You are on page 1of 12

JULY/AUGUST 1998

Donald S. Allen is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Thomas A. Pollmann provided research assistance.

How Closely Do ranged between 4 and 5 percent, possibly


reflecting higher public demand for curren-
Banks Manage cy or more conservative management by
banks as a result of the banking crises of
Vault Cash? the early 1930s and the Great Depression.
During the period from the mid-1940s to
the late 1950s, vault cash was typically
around 2.5 percent of demand deposits.
Donald S. Allen After 1959, decisions on how much
currency to hold in vaults became

B
eginning in 1959, Federal Reserve influenced by total reserve management
member banks were allowed to use decisions. Banks could choose the amount
both vault cash and deposits at Federal of their required reserves that they wanted
Reserve Banks to satisfy statutory reserve to be satisfied by currency in the vaults and
requirements. Prior to this time, member the amount they wanted to hold in their
banks were restricted to satisfying required accounts at the Fed. The opportunity costs
reserves solely with deposits at Federal were reduced for holding vault cash in
Reserve Banks. Hence, member banks excess of that required for customer demand
held currency in their vaults only to satisfy but less than required for reserves. Banks
daily demands by depositors. Fluctuations could hold more currency than they needed
in the levels of vault cash prior to 1959 for customer transactions if this currency
therefore can be assumed to reflect changes also satisfied a portion of required reserves.
in depositors’ demands for cash, or changes The result, as Figure 1 shows, was that
in the opportunity cost of vault cash (the vault cash as a percent of total demand
cost of holding versus the cost of running deposits increased steadily from 1959.1
out). Figure 1 shows the historical move- Depository institutions are currently
ment of vault cash as a percent of demand in an era of relatively low reserve require-
deposits at depository institutions from ments, yet bank vault cash holdings have
1930 to 1997. During the 1930s, vault been increasing—both in magnitude and
cash as a percent of demand deposits as a percent of net transaction deposits.

Varying Requirements for Nonmember Banks


The role of vault cash for nonmember banks and thrifts is more complex than that
for Federal Reserve member banks, as described in this article. Prior to the Monetary
1
Control Act of 1980, these institutions were subject to a wide range of state-imposed These data are for all depository
reserve requirements (see Gilbert and Lovati, 1978). In some states, no requirements institutions. Separating Federal
were imposed and vault cash presumably was held solely to meet customer needs. In Reserve member banks intro-
others, vault cash could be applied to satisfy required reserves. This system changed duces breaks in the data. We
can assume that the changes in
dramatically in November 1980, when all nonmember banks and thrifts that offer
member bank reserve manage-
transaction deposits became subject to the same reserve requirements as member ment methods contributed to
banks and could use vault cash to satisfy such requirements. The requirements for the increase. Other checkable
nonmember institutions were phased in over a seven-year period from 1980 to 1987. deposits that became significant
During this period, the vault cash behavior of nonmember institutions likely was gov- during the 1980s are included
erned by a complicated mixture of customer needs and statutory reserve requirements. as part of demand deposits for
this period.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

43
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Figure 1

Vault Cash as a Percent of Demand Deposits


All Depository Institutions, End of Year

5.5 8

5 7

4.5 6

4 5

3.5 4

3 3

2.5 2

2 1
1930 1936 1942 1948 1954 1960 1959 1967 1975 1983 1991
1933 1939 1945 1951 1957 1963 1971 1979 1987 1995

SOURCE: Friedman and Schwartz–A Monetary History of SOURCE: Federal Reserve Data
the United States, 1867-1960 (Demand Deposits plus Other Checkable Deposits)

In December 1990 and April 1992, reserve the Eighth District. The downward trend
requirements were reduced significantly. in reserves over the last three years,
In addition, starting in 1995, banks began accompanied by an upward trend in vault
“sweeping” customers’ cash reserves into cash, is obvious. By itself, the increase in
savings accounts that were not subject to vault cash does not imply a surplus. But,
reserve requirements, further reducing the as Figure 3 (taken from Anderson and
amounts designated as required reserves Rasche, 1996) shows, the quantity of “sur-
(and reported net transaction deposits). plus” vault cash (i.e., above that used to
Because of this reduction, the percentage meet reserve requirements) has increased
of required reserves satisfied by vault cash steadily. This rise in surplus vault cash, in
has increased steadily. At the same time, conjunction with the increase in nonbound
the number of “bound banks,” or banks banks, suggests that vault cash levels are
whose required reserves are not satisfied not managed very closely or are constrained
completely by vault cash, has decreased. by precautionary balances to serve customer
As shown in Table 1, the number of needs, rather than statutory reserve
bound small banks in the Eighth Federal requirements.
Reserve District decreased from 27 percent This article looks at daily vault cash
in 1993 to 20 percent in 1996; the number holdings in the Eighth District (headquar-
of bound medium banks decreased from tered in St. Louis) to determine whether
74 percent in 1993 to 51 percent in 1996; the observed amounts of vault cash held by
and the number of bound large banks banks are consistent with the fundamental
decreased from 100 percent in 1993 to 72 assumptions of a one-sided (S,s) inventory
2 An (S,s) inventory decision rule
percent in 1996. In addition, the amount decision rule, a well-known model of
establishes an upper limit, S, of total reserve requirements satisfied optimal firm inventory management.2
and a lower limit, s, on inventory. entirely by vault cash increased from 54 It also reviews how the limits implied by
When stocks fall below s, percent in 1993 to 75 percent in 1996. the (S,s) model change as a function of
inventories are replenished to Figure 2 shows total required reserves the mean and variance of demand and the
the upper limit. and the total vault cash held by banks in opportunity cost of maintaining inventories.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

44
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Table 1
A Closer Look at the Percent of Banks with Required Reserves
Reserve Requirements Satisfied by Vault Cash
Picture
Bank Size 1993 1994 1995 1996
As of 1992, the required reserve Small 73 73 79 80
margins established by the Federal Medium 26 33 43 49
Reserve for depository institutions were
Large 0 5 19 28
3 percent of net transaction deposits up
to $49.3 million and 10 percent on net Total Reserve Requirement
transaction deposits above $49.3 mil- Satisfied by Vault Cash 54% 57% 62% 75%
lion. The rate on the second tranche
was reduced from 12 percent to 10 per-
cent in April 1992, and the size of the Figure 2
first tranche was reduced from $52.0
million to $49.3 million in January Total Required Reserves
1997. Larger depository institutions vs. Total Vault Cash
have either a weekly or biweekly Eighth Federal Reserve District (Bi-Weekly, January 1989 - December 1996)
reserve account maintenance period, Billions of Dollars Billions of Dollars
beginning on a Thursday and ending on 2.4 1.8
a Wednesday, and reserve requirements
are on a contemporaneous basis. The 2.2 1.6
typical reserve requirement therefore Total Required Reserves
depends on the size of the bank. The 2
1.4
reserve requirement in the Eighth Dis-
trict averages to about 8 percent of 1.8
1.2
transaction deposits, with smaller Total Vault Cash
1.6
banks averaging around 3 percent and
1
larger banks averaging more than 8 per-
1.4
cent. Reserves are held as vault cash or 09 Jan 89 07 Jan 91 04 Jan 93 02 Jan 95 30 Dec 96
deposits at the Federal Reserve Bank. 08 Jan 90 06 Jan 92 03 Jan 94 01 Jan 96
Deposits at the Federal Reserve that are
not used to satisfy reserve requirements
may be used to satisfy clearing balances Figure 3
and are available for overnight loans to
other institutions.
Surplus Vault Cash
Billions of Dollars
8
The rest of the paper is organized as November 1980,
follows: The first section following the 7
Monetary Control Act
overview looks at why banks hold vault 6
cash and what parameters affect how 5
much they hold. The next section reviews 4 Phase-in of applied vault
the vault cash data for the Eighth District cash at member banks
3
to determine how recent developments in
2
reserve requirements have affected vault
1
cash levels. The following section provides
a review of the theoretical motivation for 0
1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995
(S,s) inventory behavior, and simulations 1962 1968 1974 1980 1986 1992
are performed to provide insight into
whether banks are managing vault cash

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

45
JULY/AUGUST 1998

conservatively. The final section offers inflow of currency, whereas a bank that
some tentative conclusions. primarily serves individual customers may
receive the bulk of its deposits in the form
of checks and thus experience a net outflow
WHY DO BANKS HOLD of currency. If the bank experiences a net
VAULT CASH? inflow of currency, which may be the case
Banks maintain an inventory of if its customers are primarily commercial
currency in vaults primarily to meet the enterprises, the bank may identify an
daily currency demands of depositors, either upper limit of vault cash that will induce it
at the teller window or in automated teller to send currency back to the Fed to credit
machines (ATMs). If banks knew with to its account. If a bank experiences a net
certainty the daily flows of currency from currency withdrawal each day, then a large
deposits and withdrawals, the amount of shipment may be received each time the
vault cash required could be determined level falls below the trigger, boosting the
precisely. In addition, if there were no costs level of vault cash. This level is drawn
associated with the shipment of currency, down over a period of time (days) until
banks could reduce their holdings of vault the lower level is reached and another
currency and increase the frequency of cur- shipment is received, again boosting vault
rency shipments. However, the relative cash levels. Both types will lead to a saw-
randomness of currency flows and the fixed tooth pattern of vault cash levels. In one
cost of obtaining currency shipments induce case, vault cash will rise slowly and fall
banks to hold higher levels of vault cash. A quickly; in the other, vault cash will rise
bank’s incentive to minimize vault cash quickly and fall gradually.
holdings is reduced further when such cash Figures 4, 5, and 6 show this typical
also counts as part of required reserves. pattern for a small, medium, and large
Uncertainty in the daily flow of bank in the Eighth District over a period
currency dictates that banks hold some in 1992. The small bank’s vault cash rises
average level of vault currency to cover the on Mondays, possibly from shipments of
probability of “stocking out” of cash. The currency from the Fed or from an influx of
fixed costs associated with currency ship- commercial deposits from weekend sales.
ments make it cost effective to achieve The end-of-day vault balance tends to fall
this average vault cash level by infrequent during the week, with Fridays showing the
shipments of larger amounts of currency. biggest decrease. The medium bank also
Thus, banks identify some trigger level has an increase in vault currency on Mon-
below which vault cash will be replenished days, but on average there are net increases
and either a maximum level to which vault during the week and again a net drop on
cash will be replenished or an economic Fridays. The large bank shows an increase
batch amount, which is considered an on Mondays, with a large drop on Fridays.
optimum shipment amount. This situation The similar patterns on Fridays may reflect
leads to a decision rule referred to in the payroll withdrawals.
inventory management literature as (S,s) As we have said, vault cash also counts
behavior, where S is the upper limit of toward reserve requirements. The Federal
vault cash, and s is the lower limit or Reserve does not pay interest on required
replenishment signal. Both the upper and reserves, but banks are able to earn credits
lower limits will depend on the intraday against other services on a portion of the
profile of withdrawals and deposits, as well deposits at Federal Reserve Banks. If a
as the cost associated with shipments and bank has a clearing balance contract, there
the opportunity costs of stocking out. is also an incentive to maintain surplus
The intraday demand profile is a func- reserves in accounts at the Fed to reduce
tion of the types of customers the bank potential overdrafts. In addition, lagged
serves. For example, a bank that primarily vault cash is used to satisfy reserve
serves retail firms may see a net daily requirements, so that lower vault cash in

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

46
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Figures 4-6

End-of-Day Vault Cash (May 1992)


Small Bank
Millions
0.8

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3
May 4 May 11 May 18 May 25

Medium Bank
Millions
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
1.6
1.4
May 4 May 11 May 18 May 25

Large Bank
Millions
28
26
24
22
20
18
16
14
May 4 May 11 May 18 May 25

BANK VAULT CASH


the current period can be used to hedge BALANCES
against unexpected changes in Fed
account balances. So there is some trade- The end-of-day vault cash balances at
off between reserves held at the Fed or all banks in the Eighth District from 1989
vault cash. But when banks are bound, to 1996 were analyzed to determine the
there is room for more conservative vault average minimum levels and replenishment
cash management than would otherwise points targeted by the banks. Figure 7
occur. This seems to be the case in the shows the average number of days
Eighth District. between replenishment of vault cash for

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

47
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Figure 7 of these levels for individual banks and for


the aggregate of all banks.3 As expected,
the volatility of total vault cash balances as
Mean Days Between Vault Cash
a percentage of net transaction deposits is
Replenishment
Days
significantly less than for the average bank.
4.0
So, whereas the frequent trips for currency
lead to high volatility for individual banks,
3.8
Small negative correlation among banks smooths
3.6 out the volatility in the aggregate. This
3.4 pattern suggests that interbank currency
transfers can reduce the role of the Federal
3.2
Reserve in providing currency.
3.0 Figures 8, 9, and 10 show the average
2.8 upper and lower levels of vault cash as a
Large Medium percentage of net transaction deposits
2.6
1989 Q1 1991 Q1 1993 Q1 1995 Q1 1997 Q1
(NTD) over the period from 1989 to 1997.
Observing the upper and lower bounds of
the average vault cash balances, one can
conclude that larger banks appear to have
Table 2 an average minimum balance of 4.4 percent
of NTD and an average maximum of
Mean Ratio of Vault Cash to Net around 5.1 percent of NTD. A decline in
Transaction Deposits
1997 followed a noticeable rise in the two
1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 prior years. Medium banks, on average,
Individual Banks hold peak vault cash balances of around
Mean 4.98 4.84 4.51 4.17 3.92 4.02 4.38 4.90 4.94* 4.5 percent of NTD and have minimum
Variance 2.35 2.79 1.03 1.26 0.64 1.31 1.42 1.74 1.23* triggers of around 3.7 percent. Small banks
Aggregate
fall in the lower 3 percent tranche of reserve
Mean 4.68 4.72 4.51 4.02 3.84 4.03 4.50 5.44 6.22* requirements but appear to be slightly
more conservative than medium banks,
Variance 0.12 0.13 0.11 0.10 0.07 0.10 0.11 0.24 0.44*
holding vault cash balances between 4.0
*1997 figures exclude small banks in the third and fourth quarters. During the last two
percent and 4.9 percent of NTD. This differ-
quarters of 1997, it appears that small banks increased reclassifications, thereby lowering ence would suggest that most small banks
net transaction deposits significantly. are nonbound most of the time. These
vault cash band widths confirm the aggre-
small, medium, and large banks in the gate results of Table 1. The increase in the
Eighth District. As the figure shows, the ratio of vault currency as a percentage of
typical number of days between replenish- NTD in large banks may also reflect the
ment remains relatively constant, at reduction in NTD due to sweeps, rather
3
approximately three. Small banks show a than an increase in the levels of vault cash
The term “net transaction
deposits” refers to those
decline in the days between replenishment being stored. Whether the accounts that
deposits subject to statutory since the start of the period, suggesting a have been moved to sweeps should be still
reserve requirements. possible decrease in the relative fixed cost considered transaction deposits in deciding
4
of shipments. the amount of vault cash needed is a sepa-
The vault cash figures shown Replenishment every three days would rate issue.
here are average end-of-day fig-
indicate a relatively volatile movement in To evaluate whether these levels are
ures. They do not give a good
view of the fluctuations during
vault cash balances (as with [S,s] inventory conservative, we need to know the distrib-
the day. For example, large management). This volatility is lowered in ution of intraday demands for withdrawals
deposits from commercial cus- the aggregate because of offsetting patterns and deposits, the transaction costs of new
tomers in the evening may at different banks. Table 2 shows the shipments of currency, and the penalty that
mask the actual minimum level mean vault cash level as a percentage of the cash manager assigns to stocking out
that has occurred. net transaction deposits and the variance of cash.4 The (S,s) model of inventory was

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

48
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Figures 8-10

Average High and Low Vault Cash Levels


Percent of Net Transaction Deposits

Small Banks
8

6
High
4
Low
2

0
1989 Q1 1990 Q1 1991 Q1 1992 Q1 1993 Q1 1994 Q1 1995 Q1 1996 Q1 1997 Q1

Medium Banks
8

6
High
4
Low
2

0
1989 Q1 1990 Q1 1991 Q1 1992 Q1 1993 Q1 1994 Q1 1995 Q1 1996 Q1 1997 Q1

Large Banks
8

6
High
4
Low

2
1989 Q1 1990 Q1 1991 Q1 1992 Q1 1993 Q1 1994 Q1 1995 Q1 1996 Q1 1997 Q1

formalized by Scarf (1960).5 One way of


ARE BANKS MANAGING
testing the optimality of the observed levels VAULT CASH CONSERVA-
of vault cash holding is to choose parame- TIVELY?
ters for Scarf’s model that suggest a band The optimization of vault cash must
width (upper and lower limits) equivalent trade off the cost of “stocking out” of cash
to the observed vault cash limits. The next against the opportunity cost of trading in
section reviews the theoretical derivation the overnight markets relative to bank cash
of the (S,s) parameters and suggests choices managers’ level of risk aversion. The
of parameters to test whether banks are problem belongs to the class of inventory 5 See Ross (1970) for an
conservative in managing vault cash. decisions. More specifically, if there are exposition.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

49
JULY/AUGUST 1998

fixed costs associated with obtaining term, and the coefficient on the quadratic
currency from the Fed (for example, trans- term of the cost equation, respectively.
portation costs), and there are zero marginal Note that h(.) is a highly nonlinear and
costs of purchasing currency, an (S,s) inven- discontinuous function. The important
tory rule for vault cash management may be parameters are the relative markup between
optimal. That is, banks may establish a min- price and marginal cost (which determines
imum vault cash level, s, below which they the benefit of adjusting) and the probability
will replenish, and a target level, S, to which distribution of demand (which determines
they will raise vault cash. When vault cash the relative cost of storage).
lies between these two levels, no action is Because the (S,s) model is nonlinear, it
taken. Although these target levels will vary is difficult to measure the effects of changes
with the probability distribution of customer in parameters on the desired level of stock
transactions and the opportunity cost of by observing contemporaneous changes.
holding cash, changes in these levels may be In other words, a change in (S,s) may or
sticky. This inherent nonlinearity of (S,s) may not result in a contemporaneous
management can lead to difficulty in identi- change in inventory level, depending on
fying interest elasticities. the initial location of the firm’s inventories
The optimality of (S,s) inventory within the band. For instance, if S were to
behavior hinges on the existence of rise as a result of a decrease in interest
nontrivial fixed adjustment costs associated rates but there were sufficient inventory to
with purchases (or production). In the delay replenishment, no concurrent move
one-period case, assuming rt is the cost of would be observed in inventory levels; in
storage and pt is the price of the product, fact, inventory would fall. If firms needed
we can determine the penalty cost of to replenish at the same time that the
stocking out and the cost of having desired upper bound increased, inventories
inventory I*t at the beginning of period t, would rise above normal. Interest rate
assuming that orders are filled instanta- elasticities computed under the two
neously. We assume that the firm observes different initial conditions would be
the inventory level at the end of the previous underestimated in one instance and
period and then decides the level of inven- overestimated in the other.
tory to hold for this period. Put another The upper bound, S, increases with
way, the firm makes a decision on the (1) an increase in mean demand, (2) an
appropriate level of inventory for period t, increase in the variance of demand, (3) a
given the level of inventory at the end of decrease in the cost of storage (r), or (4)
the previous period, the expected cost of an increase in the markup over marginal
storage, and the expected cost of stocking cost (p-a1).
out. See the shaded insert for a formal Similarly, the lower bound, s,
derivation of the limits (S,s), which decreases with (1) an increase in the
appears on page 51. “quasi-fixed” cost (a0), (2) an increase in
The determinants of the band width the cost of storage (r), (3) an increase in
(S,s) for inventory are (1) the distribution the marginal cost, (4) a decrease in the
of demand (represented by the mean, m, price (p), (5) a decrease in the mean
and the standard deviation, s), (2) the price demand, or (6) an increase in the variance
6
of the product, p, (3) the cost of storage, r, of demand.
Poole (1968) applies a similar and (4) the “shape” of the cost curve (or,
inventory model to reserve
more directly, the shape of the marginal cost
management. Here, the focus
curve). The interval can be expressed as a Adaptation to Vault Currency
is primarily on currency held
in vaults, rather than total function, h(.), of these parameters: To apply the Scarf inventory model to
reserve management. Orr and vault currency management, we need to
[S, s] = h( µ , σ , p,r, a 0 , a1 , a 2), make some modifications.6 In particular,
Mellon (1961) also used this
method to analyze expansion where a0, a1, and a2 are the constant term the “cost” associated with obtaining
of bank credit. (fixed cost), the coefficient on the linear currency is limited to the “quasi-fixed”

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

50
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Derivation of the (S, s) Inventory Rule


If demand is a random variable with known probability distribution g(D), and we
have an initial inventory level of It-1 at the end of period t-1, then we can formulate the
sum of the expected penalty and holding cost of purchasing sufficient quantity to have
an inventory level of I*t at the beginning of period t as L(I*t )
∞ I *t
(1) L ( ) = p ∫ (ξ )g(ξ )dξ + r ∫ (I - ξ )g(ξ )dξ.
I*t t
- I*t t
*
t
I *t 0

The first term represents the expected lost revenue from stocking out, when
demand exceeds inventories; it is a decreasing function of the inventory level. The sec-
ond term reflects the cost of storage, or the unit storage cost times the expected excess
of inventory over demand; it is an increasing function of inventory level. L(I*t ) is U-
shaped or V-shaped, reflecting the sum of the downward-sloping expected cost of
stocking out and the upward-sloping cost of holding inventory.
Assuming linear costs of ordering,1 if we order Qt= I*t – It–1, then the total costs (of
ordering, stockout, and inventory) can be expressed as follows:

(2) f (Qt ) + L ( ) I*t



= 
t ( t ) ( )
 a0 + a1 I* - I t -1 + L I* , if I* > I t -1
t
.
 L( I t -1 ) if I*t = I t -1
Scarf (1960) shows that if we define S as the value of I*t that minimizes a1I*t + L(I*t )
and s as the value I*t that makes

(3) a1 s + L(s) = a0 + a1 S + L(S),

then it can be shown that the optimal policy is

(4)  if I t-1 ≥ s, do not order and



 if I t-1 < s, order up to S.
We can further determine S from the following result:
p - a1
(5) G(S) = ,
p + rt

where G(S) is the cumulative distribution of the demand. Using the definition in Equa-
tion 3, we can then obtain the value of s.
1 i.e., f(Qt ) = a0 + a 1 Qt

costs (transportation and administrative) it also involves lost customer confidence 7 The Fed has instituted limits
associated with each trip to the Federal and future implications. This variable may on the number of free currency
Reserve Bank, correspondent bank, or be as much subjective as it is real. Since shipments allowed by member
other source of currency shipments.7 The cash flow will be in both directions banks. This limit would need
“cost” of stocking out of currency is not (in contrast to the monotonic decrease of to be factored into the assumed
simply the lost revenue from a transaction, inventory), the distribution of demand for cost of currency.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

51
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Table 3 exceeds the quasi-fixed cost. A choice of


S as the mean daily cash demand would
Sample Parameters for Equation 6
most likely result in at least a daily replen-
Case Mean (m) S.D.(s) p r a0 a1 S s
ishment of vault cash. If the fixed
(transportation) cost were small enough,
1 0.27 3 0.1 0.02 0.0025 0 4.31 3.48 the trigger would be relatively close to the
2 0.27 3 0.05 0.02 0.0025 0 3.34 2.43 maximum and would imply replenishment
3 0.27 3 0.05 0.02 0.002 0 3.34 2.52 more than once throughout the day.
4 0.27 3 0.02 0.02 0.002 0 2.13 1.20 The penalty for running out of vault
5 1.0 3 0.02 0.02 0.002 0 2.44 1.54 cash is difficult to define. If a bank can
6 0.3 5 0.10 0.02 0.0025 0 7.09 6.00 defer demand for large amounts of cash, then
7 0.3 2 10 0.02 0.0025 0 6.41 5.96 outliers can be eliminated from the assumed
8 0.3 2 5 0.02 0.0025 0 5.99 5.51 distribution of demand. Similarly, if cash
9 0.3 2 1 0.02 0.0025 0 4.88 4.36
can be obtained from the Federal Reserve or
other banks on relatively short notice, then
a smaller upper bound (S) and a narrow
band width can be accommodated easily.
vault cash is the joint distribution of
demand for withdrawals of currency and
the supply of currency deposits. Calibrated Cases
As an upper bound, we can assume The key to determining whether banks
that the cost of stocking out exceeds the are conservatively managing vault cash is
storage cost by a factor of 10. From Equa- by knowing the probability distribution of
tion 5 it can be shown that the maximum the intraday deposits and withdrawals. A
(threshold) of vault cash, S, is determined good model of the costs associated with
by the value that equates G(S) to p/p+r. stocking out is also required. Unfortunately,
Thus if p is 10 times r, this fraction we have neither of these. The model above
becomes 10/10+1, which is around 0.91. can be calibrated with specific choices for
This result suggests that the maximum the coefficients to give the average lower
level of vault cash should be about two and upper bounds, shown in figures 8-10.
standard deviations above the average Table 3 shows nine cases with assumed
daily demand for currency. The lower parameter values for Equation 6 and the
limit, or trigger point, is a function of the resulting upper and lower bounds. For
quasi-fixed transaction cost—in this case, Case 1, the parameters are chosen to give
primarily transportation costs. If the upper and lower limits equivalent to the
penalty portion of the cost curve (i.e., the 1993 second-quarter averages for the upper
expected cost of running out of cash) is and lower limits for small banks, shown in
steep, then the minimum will be close to Figure 8. These parameters are consistent
the maximum. In this situation, we would with the observed average of three days
expect banks to frequently replenish vault between replenishment. The mean demand
cash to their maximum levels. was chosen to produce replenishment
As a lower bound, if we assume that every three days when the separation of S
the cost of stocking out is equal to the cost and s is 0.81 percent of NTD. The cost of
of storage (foregone interest), then the maintaining vault balances was assumed to
penalty function is symmetric and G(S) = be approximately the overnight rate of bor-
r/(r+r), or 0.5. This result suggests that the rowing. The penalty cost, p, and standard
maximum vault cash level would be the deviation, s, were chosen to fix the upper
mean daily demand for vault cash. Again, limit at 4.31 percent of NTD, and the fixed
the minimum level s would depend on the cost, a0, was chosen to fix the lower limit
“quasi-fixed” cost, or transportation cost, at 3.48. The standard deviation chosen is
in such a way that replenishment takes large, compared with the mean value of
place when the expected cost of a shortfall demand, and suggests a great deal of

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

52
JULY/AUGUST 1998

uncertainty in the withdrawal/ deposit out would have to be very high to justify
rates. By way of comparison, Table 2 the levels of vault cash balances. When
shows a standard deviation of 1.67 of the banks are bound, there is less incentive
mean vault cash holdings of all Eighth Dis- to optimize currency holdings. Because
trict banks in 1990. This is obviously not the reserve requirement levels have fallen
the same as the standard deviation of daily as a result of the rate reduction and the
demand, but it represents the fluctuation implementation of “sweeps,” nonbound
around mean vault cash levels for all banks. banks have had more incentive to reduce
Cases 2 through 6 show the changes to surplus vault cash. Some banks have begun
the (S,s) interval as the other parameters to use consultants to implement vault cash
are changed. Case 2 shows the effect of management strategies. As this practice
reducing the penalty cost of running out of becomes more prevalent, currency operations
currency by one-half, from five times the at Federal Reserve Banks could see a tem-
opportunity cost of holding extra vault porary net inflow of currency and possibly
cash. The upper bound, S, falls by 1 more frequent shipments. There may also
percent of NTD to 3.34 percent of NTD. be an increase in the noise in the measure-
In Case 3, the fixed cost associated with ment of monetary aggregates and a rise in
currency shipments is lowered, making the elasticity of bank reserves to interest rate
more frequent trips economical. This changes. The implications for safety and
raises the trigger point, s, for replenishment. soundness of depository institutions are
Case 4 shows the impact of assuming sym- not immediately clear, but are not expected
metric costs of storage and stocking out. to be large. It would appear that if banks
This situation reduces the upper and lower maintain less buffer stock holdings of currency,
bounds. Increasing the mean demand, as then they may be more sensitive to increased
in Case 5, raises the upper and lower demand for currency. However, innovations
bounds. Case 6 shows that raising the in the payments system are likely to reduce
standard deviation of demand from three the demand for currency in the future.
to five, compared with Case 1, increases In summary, the degree to which banks
the band width to the level shown for large optimize their vault currency holdings has
banks in Figure 10. Case 7 shows the implications for the Fed’s currency manage-
minimum and maximum vault cash levels ment, monetary policy effectiveness, and
that would occur if a “more reasonable” the safety and soundness of financial insti-
standard deviation of demand were used, tutions. For these reasons, vault currency
but a very high penalty factor—equivalent management should be monitored. Initial
to 500 times the cost of storage—were indications are that depository institutions
applied to running short of cash. In this have begun to pay closer attention to vault
case, the minimum and maximum are in cash needs; the impact of this new aware-
the same order as those recorded in Figure ness may be minimal but should be
10. Cases 8 and 9 show the reductions in assessed, nonetheless.
minimum and maximum vault cash levels
that would occur if the penalty assigned to
running out were lowered to 250 times
and 50 times the storage rate, respectively. REFERENCES
Anderson, Richard G., and Robert H. Rasche. “Measuring the Adjusted
POLICY IMPLICATIONS Monetary Base in an Era of Financial Change,” this Review (Novem-
ber/December 1996), pp. 3-37.
The data through 1997 appear to sup-
port the idea that banks have not been Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. “A Monetary History of
managing vault cash holdings very closely. the United States 1867-1960,” Princeton University Press, 1963.
Within the context of an (S,s) inventory Gilbert, R. Alton, and Jean M. Lovati. “Bank Reserve Requirements
model, the variance of net withdrawals and Their Enforcement: A Comparison Across States,” this Review
and/or the penalty associated with running (March 1978), pp. 22-31.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

53
JULY/AUGUST 1998

Poole, William. “Commercial Bank Reserve Management in a Stochastic


Model: Implications for Monetary Policy,” Journal of Finance (Decem-
ber 1968), pp. 769-91.
“Open Market Operations During 1996,” Federal Reserve Bulletin
(July 1997), pp. 565-74.
Orr, Daniel, and W. G. Mellon. “Stochastic Reserve Losses and Expan-
sion of Bank Credit,” American Economic Review
(September 1961), pp. 614-23.
Ross, Sheldon M. Applied Probability Models with Optimization
Applications, Dover, 1970.
Scarf, Herbert E. “The Optimality of (s,S) Policies for the Dynamic
Inventory Problem,” Proceedings of the First Stanford Symposium on
Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences, Stanford University
Press, 1960.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T. L O U I S

54

You might also like