You are on page 1of 13

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp.

415–427, 2007
Crown Copyright Ó 2007 Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
0263-2373 $32.00
doi:10.1016/j.emj.2007.08.001

A Framework for
Understanding
Institutional
Governance Systems
and Climate Change:
The Case of Australia
ANDREW GRIFFITHS, UQ Business School, Australia
NARDIA HAIGH, UQ Business School, Australia
JENINE RASSIAS, UQ Business School, Australia

In this paper it is proposed that different institu- Introduction


tional governance systems bring different climate
change outcomes for nations. Furthermore, it is
The need to address climate change issues has become
argued that these institutional governance systems
more pressing as mounting evidence from the scien-
impact on the ability of public policies, industries
tific community demonstrates the affect of anthropo-
and corporations to adopt and transform their activ-
genic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions on climate
ities to meet issues associated with climate change.
change (Houghton et al., 2001; Khandekar et al.,
We propose that there is a relationship between dif-
2005). This scientific imperative is reflected in emerg-
ferent governance systems and climate change out-
ing literature in the management and public policy
comes in terms of the institutional framework,
fields which outlines the need for corporations to
policies developed, capabilities developed to inno-
respond and adapt to issues relating to climate change
vate and speed of adaptation. The case of the Aus-
(Hoffman, 2005; Kolk and Pinkse, 2005). Commenta-
tralian approach to climate change is used to
tors have argued that climate change, or ‘‘. . .any
highlight the responses that occur in political and
change in climate over time, whether due to natural
institutional environments characterised by a plu-
variability or as a result of human activity. . .’’
rality of actors and the difficulties associated with
(Houghton et al., 2001, p. 984), has become a critical
developing a coherent national response.
matter for business and economic systems (Waller-
Crown Copyright Ó 2007 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
Hunter, 2004). In addition to climate change brought
All rights reserved.
about by Earth’s geographic dynamics, such as
changes in weather patterns (Fairbridge, 1969) which
Keywords: Institutional governance systems, Sus-
itself has displaced or destroyed entire civilizations
tainability, Climate change, Australia
(Schwartz, 1957), we now face increasingly frequent
and severe weather associated with GHG emissions
(Khandekar et al., 2005; Raddatz, 2003). This has
resulted in the pressing need for national govern-
ments to act to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions.

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 415
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

Despite the overwhelming need to respond to cli- formation of national industries and firms - the stra-
mate change issues, significant variations in how tegic management and political economy literatures
nations and industries respond are apparent. For (Biggart and Guillen, 1999). The strategic manage-
instance, Denmark and Germany have responded ment perspective is largely firm-centric while the
differently to the challenges of climate change and political economy literature is primarily state-centric
greenhouse gas reductions compared to Australia in orientation.
and the United States (Hoffman, 2005; Kolk and
Pinkse, 2005). In other words countries that have The strategic management literature’s view of the
signed and committed to the Kyoto Protocol have fol- generation of competitive advantage and industry
lowed a different range of strategies at a national transformation is labelled as firm-centric because it
level to those that have not. These national commit- focuses on the relative influence of industry structure
ments have created an environment where dialogue and firm characteristics as drivers of firm perfor-
and need for action are then translated into distinct mance (Barney, 1991; Chandler, 1966; Porter, 1980,
sectoral and corporate strategies. In the case of the 1985, 1990). For the most part the explanation for
US and Australia – where national institutional competitive outcomes focuses on firm resources,
arrangements have encouraged the pursuit of status capabilities and strategies (Oliver, 1997; Schoemaker
quo, this has meant that actions on climate change and Amit, 1993) or on meso-level industry character-
and greenhouse gas reductions have been left to vol- istics and structures (McGahan and Porter, 1997).
untary initiatives by business in the context of dis- The management literature in general ignores the
putes between a plurality of parties and differing state as a variable for explaining variations in firm
industry and environmental stakeholders. This paper and industry performance. This is despite a range
seeks to understand how it is that different national of studies that suggest that country conditions and
institutions shape and influence approaches to characteristics are important determinants of firm
addressing the issue of climate change? This paper performance (Christmann et al., 1999; Thomas and
therefore proposes that differences in institutional Waring, 1999) and that state and social institutions
governance systems impact on, shape and are can impact on business group formation and eco-
shaped by corporations and industry responses to nomic outcomes (Biggart and Guillen, 1999; Rao
climate change. An institutional governance system and Singh, 2001).
is defined as the configuration of state and private
organizations and institutional arrangements that The state-centric political economy literature argues
impact on and create the mechanisms by which eco- that national governments and institutions play an
nomic and social outcomes within nations are pro- important role in fostering the competitive capabili-
duced (Griffiths and Zammuto, 2005). Furthermore ties of industries and firms (Mathews and Cho,
it is argued that these variations can not be totally 2000; Nelson and Winter, 1982; North, 1990; Skocpol,
explained by factors at a firm level or industry level 1985). Studies from this tradition are concerned with
(Hoffman, 1999). This paper contributes to a growing explaining rapid industrialisation in east Asia, partic-
literature that examines corporate strategies for ularly Japan, Korea and Taiwan, and with isolating
achieving greenhouse gas reductions but goes fur- the state capacities and institutional configurations
ther by examining the link between climate change that support such rapid economic development
response and the institutional environment. It also (Evans, 1995; Mathews, 2002). In contrast to strategic
provides insights into the role that institutional gov- management research, these studies suggest national
ernance systems play in transforming these activities governments play an active role in generating the
in response to climate change by using the case of the institutional governance systems that support and
Australian approach to greenhouse gas reduction encourage national competitive advantage (Streeck,
and emission trading. 1991) through mechanisms of coordinated adjust-
ment (Amsden, 2001; Best, 2001). Recent research
also suggests that when it comes to climate change
that national differences emerge due to structural
characteristics of economies and industries and the
Industrial Competitiveness and Climate
national policy positions adopted that link climate
Change Response change with economic development (Griffiths and
Winn, 2005).
The paper builds on a conceptual framework that
synthesises a large and diverse body of literature These two literatures are generally treated as
explaining differences in the roles of various institu- competing explanations of the ability of firms and
tional governance systems in the process of industry industries to transform activities in response to com-
transformation (Griffiths and Zammuto, 2005). The petitive pressures. The strategic management litera-
framework primarily sought to explain variations ture embodies the ideals of free enterprise – that
in national competitiveness outcomes. In this paper the most competitive economies result with minimal
the framework is extended to examine variations in state intervention; with climate change being pur-
climate change approaches. There are two major sued as a consequence of individual corporate strat-
bodies of theory and research focusing on the trans- egies – voluntarism (Hoffman, 2005). In contrast, the

416 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

political economy literature argues that managed ties and decision making and by market forces on the
economies can result in the best competitive out- other. The resulting quadrants define four institu-
comes, with climate change adaptation and mitiga- tional governance systems, which it is argued in this
tion being the result of institutional intervention paper, characterise patterns of industry engagement
such as regulation. with climate change activities. The characteristics of
each quadrant are described below. Table 1 provides
This paper ventures to treat these perspectives as a summary.
parallel and complimentary explanations of how
decision making around climate change should be Market Governance: Market governance systems are
managed and to explore how these then shape gover- characterised by fragmented value chains and a
nance systems approaches to mitigation and reduc- low level of state involvement in industry decision
tion of greenhouse gases. In this context, the making. Under this institutional governance system,
strategic management literature indicates that the market forces are used to achieve adaptation (Best,
economic coordination of activities and decision 2001; Streeck, 1991). Consequently, resources are dis-
making occurs either through market forces or tributed to those firms and industries that are most
through value chain integration. Therefore decisions profitable (Porter, 1990), and competition between
regarding climate change and sustainability issues groups and domestic rivalry leads to innovation-
more generally are left to a) a minimum compliance based outcomes (McGahan and Porter, 1997). In
position; b) capabilities and activities associated with other words, the use of market forces encourages
individual firm choice and c) voluntary initiatives firms to develop the appropriate capabilities associ-
(Hoffman, 2005). By contrast, the political economy ated with capitalising on resource access and factor
literature suggests that economic coordination and endowments. Climate change approaches are seen
decision-making occurs either through market forces as a cost rather than an opportunity, and institutional
or state involvement. Therefore the state may play a governance systems focus on protecting access to
larger role in shaping climate change outcomes, but resources (Griffiths and Zammuto, 2005). For
these are generally subservient to social and eco- instance, in Australia, coal companies and industries
nomic considerations. Thus viewed, these two per- associated with the production of energy from coal,
spectives become orthogonal dimensions sharing lobby significantly for financial compensation and
one end point rather than opposing ends of the same for protection from a range of measures associated
continuum. See Figure 1. with the introduction of carbon taxes and emissions
trading schemes. Such a governance system has char-
The framework proposed here is based on two acterised much of the national debate on climate
dimensions that broadly represent underlying change in Australia. While Canada has committed
themes about the coordination of economic activities to Kyoto, its energy sector lobby groups have also
and decision making within industries. Representing sharpened their attack on the commitment to Kyoto
the strategic management perspective is a dimension at a national level as an appropriate framework for
anchored on one end by value chain integration, achieving emissions reductions. Critics of this
where economic decision making and coordination approach note that a reliance on organisational capa-
is achieved through managerial hierarchies and, on bilities alone is insufficient to maintain country
the other, by market forces. The political economy industrial competitiveness, particularly if the indus-
perspective is represented by a dimension anchored try focuses on low value-added activities (Streeck,
on one end by state involvement in economic activi- 1991), competes for finite resources at the detriment
of value-adding outcomes (Lazonick and Gibson,
1983), and has industry value chains that are highly
atomistic (Streeck, 1991). Furthermore, the gover-
Four Institutional Governance Systems nance institutions that evolve demonstrate an inabil-
Political Economy Perspective ity to intervene in industry value chains (Griffiths,
Coordination Through
1998; Weiss, 1998). Therefore when it comes to
approaches to climate change issues, this governance
Strategic Management Perspective

State Involvement

system has the following characteristics:


Value Chain Integration
Coordination Through
Coordination Through

State Joint
Governance Governance 1. A reliance on minimum compliance standards.
Market Forces

Corporations are encouraged to achieve these


compliance standards and therefore view sustain-
Market Corporate
Governance Governance
ability initiatives as a cost. Climate change issues
and reductions in greenhouse gases are ignored.
2. If corporations pursue individual corporate climate
Coordination Through change activities, these are a consequence of mana-
Market Forces
gerial choice. In other words for the main part capa-
bilities around climate change and greenhouse gas
Figure 1 Four Institutional Governance Systems. mitigation are left to the development prerogative
Source: Griffiths and Zammuto, 2005. of individual managers and corporations.

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 417
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

Table 1 Sustainability Characteristics of the Four Governance Systems

Market Governance Corporate Governance State Governance Joint Governance

Characteristics
Value chain Fragmented Integrated Fragmented Integrated
State involvement Low Low High High
Coordination of decision Market forces Corporations through State State/corporate
making relating to climate Individual corporate managerial hierarchies In negotiation collaboration
change activity – voluntary Reliance on with unions,
voluntary actions employers,
green groups

Climate change outcomes Low and fragmented Low/Moderate Dictated High/High Moderate/High
by corporate strategy
Institutional capabilities
State involvement in Low/Minimal, protection Low/Intervenes to High/Corporatist High/Corporatist style
industry governance of resource access; address threats to style structures structures to bring key
a site of dispute between major resources that to bring key economic players
industry groups may impact on players together, together,
powerful lobby groups negotiated outcomes transformational
capabilities
Corporate involvement in Low – focus on High – focus on Low High
industry governance on compliance and an voluntary initiatives
climate change attempt to maintain
the staus quo
Rate of climate change Slow/Firm specific Fast/Firm-specific Slow Fast/Future-oriented
innovation (Rate/Focus) and patchy diffusion (consensus- capabilities that
building)/Industry enhance industry
enhancing – diffusion sustainability
widespread in activities – export
industry clusters driven
Conditions of best fit
Speed of adjustment to Slow, if adjustments Fast for individual Slow initially but Fast
sustainability challenges are made – reactionary firms – slow for leads to fast
collective industry adoption after
groups extended
negotiation periods
Stakeholder adjustment Weakest members of Weakest members Costs of adaptation Costs of adaptation
the value-chain bear of the value-chain are distributed are distributed across
the costs of industry bear the costs of across industry industry participants,
adaptation. In this case, industry adaptation participants, focus on ‘‘growing
specific community focus on ‘‘sharing the pie’’
groups or natural the pie’’
resources
(Adapted from Griffiths and Zammuto (2005)).

3. Corporations and industries may engage in cli- internal capabilities as an important institutional
mate change activities as a consequence of volun- governance system. Figure 1 characterises such insti-
teering to take part in industry or government tutional arrangements as having integrated value
sponsored sustainability programs. chains with little state involvement in the industry’s
4. The main focus of corporate and industry activity is economic activities (Griffiths and Zammuto, 2005).
to lobby and influence government outcomes and Using Chandler’s work (Chandler, 1966), one of the
to protect access to resource issues. Costs in this key characteristics of such a system is the use of man-
system tend to be distributed to the politically pow- agerial hierarchies to integrate value-adding activi-
erful and effective interest groups. Corporations ties such as the linking of systems of supply,
may attempt to sway political debate and focus production and distribution to generate competitive
on costs of adjustment – such as the loss of eco- advantages (Griffiths, 1998). Another key characteris-
nomic growth and employment as a consequence tic is that corporate institutional governance systems
of addressing greenhouse mitigation issues. enshrine competitive markets with the result that
governments are reluctant to become involved in
Corporate Governance: The second quadrant highlights competition between firms. In other words emphasis
the importance of the industrial corporation and its on climate change issues and in particular attempts

418 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

to deal with greenhouse gas reductions are left to ecological modernisation of industry through negoti-
individual corporations and self monitoring systems. ated and state led targets and policies. In other words,
If intervention, such as the creation of carbon trading the state governance quadrant illustrates the influ-
markets evolve, it is anticipated that firms take place ence of politics in the sphere of markets. Hence we
in these activities as a result of attempts to reduce could expect to see a great deal of internal variation
their risk; improve their reputational performance within Europe on how individual states negotiate
or seek to access carbon trading markets elsewhere. outcomes and goals on climate change activities. For
The corporate governance approach to climate instance, the approaches taken by Netherlands and
change is related to and similar to that of the market Sweden vary greatly in terms of how they operation-
governance approach. The United States is represen- alize and address climate change issues. However
tative of this type of institutional governance system, while the state encourages ecological modernisation
with an emphasis placed on corporate and market of industry, climate change goals take place within
led responses and solutions to climate change in a broader framework of economic and social priori-
the absence of a coherent national policy framework. ties. The characteristics of this system include:
It has the following characteristics:
1. The use of state sponsored forums and national
1. An overall reliance on corporations to take the goals to bring major stakeholders together to
lead role in effecting climate change and corporate determine and work towards achieving climate
social responsibility outcomes through their eco- change targets – such as through trading schemes
nomic endeavours. They may be influenced by and carbon taxes.
markets, loss of reputation, shareholder activism 2. The establishment and setting of regulatory targets
– but they are not led by a coordinated role under- for individual industries and the implementation of
taken by the state. individual corporate reporting requirements.
2. A focus on corporations using their supply chains 3. The ecological modernisation of industry and
and capabilities to create dynamic competitive society by implementing national level policies
advantages and capabilities from their climate on pollution, waste management, recycling and
change activities. For instance energy retail com- dematerialisation.
panies may encourage their transforming and gen- 4. To encourage industry to invest in the skills and
erating companies to pursue greenhouse gas capabilities of its workforce in order to develop
reductions and mitigations strategies. sustainability oriented products and services that
3. The use of corporate activity to influence and deter- can be used in export markets.
mine a range of policies and practices – including 5. The encouragement of industries to shift out of
minimum standards, access to resources, pollution, polluting activities or to shift these polluting activ-
energy reduction and waste control. In other words ities to other countries and or regions.
corporations may shift polluting activities to other
locations where rules and criteria are not as Joint Governance: The fourth quadrant, joint gover-
stringent. nance, describes approaches to national industrial
4. As with the market governance approach, the transformation where the state is involved in industry
development of capabilities around climate decision making and industry value chains are inte-
change and broader sustainability issues are left grated. In other words, these institutional governance
to individual corporate choice. systems can intervene in the economy (Calder, 1993),
5. Diffusion of knowledge on climate change and encourage broader systems of product and process
mitigation approaches are left to corporate activity innovation and encourage economic and industrial
and based on the competitive soundness of the learning (Amsden, 2001; Mathews, 2002). Such an
sustainability innovation. approach appears to characterise German national
responses to the impact of climate change on indus-
State Governance: The third quadrant covers those try. The major elements of the joint governance
institutional governance systems that are corporatist approach to national industrial competitiveness and
and neo-corporatist in orientation, which are charac- the obtainment of climate change goals include:
terised by a fragmented value chain and state
involvement in industry decision making. The state 1. A reliance on a mixture of large and small pri-
plays a role in negotiating and structuring outcomes vately owned firms to adopt innovative practices
between significant groups in society—state, labour, to reduce their own ecological footprint, but also
capital and green groups (Goldthorpe, 1984). How- to develop innovate technologies, services and
ever, states tend not to intervene in value chain activ- products that create export led climate change
ities, which are left to market forces and the actions of solutions;
managerial hierarchies. As Hancock (1991) argues, 2. Public/private sector research initiatives that
corporatist regimes rely on extensive private owner- focus on generating new products and services
ship; however, they also rely on public and private and seek to leverage climate change opportunities
measures designed to institutionalise structural adap- for these organisations;
tation to changing domestic and international eco- 3. Government regulatory agencies designed for
nomic conditions. The state actively encourages the coordination of these activities. They rely on a

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 419
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

combination of targets, regulatory compliance but In this section, it is argued that the Australian Gov-
seek through the use of dynamic feedback to cre- ernment’s approach to addressing the issue of cli-
ate new climate change opportunities; mate change, has for the most part been ad hoc
4. The development of inter-organisational struc- and to develop a national response to climate change
tures that cross government and industry divides and its impacts outside of International Law (i.e.
– in order to encourage the free flow of informa- Kyoto protocol). This section argues that in the
tion, the diffusion of climate change innovations absence of a National uniform regulatory framework
within the nation and as a means of updating to control and contain greenhouse gas emissions,
mature sectors of the economy and moving or there will continue to be an ad hoc and inconsistent
adjusting to a ‘carbon constrained world’. approach to the issue of climate change which will
fuel economic uncertainty and achieve little, if any,
actual emissions reductions. The Australian case is
used as an example of an institutional governance
Climate Change Responses: The Case
system associated with market governance. That is,
of Australia an institutional governance system that is character-
ized by a high degree of plurality between differing
The Kyoto Protocol was adopted on 11 December levels of government; a high degree of competitive-
1997 (United Nations, 1997) and entered into force ness between stakeholders that seek to influence
on 16 February 2005. It reaffirms the objectives and the climate change debate in order to protect or
principles of the UNFCCC, and specifies legally ‘win’ resources for their status quo position, and
binding targets which commits Parties to limit or with a national policy framework based on volunta-
reduce their greenhouse gas emissions levels. The rism, that generates a policy vacuum that hinders
main feature of the Protocol is the requirement that widespread innovation and creates uncertainty over
Parties included in Annex 1 (including developed large scale energy investments. The rest of this sec-
and industrialized nations) ensure that they meet tion sets out the chronological order of Australia’s
agreed greenhouse emissions targets (United national policy response, followed by an analysis of
Nations, 1997, Article 3 of the Kyoto Protocol. These the energy sector and the plurality of differing state
targets are set in relation to 1990 emissions levels for led initiatives to address climate change in the
the specified commitment period of 2008–2012.). The absence of a coherent national policy response.
target set for Australia was 108% of the 1990 emis-
sions level, due to its dependence on fossil fuels The Australian Government ratified the UNFCCC on
(Jones, 2002). Most other countries were required to 30 December 1992. The principles espoused in the
reduce 1990 emissions levels by about 5% (United Convention still underpin many of Australia’s strate-
Nations, 1997, Annex 1 of the Kyoto Protocol). gic and policy initiatives in relation to greenhouse
gas emissions. The National Greenhouse Response Strat-
The mechanisms designed through the Protocol to egy (NGRS) was released in 1992 as a strategic tool
assist nations in achieving emissions reductions for Australia’s long term commitment to climate
included: firstly, the establishment of an emissions change (Jones, 2002). Up to this point, the debate
trading regime which enables Parties to buy and sell on climate change in Australia seemed set and Aus-
allocated emissions permits as a means of achieving tralia joined discussions and negotiations on the
emissions levels; secondly, allowing Annex 1 Parties Kyoto Protocol.
to transfer emissions reduction units to or acquire
emissions reduction units from other Annex 1 Parties However, in 1997, Australian public policy on climate
in order to achieve emissions targets (United change altered significantly, with the Commonwealth
Nations, 1997, Article 6); thirdly, allowing parties to government’s refusal to ratify the Kyoto Protocol,
record ‘‘net changes in greenhouse gas emissions arguing that it did not provide an effective long term
from sources and removals by sinks resulting from method of reducing greenhouse gas emissions. In
direct human-induced land use change and forestry particular, the Commonwealth Government argued
activities. . .’’ (United Nations, 1997, Article 3(3)); that without the participation on the USA, India
and finally, allowing development of clean develop- and China, the Kyoto Protocol was unworkable, and
ment mechanisms which encourages Parties to that ‘‘an effective global framework to address cli-
implement emissions reductions projects in non- mate change needs to include commitments from all
Annex 1 countries and then have the projects major emitters’’ (Hare, 2001). It also disagreed with
counted towards meeting emissions targets (United the exclusion of developing countries from the
Nations, 1997, Article). In other words, the Kyoto requirement to reduce greenhouse gas emissions
protocol provided a comprehensive range of mecha- (Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, 2006).
nisms that enabled differing national institutional The refusal to ratify the agreement was taken despite
governance systems a means by which to address cli- the fact that Australia was given significant conces-
mate change activities – through a mix of public pol- sions that took into account its reliance on fossil fuels.
icy, industry innovations and changes in corporate
level strategy via the creation of a market value for In place of the Kyoto Protocol, the Commonwealth
carbon. government introduced in 1998 the National Green-

420 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

house Strategy (the NGS). The NGS stresses the need In February 2006, the Council of Australian Govern-
for an integrated approach to climate change by ments (COAG) announced that it would adopt a new
Commonwealth, State and Local governments and national Climate Change Plan of Action and establish a
promotes industry and community participation in ‘‘high-level inter-jurisdictional Climate Change
addressing climate change (Commonwealth Govern- Group to over see the implementation of the Plan’s
ment, 1998). The basis of this strategy was for recommendations’’ (Council of Australian Govern-
organizations to voluntarily improve their energy ments, 2006). Although there appears to be some
efficiency, develop sustainable land use practices urgency in COAG’s communiqué, aside from restat-
(and carbon sinks) and to promote best practice ing Australia’s commitment to the UNFCCC in rela-
approaches to greenhouse gas emissions (Horn, tion to ‘‘preventing dangerous human interference
2001). This was to be undertaken on a voluntary basis with the climate system’’(Council of Australian Gov-
and ignored setting price mechanisms – such as a ernments, 2006), there is still no indication that a
carbon taxes or emissions trading schemes – and pro- national uniform regulatory regime to control green-
vided little in the way of industry adjustment to house gas emissions levels will be developed in the
reduce industries carbon reliance. The NGS called short term.
on all levels of Government to implement initiatives
(voluntary) which encourage a reduction in the reli- Similarly, the Australian Business Roundtable on Cli-
ance on greenhouse gas producing technologies mate Change 1 has released its Report to Government
and develop ‘‘carbon sinks’’ to offset greenhouse urging early intervention on the issue of climate
emissions. change arguing that delaying action will increase
costs to business and the economy. In particular,
An example of the type of voluntary programs advo- the Roundtable Recommendations include to
cated by the Commonwealth government included ‘‘design a long, loud and legal framework to estab-
the Greenhouse Challenge (1995 to 2005) and its new lish a price signal’’ which will set short term emis-
program the Greenhouse Challenge Plus (2005–pres- sions targets to ensure transition to a low-carbon
ent). These programs encourage businesses to adopt economy (Australian Business Roundtable on Cli-
initiatives which reduce the impacts of greenhouse mate Change, 2006, p. 7). Meeting this short term
gas emissions and climate change. For instance, com- goal is seen as fundamental to achieving the long
panies involved in the program undertook energy term ‘‘goal for Australia to significantly reduce
audits, purchased green energy options and sought greenhouse gas emissions as our contribution to a
to offset emissions from their car fleets. These pro- global effort designed to avert dangerous climate
grams are non-legislative programs which rely on impacts’’ (Australian Business Roundtable on Cli-
voluntary compliance and financial inducements. mate Change, 2006, p. 7).
As such companies are not rewarded or penalized
for achieving or failing to achieve targets. They have Therefore, in line with a market based institutional
become sources of corporate reputation performance governance systems, we saw the emergence of a
– however the uptake by major corporates has been group of proactive companies arguing that there is
lacking. It has been argued that initially, the Green- an economic case for industrial adjustment to
house Challenge was supported by business and in address climate change issues. This was in contrast
particular the coal lobby, as a means of avoiding a to the coal and energy lobby that had been highly
‘‘Carbon Tax’’ and other regulatory initiatives which resistant to a carbon tax of national emission trading
could increase costs. scheme that would damage the economic underpin-
nings of those industry sectors. The Business Round-
However, increasing evidence has emerged that table of Climate Change pointed out that the current
these voluntary and market led initiatives have not approach in Australia meant that emissions targets
led to a significant reduction in greenhouse gas emis- were voluntary and piecemeal, with little consistency
sions. For instance, it is estimated that to prevent the between jurisdictions. They provide more weight to
adverse impacts of global warming, Australia must calls for the Australian Government to intervene, ie.
achieve a reduction in greenhouse gas emissions lev- via the creation of carbon trading markets, and
els of 60–80% over the period 1990 to 2050, which thereby, provide certainty for business and commu-
equates to a reduction on between 1 to 1.5% per nity investment.
annum over the 60 year period (Sullivan, 2006).
However, adopting the current national frameworks, Unfortunately, as demonstrated in the Australian
it appears at this point, that Australia is nowhere case, government strategy on climate change alone
near realizing this level of emissions reductions. In has been insufficient to provide certainty to an issue
fact, emissions levels were about 10% above 1990 which many corporations are reluctant to accept
emissions levels in 2000 (Sullivan, 2006). Given these given the potential costs attached to changing exist-
continued high emissions rate, it is uncertain as to ing practices. It appears that a clear regulatory frame-
whether the existing regime can achieve emissions work – which coordinates national, state and
levels specified in the Kyoto Protocol despite Com- industry level institutions – is required if any sub-
monwealth Government assurances that Australia stantial reduction in Australia’s levels of greenhouse
is on target. gas emissions levels is to be realized.

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 421
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

The recent weight of these initiatives – from environ- house Office, 2002). Microeconomic reform and com-
mentally progressive corporations; the reports into petition have served to make electricity cheaper for
carbon trading by the state governments and even consumers, thus increasing demand. While some
the calls for investment certainty from the energy regulatory initiatives have been undertaken to
and coal lobby groups – has seen a change in govern- reduce the reliance of the energy sector on coal, this
ment position and policy on emissions reduction and area remains of critical importance to the realization
carbon trading. The Australian Government still of reductions in greenhouse gas emissions. A Nation-
argues that the impact of climate change can be ally uniform regulation of the electricity sector would
reduced through initiatives more suited to Austra- enhance emissions reductions and provide certainty
lia’s economic and geographical position, rather than to the industry and consumers. In this section, it is
by setting emissions targets (Australian Government, firstly demonstrated that regulations regarding
2005). In other words, climate change can be energy efficiency and renewable energy targets vary
addressed through a range of voluntary measures across jurisdictions and secondly, the differing
undertaken by corporations and individuals whilst approaches to the use of carbon sequestration to off-
the Commonwealth supports research into carbon set carbon emissions.
capturing technologies. Although in recent months
the Federal government has also changed its policy The Renewable Energy (Electricity) Act 2000 (Cth) pro-
position – forming its own review to examine the vides that, by 2010, an additional 2% of Australia’s
possibility of Australia developing and taking part electricity must be produced from renewable energy
in an international emissions trading scheme. sources. This amount was intended to be in addition
to any existing alternative energy sources. This initia-
Consequently, given the recent nature in the change of tive has resulted in additional investment in hydro-
the debate on climate change in Australia, the Austra- electric schemes (Lyster, 2004).
lian Government has indicated that it is willing to
negotiate alternative agreements aimed at addressing The States have also been involved in developing
climate change. For instance, Australia is a member of strategies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions from
the Asia-Pacific Partnership on Clean Development and energy providers. For example, Queensland
Climate which aims to address energy security, cli- amended the Electricity Act 1994 (Qld) and the Elec-
mate change and air pollution issues 2. Despite Aus- tricity Regulation 2006, to provide that 13% of electric-
tralia’s move to side with the United States on this ity produced in the State must come from natural gas
issue, without a commitment to the Kyoto Protocol, (Queensland Government, 1994). 3 It achieves this
Australia cannot participate in its International car- through the development of a certificate based
bon trading scheme. Given increased industry and scheme where electricity retailers must purchase a
corporate concern over the inability to participate in percentage of their electricity from accredited gas
carbon trading markets, along with the uncertainty generators of electricity.
generated for large scale investments in renewable
technologies and other energy investments, the Aus- New South Wales and the Australian Capital Terri-
tralian Commonwealth government commissioned a tory have the Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme
business task force to examine the creation of an emis- (GGAS) which operates under the Electricity Supply
sions trading market. In response to these issues, the Act 1995 (NSW). GGAS provides a mandatory green-
Prime Ministerial Task Group on Emissions Trading house gas benchmark which must be met by all elec-
was established in 2006 and has made strong recom- tricity sector participants in NSW. Benchmarks levels
mendations for Australia to create/join an emissions are established in accordance with market share of
trading market for 2011. The institutional governance NSW electricity demand (Greenhouse Gas Abate-
system that characterizes Australia’s approach to cli- ment Scheme, 2006). 4 Participants in the GGAS
mate change appears to be in flux – shifting slowly meet allocated benchmark level by surrendering
from a system of market governance to a system more abatement certificates created from emission reduc-
characterized by a corporate governance approach to tion activities. Failure to surrender enough abate-
climate change. ment certificates to meet the mandatory benchmark
will result in a penalty being imposed. The current
However, the changes in direction at a national level, penalty for failure to comply is $11 per tonne of
mirror changes that have occurred at a state govern- shortfall (Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme,
ment level. The next section uses the electricity indus- 2006). This is Australia’s only initiative that provides
try to highlight the plurality of differing approaches a regulatory requirement that greenhouse gases be
in the absence of a coherent national policy. reduced. It is limited to the electricity sector of
NSW and the ACT.

Finally, the National Green Power Accreditation Pro-


The Electricity Sector gram has been established jointly between the gov-
ernments of South Australia, NSW, Victoria,
The electricity industry is the single biggest producer Queensland, Western Australia and the ACT. This
of greenhouse gases in Australia (Australian Green- program has been credited with achieving the major-

422 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

ity of Australia’s renewable energy production In Queensland, the Land Title Act 1994 (Qld) and the
(Lyster, 2004). It is a non-legislative scheme. These Forestry Act 1959 (Qld) provide a profit a prendre
initiatives act independently and provide a regula- mechanism to operate of freehold and leasehold
tory and policy regime that is inconsistent between land. The Queensland Government stated that this
jurisdictions and incapable of providing wide-rang- regime:
ing or systematic change.
‘‘enable[s] investors . . . to register their interests in trees
The second area that highlights the plurality of established on someone else’s land. . . Land holders can
approaches in a market based governance system use this system to sell interests in trees without having
can be seen by the variety of approaches to offsetting to sell the land the trees are growing on, and without hav-
emissions via carbon sequestration. Essentially, car- ing to fell the trees. This makes it possible to trade in
bon sequestration occurs because, as plants grow, immature plantations.’’ (Lim and Giskes, 2004, p. 7).
they remove carbon dioxide from the atmosphere.
If more carbon dioxide is removed than is released In addition, the Vegetation Management Act 1999 (Qld)
in an area of vegetation, this is known as a ‘‘carbon aims to reduce clearing of remnant vegetation for the
sink’’. 5 purpose, among other things, of reducing green-
house gas emissions 8.
The development of carbon sinks has been promoted
by the Commonwealth even though there are no South Australia’s Forest Property Act 2000 (SA) and
national legislative arrangements. Notably, the NGS Tasmania’s Forestry Rights Registration Act 1990 (Tas)
identified the development of carbon sinks as a key also establish profit a prendre systems.
area within the overall strategy to reduce greenhouse
gas emissions. Despite this, the Commonwealth Gov- By contrast the regimes in Western Australia and
ernment had, until recently, ruled out introducing a Victoria recognize the ownership of carbon seques-
National carbon trading scheme (CRC Greenhouse tration rights. The Forestry Rights Act 1996 (Vic) and
Accounting, 2003). However given political pressure the Carbon Rights Act 2003 (WA) recognize the right
and the overwhelming evidence of the costs of cli- to commercially exploit carbon sequestered by trees
mate change, this position is currently under review. (S.3 Victoria) and establish and recognize carbon
rights where a carbon right form has been registered
Regardless, most Australian States have developed (section 5, WA). Notably, the Carbon Rights Act dif-
legislation that recognizes carbon sequestration as a fers from the profit a prendre system because it does
commodity, thus establishing the foundation of a create an interest in land in relation to the effects of
National carbon trading system. These legislative carbon sequestration from, and carbon release to,
regimes are not uniform between States, with two the atmosphere. 9
main approaches to recognizing the ownership of
carbon rights being developed (Jones, 2002). These As States negotiate the possibility of a national car-
are the profit a prendre approach, which has been bon trading arrangement, the different legislative
adopted in Queensland, NSW, South Australia and approaches and State-based interests are taking prec-
Tasmania, and the introduction of statutory carbon edent over the need to reduce Australia’s greenhouse
sequestration rights, which has been introduced in gas emissions. For example, the Victorian Govern-
Victoria and Western Australia (Lim and Giskes, ment does not wish to introduce a carbon trading
2004, p. 12). A profit a prendre is the creation of a scheme that would adversely affect its own brown
right to take something off another person’s land or coal industry (Planet Ark, 2006). Similarly the Fed-
to take something out of the soil or the natural pro- eral government has given research dollars to the
duce of the soil 6. What has essentially happened in coal industry to investigate and pilot carbon capture
jurisdictions adopting this approach is that the defi- and sequestration technologies. Some states such as
nition of ‘‘forestry rights’’ has been extended to Queensland have also contributed to research by
include carbon sequestration rights (Jones, 2002). 7 the large coal mining companies into carbon seques-
tration. Significant debates has also emerged over the
In NSW, amendments to the Conveyancing Act 1919 prospect of the introduction of a nuclear power
(NSW) has established a framework which recog- industry. This had generated conflict between differ-
nizes carbon sequestration rights and forestry rights ent sectors and industries in the Australian economy.
as a profit a prendre. Accordingly, this allows the The coal industry for instance wants public funds
carbon sequestrated from trees to be traded (Lim directed into research into clean coal technology
and Giskes, 2004, p. 13). Amendments have also been whilst several of the large resource companies see cli-
made to the Energy Services Corporations Act 1995 mate change and emissions reduction as an opportu-
(NSW) has enabled energy companies to deal and nity for Australia to expand its uranium mining
trade in carbon sequestration rights through the capacity and increase the prospects for the establish-
GGAS program and amendments for the Forestry ment of a ‘clean’ nuclear enrichment and power
Act 1916 (NSW) enables the Forestry Commission industry. Furthermore, it appears that as these issues
of NSW to participate in the scheme (Lim and Giskes, become more central to political debates, that
2004, p. 13). green and other environmental groups have been

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 423
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

marginalized as large corporations seek to influence issues present to some industries. States that are
the design and structure of any carbon tax or emis- not involved in industry decision making rely on
sions trading scheme. This further supports the need market forces or minimum compliance approaches
for the Australian Government to introduce manda- to structure industry adaptation to climate change –
tory greenhouse gas emissions levels, which, to the case of Australia. In Australia, we saw that the
enable industries to maintain competitiveness, could national government had a national strategy to deal
include a carbon trading mechanism. This highlights with climate change - in keeping with an institutional
the plurality and fragmented approach under an governance system characterised by market gover-
institutional governance system that places compet- nance. However this strategy was reliant upon vol-
ing interest groups ahead of broader national envi- untarism by industry and corporations and did not
ronmental goals. require mandatory targets in energy efficiency or
emissions reduction. Furthermore, it enabled indi-
vidual state governments to develop their own tar-
gets for renewable energy use and protect state
Discussion and Conclusion economies at the expense of national objectives. For
industries and corporations, this meant that they
It has been proposed in this paper that the institu- may have to achieve different renewable targets if
tional governance systems framework expands our they were operating in different jurisdictions and
understanding of the response of national industries also emboldened powerful lobby groups – such as
to climate change issues by focusing on the intersec- the coal sector – to influence policy decisions.
tion of state and industry activities to coordinate
decision making and economic activity. An institu- The institutional governance system characterised by
tional governance system is not just government market governance proved quite reactive and slow
involvement in an industry or just industry structure, given the absence of a national emissions target strat-
but something that incorporates both. egy and carbon price mechanism. Consequently, the
short term costs of adaptation under the market gover-
It has been argued in this paper, that in order to nance and corporate governance institutional systems
understand variations in climate change approaches, are borne by those groups that are pluralistically or
that it is important to understand how a national politically weak—either labour, environmental
governance system helps shape industry and corpo- groups or those that are in a disadvantageous position
rate activities in response to the challenges of green- (community groups) or occupy a weak place in the
house gas reductions. The framework developed supply chain (the tourism industry as opposed to the
suggests that neither firm nor state-centric explana- coal industry ). However, there is a question of the rel-
tions can account for variations in responses to trans- ative long term costs of each pattern of adaptation.
forming industry systems in response to climate
change issues. In other words, attempting to explain Further research is required to understand how insti-
differences in climate change response by purely an tutional governance systems develop the capability to
emphasise on firm level capabilities – or even structure the adaptation process as climate change
national level policies – leaves a void in understand- conditions change. For instance, there has been a
ing why it is that some governance systems may recent and sudden shift in the institutional gover-
seem to generate better sustainability outcomes. nance system in Australia, as the national govern-
ment has made commitments to implement a cap
The institutional governance system framework’s and trade carbon trading scheme after 2011. The
contribution is that it identifies the firm/industry- development of such a system has now become the
level and state-level characteristics of each governance battleground for lobby groups and major carbon
system which, in turn, facilitates comparison across emitters. Particularly, there has been a shift by the
the different patterns of industry engagement with cli- major mining and energy users to influence the crea-
mate change. These comparisons starts the process of tion and design of such a market. On the other side, it
enabling us to examine the conditions under which has signalled to business groups that they have an
particular institutional governance systems are likely adjustment period to implement efficiencies to reduce
to succeed or fail, and to develop a more sophisticated their carbon emissions and encourages them to find
picture of both an industry’s and the state’s roles in innovations in technology and investment. Similarly,
fostering or hindering the transformation of industries the shift in institutional governance systems, via the
in response to climate change issues. creation of a national framework for emissions trad-
ing, will create the conditions that will reduce differ-
The institutional governance framework, as applied ences between the individual state governments
to the Australian case, shows that the patterns of renewable energy targets and carbon sequestration
industry and firm adaptation differ across the gover- strategies, thereby reducing corporate uncertainty.
nance systems with respect to the relative speed with
which adaptation occurs and who within a society Research is also needed to determine whether differ-
bears the cost of adaptation. This is particularly ent institutional governance systems enhance the
important given the difficulties that climate change long term innovative and knowledge capital of indi-

424 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

vidual firms within an industry. For instance will Notes


firms that exist in state governance and joint gover-
nance approaches develop more value added 1. The Business Roundtable is comprised of BP Australia, AIG,
approached to climate change, that become the basis Origin Energy, Swiss Re, Visy Industries and Westpac. The
Australian Conservation Foundation also worked with the
of new business models? Roundtable and research was provided by the CSIRO and
Allen Consulting Group.
This paper raises several interesting challenges and 2. Other members of the partnership are China, India, Japan,
questions over the structure and response of gover- Republic of Korea and the USA.
nance systems to climate change issues. How do 3. The objects of Chapter 5A of the Electricity Act 1994 are ‘‘(a)
reduce the growth in greenhouse gases associated with electricity use
institutional governance systems break out of path in the State; and (b) contribute to the diversification of the State’s
dependencies and develop capabilities that enable energy mix towards the greater use of gas in electricity generation;
them to shift and adjust their response to changing and(c) encourage the development of new gas sources and gas
climate change? Do changing industry conditions infrastructure to meet the State’s future energy requirements’’.
4. This system commenced on 1 January 2003 in NSW and 1
(i.e., technological innovations, deregulation, indus-
January 2005 in the ACT.
try globalisation, changes in the ease of resource 5. State Forest of NSW; Forest Facts; Generating Carbon Benefits for
flows across borders, emergence of trading blocks) Public and Privately Owned Forests,http://www.for-
force states and industries to rethink the extent of est.nsw.gov.au, accessed 25 April 2006.
cooperation in their relationships and in industry 6. Australian Softwood Forests Pty Ltd v Attorney-General (NSW); Ex
Rel Corporate Affairs Commission (1981) 148 CLR 121 at 130. See
structure? What impact does global climate change also Corporate Affairs Commission v ASC Timber Pty Ltd (1989) 18
issues have on the speed and pace of industry and NSWLR 577 for definition of profit a prendre.
firm transformation? 7. See for example, theForestry Act 1916 (NSW); section 33C.
8. Vegetation Management Act 1999 (Qld); section 3(1)(g).
There is the question of whether this framework 9. Carbon Rights Act 2003 (WA), p. 1. This Act commenced on 24
March 2004.
applies at the industry or state-level of analysis.
While Biggart and Guillen’s (1999) analysis suggests
that social institutions are likely to have a homoge-
nous effect on industry development within a nation, References
there can be significant variation in the governance
systems across a nation’s industries. Even if we Amsden, A.H. (2001) The Rise of The Rest: Challenges to the
assume that the nature of state-industry relations is West from Late-Industrializing Economies. Oxford Uni-
versity Press, Oxford, New York.
fixed across industries within a given state, there is Australian Business Roundtable on Climate Change (2006)
considerable variation in the degree of value chain The Business Case for Early Action, accessed at
integration across industries. Moreover, there are http://www.businessroundtable.com.au/html/docu-
likely to be significant variations in the relative ments.html on 31 May 2007.
power of value chain members across industries. Australian Government (2005) Address to the United
Nations Climate Change Conference by Senator the
For instance, stakeholder groups such as green Hon. Ian Campbell on December 8, 2005, accessed at
groups may have a significant impact on governance http://www.environment.gov.au/minister/env/2005/
system development in a traditional industry, such tr08dec05.html on 15 March 2007.
as mining, but less impact in newer industries like Australian Greenhouse Office (2002) National greenhouse gas
information technology. inventory 2000 with methodology supplements 1990, 1995
and 2002. Australian Greenhouse Office, Canberra.
Barney, J. (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive
Furthermore, the institutional governance system advantage. Journal of Management 17(1), 99–120.
framework proposed here, enables managers to Best, M.H. (2001) The New Competitive Advantage: The
understand why it is that different nations, with Renewal of American Industry. Oxford University Press,
competing jurisdictions of government (federal, Oxford, New York.
Biggart, N.W. and Guillen, M.F. (1999) Developing differ-
state) generate different policy and industry out- ence: Social organization and the rise of the auto
comes. Whilst this provides managers with difficul- industries of South Korea, Taiwan, Spain, and Argen-
ties in managing complexity it also provides them tina. American Sociological Review 64(5), 722–747.
with an understanding of strategies that they can Calder, K.E. (1993) Strategic Capitalism: Private Business and
Public Purpose in Japanese Industrial Finance. Princeton
pursue to influence desirable policy outcomes. For University Press, Princeton, NJ.
instance, part of the resilience of the coal industry Chandler, A.D. (1966) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the
in Australia has been its effective ability to lobby History of the Industrial Enterprise. Doubleday, Garden
governments to attract resources and desirable policy City, NY.
outcomes. This framework enables us to understand Christmann, P., Day, D.L. and Yip, G.S. (1999) The relative
influence of country conditions, industry structure
the process by which this occurs. and business strategy on MNC subsidiary perfor-
mance. Journal of International Management 5, 241–265.
Finally, the institutional governance framework Commonwealth Government (1998) The national green-
allows the internal differences between industries house strategy: Strategic framework for advancing
within a country to be examined as well as differ- australia’s greenhouse response, accessed at http://
www.greenhouse.gov.au/government/ngs/pubs/ngs.
ences across countries. The approach proposed here pdf on 20 March 2007.
enables such dynamics and their outcomes to be Council of Australian Governments (2006) Council of
explored rather than determined a priori. Australian governments’ meeting, 10 February 2006,

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 425
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

accessed at http://www.coag.gov.au/meetings/ Research Brief No 2004/03, Queensland Parliamen-


100206/index.htm on 20 March 2007. tary Library.
CRC Greenhouse Accounting (2003) Opportunities for Lyster, R. (2004) The implications of electricity restructur-
the Western Australian land management sector ing for a sustainable energy framework: What’s law
arising from greenhouse gas abatement, accessed at got to do with it? Paper presented at the IUCN
http://portal.environment.wa.gov.au/pls/portal/docs/ academy of environment law 2003 Colloquium,
PAGE/DOE_ADMIN/PROJECTS/GREENHOUSE/ Shanghai, China, 4 November 2004.
CRCGREENHOUSE.PDF on 20 March 2007. Mathews, J. and Cho, D.S. (2000) Tiger Technology: The
Department of Foreign affairs and trade (2006) Climate Creation of Semi Conductor Industry in East Asia.
change – Australia’s position, accessed at http:// Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, New
www.dfat.gov.au/environment/climate/ on 20 April York.
2006. Mathews, J.A. (2002) The origins and dynamics of Taiwan’s
Evans, P.B. (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial R&D consortia. Research Policy 31(4), 633–652.
Transformation. Princeton University Press, Princeton, McGahan, A.M. and Porter, M.E. (1997) How much does
NJ. industry matter, really? Strategic Management Journal
Fairbridge, R.W. (1969) Polar migration, sea-floor spread- 18, 15–30.
ing, atolls and climate change. Tectonophysics 7(5-6), Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982) An Evolutionary
545. Theory of Economic Change. Belknap Press, Cambridge
Goldthorpe, J.H. (1984) Order and Conflict in Contemporary (MA).
Capitalism. Clarendon Press, Oxford. North, D.C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and
Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme (2006) Introduction to Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press.
the GGAS, accessed at www.greenhousegas.nsw.gov. Oliver, C. (1997) Sustainable competitive advantage: Com-
au on 25 April 2006. bining institutional and resource based views. Strate-
Griffiths, A.B. (1998) Institutional capacity and national gic Management Journal 18(9), 697–713.
competitive advantage: The rise and stagnation of the Planet Ark (2006) Analysis – Australian States’ Carbon
Australian meat industry. Industry and Innovation 5(2), Trading Faces Battle, accessed at http://www.planetark.
185–200. com/dailynewsstory.cfm/newsid/35863/story.htm on
Griffiths, A.B. and Zammuto, R.F. (2005) Institutional 2 May 2006.
governance systems and variations in national com- Porter, M.E. (1980) Competitive Strategy: Techniques for
petitive advantage: An integrative framework. The Analyzing Industries and Competitors. Free Press, Collier
Academy of Management Review 30(4), 823–842. Macmillan, London, New York.
Griffiths, A. and Winn, M. (2005) Slack and Sustainability, Porter, M.E. (1985) Competitive Advantage: Creating and
Paper presented at the Academy of Management Sustaining Superior Performance. Free Press, Collier
Conference, ONE division. Macmillan, London, New York.
Hancock, M. (1991) Contrasting approaches to economic Porter, M.E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations.
management and industrial policy. In Managing Mod- The Free Press, New York.
ern Capitalism: Industrial Renewal and Workplace Democ- Queensland Government (1994) Electricity Act 1994,
racy in the United States and Western Europe, (eds) M. accessed at http://www.legislation.qld.gov.au/LEG-
Hancock, J. Logue and B. Schiller, pp. 3–9. Greenwood ISLTN/ACTS/1994/94AC064.pdf on 15 March 2007.
Press, New York. Raddatz, R.L. (2003) Agriculture and tornadoes on the
Hare, W. (2001) Australia and Kyoto: in or out? University Canadian Prairies: Potential impact of increasing
of New South Wales Law Journal 24(2), 556–564. atmospheric CO2 on summer severe weather. Natural
Hoffman, A.J. (1999) Institutional evolution and change: Hazards 29(2), 113–122.
Environmentalism and the US chemical industry. The Rao, H. and Singh, J. (2001) The construction of new paths:
Academy of Management Journal 42(4), 351–371. Institution building activity in the early automobile
Hoffman, A.J. (2005) Climate change strategy: The business and biotech industries. In Path Dependence and Creation,
logic behind voluntary greenhouse gas reductions. (eds) R. Garud and P. Karnoe, pp. 243–268. Lawrence
California Management Review 47(3), 21–46. Erlbaum Associates, New Jersey.
Horn, L. (2001) The kyoto protocol: Australia’s commit- Schoemaker, P.J.H. and Amit, R. (1993) Investment in
ment and compliance. University of NSW Law Journal strategic assets: Industry and firm level perspectives.
24(2), 583–587. Advances in Strategic Management 10, 3–33.
Houghton, J.T., Ding, Y., Griggs, D.J., Noguer, M., van der Schwartz, D.W. (1957) Climate change and culture history
Linden, P.J., Dai, X., Maskell, K. and Johnson, C.A. in the Grand Canyon region. American Antiquity 22(4),
(2001) Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis. Contri- 372–377.
bution of Working Group I to the Third Assessment Report Skocpol, T. (1985) Bringing the state back in: strategies of
of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cam- analysis in current research. In Bringing the State Back,
bridge University Press, Cambridge. (eds) P. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol.
Jones, D. (2002) The Kyoto Protocol, carbon sinks and Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
integrated environmental regulation: An Australian Streeck, W. (1991) On the institutional conditions of
perspective. Environmental and Planning Law Journal diversified quality production. In Beyond Keynesianism:
19(2), 109–130. The Socio-Economics of Production and Employment, (eds)
Khandekar, M.L., Murty, T.S. and Chittibabu, P. (2005) The E. Matzner and W. Streeck, pp. 21–61. Edward Elgar,
global warming debate: A review of the state of London.
science. Pure and Applied Geophysics 162(8-9), Sullivan, R. (2006) Greenhouse challenge plus: A new
1557–1586. departure or more of the same?. Environmental and
Kolk, A. and Pinkse, J. (2005) Business responses to climate Planning Law Journal 23(1), 60–73.
change: Identifying emergent strategies. California Thomas, L.G. and Waring, G. (1999) Competing capital-
Management Review 47(3), 6–20. isms: Capital investment in American, German and
Lazonick, W. and Gibson, W. (1983) The performance of Japanese firms. Strategic Management Journal 20,
the British cotton industry, 1870-1913. Research in 729–748.
Economic History 9, 1–44. United Nations (1997) Kyoto protocol to the United
Lim, S. and Giskes, R. (2004) Carbon Commodities on Nations framework convention on climate change,
Leasehold Land under the Natural Resourses and accessed at http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/items/
Other Legislation Amendment Bill 2004 (Qld). 2830.php on 31 March 2007.

426 European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007
A FRAMEWORK FOR UNDERSTANDING INSTITUTIONAL GOVERNANCE SYSTEMS AND CLIMATE CHANGE

Waller-Hunter, J. (2004) Climate change: The challenge Weiss, L. (1998) The Myth of the Powerless State: Governing
continues. The OECD Observer 242, 30–31. the Economy in a Global Era. Polity Press, Cambridge.

ANDREW GRIFFITHS, NARDIA HAIGH, UQ


UQ Business School, Business School, The
The University of University of Queens-
Queensland, Qld 4072, land, Qld 4072, Austra-
Australia, E-mail: lia.
a.griffiths1@uq.edu.au
Nardia Haigh is a Ph.D.,
Dr Andrew Griffiths is an Student at The University
Associate Professor in the of Queensland Business
UQ Business School. School in Brisbane,
Andrew’s areas of research Australia. Nardia’s work
include: business strategy focuses on investigating
and climate change, corpo- how firms respond to
rate sustainability strategy and change. His work has sustainability issues and identifying strategic vulner-
been published in leading international journals, abilities. In particular, her Ph.D, is complementing
including The Academy of Management Review and the organization theory and strategy by investigating how
Journal of Management Studies. electricity firms are making sense of and respond to
climate change issues, while identifying climate
change-related vulnerabilities within the electricity
JENINE RASSIAS, UQ supply industry.
Business School, The
University of Queens-
land, Qld 4072, Austra-
lia.

Jenine Rassias, is a Senior


Treasury Officer with
Queensland Treasury. She
has Master of Commerce
and recently completed a
law degree majoring in
environmental law. Her
areas of research include environmental law, carbon
sequestration and emissions trading.

European Management Journal Vol. 25, No. 6, pp. 415–427, December 2007 427

You might also like