You are on page 1of 14

Prospering in Dynamically-Competitive Environments: Organizational Capability as Knowledge

Integration
Author(s): Robert M. Grant
Source: Organization Science, Vol. 7, No. 4, (Jul. - Aug., 1996), pp. 375-387
Published by: INFORMS
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2635098
Accessed: 27/06/2008 08:11

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=informs.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the
scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that
promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org
Prospering in Dynamically-compe
Environments:OrganizationalCapability
as Knowledge Integration

Robert M. Grant
School of Business, GeorgetownUniversity,Washington,DC 20057

Abstract determinants of competitive advantage in dynamically-


Unstable market conditions caused by innovation and in- competitive market environments by analyzing the role
creasingintensityand diversityof competitionhave resulted of knowledge in organizational capability. Building
in organizational capabilitiesrather than servedmarketsbe- upon four major theoretical streams: competition as a
coming the primarybasis upon which firms establish their dynamic process, the resource-based view of the firm,
long-termstrategies.If the strategicallymost importantre- organizational capabilities and conipetences, and orga-
source of the firm is knowledge,and if knowledgeresides in nizational knowledge and learning, this paper estab-
specializedform among individualorganizationalmembers, lishes the rudiments of a knowledge-based theory of
then the essence of organizationalcapabilityis the integra-
tion of individuals'specializedknowledge. the firm. At the heart of this theory is the idea that the
This paper develops a knowledge-basedtheory of organi- primary role of the firm, and the essence of organiza-
zationalcapability,and drawsupon researchinto competitive tional capability, is the integration of knowledge. The
dynamics,the resource-basedview of the firm,organizational paper explores how knowledge is integrated to form
capabilities,and organizationallearning.Centralto the the- organizational capability, and goes on to identify char-
oiy is analysisof the mechanismsthroughwhichknowledgeis acteristics of capabilities which are associated with
integrated within firms in order to create capability.The creating and sustaining competitive advantage in dy-
theory is used to explore firms' potential for establishing namically-competitive markets, including the achieve-
competitiveadvantagein dynamicmarketsettings,including ment of flexible integration across multiple knowledge
the role of firm networksunder conditionsof unstablelink- bases. Finally, I consider the relative merits of internal
ages between knowledge inputs and product outputs. The versus external knowledge integration and the benefits
analysispoints to the difficultiesin creating the "dynamic"
and "flexible-responsecapabilities"which have been deemed of firm networks in coping with hypercompetitive mar-
criticalto success in hypercompetitivemarkets. ket conditions.
(Knowledge; OrganizationalCapability; CompetitiveAd-
vantage)
Background
The displacement of static theories of competition
Introduction associated with neoclassical microeconomics and the
The growing intensity and dynamism of competition "structure-conduct-performance" school of industrial
across product markets has had profound implications economics by the more dynamic approaches associated
for the evolution of strategic management thought with the Austrian school of economics, especially with
during the 1980s and 1990s. Increasing turbulence of Schumpeter's concept of competition as a process of
the external business environment has focused atten- "creative destruction" (Schumpeter 1934), has had pro-
tion upon resources and organizational capabilities as found implications for strategic management thought
the principal source of sustainable competitive advan- (Jacobsen 1992). During the early part of the 1980s,
tage and the foundation for strategy formulation. As strategy analysis was focused upon the quest for
the markets for resources have become subject to the monopoly rent through industry and segment selection
same dynamically-competitive conditions that have af- and the manipulation of market structure to create
flicted product markets, so knowledge has emerged as market power (Porter 1980). However, if market struc-
the most strategically-significant resource of the firm. ture is in a state of flux, and if monopoly rents quickly
This paper seeks to extend our understanding of the succumb to new sources of competition, approaches to

1047-7039/96/0704/0375/$01.25
Copyright ? 1996. Institute for Operations Research
and the Management Sciences ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VO1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 375
ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

strategy based upon choices of product markets and market and segment selection and competitivepositions
positioning within them are unlikely to yield profit based upon some form of "generic strategy";
advantages that are more than temporary. The impact Second, such resource and capability-basedadvantages
of the resource-based view of the firm on strategic are likely to derivefrom superioraccess to and integration
management thinking can be attributed to two factors. of specialized knowledge.
First, given the lack of evidence that monopoly power
The literature on organizational knowledge and
is an important source of profit (Rumelt 1991),
learning has explored the role of organizations in the
Ricardian rents (returns to resources over and above
acquisition, processing, storage, and application of
their opportunity costs) appear to be the primary source
knowledge (Argyris and Schon 1978, Levitt and March
of interfirm profitability differences. Second, if exter-
1988, Organization Science 1991, Starbuck 1992). The
nal markets are in a state of flux, then the internal
primary emphasis of this literature is on the acquisition
resources and capabilities of a firm would appear to be
of information by organizations. Nonaka (1994) pro-
a more stable basis for strategy formulation than the
poses a theory of knowledge creation built around
external customer focus that has traditionally associ-
dynamic interaction between two dimensions of knowl-
ated with the marketing-orientation to strategy (Levitt
edge transfer: transformations from tacit to explicit
1960).
knowledge and vice-versa; and transfers between indi-
This emphasis on the "supply-side" rather than the
vidual, group, organizational, and interorganizational
"demand side" of strategy has been closely associated
levels. However, as Spender (1992) recognizes, firms
with recent work on organizational capabilities.
are engaged not only in knowledge creation but also in
Prahalad and Hamel (1990) argue that sustainable
knowledge application. The distinction between these
competitive advantage is dependent upon building and
two processes is crystallized in Demsetz's (1991) obser-
exploiting "core competences"-those capabilities
vation that efficiency in the acquisition of knowledge
which are fundamental to a firm's competitive advan-
requires that individuals specialize in specific areas of
tage and which can be deployed across multiple prod-
knowledge, while the application of knowledge to pro-
uct markets. Porter's recent work emphasizes the need
duce goods and services requires the bringing together
for firms and countries to broaden and upgrade their
of many areas of specialized knowledge.
internal advantages in order to sustain and extend
Much of the research into the management issues
competitive advantages (Porter 1991, 1992).
concerning the integration of different types of special-
While extreme forms of dynamic competition (termed
ized knowledge has been within the context of new
"hypercompetition" by D'Aveni 1994) are characteristic
product development (Nonaka 1990, Clark and
of product markets, dynamically competitive conditions
Fujimoto 1991, Wheelwright and Clark 1992). While
also are present in the markets for resources. Indeed,
some innovations are the result of the application of
competitive conditions in product markets are driven,
new knowledge, others result from reconfiguring exist-
in part, by the conditions of competition in the markets
ing knowledge to create "architectural innovations"
for resources (Barney 1986). Thus, the speed with
(Henderson and Clark 1990, Henderson and Cockburn
which positions of competitive advantage in product
1995). This ability of the firm to "generate new combi-
markets are undermined depends upon the ability of
nations of existing knowledge" and "to exploit its
challengers to acquire the resources needed to initiate
knowledge of the unexplored potential of the technol-
a competitive offensive. Sustainability of competitive
ogy" is what Kogut and Zander (1992, p. 391) describe
advantage therefore requires resources which are id-
as "combinative capabilities".
iosyncratic (and therefore scarce), and not easily trans-
The theory of organizational capability which follows
ferable or replicable (Grant 1991). These criteria point
represents an extension and synthesis of these contri-
to knowledge (tacit knowledge in particular) as the
butions, based upon the idea that the essence of orga-
most strategically-important resource which firms pos-
nizational capability is the integration of individuals'
sess (Quinn 1992). Thus, this paper's focus upon knowl-
specialized knowledge.
edge and its integration is justified by two assumptions
about the success in dynamically-competitive market
environments: The Model: Organizational Capability
First, under dynamic competition, superiorprofitability as Knowledge Integration
is likely to be associated with resourceand capability-based My model of organizational capability rests upon basic
advantagesthan withpositioning advantagesresultingfrom assumptions regarding the characteristics of knowledge

376 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/Vol. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

and its deployment. From these assumptions I develop edge, transfer is both difficult and necessitates transac-
propositions concerning the nature of organizational tion-specific investment. This view of the firm as an
capability, the linkage of capability to organizational institution for knowledge integration establishes a view
structure, and the determinants of competitive advan- of the firm based upon close integration between orga-
tage. nizational members implying stability, propinquity and
social relationships, but it does not readily yield preci-
Assumptions sion definition of the firm and its boundaries. For this
The focus of this paper is upon a single resource: reason, Demsetz (1991) refers to "firm-like organiza-
knowledge. This emphasis is justified by the assump- tions".
tions that, first, knowledge accounts for the greater Integration of specialist knowledge to perform a
part of value added,1 second, barriers to the transfer discrete productive task is the essence of organizational
and replication of knowledge endow it with strategic capability, defined as a firm's ability to perform repeat-
importance. I define knowledge broadly to include edly a productive task which relates either directly or
both "explicit" knowledge which can be written down, indirectly to a firm's capacity for creating value through
and "tacit" knowledge which cannot. The emphasis is effecting the transformation of inputs into outputs.
on tacit knowledge since, in the form of "know-how", Most organizational capabilities require integrating the
skills, and "practical knowledge" of organizational specialist knowledge bases of a number of individuals.
members, tacit knowledge is closely associated with A hospital's capability in cardiovascular surgery is de-
production tasks, and raises the more interesting and pendent upon integrating the specialist knowledge of
complex issues regarding its transfer both within and surgeons, anaesthetist, radiologist, operating-room
between organizations. nurses, and several types of technicians. L.L. Bean's
The key managerial issues arising from the charac- order processing capability, Rubbermaid's new product
teristics of knowledge stem from the observation that development capability and McDonald's Restaurants'
tacit knowledge is acquired by and stored within indi- capability in preparing and serving hamburgers are all
viduals. Due to the cognitive limits of the human brain, examples of organizational capabilities requiring the
knowledge is acquired in a highly specialized form: an integration of specialized knowledge across quite large
increase in depth of knowledge implies reduction in numbers of employees.
breadth. Advances in knowledge tend to be associated
with increased specialization. However, production
the creation of value through transforming input into The Architectureof Capabilities
output-requires a wide array of knowledge, usually The integration of knowledge into organizational capa-
through, combining the specialized knowledge of a bilities may be viewed as a hierarchy. This hierarchy is
number of individuals. not one of authority and control, as in the traditional
concept of an administrative hierarchy, but is a hierar-
Integrating Knowledgeto Form chy of integration. At the base of the hierarchy is the
Organizational Capability specialized knowledge held by individual organiza-
These assumptions provide the basis for a knowledge- tional members. At the first level of integration are
based view of the firm. If knowledge is a critical input capabilities which deal with specialized tasks. Moving
into all production processes, if efficiency requires that up the hierarchy of capabilities, the span of specialized
it is created and stored by individuals in specialized knowledge being integrated broadens: task-specific ca-
form, and if production requires the application of pabilities are integrated into broader functional capa-
many types of specialized knowledge, then the primary bilities-marketing, manufacturing, R & D, and finan-
role of the firm is the integration of knowledge. But cial. At higher levels of integration are capabilities
why are institutions called "firms"needed for the inte- which require wide-ranging cross-functional integration
gration of knowledge? It is because the alternatives are -new product development involves especially wide-
too inefficient. An individual's ability to integrate ranging integration (Clark and Fujimoto 1991). Figure
knowledge is constrained by cognitive limits: it is not 1 illustrates this concept of hierarchy of capabilities by
feasible for each individual to try to learn the knowl- providing a vertical segment of the hierarchically-
edge possessed by other specialists. Integration across arranged organizational capabilities of a manufacturer
markets is difficult: in the case of explicit knowledge it of private-branch telephone exchanges (PBXs).
is difficult to appropriate the value of the knowledge The wider the span of knowledge being integrated,
through market contracts; in the case of tacit knowl- the more complex are the problems of creating and

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/Vo1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 377


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

Figure 1 Organizational Capabilities of a PBX Producer: A Partial Vertical Segment

CROSS- New product Customer Quality


FUNCTIONAL development support management
CAPABILITIES capability capability capability

BROAD Operations R & D and MIS Marketing Human


FUNCTIONAL capability design capability and sales resource mgt.
CAPABILITIES capabillty capability capability

ACTIVITY- Manufacturing Materials Process Product Test


RELATED capability management engineering engineering engineering
CAPABILITIES capability capability capability |pblt
(Operations-L
related only)

SPECIALIZED Printed Telset System


CAPABILITIES circuit-board assembly assembly
(Manufacturing assembly
related only)

. __~~~~~~~A
SINGLE-TASK Automated Manual Surface Wave
CAPABILITIES through-hole Insertion of mounting of soldering
(Only those component components components
related to Insertion
PCB assembly)

I N DIVIDUALS S I D KNOWLEDGE

managing organizational capability. The "quick re- the number of individuals who can be directly involved
sponse capability" which Richardson (1996) identifies in the process is small.2 Cross-functional product de-
among apparel suppliers Benetton, The Gap, and velopment teams are not so difficult to set up, the
Giordano is an important competitive advantage pri- challenge (as confirmed by Imai et al. 1985 and Clark
marily because it is difficult to achieve it involves and Fujimoto 1991) is for the team to access the
integrating across multiple vertical stages. The difficul- breadth and depth of functional knowledge pertinent
ties experienced by the Bell operating companies in to the product, and integrate that knowledge.
transferring the new capabilities developed in their In most companies, hierarchies of capabilities do not
overseas businesses back to their domestic operations correspond closely with their authority-based hierar-
can be attributed to the fact that many of these new chies as depicted by organization charts. In particular,
capabilities (e.g. wireless communication, fiber-optics, some top management capabilities such as capital bud-
marketing within competitive markets, and managing geting, strategic planning, and government lobbying
joint ventures) require integration across broad-spans may involve a limited scope of knowledge integration,
of knowledge and expertise (Smith 1996). and hence are closer to the base than to the apex of
Although higher-level capabilities involve the inte- the capability structure. At the same time, if knowledge
gration of lower-level capabilities, such integration can is to be integrated effectively by the firm, the architec-
only be achieved through integrating individual knowl- ture of capabilities must have some correspondence
edge. This is precisely why higher level capabilities are with the firm's structure of authority, communication,
so difficult to perform. New product development re- and decision making, whether formal or informal. For
quires the integration of an extremely broad basis of example, Clark and Fujimoto find that, within automo-
knowledge, but communication constraints imply that biles, superior capabilities in new product development

378 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VO1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

require product managers with substantial influence (ii) OrganizationalRoutines. Direction involves cod-
and decision making authority what they term ifying tacit knowledge into explicit rules and instruc-
"heavyweight product managers".The need for organi- tions. But since a characteristic of tacit knowledge is
zational capabilities to be supported by firm structure that "we can know more than we can tell" (Polanyi
poses difficulties for the creation of new capabilities. 1966), converting tacit knowledge into explicit knowl-
In the case of the Bell telephone companies, new edge in the form of rules, directives, formulae, expert
capabilities were created outside the formal structure systems, and the like inevitably involves substantial
through "garbage can" processes (Smith 1996). knowledge loss.
An organizational routine provides a mechanism for
coordination which is not dependent upon the need for
Mechanisms for Integrating Knowledge communication of knowledge in explicit form. March
How is knowledge integrated by firms to create organi- and Simon (1958, p. 142) "regard a set of activities as
zational capability? Explicit knowledge involves few routinized to the extent that choice has been simplified
problems of integration because of its inherent com- by the development of a fixed response to a defined
municability. Advances in information technology have stimuli." Such patterns of stimulus and response may
greatly facilitated the integration of explicit knowledge lead to highly complex and variable patterns of seem-
through increasing the ease with which explicit knowl- ingly-automatic behavior. Within our knowledge-based
edge can be codified, communicated, assimilated, view, the essence of an organizational routine is that
stored, and retrieved (Rockart and Short 1989). How- individuals develop sequential patterns of interaction
ever, the most interesting and complex issues concern which permit the integration of their specialized
the integration of tacit knowledge. The literature points knowledge without the need for communicating that
to two primary integration mechanisms: knowledge.
(i) Direction. Demsetz (1991, p. 172) identifies di- Observation of any work team, whether it is a surgi-
rection as the principal means by which knowledge can cal team in a hospital operating room or a team of
be communicated at low cost between "specialists and mechanics at a grand prix motor race, reveals closely-
the large number of other persons who either are coordinated working arrangements where each team
nonspecialists or who are specialists in other fields." member applies his or her specialist knowledge, but
To optimize the operation of a McDonald's restaurant, where the patterns of interaction appear automatic.
it is more efficient for McDonald's to create an operat- This coordination relies heavily upon informal proce-
ing manual which covers almost every aspect of the dures in the form of commonly-understood roles and
restaurant's management than to educate every interactions established through training and constant
McDonald's manager in cooking, nutrition, hygiene, repetition, supported by a series of explicit and implicit
engineering, marketing, production management, signals (see Pentland and Rueter 1994, for a careful
human resource management, psychology, accounting analysis). The advantage of routine over direction is in
and finance, and the other specialist areas of knowl- economizing on communication and a greater capacity
edge embodied in standard operating rules. to vary responses to a broad range of circumstances.
The more complex an activity, the greater the num-
ber of locations in which that activity must be repli-
cated, and the more stringent the performance specifi-
cations for the outcome of that activity, the greater is
Competitive Advantage in
the reliance on knowledge integration through direc- Dynamically-competitive
tion. British Airways operates aircraft maintenance fa- Environments
cilities in 67 locations distributed across the globe. Creating and Sustaining Advantage
Service and repair at these facilities is guided by a host Under conditions of dynamic competition, the poten-
of highly formalized procedures and directives based tial of organizational capabilities to earn rents for the
upon the standards established by the major regulatory firm through establishing sustainable competitive ad-
authorities (the Federal Aviation Authority, the British vantage depends upon their capacity for both creating
Civil Aeronautics Board, and others), guidance and and sustaining advantage. Competitive advantage is
technical information provided by aircraft manufactur- determined by a combination of supply-side and de-
ers, and the company's own policies and procedures. mand-side factors. On the demand side, a firm's pro-
These directives, policies, and procedures embody the ductive activities must correspond to a market need.
technical knowledge of a large number of specialists. On the supply side, the firm must have the capabilities

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/Vol. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 379


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

not only to serve that market need, but to serve it more proaches to knowledge integration. The key contribu-
effectively or efficiently than other firms. For simplic- tion of our analysis is in recognizing the common
ity's sake, let us abstract from demand-side considera- requirements of these different approaches.
tions and focus exclusively upon the supply side: the
ability to create unique advantages and to protect these
advantages against imitation. The Efficiency of Integration
The first observation is that the critical source of Competitive advantage depends upon how productive
competitive advantage is knowledge integration rather firms are in utilizing the knowledge stored within indi-
than knowledge itself. Specialized knowledge cannot, vidual organizational members, which is dependent
on its own, provide a basis for sustainable advantage, upon the ability of the firm to access and harness the
first, because specialized knowledge resides in individ- specialized knowledge of its members. Three factors
uals, and individuals are transferable between firms; are important in determining the efficiency with which
second, because the rents generated by specialized a firm integrates the specialized knowledge available
knowledge are more likely to be appropriated by indi- within it:
viduals than by the firm. Of course, some knowledge (a) The Level of Common Knowledge. Both direction
(patents, copyrights, trade secrets) is proprietary to the and routine require communication between individu-
firm, and is appropriable. However, empirical evidence als. Demsetz (1991) identifies the prerequisite for
suggests that the value of proprietary knowledge de- communication between different specialists as the
preciates quickly through obsolescence and imitation presence of common knowledge between them. If spe-
(Levin et al. 1987). Hence, even in technology-intensive cialized knowledge must be reduced to common knowl-
industries, the key to sustainable advantage is not edge in order to communicate it, there is inevitably
proprietary knowledge itself, but the technological ca- substantial information loss. The size of this loss de-
pabilities which permit the generation of new knowl- pends upon the level and sophistication of common
edge. knowledge. A basic prerequisite is a common language.
If knowledge integration is the basis for competitive Direction is almost entirely ability upon detailed articu-
advantage under dynamic market conditions, what are lation of instructions. Routines typically rely upon a
the characteristics of knowledge integration associated much more limited set of cues and responses which
with the creation and sustenance of such an advan- serve not so much as to communicate knowledge, but
tage? I identify three characteristics of knowledge inte- to permit a sequencing of individual's application of
gration pertinent to the competitive advantage and the knowledge inputs. For both integration mechanisms,
rents associated with such advantage: efficiency of communication depends upon commonal-
(i) The efficiencyof integration the extent to which ity of vocabulary, conceptual knowledge, and experi-
the capability accesses and utilizes the specialist knowl- ence between individual specialists. Shared behavioral
edge held by individual organizational members; norms form a central part of the common knowledge
(ii) by the scope of integration the breadth of spe- which facilitates communication and understanding
cialized knowledge the organizational capability draws (Garfinkel 1967, Zucker 1987). Generally speaking, the
upon; wider the scope of knowledge being integrated (and,
(iii) the flexibilityof integration-the extent to which hence, the greater the diversity of the individuals in-
a capability can access additional knowledge and re- volved), the lower is the level of common knowledge,
configure existing knowledge. and the more inefficient the communication and inte-
My goal is to explore the performance requirements gration of knowledge. Thus, the effectiveness of social
of systems of knowledge integration conducive to at- networks among biotechnologists as mechanisms for
taining competitive advantage. Given the uniqueness of communicating and integrating knowledge reflected
each firm's stock of specialized knowledge and the their high level of common knowledge arising from
idiosyncracy of each firm's institutional heritage, it is their comparatively narrow spread of knowledge and
impossible to specify the organizational arrangements commonality of behavioral norms (Liebeskind et al.
conducive to the formation of organizational capability 1996). Organizational culture may be regarded as a
through knowledge integration. Critical to the analysis form of common knowledge, one of the functions of
of this paper is an equifinality view (Van de Ven and which is to facilitate knowledge integration within the
Drazin 1985) that, recognizing uniqueness of knowl- company.
edge bases and institutional conditions, firms can (b) Frequency and Variabilityof Task Performance.
achieve equally effective, yet highly differentiated ap- The efficiency with which organizational routines

380 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VOl. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

integrate the specialized knowledge of team members concern for its interactions with the others (Simon 1973,
depends upon the sophistication of the system of sig- p. 270),
nalling and responsiveness which develops between
team members as a result of repetition and improve- and Williamson's "principle of hierarchical decomposi-
ment. The efficiency of an organizational routine de- tion" (Williamson 1981, p. 1550), may be viewed as
rives from the fact that: organizational conditions for optimizing the efficiency
of knowledge integration.
While each organization member must know his job, there is Modularity is especially important in organizing
no need for anyone to know anyone else's job. Neither is there highly complex capabilities which involve broad-scope
a need for anyone to be able to articulate or conceptualize the
knowledge integration. Clark and Fujimoto (1991) show
procedures employed by the organization as a whole (Nelson
and Winter 1982, p. 105).
how the hugely complex task of developing a new
model of automobile is facilitated by means of organiz-
ing the task:
The critical requirement is the "ability to receive and
interpret a stream of incoming messages from other . into sequential phases (concept development, vehicle
members and from the environment" (ibid, p. 100). design and layout, component design, prototype build-
Integrative efficiency depends upon the effectiveness ing, process engineering);
of this communication in eliciting appropriate re- * by function (marketing, product engineering, test en-
sponses from each organization member. This is a gineering, process engineering);
function of the frequency with which the particular * by product segment (body, chassis, engine, transmis-
pattern of coordinated activity is performed. The sion, electrics and electronics).
greater the variation in the routine which is required in The problem of many conventional approaches to
response to variation in environmental circumstances, modularity is that they rest heavily upon time-sequenc-
the lower is integrating efficiency likely to be. The ing. Under conditions of hypercompetition such se-
ineffectiveness of the response by the National Guard quencing is simply too time consuming. The organiza-
to the Los Angeles riots of 1992 and the Russian Army tional challenge is creating modularity which permits
to the Chechnya rebellion of 1994/95 reflects, in part, either overlapping phases or full simultaneity.
the infrequence with which these organizations were
required to suppress insurrection.
(c) Structure.Efficiency of knowledge integration re- The Scope of Integration
quires economizing upon the amount of communica- Increases in the span of knowledge which are inte-
tion needed to effect integration. Organization struc- grated within an organizational capability increases the
tures need to be designed with a view to organizing potential for both establishing and sustaining competi-
activities such as to reduce the extent and intensity of tive advantages through two sources:
communication needed to achieve knowledge integra- (i) Different types of specialized knowledge are
tion. Bureaucracy is a structure which (under certain complements rather than substitutes in production. Up
circumstances) maximizes the efficiency of knowledge to the point of diminishing relevance, the marginal
integration in an organization where direction is the revenue product of a unit of specialist knowledge in-
predominant integrating mechanism. A key feature of creases with the addition of different types of knowl-
organizational innovations such as Henry Ford's mov- edge.
ing assembly line, the kanban system for just-in-time (ii) The greater the scope of knowledge being inte-
scheduling, multidivisional structure (or "M-form") is grated within a capability, the greater the difficulty
their promotion of efficiency through achieving higher faced by competitors in replicating that capability due
levels of coordination with lower levels of communica- to increases in "causal ambiguity"(Lippmanand Rumelt
tion. 1982) and time-based diseconomies of replication
The principle of modularity is fundamental to the (Dierickx and Cool 1989). The complexities associated
structuring of organizations to achieve communication with broad-scope integration are further increased
efficiencies. Simon's observation that: when different types of knowledge require different
patterns of integration. Toyota's lean production sys-
.. . division of labor means factoring the total system of deci- tem combines cost efficiency, quality, flexibility, and
sions that need to be made into relatively independent subsys- innovation. These different performance dimensions
tems, each one of which can be designed with only minimal involve different types of integration. While cost effi-

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VOl. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 381


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

ciency may be best served through organization around (Henderson 1995, p. 3)-in driving such innovation.
"sequential interdependence", flexibility is likely to re- Her studies of pharmaceuticals and the semiconductor
quire more complex patterns of "reciprocal interde- photolithographic alignment equipment industry pro-
pendence" (Thompson 1967, p. 40). Similar complexi- vide strong support for the role of broad-scope knowl-
ties of integration are likely among suppliers of fashion edge integration in supporting superior performance.
apparel which combine low costs with fashion-based Such architectural innovations are concerned not
differentiation and quick response capability only with product and process innovations, but also
(Richardson 1996). with strategicinnovations which reconfigure knowledge
into new approaches to competing. Such "new-game
strategies" (Buaron 1981) are not specific to technol-
The Flexibility of Integration ogy-based industries. Baden-Fuller and Stopford (1994,
While integration across a wide scope of specialist Chapter 3) show that strategic innovation is fundamen-
knowledge is important in sustaining competitive ad- tal to creating competitive advantage in mature busi-
vantage, hypercompetitive conditions ultimately result ness environments. In fashion clothing for example,
in all positions of competitive advantage being eroded Benetton and The Limited have created "quick-
by imitative or innovative competition. Hence, main- response capability" through innovative approaches to
taining superior performance ultimately requires the value-chain reconfiguration (Richardson 1996).
continual renewal of competitive advantages through Most examples of firms' reconfiguring knowledge
innovation and the development of new capabilities. into architectural innovations (EMI's CT scanner, the
Within the context of our model, there are two dimen- Polaroid instant camera, the Apple Macintosh,
sions to such renewal: extending existing capabilities to Pilkington's float glass process, Lanier's "virtual
encompass additional types of knowledge, and recon- reality') and strategic innovations (Nucor in steel,
figuring existing knowledge into new types of capabil- Benetton in apparel, Starbuck's in coffee houses) point
ity. to these innovations as isolated successes rather than
The ease with which existing capabilities can be evidence of flexible capabilities which have the capac-
extended to encompass new knowledge depends heav- ity to continuously and repeatedly reconfigure knowl-
ily upon the characteristics of knowledge with regard to edge in new patterns of interaction. Given the difficul-
communicability. If new knowledge is explicit, or if ties inherent in integrating tacit knowledge and depen-
tacit knowledge can be articulated in explicit form, dence of such integration upon routines and communi-
then integrating new knowledge does not pose major cation patterns developed over time, establishing orga-
difficulties. In designing its 777 passenger plane, Boe- nizational arrangements needed to achieve the "flexi-
ing was able to greatly extend its knowledge of elec- ble integration" proposed by Henderson (1995) and
tronics and new materials through an advanced CAD "meta-flexibility" proposed by Volberda (1996) repre-
system which provided a common language for special- sents a formidable challenge to management. Continu-
ists across widely different knowledge areas and differ- ous innovation in dynamically-competitive environ-
ent companies to communicate and integrate. By con- ments (e.g., Rubbermaid in plastic housewares, 3M in
trast, General Motors' upgrading of its manufacturing adhesive and thin-film products, Sony in consumer
capability to encompass the knowledge embodied in electronics, Motorola in communication products)
Toyota's system of lean production was a slow and tends to be the result of the deployment and extension
painful process because much of that knowledge was of a continuing core of capabilities rather than the
tacit and the routines for its integration were deeply constant creation of new capabilities. Achieving flexi-
embedded with Toyota's history and culture. ble integration, either through continually integrating
The reconfiguration of existing knowledge through new tacit knowledge or through constantly reconfigur-
new patterns of integration is more complex, but may ing existing knowledge, is likely to impose substantial
be even more important in creating competitive advan- costs in terms of reducing the efficiency of knowledge
tage. Such knowledge reconfiguration is central to integration. The implication is that radical, discontinu-
Abernathy and Clark's (1985) concept of "architectural ous change in industry environments (such as the micro
innovation". Subsequent research by Henderson and revolution in computing and the possible displacement
Clark (1990) and Henderson and Cockburn (1995) of internal combustion engines by electric motors in
identifies the critical role of "architecturalknowledge" autos) is likely to be accompanied by the decline of
-the "integration of knowledge across disciplinary established market leaders. The noteworthy feature of
and organizational boundaries within the firm" IBM's performance during the 1980s and 1990s is not

382 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VOl. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

so much its decline during the 1990s, but its remark- its sources or uncertainty over its applicability to the
able success in microcomputers during the 1980s. firm's products may not justify the internalization of its
producers within the firm. Networks, either of firms or
of individuals, may be well-suited to the transfer and
Internal Versus External Integration: integration of such knowledge. Thus, in biotechnology,
The Case for Networks social networks of scientists provide a powerful vehicle
The need for flexibility in organizational capabilities for the transfer of scientific knowledge since such
poses complex issues with regard to firm boundaries networks provide the reputational assets and the re-
and choices between internal and external knowledge peated-game characteristics necessary to avoid the
integration. In common with other types of transac- inefficiencies associated with market exchanges
tions, there are three basic alternatives for knowledge (Liebeskind et al. 1996).
transfer and integration: internalization within the firm, Interfirm collaboration through relational contracts
market contracts, and relational contacts (which in is also likely to provide efficient mechanisms for knowl-
multiple form create firm networks). Given uncertain- edge integration where there is a lack of perfect corre-
ties over appropriability and valuation, market con- spondence between the knowledge base of the firm
tracts are typically inefficient means for transferring and its set of products. The scope of a firm may be
knowledge. In Demsetz's (1991) analysis, market trans- defined in terms of its range of knowledge or its range
actions are only efficient in transferring knowledge of products. Where the boundaries of both knowledge
when that knowledge is embodied within a product. and products correspond perfectly, not only are firm
Such transfer of product-embodied knowledge across boundaries unambiguous, but knowledge resources are
markets is efficient when the effective utilization of the fully utilized. Where a perfect correspondence does
product by buyers is not dependent upon the buyers not exist, or where uncertainty exists over the linkages
needing access to the knowledge embodied within the between knowledge and products, then two conse-
product. Thus, within the context of fashion apparel quences follow:
(Richardson 1996), Benetton does not need to inte- (a) ambiguity is created over the optimal boundaries
grate knowledge of the application of computer science of the firm;
to computer-aided design into its design capability, if it (b) internal provision of the full range of specialized
can purchase CAD software adequate to its needs. On knowledge needed for a particular set of products must
the other hand, expertise in fashion design is tacit, and result in the inefficient exploitation of at least some of
it cannot be embodied into expert-system software. that specialist knowledge.
Thus, Benetton cannot purchase fashion design knowl- In such circumstances, interfirm collaboration can
edge packaged into software, neither can Benetton rely increase the efficiency with which specialized knowl-
upon purchasing individual fashion designs from inde- edge is utilized. A consequence of hypercompetition is
pendent designers because of the need for garment uncertainty over links between knowledge inputs and
design to integrate multiple knowledge bases: fashion product outputs. In biotechnology, new knowledge may
design flair, Benetton's own market knowledge, and have applications in "human health, crop production
manufacturing expertise. The implication is that Benet- and protection, chemical feedstock production and
ton is likely to require internalization of at least some processing, food processing, and waste management"
of fashion design capability. Similarly, in the case of (Liebeskind et al. 1996). As a result, "these sources of
the regional Bell companies' expansion into wireless technological and competitive uncertainty make it ex-
communication. If knowledge concerning wireless tremely difficult to determine which scientific knowl-
switching and siting of cellular bases is not capable of edge is potentially valuable and which is not" (ibid).
embodiment within marketable products and services, While my analysis points to the superiority of intrafirm
then these companies will, ultimately, be required to relationships in integrating knowledge, the importance
extend their capabilities to embody such knowledge of networks in sourcing biotechnological knowledge
(Smith 1996). suggests that the inefficiencies of interorganizational
Relational contracts, either in individual strategic relationships are outweighed by the flexibility advan-
alliances or broader interfirm networks, are an inter- tages associated with a wider set of knowledge-product
mediate solution justified by a number of intermediate linkages.
situations. For example, explicit knowledge which is A final consideration concerns the speed with which
not embodied in specific products cannot be efficiently new capabilities can be built and extended. Even if
transferred through market contracts, but diffusion of relational contracts are imperfect vehicles for integrat-

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VOl. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 383


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiuveEnvironments

ing knowledge, a critical concern is that they can limited. Further progress is critically dependent upon
permit knowledge to be transferred and integrated closer observation of the processes through which tacit
with a comparatively short time. If competitive advan- knowledge is transferred and integrated.
tage in dynamic market settings is critical dependent Despite its limited achievements so far, this analysis
upon establishing first-mover advantage then the criti- offers considerable potential-especially in building
cal merit of firm networks is in providing speed of bridges between strategic management and organiza-
access to new knowledge. Such considerations proved tion theory and design. Conventional notions of organi-
to be critically important both in biotechnology zational structure rest heavily upon concepts such as
(Liebeskind et al. 1996, and in telecommunications division of labor, unity of command, and grouping of
(Smith 1996). In fashion apparel where the need to similar tasks. The view of the firm as an integrator of
access new knowledge was less apparent, firm networks .knowledge provides a rather different perspective on
did not provide any clear advantage over vertical inte- the functions of organization structure. The analysis
gration (Richardson 1996). can also offer insight into many current developments
Similar considerations explain the establishment of in management practice. Cross-functional product de-
the Nordvest Forum regional learning network velopment teams, TQM, and organizational change
(Hanssen-Bauer and Snow 1996). Although such in- programs such as GE's "workout" can be viewed as
terorganizational contacts have limited potential for attempts to change organizational structure and pro-
integrating knowledge across companies, such a net- cesses to achieve better integration across broad spec-
work permits fuller utilization of knowledge by permit- tra of specialized knowledge. The trend towards "em-
ting firms to share knowledge that has application powerment" takes account of the nature of knowledge
outside of each firm's product set. Second, it encour- acquisition and storage in firms:-if each employee
ages investments in knowledge acquisition in the face possesses unique specialized knowledge and if each
of uncertainty over knowledge-product linkages. employee has access to only part of every other em-
ployee's knowledge base-then top-down decision
making must be a highly inefficient means of knowl-
Summary and Conclusion edge integration. The task is to devise decision pro-
I have established that knowledge is the preeminent cesses that permit integration of the specialized knowl-
resource of the firm, and that organizational capability edge held throughout the organization-not just in the
involves the integration of multiple knowledge bases. boardroom, but on the shop floor as well.
The resulting theory of organizational capability pro- The paper offers little solace to managers grappling
vides a more cogent description of firm competence with the uncertainties and demands of hypercompeti-
and analyzes more precisely than hitherto the relation- tive environments. While establishing that, under con-
ship of organizational capability to competitive advan- ditions of intense and dynamic competition, internal
tage in markets where market leadership and power is capabilities provide a more stable basis for strategy
continually undermined by competition and external than market positioning, my analysis points to the
change. I show that the processes through which firms difficulties inherent in achieving the dynamic capabili-
integrate specialized knowledge are fundamental to ties which for many are the "solution" to the problem
their ability to create and sustain competitive advan- of sustaining competitive advantage under conditions
tage. Figure 2 summarizes this theory of organizational of hypercompetition. Volberda (1996) identifies these
capability and its implications for competitive advan- dynamic capabilities with "the repertoire of flexibility-
tage in hypercompetitive environments. increasing capabilities that management possesses."
While making some progress in integrating prior But, if such capabilities depend upon integration across
research on organizational learning and organizational a broad span of largely-tacit knowledge, then a firm's
resources and capabilities, much remains to be done at strategic flexibility is limited by two factors: first, its
both the empirical and the theoretical level, especially repertoire of capabilities is unlikely to extend far be-
in relation to understanding the organizational pro- yond those currently deployed within existing business
cesses through which knowledge is integrated. For ex- activities; second, the time horizon and uncertainty
ample, while organizational routines are generally rec- associated with creating new capabilities. The "flexible
ognized as important mechanisms for coordination integration" and network relationships I propose as
within firms, with a few notable exceptions (e.g. responses to this problem identify what is required, but
Pentland 1992, Pentland and Rueter 1994), detailed offer little guidance as to the management actions
study of the operation of organizational routines is needed to achieve flexibility in knowledge integration.

384 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/Vol. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

Figure 2 Summary: The Knowledge-based Theory of Organizational Capability

ASSUMPTIONS
* Knowledge is the principal productive resource of the firm.
*.Of the two main types of knowledge, explicit and tacit, the latter is especially important due to its limited transferability.
*Tacit knowledge is acquired by and stored within individuals in highly specialized form.
* Production requires a wide array of knowledge.

I
PROPOSITIONS

1. The nature of the firm. The fundamental role of the firm is the integration of individuals' specialist knowledge. Organizational
capabilities are the manifestation of this knowledge integration.

2. Capabilityand structure. The capabilities of the firmare hierarchicallystructured according to the scope of knowledge which they
integrate. Effectiveness in creating and managing broad-scope capabilities requires correspondence between the scope of
knowledge and the structures needed for managing such integration.

3. Integration mechanisms. Two primary mechanisms exist to integrate knowledge: direction and routine. Reliance upon direction
increases with complexity of the activity, the number of locations in which the activity is performed, and the stringency of
performance specifications. The advantage of routine in integrating tacit knowledge is in economizing upon communication and
permitting flexible responses to changing circumstances.

4. Capabilityand competitive advantage.


(A) The competitive advantage conferred by an organizational capability depends, in part, upon the efficiency of knowledge
integrationwhich is a function of: (a) the level of common knowledge among organizational members; (b) frequency and variability
of the activity; (c) a structure which economizes on communication (e.g., through some form of modularity).

(B) An organizational capability's potential for establishing and sustaining competitive advantage increases with the span of
knowledge integrated.

(C) Sustaining competitive advantage under conditions of dynamic competition requires continuous innovation which requires flexible
integration through either (a) extending existing capabilities to encompass new knowledge, or (b) reconfiguring existing
knowledge within new patterns of integration. Since efficient integration of tacit knowledge requires experience through repitition,
achieving flexible integration represents a formidable management challenge.

IMPLICATION:
FIRMNETWORKSUNDER HYPERCOMPETITION

Firm networks based upon relational contracts are an efficient and effective basis for accessing knowledge:
- where knowledge can be expressed in explicit form;
- where there is a lack of perfect correspondence between the knowledge domain and product domain of individualfirms, or
uncertainty over the product-knowledge linkages;
- where speed in extending the knowledge base of the firm is critical in creating competitive advantage.

Acknowledgements resources owned by the firm, a major part of which comprise or


I am grateful to Jon Hanssen-Bauer, Duane Helleloid, Arie Lewin, embody the knowledge of people. International differences in living
Julia Liebeskind, Steve Postrel, James Richardson, Ann Smith, and standards and productivity are mainly due to differences in human
Henk Volberda for helpful comments and suggestions. capital. Denison's research into international differences in growth
rates found that, in the case of Britain, advances in knowledge
Endnotes accounted for 46 percent increases in real national income per
1The part of national income attributable to knowledge may be person employed between 1950 and 1960 (Denison 1968).
calculated as wages and salaries over and above that which would be 2A key distinction between an administrative hierarchy and the hier-
earned by unskilled manual labor, plus royalties and license fees. To archy of capabilities is that, in the administrative hierarchy, the span
this a major part of profit can be added, since profit is a return to the of control can remain constant throughout the hierarchy. In the

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VO1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 385


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

hierarchy of capabilities, the fact that each layer of capabilities Levitt, T. (1960), "Marketing Myopia," Harvard Business Review,
cannot directly integrate the preceding layer of capabilities and must July-August, 24-47.
return to the base in terms of integrating individual's knowledge, Liebeskind, J. P., A. Oliver, L. Zucker, and M. Brewer (1996),
means that the span of integration increases as one ascends the "Social Networks, Learning, and Flexibility: Sourcing Scientific
hierarchy. Knowledge in New Biotechnology Firms," OrganizationScience,
7, 4, 428-443.
References Lippman, S. and R. Rumelt (1982), "Uncertain Imitability; An Anal-
Abernathy, W. J. and K. B. Clark (1985), "Innovation: Mapping the ysis of Interfirm Differences in Efficiency Under Uncertainty,"
Winds of Creative Destruction", Research Policy, 14, 3-22. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 418-438.
Argyris, C. and D. A. Schon (1978), OrganizationalLearning, Read- March, J. and H. Simon (1958), Organizations,New York: Wiley.
ing, MA: Addison-Wesley. Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Eco-
Baden-Fuller, C. and J. M. Stopford (1994), Rejuvenatingthe Mature nomic Change, Cambridge: Belknap.
Enterprise,Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Nonaka, I. (1990), "Redundant, Overlapping Organization: A
Barney, J. (1986), "Strategic Factor Markets: Expectations, Luck and Japanese Approach to Managing the Innovation Process," Cali-
Business Strategy," Management Science, 32, 1231-1241. fornia ManagementReview, 32, Spring, 27-38.
Buaron, R. (1981), "New-game Strategies", McKinsey Quarterly,Fall, (1994), "A Dynamic Theory of Organizational Knowledge
24-40. Creation," OrganizationScience, 5, 1, 14-37.
Clark, K. B. and T. Fujimoto (1991), Product Development Perfor- OrganizationScience (1991), Special Issue, "Organizational Learning:
mance, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Papers in Honor of (and by) James G. March," 2, 1, 1-163.
Demsetz, H. (1991), "The Theory of the Firm Revisited," in 0. E. Pentland, B. T. (1992), "Organizing Moves in Software Support,"
Williamson and S. Winter (Eds.), The Nature of the Firm, New AdministrativeScience Quarterly,37, 527-548.
York: Oxford University Press, 159-178. and H. H. Rueter (1994), "Organizational Routines as Gram-
Denison, E. F. (1968), "Economic Growth," in R. E. Caves (Ed.), mars of Action," AdministrativeScience Quarterly,39, 484-510.
Britain'sEconomic Prospects, Washington: Brookings Institution. Polanyi, M. (1966), The Tacit Dimension, New York: Anchor Day.
Dierickx, I. and K. Cool (1989), "Asset Stock Accumulation and Porter, M. E. (1991), The CompetitiveAdvantage of Nations, New
Sustainability of Competitive Advantage," Management Science, York: Free Press.
35, 1504-1513. (1992), "Towards a 'Dynamic Theory of Strategy," Strategic
Garfinkel, H. (1967), Studies in Ethnomethodology, Englewood Cliffs, ManagementJournal, 12, Winter Special Issue, 95-118.
NJ: Prentice-Hall. Prahalad, C. K. and G. Hamel (1990), "The Core Competences of
Grant, R. M. (1991), "The Resource-based Theory of Competitive the Corporation," HarvardBusiness Review, May-June, 79-91.
Advantage: Implications for Strategy Formulation", California Quinn, J. B. (1992), IntelligentEnterprise,New York: Free Press.
Management Review, 33, 3, 114-135. Richardson, J. (1996), "Vertical Integration and Rapid Response in
Hanssen-Bauer, J. and C. C. Snow (1996), "Responding to Hyper- Fashion Apparel," OrganizationScience, 7, 4, 400-412.
competition: The Structure and Processes of a Regional Learn- Rockart, J. F. and J. E. Short (1989), "IT in the 1990s: Managing
ing Network Organization," OrganizationScience, 7, 4, 413-427. Organizational Interdependence," Sloan ManagementReview, 30,
Henderson, R. and K. Clark (1990), "Architectural Innovation: The 2, 17-33.
Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Fail- Rumelt, R. P. (1991), "How Much Does Industry Matter?", Strategic
ure of Established Firms", AdministrativeScience Quarterly,35, ManagementJournal, 12, 167-185.
9-31. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development,
Henderson, R. and I. Cockburn (1995), "Measuring Competence? Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Exploring Firm Effects in Pharmaceutical Research," Strategic Simon, H. A. (1973), "Applying Information Technology to Organi-
ManagementJoutnal, 15, winter, 63-84. zation Design," Public AdministrationReview, 106, 467-482.
Imai, K., I. Nonaka, and H. Takeuchi (1985), "Managing the New (1991), "Bounded Rationality and Organizational Learning,"
Product Development Process: How Japanese Companies Learn OrganizationScience, 2, 125-134.
and Unlearn," in K. Clark, R. Hayes, and C. Lorenz (Eds.), The Smith, A. and C. Zeithaml (1996), "Baby Bells, Garbage Cans, and
UneasyAlliance, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Hypercompetition," OrganizationScience7, 4, 388-399.
Jacobsen, R. (1992), "The 'Austrian' School of Strategy,"Academy of Spender, J-C. (1992), "Limits to Learning from the West: How
ManagementReview, 17, 782-805. Western Management Advice May Prove Limited in Eastern
Kogut, B. and U. Zander (1992), "Knowledge of the Firm, Combina- Europe," International Executive, 34, 5, September/October,
tive Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology," Organiza- 389-410.
tion Studies, 3, 383-397. Starbuck, W. H. (1992), "Learning by Knowledge-intensive Firms,"
Levin, R. C., A. K. Klevorick, R. R. Nelson, and S. G. Winter (1987), Journal of Management Studies, 29, 713-739.
"Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and De- Thompson, J. D. (1967), Organizations in Action, New York:
velopment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783-820. McGraw-Hill.
Levitt, B. and J. G. March (1988), "Organizational Learning," An- Van de Ven, A. H. and R. Drazin (1985), "The Concept of Fit in
nual Review of Sociology, 14, 319-340. Contingency Theory," in L. L. Cummins and B. Staw (Eds.),

386 ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VO1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996


ROBERT M. GRANT Dynamically-competitiveEnvironments

Research in Organizational Behavior, 7, Greenwich, CT: JAI (1981), "The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, At-
Press, 333-365. tributes," Journal of Economic Literature, 19, 1537-1568.
Volberda, H. W. (1996), "Towards the Flexible Form: How to Winter, S. G. (1987), "Knowledge and Competence as Strategic
Remain Vital in Hypercompetitive Environments," Organization Assets," in D. Teece (Ed.), The Competitive Challenge, Cam-
Science, 7, 4, 359-374. bridge, MA: Ballinger.
Wheelwright, S. C. and K. B. Clark (1992), RevolutionizingProduct
Zucker, L. (1987), "Institutional Theories of Organizations," Annual
Development, New York: Free Press.
Review of Sociology, 13, 443-464.
Williamson, 0. E. (1975), Marketsand Hierarchies,Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Accepted by Arie Y. Lewin; receivedJune 1994. Thispaper has been with the authorfor two revisions.

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE/VO1. 7, No. 4, July-August 1996 387

You might also like