You are on page 1of 10

Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Sustainable Production and Consumption


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/spc

Research article

A dynamic price model based on supply and demand with application


to techno-economic assessments of rare earth element recovery
technologies
Sidi Deng a,b,∗, Denis Prodius c, Ikenna C. Nlebedim c, Aihua Huang a, Yuehwern Yih b,
John W. Sutherland a
a
Environmental and Ecological Engineering, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907, United States
b
School of Industrial Engineering, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907, United States
c
Critical Materials Institute, Ames Laboratory, US Department of Energy, Ames, Iowa 50011-3020, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Rare Earth Elements (REEs) are essential for sustainable energy technologies. Techno-economic Assess-
Received 16 October 2020 ments (TEAs) have been conducted to evaluate innovative approaches to recover REEs from waste
Revised 5 March 2021
streams. However, most TEA studies do not consider the price volatility of REEs, which raises concern
Accepted 8 April 2021
over the reliability of the analysis in an unpredictable dynamic market. To address this shortcoming, a
Available online 20 April 2021
dynamic price model is proposed that adjusts REE price based upon supply-demand conditions. The dy-
Editor: Prof. Ignacio Grossmann namic market behavior is simulated and its effect on a TEA is examined via a case study. The results of
the dynamic simulation indicate a growing trend of the market price for REE materials/products. Com-
Keywords:
Rare earth elements pared to a conventional TEA that does not consider price dynamics, a significant difference in economic
Techno-economic assessment performance metrics is identified from the dynamic TEA results. The proposed dynamic TEA method is
Price oscillation not limited to a specific application and can provide insights for evaluating a broad range of technologies.
Price elasticity
© 2021 Institution of Chemical Engineers. Published by Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction elements are essential for sustainable technologies including pho-


tovoltaics, wind turbines, and electric and hybrid vehicles [1]. REEs
Worldwide production and consumption rely heavily on the use are distributed diffusely and are thus difficult to easily extract in
of limited natural resources. As industries around the globe transi- large and economically viable quantities. The uncertainty in the
tion to more sustainable and environmentally friendly approaches, global supply of REEs may be alleviated somewhat through recy-
there is a growing utilization of certain critical materials that have cling approaches. Although new innovative technologies are be-
essential and unique properties needed for advanced energy pro- ing explored to recover REEs from used products or other waste
duction, transmission, storage, and use. The products or systems streams, uncertainties still exist about the economic feasibility of
reliant on these critical materials are fast becoming key instru- recovery methods.
ments that are indispensable for clean energy technologies. This prompts the need for a rigorous examination of the eco-
The market volatility of critical materials (such as price spikes) nomic aspects of newly developed REE recovery methods. One
results from a disparity between the supply and demand, and has method for performing this economic examination is techno-
existed for decades. While global demand for these materials is ris- economic assessment (TEA), a technique that combines produc-
ing rapidly due to their extensive applications, the supply is sub- tion cost modeling with customer/financial analysis, and has
ject to disruption and often fails to match the increasing demand. been widely applied to provide guidelines for decision making
The complex dilemma surrounding critical materials is raising en- to optimize economic performance. At present, most TEAs are
vironmental, economic, political, and social concerns, which in turn conducted using static modeling assumptions without consider-
calls for intervention. ing fluctuations in market price. However, in light of the sup-
Currently, one of the most significant discussions relating to ply challenges of REEs, results from conventional TEA meth-
critical materials revolves around rare-earth elements (REEs). These ods may often be misleading. The purpose of this study is
to enhance a static TEA model with dynamic market behav-
∗ ior considerations based on supply and demand price elasticity.
Corresponding author.
E-mail address: deng100@purdue.edu (S. Deng). In particular, we aim to establish a “Dynamic TEA Model” that

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.04.013
2352-5509/© 2021 Institution of Chemical Engineers. Published by Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

search institutions to formulate innovative strategies to mitigate


Nomenclature the supply risk of REEs [8]. These efforts can be divided into three
categories: (1) diversify and expand REE sources [9,10], (2) reduce
QD Dynamic quantity of demand over time demand by identifying and developing substitutes [11,12], and (3)
QS Dynamic quantity of supply over time facilitate reuse and recycling to recover waste REEs [13,14]. In par-
P Market price of the product, with steady state de- ticular, new technologies are being explored to recover materials
noted as P∗ from used products and other waste streams. Both technical via-
y Relative change of P, with steady state denoted as bility and economic feasibility are crucial factors that incentivize a
y∗ transition towards sustainable production/consumption approaches
D Static quantity of demand in a fixed demand curve [15]. Notably, even if a clean energy approach exists, it will not be
S Static quantity of supply in a fixed supply curve implemented if it is not economically attractive [16]. To ensure the
α Demand shifter industrial deployment of these newly developed technologies, it is
β Supply shifter desirable to apply techno-economic assessments (TEAs) to analyze
u1 ( t) Relative change of demand shifter (α ) over time market opportunities and technical bottlenecks [17].
u2 ( t) Relative change of demand shifter (β ) over time Techno-economic assessment (TEA) is a tool used to evalu-
K1 Price elasticity of demand shifter (α ) ate the economic prospects of a project, process, or technology
K2 Price elasticity of supply shifter (β ) through production cost modeling and financial analysis [18]. It
ζ Damping ratio of the oscillator can provide decision-making insights to research and development.
ωn Natural frequency of the oscillator A TEA investigates all the cost components (e.g., operating, in-
direct, and capital expenses), and revenue components (earnings
from selling the product and non-operating income), to quantify
adjusts the revenue from selling REE-related products or output the economic performance by calculating multiple metrics, such as
materials. break-even point (BEP), net cash flow (NCF), and internal rate of
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. First, a brief return (IRR).
background on the supply and demand features of the REE mar- There is a need and growing trend for researchers to inves-
ket is provided. Then, a discussion is provided on how the ever- tigate the economic performance of clean and renewable energy
changing market supply-demand conditions contribute to the dy- technologies, e.g., microbial approaches [19]. Others have recovered
namic behavior of the price. After that, an oscillator model is pro- REEs from waste, for example, coal ash [20] and cracking catalysts
posed to incorporate the dynamic market features into the TEA [21]. Even though some TEAs consider the time value of money by
framework, where the mathematical formulation is established applying discount rate for future cash flows, as with the biosorp-
based upon the concept of price elasticity. Finally, a case study of tion process considered by Reed et al. [22], the selling prices of
REE recovery from waste hard disk drives (HDDs) is presented to the target products or materials are assumed to be constant. In
demonstrate the application of the proposed dynamic TEA model. view of this, the result of a TEA that relies on static cost-benefit
analysis would be badly flawed in a situation where the demand
2. Literature review is growing geometrically and supply is at risk. Particularly, when
evaluating the economic feasibility of a REE-related project, most
The 15 Lanthanide elements, along with the chemically similar traditional TEAs do not anticipate a potentially forthcoming large
elements scandium and yttrium, are often collectively known as increase in REE prices, which can undermine the reliability of the
the rare earth elements [1]. The reasons that they are considered conclusion.
as critical materials can be explained from two aspects: demand To address the market uncertainty that is essential in deter-
and supply. In terms of demand, the unique physical and chemical mining economic feasibility, one potential solution is to incorpo-
properties make REEs indispensable for various products, and there rate dynamic market behavior into the TEA model by adjusting
are no easy substitutes that can alleviate the demand pressure the unit price of products/materials based on supply and demand
without compromising performance or product quality [2]. During relationships. The conventional approaches that study price fluc-
the past twenty years, there has been an explosion in demand for tuations are primarily based on time-series analysis of historical
many applications that require REEs, such as fluorescent lighting, price data. Common techniques, including exponential smoothing
cell phones, and computers. Moreover, as growing environmental and curve fitting, are applied to capture the features of existing
concerns call for sustainable energy approaches, there is a greater data and extrapolate future trends [23]. Based on statistical infer-
emphasis on electric vehicle (EV) and wind energy technologies. ence, future prices can be estimated through stochastic simulation
Consequently, as the market of motors and generators using mag- or univariate-based machine learning [24]. One inherent problem
nets made with rare earth compounds burgeons, the demand for of the conventional price prediction methods is that they often
REEs continues to soar [3]. fail to characterize the extreme events that may cause the price to
Apart from the increasing demand, the global REE supply is un- surge or plummet, such as a market shortage or a policy change.
stable and susceptible to interruptions. Because of their geochem- This is because it is difficult to infer the patterns of market contin-
ical properties, REEs are typically dispersed and not often found gencies solely based on price data, without a good understanding
in concentrated ore deposits for their exploitation to be economi- of the underlying forces that govern price dynamics.
cally viable [4,5]. Furthermore, the unequal geographic distribution Instead of resorting to pure statistical methods, this work will
has led to economic and political challenges to secure the REE sup- study the price dynamics from a microeconomics perspective by
ply chain. In fact, China dominates global production/processing of exploring the classical economic model of price determination
REEs and when it curtailed its exports in 2011, this resulted in REE based on supply and demand.
prices skyrocketing by a factor of about 15 [6]. Additionally, envi-
3. Methods
ronmental regulations and policies may also impose challenges on
REE supply reliability [7]. 3.1. Dynamic market behavior
Due to the imbalance between global supply and demand, the
market for REEs is often subject to unpredictable fluctuations. This In microeconomics, the quantities of supply and demand are
growing REE market crisis calls for government, industry, and re- regarded as functions of the price of the product. The standard

1719
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

Fig. 1. Static and dynamic price model comparison.

graphical representation for this is known as the supply-demand will undergo some fluctuations before reaching the new equilib-
curves, which has price on the vertical axis and quantity on the rium. A general price response over time after the shift has oc-
horizontal axis [25]. Generally, a market equilibrium is defined to curred can be illustrated by the conceptual graph at the right-hand
be a situation where the quantity demanded is exactly balanced side of Fig. 1.
by the quantity supplied in a market. It can be graphically rep- After a shift of demand has occurred, there will be no supply
resented by the intersection of supply and demand curves (to be response in the very short term, since time is required for the sup-
further discussed later). pliers to increase their production, and new products will not en-
However, the supply and demand curves are only a two- ter the market straightaway. Because of this, a market shortage will
dimensional representation of a multi-variable function and the immediately emerge. Therefore, customers are willing to purchase
quantities of supply and demand are not exclusively influenced by products with a relatively high price. When a shortage suddenly
the price [26]. The changes in any other determinants of the sup- occurs, hypothetically, the market status will instantaneously move
ply or demand functions cause the curve to shift to a new posi- from e1 to e1 , and the price will undergo a drastic surge at the
tion, which is referred to as “change in demand/supply” or “shifts” beginning. However, the market shortage (higher price) also acts
of the curves [27]. A shift (change in demand or change in sup- as an inducement for suppliers to increase their production. As
ply) could be triggered by some underlying exogenous factors com- the suppliers take actions to meet the demand, the full increase
monly known as “shifters.” Since demand directly relates to the in price will not be achieved; rather the expected increase will
willingness and ability of customers to purchase a product/service, be attenuated. When the price reaches its peak value P3 (which
a change in demand can be caused by changes in income, popu- is smaller than the price at e1 since the shortage has been miti-
lation, price of substitutes/complements, expectations/preferences, gated), the market surplus caused by overproduction of the prod-
etc. Regarding the supply curve, the quantity supplied at a given uct is prominent enough to bring down the price, which is a signal
market price can be interpreted as the quantity that producers are to discourage supply. As the price and supply quantities fall below
willing and able to sell in order to make a profit; so the shape their equilibrium values, the market then undergoes a new period
and position of the supply curve are determined by the factors of temporal shortage but less severe, after which the price rises
that influence the production cost. Hence, the supply shifters could again. Assuming that the market converges to a new steady state,
include input prices, taxes and subsidies, opportunity costs, and the price will overshoot and cross the destined equilibrium price
technological innovations. (P2 ) several times, as it oscillates with a gradually decreasing am-
The supply and demand curves serve as a static model that plitude.
graphically depicts market steady state before and after a shift. Interestingly, the moving pattern of the price can be analo-
However, it fails to describe the micro progression as the market gized to an underdamped physical system that displays harmonic
moves from one equilibrium to another. Consequently, it is not ap- motion. Such a system may be described by an oscillator model
plicable in many situations, especially for an REE market that is [28] to analyze the mechanism of price dynamics, as shown in
undergoing continuous fluctuations. To take account of the price Fig. 2. Note that the coefficients in the annotation will be discussed
volatility, it is required to establish a dynamic price model that in Section 3.2.
better reflects realistic market behavior. This mechanical oscillator model can interpret market behav-
To elucidate the difference between static and dynamic mod- ior using descriptions from physics [29]. A classic damped har-
els, consider a scenario where the demand of a product has just monic oscillator consists of three components: mass, spring, and
increased. From the perspective of static analysis, as Fig. 1 shows, damper. Here the price is analogous to the vertical position of the
when the position of a demand curve shifts from D1 to D2 , the mass, and the supply and demand shifters serve as external driving
market equilibrium will shift from an old state (e1 , with price P1 ) forces that trigger the oscillation. As the traders (suppliers and cus-
to a new state (e2 , with price P2 ). However, the transition will not tomers) tend to make transactions that performed well in the past
happen either instantly or monotonically. Instead, the market price [30], there is a momentum of price movement that keeps the price

1720
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

demand curve has shifted outward. The repositioning of the static


demand curve and the corresponding dynamic market reaction are
visualized in Fig. 3.
As evident in Fig. 3, by observing the horizontal dashed lines
at different prices, there are gaps between QD and QS as long as
the price is not at the equilibrium. This is exactly this difference
that forces the price to move and converge to the equilibrium, and
the rate of price change (i.e., the derivative of P) is proportional to
QD –QS as explained by Eq. (3).
Rather than considering the actual price, the relative change in
price, may be considered. Suppose the initial price is P0 , and the
Fig. 2. The supply-demand oscillator model.
price at an arbitrary time is P; the relative change of price is de-
fined by rescaling P as y = (P-P0 )/P0 . Suppose the price at steady
moving in a certain direction, e.g., an upward moving price tends state is denoted as P∗ . Accordingly, the relative change of price can
to keep moving upward. Whenever there is a market shortage or de denoted as y∗ . The behavior of the market system will be easily
surplus, the traders adjust their activities and act to push back the interpreted by monitoring the y, which in turn allows the model
price to the equilibrium point. This phenomenon can be physically to be adapted to other scenarios, since the relative change of price
interpreted as the mechanical force from the spring that is propor- does not concern the specific value of price.
tional to the deviation of the mass from the equilibrium. Further- Eqs. (1)-(3) can be rewritten in terms of y as a single sec-
more, assuming both suppliers and customers prefer a stable mar- ond order differential equation (as shown by Eq. (6)) by inserting
ket, the market activities will mechanically prevent the price from P = P0 y+P0 into Eq. (1):
excessively drastic change. This is a feedback for the rate of change
and can be characterized by the damper in mechanical system. d2 y 1 − λ(α2 + β2 ) dy α1 + β1 α0 − α1 P0 − (β0 + β1 P0 )
+ + y= .
dt 2 λ(α3 + β3 ) dt α3 + β3 P0 (α3 + β3 )
3.2. Modeling principles (6)

To reach a market equilibrium, it is required that the quantity The right-hand side of Eq. (6) serves as the system input, that
of supply be equal to the quantity of demand, i.e., QD = QS . Gener- is, the driving force that elicits system behavior. Let us observe its
ally, price is determined by producers (suppliers) and adjusted in numerator closely. α 0 -α 1 P0 is in fact the demand quantity at the
the light of circumstances. To put it simply, when there is excess equilibrium and β 0 +β 1 P0 is essentially the supply quantity at the
demand, price will rise, whereas when there is excess supply, price equilibrium. This can be easily verified by assigning the deriva-
will go down. Based on this principle, a simple model for market tive terms as 0 in Eq. (1). The shifting behaviors of the supply
dynamics for a general commodity was proposed by Sandoval et al. or demand curves are equivalent to changes in α 0 , α 1 , β 0 , and
[31]: β 1 . Or equivalently, a shift happens when the steady state price
P ∗ = (α0 − β0 )/(α1 + β1 ) has been updated, i.e., the system will
QD = α0 − α1 P + α2 P˙ − α3 P̈ , (1) move from an old equilibrium to a new equilibrium.
To completely describe the system dynamics, all the parameters
QS = β0 + β1 P − β2 P˙ + β3 P̈ , (2) in Eq. (6) (α -terms, β -terms, and λ) have to be defined, which also
indirectly explains the dynamics of supply and demand as shown
in Eq. (1) and (2). However, the estimation of all these parameters
P˙ = λ(QD − QS ). (3) is challenging and requires numerous assumptions. In addition, it
may be the case that in practice there are correlations between the
Here the quantities of supply and demand, as well as the price
parameters. Given this issue, it is desirable to construct a simpli-
P are assumed to be continuous functions of time. The terms P˙
fied expression with less parameters that make the dynamic price
and P̈ denote the first and second derivative of P with respect to
model more manageable. As discussed above, the price plot in the
time t. All the α -terms, β -terms, and λ are assumed to be posi-
time domain resembles the fluctuation pattern of an oscillator. This
tive constants. To interpret the expressions in this dynamic model,
inspires us to directly implement the classic underdamped har-
P˙ can be considered as the “tendency” or “momentum.” A positive
monic oscillator model (as shown in Fig. 2) to characterize the
P˙ indicates that the market has perceived an upward tendency of
price dynamics. In other words, we can use the standard form of
price. Accordingly, the P̈ terms (−α3 P̈ and +β3 P̈ ) can be analogized
the second-order linear differential equation that mathematically
as “inertia,” which resist the impact of “tendency,” as their coef-
describes a general underdamped oscillator [32,33] as a shortcut
ficients have opposite signs from that of the P˙ terms (+α2 P˙ and
to reformulate Eq. (6).
−β2 P˙ ).
To establish this simplified expression for the price dynamics,
By assigning the derivative terms to 0 in Eqs. (1) to (3) and
some additional terms need to be defined. Let α denote a param-
setting QD and QS to be equal, we obtain the equilibrium price as
eter that shifts the demand curve and β denote a parameter that
P ∗ = (α0 − β0 )/(α1 + β1 ). At the equilibrium, the dynamic system
shifts the supply curve. Note that α and β can be treated as either
can be assumed to be in a "stable" or “static” position, i.e., QD = D,
single shifters or “compound shifters” that aggregate the impacts
QS = S. Thus, we also have:
of multiple shifters as listed in the background section. The static
D = α0 − α1 P, (4) quantities of demand and supply are defined as D = D (P, α ) and
S = S (P, β ), respectively. The definitions of D and S imply that the
demand shifter α will have no impact on the supply curve, and
S = β0 + β1 P. (5)
supply shifter β will have no impact on the demand curve.
This can be considered as the implicit static model behind the The inputs of the oscillator system should quantify the degree
dynamic model, which is linear. To illustrate the market behavior to which the demand and supply curves have shifted at a given
that accompanies this linear model, without loss of generality, con- time t. Applying a similar idea as when we defined y, let u1 (t) rep-
sider a case where an increase in demand has occurred, i.e., the resent the real-time relative change of the demand shifter α , and

1721
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

Fig. 3. Static and dynamic model comparison of the simple linear model.

u2 (t) denote the real-time relative change in the supply shifter β . And K2 is exactly the price elasticity of the supply shifter, which
Since the shifters can be abstract concepts, by rescaling a shifter by measures the price’s sensitivity to a change in the supply shifter β .
the relative change, we have avoided obscuring the physical inter- The settings for K1 and K2 will have deterministic impacts on the
pretation of its magnitude. Based on the input and output defini- extent of fluctuation of the price response, and will be addressed
tions above, by adopting the conventional notations for an under- in detail in the following subsection.
damped oscillator, the oscillator model can be written in standard
form as: 3.3. Applying the concept of elasticity
d2 y dy
+ 2ζ ωn + ωn2 y = K1 ωn2 u1 (t ) + K2 ωn2 u2 (t ). (7) The elasticity of a variable Y with respect to another variable X
dt 2 dt
is termed the “X-elasticity of Y” [35], and may be denoted as eY,X .
It is assumed that 0<ζ <1, so the discriminant term (2ζ ωn − )2
It measures the fractional response of Y to a fractional change in
4ωn2 = 4ωn2 (ζ 2 − 1 ) is negative, regardless of the model inputs.
X, and can be expressed as:
Thus, while Eq. (6) describes a wide range of second order dynamic
systems, Eq. (7) is limited to the underdamped systems, where the Y/Y dY X
eY,X = = . (11)
amplitude of the oscillation will gradually decay until the system X/X dX Y
reaches a steady state. In other words, as a special case for Eq. (6),
Elasticity quantifies the degree of sensitivity of the output Y
Eq. (7) can be a simpler and more befitting model to characterize
in response to the input X, rather than directly providing a static
the converging price fluctuations to the equilibrium point. By re-
prediction from an empirical function. Elasticity can be estimated
placing the coefficient of each term in Eq. (6) with its correspond-
based on historical data and statistical analysis, which makes a
ing coefficient in Eq. (7), we can reduce the parameters required
prediction based on elasticity more reliable than a baseless pos-
to describe the model to four: the damping ratio ζ , the natural
tulation. Moreover, as a dimensionless ratio that is independent of
frequency ωn , and the gains K1 & K2 . These parameters can be eas-
variable units, elasticity greatly simplifies its interpretation.
ily interpreted using their corresponding physical concepts as illus-
Since the elasticity terms K1 and K2 may be calculated through
trated in Fig. 2.
empirical studies, they can be used as a proxy to establish the
Based on Eq. (6) and (7), the relative price change at equilib-
static price model, i.e., to help avoid defining the exact expression
rium is (see Supporting Information):
of the supply and demand curves as in Eq. (4) and (5). Besides,
y∗ = K1 u1 (t ) + K2 u2 (t ). (8) elasticity can be used to separately analyze the price sensitivity
to an individual factor. This is crucial for studying the oscillator
Therefore, the impacts of the supply shifter and demand shifter
model, since it is assumed that all the external “forces” applied to
can be analyzed separately. Suppose the supply curve is fixed, i.e.,
the underdamped system are independent of one another.
u2 (t) = 0. The demand shifter u1 (t) is assumed to be constant at
The next step is to numerically determine the values of K1
the steady state. Thus,
and K2 . As explained by its expressions, K1 can be interpreted as
y∗ %ChangeofPrice the change in price P caused by a given change in the demand
K1 = = . (9)
u1 (t ) %Changeofα shifter α . Therefore, using the conventional terminologies from
economics, essentially K1 is the “α elasticity of the price”, denoted
It turns out that the expression of K1 precisely matches the def-
as eP,α . In the same way, K2 can be termed as the “β elasticity of
inition of price elasticity of the demand shifter in economics [34],
the price”, which is denoted as eP,β . Intuitively, they characterize
as it measures the price’s sensitivity to the demand shifter α .
the effect of a small change in one of the exogeneous parameters
Similarly, suppose the demand curve is fixed, i.e., u1 (t) = 0, we
then have:
α or β on the market equilibrium price [26]. Without loss of gen-
erality, we assume that α and β are independent.
y∗ % Change of Price Let us first only consider the impact of a shift in demand while
K2 = = . (10)
u2 (t ) % Change of β the supply curve is fixed. Specifically, we will analyze the price’s

1722
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

response to a shift in demand by varying α while keeping β con- Again, assuming S = D = Q, it follows that:
stant. By the application of differential calculus and the general ∂S
chain rule, we have the total derivatives of demand D and supply dP β ∂β β
K2 = eP,β = = ∂D
S with respect to α as: dβ P − ∂S P
∂P ∂P
(19)
∂S β ∂S β
dD dD(P, α ) ∂ D dP ∂ D dα ∂ D dP ∂ D ∂β Q ∂β S eS,β
= = + = + , and (12) =  ∂D  = ∂D = .
dα dα ∂ P dα ∂α dα ∂ P dα ∂α ∂S P P
− ∂∂ PS P eD,P − eS,P
∂P − ∂P Q ∂P D S

The denominator of K2 is exactly the negative of that of K1 . On


dS dS(P, β ) ∂ S dP ∂ S dβ ∂ S dP the other hand, its numerator, eS,β , which characterizes the sup-
= = + = . (13)
dα dα ∂ P dα ∂β dα ∂ P dα ply’s sensitivity with respect to the shifter β , can also be adjusted
by the specific shifter β under study.
As is numerically evident from Eqs. (12) and (13), the supply It has been identified that both K1 and K2 can be expressed in
will not be directly influenced by α . Instead, the supply will re- terms of eD,P (<0) and eS,P (>0), and that these two price elastic-
spond to the change in equilibrium price (as the term ∂ S/∂ P in ities are usually obtained by examining the static supply and de-
Eq. (13) implies), and the equilibrium price will be shifted when α mand curves. As discussed in Section 3.2, the dynamic oscillator
changes (as dP/dα in Eq. (12) and (13) implies). Suppose the mar- model implies that both D (P, α ) and S (P, β ) are linear. For linear
ket reaches a new equilibrium after a shift in demand, it means supply and demand curves, the price elasticities of demand and
that dD/dα = dS/dα . Then we obtain: supply (eD,P and eS,P ) are not constant. Instead, they change as the
∂D
price changes [26], which in turn makes it impossible to derive
dP
= ∂ S ∂α ∂ D . (14) fixed values for K1 and K2 .

∂P − ∂P In fact, the linear oscillator model as described by
Eq. (7) should be considered as a linear approximation of the
Recall that our goal is not to analyze the supply-demand pro- “true” price dynamics, and accordingly the associated static model
cess by analyzing derivatives based on specific algebraical con- D (P, α ) and S (P, β ) can be considered as linear approximations of
struction of supply and demand curves. Instead, we intend to use the “true” demand and supply curves. In view of this, one possible
the concept of elasticity as a shortcut. Based on the symbolic ex- solution to define fixed elasticities is to model the “true” static
pression dP/dα , it follows that K1 , the α -elasticity of the price eP,α , supply and demand curves as nonlinear isoelastic functions. Then
can be calculated according to Eq. (11). By denoting the equilib- the elasticities extrapolated from the nonlinear form can be used
rium quantity of supply and demand as Q (Q = S = D), the deriva- as estimations for the fixed eD,P and eS,P , which determine the K1
tion of K1 is as follows: and K2 in the linear oscillator model.
∂D
A general isoelastic function can be expressed in exponential
dP α α form as Y = aXb . Given this functional form, elasticity can be writ-
K1 = eP,α = = ∂ S ∂α ∂ D
dα P − P ten as:
∂P ∂P
∂D α ∂D α
(15)
eD,α dY X X
=  ∂S
∂α Q
 = ∂S ∂α D = . eY,X = = abX b−1 b = b. (20)
∂D P ∂ dX Y aX
S,P − eD,P
P D P e
∂P − ∂P Q ∂P S
− ∂P D
So, in this case the “X-elasticity of Y” is exactly the exponent
We conclude that K1 can be expressed in terms of three differ- parameter, b. A logarithmic transformation of the X-Y relationship
ent elasticities. The two terms in the denominator are frequently results in ln Y = ln a+b ln X, which allows b to be estimated
referred as “price elasticity of supply” and “price elasticity of de- through a linear regression model with ln X as the input variable,
mand,” which can be inferred from historical data. The term eD,α in and lnY as the output variable. With this in mind, we define the
the numerator characterizes the demand’s sensitivity to the shifter “true” demand curve as D = a1 Pb1 , which may be approximated
α . Since there are many factors that can shift the demand curve, as D= α 0 - α 1 P in Eq. (4), with b1 representing the price elasticity
the value of eD,α will depend on the specific α that is investigated. of demand (eD,P ). Similarly, the “true” supply curve is defined as
The impact of β on the equilibrium price can be analyzed in a S = a2 Pb2 , which is approximated as S = β 0 + β 1 P in Eq. (5), with
similar way. For both demand and supply, we obtain the deriva- b2 representing the price elasticity of supply(eS,P ).
tives with respect to β , where α is fixed. Recall that a “shift” in either supply or demand is caused by
the shifter α or β rather than a change in price. To mathemat-
dD dD(P, α ) ∂ D dP ∂ D dα ∂ D dP ically explain this, a1 can be perceived as a function of the de-
= = + = (16)
dβ dβ ∂ P dβ ∂α dβ ∂ P dβ mand shifter α , and a2 can be perceived as a function of the supply
shifter β . Whether the demand and supply curves shift or not, i.e.,
dS dS(P, β ) ∂ S dP ∂ S dβ ∂ S dP ∂ S whether α and β stay constant or not, the elasticities (b1 and b2 )
= = + = + . (17)
dβ dβ ∂ P dβ ∂β dβ ∂ P dβ ∂β will not be influenced. Therefore, elasticity separates the impacts
from price and impacts from shifters on the supply/demand quan-
Similar to the way α indirectly influences the supply, although tity, which makes it particularly suitable to analyzing supply and
the demand curve will not be directly shifted by β , the demand demand curves with exponential forms. To sum up, the shifters (α
quantity at the equilibrium will still change in response to a and β ) influence the curves by altering the scalar parameters (a1
change in β . That is because the equilibrium quantity of demand and a2 ), which are independent from the exponent parameters (b1
is related to equilibrium price (as the term ∂ D/∂ P in Eq. (16) im- and b2 ) that represent the price elasticities.
plies), and P varies as β changes(as the term dP/dβ in Eq. (16) and With nonlinear static models for supply and demand curves de-
(17) indicates). fined, the next step is to estimate the elasticity (b1 and b2 ) through
By setting Eqs. (16)and (17) equal to one another we obtain: regression. Historical data regarding the supply, demand, and
prices of different REE products from 1998 to 2018 in the United
∂S
dP ∂β States were collected from the U.S. Geological Survey (USGS) an-
= ∂D . (18) nual mineral commodities summaries [36]. There were multiple
dβ ∂S
∂P − ∂P sources of price data for different categories of REE products, and

1723
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

the most representative one needed to be selected. The price data is a piecewise function that maintains a constant value throughout
for mischmetal were available for each year, which makes it a rel- the year (the time unit) and updates its value at the end of each
atively consistent and reliable data source compared to data for year. Equivalently, this implies that the static demand curve shifts
other REEs. It is also noteworthy that mischmetal is mainly com- to a new position at the beginning of each year.
posed of Ce, La, and Nd (with perhaps a small amount of Pr) [37], We then define u2 (t), i.e., the relative change of β that quan-
which are some of the most commonly utilized REEs. Thus, mis- tifies the future supply behavior. As noted in Section 2, there are
chmetal is a good proxy for the price behavior of the overall REE increasing concerns about the reliability of the REE supply chain.
market. Therefore, we selected the price of mischmetal as a price Hence, first u2 (t) was assumed to be a piecewise function that
index to establish a multipurpose price model for most REEs. takes random values from a normal distribution with a mean of
After some necessary data preprocessing, model adjustments, 0 and a standard deviation of 0.1. Additionally, since we expect the
and parameter tuning (see Supporting Information for details), val- US supply to have a downward trend, we only keep the negative
ues of eD,P = -2.4863 and eS,P = 0.4472 were obtained from regres- values. A change in u2 (t) indicates a shift of the static supply curve,
sion. So, the shifter-elasticities of supply and demand can be cal- which only happens at the beginning of each year.
culated as: Similar to the assumptions for model coefficients, it is noted
eD,α eD,α that the input functions u1 (t) and u2 (t) were defined for demon-
K1 = = = 0.3409eD,α , and (21)
eS,P − eD,P 0.4472 − (−2.4863 ) stration. And they can always be customized for other situations.
The simulated dynamic relative/percentage change of REE price y
eS,β eS,β from year 1 to year 20 along with the values of model inputs u1 (t)
K2 = = = −0.3409eS,β . (22)
eD,P − eS,P −2.4863 − 0.4472 and u2 (t), are illustrated in Fig. 4.
With every coefficient of the oscillator model now estimated, As can be observed from the three plots in Fig.. 4, whenever
the next section will demonstrate how the oscillator model works the demand and supply shift instantly, the price will not reach a
to describe the REE price in a dynamic market, and how the dy- new steady value straightaway (although it responds immediately).
namic features can be applied in a TEA. Instead, the price of REE will be updated every month and grad-
ually converge to a value. The response y of the oscillator mani-
4. Results fests the synergistic impact from both demand shifter α and sup-
ply shifter β . It is possible that a new shift would occur before the
4.1. Simulating the dynamic price price reaches a steady state.
As y represents the estimated dynamically-changing price for
The oscillator will predict REE prices through a dynamic sim- the 20-year duration of the simulation, it is denoted as a dynamic
ulation, which will be conducted under a synthetic market sce- price index. In the next subsection, a case study will be used to
nario. Let us first define ζ and ωn ; these two coefficients together demonstrate how to incorporate this dynamic price index into the
are enough to define the homogeneous dynamics of the system. techno-economic assessment framework.
Without loss of generality, the damping ratio ζ is assumed to be
0.2. We set the time for a single undamped oscillation period as 6 4.2. Case study: Recovering REE from HDDs
months, which implies that there are 2 oscillation cycles per year,
so the undamped natural frequency ωn equals to 2π × 2 = 4π . To provide critical resources needed for clean energy technolo-
To fully define K1 and K2 from Eq. (21) and (22), we assume the gies, it has been suggested that REEs may be recovered from used
value of eD,α to be 7.0 (which quantifies the demand’s sensitivity to hard disk drives (HDDs) [39]. It is also to be noted that there is a
the demand shifter α ), and the value of eS,β to be 5.0 (which quan- currently high availability of used HDDs and the disposal of used
tifies the supply’s sensitivity to the shifter β ). Note that although HDDs is carefully managed for data security purposes [40]. These
these predetermined values were selected arbitrarily, it does not factors serve to incentivize the development of innovative tech-
limit the applicability of the model to just this particular scenario. nologies for value recovery from HDDs. In this study, we performed
All the numerical assumptions are intended to help easily demon- a TEA on a newly developed acid-free leaching process for HDD
strate how the dynamic price model operates, and the magnitudes value recovery, developed by Ames Laboratory [41]. This leach-
of eD,α and eS,β can always be adjusted according to a specific sit- ing technology can be illustrated by the simplified process flow
uation. diagram shown in Fig. 5. The feedstock of this approach is the
As discussed above, the complete expression for the oscillator End-of-Life (EoL) HDDs that contain Nd-Fe-B magnets. At the first
model can be written as: step, shredded HDD-magnets are dissolved using CuSO4 solution at
room temperature. Followed by filtration, precipitation, and calci-
d2 y dy
+ 5.03 + 157.91y = 376.83u1 (t ) − 269.16u2 (t ). (23) nation, the process produces rare earth oxide (primarily Nd2 O3 ),
dt 2 dt FeSO4 , and copper powder as the main outputs. Based on the ex-
The model simulates the market contingency or fluctuations by perimental data, around 0.32 metric tons of rare earth oxide (REO)
predefining the system input u1 (t) and u2 (t) as specific functions can be produced per year through processing 125 metric tons of
(e.g., step, impulse, periodic functions), and these functions charac- EoL HDDs.
terize the expected tendency or variations of the shifter variables A TEA was conducted to analyze the economic performance of
(i.e., α and β ). If necessary, random noise can also be applied to the new technology on the basis of a 20-year industrial-scale op-
input functions to represent market uncertainties. eration. Based on the mass and energy flow analysis, the cost and
Assuming that January of 2020 is the starting point (origin on revenue components were identified and modeled. A normal TEA
the time axis), we simulated the REE price for the next 20 years. that does not consider the dynamic features shows that the project
To define u1 (t), we plan to use the REE investment amount as the is economically feasible: the net present value (NPV) is $1.2M, and
indicator α , which is assumed to be proportional to the GDP of the the internal rate of return (IRR) turns out to be 38%. More informa-
United States (at the official exchange rate). In this setting, the rate tion including detailed process flow, cost and revenue breakdowns
of change in GDP will be the same as the rate of change in REE in- and comprehensive TEA outputs are available in Supporting Infor-
vestment. The GDP data for the next 20 years were predicted with mation.
machine learning methods based on historical data [38] (this is ex- The next step is to incorporate the market dynamics of REEs
plained in detail in the Supporting Information). In summary, u1 (t) into the TEA framework. A TEA model with dynamic features is

1724
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

Fig. 4. REE price dynamic simulation.

Fig. 5. Process flow diagram for acid-free REE leaching route.

1725
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

Fig. 6. Net cash flow (NCF) comparison between normal and dynamic TEA models.

denoted as “dynamic TEA,” contrary to the normal TEA. As dis- its underlying factors: supply and demand. The proposed oscilla-
cussed above, by simulating the dynamic behavior of the oscilla- tor model simulated how exactly the market equilibrium moves
tor price model, we have obtained the dynamic price index y that over time in response to shifts in the supply and demand. The
indicates the relative change of the REE prices. For the dynamic study also highlights the benefits of using a mechanical system as
TEA model, all products are assumed to be sold every month with an inspiration to model economic features and extends the utility
equal amount (note that the selling frequency and amount distri- of price elasticities of supply and demand. The freedom of choice
bution can be adjusted). The prices for REO products will be up- for input functions endows tremendous flexibility upon the oscil-
dated every month based on the value of y as illustrated in Fig. 4. lator model. As the input functions can be customized for various
The monthly revenue gained from selling the REO products can be market scenarios, the model allows us to simulate certain extreme
considered as “dynamic revenue” that will be constantly changing events that are hard to manifest from the results of conventional
over the plant life. time-series analysis. This study will also provide policymakers with
To summarize how the oscillation model contributes to the decision-making guidelines since governmental interventions (e.g.,
analysis, a comparison for the net cash flow (NCF) of the normal legislation, taxes, subsidies, investments, and trade policies) can be
and dynamic TEA outputs are given in Fig. 6. characterized as demand and supply shifters. By applying the os-
Since the major revenue source for this case study is actually cillator model, the impact of new policies on the market price can
the data destruction fee charged for e-waste management, and due be simulated and evaluated first to prevent strategic failure.
to the limited amount of REO that can be extracted from the HDDs, One limitation of the price dynamic model might be the issue
the impact of dynamic revenues from selling REE-products is not of overgeneralization. The model assumes the same demand and
particularly dominant. However, if we examine the data closely, we supply tendencies (as described by u1 (t) and u2 (t)) for all REEs. In
do observe more promising economic performance with the dy- regard to supply, this is acceptable, since REEs are often co-mined,
namic price index added to the analysis. The NPV of the dynamic and the supply of individual REEs tends to be highly correlated.
TEA output is about 31% higher than that of the normal (static) However, the demand varies according to the REE type, and de-
TEA, and the internal rate of return (IRR) increases from 38% to pends on the market for products derived from individual REEs.
57%. All these results indicate that incorporating dynamic behav- It is beyond the scope of this study to examine the price dynam-
ior of the product price will influence the evaluation of economic ics for every specific REE due to the limited data availability. To
performance. overcome this drawback, more rigorous empirical models for price
This case study serves as an example to showcase how to im- elasticities is recommended for future study.
plement dynamic elements into a TEA, and its consequential influ-
ence on the evaluation results. Economic performance metrics that Declaration of Competing Interest
account for market dynamics will provide more trustworthy results
for the development of processes used to recover critical materials The authors declare that they have no known competing finan-
that are subject to high price volatility. As discussed above, the as- cial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to
sumptions for the supply-demand shifters can always be adjusted influence the work reported in this paper.
to meet a specific scenario, and the dynamic price index y will vary
from case to case. Acknowledgments

5. Conclusion This research was supported by the Critical Materials Institute


(CMI), an Energy Innovation Hub funded by the U.S. Department
Motivated by the desire to move toward environmental sustain- of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, Ad-
ability, there is increased demand for REEs that are needed for vanced Manufacturing Office. CMI is led by Ames Laboratory, oper-
clean energy technologies. This study applied a mechanical oscil- ated for the U.S. Department of Energy by Iowa State University of
lator model to physically interpret and model the price dynamics Science and Technology under Contract No. DE-AC02-07CH11358.
of an REE market. The concept of elasticity was used as a proxy To Professor Thomas L. Morin, your legacy of 45 years of service
to quantify the sensitivity of price to demand and supply shifters, to Purdue IE will be remembered forever.
then a price prediction model based on dynamic supply-demand
was proposed. The price dynamics under a specific setting were Supplementary materials
simulated and then incorporated into a TEA case study.
Unlike mainstream price estimation methods primarily based Supplementary material associated with this article can be
on statistics, this study explores the price dynamics by analyzing found, in the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.spc.2021.04.013.

1726
S. Deng, D. Prodius, I.C. Nlebedim et al. Sustainable Production and Consumption 27 (2021) 1718–1727

References Lauer, M., 2008. Methodology guideline on techno economic assessment (TEA). In-
tell. Energy Eur..
N.Connelly, T.Damhus, R.Hartshorn, and A.Hutton, “Nomenclature of Inor- M.Van Dael, S.Kreps, A.Virag, K.Kessels, K.Remans, D.Thomas, and F.De
ganic Chemistry – IUPAC Recommendations 2005,”Chemistry International Wilde, “Techno-economic assessment of a microbial power-to-gas plant
– Newsmagazine for IUPAC, vol. 27, no. 6. RSCPublishing, pp. 25–26, doi: – Case study in Belgium,” Appl. Energy, vol. 215, pp. 416–425, doi:
10.1515/ci.2005.27.6.25. 10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.01.092.
Nassar, N.T., Du, X., Graedel, T.E., 2015. Criticality of the Rare Earth Elements. J. Ind. M.Alipanah, D. M.Park, A.Middleton, Z.Dong, H.Hsu-Kim, Y.Jiao, and H.Jin, “Techno-
Ecol. 19 (6), 1044–1054. doi:10.1111/jiec.12237. Economic and Life Cycle Assessments for Sustainable Rare Earth Recovery from
N.Mathur, S.Deng, S.Singh, Y.Yih, and J. W.Sutherland, “Evaluating the environmental Coal Byproducts using Biosorption,” ACS Sustain. Chem. Eng., vol. 8, no. 49, pp.
benefits of implementing Industrial Symbiosis to used electric vehicle batteries,” 17914–17922, doi: 10.1021/acssuschemeng.0c04415.
2019, doi: 10.1016/j.procir.2019.01.074. S.Deng, J.Perez-Cardona, A.Huang, Y.Yih, V. S.Thompson, D. W.Reed, H.Jin, and J.
G. J. O. Gordon B.Haxel, James B.Hedrick, “Rare Earth Elements—Critical Resources W.Sutherland, “Applying design of experiments to evaluate economic feasibil-
for High Technology,” 2002. https://pubs.usgs.gov/fs/2002/fs087-02/. ity of rare-earth element recovery,” 2020, doi: 10.1016/j.procir.2020.02.005.
MIT, 2016. Rare Earth Elements-A Comprehensive Background. Strategic Mineral Jin, H., Park, D.M., Gupta, M., Brewer, A.W., Ho, L., Singer, S.L., Bourcier, W.L.,
Management https://web.mit.edu/12.0 0 0/www/m2016/finalwebsite/elements/ Woods, S., Reed, D.W., Lammers, L.N., Sutherland, J.W., Jiao, Y., 2017. Techno-
ree.html. economic Assessment for Integrating Biosorption into Rare Earth Recovery Pro-
Hatch, G.P., 2012. Dynamics in the Global Market for Rare Earths. Elements 8 (5), cess. ACS Sustain. Chem. Eng. doi:10.1021/acssuschemeng.7b02147.
341–346. doi:10.2113/gselements.8.5.341, Oct. E. S.Gardner, “Exponential smoothing: The state of the art—Part II,” Int. J. Forecast.,
Alonso, E., Sherman, A.M., Wallington, T.J., Everson, M.P., Field, F.R., Roth, R., Kir- vol. 22, no. 4, pp. 637–666, doi: 10.1016/j.ijforecast.20 06.03.0 05.
chain, R.E., 2012. Evaluating rare earth element availability: A case with revo- Laptev, N., Yosinski, J., Li, L.Erran, Smyl, S., Li, E.L., Smyl, S., 2017. Time-series Ex-
lutionary demand from clean technologies. Environmental Science and Technol- treme Event Forecasting with Neural Networks at Uber,” Int. Conf. Mach. Learn.
ogy 46 (6), 3406–3414. doi:10.1021/es203518d. - Time Ser. Work..
Tukker, A., 2014. Rare earth elements supply restrictions: Market failures, not Marshall, A., 2013. Principles of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan UK, London.
scarcity, hamper their current use in high-tech applications. Environmental Sci- Nicholson, W., Snyder, C., 2011. Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Exten-
ence and Technology doi:10.1021/es503548f. sions 11th edition.
Vaccarezza, V., Anderson, C., 2020. An Overview of Beneficiation and Hydrometal- Bryant, W.D.A., 2021. Advanced Microeconomics. WORLD SCIENTIFIC.
lurgical Techniques on Eudialyte Group Minerals. Mining, Metallurgy and Explo- Kluever, C.A., 2015. Dynamic Systems: Modeling, Simulation, and Control. Wiley.
ration doi:10.1007/s42461- 019- 00132- 5. Stádník, B., 2014. Spring Oscillations within Financial Markets. Procedia - Soc. Behav.
K. L.Lyon, V. P.Utgikar, and M. R.Greenhalgh, “Dynamic Modeling for the Separation Sci. doi:10.1016/j.sbspro.2013.12.964.
of Rare Earth Elements Using Solvent Extraction: Predicting Separation Perfor- Y.Khoroshilov, “Momentum trading strategy and investment horizon: an experimen-
mance Using Laboratory Equilibrium Data,” Ind. Eng. Chem. Res., vol. 56, no. 4, tal study,” J. Econ. Stud., vol. 39, no. 1, pp. 4–12, doi: 10.1108/01443581211192071.
pp. 1048–1056, doi: 10.1021/acs.iecr.6b04009. Sandoval, L., Franca, I.D.P., 2011. Shocks in financial markets, price expectation,
Sridharan, N., Cakmak, E., List, F.A., Ucar, H., Constantinides, S., Babu, S.S., Mc- and damped harmonic oscillators. Cornell University Library arXiv.orgarXiv.org,
Call, S.K., Paranthaman, M.P., 2018. Rationalization of solidification mechanism Ithaca[Online]. Available: http://arxiv.org/abs/1103.1992 .
of Nd–Fe–B magnets during laser directed-energy deposition. J. Mater. Sci. Riley, K.F., Hobson, M.P., Bence, S.J., 2002. Mathematical Methods for Physics and
doi:10.1007/s10853- 018- 2178- 7. Engineering.
Kassen, A.G., White, E.M.H., Tang, W., Hu, L., Palasyuk, A., Zhou, L., Anderson, I.E., “Second-Order Linear Ordinary Differential Equations.” http://sites.science.
2017. Compression Molding and Novel Sintering Treatments for Alnico Type-8 oregonstate.edu/math/home/programs/undergrad/CalculusQuestStudyGuides/
Permanent Magnets in Near-Final Shape with Preferred Orientation. JOM doi:10. ode/second/so_lin/so_lin.html (accessed Aug. 06, 2020).
1007/s11837- 017- 2453- 0. A.Hayes, “Elasticity,” 2020. https://www.investopedia.com/terms/e/elasticity.asp.
L.Cong, H.Jin, P.Fitsos, T.McLntyre, Y.Yih, F.Zhao, and J. W.Sutherland, “Modeling the Becker, G.S., Michael, G., Michael, R.T., 2017. Economic Theory. Routledge.
value recovery of rare earth permanent magnets at End-of-Life,” 2015, doi: “Rare Earths Statistics and Information,” National Minerals Information Center. https:
10.1016/j.procir.2015.02.015. //www.usgs.gov/centers/nmic/rare- earths- statistics- and- information.
Brewer, A., Dohnalkova, A., Shutthanandan, V., Kovarik, L., Chang, E., Sawvel, A.M., Jurczyk, M., Rajewski, W., Majchrzycki, W., Wójcik, G., 1999. Mechanically alloyed
Mason, H.E., Reed, D., Ye, C., Hynes, W.F., Lammers, L.N., Park, D.M., Jiao, Y., MmNi 5-type materials for metal hydride electrodes. J. Alloys Compd. 290 (1),
2019. Microbe Encapsulation for Selective Rare-Earth Recovery from Electronic 262–266. doi:10.1016/S0925- 8388(99)00202- 9.
Waste Leachates. Environ. Sci. Technol. 53 (23), 13888–13897. doi:10.1021/acs. IndexMundi, “United States GDP (official exchange rate).” https://www.indexmundi.
est.9b04608, Dec. com/united_states/gdp_(official_exchange_rate).html.
A. A.Taleizadeh, V. R.Soleymanfar, and K.Govindan, “Sustainable economic produc- Nlebedim, I.C., King, A.H., 2018. Addressing Criticality in Rare Earth Elements via
tion quantity models for inventory systems with shortage,” J. Clean. Prod., vol. Permanent Magnets Recycling. JOM doi:10.1007/s11837- 017- 2698- 7.
174, pp. 1011–1020, doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.10.222. H.Jin, K.Frost, I.Sousa, H.Ghaderi, A.Bevan, M.Zakotnik, and C.Handwerker, “Life cycle
Deng, S., Zhou, X., Huang, A., Yih, Y., Sutherland, J.W., 2020. Evaluating economic assessment of emerging technologies on value recovery from hard disk drives,”
opportunities for product recycling via the Sherwood principle and machine Resour. Conserv.Recycl., vol. 157, doi: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2020.104781.
learning. Resour. Conserv.Recycl., 105232 doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2020.105232, Prodius, D., Gandha, K., Mudring, A.V., Nlebedim, I.C., 2020. Sustainable Urban Min-
no. October. ing of Critical Elements from Magnet and ElectronicWastes. ACS Sustain. Chem.
National Energy Technology Laboratory, “2019 Project Portfolio Disclaimer,” 2019. Eng. doi:10.1021/acssuschemeng.9b05741.
https://www.netl.doe.gov/sites/default/files/2019-04/2019- REE- Project- Portfolio.
pdf (accessed Jun. 20, 2020).

1727

You might also like