You are on page 1of 10

Home | Other Papers and Essays

Explanations of Japan’s
Imperialistic Expansion, 1894-1910
Bill Gordon

December 2003

Japan emerged in 1853 from two and a half centuries of self-imposed peaceful
isolation, but within a few decades the country’s leaders embarked on a policy of
aggressive territorial expansion. During the last half of the nineteenth century, the
Western imperialist powers of England, France, and Germany established the model
for acquisition of colonies in Asia and for the partition of China into spheres of
influence. Near the end of the century, about the same time Japan began to capture
colonial territory, the United States and Russia also initiated their imperialistic
expansion in Asia.

This paper will examine four of the most influential theories of imperialism to
determine whether they can provide explanations for Japan’s imperialism from 1894
to 1910, when Japan formally annexed Korea. The four theories to be reviewed will
be Hobson's theory of domestic market underconsumption that leads to capitalists
seeking profits overseas, Lenin's theory of the monopoly stage of capitalism,
Schumpeter's theory of inherited warlike tendencies from prior generations, and
nationalism's focus on politics as the critical factor. Although other theories of
imperialism exist, these four theories cover a broad range of economic, political, and
sociological factors that could explain Japan’s imperialistic expansion. This essay's
review of Japan's history of imperialism from 1894 to 1910 will show that the theory
of nationalism provides the best explanations of the causes of Japan's militaristic
actions and colonial acquisitions, although Schumpeter's sociological-based theory
seems to provide some explanation for the actions of the Meiji Period (1868-1912)
leaders.

Section 1 of this essay reviews the key points of the four theories of imperialism.
The following section examines some highlights of Japan's history of imperialism
between 1894 and 1910. Section 3 evaluates each theory as to whether or not it
explains Japan's imperialistic actions during this time period. The final section
provides conclusions.

1. Theories of Imperialism

Imperialism can be defined as direct or indirect domination of an industrialized


country over a colonial territory or another country. Although the theories of
Hobson, Lenin, and Schumpeter generally focus on imperialism of European
powers, especially Great Britain, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries,
this paper will examine these theories to assess their relevance in explaining the
causes of Japan’s imperialist push into other countries of Asia. These three theories
and the theory of nationalism have been subjected to various criticisms, but
proponents still exist for each one. For example, Nowell (2000) argues for the
historical validity and contemporary relevance of Hobson's theory. Schumpeter's
"idea still has a large following" (Howard and King 2000, 19), and there have
always been numerous supporters for Lenin's theory and the nationalist theory.

J.A. Hobson ([1905] 1938, 80-81) identified the taproot of imperialism to be surplus
capital in the home country in search of profitable investments in foreign markets.
The profits earned by the small number of rich capitalists in the home market
resulted in chronic oversaving, since they had a lower marginal propensity to
consume than poor workers with wages based upon the cost of living rather than the
efficiency of their labor (83-84). Although imperialism does not make sense as a
business policy for a nation as a whole due to its enormous military and
administrative expense, "strong organized industrial and financial interests" that
stand to gain from imperialism find ways to put this expense on the general public
(46, 106). Hobson argued that if purchasing power were reapportioned from the rich
to the poor, then the home market would provide full employment of capital and
labor with no overproduction, and there would be no need for the imperialistic fight
for foreign markets (86-87).

Lenin ([1917] 1939, 14, 88) expressed the Marxist view of imperialism as the
"monopoly stage of capitalism," the highest and final stage of capitalism prior to the
proletarian social revolution. Essential features of imperialism include the
concentration of production and capital into monopolies (large-scale firms), the
merging of bank and industrial capital, the export of capital, the apportionment of
the world among the large-scale firms, and the division of territories of the world
among the great capitalist powers (89). Lenin also emphasized that the need for raw
materials drove capitalists to acquire colonies (82-84). Like Hobson, Lenin argues
that surplus capital will be exported abroad for the purpose of increasing profits (63).
However, in contrast to Hobson's view that the problem of surplus capital could be
resolved by redistribution of purchasing power within the home country, Lenin
believed that the wretched condition of the masses was inevitable and that
imperialistic expansion by capitalist countries could not be avoided.

Joseph Schumpeter ([1919] 1951, 6) considered imperialism to be "the objectless


disposition on the part of the state to unlimited forcible expansion." Although
Schumpeter does not specifically address Japanese imperialism, he provides a wide
range of historical examples to show that nations and classes seek expansion only for
the sake of expanding and dominion only for the sake of ruling. The bellicosity of
an autocratic state derives from "the necessities of its social structure, from the
inherited dispositions of its ruling class, rather than from the immediate advantages
to be derived from the conquest" (59). As a country becomes more capitalistic, the
energy for war decreases as the "competitive system absorbs the full energies of
most of the people at all economic levels" (69). Schumpeter viewed imperialism as
an atavism in the social structure of capitalist states, an element from prior history
that affects emotional reactions (65).

Nationalism as a theory of imperialism goes under several other names, such as


"power politics" (Cohen 1973, 231; Mommsen 1980, 74) and "mercantilism"
(Brown 1974, 26; Gilpin 1975, 27). The theory of nationalism emphasizes the
essential role of the state in imperialistic behavior as a nation seeks to maximize its
power, prestige, and wealth relative to other countries. Nationalists consider
economic relations between nations to be conflictual, a zero-sum game where the
gain of one nation is the loss of another nation. This theory views capitalists as
willing to invest wherever profits are expected to be greatest, either in the home
country, overseas colonies, or other countries, so sometimes the interests of state
leaders and business capitalists may coincide in plans for imperialist expansion.
However, according to nationalism, ultimately politics determines economic
relations and organization. Nationalists stress national security and national
sentiment in international political and economic dynamics (Gilpin 1975, 31).

2. Japan Joins the Imperialist Club

Japan forcefully acquired three major foreign territories between 1894 and 1910:
Taiwan in 1895 after the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5; Korea as a protectorate in
1905 after the Russo-Japanese War of 1904-5, then as a colony when unilaterally
annexed by Japan in 1910; and the Kwantung Leased Territories in 1905 in southern
Manchuria when Japan succeeded to Russia's leases after the Russo-Japanese War.
This section of the essay summarizes briefly the imperialistic expansion of Japan
during the period and the actions of the world's imperialist powers that influenced
the course of Japan's actions.

Korea occupied a strategically important geographic position just to the west of the
southern part of Japan. For the two decades prior to the start of the Sino-Japanese
War of 1894-5, China and Japan quarreled over Korea's internal politics and Chinese
influence in the country's government. Japan went to war with China over proposed
administrative and financial reforms in Korea. As a result of the treaty after the
Japanese victory, China recognized Korea's independence. Japan also received a
large indemnity; acquired Taiwan and the Liaodong Peninsula in southern
Manchuria; and obtained several other concessions from China.

Soon after Japan and China signed the treaty to conclude the Sino-Japanese War, the
Western imperialist powers made the first of several moves that would influence
significantly Japan's ideas about future imperialistic expansion. Japan observed the
Western powers' intense rivalries and imperialistic acquisitions. Only six days after
signing the treaty, Germany, Russia, and France forced Japan to surrender its claims
on the Liaodong Peninsula, which became a bitter diplomatic defeat for Japan. In
1898, only three years later, Russia pushed into Manchuria and obtained a leasehold
from China for the same peninsula Japan had been forced to relinquish. During the
same year, the United States, which embarked on its overseas imperialistic
expansion about the same time as Japan, annexed Hawaii and the Philippines. From
1895 to 1900, the imperialist powers of France, Germany, Russia, and England
divided up China into spheres of influence, which included special railway and
mining concessions, leased territory, and promises from China that comparable
privileges would not be granted to other countries in a specified area.

Between 1900 and 1905, Japan became a full-fledged member in the club of
imperialist powers. In 1900, Japan showed its military prowess when 8,000 of its
troops joined 9,000 soldiers from the Western powers to fight side by side to defeat
the Boxer Rebellion in China. In 1902, Japan and Great Britain signed a mutual
defense alliance, a document that in effect recognized Japan as one of the world's
great powers. In 1904 and 1905, Japan and Russia went to war over their territorial
and political disputes in Korea and southern Manchuria. After the destruction of the
Russian fleet, Japan emerged from the Russo-Japanese War as one of the world's
great military and political powers. The Portsmouth Treaty to end the war gave
Japan control of Korea and the Kwantung Leased Territories. Japan stood as one of
the world's powers with a colonial empire of its own.

3. Explanations of Japan’s Early Imperialism

This section assesses the four theories of imperialism to determine whether they help
to explain Japanese imperialistic expansion between 1894 and 1910.

A. Hobson’s Theory

The core of Hobson’s theory is the existence of excess capital seeking profits
overseas. However, during this period Japan had no excess capital and had to
borrow large amounts from Britain and the United States to finance its rapid
industrial expansion and its wars with China and Russia. Japan's outstanding foreign
loan indebtedness grew steadily, starting from near zero in 1896, to 421 million yen
in 1904, and then to 1,970 million yen in 1913 (Lockwood 1954, 254-255). Foreign
holdings of government bonds comprised over 60% of Japan's national debt of 2,600
million yen in 1913 (256).

Hobson's theory does not hold up as an explanation for Japan's early imperialism
because of the relative unimportance of the financial transactions between the home
country and its colonies. Although imports from the colonies as a share of total
trade with other countries increased from 1.7% in 1894-1903 to 6.9% in 1904-1914
and exports to the colonies increased from 2.7% of total trade in 1894-1903 to 7.8%
in 1904-1913 (Cohen 1973, 62), the levels remained very low. Foreign trade made
up about one quarter of Japan's economic activity from 1904 to 1913 (Crawcour
1997, 78), so trade with the colonies accounted for less than 2% of Japan's total
economic activity during this period.
B. Lenin’s Theory

Lenin advocated a theory of monopoly capital where capitalists wanted to employ


surplus capital abroad to achieve higher profits than the domestic market. As
explained in the previous section, Japan had loans from foreign countries and a
relatively low level of economic activity with the colonies during the period of
Japan's first imperialistic acquisitions. Most of the funds from foreign debt went for
military expenditures, and only 3% of the funds went to development of Japan's
colonies (Lockwood 1954, 35).

Lenin considered the existence of large-scale firms with great economic power
(monopolists) and the merging of bank and industrial capital to be key
characteristics of imperialism. In Japan between 1894 and 1910, a handful of huge
privately-owned conglomerates called zaibatsu increased their economic power.
Although some of the zaibatsu such as Mitsui and Sumitomo had histories of more
than 200 years, they strengthened their economic position as the government,
starting in the early 1880s, sold to them several industrial plants and mines that
become very profitable. Each zaibatsu also owned a bank, but the five largest banks'
share of loans was only 17% of the total market by 1910 (Nakamura [1971] 1983,
207), so this low figure provides little support for Lenin's assertion of finance capital
monopolies being an essential feature of imperialism. Likewise, the economic
power of the zaibatsu companies from 1894 to 1910 did not approach anywhere near
their domination just prior to and during World War II. Although Japan had made
rapid progress in industrialization and modernization up to 1910, it could still be
considered a developing country. Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries accounted for
33% of economic output and 67% of employment in 1910. Manufacturing and
construction contributed only 23% to economic output, and over half of
manufacturing production came from cottage industries employing less than five
people. Manufacturing consisted mainly of food products and textiles at 34% each,
whereas heavy industry made up only 21% (21-23, 80).

In addition to surplus capital in search of higher profits overseas, Lenin stressed the
acquisition of raw materials as a major reason for capitalists to acquire colonies.
Very little evidence exists to support that Japan acquired its colonies between 1894
and 1910 for raw materials. Korea and Taiwan had no significant known mineral
resources except for a small amount of iron ore in Korea, so the only substantial
natural resources were agricultural products, mainly rice but also sugarcane in
Taiwan. Although Korea and Taiwan provided rice to Japan, especially in poor
harvest years, only 18% of Japan's annual rice imports came from these two colonies
from 1905 to 1910 (Duus 1984, 171). After acquiring Taiwan as a colony in 1895,
Japan encouraged the planting of sugarcane to supply domestic needs. However,
Taiwanese land devoted to sugarcane production from 1901 to 1910 was only 7% of
the amount of land devoted to rice (Beasley 1987, 150), and Japan imposed a high
tariff on sugar imports from countries other than Taiwan, so Japanese consumers
suffered from higher prices. The Kwantung Leased Territories had few natural
resources, but they did help serve as a foothold to facilitate the development and
extraction of Manchuria's natural resources (Ho 1984, 350).

Lenin's theory does not help explain Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1910 due to
the nonexistence of capital surpluses, the low level of economic activity with the
colonies, the lack of dominance of the zaibatsu, and the low levels of the colonies'
raw materials.

C. Schumpeter’s Theory

Schumpeter believed that imperialism represented the survival of older social


structures, such as a warrior class, within a capitalist economy. This theory seems to
partially explain the attitudes of Japan's leaders toward imperialistic expansion.
Japan had a feudalistic social structure with a warrior class (samurai) until the
downfall of the Shogunate in 1868 and the implementation of numerous reforms
over the next five years under the new Meiji government. Members of the former
military aristocracy took leadership positions in the new government, and the
military bent of some of these leaders became quickly evident, as they strongly
pressed for military action in the early 1870s to conquer Korea. A majority of the
country's leaders decided to postpone this military action to concentrate on
modernization and industrialization, but even the leaders who recommended not to
go to war did not necessarily oppose the action in theory, only that the timing should
wait until Japan became stronger industrially and militarily.

Although some authors contend that Japan's imperialistic spirit dated back to before
the beginning of the start of the Tokugawa Period in 1600, they provide little
evidence as to why such a militaristic attitude would remain entrenched in a people
living in a country where peace reigned for about two and half centuries under the
Tokugawa Shogunate (1600-1868). Boulding and Gleason (1972, 241-242) argue
that Japan's imperialistic expansion was a continuation from several centuries
before: "Even before 1600, . . . colonies were established in areas of Southeast Asia,
and in 1592 Korea was invaded in an extraordinary, but abortive, attempt to conquer
China. . . . But the Meiji government, once isolationism had been abandoned,
resumed the imperialistic practices of the earlier era." Lockwood (1954, 7) argues
that the coming of Westerners in the last half of the nineteenth century "revived and
intensified memories of European ambitions and predatory rivalries dating back to
the sixteenth century." Although some leaders in the Meiji Era tried to revive
memories of historical events for their own propaganda purposes, little evidence
exists that such militaristic attitudes and memories of Western aggression continued
in the Japanese people during a period of peace lasting over 200 years.

Schumpeter argued that capitalists have no economic incentives for imperialism, and
Hobson also considered that imperialism is not profitable for a nation due its huge
military and administrative costs. The evidence in Japan's case supports Schumpeter
and Hobson since the colonies did not provide profits for the country as a whole.
Lockwood (1954, 52) summarizes the effects of Japan's early imperialism:
But it is certain that colonial enterprise occupied a subordinate place in Japanese
economic development during the first three decades of the twentieth century. And
it is likely that whatever contributions were made to Japan's national income and
industrial development by political control over these areas were more than offset,
even at the time, by the costs of the military outlays, developmental subsidies, and
tariff preferences through which she acquired and developed her empire.

Duus (1984, 147) points out that business leaders during the period of Japan's early
imperialistic expansion had much more interest in China, with a "vast population,
size, and well-developed commercial economy" that "made its market larger, more
penetrable, and more easily exploited than those of Taiwan or Korea."

Schumpeter's theory provides some insights into the reasons for Japan's imperialism
from 1894 to 1910, but it fails to explain how Japan suddenly became an aggressive
conqueror of foreign territories after over two centuries of self-imposed peaceful
isolation.

D. Nationalism

The theory of nationalism provides the best explanations for Japan's imperialistic
actions between 1894 and 1905. The following points support nationalism as the
best theory to understand Japan's wars and colonial acquisitions: (1) Japan's deep
concerns for national security, (2) its emulation of the imperialistic behaviors of
Western powers, and (3) Japanese national ideals and personal characteristics.

The United States forcibly opened Japan to the outside world in 1853. Soon
thereafter, Japan was pressured by the imperialist powers to sign "unequal treaties,"
which granted foreigners in Japan extraterritoriality in legal cases and which
imposed on Japan low tariff rates for which the imperialist countries did not grant
corresponding concessions in their rates. The leaders of the Meiji government,
formed in 1868 after the downfall of the Tokugawa Shogunate, considered national
security and defense to be the top priority in order to prevent subjugation by the
Western powers. The nationalistic policy of fukoku kyōhei (rich country, strong
military) emphasized Japan's goals to develop the country economically to catch up
with the Western powers and to increase its military strength to ensure its existence
as an independent country. Japan fought the later wars against China and Russia in
1894-5 and 1904-5, respectively, to ensure that Korea would not be used by another
imperialist power to threaten Japan's security.

Japan emulated the imperialistic behaviors of the Western powers. From the
beginning of the Meiji Period in 1868, Japan's leaders sought to make the country an
industrial and military power on par with the Western imperialist powers. When
Japan emerged from its isolation and took steps to industrialize and modernize, the
international environment was one of intense competition between powers that tried
to maximize their political and economic positions relative to other powers and less
developed countries. Overseas colonies provided the imperialist powers with
prestige and status, so Japan's leaders naturally celebrated when its empire expanded
to include Taiwan, Korea, and the Kwantung Leased Territories.

The Western concept of Social Darwinism, with the ultimate domination of the
world by the strongest nations, fit well with belief of many Japanese that they were
the chosen people of Asia and a divinely favored race. Yukichi Fukuzawa, one of
Japan's educational leaders and founder of one of Japan's most influential
newspapers, expressed Japan's early imperialistic desires in 1882, "We shall
someday raise the national power of Japan so that not only shall we control the
natives of China and India as the English do today, but we shall also possess in our
hands the power to rebuke the English and to rule Asia ourselves" (Nester 1996, 63).
The Japanese people also had certain personal characteristics that supported the
country's rapid economic growth and imperialistic expansion. Allen (1981, 15)
explains, "Throughout their history they have shown a gift for rapidly assimilating
new ideas and practices, a boldness in executing large projects and, above all, a
trained and frequently exercised capacity for organization."

4. Conclusion

The theories of Hobson and Lenin provide little insight into the reasons for Japan's
imperialist expansion between 1894 and 1910 since the economic conditions they
considered to be the causes for imperialism did not exist in Japan at the time.
Schumpeter's theory of imperialism has some relevance to Japan's case, since the
leaders who promoted Japan's wars in the Meiji Period came from the former
samurai class. However, this theory does not fully explain Japan's imperialistic
actions since the samurai did not fight for over two centuries during the self-
imposed peaceful isolation of the Tokugawa Period.

Japan's concerns for national security, its emulation of Western powers in their
imperialistic expansion, and Japanese national ideals supporting overseas expansion
lead to the conclusion that nationalism provides the best explanation of Japan's
imperialistic expansion in comparison to the other three theories of imperialism.
Although the theory of nationalism sheds the most light on Japan's imperialism from
1894 to 1905, this does not mean that Japan's aggression and colonial expansion
represented the best course of action. Kōtoku Shūsui, a Socialist leader in Japan,
vividly described in 1901 imperialism's serious drawbacks (Iriye 1972, 75):

Imperialists in Japan and elsewhere are like drunken men, intoxicated by patriotism
and militarism, which are nothing but expressions of their animal instincts. They
bleed people white with taxes, expand armaments, divert productive capital for
unproductive ends, cause prices to rise, and invite excessive imports. These are all
for the sake of the state. Government, education, commerce, and industry are
sacrificed to patriotism, which is the root of militarism and imperialism.

Bibliography
Allen, G.C. 1981. A Short Economic History of Modern Japan. Fourth edition.
New York: St. Martin's Press.

Beasley, W.G. 1987. Japanese Imperialism 1894-1945. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Boulding, Kenneth E. and Alan H. Gleason. 1972. "War as an Investment: The


Strange Case of Japan." In Kenneth E. Boulding and Tapan Mukerjee, eds.,
Economic Imperialism: A Book of Readings, pp. 240-261. Ann Arbor: University
of Michigan Press.

Brown, Michael Barratt. 1974. The Economics of Imperialism. Harmondsworth:


Penguin Books.

Cohen, Benjamin J. 1973. The Question of Imperialism: The Political Economy of


Dominance and Dependence. New York: Basic Books.

Crawcour, E. Sydney. 1997. "Industrialization and technological change, 1885-


1920." In Kozo Yamamura, ed., The Economic Emergence of Modern Japan, pp.
50-115. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Duus, Peter. 1984. "Economic Dimensions of Meiji Imperialism: The Case of


Korea, 1895-1910." In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese
Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 128-171. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Gilpin, Robert. 1975. U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political
Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. New York: Basic Books.

Ho, Samuel Pao-San. 1984. "Colonialism and Development: Korea, Taiwan, and
Kwantung." In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese
Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 347-398. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Hobson, J.A. [1905] 1938. Imperialism: A Study. Reprint, with an introduction by


Philip Siegelman, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Howard, M.C. and J.E. King. 2000. "Whatever Happened to Imperialism?" In


Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of Imperialism: Critical Appraisals,
pp. 19-40. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

Iriye, Akira. 1972. Pacific Estrangement: Japanese and American Expansion,


1897-1911. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Lenin, V.I. [1917] 1939. Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. New
York: International Publishers.

Lockwood, William W. 1954. The Economic Development of Japan: Growth and


Structural Change, 1868-1938. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Mommsen, Wolfgang J. 1980. Theories of Imperialism. Translated by P.S. Falla.


New York: Random House.

Nakamura, Takafusa. [1971] 1983. Economic Growth in Prewar Japan. Translated


by Robert A. Feldman. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Nester, William R. 1996. Power across the Pacific: A Diplomatic History of


American Relations with Japan. New York: New York University Press.

Nowell, Gregory P. 2000. "Hobson's Imperialism: Its Historical Validity and


Contemporary Relevance." In Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of
Imperialism: Critical Appraisals, pp. 85-109. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman &
Littlefield Publishers.

Schumpeter, Joseph. [1919] 1951. "The Sociology of Imperialism." In Imperialism


and Social Classes, pp. 1-98. New York: Meridian Books.

Home | Top | Other Papers and Essays | About the Author

You might also like