You are on page 1of 11

European Management Journal Vol. 18, No. 1, pp.

52–62, 2000
Pergamon  2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
PII: S0263-2373(99)00068-7 0263-2373/00 $20.00

Linking Intangible
Resources and
Competition
KNUT HAANES, Norwegian School of Management
ØYSTEIN FJELDSTAD, Norwegian School of Management

Recent strategy literature suggests that intangible Fjeldstad, 1999). In this paper we link
resources — in particular competencies and these observations to a framework con-
relationships — are critical drivers of competitive sisting of three fundamental levels of
advantage. However, there seems to be a lack of resource-competition, each respective
understanding of when certain types of com- level requiring specific types of com-
petencies and relationships are most critical. This petencies and relationships. Then, we
paper introduces a framework consisting of three link our framework to the pharma-
fundamental levels of resource-competition. The ceutical industry. This industry is
framework is illustrated through the pharmaceut- suitable for illustrating the three lev-
ical industry. We argue that (1) biotech firms mainly els of resource-competition due to
engage in entrepreneurial competition; (2) tra- several factors, in particular the
ditional pharmaceutical firms — here referred to as important role of patents as an isolat-
big-pharma — increasingly undertake contractual ing mechanism protecting technical
competition and, finally, (3) generic drug makers innovations from instant diffusion
compete predominantly operationally. The paper (Rumelt, 1987).
argues that intangible resources contribute differ-
ently to competitive advantage depending on level The paper argues that intangible
of competition.  2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All resources contribute differently to
rights reserved competitive advantage
depending on level of compe-
tition. By elaborating the com-
petitive nature of intangible
Introduction resources this approach may
help managers better under-
Lately, there has been an increasing stream of strat- stand their firms’ resources,
egy literature declaring the importance of intangible and thereby align com-
resources in explaining firms’ competitive advantage petitive moves with
(e.g. Itami, 1987; Barney, 1991; Normann and Rami- the firm’s dominant
rez, 1993). A review of this literature concludes that logic (Prahalad
competencies and relationships are increasingly con- and
sidered to be the most critical firm-specific
resources, but also finds a lack of elaboration of
which types of competencies and
relationships are most
important (Haanes
and

52 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

Bettis, 1986). We draw attention to the idea that all The literature generally distinguishes between tan-
competencies and relationships are not equally gible and intangible resources (Itami, 1987). Tangible
important, and that the importance to a large degree resources are concrete and tradeable, and include
depends upon how it supports the way of competing. physical entities such as factories, technology, capital,
For instance, according to this approach, a firm with raw material and land. Intangible resources are gen-
competencies and relationships that support erally more difficult to transfer than tangible
efficiency (e.g. facilitating the flow of goods, ‘just-in- resources, as the value of intangible resources is dif-
time’ delivery of supplies, etc.) should be careful ficult to define and measure. Intangibles include
about competing to create wholly new technologies. skills, knowledge, relationships, culture, reputation
Conversely, a firm with competencies that support and competencies. Although both tangible and intan-
innovative behavior is often well advised not to take gible resources may be scarce and represent the input
its new product ideas to the point where it competes needed to create economic value (Lippman and
head-on with specialized manufacturers. Developing Rumelt, 1982), competencies have received particular
appropriate resources is an expensive and time-con- attention as potential sources of sustained competi-
suming effort (Dierickx and Cool, 1989), and the tive advantage in this literature. Competencies are
extant stock of resources largely decides how the firm the means by which a firm deploys resources in a
can compete in the short- and medium-term characteristic manner in order to compete. Thus,
(Penrose, 1959). Our arguments thus follow the path competencies integrate skills and knowledge, and
dependent assumptions of the resource-based view organizational competencies include the firm’s
(Barney, 1991). knowledge, routines and organizational culture. In
different ways, several authors have identified com-
petence as the crux to superior organizational per-
formance. In particular, Prahalad and Hamel’s notion
Theoretical Background of core competence is important (Prahalad and
Hamel, 1990). Here, competence is seen as competi-
Two perspectives in strategic management are parti- tively important due to three factors. First, a core
cularly relevant for understanding how firms deploy competence potentially provides access to a wide
scarce resources to create superior value. These are variety of markets. Second, it may make a significant
the resource-based (Wernerfelt, 1984; Barney, 1991) contribution to the perceived customer’s benefits of
and the activity-based (Porter, 1985, 1996; Stabell and the end products, and third, it is difficult for competi-
Fjeldstad, 1998) views. These perspectives are comp- tors to imitate or otherwise substitute. In addition,
lementary. The resource-based view focuses on what the value of competencies does not depreciate with
the firm has, whereas the activity perspective focuses use — the way raw materials and other more tangible
on what the firm does. However, as the essence of resources do — but rather increases. Competencies
strategy is to combine the two foci, namely to under- may lead to increasing returns and sustain long-term
stand how to create an appropriate value with scarce economic growth. Other contributions that add to
resources, we will look at how to bridge them. our understanding of competencies in competition
include the notions of absorptive capacity (Cohen
and Levinthal, 1990), architectural knowledge
The Resource-based View (Henderson and Clark, 1990), distinctive com-
petencies (Selznick, 1957) and dynamic capabilities
The underlying approach of the resource-based view (Teece et al., 1997).
is (1) to see the firm as a bundle of tangible and intan-
gible resources, and (2) to see some of these resources
as costly to copy and trade. According to Barney The Activity-based View
(1991), a firm’s resource position can lead to sus- The activity based perspective was for a long time
tained competitive advantage if it allows the firm to mainly concerned with seeing firms as value chains
create value; if the resources are rare and imperfectly (Porter, 1985), i.e. as systems where value is created
imitable, and if the advantage is not subject to substi- by transforming a set of inputs into more refined out-
tution. Moreover, in order to become a source of sus- puts. The strategic challenges associated with manag-
tained competitive advantage, the resources also ing a value chain are related to manufacturing pro-
have to be organized, combined and deployed appro- ducts with the right quality at the lowest possible
priately. Resources may be difficult to imitate due to cost. The ways to reduce costs — or increase value —
isolating mechanisms such as historical conditions, are primarily found through economies of scale,
time compression diseconomies, ambiguity in the efficient capacity utilization, learning effects, product
relation between the resources, or simply because the and information flows, and quality measures. Critical
value created with the resource is socially complex drivers of value creation in chains also include the
(Dierickx and Cool, 1989). This stream of research is interrelationships between primary activities, on the
influenced both by previous work illuminating firm one hand, and product development, marketing and
heterogeneity (e.g. Barnard, 1938; Selznick, 1957; Pen- service, i.e. support activities, on the other hand.
rose, 1959) and by an economics-based reasoning:
firms are seen as rent seekers (Rumelt, 1987). Today, this approach has been extended to also

European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000 53


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

explain other ways of creating value, such as through ❖ Resources are generally agreed to represent an
networks (Normann and Ramirez, 1993) and value appropriate unit of analysis for explaining com-
systems (Porter, 1996). Stabell and Fjeldstad (1998) petitive advantage (Wernerfelt, 1984; Barney,
formalized three types of value creations into a ‘value 1991);
configuration’ framework. In addition to the value ❖ Competencies and relationships are often con-
chain, they introduced the value network and the sidered to be the most critical types of resources
value shop. Value networks create value by (Itami, 1987; Normann and Ramirez, 1993).
mediating products or services between customers. ❖ Activity-based — or more precisely value con-
The value is found in how the specific network gives figuration — analysis is a widely accepted tool for
buyers access to sellers of what they want, and vice determining on which basis the firm may build a
versa. The value shop creates value by solving competitive advantage (Porter, 1985; Stabell and
unique problems for customers. Value is created by Fjeldstad, 1998).
mobilizing resources (Haanes, 1997) — essentially
❖ There is a need for a more developed understand-
relevant competencies — to solve particular prob-
ing of the nature of resources in action (Black and
lems. Problem-solving involves developing solutions
Boal, 1994; Haanes, 1997; Majumdar, 1998).
tailored to problems that the clients will not — or
more often cannot — solve themselves. In order to
determine which type of value creation takes place Hence, one may argue that the current perspectives
in a given firm, we need to look at what the firm gets in strategic management have the shortcoming that
paid for by their customers. intangible resources, such as competencies and
relationships, are not yet linked to how firms create
❖ Value chains sell products that are the outcome of value and to how they compete in their industries.
a transformation process. The customers pay for Consequently, there is not yet a distinction
the total quality of the product. Examples of firms explaining when certain competencies and relation-
that create value as chains include producers of ships are most critical.
automobiles, clothing, electronics, food, com-
puters, furniture and pharmaceuticals.
❖ Value networks sell mediation between cus-
tomers. The customers pay for access to and inter-
Three Levels of Resource-competition
action with other customers. Examples of compa-
nies creating value as networks include The study of how firms compete is the essence of
commercial banks, airlines, postal agencies, the academic field of strategy. This framework helps
insurers, brokers, stock exchanges and overnight better understand how resources can be mobilized to
delivery companies. compete. There are many other useful dimensions of
❖ Value shops sell competencies and approaches to competition in addition to the one presented here,
help solve certain unique problems. The cus- such as price competition, technology competition,
tomers pay for solutions of, or effort spent on, competition for standards, service competition, etc.
their problems. The latter reflects the fact that We will, however, argue that this specific approach
problem-solving is uncertain, and that customers complements and extends other approaches by
in many cases are willing to pay for expected specifically linking types of resources to ways of
rather than realized value (Levitt, 1981). Examples competing.
of companies that create value as ‘shops’ include
accountants, academics, investment bankers, Resource-competition may be classified into three
physicians, designers, lawyers, business consult- different levels. First, operational competition is con-
ants and consulting engineers. cerned with efficiency in the production process
(Porter, 1996). This can be gained through scale and
experience, as well as by substituting capital for
labor. At the other extreme of the competitive spec-
Bridging the Two Perspectives trum lies entrepreneurial competition. This implies the
more Schumpeterian sources of performance advan-
Resources per se do not create value (Penrose, 1959, tage, which result from the formation and implemen-
Porter, 1991). Rather, value creation results from the tation of entirely new combinations (Schumpeter,
activities in which the resources are applied. Strang- 1934). Both the operational and the entrepreneurial
ely, there is not yet an explicit link between these level of competition are well captured by the activity-
two perspectives. Although researchers today have a based perspectives in strategy (e.g. Porter’s distinc-
deeper and more sophisticated understanding of tion between cost leadership and differentiation), and
competencies and activities separately, there is still a by other organizational theories [e.g. the distinction
need for a more developed understanding of how between exploration and exploitation (March, 1991)].
and when certain competencies are most appropriate Moreover, the resource-based perspective (e.g. Wer-
to obtain competitive advantage. One may make nerfelt, 1984; Barney, 1991) helps us distinguish a
some general observations about the current status third type of resource-competition. This implies the
of these two complementary perspectives: effective appropriation and mobilization of certain

54 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

imperfectly traded resources. We here label this con- companies experiment with new combinations. As
tractual competition. This level of competition has pre- noted by Mansfield (1977), products in an emergent
viously been alluded to by Miles and Snow (1978) as industry do not emerge fully developed. Neither do
the activities associated with the ‘analyzer’, a type of the commercial aspects of the industry, as experimen-
firm that screens the environment for interesting tation with different business models takes place.
ideas and then moves relatively early to realize these Hence, it may eventually create great difficulties for
commercially. However, whereas the approach of established firms (Utterback, 1994) which offer close
Miles and Snow was to create a typology of firms, substitutes. Entrepreneurial competition is made dif-
our focus is to identify levels of competition and ficult by the ‘failure trap’. The firm comes up with
types of intangible resources. new ideas, but does not have the necessary patience
to wait for the payback. This may lead to a vicious
The three levels of resource-competition are dis- circle, where the firm continuously creates new con-
tinctly different: cepts but where the ideas spill over to competitors
who manage to appropriate their value.
❖ Entrepreneurial competition implies performance
in the creation of new technologies or entirely
new solutions; Contractual-level Competition
❖ Contractual level competition implies perform-
ance in expanding the available set of non-freely On the contractual level, firms compete on the appro-
traded resources that can be applied to a given priation of scarce resources used by a given tech-
technology; nology in an imperfect resource market. In order to
mobilize imperfectly traded resources, the contrac-
❖ Operational competition implies efficiency in the tual challenges are to identify and understand market
actual transformation of freely traded input fac- potential where it is not yet developed and then to
tors into products and services. fast build a commercial structure. Contractual com-
petition is about building systems to commercialize
At each level of resource-competition, distinct categ- new technologies, many of which have been intro-
ories of associated competencies contribute to duced outside the company. Contractual competition
superior performance. However, the differences consists of two main activities. First, screening the
between the three levels are a matter of degree, and environment for interesting novelties with a commer-
we do not pretend that the boundaries between these cial potential, and second, establishing a set of con-
can be easily defined. Most firms will to some extent tracts to actually commercialize the selected novel-
engage in resource-competition on all three levels. ties. In order to develop contractual-level competitive
Nevertheless, one level will often be dominant in the advantage, support activities such as procurement,
way a business unit competes. human resource management and marketing can be
critical. Performance advantage is not related to
superior implementation and execution of the given
Entrepreneurial-level Competition technology, but rather to its extension to a larger
market domain than the initial innovators. This
At the entrepreneurial level, the creation and modi- means finding a market potential that has not yet
fication of technologies and products departing from been realized. For instance, it is well known that
past solutions is the meta-activity. This implies explo- many of the basic concepts of Apple’s Macintosh
ration (March, 1991). Exploration is associated with computer (such as the mouse and the user interface)
the long-term, and implies experimentation and first originated in Xerox Parc, but that Xerox were
search for new opportunities, technologies, strategies not capable of commercializing these (and many
and competencies. The returns to exploration are dis- other) ideas.
tant in time and space. It takes time to create value
with a new exploration, and even if a new product
is realized the value may be appropriated by other Operational-level Competition
organizations (Teece, 1986). Applying a short time
perspective to exploration makes all new ideas look In operational-level competition, firms are seen to
bad, whether they are good or bad. A firm that only obtain competitive advantage through superior
explores puts itself at a short-term risk, as it neglects execution of activities, based on established techno-
present opportunities. Entrepreneurial level compe- logies. In operational competition, the technology is
tition changes the pattern of resource deployment on generally taken for granted and the firms look for
two levels simultaneously. An emerging industrial performance in terms of (1) scale and scope, and (2)
logic is formed on both a new architecture and new efficient implementation. Drivers of performance in
components (Henderson and Clark, 1990). The archi- operational competition include learning effects,
tecture refers to the way components are put together capacity utilization, vertical integration and links
in the industry, whereas the components refer to each between activities (Porter, 1985). The fundamental
specific portion of the product. Both change dramati- activities in entrepreneurial and contractual compe-
cally in the early stages of the industry, as different tition were exploration and expansion, respectively.

European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000 55


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

In operational competition the fundamental activity industry is well-defined and a factor market estab-
is exploitation (March, 1991). Exploitation refers to the lished, there is room for operational activity. This is
short-term improvement and refinement of present about winning the head-on competition through
knowledge, opportunities and technologies. A firm lower costs and efficiency, and at this stage improve-
that puts too much emphasis on exploitation risks not ments will tend to be slower and more incremental.
surviving in the long-term, because it neglects build-
ing knowledge to seize new opportunities. The ‘suc- For the purpose of this paper it is important to note
cess trap’ is associated with too much exploitation, that the competencies required to compete efficiently
i.e. the firm being satisfied with the returns on varies with the level of resource-competition. This
exploiting present knowledge and technologies. has important implications for strategy.
Present recipes will easily lead the firm to continue
exploiting at the neglect of exploration, which is
necessary in the long-term.
Competition in the Pharmaceutical
Figure 1 is meant to illustrate the three levels, not to
suggest that all firms fit neatly into one. Some firms
Industry
actually succeed in all three. Intel in microprocessors
is an example of this, having gone from the early dis- The pharmaceutical industry provides an interesting
covery to today also being the most efficient pro- illustration of this framework for several reasons.
ducer. First, this is an intensely competitive and global
industry with a strong focus on innovation. The fun-
The three types of resource-competition will tend to damental challenge for most firms in the industry is
have a chronological sequence for a given tech- to create patented drugs that can be commercialized
nology. A new industry emerges through entrepren- internationally. The companies in the industry aver-
eurial action, implying experimentation and the dis- age R&D investments of more than 20 per cent, and
covery of a technological opportunity. Often, many the total research and development investment is
competitors with similar motives, but with different expected to hit $24 billion in 1999 (Hess, 1999).
technologies, emerge at the same time. Utterback and Second, the patent protection and the required medi-
Abernathy (1975) noted that this stage is charac- cal approval (e.g. by the US Food and Drug Adminis-
terized by uncoordinated activity, and that each actor tration [FDA]) create well-defined isolating mech-
tends to be inefficient and have slack. The firms are anisms. These make each product imitation difficult,
often small and purely technology oriented, and but on the other hand facilitate technology diffusion.
incumbents often overlook them. Their competencies Finally, this is an industry with extensive competition
are often more advanced when it comes to the possi- and cooperation between both small and large com-
bilities with the technology than when it comes to panies. This article merely presents an overview of
grasping the commercial opportunity — or more cor- the industry for illustrative purposes. For a richer
rectly; understanding how to develop the commercial and more detailed analysis of strategic groups in the
opportunity. Then, contractual activity develops the pharmaceutical industry, see Bogner and Thomas
commercial industry, which often results in a domi- (1996).
nant design (Abernathy and Utterback, 1978), both in
terms of technology and markets. Here the actors The creation and manufacturing of drugs has become
find efficient systems and solutions. Finally, when the one of the largest and most profitable industries

Figure 1 Three Levels of Competition

56 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

worldwide. The annual sales of medical drugs total tuted technology. It is comprised of many interdisci-
$300 billion, with a profit margin that has been esti- plinary skills and techniques, with wide-ranging
mated at 30 per cent (Economist, 1998). The tra- applications. Biotechnology can also be described as
ditional actors in the industry, namely the integrated an enabling technology capable of affecting many
pharmaceutical firms, have been undergoing large areas of industrial, medical, and agricultural activity.
changes during the last decade as a consequence of The term biotechnology is often used for ‘genetic
(1) increased buyer pressures (particularly from engineering’, which has emerged during the last dec-
Governments and HMO’s), (2) harder price compe- ades. This includes recombinant DNA techniques,
tition from generic drug makers, and (3) innovative established enzyme technology, monoclonal anti-
pressures from biotech companies. The industry can bodies, as well as instrumentation technology for the
as a consequence increasingly be analytically divided automated sequencing of DNA, proteins and the syn-
into three levels of competition, i.e. that undertaken thesis of peptides. The biotech industry has from its
by: (1) traditional pharmaceutical firms, (2) biotech inception been closely linked to the pharmaceutical
firms, and (3) generic drug makers. This division into industry, and there are today more than 2000 ‘biome-
different ways of competing is not clear-cut with dicine’ firms. As of 1999, more than 2200 biotech-
regards to all firms, however, as many corporations based medicines are in various stages of clinical test-
undertake all three forms of competition. For ing, and some 350 drugs are in the process of seeking
instance, the big-pharma firm Roche owns over 80 approval by the FDA. Of these, 30 per cent are in the
per cent of Genentech, a major biotech firm. Simi- late stages of this process. Biotech firms are important
larly, both Novartis and Merck, large traditional technical innovators. They are generally smaller than
pharmaceutical companies, are also producers and traditional pharmaceutical companies, and they are
distributors of generic drugs. In addition, there are often spin-offs from universities and research entities
numerous alliances between biotech firms and big- (Powell et al., 1996). Only three biotech firms —
pharma firms. These collaborations seem to affect Amgen, Chiron and Genentech — had 1998 turn-
innovation positively, and there is often a mutual overs that exceeded $1 billion. Many biotech firms
dependency between these two types of firms (Shan function almost as basic research labs, utilizing their
et al., 1994). small size and targeted competencies to develop new
ideas and to produce technical breakthroughs.
Time pressures have accelerated the division of labor
in the industry for at least two reasons. First, it takes Producing innovation requires certain competencies,
a long time to develop a new drug and second, once such as an advanced understanding of the basic tech-
developed, the company needs to break-even fast in nology underlying the respective biotech firm’s area
order to be profitable before the patents run out. On of activity. Successful biotechnology firms live on the
average it takes 15 years to develop a new drug, and innovation edge, and need to master the state-of-the-
it costs more than $400 million. Although firms that art in their chosen activity. Furthermore, they need
produce a successful drug are protected through the ability to learn from formal and informal collab-
their patents (normally for 20 years), there is a high oration. Typically, many such partnerships are found
pressure to save time in commercialization. Only 30 with universities. As seen by the manager of a
per cent of all drugs introduced ever break-even biotechnology company we studied: ‘We were really
(Gimartin, 1998). High R&D investments, as well as very fortunate because we could start cooperating
marketing costs, have to be recouped before a given with researchers on the cellular applications for the
drug becomes profitable. Hence, most biotech firms future. In this way we evolved with our customers.’
simply do not have the time or resources to grow
organically, even if they have developed a drug with Biotechnology firms typically have the willingness to
a high market potential. It often turns out that tra- experiment with new designs. Their raison d’etre is
ditional pharmaceutical firms — which often them- prototyping entirely new concepts. In essence, the
selves face declining returns to scale in terms of inno- competence that distinguishes a successful biotechn-
vation (Graves and Langowitz, 1993) — have ology firm is its ability to grasp and diagnose new,
competencies and relationships that make them bet- unique problems and to come up with innovative sol-
ter suited for efficient commercialization. Below, we utions. Advanced problems are often accessed
will look at the three types of competition in the through the research network. Participating at the
pharmaceutical industry. frontier of research provides the biotech firms lever-
age to access, assimilate, and exploit additional ideas
and information. R&D collaboration both gives
access to an information network and represents a
Entrepreneurial Competition — Biotech Firms vehicle for the rapid communication of news about
market possibilities and obstacles (Kreiner and
Biotechnology can be defined as the integration of Schutz, 1993). Hence, successful biotech firms have
natural science and engineering science in order to intangible resources that assist in the identification
develop products and services based on the appli- of, and inquiry into, new problems, including a net-
cation of organisms, cells and molecular parts. work to access relevant technological competencies
Biotechnology is, however, not a narrowly consti- and access to advanced know-how.

European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000 57


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

In fact, biotech firms need to build relationships that traditionally based their research on organic chemis-
support entrepreneurial competition. These relation- try.
ships include (1) access to leading customers, and (2)
access to technical knowledge. These relationships The current focus of big-pharma firms is to identify
are usually of both a formal and an informal nature. promising discoveries and then to take these through
Both types of networks facilitate new idea generation, testing and approval onto the market. The approval
in terms of new market solutions or new technical process requires a large investment, where the big-
solutions. For instance, having links to other knowl- pharma firms possess internal laboratories, links to
edge-intensive firms may help the firm pick up new clinical hospitals and experience in managing the
ideas and stimulate to think in new ways (Porter, FDA approval procedure. These are critical resources
1990). Such relationships might include cooperation in the commercialization process. Once a drug is
with research centers, etc. This requires that the firm accepted, the big-pharma firms use their global sales
is open to learn from customers and suppliers. As and marketing networks to commercialize it. Increas-
argued by Powell et al. (1996, p. 121) in a study of ingly, the big-pharma firms also have a contracting
inter-firm collaboration between biotech firms: approach to leverage their know-how in generic
drugs towards the end of the patent life-cycle. The
‘…once a firm begins collaborating, it develops experience at critical competencies for big-pharma firms include
cooperation and a reputation as a partner. Over time, firms their ability to screen and understand potential com-
develop capabilities for interacting with other firms. Experience mercial breakthroughs (often made in research-inten-
with collaborative networks proves a fertile ground for both sive companies, e.g. biotech firms). This requires
further formal partnerships and an expanding array of informal competitive intelligence and a blend of technological
relationships. A broader range of collaborative efforts provides and commercial knowledge, i.e. an absorptive
greater opportunity to refine organizational routines far coop-
erating and render them more versatile.’ capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Contractual
competition requires an understanding of the poten-
tial market and an ability to organize a web of
The relationships of successful biotech firms gener- internal and external contracts. The relationships that
ally include links to ‘idea rich’ surroundings, such as are important for big-pharma firms include a large
research institutions, other biotech firms and set of contacts into research settings in order to screen
advanced pharmaceutical companies. These allow new opportunities. Moreover, it is an advantage to
the firms to pick up new ideas, to think in new ways, have an established reputation as a serious collabor-
and to put an intense research commitment behind ative partner. Finally, in order to sell and market new
new technological innovations. In addition, they rep- products, the big-pharma firms need good relations
resent ‘reservoirs’ of available competencies that may to physicians, pharmacies and other large customer
be mobilized when new opportunities are seen. groups, as well as a brand name that facilitates the
introduction of new products. In sum, two important
resources of big pharma firms are contactability, an
ability to access and manage contacts in many areas,
Contractual Competition — (‘Big’ Pharma) and contractability, a reputation for trustworthiness.
Traditional Pharmaceutical Firms

The traditional pharmaceutical industry has been Operational Competition — Generic Drug
very profitable and R&D intensive, and this trend is Manufacturers
predicted to continue due to ongoing advances in
technology and an aging population in the largest Generic drug manufacturers produce generic drugs.
markets. The traditional pharmaceutical firms (here A generic drug is called by its basic chemical name
called ‘big-pharma’) encompass some of the world’s instead of a registered brand name, which is usually
largest and most profitable firms altogether. For held by big-pharma. In general, generic drug makers
instance, Merck, Roche, Glaxo and Novartis each had do not undertake R&D themselves. Rather, they start
a 1998 turnover exceeding $7 billion. The high risks producing ‘me too’ products once the patents of orig-
and increasing costs of product development, never- inal products have run out. Generic drugs have the
theless, does affect how the large pharmaceutical same active ingredients as brand-name drugs. If a
companies organize innovation. Although they still physician prescribes a generic drug instead of a
undertake extensive research and development brand-name product, good standard practice and
internally, increasingly the discovery of entirely new most countries’ laws require that it be therapeutically
solutions originate in biotech firms and research lab- equivalent. In addition to not having a brand name,
oratories. Therefore, we see more joint ventures with the generic drugs are often priced much lower.
biotech companies with interesting technologies. In Today, managed care organizations affect the pharm-
fact, many large pharmaceutical companies seem to aceutical business in every significant market seg-
prefer cooperation to acquisition, even if the take- ment. As those organizations have continued to grow
over price is no hindrance (Bower, 1993). This is in size and influence, they have increasingly
partly due to the fact that biotechnological inno- demanded discounts from pharmaceutical compa-
vation is foreign to pharmaceutical firms, which have nies. This has provided the generic drug makers,

58 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

such as Mylan Laboratories, Teva Pharmaceuticals, Discussion and Conclusion


Barr Laboratories, Ivax, etc. with a growing market
opportunity. Also, in many countries the generic
drug makers have been helped by an increasing To summarize, how competencies and relationships
reluctance by governments to pay high prices for may contribute to competitive advantage differs with
original drugs. Moreover, some big-pharma firms the competitive level. With respect to competencies
have also entered into generic drug manufacturing we distinguish the exploration-related competencies
in order to expand their volumes and capitalize on needed for successful entrepreneurial action; the
already incurred plant investments. expansion-related competencies needed for success-
ful contractual action, and finally; the exploitation-
The focus of generic drug manufacturers is on related competencies needed for successful oper-
efficiency (in order to compete on price). The com- ational action. This framework has been illustrated
petencies required to compete operationally are with a look at the pharmaceutical industry. We do,
mainly linked to efficiency in production. This however, believe that also other industries can be bet-
includes the ability to identify a scope for economies ter understood through this approach.
of scale and capacity utilization, as well as for better
linkages between the different activities. They are Developing the market commercially is done through
also connected to an efficient flow of goods. This contractual competition (here by ‘big-pharma’ firms),
implies the ability to gradually improve the logistics often undertaken by larger firms diversifying into the
connected to a very complex flow of people, techno- industry or the new market. These are not usually
logies and materials. Another critical competence is first movers, but rather early movers, who have a dif-
negotiation skills, allowing the firm to continuously ferent focus than the one competing entrepreneuri-
reduce the costs of suppliers by (1) making sure they ally (here biotech firms). Whereas companies compet-
reduce costs, and (2) reducing both transaction and ing entrepreneurially explore product and
linkage costs. Furthermore, the relationships needed technology opportunities, the company competing
for generic drug makers to compete operationally contractually is concerned with developing the actual
include a set up with suppliers and customers that market. The companies that are successful in contrac-
facilitates an efficient flow of information and pro- tual competition are innovators when it comes to
ducts. Also, close contacts to customers and a limited understanding and exploiting the market opport-
number of suppliers may limit transaction costs. The unity. This framework introduces contracting as a
relationships developed by successful generic drug way of competing that has not yet been discussed
makers are largely aimed at cutting cost and improv- sufficiently in the literature. However, aspects of the
ing flows. This may imply reducing the number of contractual competition have been discussed by
suppliers and increasing the business with the Chandler (1990); Miles and Snow (1978). Chandler,
remaining partners. for instance, found that the most successful industrial
firms were the first to build management (p. 131).:
We will argue that the three ways of competing, as ‘The dominant companies are those whose founders
illustrated above, require different competencies and and senior executives understood …the logic of
different relationships. These are summarized in managerial enterprise, that is, the dynamic logic of
Table 1. growth and competition that drives modern indus-

Table 1 The Competencies and Relationships Related to Level of Competition

Level of competition Supporting competencies Supporting relationships

Entrepreneurial competition Know-how in basic technology Networks to access relevant technological


Ability to learn from on-going projects competencies
Ability and willingness to experiment Networks to access advanced problems
Ability to solve new problems and come up with Networks to access informal communication
innovative solutions about opportunities and obstacles
Contractual competition Understanding of markets, actors and resources Contractability — reputation for trustworthiness
Ability to see commercial opportunity where it and commercial capabilities
does not yet exist Contactability — many potential relationships in
Ability to organize commercial contracts a wide area of activities (‘loose ties’)
Ability to mobilize new and not yet
commercialized resources
Operational competition Efficiency in production and transformation ‘Just-in-time’ set-up with suppliers and
Quality management in order to reduce customers
complaints and need for slack Low transaction costs with relevant parties
Flow of goods and information High bargaining power vis-à-vis vendors
Negotiation skills

European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000 59


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

trial capitalism.’ Similarly, Miles and Snow identified firm to gain unique insights into a technology, and
the analyzer as a competitive archetype, alongside to combine technological knowledge in new ways.
the defender (focused on efficiency), the prospector ❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the
(innovation) and the reactor (follower). According to firm to learn continuously from experimentation.
Miles and Snow (p. 68) the analyzer is: ‘…an organi- ❖ Competencies and relationships that facilitate
zation that minimizes risk while maximizing the unique problem-solving.
opportunity for profit, that is, an experienced Ana-
lyzer combines the strengths of both the Prospector The competencies that are key to contractual-level
and the Defender into a single system’. These obser- competition are those that allow the firm to expand
vations, in addition to more recent studies docu- rapidly on the basis of existing technologies. To
menting that the early movers, as opposed to first accomplish this the firm needs superior resources
mover, are the most successful (Tellis and Golder, that support procurement, resource management and
1996) seem to suggest that the contracting is a sig- marketing when facing imperfect factor and output
nificant level of competition. It undertaken by the markets. The competencies that support contractual
company that understands the potential of resources competition encompass (1) the ability to see commer-
that are not yet commercially recognized. It is not the cial opportunities in the market for existing techno-
one that develops the technology, but often the one to logies, and (2) the ability to access the resources to
appropriate (Teece, 1986) much of its potential value. seize the opportunities. Accessing (imperfectly
traded and imitated) resources requires both the
This discussion has implications for our understand- ability to manage a variety of contractual mech-
ing of competition and competencies. There are dif- anisms simultaneously and a broad network reach.
ferent ways of competing and, consequently, differ- For instance, when operating in imperfect output
ent types of competencies that support each way of markets, the firm needs competencies to build
competing. This can be stated through a set of prop- brands, trust and loyalty to all parties, including the
ositions about resource-competition in the pharma- suppliers of competence (i.e. the employees and other
ceutical industry. contractual parties). These relationships must allow
the firm an extensive reach within the relevant
domain. This leads to the following proposition
Proposition 1 about traditional pharmaceutical firms:

There are systematic differences in the properties of


competencies and relationships leading to superior Proposition 3
performance in the pharmaceutical industry. These
depend on whether firms compete to (1) create new Superior performance in the pharmaceutical industry
technologies (potential products), (2) create new busi- for drug firms in terms of developing new business
ness systems based on newly introduced techno- systems requires:
logies, or (3) compete on price/quality with estab-
lished technologies within established business ❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the
systems. These ways of competing are closely asso- firm to understand the potential of a not yet fully
ciated with the biotech firms, traditional pharmaceut- developed product (that may well have been
ical firms and generic drug makers, respectively. developed elsewhere).
❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the
We will deal with these levels in turn below. First, firm to organize a nexus of contracts in order to
entrepreneurial level competencies allow the devel- build the business system and develop the market.
opment of new solutions. This may include intimate ❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the
knowledge of state-of-the-art in basic research, or a firm to access technologies and mobilize the
deep knowledge about the market. Relevant com- resources that allow commercial exploitation of
petencies are correlated with innovative efficiency the technology.
(Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). This includes attracting
creative people, the ability to manage innovation, the
Finally, operational-level advantages stem from the
ability to motivate people, and the will to take risks
efficient implementation of primary activities. The
on unproved solutions. One may create the following
intangible resources that are key at this level facilitate
proposition about biotech firms:
resource acquisition efficiency, with the aim of cost
reduction. This requires competencies in manufactur-
ing, logistics, negotiations, as well as the ability to
Proposition 2 retain quality and improve incrementally. Sustaining
operational level advantages requires competencies
Superior performance as a biotech firm in developing that optimize the use of resources and, thus, give an
new product or process technologies requires: advantageous cost position in the chosen segment
(Porter, 1980). Therefore, firms that compete oper-
❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the ationally need competencies to build relationships to

60 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

support operational level performance. Such relation- Barnard, C. (1938) The Functions of the Executive. Harvard Uni-
ships are linked to efficient resource acquisition. versity Press, Cambridge.
Barney, J. (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive
Examples of such relationships include just-in-time advantage. Journal of Management 99–120.
set-up with suppliers and customers, and the estab- Black, J. and Boal, K.B. (1994) Strategic resources: traits, con-
lishment of bargaining power vis-à-vis vendors. figurations and paths to sustainable competitive advan-
Finally, one may make the following proposition tage. Strategic Management Journal 15, 131–148.
about generic drug makers: Bogner, W.C. and Thomas, H. (1996) Drugs to Market: Creating
Value and Advantage in the Pharmaceutical Industry. Perga-
mon, Oxford.
Bower, D.J. (1993) New product development in the phama-
ceutical industry: pooling network resources. Journal of
Proposition 4 Prod. Innov. Management 10, 367–375.
Chandler, A.D. (1990) Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Indus-
Superior performance within generic drug pro- trial Capitalism. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
duction requires: Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990) Absorptive capacity:
a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adminis-
❖ Competencies that allow the firm to produce trative Science Quarterly 35(1), 128–152.
Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989) Asset stock accumulation and
efficiently. sustainability of competitive advantage. Management
❖ Competencies and relationships that allow the Science 35, 1504–1511.
firm to get an optimal flow of inputs and outputs. Economist (1998) The Pharmaceutical Industry, Special Survey,
Febr. 21, pp. 1–18.
❖ Competencies and relationships that minimize Gimartin, R.V. (1998) Winning in pharmaceutical research.
transaction costs. Research Technology Management Jul.–Aug., 9–12.
Graves, S.B. and Langowitz, N.S. (1993) Innovative pro-
Both contractual and entrepreneurial competition ductivity and returns to scale in the pharmaceutical
industry. Strategic Management Journal 14, 593–605.
means combining resources in new ways Haanes, K. (1997) Managing resource mobilization. Unpub-
(Schumpeter, 1934). The company competing entrep- lished Ph.D. dissertation, Copenhagen Business School.
reneurially combines resources to create new pro- Haanes, K. and Fjeldstad, Ø. (1999) The strategic link between
ducts, whereas the company competing contractually competition and competencies. In Formulating Com-
takes these new product ideas and develops new petence-Based Strategy, eds R. Sanchez and A. Heene (in
press).
markets. Companies competing operationally (here Henderson, R. and Clark, K. (1990) Architectural innovation:
generic drug makers) take both products and mar- the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and
kets for granted and focus purely on efficiency. They the failure of established firms. Administrative Science
innovate in terms of building a system that outcom- Quarterly 35, 9–30.
petes the two others on costs (through economies of Hess, G. (1999) FDA accelerates its approval of new drugs.
Chemical Market Reporter, Feb. 15, p. 21.
scale, capacity utilization, flow of goods manage- Itami, H. (with T. Roehl) (1987) Mobilizing Invisible Assets. Har-
ment, etc.). This requires competencies that support vard University Press, Cambridge.
efficient operations, and these types of competencies Kreiner, K. and Schutz, M. (1993) Informal collaboration in
are different from both those required for contractual R&D. The formation of networks across organizations.
and entrepreneurial competition. Organization Studies 14(2), 189–209.
Levitt, T. (1981) Marketing intangible products and product
intangibles. Harvard Business Review May–Jun., 94–102.
This framework may have interesting implications Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (1982) Uncertain imitability:
for managers. First, it helps us better understand an analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under
which intangible resources are most critical for our competition. Bell Journal of Economics 13, 418–438.
firm. Second, it may help managers clarify what Majumdar, S.K. (1998) On the utilization of resources: per-
spectives from the US telecommunications industry. Stra-
kinds of competitive activities their firm is actually tegic Management Journal 19(9), 809–831.
engaged in. It is clearly important to distinguish cre- Mansfield, E. (1977) The Production and Application of New
ation (of new industries) from operational compe- Industrial Technology. Norton, New York.
tition. Finally, this framework helps us link the three March, J.G. (1991) Exploration and exploitation in organiza-
main levels of strategy, namely competencies, com- tional learning. Organization Science 2, 71–87.
Miles, R.E. and Snow, C.C. (1978) Organizational Strategy,
panies and competition. So far, most theories have Structure, and Process. McGraw-Hill, New York.
been concerned with one of these. Montgomery, D.B. and Lierberman, M.B. (1988) First-mover
advantages. Strategic Management Journal Special Issue 9,
Note. This is an extended version of a paper 41–58.
presented at the 18th Annual International Confer- Normann, R. and Ramirez, R. (1993) From value chain to
value constellation: designing interactive strategy. Harv-
ence of the Strategic Management Society, Orlando, ard Business Review Jul.–Aug., 65–77.
1998, and at a SCANCOR seminar at Stanford Uni- Penrose, E. (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Basil
versity, January 1999. Blackwell, London.
Porter, M.E. (1980) Competitive Strategy. Free Press, New York.
Porter, M.E. (1985) Competitive Advantage. The Free Press,
New York.
References Porter, M.E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations. The
Free Press, New York.
Abernathy, W. and Utterback, J. (1978) Patterns of industrial Porter, M.E. (1996) What is strategy? Harvard Business Review
innovation. Technology Review 80(7), 40–47. Nov.–Dec., 61–78.

European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000 61


LINKING INTANGIBLE RESOURCES AND COMPETITION

Prahalad, C.K. and Bettis, W. (1986) The dominant logic: a competitive advantage: on chains, shops and networks.
new linkage between diversity and performance. Stra- Strategic Management Journal 19(5), 413–437.
tegic Management Journal 7, 285–301. Teece, D. (1986) Profiting from technological innovation:
Prahalad, C.K. and Hamel, G. (1990) The core competence of implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and
the corporation. Harvard Business Review May–Jun., 79– public policy. Research Policy 15, 27–44.
91. Teece, D., Pisano, G. and Shuen, A. (1997) Dynamic capabili-
Rumelt, R. (1987) Theory, strategy, and entrepreneurship. In ties and strategic management. Strategic Management
The Competitive Challenge, ed. D. Teece, pp. 137–158. Journal 18(7), 509–533.
Harper and Row, New York. Tellis, G.J. and Golder, P.N. (1996) First to market, first to fail?
Schumpeter, J. (1934) The Theory of Economic Development. Har- Real causes of enduring market leadership. Sloan Man-
vard University Press, Cambridge. agement Review Winter, 65–75.
Selznick, P. (1957) Leadership in Administration. Row, Peter- Utterback, J.M. (1994) Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation.
son & Co., Evanston. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge.
Shan, W., Walker, G. and Kogut, B. (1994) Interfirm Utterback, J.M. and Abernathy, W.J. (1975) A dynamic model
cooperation and startup innovation in the biotechnology of process and product innovation. Omega 3(6), 639–656.
industry. Strategic Management Journal 15, 387–394. Wernerfelt, B. (1984) A resource-based view of the firm. Stra-
Stabell, C.B. and Fjeldstad, Ø.D. (1998) Configuring value for tegic Management Journal 5, 171–180.

KNUT HAANES, ØYSTEIN FJELDSTAD,


Norwegian School of Man- Norwegian School of Man-
agement — BI, P.O. Box agement — BI, P.O. Box
580, 1301 Sandvika, Nor- 580, 1301 Sandvika, Nor-
way. way.

Knut Haanes is an Associate Øystein Fjeldstad is an


Professor of Strategy at the Associate Professor of Strat-
Norwegian School of Man- egy at the Norwegian School
agement — BI in Oslo, Nor- of Management — BI, and
way. He gained his Ph.D. in Chair of the Department of
Strategy from Copenhagen Strategy. He gained his
Business School, and has previously been a research Ph.D. from the University of Arizona and his work has
associate at IMD in Switzerland and a visiting scholar been published in international journals and books.
at Stanford University. He has published several art- Together with Charles Stabell he has introduced an
icles and cases in journals and books, and presented integrated value configuration framework, which first
his work internationally. His research interests include appeared in the Strategic Management Journal in 1998.
resource-based strategies and collaborative alliances. His research interests include different forms of value
creation, both on a firm and industry level.

62 European Management Journal Vol 18 No 1 February 2000

You might also like