You are on page 1of 18

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/230548022

Structuring Cooperative Relationship Between Organizations

Article  in  Strategic Management Journal · October 1992


DOI: 10.1002/smj.4250130702

CITATIONS READS

2,755 11,300

2 authors:

Peter S. Ring Andrew H Van De Ven


Loyola Marymount University University of Minnesota Twin Cities
57 PUBLICATIONS   12,350 CITATIONS    140 PUBLICATIONS   41,868 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Minnesota Innovation Research Project View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Peter S. Ring on 05 June 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Structuring Cooperative Relationships between Organizations
Author(s): Peter Smith Ring and Andrew H. Van De Ven
Source: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 13, No. 7 (Oct., 1992), pp. 483-498
Published by: John Wiley & Sons
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2486599
Accessed: 23/09/2008 12:20

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=jwiley.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the
scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that
promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

John Wiley & Sons is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Strategic
Management Journal.

http://www.jstor.org
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 13, 483-498 (1992)

STRUCTURINGCOOPERATIVERELATIONSHIPS
BETWEENORGANIZATIONS
PETER SMITH RING
College of Business Administration, Loyola Marymount University, Los Angeles,
California, U.S.A.
ANDREW H. VAN DE VEN
Curtis L. Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis,
Minnesota, U.S.A.

Alliances and similar cooperative efforts are receiving increased attention in the strategic
management literature. These relationships differ in significant ways from those governed
by markets or hierarchies, and pose very different issues for researchers and managers. In
this paper we address alternativeforms of governance in cases where multiple organizations
repeatedly cooperate. We explore their characteristics and follow this with a discussion of
criteria which we believe bear on the choice of governance: risk and reliance on trust. We
offer propositions on relationships between these criteria and the choice of governance
mechanisms. In the concluding section of the paper we explore the implications of our
analysis for managers and scholars.

Rapid changes in technology, the competitive based governance forms employed in pursuing
environment, firm strategies and other pressures these diverse business objectives include strategic
are prompting many firms to seek continuing alliances (e.g. James, 1985), partnerships (e.g.
cooperative relationships with other firms. These Perlmutter and Heenan, 1986), coalitions (e.g.
joint efforts are seen as expeditious ways to keep Porter and Fuller, 1986), franchises (e.g. Fried-
pace, especially when the firm is seeking unique lander and Gurney, 1981), research consortia
and pioneering resources. But why are firms (Ouchi and Kremen-Bolton, 1988), and various
engaging in such repeated, contract-based trans- forms of network organizations (e.g. Eccles and
actions of idiosyncratic assets with the same Crane, 1987; Jarillo, 1988; Lincoln, 1990; Powell,
organization when received theory (see, gener- 1990).2
ally, Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975, 1985) Comparative analysis of the mechanisms avail-
predicts that they should be using hierarchical
arrangements? Powell (1987) suggests that these single organization, and gaining synergy by combining the
firms are pursuing a diverse set of business strengths and overcoming the weaknesses of firms in
objectives that require cooperation because they undertaking a venture that is much broader and deeper than
a simple supplier relationship, marketing joint venture, or
involve reciprocal dependencies.' The contract- technology licensing arrangement. Similar arrangements
appear to be employed by organizations that contract out in
'restructuring' or in 'downsizing' their operations (e.g.
Key words: Governance structures, relational con- Cameron, K., Freeman, and Misha, 1991; Richardson, 1988;
tracts, recurrent contracts, reliance on trust, contract Sutton and D'Aunno, 1989) or by governmental agencies
risk engaged in the privatization of public services (e.g. Bryson
and Ring, 1990).
I These business objectives include gaining access to new 2 Our argument in this paper is solely with the adequacy of
technologiesor markets,benefitingfrom economies of scale the TCE literature in treating these interorganizational
in joint research, production, and/or marketing, gaining relationships. Gray (1990) and Oliver (1990), however,
complementaryskills by tapping into sources of know-how provide excellent reviews of the adequacy of the interorgani-
located outside the boundariesof the firm, sharingthe risks zational relations (IR) literature in dealing with these
for activities that are beyond the scope or capabilityof a emerging forms.

0 143-2095/92/080483-16$08. 00 Received 2 July 1990


(C) 1992 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Final revision received 24 February 1992
484 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

able to govern these kinds of business relation- it solves many of the problems associated
ships has been undertaken by scholars working with opportunistic behavior by the parties.
within a branch of institutional economics that Stinchcombe (1990), however, provides a compel-
is now known as transaction cost economics ling counter-argument: that when deemed neces-
(TCE) (see, generally, Williamson, 1975, 1985). sary, contracts can be constructed to simulate
Briefly, TCE analysis of governance structure hierarchies.
alternatives explores the following fundamental Stinchcombe's argument points out that this
question: when does a manager pursuing the substitution occurs through a 'network of con-
kinds of business objectives described above use tracts (1990: 236).' However, as Doz and Pra-
the market, rely on her own organization, or use halad (1991: 148) note: '[t]he usefulness of
a mixed-mode relationship? transaction cost analysis for research on manage-
TCE researchers operate on an assumption ment processes is limited by. . .its primary focus
that in answering this question, managers will be on single transactions as units of analysis.' The
motivated solely by efficiency considerations; that cooperative arrangements that are emerging
is, they will select the least costly of these in many industries, however, involve repeated
alternatives, taking account of the combined transactions between the same partners. In
effects of transaction and production costs (e.g. addition, although managers invariably confront
Williamson, 1985: 61). Other motivations, such the make or buy decision in dynamic contexts,
as equitable outcomes, are understated in these facing real time constraints, TCE analysis is
analyses. TCE analysis also assumes that econ- static.3
omic actors are opportunistic. The implications Thus, although TCE provides a sound theoreti-
of trusting behavior in designing governance cal foundation for the exploration of market
mechanisms are generally ignored. versus hierarchical mechanisms for solving stra-
Williamson (1991: 269) has pointed out that tegic dependencies, it suffers from not adequately
'transaction cost economics has been criticized exploring other available governance structures,
because it deals with polar forms-markets and repeated transactions, the dynamic evolution of
hierarchies-to the neglect of intermediate or governance and transactions, and the key roles
hybrid forms.' More pointedly, Stinchcombe of trust and equity in any interorganizational
(1990: 198) notes that: relationship. We seek to partially fill these
shortcomings in this paper.4 We focus our
[a] common danger with the ideal-type method attention on recurrent and relational contracting,
[employedin TCE literature]is that one of the and the inherent flexibility they provide parties
types, usually the most interesting, is defined
residually,by contrastwith an empty ideal-type
into which few empiricalobservationsfall. This 3 A broader discussion of mergers is beyond the scope of
means not only that intermediate cases are this paper (e.g. Berg, Duncan and Friedman, 1983; Harrigan,
misanalyzed, but that even the poles of contract 1985. 1986; Killing, 1983; Walsh and Ellwood, 1991). Time
and hierarchy are poorly defined (emphasis constraints may explain why, contrary to the logic of TCE,
added). firms acquire (or merge with) other firms to obtain assets
that are not idiosyncratic and will not be transacted for
repeatedly under conditions of uncertainty. As pointed out
Although cognizant of alternative modes of by a reviewer of earlier drafts of this manuscript, acquiring
governance, the tendency to emphasize markets the whole when only a part is sought is inherently inefficient.
The static approach of TCE masks the conflict inherent in
and hierarchies in the formulation of the govern- many mergers: they provide a relatively faster, more certain,
ance question leaves a significant void in our and sometimes less expensive way of achieving the kinds of
understanding of alternatives. This is especially business objectives Powell (1987) identifies, but at the risk
of diverted management attention, increased organizational
the case in our understanding of alternative forms complexity and (more often than not) greater investment.
for the governance of repeated transactions of We argue that recognition of this conflict ultimately will lead
highly idiosyncratic assets under conditions of managers to consider relational contracting as an alternative
means of meeting these kinds of needs.
uncertainty, and small numbers bargaining, such 4 Although beyond the scope of this paper, we would argue

as biotechnology research, transnational joint that the agency theory, for many of the same reasons, has
ventures, or extractive resources exploration. left a similar void in our understanding of the governance of
transactions within the hierarchy. We will touch briefly on
TCE theorists argue that these kinds of trans- the implications of our argument as they relate to internal
actions are best governed by hierarchy because governance in the concluding section of the paper.
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 485

who can rely on trust in governing risk in buyer's debt of payment are unambiguous. Since
transactions. Indeed, relational contracting is the property, products, or services exchanged
manifest in the extremely wide variety of new here tend towards the non-specific, and can be
forms governing repeated transactions among transacted among many traders, the competitive
organizations (e.g. Dore, 1983). marketplace and classical contract law provide
We begin with an analysis of the characteristics efficient safeguards to the parties for governing
of alternative governance mechanisms. We then these transactions (Macneil, 1978; Williamson,
outline criteria which we believe bear on the choice 1985). When individuals contract on behalf of
of governance. This is followed by a discussion of their organizations, they require some security
relationships between these criteria and the choice that the terms of their transactions will be
of governance mechanisms. In the concluding enforceable. The laws of contract enable trans-
section of the paper we explore the implications acting parties to appeal to the state's powers of
of our analysis for managers and scholars. coercion. Should conflict arise among the parties,
ultimate security is provided by the state which
enforces the terms of such a contract, if it is
ALTERNATIVE FORMS FOR judged to be lawful.
GOVERNING TRANSACTIONS In such imperfectly competitive market circum-
stances, parties to a bargaining transaction are
The characteristics of two polar forms for assumed to be equal and legally free. Thus, social
governing transactions-market-based discrete relations between parties tend to be limited as
contracts and hierarchies-have been the focus developing them can be costly. If they do exist,
of intense scholarly interest by institutional social relations between the parties have come
economists (Commons, 1934, 1950; Coase, 1937; to be viewed by many scholars as atomized and
Williamson, 1975, 1981), organizational sociol- irrelevant (e.g. Williamson, 1985: 69). Indeed,
ogists (Barney, 1990; Granovetter, 1985; Oliver, as Adam Smith observed in 1776, social atomi-
1990; White, 1981), lawyers (Goldberg, 1980; zation is a prerequisite to perfect competition.
Klein, 1982; Macneil, 1974, 1978, 1980) and In contrast, hierarchical or managerial trans-
strategic management and organizational theorists actions usually deal with the production of wealth
(Barney and Ouchi, 1986; Donaldson, 1990; Hill or the rationing of resources among superiors
and Kim, 1988; Hill, 1990; Jones and Hill, 1988). and subordinates. Commons (1950) pointed out
A very brief review of these characteristics is that a lawful managerial transaction requires
instructive because they provide the basis for legal ownership of property, obtained through
exploring alternative frameworks for governing bargaining transactions. While the law of bargin-
transactions. In Table 1, some of the more ing transactions in markets sets up an ethical
distinguishing characteristics of a broader set of ideal of persuasion between individuals who are
alternative governance mechanisms are outlined. legally equal and free, the law of managerial
In this paper we explore the advantages of tranisactions rests on the legal right of the owner
recurrent and relational contracts, which, we will to issue commands to laborers and on the
argue, can provide transacting parties with an correlative duty of obedience by the laborers to
ability to avoid many of the liabilities caused by the commands of owners (Commons, 1950: 54).
the use of discrete contracting and/or hierarchies Williamson (1975, 1985) proposes that where
as governance mechanisms. transactions have highly uncertain outcomes,
Market-based transactions can be simply recur frequently, and require unique or trans-
characterized as discrete contracts: relatively action-specific investments, they can be perfor-
short-term, bargaining relationships between med most efficiently within hierarchies. When
highly autonomous buyers and sellers designed conflict arises, it is resolved by resort to the
to facilitate an economically efficient transfer of authority or fiat that is embedded in the
property rights. The conditions associated with asymmetrical command and obedience roles
these transactions are 'sharp in;' that is, they are relationships that are characteristic of hierarchy.
accompanied by a clear-cut, complete, and In these unified governance structures, the
monetized agreement. They are also 'sharp out,' employment contract is the relevant legal form
i.e., the seller's debt of performance and the of governance.
486 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

and the
Status Terms Nature Table
structure
Relevant of 1.
resolution Temporal of of
investment
Mechanisms the
transaction characteristics
Distinguishing
governance for
contract duration exchange exchange
Transaction-specific
parties
law of
dispute Distinguishing

by
and
equal Clear,
marketsystem pay
Classical External relation
Limited, One-timeDiscrete
property
and monetized,
agreement,
societal and
Nonspecific transactions characteristics
performance
Simultaneous
free rights of
market between complete market
legal
contract sharp
sharp transfer
governance nonunique in
parties out and of forms
norms legally exchange by
of

role and
quits
unified unequal
Internal
authority
resolution
between Indefinite
Structural the superior
AuthorityOn-going transactions
relationship
subordinate
Idiosyncratic transactions
Hierarchical
Employment
by hires rationing
parties
legally
conflict relationship of
fiat obeys
governance structure
command-obedience
functional or production
contract
and employment
wealth managerial

Forms
legal free and
Short Mixed
market Norms relation to
and Certain,
property
Episodic
of
reciprocity Unlimited, contingent
safeguards Recurrent
Neoclassical
systems performance; transfer transactions
equal on
and rights
of
equity between experimentation
governance uniquemoderate complete
onplans
prior production
contract and
parties for contracting
societal
of legally term

by
and
based
the equal, Mixed
bilateral relation bilateral property
on Moderate Sustained
Relational and Extensive, and resolution
safeguards
Uncertain,
incomplete;
Relational
Endogenous to transfer transactions
parties
trust and rights
free of
social-embedded
between open
learning
and uniquelong plans
contracts
governance
designed forand production
contracting
parties
legally conflict
term idiosyncratic
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 487
Quite different from the generally well under- contracting requires that we make a set of
stood forms of market and hierarchical govern- assumptions about the transacting parties. First,
ance, the interorganizational relationships we we assume that risk and trust are separable
explore in this paper can be governed by two, concepts for transacting parties. Second,
less well explored, types of contracting: recurrent employing a behavioral assumption of trustworthi-
and relational. Recurrent contracts involve ness (open, other-regarding behavior) rather than
repeated exchanges of assets that have moderate opportunism (self-interest seeking with guile)
degrees of transaction specificity.5 The terms of enables us to (a) define how firms might build
these exchanges tend to be certain, but some trust through recurrent contracts and (b) explore
contingencies may be left to future resolution. the benefits of governing long-term uses of
Temporally, the duration of these contracts is idiosyncratic assets through relational contracts
relatively short-term. The parties see themselves in lieu of hierarchies. Third, we assume that
as autonomous, legally equal, but contemplating parties to contracts negotiated and agreed to on
a more embedded relationship. They use the the basis of trustworthiness are far less constrained
recurrent contracting to explore outcomes driven ex ante about the ex post contract implications
by motives other than efficiency, to experiment of their bounded rationality (i.e., they trust each
with safeguards, and with alternative methods other to deal fairly with gaps in the contract that
for resolving conflict. Neoclassical contract law result from their inability to perfectly forsee the
(Macneil, 1974) provides the legal framework future). These assumptions about conditions
within which these predominantly market-based under which relational contracting occurs are
transactions are governed. associated with criteria that bear on the govern-
In contrast, relational contracts tend to involve ance choices confronting transacting parties, a
long-term investments that stem from groundwork premise we now develop in more detail.
laid by recurrent bargaining on the production and
transfer of property rights among these legally
Risk
equal and autonomous parties. The property,
products, or services jointly developed and A recurring source of risk in all transactions is
exchanged in these transactionsentail highly specific the need to make decisions in the face of the
investments, in ventures that cannot be fully uncertainty of accomplishing tasks that require
specified or controlled by the parties in advance sustained cooperation with others, particularly
of their execution. As a consequence, the parties when they represent difficult or novel ventures
to these rational contracts are exposed to a much (Ring and Van de Ven, 1989). This uncertainty
broader variety of trading hazards than their can lead to various types of risk. Chakravarthy
counterparts employing either market or hier- (1985: 260) describes one form as commercial
archical transactions experience. Disputes are risk (i.e., the probabilities of finding
resolved through internal mechanisms designed to 'price-performance niches' in the market) and
preserve the relationship and insure that both the another as technological risk (i.e., the probability
efficiency and equity outcomes sought in the long- of bringing technology to the market). Risk may
term relationship are realized. In contrast to the also reflect difficulty in establishing probabilities
unified governance typically attributed to hierarchy to scientific (i.e. 'a lack of fundamental
(e.g. Williamson, 1985, 1991), bilateral governance knowledge') or engineering (i.e. will a technology
is employed in relational contracts. work?) uncertainty (Marcus, 1988: 140). Finally,
risk may be defined in terms of 'corporate risk'
(see, generally, Bromiley, 1991; Miller and
CRITERIA BEARING ON CHOICE OF Bromiley, 1990). This kind of risk frequently
GOVERNANCE FORMS presents itself as managers confronting the need
for resources choose between a slower process
Our analysis of cooperative agreements that of further enhancing their own organization's
are governed by recurrent and/or relational capabilities, or acquiring those capabilities rap-
idly, but at high investment costs, through a
5 Williamson (1985) would characterize these as being mixed merger.
idiosyncratic assets. Deciding whether an organization should face
488 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

circumstancesin which these forms of risk all Trust


occur alone, or through cooperative arrange-
ments, leads to 'corporate strategic risk' (Baird Although higher degrees of risk mean that
and Thomas, 1985). In their view, this kind of managers must focus more of their attention on
risk involves 'venturing into the unknown, the commercial and financial characteristics of a
[moves]that may resultin corporateruin-moves deal they are contemplating, the need to work
for which the outcomes and probabilitiesmay be cooperatively over sustained periods of time
only partially known and where hard to define means that they must also concern themselves
goals may not be met' (Baird and Thomas, with the trustworthiness of other parties to a
1985:231-232). deal. Two different definitions of trust are
In this paper we proceed on an assumption frequently used in the literature: (1) confidence
that the degree of risk inherentin any transaction or predictability in one's expectations (Zucker,
generallywill rise in directproportionto decreases 1986) and confidence in the other's goodwill
in time, information,and control (MacCrimmon (Friedman, 1991). We employ the second defi-
and Wehrung, 1986: 14-19). Time accentuates nition in this paper. We operate from the
risk when demands for action are beyond the perspective that personal embeddedness at a
control of the parties to a deal. For example, minimum, is a necessary condition for trust (e.g.
fear of losing first-moveradvantagescan drive a Blau, 1964).
firmto prematurelymarketnew products,even in There is pervasive evidence supporting the
the face of high commerecialand/ortechnological inclusion of trust as a critical factor in a structural
risk. model of transactions. For example, Arrow
Unexpected natural events (earthquakes, (1973: 24) points out that '. . .ethical elements
blizzards) or environments that regulate the enter in some measure into every contract;
activitiesof organizations(such as unions, quality without them, no market could function. There
conscious buyers; e.g. Ring, 1989) can lead to is an element of trust in every transaction' and
increasedrisk by reducingmanagement'scontrol it varies with transacting parties. Fried (1982: 8)
over the way in which it manages its operations. argues:
The absence of required resources also reduces
an organization'scontrol over its own actions when my confidence in your assistance derives
(e.g. Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). And, as from my conviction that you will do what is
MacCrimmonand Wehrung (1986) point out, a right (not just what is prudent), then I trust
you, and trust becomes a powerfultool for our
lack of control is usually accompaniedby a lack working our mutual wills in the world. So.
of information. This lack of information also powerfula tool is trust that we pursueit for its
affects the degree of risk faced by the parties to own sake; we prefer doing things cooperatively
a transaction. when we might have relied on fear or interest
The lack of information may be a result or worked alone.
of scientific or engineering uncertainty, or a
consequence of information asymmetries (e.g. Thus, we conclude that some element of trust
Arrow, 1971). Whatever its source, a lack of will be required for any transaction in which
informationalso will affect choices regardingthe
simultaneous exchange is unavailable to the
design of transaction governance structure. In parties. Needless to say, the condition applies to
dealing with risk, parties to a transaction will
most modern business transactions. Williamson
select a governance structure that provides (1985: 62-63) acknowledges the utility of trust.
appropriatesafeguards against that risk. Those He observes that '[o]ther things being equal,
safeguards,generally, will lead to more complexidiosyncratic exchange relations that feature
governancestructuresas levels of risk increase.personal trust will survive greater stress and will
Thus, consistent with Williamson (1975, 1985) display greater adaptability.'
we propose: Generally, trust emerges in two ways. First it
may be based on norms of equity which define
P1: The greaterthe risk in a transaction,the the degree to which one party judges that another
more complexthe governancestructure,ceteris party will fulfill its commitments and that the
paribus. relationship is equitable (Van de Ven and Walker,
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 489

1984). The concept of equity is developed in between the parties affirming the observance of
exchange theory, which argues that participants norms of equity by both parties.
in a relationship desire: (1) reciprocity, by which
one is morally obligated to give something in
return for something received (Gouldner, 1959),
Risk and trust are related
(2) fair rates of exchange between utilitarian
costs and benefits (Blau, 1964), and (3) distribu- Parties with a history of successful transactions
tive justice, through which all parties receive are less likely to suffer the adverse affects of
benefits that are proportional to their investments information asymmetry because they will share
(Homans, 1961). information that reduces technological or com-
The desire to be viewed as trustworthy also mercial risk more freely with each other. As they
has more direct, utilitarian roots. First, there are transact repeatedly, and observe norms of equity
many non-legal sanctions which make it expedient and reciprocity, they may place greater reliance
for individuals and organizations to fulfill commit- on parties not to act opportunistically when given
ments (Macaulay, 1963). Repeated personal access to proprietary information. Moreover,
interactions across firms encourage some mini- these same parties are likely to view the
mum level of courtesy and consideration, and information they received from each each as
the prospect of ostracism among peers minimizes more reliable (see, e.g. Normann, 1971 on the
individual opportunism. At the organizational effects of known intermediaries on information
level, the prospect of repeat business discourages exchanges).
attempts to seek a narrow, short-term advantage As organizations transact more frequently, and
(Maitland, Bryson and Van de Ven, 1985). for very different reasons, with other parties, it
Thus, trust is more likely to be extended to increases the likelihood that they will be able to
an organization when that organization earns a exercise greater autonomy without fearing a loss
reputation in the market place for following of control in subsequent transactions. As they
norms of equity.6 We argue, however, that a observe norms of equity and reciprocity regarding
reputation for trustworthiness, while necessary the 'management' and their contractual relation-
for acting in reliance on trust in a business ships, they may loosen constraints on operating
relationship, is not sufficient. autonomy that are employed to guard against
Reliance on trust by organizations can be opportunistic behavior. These'controls' manifest
expected to emerge between business partners themselves as ex post costs of contracting such
only when they have successfully completed as bonding costs, or as 'agency' costs such
transactions in the past and they perceive one as monitoring expenditures of the parties as
another as complying with norms of equity. The principals (e.g. Jensen and Meckling, 1976).
more frequently the parties have successfully The more frequently that an organization
transacted, the more likely they will bring higher transacts with different types of organizations,
levels of trust to subsequent transactions. As the the more its stock of information regarding the
level of trust increases, greater reliance may be predictability or reliability of parties is likely to
placed on the actions of the trusted party. Thus, increase. Diversity in transactions is also likely
we propose that: to increase its store of information regarding the
efficacy of contractual safeguards. Finally, even
P2: Trust is a necessary, but not sufficient, though a lack of time is frequently something
condition for market transactions, ceteris par- over which all parties to a transaction have
ibus. relatively little control, a history of successful
past transactions may enable parties to prolong
P3: Reliance on trust will emerge only as a the time within which decisions have to be made.
consequence of repeated market transactions Past success can also diminish the time required
to gather information. Thus, we propose that:
6
Weigelt and Camerer (1988) provide a very useful review P4: The greater the ability to rely on trust,
of reputation. Their analysis of reputation as a screening
mechanism is pertinent to our approach, but a more detailed the less the risk inherent in a transaction, ceteris
explication is not essential to the arguments made here. paribus.
490 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN Cell 1


GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE, TRUST
AND RISK In many business transactions, each party has
easy access to information needed to evaluate
The foregoing discussion implies that relation- commercial or technological risk. Time frames
ships may exist between degrees of risk, reliance within which the transaction is to be carried out
on trust and the kind of governance structures are short enough that the parties can exercise
employed by parties to a transaction. More appropriate levels of control. These transactions
explicitly, we offer the following propositions. reflect low risk. Thus, the parties need not
depend on a single partner to accomplish a
P5: Varying levels of risk and reliance on transaction or, for that matter, on any party's
trust will explain the governance structures of trustworthiness. Discrete contracts, classical con-
transactions. tract law and markets provide an ideal combi-
nation for governing these kinds of transactions.
PSa: Low risk, low reliance on trust trans- Even when simultaneous exchange is not possible,
actions will be governed by markets, ceteris if these transacting parties encounter conflict,
paribus. mistrust, or malfeasance, they can seek recourse
from the courts rather than depending on the
P5b: High risk, low reliance on trust trans- party to 'make things right', and then 'can simply
actions will be governed by hierarchies, ceteris move on to the legion of other traders willing to
paribus. do business on market terms; social relations and
their details thus become frictional matters'
P5c: Low risk, high reliance on trust trans- (Granovetter, 1985: 484).
actions will be governed by recurrent contracts, Consequently, while sufficient for transacting
ceteris paribus. in such circumstances, reliance on trust is not
necessary and, in fact, levels of trust may be
P5d: High risk, high reliance on trust trans- very low or nonexistent in many such transactions.
actions will be governed by relational contracts, However, if parties wish to establish reputations
ceteris paribus. for trustworthiness in the market, they can only
do so by refraining from opportunistic behavior
In Figure 1 we illustrate these propositions. In in the course of negotiating and executing discrete
the discussion which follows we expand upon the contracts.
logic that supports them.
Cell 2
RISKOF TE DEAL In contexts in which' high levels of risk may be
encountered, and economic efficiency is the sole
fh
objective of the parties, hierarchical governance
1 ~~~~~~2 structuresgenerally provide the parties with appro-
low priate safeguards. Dependence is eliminated on
complex and costly negotiations to anticipate
markuts hiaarchy properly the totality of investments and all possible
outcome contingencies that may be entailed in
ON TRUST
RELLANCE undertaking a high-risk venture through a discrete
AMONGTHE PARTIES 3 4
contract-based market transaction. In addition, in
high-risk situations in which time is of the essence,
the parties may employ hierarchy as a governance
high recurrentcontrac relationalcontrac
mechanism through a merger. But, this gives rise
to the conflicts outlined above.
Figure1. A typology of governancestructuresI Or, the parties can simply agree to create a
new hierarchy through a joint venture. This has
Figure1. A typologyof governancestructures the effect of reducing some of the corporate risk
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 491

in the transaction by limiting the degree of relationships between the transactions of a single
investment in the hierarchy (in contrast to party. Thus, a transaction undertaken by a party
merger, or acquisition, of the whole hierarchy of at time (t4) is made independent of the future
another organization). In this 'newco,' opportun- needs of that party, including the need for
ism is mitigated and constrained by the role and transaction-specific assets at time (t,+ 1).8 The
authority relations that are prescribed, motivated, static nature of TCE, and its focus on single
and monitored in a unified governance structure. transactions, also means that transaction cost
By appeal to authority and fiat, internal organi- analysis does not require explicit assumptions
zation is 'an enormously efficient way to settle regarding history between focal transacting par-
instrumental differences' (Williamson, 1975: 30). ties.
Reliance on high levels of trust may be Recurrent contracting enables the parties to
sufficient for organizing such transactions within build trust, by demonstrating norms of equity
the unified governance structure that charac- and reciprocity. This form of governance also
terizes hierarchy, but it need not be necessary. enables them to experiment with elements of
Indeed, in hierarchical governance structures, hierarchy that can be incorporated into contract:
dependence on maintaining good social relations command structures and authority systems, incen-
can be virtually eliminated. Role relations tive systems, administered pricing systems (costs,
between legally unequal superiors and subordi- qualities, prices), a structure for the resolution
nates are substituted, and as they become of conflict and standard operating procedures
institutionalized their efficacy can grow.7 In this (Stinchcombe, 1990).
kind of context, Granovetter (1985) argues that If we assume that parties act strategically, then
an over-socialized account of human action recurrent contracting provides an approach to
emerges in which institutional role arrangements governing transactions in time (t,j) that would
attenuate the dependency on personal trust not be efficient if no future transaction between
characteristic of behavior in socially embedded the parties was contemplated. As we have
relationships. Thus, like the under-socialized, suggested, the parties may experiment with
atomistic view of social relations between parties exogenous or endogenous safeguards that would
in simple market transactions, this over-socialized not be necessary if they were to rely solely on
view of role relationships between superiors and the market as a governance mechanism. The
subordinates in hierarchical transactions tends to ability to rely on trust enables parties anticipating
relegate social relations to frictional matters. the need for transaction-specific assets at time
In sum, parties transacting by discrete contract (t,+ j) to consider each other in time (tj) as
in markets or within hierarchies rely on atomistic sources of those assets.
market norms or superior/subordinate role Thus, given the opportunity, parties may
relationships. In contrast, we argue that trust is engage in recurrent low-risk transactions within
the principal mode of social control among parties market governance structures for purposes of
using recurrent or relational contracting as a establishing higher levels of trust with their
means of governance. partners.9 Over time, recurrent contracting
between parties also permits experimentation
with safeguards calibrated to higher degrees
Cell 3
of risk and greater reliance on trust. These
Nothing in the theory of transaction cost eco- safeguards, ultimately, may offset the need to
nomics requires that assumptions be made about rely upon the more costly (both in production

I As most students of organizations will 8 The more likely implicit assumption in TCE is that if the
recognize, achieving
these kinds of results in practice is quite difficult. Authority party is aware of the need for transaction-specific assets in
leads to its own abuses (e.g. Dow, 1987). Because decision- the future, they will understand that the most efficient way
making powers are not always clearly delineated, uncertainty of meeting the need is by resort to a hierarchy.
abounds within the hierarchy. Moreoever, information I Williamson (1985: 62-63) recognizes that recurrent trans-
asymmetries, organizational politics, rapid changes in internal actions can reduce transaction costs that arise from the
and external environments all create risk and give rise to the 'fundamental transformation' of a large numbers bidding
need to establish and rely upon trust. We explore these issues condition to a small numbers bidding condition. See, more
briefly in the conclusion. generally, Williamson (1985: 343-345).
492 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

and transaction costs) unified governance that characterized by high asset specificity, uncer-
tends to accompany hierarchy. In the future they tainty, and recurrence in a small numbers
may be able to pursue more flexible production bargaining condition. In these high-risk trans-
processes, by employing a governance structure actions, the TCE argument is that hierarchy is
that does not create redundancies to existing, the most efficient governance structure, ceteris
hierarchically based solutions to engineering or paribus. Lincoln (1990: 281) concludes, however,
administrative problems (Miles and Snow, 1978). that such an argument 'stresses the cold, rational,
We also argue that recurrent contracting and formal side, [of transacting]'and ignores the
enables the parties to a transaction to more easily crucial role that informal, socially embedded
pursue equitable outcomes that lead to higher personal relationships have in producing stable
levels of trust. The low risk condition of recurrent relations of trust, obligation, and custom among
contracting solutions to governance enables the formally independent firms."'
parties to explore a wider variety of administered The flexibility inherent in relational contracting
pricing schemes, or to leave other performance creates strong incentives to become involved with
measures (e.g. quantities, quality, delivery time) parties in whose trustworthiness heavy reliance
open to future determination. can be placed. Among these flexibilities is the
Neoclassical contract law (e.g. Macneil, 1978) ability to avoid the kinds of conflicts, previously
provides parties engaged in recurrent contracting discussed, that arise in mergers, such as making
with greater flexibility. This flexibility is denied trade-offs between timeliness and high investment
them by classical contract law that is most costs.
efficiency applied in cases of discrete contracting Because risk is high in these transactions, high
which, we argue, will be employed in the low- levels of trust are not only sufficient; they are
risk, low-trust conditions of Cell 1 of our model. also necessary. The degree to which the parties
As Williamson (1991: 271) observes: rely on trust in designing endogenous safeguards
for their transaction will depend upon the degree
Neoclassical contract law. . .relieves parties from of risk the parties will face in their transaction.
strictenforcement[in] contractsin which parties Relational contracts require a more elaborate
to the transactionmaintain autonomy but are internal governance structure than is associated
bilaterally dependent to a nontrivial degree.
Identityplainlymattersif prematuretermination with discrete transactions, or recurrent con-
of persistent maladaptionwould place burdens tracting, but one that is less elaborate than that
on one or both parties. which accompanies unified governance. Whereas
discrete transactions rely heavily on public
The ability to engage in recurrent contracting ordering of legal and market sanctions, and
also provides parties anticipating the need to rely unified governance relies on elaborate authority
on each other for idiosyncratic assets in the relationships, relational contracting rests much
future to guard against one final contingency. In more on private ordering emerging from what
our discussion of risk and trust we made no Kronman (1985) describes as a 'state of union':
judgement about the impact, if any, time would an evolving set of safeguards that are mutually
have on their variability. Now we make the agreed to by, and for, the immediate parties
following assumption: parties will have the
opportunity to engage in riskier transactions "I Indeed, Dore (1983), Granovetter (1985), Lincoln (1990)
sooner than they can develop offsetting capabili- and Powell (1990) argue that occasional reliance on socially
ties to rely on trust between themselves. In such embedded relations often produces sufficient levels of trust
situations, neoclassical contract law provides the and obligation between parties to efficiently avert market
failure and the need for full internalization of transactions
flexibility required to experiment with safeguards within a hierarchy. As exemplified in Eccles' (1981) construc-
that offset the parties' inability to rely more tion industry and investment banking (Eccles and Crane,
heavily on trust in governing the transaction. 1987) studies, the overlay of long-term, personal relationships
on economic transactions between firms generates standards
of expected behavior, reliable information, and monitoring
procedures that are at least equal or superior to those of
Cell 4 internal hierarchical relations in discouraging malfeasance.
In this sense, relational contracting combines the efficiency
The kinds of reciprocal dependencies described and flexibility of markets with the control and information-
in our opening paragraphs involve transactions processing advantages or organization (Lincoln, 1990: 281).
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 493

because they see their interests as convergent. that may flow from the transaction due to conflict
In cases in which the parties face reciprocal between the parties, as well as the decision
strategic dependencies of the types previously processes, review provisions, and due process
described, interests do converge. appeals that may be followed by parties as they
The successful reliance on high levels of trust seek (at a minimum) to insure that levels of
that can emerge from recurrent contracting enables harmony that existed ex ante are maintained
the parties to employ relational contracts in repeat throughout the duration of a relational contract,
transacting for idiosyncratic assets, even in cases or beyond, if the parties are interested in
in which ex ante transaction risk is very high. The employing relational contracts as a governance
use of appropriate endogenous safeguards to structure for future transactions.
achieve an internal harmonizing of conflict and the Several corollaries to Proposition 6 become
preservation of relationships built to solve strategic evident when we further consider the main and
dependencies is of paramount importance in interaction effects of trust and risk on the
relational contracts (e.g. Macneil, 1978). structuring of safeguards for relational contracts.
We argue that greater harmony (and an Under conditions of high contracting risk and
enhanced ability to preserve a relationship) flows high levels reliance on trust,'2 parties will seek
from the increased production and transaction
flexibility available to the parties through
relational contracts. Authority and control sys- the safeguards will be designed to take account of the
tems related to performance outcomes can be following legal and managerial requirements.
To be lawful, contracts must involve an agreement between
loosely specified in the contract. Incentive systems competent persons. They must be based on consideration,
can be left adaptable to the changing needs of which can be defined as a right, interest, profit or other form
the specific relationship, and made independent of benefit that accrues to one party or some detriment,
disadvantage, responsibility or loss assumed by the other
of other systems employed by the parties. Issues party (e.g. Becker v. Colonial Life Ins. Co., 138 NYS 491
such as costs, quality, prices, volume, and other [1912]). Thus, consideration reflects a promise (or a set of
production-related matters can be left relatively promises) to do or not to do something. In designing the
contract, it is essential that both parties agree to the same
open-ended. thing in the same sense and that they enjoy a meeting of the
This flexibility obviates the necessity of leaving minds on the essential terms and conditions of the contract
gaps in the contract which, in all likelihood, (e.g. Patrick v. Bowman, 149 US 411, 37 Led 790, 13 SCt
811, (1893]). This mutual consent must be evident in the
would render the contract void under classical language that the parties employ or from their words or
contract law. The ability to internally harmonize actions. Finally, what parties promise must be valid subject
conflict also enables the parties to avoid over- matter; that is, it should not be contrary to public law,
general policy or public justice, or violate provisions of
specifying the contract, which could leave them federal or state constitutions, federal or state statutes, or the
with little or no production or transaction-related common law (e.g. Ard Bottling Co. v. Dr. Pepper Co., 202
flexibility. Thus, we propose that: F2d 372 [1953]). Where these four primary ingredients are
present, a contract is formed and the promise (or multiple
promises), if breached, will be remedied. Conversely, when
P6: The elaborateness of safeguards in a contract is formed, performance of its terms will be
relational contracts is a function of the perceived recognized, in some way, as a duty (see, generally, American
Law Institute, Restatement, Second, Contracts, 1981).
level of risk in a transaction and the reliance To be managerially relevant, contracts must adequately
on trust by the parties to the exchange. specify the nature of the parties' relationship of five critical
dimensions: (1) risk, the level and nature of the risks accepted
or imposed on transacting parties by their inability to control
Broadly, these safeguards elaborate the rights the future; (2) returns, the parties expected rewards and
and duties of parties pertaining to the conditions outcomes given the asset commitments made by each party;
of the transaction. "IThey will also govern claims (3) control, the structures and procedures for allocating
authority and responsibility between the parties; (4) duration,
the length of time during which the parties are committed
I These broadly defined types of safeguards will also be to a transaction (Klein, 1982); and (5) termination, the events
employed in governing the three other nodal types of and procedures which allow parties the right of exit from a
governance outlined in Table 1. In our brief discussion of transaction.
the kinds of contract law used in each type of governance ' When we describe varying risk-trust contexts as high or
mechanism, we have touched on some of the issues related low we are, of course, speaking in relative terms. Because
to safeguards. Safeguard issues related to Cells 1 and 2 in we are focused here on relational contracts as the governance
Figure 1 should be well understood. Our discussion of mechanism, we are operating within a high risk-high trust
recurrent contracting provides some insight into the oppor- context in general, but accept the fact that among parties to
tunities to experiment with safeguards. In all of these cases, transactions degrees of risk and trust will remain variable.
494 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

to draft relational contracts that increase the making of such decisions conveniently and
timeliness and amount of information collectively effectively for [name omitted].
available to them, yet safeguard control over
proprietary know-how. The objective of these Another safeguard in such cases involves
safeguards is to immunize the parties from the developing machinery for gathering and dissemi-
adverse consequences that could flow from nating information while recording reputational
unanticipated commercial or technological risks effects (Williamson, 1985: 121). Supplier associ-
(Chakravarthy, 1985). ations are offered by Williamson as an exemplar
High levels of risk and trust typically will be of these kinds of safeguards.
present in cases where organizations use relational High-risk relational transactions in which par-
contracts to govern joint R&D, technology, ties may still be learning to rely more heavily on
or product development ventures. Among the trust are likely to make extensive use of hostages
employed safeguards, we would expect to find and collateral as a means of reducing risk
provisions that facilitate a just distribution of the otherwise surrounding a lack of exclusive control
tacit know-how assets (Winter, 1987) that are over idiosyncratic assets. In such cases the parties
produced through such cooperative ventures. By may seek to guard against risks related to a lack
its nature, tacit know-how is difficult to 'divide of information or information asymmetry by
up', and it is virtually impossible to do so in requiring reciprocity (Williamson, 1985: 190),
advance of its creation. We would also expect to especially in the exchange of tacit know-how
find provisions on how the parties would jointly (Winter, 1987). These forms of consultation may
deal with other opportunistic actors, e.g. collec- not be sufficient in cases in which heavy
tively or individually funding efforts to create investments in idiosyncratic physical or site-
stronger regimes of appropriability (Teece, specific assets are involved in the transaction. In
1986). 13 such cases, control risks may be safeguarded
Consultation designed to reduce information by requiring partial financing through equity
asymmetries (Williamson, 1985: 307) is one safe- collateral, or by the exercise of voting rights that
guard offered by TCE theory that can be accompany equity positions or membership on a
employed by parties to relational contracts. An board of directors (Williamson, 1985: 307).
attorney friend of one of the authors, specializing Because the full potential of relying on high
in relational contracts between U.S. and Japanese trust is yet to be realized, in these kinds of cases
firms, argues that he frequently uses: the parties may also provide for numerous
procedural safeguards, review provisions, and
clauseswhichstate how partieswillworktogether either bilateral or trilateral (Williamson, 1985)
on key matters.. .without getting involved in mechanisms for dispute resolution. In determin-
proceduralmechanics and details. The annual ing which of these kinds of safeguards are more
and long range business plan provisionsare an
'invention'of mine and I believe they work to efficacious, the parties are likely to consider the
eliminatedisputesby puttingthe partiestogether extent to which the review procedure minimizes
in constructive planning environments on a risk associated with a lack of control over time.
regularbasis. (personalcommunication,1990). Extensive provisions for allocating benefits and
burdens as well as due process appeals will be
An example of this kind of language follows: required because parties want some assessment
of the time that will be associated with the
The partiesagree that [nameomitted]and [name procedures for conflict resolution as a means to
omitted] are authorized to consult and agree minimize unjust or inequitable outcomes to
with respect to major policy decisions for the future contingencies with other parties whose
[name omitted] in accordancewith procedures
agree upon between them in orderto enable the trustworthiness is questioned (Bies, Shapiro and
Cummings, 1988). An alternative approach in
such cases is to increase trustworthiness, perhaps
1' Home or host country laws might prevent parties to a by requiring the 'social conditioning' or 'edu-
relational contract from different countries from engaging in cation' of one or both of the parties (Williamson,
'political' activities. Consequently, one party might have to
assume some or all of the costs of attempting to safeguard 1985: 247, 311).
both from opportunism by a third. These high-risk, lower reliance on trust,
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 495

relational contracting transactions are likely to 1989; Ring and Rands, 1989; Ring and Van de
occur in cases in which parties find it necessary Ven, 1989). We hope that they will stimulate
to transact in new 'markets' in order to maintain further theoretical and empirical work.
their global competitiveness. They may take The model developed thus far describes the
the form of joint marketing agreements, joint antecedents and structural forms of relational
manufacturing agreements, etc. In some of these contracts in relatively static terms. However, our
cases the safeguards may also include customer analysis implies that the emergence of these
or territorial restrictions. For many of these kinds relational contracts is a dynamic process. Levels
of relational contracts, the resemblance to unified of risk in deals and reliance on trust between
governance will be considerable, but may remain parties can and will change over time, and with
in place only so long as it takes to establish an these changes parties will alter their choices in
ability to rely more heavily on trust. governance structures and accompanying safe-
Under conditions in which risk is low but guards. Our argument implies a number of
reliance on trust is high, parties to a relational paths by which parties use different governance
contract transaction can be expected to resort to structures, as risk and reliance on trust vary
even more efficient informal 'handshakes,' or as across individual transactions. In general, the
is the case in Japan, to te-uchi (the clapping of foregoing discussion implied a progression from
hands) in governing their relationships. These discrete to recurrent to relational contracting.
relational contracts are likely to contain few Alternatively, we have observed that a firm might
endogenous safeguards because of the parties' move from hierarchical governance to governance
reliance on the trust that they have for each by recurrent contracting, to relational contracting
other as a result of prior recurrent or relational as it contracts out functions it previously found
contracts, or for reasons that stem from the social to be more efficiently governed through hier-
embeddedness of the transaction. These types of archy. An appreciation of the dynamics associated
transactions are exemplified in the socially with shifting across governance mechanisms
embedded relationships often found between requires a processual understanding of how and
recurrent contractors and subcontractors in the why recurrent and relational contracts develop,
building construction industry. evolve, and dissolve over time. However, an
explication of these processes is beyond the scope
of this analysis (Van de Ven and Ring, 1991).
CONCLUSION For example, our propositions about the actions
of transacting parties have been developed
This paper has provided a conceptual framework independently of the environment in which a
for understanding a broader variety of governance firm is operating at the time a transaction is
mechanisms than those typically accompanying a undertaken. Further elaboration of the frame-
focus on markets and hierarchies. We have work should consider its operation in the specific
explored varying combinations of risk and reliance contexts in which organizations find themselves
on trust that will lead transacting parties to select as parties to a transaction. For example, the
among four nodal forms of governance: discrete, extent to which specific industry contexts lead to
recurrent, or relational contracting, or hierarchy, higher or lower levels of risk or trust was beyond
in governing their transactions. We have argued the discussion of those concepts required here.
that trust is central to understanding bargaining These contexts might include the strategy which
transactions, but has been assumed away as a a firm was pursuing, its strategic predisposition,
frictional matter in prior treatments of simple or the stage of industry or product life cycle
market or hierarchical transactions. Many of the which the firm confronts (e.g. Hudson and Ring,
observations and propositions about the structure 1986; Van de Ven and Garud, 1989). Moreover,
of relational bargaining transactions presented in this global economy, relational bargaining
here were inferred from an interdisciplinary transactions are increasingly occurring between
literature in law, economics, sociology, and parties from different nation states, cultures, and
management and from inductive observations of languages. They represent a much more complex
a small number of cooperative interorganizational set of conditions than have been examined
relationships over time (Garud and Van de Ven, here. While these more complex environmental
496 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven

conditionscan be incorporatedin the conceptual reviewers for the Strategic Management Journal.
framework developed here (e.g. Ring, 1991), This research program has been supported (in
their systematicdevelopmentwill requirea much part) by a grant to the Strategic Management
better understandingof how trust is developed, Research Center, University of Minnesota from
or manifested,in differentculturesthan currently the Program on Organization Effectiveness,
provided in the literature. In addition to these Office of Naval Research, under Contract
macro level issues, we also ignore the potential N. N00014-84-K-0016, by a Grant from the
effects of individual differences (e.g. how they Graduate School of the University of Minnesota,
are likely to alter perceptionsof risk and trust). and by a Summer Research Grant from Loyola
The conceptualframeworkpresentedhere also Marymount University.
applies to the use of recurrent or relational
contracts within complex multidivisionalorgani-
zational hierarchies. If, as Stinchcombe (1990) REFERENCES
argues, contractscan simulatecriticalelementsof
American Law Institute, Restatement, Second, Con-
hierarchy in the market, then contracts within tracts, Philadelphia, PA, 1981.
organizationscan be similarlyemployed.As Ouchi Ard Bottling Co. v. Dr. Pepper Co., 202 F2d 372,
(1984) has argued, recurrenttransactionsamong 1953.
divisionsin these quasi-marketM-formorganiza- Arrow, K. Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing,
tions are based more on trust and equity than on North-Holland, Chicago, IL, 1971.
Arrow, K. Information and Economic Behavior,
the limited monitoringand control capabilitiesof Federation of Swedish Industries, Stockholm,
hierarchy. Perhaps in high-risk cases in which Sweden, 1973.
relianceon high levels of trustis possible,we will Baird, I. and H. Thomas. 'Toward a contingency model
find hierarchiesthat look more like clans, or of strategic risk taking', Academy of Mangement
networks of contracts to employ Stinchcombe's Review, 10, 1985, pp. 230-243.
Barney, J. B. 'The debate between traditional manage-
(1990) concept, than current M-form organiza- ment theory and organizational economics: Substan-
tions.14 Bromiley and Cummings (1990) are tive differences or intergroup conflict', Academy of
extendingthis schemeby pointingto the increased Management Review, 15, 1990, pp. 382-393.
efficienciesthatare producedwhensociallyembed- Barney, J. B. and W. G. Ouchi. Organizational
ded hierarchical reporting relationships are Economics, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA, 1986.
Becker v. Colonial Life Ins. Co., 138NYS 491, 1912.
designedto promotetrust.Bowie (1990)speculates Berg, S. V., J. Duncan and P. Friedman. Joint
on similarphenomenawhile consideringthe firm Strategies and Corporate Innovation. Oelgeschlager,
as a moral community.And, as we have noted, Gunn and Hain, Publishers, Inc., Cambridge, MA,
the ability to rely on trust in high-risksituations 1983.
can lead organizationsto considerrelationalcon- Bies, R. J., D. L. Shapiro and L. L. Cummings. 'Casual
accounts and managing organizational conflict: Is
tractingas a meansof restructuring the hierarchy. it enough to say it's not my fault', Communication
Only through such research will we begin to Research, 15, 1988, pp. 381-399.
develop an empiricalgroundingof the transaction Blau, P. M. Exchange and Power in Social Life, Wiley,
structureswhichorganizationsand theiragentswill New York, 1964.
find helpful to design, maintain, and conclude Bowie, N. 'The firm as moral community'. Strategic
Management Research Center, University of Minne-
cooperativerelationshipsbetweenorganizations. sota, Minneapolis, MN, Working Paper, 1990.
Bromiley, P. 'Testing a causal model of corporate risk
taking and performance', Academy of Management
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Journal, 35, 1991, pp. 37-59.
Bromiley, P. and L. L. Cummings. 'Transaction costs
in organizations with trust'. Strategic Management
We gratefully acknowledge extremely helpful Research Center, University of Minnesota, Minnea-
comments on previous drafts of this paper from polis, MN, Working Paper, 1990.
Bryson, J. and P. S. Ring. 'A transaction cost approach
to policy intervention', Policy Studies, 23, 1990,
14 More complete exploration of the roles of recurrent pp. 205-230.
and relational contracting in governing relationships within Cameron, K., S. Freeman and A. Mishra. 'Best
organizations is beyond the scope of this paper. We believe, practices in white collar downsizing: Managing
however, that our framework can usefully be employed in contradictions', Academy of Management Executive,
such cases. 5, 1991, pp. 57-73.
Structuring Cooperative Relationships 497
Chakravarthy, B. S. 'Business-government partner- Harrigan, K. R. Managing for Joint Venture Success,
ships in emerging industries; Lessons from the Lexington Books, MA, 1986.
American synfuels experience', Advances in Stra- Hill, C. W. L. 'Cooperation, opportunism, and the
tegic Management, 3, 1985, pp. 257-275. invisible hand: Implications for transaction cost
Coase, R. 'The nature of the firm', Economica, 4, theory', Academy of Management Review, 15, 1990,
1937, pp. 386-405. pp. 500-513.
Commons, J. R. Institutional Economics, University Hill, C. W. L. and W. C. Kim. 'Searching for a
of Wisconsin Press, Madison, WI, 1934. dynamic theory of the multinational enterprise: A
Commons, J. R. The Economics of Collective Action, transaction cost model', Strategic Management
University of Wisconsin, Madison, WI, 1950. Journal, 9, 1988, pp' 93-104.
Contractor, F. J. 'International business: An alternative Homans, G. Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms,
view', International Marketing Review, 7, 1986, Harcourt, New York, 1961.
pp. 75-85. Hudson, R. L. and P. S. Ring. 'Designing low cost
Donaldson, L. 'The ethereal hand: Organizational governance structures'. Discussion Paper No. 60,
economics and management theory', Academy of Strategic Management Research Center, University
Management Review, 15, 1990, pp. 369-381. of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, 1986.
Dore, R. 'Goodwill and the spirit of capitalism', British James, B. G. 'Alliance, the new strategic focus', Long
Journal of Sociology, 34, 1983, pp. 459-482. Range Planning, 18, 1985, pp. 76-81.
Dow, G. K. 'The function of authority in transaction Jarillo, J. C. 'On strategic networks', Strategic Manage-
cost economics', Journal of Law, Economics, and ment Journal, 9, 1988, pp. 31-41.
Organizational Behavior, 5, 1987, pp. 13-38. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling. 'Theory of the firm:
Doz, I. and C. K. Prahalad. 'Managing DMNCs: A Managerial behavior, agency costs, and capital
search for a new paradigm', Strategic Management structure', Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 1976,
Journal, 12, Special Issue, 1991, pp. 145-164. pp. 305-360.
Eccles, R. G. 'Bureaucratic versus craft administration: Jones, G. R. and C. W. L. Hill. 'Transaction
The relationship of market structure to the construc- cost analysis of strategy-structure choice', Strategic
tion firm', Administrative Science Quarterly, 26, Management Journal, 9, 1988, pp. 159-172.
1981, pp. 449-469. Killing, J. P. Strategies for Joint Venture Success,
Eccles, R. G. and D. Crane. 'Managing through Praeger, New York, 1983.
networks in investment banking', California Man- Klein, W. 'The modern business organization: Bar-
agement Review, 30, 1987, pp. 176-195. gaining under constraints', The Yale Law Journal,
Fried, C. Contract as Promise, Harvard University 91, 1982, pp. 1521-1564.
Press, Cambridge, MA, 1982. Kronman, A. 'Contract law and the state of nature',
Friedman, R. A. 'Trust, understanding, and control: Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1,
Factors affecting support for mutual gains bargaining 1985, pp. 5-31.
in labor negotiations'. A paper presented at the Lincoln, J. R. 'Japanese organization and organization
Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management, theory'. In L. L. Cummings and B. Staw (eds.),
Miami, FL, August, 1991. Research in Orgapizational Behavior, 12, 1990,
Friedlander, M. Jr. and G. Gurney. Handbook of pp. 255-294.
Successful Franchising, Van Nostrand Reinhold, Macaulay, S. 'Non-contractual relations in business',
New York, 1981. American Sociological Review, 28, 1963, pp. 55-70.
Garud, R. and A. H. Van de Ven. 'Technological MacCrimmon, K. R. and D. A. Wehrung. Taking
innovation and industry emergence: The case of Risks: The Management of Uncertainty, Free Press,
cochlear implants'. In A. Van de Ven, H. Angle, New York, 1986.
and M. S. Poole (eds.), Research on the Management Macneil, I. R. 'The many futures of contract', Southern
of Innovation: The Minnesota Studies, Ballinger/ California Law Review, 47, 1974, pp. 691-816.
Harper & Row, New York, 1989, pp. 489-532. Macneil, I. R. The New Social Contract, Yale
Goldberg, V. 'Relational exchange: Economics and University Press, New Haven, CT, 1980.
complex contracts', American Behavioral Scientist, Macneil, I. R. 'Contracts: Adjustments of long-term
23, 1980, pp. 337-352. economic relationship under classical, neoclassical,
Gouldner, A. 'Reciprocity and autonomy in functional and relational cbntract law', Northwestern University
theory'. In L. Gross (ed.), Symposium on Sociologi- Law Review, 72, 1978, pp. 854-906.
cal Theory, pp. 241-280, Harper and Row, New Maitland, I., J. Bryson and A. H. Van de Ven.
York, 1959. 'Sociologists, economists, and opportunism', Acad-
Granovetter, M. 'Economic action and social structure: emy of Management Review, 10, 1985, pp. 59-65.
The problem of embeddedness', American Journal Marcus, A. A. 'Risk, uncertainty and scientific
of Sociology, 78, 1985, pp. 481-510. judgement', Minerva, 26, 1988, pp. 138-143.
Gray, B. 'Building interorganizational alliances: Miles, R. and C. C. Snow. Organizational Strategy,
Planned change in a global environment', Research Structure, and Process, McGraw-Hill, New York,
in Organizational Change and Development, 4, 1978.
1990, pp. 101-140. Miller, K. and P. Bromiley. 'Strategic risk and
Harrigan, K. R. Strategiesfor Joint Ventures, Lexington corporate performance: An analysis of alternative
Books, Lexington, MA, 1985. risk measures', Academy of Management Journal,
498 P. S. Ring and A. H. Van de Ven
33, 1990, pp. 756-779. Ballinger/Harper Row, New York, 1989, pp.
Normann, R. 'Organizational innovativeness: Product 337-366.
variation and reorientation', Administrative Science Stinchcombe, A. Information and Organizations, Uni-
Quarterly, 16, 1971, pp. 203-215. versity of California Press, Berkeley, CA, 1990.
Oliver, C. 'The determinants of interorganizational Sutton, R. I. and T. D'Aunno. 'Decreasing organi-
relationships: Integration and future directions', zational size: Untangling the effects of money and
Academy of Management Review, 16, 1990, people', Academy of Management Review, 14, 1989,
pp. 241-265. pp. 194-212.
Ouchi, W. G. The M-Form Society, Addison-Wesley, Teece, D. 'Profiting from technological innovation:
Reading, MA, 1984. Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing
Ouchi, W. G. and M. Kremen-Bolton, 'The logic and public policy', Research Policy, 15, 1986,
of joint research and development', California pp. 285-305.
Management Review, 30, 1988, pp. 9-33. Van de Ven, A. H. and R. Garud. 'A framework for
Patrick v. Bowman, 149 US 411, 37 Led 790, 13 Sct understanding the emergence of industries'. In R.
811, 1893. Rosenbloom and R. Burgelman (eds.), Research in
Perlmutter, H. V. and D. Heenan. 'Thinking ahead', Technological Innovation, Management and Policy,
Harvard Business Review, 86(2), 1986, pp. 136-152. 4, 1989, pp. 195-225.
Pfeffer, J. and G. R. Salancik. The External Control Van de Ven, A. H. and G. Walker. 'The dynamics
of Organizations, Harper & Row, New York, 1978. of interorganizational coordination', Administrative
Porter, M. E. and M. B. Fuller. 'Coalitions and global Science Quarterly, 29, 1984, pp. 598-621.
strategies'. In M. E. Porter (ed.), Competition Van de Ven, A. H. and P. S. Ring. 'The development
in Global Industries, Harvard University Press, of relational contracts between organizations',
Cambridge, MA, 1986, pp. 315-343. Strategic Management Research Center, University
Powell, W. W. 'Hybrid organizational arrangements', of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, Working Paper,
California Management Review, 30, 1987, pp. 67-87. 1991.
Powell, W. W. 'Neither market nor hierarchy: Network Walsh, J. P. and J. W. Ellwood. 'Mergers, acquisitions,
forms of organization'. In L. L. Cummings and B. and pruning of managerial deadwood', Strategic
Staw (eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior, Management Journal, 12, 1991, pp. 201-218.
12, 1990, pp. 295-336. Weigelt, K. and C. Camerer. 'Reputation and corpor-
Richardson, P. R. Cost Containment: The Ultimate ate strategy', Strategic Management Journal, 9,
Advantage, Free Press, New York, 1988. 1988, pp. 443-454.
Ring, P. S. 'Strategic alliances: A conceptual frame- White, H. 'Where do markets come from?', American
work'. Strategic Management Research Center, Journal of Sociology, 87, 1981, pp. 517-541.
University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, Work- Williamson, 0. Markets and Hierarchies, Free press,
ing Paper, 1991. New York, 1975.
Ring, P. S. 'The environment and strategic manage- Williamson, 0. 'The economics of organization: The
ment'. In Jack Rabin, Gerald Miller, W. Bartley transaction cost approach', American Journal of
Hildreth (eds.), Handbook on Strategic Manage- Sociology, 87, 1981, pp. 548-577.
ment, Marcel Dekker, New York, 1989, pp. 55-89. Williamson, 0. The Economic Institutions of Capi-
Ring, P. S. and A. H. Van de Ven. 'Legal and talism, Free Press, New York, 1985.
managerial dimensions of transactions'. In A. H. Williamson, 0. 'Comparative economic organization',
Van de Ven, H. Angle and M. S. Poole (eds.), Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 1991,
Research on the Management of Innovation: The pp. 269-296.
Minnesota Studies, Ballinger/Harper Row, New Winter, S. 'Knowledge and competence as strategic
York, 1989, pp. 171-192. assets'. In D. E. Teece (ed.), The Competitive
Ring, P. S. and G. Rands. 'Sensemaking, understand- Challenge, Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, 1987, pp.
ing, and committing: Emergent interpersonal trans- 159-184.
action processes in the evolution of 3M's micrograv- Zucker, L. G. 'Production of trust: Institutional
ity research program'. In A. H. Van de Ven, H. sources of economic structure'. In B. M. Staw and
Angle and M. S. Poole (eds.), Research on the L. L. Cummings (eds.), Research in Organizational
Management of Innovation: The Minnesota Studies, Behavior, 8, 1986, pp. 53-112.

View publication stats

You might also like