You are on page 1of 8

Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Biomass and Bioenergy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/biombioe

Research paper

Asset fixity and economic competitiveness of US ethanol production T


a b c,∗,1
Zidong Wang , Marta Wlodarz , Bruce McCarl
a
Alibaba Group Holding Limited, China, Wen Yi Xi Lu 969, Hangzhou, China
b
McKinsey & Company, Inc. Switzerland, Bleicherweg 30, Zurich, 8002, Switzerland
c
Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX, 77843-2124, USA

A R T I C LE I N FO A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Once refineries are built they become fixed assets in location, general class of feedstocks that can be used and
Asset fixity basic technology employed. These fixed characteristics are ignored by most existing national-level biofuel
Cellulosic ethanol modeling analyses. In this study, we introduced such characteristics (asset fixity) into a model that is used in the
Mathematical modeling USEPA (Environmental Protection Agency) Renewable Fuel Standard Analysis. Analysis is then done on re-
Market penetration
newable fuel issues with and without considering such fixity. The results show that neglecting fixity upwardly
biases estimates of renewable fuel market penetration. Also ignoring fixity results in unrealistic location and
feedstock usage for simulated refining. Additionally under asset fixity the ethanol price needed to make cellu-
losic ethanol economically competitive is substantially higher than current levels and predictions of models
ignoring the fixity, reaching $1.06/liter.

1. Introduction their economic life. The concept has been subsequently been considered
in number of agriculturally-related analyses [10–12].
A number of studies have examined ethanol market penetration and Putty-clay technology is a highly related concept originating with
feedstock usage including several associated with USEPA Johansen [13,14]. In this concepts investments can be moved around
(Environmental Protection Agency) renewable fuel standard rule- before construction (putty) but then harden into place once built (clay).
making [1,2]. However, the results of such studies can exhibit un- Fuss [15] argued a key technology characteristic is the extent to which
realistic feedstock mixes and biorefinery locations. In particular, the production flexibility is constrained by in place investments. He illu-
results often show a feedstock used in one place initially then later use strated this arguing that the ability to adjust to energy price increases
of other feedstocks in other places abandoning what in reality would be was constrained by energy infrastructure that was already in place.
expensive previously employed bio-refineries. Our experimentation Atkeson and Kehoe [16] showed that putty clay/AF considerations help
shows this occurs in one model used by EPA - the Forestry and Agri- explain the gradual shifts in energy use in response to persistent
culture Sector Optimization Model or FASOM [1,3,4]). Here we ex- changes in energy prices. Additionally, Rajagopal and Zilberman [17]
amine the extent to which ignoring asset fixity (AF) can bias results on indicated that AF – putty-clay limited producer flexibility to adjust.
processing location, feedstock mix, market penetration and fuel cost. Another related theory is that of irreversible investment under un-
certainty also known as real option theory [18]. That theory asserts that
2. Background on asset fixity it in certain cases it is best to delay making fixed asset investment de-
cisions so as to allow one to obtain more information about such things
Asset fixity has long been a concern when analyzing major invest- as processing technology, feedstock cost and other costs. Furthermore,
ments. Glenn Johnson [5] did early agricultural work on the concept Skevas et al. [19] showed the investment irreversibility and uncertainty
motivated by the writings of D. Gale Johnson [6]. Later the AF concept coupled to dampen incentives to invest.
was formalized by Edwards [7] and Johnson and Quance [8]. Gardner In the context of biofuel refining AF means that refineries once built
[9] summarizes earlier findings indicating that AF influences market are fixed in location, general class of feedstocks that can be used and
and policy responses since many investments once constructed are fixed the technology they employ. Although AF constraints such as location
in place and many operating characteristics limiting responses during and feedstock types are commonly considered in place specific


Corresponding author.
E-mail address: mccarl@tamu.edu (B. McCarl).
1
Seniority of authorship is shared.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.biombioe.2019.01.003
Received 23 February 2018; Received in revised form 2 December 2018; Accepted 11 January 2019
Available online 25 January 2019
0961-9534/ © 2019 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 1. Visual representation of asset fixity concept depicted dynamically over two time periods.

biorefinery supply chain designs (i.e. determining optimal facility lo- However, if the demand grows in period 2 (from AD1 to AD2), the
cation, feedstock choice and transport routes) [20,21], to our knowl- price of ethanol rises from P1 to P2, which exceeds the entry price for
edge AF concerns have not been included in national-level modeling new construction then this stimulates new investment. So in general the
studies on biofuel feedstocks and market penetration. Here we will do market favors ethanol from the existing (AF) plants (because their
an analysis with and without AF consideration to see the implications. marginal production costs are cheaper) and new construction will occur
only if demand causes prices above the new plant entry price.
Furthermore, several AF aspects further complicate the situation but
3. Analytical exploration
are not shown in the graphical framework. First, the existing plants
create AF not only due to plant capacity but also in location, feedstock
Some important insights into the effects of AF can be developed
use and technology employed flexibility. The new capacity can only
using graphical economics (see Fig. 1). To do this we use a two-time
operate in the region where it is constructed and generally, the avail-
period framework following Tietenberg and Lewis [22]. In the first
able technology limits feedstock use to a given class of feedstocks and
period, ethanol is supplied to the market from existing (panel a) and
particular cost structure. Second, the supply curve for new plants is
possibly new capacity (panel b) resulting in the composite supply as
flatter than that for existing plants to reflect the fact that larger capa-
portrayed in panel c. For existing plants the capital costs are sunk fixed
cities can be reached by constructing new plants while the existing
costs, and the marginal supply costs include only maintenance and
facilities have a steeper cost curve since they can only raise production
variable costs. Consequently, supply arises from existing plants at a
by employing more expensive forms of operation. Third, if new capacity
lower price that does supply from new plants as their use involves in-
were constructed in period one then there would be a shift in the period
curring both variable and fixed production costs.
two existing capacity supply curve as the fixed costs become sunk ones.
Now suppose we consider demand market equilibrium. In the period
Furthermore, as time progresses, more plants are constructed ex-
1 graph if the industry confronts demand curve AD1 then equilibrium
panding the existing capacity category in the period of construction and
price for fuel is below the entry price for new plants and thus only
subsequent periods up until the point at which the plant becomes
existing plants would be used. In that case, the equilibrium price is not
functionally obsolete. This all means that once built the industry is
high enough to induce new plant construction incurring their fixed and
much more likely to use the currently existing plants in their places
operating costs and no new plants are constructed.

38
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 2. Ethanol price projection scenarios based on AEO 2015.

FASOM contains demand curves for agricultural raw commodities and


processed goods. When solved, FASOM endogenously determines the
equilibrium price and quantity of all modeled agricultural primary and
secondary commodities by maximizing net market surplus given the
supply-demand balance constraints and resource restrictions. GHG ac-
counting is also incorporated. Broadly speaking the FASOM model
maximizes the net present value of consumers' and producers' surplus
which following McCarl and Spreen [23] leads to a simulation of an
economic equilibrium for all the modeled commodities in all the
modeled time periods. FASOM in this case simulates activities for 100
years in five year intervals. FASOM simulates crop and livestock pro-
duction in the 63 regions choosing acreage of each crop along with its
management in terms of irrigation use, fertilization, and tillage method.
This includes growing energy crops of switchgrass, energy sorghum,
Fig. 3. Ethanol Production by feedstock in Base scenarios with and without AF. miscanthus, short rotation poplar, and willow. It also includes potential
harvest of crop residues like corn stover, and wheat straw. Livestock
include beef, dairy, sheep, hogs and poultry. Resources constraining
with their characteristics and not to abandon those plants jumping
production include cropland, grazing land, irrigation water, family and
around chasing lower cost feedstock.
hired labor and for livestock available feed.
Additionally in the model regional productions move into livestock
4. Material and methods feed, demand, interregional transport, export or processing with im-
ports also allowed. The processing activities broadly convert crops to
4.1. FASOM overview mixed livestock feeds, sugar, soy meal and oil, corn syrup, crop ethanol,
cellulosic ethanol and biodiesel. Byproducts from processing can go into
So that we might examine the effects of including/excluding AF we further processing or feed. Livestock are also processed into meat, milk
needed a model structure where we could impose or neglect it. To do products, tallow and yellow grease. Readers wishing more details on
this we introduced option AF variables and constraints into the agri- FASOM should examine the on line documentation in Beach and McCarl
cultural sector component of the FASOM model that is under use in EPA [1], and Adams et al. [3].
analyses of ethanol market feedstock roles, refining locations, produc-
tion costs etc. [1,3,4]. FASOM is a dynamic, nonlinear, and price en-
dogenous model for the agricultural and forestry sectors in the con- 4.2. Modeling of asset fixity
tiguous U.S. with the rest of the world modeled as exogenous trading
regions. Here we use the agricultural component deactivating forestry. In the absence of AF, the FASOM model contained biofuel proces-
In the agriculture component the contiguous U.S. is divided into 63 sing variables that allowed the choice of producing region and feed-
production regions. Key decision variables are the allocation of land stock without any links between adjacent time periods. This meant that
over time to crop and livestock activities along with levels of process, it was free to, for example, generate ethanol at a plant in the Midwest
consumption, imports and exports of commodities, depicting the con- from corn stover in one time period then in the next generate the
sequential economic, social and environmental impacts. In total, ethanol from switchgrass in the Southeast. To model AF we separated
FASOM includes about 100 commodity types arising from 40 crops, 25 the ethanol variables into two parts; one for facility construction and
livestock production systems including 50 types of processed goods one for level of refining where the constructed capacity provided an
(with different types of ethanol production included). On the supply upper limit on refining. Additionally the capacity was made persistent
side, all the modeled commodities and production activities compete with for example construction in 2020 supplying capacity from 2020
for scarce resources such as land, labor, and other inputs (e.g. fertilizer, through to the end of the plants assumed life which we set at 30 years.
energy), leading to upward-sloping supply curves. On the demand side, In order to have capacity beyond that life a new plant would need to be

39
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 4. Ethanol production by region and feedstock in Base scenarios with and without AF.

built. In turn, the FASOM model decided where to locate processing operations, Yt , reg, process, class , was constrained by the cumulative capacity
facilities and their characteristics. of previously built and any newly built plants as in equation (1).
In setting up the investment an operating parts we used EPA and t
NREL (National Renewable Energy Laboratory) estimates of feedstock ∑ Yt , reg, process, class ≤ ∑ CAPclass Ztt , reg, class
bio-refining budgets and separated the costs into fixed and operating process tt = t − k
∈ p (class ) tt − k > 0
cost components. In turn, we developed an estimate that the capital
t
construction costs were 35% of the cost per gallon estimates and the
+ ∑ CAPclass ZPtt , reg, class
operating/variable cost components were 65%. We then formed the tt = t − k
investment variables as plant construction in a location at a fixed cost tt − k ≤≤ 0 (1)
equal to the net present value of 35% of the per gallon costs times the
Here the capacity is summed across all previously constructed
plant capacity over a 30 year operation and then had that supply the
plants in the previous k years where k is the economic life of the bio-
processing capacity for handling a particular feedstock class for 30
refinery, process identifies the specific bio-refinery production process
years. These feedstock classes then contain feedstocks with similar
product and treatment method (e.g. grain dry mill or switchgrass based
characteristics (see the class definitions in the Appendix).
cellulosic) and CAPclass is the capacity of plants built to handle feed-
In the modeling we also had to deal with technical progress. In
stocks in a type class. The capacity also includes plants that exist when
particular EPA and NREL both assume substantial processing cost re-
the model starts up (ZP). Also, a maximum rate of new construction was
ductions due to technological developments in the future. In the ex-
also incorporated. During the boom between 2005 and 2010 there were
isting FASOM model, in the absence of AF, the model can exploit the
many plants waiting construction due to capacity of contractors and we
falling costs producing at a relatively higher cost in 2020 and then
set the five year maximum as the amount built in 2005–2009.
going to a lower cost in 2025 and yet a lower one in 2030 etc. However,
the ability to take advantage of new technological developments is
limited once a plant is built, it is built to use a particular technology. 4.3. Analysis design
When we modified FASOM to incorporate AF we reflected this in the
capital and operating costs. In particular the capital costs were all in- To illustrate the impact of AF we did a number of model runs. First,
curred at the time the plant was built using the costs in place then not we ran AF and no AF cases without imposing the renewable fuel re-
future lower ones. Thus we did not let the costs continue to fall over quirements from the 2007 Energy Independence and Security Act
time rather locking in the technology and making the particular facility (which we will call RFS2). In the non-AF scenario we did not include
unable to take advantage of future technological developments. data on existing capacity.3
Mathematically, this involved adding a plant construction variable, Second, we examined effects of AF inclusion/exclusion in a setting
Zt , reg, class representing the amount of bio-refining capacity that is built where we imposed mandates for 2025 at the levels suggested in RFS2.
in period t in region reg that uses feedstocks in the group identified as This involved imposing constraints requiring 406 billion liters of
class.2 In turn the annual amount of ethanol production created by plant
3
Activating the existing capacity in the AF scenario would make ethanol
processing cost cheaper than the non-AF scenario since the cost for existing
2
A detailed list of the feedstock classes appears in Appendix I. capacity was sunk cost and not reflected in the model objective function.

40
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 5. Ethanol production by region and type in RFS2 scenarios with and without AF.
Note: CB: Corn Belt; GP: Great Plains; LS: Lake States; NE: Northeast; RM: Rocky Mountains; PSW: Pacific Southwest; PNWE: Pacific Northwest - east of the Cascade
mountain; SC: Southcentral; SE: Southeast; SW: Southwest.

ethanol blending with no more than 57 billion liters coming from corn 5. Results
grain and a minimum of 49 billion liters from cellulosic ethanol.4
Third, we set up several ethanol price scenarios in the absence of the 5.1. AF effects without RFS2
RFS2 requirements in an exercise designed to see how much cellulosic
ethanol was economically competitive with and without AF. The base Fig. 3 shows the ethanol production by feedstock in the absence of
scenario was set at $0.48 per liter (or $1.8 per gallon), an upper bound mandates with and without AF. In both scenarios ethanol production is
for the ethanol price observed from since 2016. The high price scenario projected to increase over time due to rising ethanol price and tech-
of $1.06 per liter (or $4 per gallon) was set as based on the existing RIN nological progress in agricultural crop yields lowering commodity
(Renewable Identification Number) price of $0.7/liter, which is the prices and in turn feedstock supply prices.
price obligated parties such as refinery facilities needed to pay to In the results a significant difference is observed between the AF and
ethanol producers under the RFS2 mandate, indicating the price gap non-AF scenarios. With AF present, the total amount of conventional
between cellulosic ethanol supply and demand without the current crop ethanol increased to 95 billion liters by 2050, about 16% lower
production mandate. Another scenario of $0.79/liter (or $3/gallon) than that in the non-AF projection (see Fig. 3). No cellulosic ethanol
was set as intermediate scenario between the base and high scenario. production was projected with AF in place, compared with 1.6 billion
Price in all three scenarios escalated at the rates projected in AEO liter in 2030 without AF scenario (about 0.83 billion from switchgrass,
(Annual Energy Outlook) 2016 (see Fig. 2). The model setup in this case 0.57 billion from bagasse and the rest from agricultural residues). This
did not have RFS2 mandates imposed but did have the NREL projected shows omitting AF biases upwards the market potential of cellulosic
reductions in cellulosic ethanol production costs. ethanol. More significant differences occur in the regional results as
discussed below.
As expected without AF (as indicated in Fig. 4 by the red lines),
4
RFS2 requires 61 billion liters (16 billion gallons) of cellulosic biofuel by unrealistic spatially varying variations in ethanol production were ob-
2022. Here we require 49 billion liters (13 billion gallons) of cellulosic ethanol served. For example, there were about 23 million liters of cellulosic
assuming the rest is fulfilled by advanced biodiesel production.

41
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 6. Ethanol production by price and type with and without AF.

ethanol production in the Pacific Southwest in 2025 but no production Mountain, Great Plains and Lake States. Such a production patterns
before or afterwards. Similar short-term variations were also observed would not be likely in reality as it implies building then abandoning
for other regions such as Pacific Northwest-east of the Cascade expensive facilities. The AF solution exhibited much more stability (See

42
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Fig. 7. Cellulosic ethanol production by feedstock in the AF model.

the blue lines in Fig. 4). Again ignoring AF allows the model solution to cellulosic ethanol was produced (prices above $0.79/liter). When
jump around exploiting lower costs and alternative regional rates of ethanol price increased to $1.06/liter, a considerable amount of
technological progress upwardly biases cellulosic ethanol production, switchgrass based ethanol entered (see Fig. 7).
leading to an over-optimistic prediction of market penetration.
6. Concluding comments
5.2. AF effects under RFS2
When a bioenergy plant is built, the location, capacity, processing
We also investigated the effects of AF under the renwable fuels technology and class of feedstock it can use are generally fixed, which
mandate obtaing the results shown in Fig. 5. Again omitting AF resulted we call asset fixity herein. Our results unsurprisingly show neglecting
in unrealistic production patterns. For example, about 8 billion liters asset fixity in a spatial, multi-feedstock model causes production, and
were produced in the Northeast in 2035 but this was reduced to 4 feedstock use to jump around between time periods. This permits pro-
billion in 2040 and disappeared in 2045. Also, more than 15 billion duction to occur with whatever technology, feedstock combination is
liters of ethanol production moved from the Great Plains to the Corn cheapest at that particular time. In other words, without asset fixity
Belt between 2015 and 2020. No such dramatic changes were observed assumption a model fail to consider continuity of biorefinery capacity at
once AF although there was a shift in Great Plains during 2040–2045 at a location as well as designed feedstock usage. Also this assumes plants
the end of a plants life. can utilize all technological developments as they come along without
any constraints imposed by refinery equipment and design. Running
with and without place, feedstock and cost stage fixity shows a sub-
5.3. AF and cellulosic ethanol competitiveness
stantial bias in fuel production costs and market share when the model
is allowed to cherry pick and does not have to lock in facility locations,
We also wanted to examine whether AF omission biased the prices
feedstock capabilities and cost structure.
at which ethanol would rise to the volumes contemplated by the RFS2
Collectively this shows that when models do not fully consider asset
in a competitive market. Fig. 6 shows total crop and cellulosic ethanol
fixity that their results can substantially understate the costs of ethanol
production for different price scenarios with and without AF. Here
production and or overstate potential market penetration. In particular,
under AF we only see mandate comparable volumes in 2025 if the price
in some of our analyses the consideration of asset fixity substantially
is $0.79 per liter or higher. On the other hand, without AF the projected
reduced production of both conventional and cellulosic ethanol ulti-
ethanol production is much higher.
mately eliminating cellulosic ethanol production.
A few more details are noteworthy. First, crop ethanol grows be-
This paper also examined the future economic competitiveness of
yond today's levels as the price escalates over time in all cases but at
cellulosic ethanol with different price projections with AF considered.
low prices, we see no real penetration from cellulosic sources. However,
The results showed free market ethanol production by 2025 only ap-
as initial ethanol price rises above $1.06/liter, then cellulosic ethanol
proached US legislatively contemplated levels if the price of fuel ap-
surpasses the 49-billion-liter level contemplated in RFS2 by 2025. This
proached $1.06 per liter compared to recent prices of $0.48 per liter.
was consistent with price plus RIN levels in June 2017 (gas was $0.41/
This is substantially greater than the highest historical ethanol price
liter and the cellulosic RIN price $0.7/liter, placing the price needed to
($0.68 per liter in 2006).6
induce cellulosic ethanol at $1.11/liter 5).
Second, let us examine the feedstocks used. On the first-generation
side corn was the dominant feedstock. For cellulosic, agricultural re- Acknowledgement
sidues, mainly corn stover, were the dominant feedstock when
This paper was partially funded by the Texas A&M Institute for
5
We used the following approximation formula as suggested by Dr. Wallace
6
E. Tyner: Pcell = Pgas ∗ 2/3 + RINcell where 2/3 adjusts the difference in energy See at: http://www.neo.ne.gov/statshtml/66.html. Accessed Feb. 26th,
content between gasoline and ethanol. 2017.

43
Z. Wang et al. Biomass and Bioenergy 122 (2019) 37–44

Advanced Study and an agreement with Environmental Protection interest to disclose.


Agency through Research Triangle Institute. We have no conflicts of

Appendix

When adding AF we required plants to be built with a choice of general type of feedstock to use where we grouped the feedstock types into
classes. For example, plants constructed that produce dry mill ethanol were assumed to be able to use both corn and sorghum, but were not allowed
to handle other feedstocks such as wheat or oats. We also defined similar AF classes for and biodiesel production. The classes and permitted
feedstocks for ethanol and biodiesel are listed in Table A1.

Table A1
Asset fixity classes and attached feedstocks modeled in FASOM

Bioenergy AF Class Feedstocks in the class

Crop Ethanol Dry Mill Ethanol Corn (Dry Mill), Sorghum


Wet Mill Ethanol Corn (Wet Mill)
Sugar Ethanol Sugar
Sweet Sorghum Ethanol Sweet Sorghum
Wheat Ethanol Five types of wheat -Soft White, Hard Red Winter, Soft Red Winter, Durum, Hard Red Spring
Oats Ethanol Oats
Rice Ethanol Rice
Barley Ethanol Winter Barley, Spring Barley
Cellulosic Ethanol Sweet Sorghum Pulp Cell Ethanol Sweet Sorghum Pulp
Bagasse Cell Ethanol Bagasse
Crop Residue Cell Ethanol Corn Residue, Wheat Residue, Sorghum Residue, Barley Residue, Oats Residue, Rice Residue
Grass Cell Ethanol Switchgrass
Wood Cell Ethanol Hybrid poplar, Willow
Biodiesel Biodiesel Oil Soybean Oil, Corn Oil, Corn Oil Non-food-grade, Canola Oil
Biodiesel Fats Tallow, Lard

References alternative agricultural productivity growth assumptions on land management,


greenhouse gas emissions, and mitigation potential, Am. J. Agric. Econ. 95 (2013)
435–441.
[1] R.H. Beach, B.A. McCarl, US Agricultural and forestry impacts of the energy in- [14] L. Johansen, Production Functions; an Integration of Micro and Macro, Short Run
dependence and security act: FASOM results and model description, Res. Triangle and Long Run Aspects, (1972) http://www.sidalc.net/cgi-bin/wxis.exe/?
Park NC RTI Int. (2010) 1–31 RTI Project Number 0210826.003 http://agecon2. IsisScript=COLPOS.xis&method=post&formato=2&cantidad=1&expresion=
tamu.edu/people/faculty/mccarl-bruce/FASOM.html. mfn=006062.
[2] EPA, Renewable Fuel Standard Program (RFS2) Regulatory Impact Analysis, [15] M.A. Fuss, The structure of technology over time: a model for testing the “putty-
Assessment and Standards Division, Office of Transportation and Air Quality, U.S. clay” hypothesis, Econom. J. Econom. Soc. (1977) 1797–1821.
Environmental Protection Agency, Ann Arbor, MI , 2010. [16] A. Atkeson, V.V. Chari, P.J. Kehoe, Taxing capital income: a bad idea, Fed, Reserve
[3] D.M. Adams, R.J. Alig, B.A. McCarl, B.C. Murray, FASOMGHG Conceptual Bank Minneap. Q. Rev.-Fed. Reserve Bank Minneap. 23 (1999) 3.
Structure, and Specification: Documentation, (2005) http://agecon2.tamu.edu/ [17] D. Rajagopal, D. Zilberman, On market-mediated emissions and regulations on life
people/faculty/mccarl-bruce/papers/1212FASOMGHG_doc.pdf. cycle emissions, Ecol. Econ. 90 (2013) 77–84.
[4] H.C. Lee, B.A. McCarl, U.A. Schneider, C.C. Chen, Leakage and comparative ad- [18] A.K. Dixit, R.S. Pindyck, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton university press,
vantage implications of agricultural participation in greenhouse gas emission mi- 1994, https://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=VahsELa_qC8C&oi=fnd&
tigation, Mitig. Adapt. Strategies Glob. Change 12 (2007) 471–494. pg=PR7&dq=dixit+pindyck+1994&ots=FCyVvBYakL&sig=
[5] G.L. Johnson, Supply function-some facts and notions, Probl. Grow. Econ. (1956) xNBNUAbZe6mjgcXBZrGr7o-E56Q.
74–93. [19] T. Skevas, S.M. Swinton, S. Tanner, G. Sanford, K.D. Thelen, Investment risk in
[6] D.G. Johnson, The nature of the supply function for agricultural products, Am. bioenergy crops, GCB Bioenergy 8 (2016) 1162–1177.
Econ. Rev. 40 (1950) 539–564, https://doi.org/10.2307/1808424. [20] T.E. Yu, Z. Wang, B.C. English, J.A. Larson, Designing a dedicated energy crop
[7] C. Edwards, Resource fixity and farm organization, J. Farm Econ. 41 (1959) supply system in Tennessee: a multiobjective optimization analysis, J. Agric. Appl.
747–759. Econ. 46 (2014) 357.
[8] G.L. Johnson, C.L. Quance, M.E. Abel, The overproduction trap in US agriculture, [21] F. You, L. Tao, D.J. Graziano, S.W. Snyder, Optimal design of sustainable cellulosic
Soil Sci. 116 (1973) 131. biofuel supply chains: multiobjective optimization coupled with life cycle assess-
[9] B.L. Gardner, Changing economic perspectives on the farm problem, J. Econ. Lit. 30 ment and input–output analysis, AIChE J. 58 (2012) 1157–1180.
(1992) 62–101. [22] T.H. Tietenberg, L. Lewis, Environmental and Natural Resource Economics,
[10] R.G. Chambers, U. Vasavada, Testing asset fixity for US agriculture, Am. J. Agric. Routledge, 2016, https://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=
Econ. 65 (1983) 761–769. 8ROtCwAAQBAJ&oi=fnd&pg=PP1&dq=tietenberg+lewis+2009&ots=
[11] C. Nelson, J.B. Braden, J.S. Roh, Asset fixity and investment asymmetry in agri- fEwdEb7n-x&sig=IkwYnWpP5Hi4qEKkr61GecVxhKI.
culture, Am. J. Agric. Econ. 71 (1989) 970–979. [23] B.A. McCarl, T.H. Spreen, Applied Mathematical Programming Using Algebraic
[12] S.H. Hsu, C.C. Chang, An adjustment-cost rationalization of asset fixity theory, Am. Systems, (1997) Cambridge, MA http://agecon2.tamu.edu/people/faculty/mccarl-
J. Agric. Econ. 72 (1990) 298–308. bruce/mccspr/thebook.pdf.
[13] J.S. Baker, B.C. Murray, B.A. McCarl, S.J. Feng, R. Johansson, Implications of

44

You might also like