry by Klepper and Simons (2000), and/or foreign ownership, the costs associated
Internet service providers (ISPs) by Greenstein with acquisition may be prohibitive. In others,
(2000), and the generic pharmaceutical industry joint venturing with the desired party may turn
by Scott Morton (1999). Klepper and Simons out to be simply unattainable. However, a
(2000) show that prior experience in radio growing body of research suggests that, where a
technology was a major determinant of success choice exists, joint venturing tends to be
1 among entrants to© 2009 The Authors
the rapidly expanding TV associated
8 Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and Britishwith a of
Academy lack of specific expertise (of
Management
markets, technology, cultures, etc.) on the part of capital market innovations and a reduction in
the firm con- cerned. Singh and Kogut (1989) transaction costs (Hoskisson andMarch 2009and
Turk 1990)
using foreign entrants to the US, Hennart and a decline in scarcity rents to the resource of
Reddy (1997) for Japanese entrants to the US, general management (Goold and Luchs 1993).
and Thompson (1999) using domestic and Since these changes coincided with the
foreign expansions by diversifying UK utility internationalization and deregulation of capital
companies, all report that having controlled for markets in the 1980s, the reversal of corporate
size, prior market experience encourages diversification also dates from this time (Haynes
expansion by acquisi- tion rather than joint et al. 2003).
venture. Such a result is supportive of the RBV in By contrast, the AT hypothesis attributes over-
that it confirms that outsiders with incomplete diversification to the diversion of free cash flow
resources need to secure specific resources via into preferred (sometimes negative net present
cooperation with the insider. The experienced value) investments by managers insulated from
entrant is able to purchase the relevant resources capital market discipline by weak corporate
by acquiring a suitable company. Of course, this governance arrangements (Jensen 1986). The
does not pre- clude joint venturing having other widespread subsequent reversal of this process is
advantages.3 again attributed to capital market changes,
particularly the rise in hostile and debt-financed
takeovers in the 1980s that tended to pressurize
Corporate Refocusing (Market Exit)
managers into a return towards value-maximizing
The reversal of diversification is refocusing. It is behaviour (Jensen 1986, 1993).
reasonably well established (see Haynes et al. A growing volume of empirical studies of
2003; Markides 1995, and references therein) corporate refocusing provides support for both
that, in the USA and UK, there was a continuing strategy and governance hypotheses in explaining
increase in diversification among larger firms the phenomenon (Johnson 1996). Markides
until the early 1980s. Thereafter, there has been a (1992) found that refocusing firms were highly
discernible trend towards cor- porate refocusing, diversified and suffered from poor performance
defined here as the disposal of peripheral relative to their industry counterparts. He also
activities and the renewed con- centration upon found that the higher the R&D intensity of the
core businesses. In the past, this has frequently core business, the lower the likelihood that the
involved the divestment of unrelated activities firm would refocus. Haynes et al. (2003), using a
4

acquired in the conglomerate merger boom of the panel of large UK firms, include strategic and
1960s and 1970s (Shleifer and Vishny 1991). governance variables in an analysis of divestment
This reversal of the trend towards diversification activity. They find that divestment, variously
suggests a number of interesting questions for measured, increases with size, diversification and
researchers. First, why did so many firms engage market share in the firm’s core business, while
in apparently unsuccessful diversification, falling with performance. However, they also
especially unre- lated diversification, in the 1960s report a significant positive coefficient for
and 1970s? Second, what caused this policy to be leverage, in line with Jensen’s (1993) free cash
reversed? And third, why did this reversal occur flow reasoning and, tellingly, a large and highly
in the 1980s? significant increase in divestment in the year
Both the RBV and Agency Theory (AT) following the publication of a bid rumour. They
provide insights into these questions which are, at find some support for strategy-governance
least in part, both substitutes and com- plements. interaction effects. For example, firms with
From the perspective of the RBV, there are at ‘strong’ governance regimes, defined in terms of
least two contending explanations for widespread management equity ownership and the existence
over-diversification among large firms. First, a of substantial ‘blockholders’, ex- perience a
large number of managers, perhaps acting on much larger sensitivity to poor performance. In
incorrect suppositions of internal capital market contrast to Johnson (1996), who finds internal
superiority may have simply got it wrong. In the and external antecedents to corporate refocusing
RBV, as in Austrian economics (see below), in the US, Haynes et al. (2003) do not find a
there appears to be no necessary presumption that significant role for senior management changes.
managers always make correct decisions. Second, While the RBV does not unambiguously
it is possible that previously optimally organized support the superiority of related diversification
firms found themselves over-diversified because over unrelated diversification (see Chatterjee and
the comparative advantage of the M-form had Wernerfelt 1991), there is a presumption in much
© 2009 The Authors 1
declined. This has
Journal compilation been
© 2009 alternatively
Blackwell Publishing Ltdattributed to of
and British Academy
the refocusing literature that divesting
of Management 9
peripheral activities to concentrate upon those of cases must resist the misplaced certainty of ex
The resource-based viewrelated
more closely of thetofirm
one another should raise post rationalizations. Analyses offering 20:20
performance. This is reinforced by arguments, hindsight do not merely disguise the complexity
dating back at least to Penrose (1959), that of the decision-taking they cover but are also
suggest the costs of management rise with size unfalsifiable. Under imperfect information, ex
and complexity and, unless these are offset by ante optimal decisions can have unpleasant
comparable benefits, as prom- ised, for example, outcomes while ex ante mistakes can yield
by the M-form hypothesis, performance may be fortuitous mistakes. As Donald Rumsfeld opined
enhanced by decoupling. These conjectures have about the problems facing US military operations
been supported by a number of studies of the in Afghanistan:
effects of divestiture on corporate performance.
Montgomery and Thomas (1988), John and Ofek Reports that say that something hasn’t happened
(1995) and Hoskisson and Johnson (1992) all are always interesting to me, because as we know,
reported an improvement in ROA following there are known knowns; there are things we know
corporate asset sales. Markides (1995) found a we know. We also know there are known
large and statistically significant increase in unknowns; that is to say we know there are some
profitability following reductions in things we do not know. But there are also unknown
diversification, although his results also suggest unknowns - the ones we don’t know we don’t
that the gains were larger for the earlier cases of know.
refocusing in his sample. Haynes et al. (2002), in
a dynamic panel study of firm profitability, report Clearly there are resources - known knowns -
statis- tically significant positive shocks whose potential to impact on a firm’s future
following divestment for up to four years after growth is appreciated. Similarly, there are factors
the event. This study also explores the effect of - known unknowns - whose causal direction is
‘complexity’, measured as the interaction of size understood but whose impact can only be
and the level of diversification, and reports that evaluated ex post. Finally, there are the unknown
the benefits of divestment are substantially unknowns, the products of unfolding market,
greater for ‘complex’ firms. In brief, the technological or other events, whose
refocusing literature tends to reinforce the manifestation cannot be anticipated and
conclusion from that on corporate diversi- incorporated in even the most careful scenario
fication, in many respects its opposite, about the planning. For example, firm managers may know
importance of relatedness in successful firm that their firm is outperforming its rivals but are
growth. unable to explain why this is the case, i.e. the
causal ambiguity problem. An example of known
Practical Insights from the Resource-based unknowns would be the future value of a firm’s
View resources as markets evolve. We know the value
of the resources will change over time but not
As academics working in Business and how. We may not be on our own in not being
Management Schools, we are increasingly able to under- stand the notion of unknown
encouraged to make prescriptive statements on unknowns.
the basis of existing management knowledge. Known knowns are unlikely to enable a firm
The use of case studies in strategy teaching to outperform its rivals in the medium to long run
illustrates this dilemma. On the one hand, the unless there are market impediments that prevent
suitably selected case can illustrate neatly the competition for the underlying resources (this is
successful or unsuccessful past attempt of some the genesis of Barney’s 1991 paper). Known
managers to achieve a winning fit between unknowns, however, are much more interesting
resources and strategy. Such teaching aids both from an RBV perspective. The role of managers
reinforce the analysis we are offer- ing and is to try and make sense of known unknowns and
capture the attention of the class by grounding to manage the ambiguity surrounding them. As
the subject in a relevant business context. One the for unknown unknowns, what can we do about
other hand, the subject also emphasizes the them if we do not ever know about them, even ex
importance of the unknown in the specifics of post?
individual cases. Indeed, as noted above, the The approach adopted in this paper is to treat
inevitable ignorance of the outsider confronted the RBV not as a theory of firm behaviour but,
by causal ambiguity is both an important device primarily as a theory that offers insights about the
to sustain com- petitive advantage and a partial decision-making behaviour of managers. Below,
2 © 2009 The Authors
0
blindfold to any would-be case analyst. The user
Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management
we have outlined some of the main practical consumer tastes, allied to the competitive
insights of the RBV, which are presented as an process, will tend to erode theMarch 2009
value of many
illustrative rather than exhaustive list. resources over time. In general, the resources that
First, managers need to understand what are may hold the key for a firm’s position of
the strengths and weaknesses of a firm. competitive advantage in one period may merely
Wernerfelt’s motivation for writing his seminal become a necessary resource to earn normal
paper in 1984 was a disagreement with Porter’s returns. Consequently, firms should continuously
work on industry analysis and generic com- seek to manage their resource bases, investing in
petition, which abstracted away from inter-firm decaying resources and also seeking to develop
differences (Lockett et al. 2008). Wernerfelt’s new resources.
view was that opportunities and threats cannot be
Fifth, acquiring competitive advantage in a
exploited solely through the external posi-
resource market is not possible in the absence of
tioning of businesses. The firm’s distinctive
internal characteristics are central to any asymmetric information and/or co-specialized
discussion of strategy formulation. Strategy resources with which you are going to aug- ment
should encapsulate what the firm is distinctively the new resources (Denrell et al. 2003).
good at, and also seek to address the potential Therefore, it is likely that any position of
weaknesses of the firm. A rare example of competitive advantage will have to be internally
authors who have focused on the problems developed (Barney 1986).
associated with firm weaknesses are West and
DeCastro (2001) or Powell’s (2001) considera- The Resource-based View Looking Forward
tion of competitive disadvantage.
Second, the resource base of the firm is path Where is the RBV going, and where should it be
dependent, i.e. history matters. Firm resources going? The RBV, owing to its permeable and
are developed through competition in markets, eclectic nature, has become something of a broad
and so the markets in which the firm competes church (Hoskisson et al. 1999). In this paper, we
today, and the way in which it competes, will be have focused on the core essence of the RBV, but
the most important determinants of that firm’s many sub-fields have developed as areas of
resource base tomorrow. In effect, any learning study, including the study of knowledge (as a
by the firm will be, ceteris paribus, closed in to specialized firm resource), capabilities (created
its existing operations. by bringing together bundles of resources) and
Third, managers need to be able to under- dynamic capabilities (the ability to continuously
stand the functionality of their resources. adapt and re- configure a resource and capability
Resources are defined by their usage. For base). We cannot predict where future
example, a building may be used for a number of developments will take the RBV. Instead, we
different purposes, but its current usage may conclude by offering a subjective view on where
blinker managers from fully appreciating the full we think scholars should focus their efforts in the
range of potential functions the building could be future. We focus on theory and method as we feel
used for. This idea links back to Levitt’s (1960) that empirical evidence and practical insights will
marketing concept, in that customers are not follow logically in time.
interested in the resources of a firm, rather they First, rather than focusing on the conse-
are interested in how firm resources may satisfy quences of firm heterogeneity, more scholarly
their wants and needs. Two firms may be able to attention needs to be devoted to the theoretical
satisfy similar wants and needs of a customer but issue of the causes of firm heterogeneity. All
by using different resources. In the area of RBV work begins with the explicit or implicit
information and communication technology, high assumption of firm heterogeneity. Even Dierickx
degrees of technological change have led to a and Cool’s (1989) arguments about the causes of
blurring of market boundaries. Companies from competitive advantage focus on how differences
com- puting, telecommunications, software, between firms may become amplified over time.
consumer electronics are now all competing If the RBV is to develop as a theory, it is
against one another in similar markets but with important that we understand the origins of firm
histori- cally very different backgrounds. heterogeneity. In a recent interview Birger
Fourth, the resource base of the firm is con- Wernerfelt has posed the question as to whether
tinuously subject to the processes of resource or not it is possible to start with a model of
creation and decay. As markets evolve, the homogeneous firms or homogeneous people, or
underlying value of a firm’s resource base at least randomly distributed people, and generate
© 2009 The Authors significant heterogeneities between firms 2
changes over ©time.
Journal compilation Changing
2009 Blackwell technology
Publishing Ltd and British and
Academy of Management 1
(Lockett et al. 2008). We feel that, by providing need to become more diligent in their search for
The resource-based viewtheoforigins
insights into the firm
of firm heterogeneity, we suitable instruments to overcome the endogeneity
may be able to understand better how managers problem in commonly employed variables
can generate and manage their firm’s distinctive (Lockett et al. 2008). These improve- ments in
differences. quantitative investigation will hope- fully be
Second, more scholarly attention needs to be accompanied by insightful case-study work.
focused on the neglected theoretical issue of
resource functionality. Evidence of this neglect Notes
can be identified in the burgeoning literature on
dynamic capabilities (see Ambrosini and 1 Address for correspondence: Andy Lockett, Profes-
Bowman 2009). Scholars of dynamic capabilities sor of Strategy and Entrepreneurship, Nottingham
have focused on the role of resource University Business School, Jubilee Campus,
creation/decay and resource recom- bination, but Wollaton Road, Nottingham, NG8 1BB, UK. Tel.:
have not addressed the issue of resource +44 (0) 115 9515268; Fax: +44 (0)115 8466667; e-
mail: Andy.Lockett@nottingham.ac.uk
functionality. Any discussion that products and
2 Lockett and Thompson (2001) argue that there is a
resources are two sides of the same coin, and that
considerable body of empirical evidence in the field
resource usage may determine how we perceive of economics that empirically tests hypotheses
the functionality of a resource is largely absent congruent to the RBV; i.e. the RBV is present but
from the RBV literature. We feel that this is a unrecognized.
fundamental weakness of the RBV literature to
date. It is important, therefore, that more 3 It can avoid some of the management/digestion
scholarly effort is invested in trying to understand problems associated with the acquisition of
resource functionality and how this relates to the diversified firms (see Kay 1997). An expanding
firm entering a joint venture can target the
potential product/service market space a firm
resources it requires without having to acquire and
may compete in. There are obvious links that
subsequently dispose of (see Ravenscraft and
may be made here to cognitive psychology and Scherer 1987) the unwanted remainder. Similarly,
decision framing. the lower level of sunk commitment associated
Third, as the RBV is a theory about what firms with joint venturing may reduce risk by comparison
are, and does not require a host of limiting with a full acquisition (see Balakrishna and Korza
assumptions, it can be deployed with other 1993).
theories to explain strategic behaviour. This is a 4 A result that suggests that diversification is bene-
huge advantage of the RBV, as com- plex ficial in capturing the spillover effects of R&D.
relationships can seldom be understood through a
single theoretical lens (Gray and Wood 1991). To
date the RBV has been linked to theories of the
References
firm, such as AT and trans- action cost Ambrosini V. (2007). The resource-based view of the
economics. For example, RBV provides insights firm. In Jenkins, M., Ambrosini, V. and Collier, N.
into the issue of value creation within firms, (eds), Advanced Strategic Management: A Multi-
whereas TCE provides insights into economic Perspective Approach. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
organization (Madhok 2002). We urge scholars to Ambrosini, V. and Bowman, C. (2001). Tacit
embrace the permeable, eclectic and permissive knowledge: some suggestions for operationalization.
nature of the RBV to generate new insights into Journal of Management Studies, 38, 811-829.
Ambrosini, V. and Bowman, C. (2009). What are
firm behaviour.
dynamic capabilities and are they a useful construct
Finally, scholars need to reflect on their
in strategic management? International Journal of
methodological approaches to empirical research Management Reviews, this issue.
on the RBV. We have suggested that it is those Amit, R. and Schoemaker PJ.H. (1993). Strategic
resources that are complex, unob- servable and assets and organizational rent. Strategic Manage-
difficult to measure that are likely to be of ment Journal, 14, 33-46.
greatest importance. Further- more, the paper has Armstrong, C.E. and Shimizu K. (2007). A review of
noted that problems of multicollinearity and approaches to empirical research on the resource-
endogeneity plague hypothesis testing in the area, based view of the firm. Journal of Management, 33,
particularly with firm-level data. Addressing 959-986.
these problems will not be easy. It may be that Balakrishnan S. and Korza, M. (1993). Information
more effort needs to be devoted to the collection asymmetry, adverse selection and joint ventures:
of data at the business unit level or with samples theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior
of smaller firms where the resource set is less and Organization, 20, 99-117.
2 © 2009 The Authors
complex. Also, management researchers may Barney, J. (1986). Strategic factor markets:
2 Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management
expectations, luck, and business strategy. competitive advantage. Managerial and Decision
Management Science, 32, 1231-1241. Economics, 24, 291-307. March 2009
Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained com- Godfrey, P.C. and Hill, C.W.L. (1995). The problem of
petitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17, 99- unobservables in strategic management research.
120. Strategic Management Journal, 16, 519-533.
Barney, J. (1995). Looking inside for competitive Goold, M. and Luchs, K. (1993). Why diversify? Four
advantage. Academy of Management Executive, decades of management thinking. Academy of
9(4), 49-61. Management Executive, 7(3), 7-26.
Barney, J. (2001a). Is the resource-based ‘view’ a Gray, B., and Wood, D.J. (1991). Collaborative
useful perspective for strategic management alliances: moving from practice to theory. Journal
research? Yes. Academy of Management Review, of Applied Behavioral Science, 27(1), 3-22.
26, 41-58. Greenstein, S. (2000). Building and delivering the
Barney, J. (2001b). Resource-based theories of com- virtual world: commercializing services for internet
petitive advantage: a ten-year retrospective on the access. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 391-
resource-based view. Journal of Management, 27, 412.
643-650. Grubaugh, S.G. (1987). Determinants of direct foreign
Barney, J. and Arikan, A.M. (2001). The resource- investment. Review of Economics & Statistics,
based view: origins and implications. In Hitt, M.A., 69(1), 149-152.
Freeman, R.E. and Harrison, J.S. (eds), Handbook Harrison, R.E., Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E. and
of Strategic Management. Oxford: Blackwell. Ireland, D. (1991). Synergies and post-acquisition
Barney, J., Wright, M. and Ketchen, D.J. (2001). The performance: differences versus similarities in
resource-based view of the firm: ten years after resource allocations. Journal of Management, 17,
1991. Journal of Management, 27, 625-641. 173 -190.
Bowman, C. and Collier, N. (2006). A contingency Haynes, M., Thompson, S. and Wright, M. (2002). The
approach to resource creation processes. impact of divestment on firm performance:
International Journal of Management Reviews, 8, empirical evidence from a panel of UK companies.
191-211. Journal of Industrial Economics, 50, 173-196.
Carroll, G.R., Bigelow, L.S., Siedel, M.D.L. and Tsai, Haynes, M., Thompson, S. and Wright, M. (2003). The
L.B. (1996). The fates of de novo and de alio determinants of divestment: a panel data analysis.
producers in the American automobile industry. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization,
Strategic Management Journal, 17(Summer Special 52(1), 147-166.
Issue), 117-137. Hennart, J.F. and Reddy, S. (1997). The choice
Caves, R.E. (1996). Multinational Enterprise and between mergers/acquisitions and joint ventures: the
Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer- case of Japanese investors in the United States.
sity Press. Strategic Management Journal, 18, 1-12.
Chatterjee, S. and Wernerfelt, B. (1991). The link Hoskisson, R.E. and Johnson, R.A. (1992). Corporate
between resources and type of diversification: restructuring and strategic change: the effect of
theory and evi- dence. Strategic Management diversification strategy and R&D intensity. Strategic
Journal, 12, 33-48. Management Journal, 13, 625-634.
Coase, R.H. (1937). The theory and nature of the firm. Hoskisson, R.E. and Turk, T.A. (1990). Corporate
Economica, 4(16), 386-405. restructuring: governance and control limits of the
Collis, D.J. (1994). Research note: how valuable are internal capital market. Academy of Management
organizational capabilities? Strategic Management Review, 15, 459-477.
Journal, 15(Winter Special Issue), 143-152. Hoskisson, R.E., Hitt, M.A., Wan, W.P. and Yiu, D.
Combs, J. and Ketchen, D.J. (1999). Explaining (1999). Theory and research in strategic
interfirm cooperation and performance: toward a management: swings of a pendulum. Journal of
reconciliation of predictions from the resource- Management, 25, 417-456.
based view and organizational economics. Strategic Ingham, H. and Thompson, S. (1995). Deregulation,
Management Journal, 20, 867-888. firm capabilities and diversifying entry decisions:
David, R.J. and Han, S.K. (2004). A systematic assess- the case of financial services. Review of Economics
ment of the empirical support for transaction cost & Statistics, 77(1), 177-183.
economics. Strategic Management Journal, 25, 39- Jensen, M.C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow,
58. corporate finance and takeovers. American
Denrell, J., Fang, C. and Winter, S. (2003). The Economic Review, 76, 323-329.
econom- ics of strategic opportunity. Strategic Jensen, M.C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution,
Management Journal, 24, 977-990. exit, and the failure of internal control systems.
Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989). Asset stock accumu- Journal of Finance, 48, 831-880.
lation and sustainability of competitive advantage. John, K. and Ofek, E. (1995). Asset sales and the
Management Science, 35, 1504-1511. increase in focus. Journal of Financial Economics,
Foss, N.J. and Knudsen, T. (2003). The resource-
© 2009 The Authors
37, 105-126. 2
based
Journal tangle: ©towards
compilation a sustainable
2009 Blackwell explanation
Publishing Ltd of Johnson,
and British Academy R.A. (1996). Antecedents and outcomes 3of
of Management
corporate refocusing. Journal of Management, 22, Diversification, Ricardian rents, and Tobin’s q.
The resource-based view of the firm
439-494. Rand Journal of Economics, 19, 623-632.
Kay, N.M. (1997). Pattern in Corporate Evolution. Newbert, S.L. (2007). Empirical research on the
Oxford: Oxford University Press. resource-based view of the firm: an assessment and
Klepper, S. and Simons, K.L. (2000). Dominance by suggestions for future research. Strategic Manage-
birthright: entry of prior radio producers and com- ment Journal, 28, 121-146.
petitive ramifications in the U.S. television receiver Penrose, E.T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the
industry. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 997- Firm. New York: John Wiley.
1016. Peteraf, M. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive
Lado, A. and Wilson, M. (1994). Human resource advantage: a resource-based view. Strategic Man-
systems and sustained competitive advantage: a agement Journal, 14, 179-192.
competency-based perspective. Academy of Man- Peteraf, M. and Barney, J. (2003). Unraveling the
agement Review, 19, 699-727. resource-based tangle. Managerial and Decision
Lemelin, A. (1982). Relatedness in the patterns of Economics, 24, 309-323.
interindustry diversification. Review of Economics Peteraf, M. and Bergen, M. (2003). Scanning dynamic
and Statistics, 64, 646-657. competitive landscapes: a market-based and
Levitt, T. (1960). Marketing myopia. Harvard resource-based framework. Strategic Manage- ment
Business Review, 38(4), 45-56. Journal, 24, 1027-1041.
Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R. (2003). The pay- ments Porter, M. (1980). Competitive Strategy. New York:
perspective: micro-foundations of resource analysis. Free Press.
Strategic Management Journal, 24, 903 - 927. Powell, T.C. (2001). Competitive advantage: logical
Lockett, A. (2005). Edith Penrose’s legacy to the and philosophical considerations. Strategic Man-
resource-based view. Managerial and Decision agement Journal, 22, 875-888.
Economics, 26, 83-98. Priem, R.L. and Butler, J.E. (2001a). Is the resource-
Lockett, A. and Thompson, S. (2001). The resource- based ‘view’ a useful perspective for strategic man-
based view and economics. Journal of Management, agement research? Academy of Management
27, 723-754. Review, 26, 22-40.
Lockett, A., O’Shea, R. and Wright, M. (2008). The Priem, R.L. and Butler, J.E. (2001b). Tautology in the
development of the resource-based view of the firm: resource-based view and the implications of exter-
reflections from Birger Wernerfelt. Organiza- tion nally determined resource value: further comments.
Studies, 29, 1125-1411. Academy of Management Review, 26, 57- 66.
MacDonald, J.M. (1985). R&D and the direction of Ravenscraft, D.J. and Scherer, F.M. (1987). Mergers,
diversification. Review of Economics and Statistics, Sell-offs and Economic Efficiency. Washington, DC:
67, 583-590. Brookings Institutions.
Madhok, A. (2002). Reassessing the fundamentals and Ray, G., Barney, J.B. and Muhanna, W.A. (2003).
beyond: Ronald Coase, the transaction cost and Capabilities, business processes, and competitive
resource-based theories of the firm and the advantage: choosing the dependent variable in
institutional structure of production. Strategic Man- empirical tests of the resource-based view. Strategic
agement Journal, 23, 535-550. Management Journal, 25, 23 -37.
Markides, C.C. (1992). Consequences of corporate Richardson, G.B. (1972). The organization of industry.
refocusing. Academy of Management Journal, 35, Economic Journal, 82, 883 - 896.
398-412. Rouse, M.J. and Daellenbach, U.S. (1999). Rethinking
Markides, C.C. (1995). Diversification, restructuring research methods for the resource-based
and economic performance. Strategic Management perspective: isolating sources of sustainable
Journal, 16, 101-118. competitive advan- tage. Strategic Management
McGahan, A.M. and Porter, M.E. (1997). How much Journal, 20, 487-494.
does industry matter really? Strategic Management Rumelt, R. (1984). Towards a strategic theory of the
Journal, 18(Summer Special Issue), 15-30. firm. In Lamb, R. (ed.), Competitive Strategic Man-
Mitchell, W. (1991). Dual clocks: entry order influ- agement. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
ences on incumbent and newcomer market share and Scott Morton, F.M. (1999). Entry decisions in the
survival when specialized assets retain their value. generic pharmaceutical industry. Rand Journal of
Strategic Management Journal, 12, 85-100. Economics, 30, 421-440.
Montgomery, C.A. (1994). Corporate diversification. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1991). Takeovers in the
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(3), 163-178. ’60s and the ’80s: evidence and implications.
Montgomery, C.A. and Hariharan, S. (1991). Diversi- Strategic Management Journal, 12(Winter Special
fied expansion by large established firms. Journal of Issue), 51-59.
Economic Behavior & Organization, 15(1), 71-89. Singh, H. and Kogut, B. (1989). Industry and com-
Montgomery, C.A. and Thomas, A.R. (1988). Divest- petitive effects on the choice of entry mode.
ment: motives and gains. Strategic Management Academy of Management Proceedings, 116-120.
2 Journal, 9, 93-97. © 2009 The Authors Sirmon, D.G., Hitt, M.A. and Ireland, R.D. (2007).
4 Montgomery, C.A. Journaland compilation
Wernerfelt,
© 2009B. (1988).
Blackwell Managing
Publishing Ltd firm resources
and British Academy in dynamic environments
of Management
to create value: looking inside the black box. 31-51.
Academy of Management Review, 32, 273-292. March
Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based 2009
view of the
Swann, G.M.P. (2006). Putting Econometrics in Its firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5, 171-180.
Place: A New Direction in Applied Economics. West, G.P. and DeCastro, J. (2001). The Achilles heel
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. of firm strategy: resources weakness and distinctive
Teece, D.J., Pisano, G. and Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic inadequacies. Journal of Management Studies, 38,
capabilities and strategic management. Strategic 417-442.
Management Journal 18, 509-533 Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies:
Thompson, S. (1999). Takeovers, joint ventures and Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free
the acquisition of resources for diversification. Press.
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 46, 303-318.
Thompson, S. (2007). The role of industry-specific
capabilities during the diffusion of a new
technology: the case of digital cameras. Andy Lockett, Steve Thompson and Uta
Schmalenbach Business Review, 59, 243-260. Morgenstern are from the Business School,
Wang, C.L. and Ahmed, P.K. (2007). Dynamic Nottingham University, Jubilee Campus, Wollaton
capabil- ities: a review and research agenda. Road, Nottingham, NG8 1BB, UK.
International Journal of Management Reviews, 9,

© 2009 The Authors 2


Journal compilation © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd and British Academy of Management 5

You might also like