You are on page 1of 7

633907

research-article2016
RAP0010.1177/2053168016633907Research & PoliticsAsunka

Research Article
Research and Politics

Partisanship and political accountability in January-March 2016: 1­–7


© The Author(s) 2016
DOI: 10.1177/2053168016633907
new democracies: Explaining compliance rap.sagepub.com

with formal rules and procedures in Ghana

Joseph Asunka

Abstract
Standard political agency models generally predict an inverse relationship between the degree of partisan allegiance
among citizens and political accountability. Does variation in voter attachments to political parties influence the behavior
of public officials in new democracies? I take advantage of data from a unique audit of local governments in Ghana—
the Functional Organizational Assessment Tool (FOAT)—to examine the impact of partisanship on public officials’
compliance with formal rules and procedures. Because unattached or weakly attached voters are more responsive to
the performance of incumbent officials, they are more likely to deter rent seeking, corruption, and other administrative
malpractices. Analysis of the baseline FOAT results provides strong support for this idea: compliance with formal rules
and procedures is significantly higher in districts where voters evince weak attachments to political parties. This result
is robust to controls for alternate explanations and sheds light on the conditions under which politicians would abjure
rent seeking and corruption, even in the context of a new democracy where they have so much opportunity to do so.

Keywords
Voter attachment, compliance, Ghana, local government

Introduction
Political parties are an important instrument and institution work in different contexts confirms this inverse relation-
of democratic politics. That modern representative democ- ship. Strong partisanship reduces voter responsiveness to
racy is not conceivable without political parties is widely politicians’ performance (Anderson, 2000; Hellwig and
accepted among researchers (Ladd, 1992). By articulating Samuels, 2008; Kayser and Wlezien, 2011; Moehler and
and integrating different interests, visions, and opinions, Lindberg, 2009) and undermines their ability to remove
parties mobilize citizen engagement in the political process corrupt and nonperforming politicians from office (Eggers,
with the ultimate goal of winning political power and influ- 2014). From the politicians’ point of view, strong partisan-
encing government policy. While popular participation in ship reduces elected officials’ incentives to exert energy
the political process is essential for democratic develop- toward providing quality basic services to their constitu-
ment, research suggests that the degree of partisan attach- ents (Keefer and Khemani, 2009). I extend this logic to
ments among citizens has important implications for address an important but relatively underexplored question
political accountability and, hence, the proper functioning in new democracies where formal rules and procedures
of democracy and the overall welfare of citizens. are less well institutionalized and politicians have signifi-
Standard political agency models generally predict cant opportunity to manipulate the weaknesses in the
an inverse relationship between the degree of partisan
allegiances among citizens and political accountability University of California, USA
(Besley, 2007; Persson and Tabellini, 2000). When voters
Corresponding author:
grow strongly attached to and prioritize electoral victory of Joseph Asunka, University of California, 4289 Bunche Hall, Los Angeles,
their favorite parties over other considerations, electoral CA 90095, USA.
control of politicians suffers. A large body of empirical Email: asunka@ucla.edu

Creative Commons NonCommercial-NoDerivs CC BY-NC-ND: This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative
Commons Attribution- NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 License (http://www.creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/) which
permits non-commercial use, reproduction and distribution of the work as published without adaptation or alteration, without further permission
provided the original work is attributed as specified on the SAGE and Open Access pages (https://us.sagepub.com/en-us/nam/open-access-at-sage).
2 Research and Politics 

accountability system and extract public resources for pri- different parties, that would be indicative of weaker parti-
vate ends. I ask whether variation in voters’ partisan pref- san preferences among some voters in the district. Secondly,
erences influences the behavior of public officials in these to capture the effect of the magnitude of nonpartisan voters,
contexts. In other words, does the inverse relationship I use the Pedersen index of electoral volatility to compute
between partisanship and political accountability apply in the proportion of voters that switched between the two par-
developing democracies? ties in each district in the two prior elections.2 For a stable
Because the voting decisions of unattached or weakly two-party system with consistently high voter turnout as in
attached voters are increasingly influenced by the perfor- Ghana, we would expect this measure to capture the rate of
mance of incumbent politicians in new democracies (Fridy, voter switching between the two parties over time.
2007; Lindberg and Morrison, 2008; Youde, 2005), the Consistent with the idea that weak partisanship deters
theory would predict that these voting behaviors are likely rent seeking and other corrupt practices, I find that compli-
to deter official impropriety; incumbent politicians would ance with formal budget rules and administrative proce-
risk damaging their re-election chances and those of their dures is significantly higher in districts where voters have
party if they engage in rent seeking, corruption, and other weaker attachments to political parties. The results suggest
administrative malpractices in contexts where partisan loy- that even in contexts where formal institutional constraints
alties are weak. To test this idea empirically, I use a unique are limited and politicians have the greatest opportunity to
and highly comparable baseline dataset from a standardized manipulate or override the existing rules and procedures for
assessment of the budget implementation activities of personal gain, weak partisan loyalties can constrain the
local governments in Ghana. This on-going annual assess- incentive to exploit those opportunities. This paper contrib-
ment program, known as the Functional Organizational utes to the broader literature about the relationship between
Assessment Tool (FOAT), started in 2008 and is designed partisanship and political accountability by focusing on the
to gauge the extent of local governments’ compliance with effect of partisan loyalties on rent seeking behavior among
the formal rules and administrative procedures governing public officials in new democracies with fledgling institu-
budget implementation. These rules and procedures, nota- tions. The paper also contributes to the literature on how
bly those contained in Ghana’s Financial Administration competitive configurations create incentives for politicians
and Public Procurement Acts (more below), are designed to to tie their own hands through administrative reforms
decrease the prevalence of rent seeking and corruption (Finkel, 2008; Geddes, 1991; Lehoucq and Molina, 2002).
among public officials. Thus, greater adherence to these Finally, the evidence presented here is consistent with
rules and procedures means less rent seeking and/or corrup- recent research that shows a rising trend of performance-
tion. However, the formal institutional structure of local based voting in Africa (Bratton, 2013; Fridy, 2007; Lindberg
government in Ghana (see overview below) makes local and Morrison, 2008; Youde, 2005), a trend that is largely
politicians more accountable to the president and the ruling concentrated among unattached or weakly attached voters
national party and thus significantly weakens enforcement (Weghorst and Lindberg, 2013).3
of and accountability vis-à-vis the rules at the local level.
Even despite this single country-wide administrative
Empirical setting
structure, however, the results of the baseline FOAT
assessment reveal wide variation in local governments’ Ghana is a unitary state divided into 10 administrative
compliance with rules and procedures. I argue that the regions. The principal units of local government are the
degree of partisan attachments among voters accounts for districts, of which there are presently 216 nested within
this variation. the 10 regions. This is the level of government at which
To measure the extent of voter attachments to political the national budget is allocated and spent. The political
parties in each local government district, I use two indica- heads of local government are known as District Chief
tors based on electoral outcomes in the two general elec- Executives (DCEs)—the equivalent of city mayors else-
tions preceding the baseline assessment in 2006 (i.e. the where. The president appoints all the DCEs and they have
2000 and 2004 general elections). Firstly, taking advantage significant authority over all spending decisions in their
of Ghana’s concurrent presidential and legislative elec- districts. The administrative setup of local government
tions, I create a dichotomous variable that takes a value of means that the president and the governing national party
1 if the majority of voters in the district voted for the presi- have broad, centralized control over the affairs of all dis-
dential candidate of one party and the parliamentary candi- tricts in the country.
date of a different party in one or both prior elections, and As the main agents of development at the local level,
0 otherwise. I call this split-ticket voting.1 Strongly attached local governments, specifically the DCEs, control large
voters have an incentive to vote for the candidates of their amounts of financial and other development resources. To
favorite parties in both the presidential and legislative elec- check abuse or misappropriation of public resources, Ghana
tions. Thus, if the winning candidates in the (concurrent) has, since its transition to democracy in 1992, introduced
presidential and legislative elections in a district are from various laws to govern development policy implementation
Asunka 3

at all levels of government, including, in particular, local local officials and thus makes subsequent FOAT results
governments. These laws, in particular the Financial less ideal for investigating the political sources of official
Administration Act and the Public Procurement Act, both compliance with rules and procedures. In fact, all the dis-
enacted in 2003, are designed to prevent rent seeking and tricts have become “masters of the game” over time; in
corruption among public officials. In addition to these two recent assessments, the scores on all the FOAT PMs are
pieces of legislation, there are many other formal guide- so high that there is very little cross-district variation to
lines and administrative procedures for administering the make any meaningful analysis.
numerous development resources that flow to the districts.
However, the sweeping appointment powers of the presi-
Data and measurement
dent significantly weaken local-level accountability and
enforcement of the formal rules and procedures. Thus, local In 2006, the baseline year of the FOAT assessment, Ghana
officials have significant opportunity to manipulate or had a total of 138 districts and all were assessed and hence
override the existing rules and procedures and extract pub- are included in the analysis below.
lic resources for political or private ends with little or no
legal sanction.
The apparent weak enforcement of the rules and pro-
Dependent variables
cedures and, hence, widespread rent seeking and corrupt Compliance with formal rules and administrative
practices at the level of local government partly prompted
procedures
the introduction of the independent assessment program
in 2008. Four of Ghana’s major bilateral donors partnered I operationalize the dependent variable in two ways: first
with the government to introduce the FOAT program to I use the total compliance score on all the eight FOAT
assess all local governments annually on their compli- PMs used for the baseline assessment. The ninth PM—
ance with budget rules and administrative procedures, to Environmental Sanitation Management—was introduced
motivate compliance with the established rules proce- in subsequent assessments. The total score on all PMs is
dures, and to eliminate official malfeasance.4 The pro- 100. Secondly, I use the compliance score on procure-
gram’s accountability indicators are divided into two ment alone. The procurement PM gauges local govern-
groups: minimum conditions (MCs) and performance ments’ compliance with the formal rules governing
measures (PMs). The PMs, the focus in this paper, are the contracting and contract execution and includes indica-
dimensions used to assess local governments’ compli- tors such as procedures for inviting tenders, contract
ance with the existing formal rules and procedures gov- mobilization, tender review process, timeliness of pro-
erning implementation of the national budget in nine jects execution, and contract retention. The maximum
broad areas.5 score on this measure is 9. I single out procurement for
Although the program was introduced in 2008, the two reasons: firstly, studies on Ghana’s national budget
baseline assessment was conducted on the 2006 fiscal show that more than half—between 50 and 70 percent—
year activities. I use the results of the baseline assessment is procurement-related (World Bank, 2003). Since much
for the analysis in this paper. The baseline results are of government spending goes into procurement, rent
ideal for investigating the political sources of the varia- seeking and corruption is likely to be concentrated in this
tion in compliance with formal rules and procedures for area. Secondly, procurement is an activity that is most
at least two reasons. Firstly, the 2006 baseline assessment susceptible to rent seeking behavior and corruption: offi-
was akin to a surprise audit of the behavior of local offi- cials can bend the rules of contracting and pricing of
cials in the budget implementation phase. The 2006 fiscal goods and services. If local officials seek to extract pri-
year activities were executed without any knowledge of a vate benefits, they would most likely do so through
possible assessment in the future and, hence, local offi- procurement.7
cials would have conducted their activities on the basis of
business-as-usual. This should be contrasted with the
Control variables
standard annual audits of local governments conducted
by the auditor general, which local officials are very I control for several socio-economic and demographic
much aware of and often take steps to ensure that they get characteristics of the districts. Firstly, I control for
favorable audit opinions. We can imagine that corrupt Education, as well-educated voters may demand more effi-
officials are capable of buying the best audit opinions in cient management and use of public resources and may be
the circumstance.6 Secondly, the FOAT program came more likely to punish politicians who behave otherwise. I
with an incentive package: districts that do well in com- operationalize this concept using the share of district popu-
plying with the rules are rewarded with extra discretion- lation that has at least a high school education. Secondly, I
ary funding. This monetary incentive, which became control for ethnic diversity, arguably the most important
apparent only in 2008, now complicates the behavior of factor in African elections (Posner, 2007). Ghana’s 2000
4 Research and Politics 

Table 1.  Split-ticket voting and local governments’ compliance with formal rules and administrative procedures in Ghana.

VARIABLES Dependent variable: Total FOAT Dependent variable: Procurement


score (Range: 0–100) score (Range: 0–9)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4


Split ticket 5.547*** 3.413** 0.911*** 0.570**
  (1.561) (1.470) (0.283) (0.266)
Ethnic fractionalization 14.503*** 2.971***
  (3.453) (0.624)
Percent over high school −6.575 −2.335
  (13.993) (2.529)
Bureaucratic capacity 1.199** −0.061
  (0.484) (0.087)
Pop density (logged) 4.858** 1.070***
  (1.864) (0.337)
Average turnout −4.878 2.151
  (13.966) (2.524)
Constant 42.831*** 24.778** 5.528*** 0.982
  (1.753) (11.568) (0.318) (2.091)
Region fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 138 138 138 138
R-squared 0.210 0.381 0.133 0.324

Standard errors in parentheses.


***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1.
FOAT: Functional Organizational Assessment Tool.

population and housing census includes a breakdown of Results


the ethnic composition of the population in each district. I
use this data to compute an index of ethno-linguistic frac- Table 1 presents the OLS regression results of the effect of
tionalization (ELF), which is a decreasing transformation split-ticket voting on local governments’ compliance with
of the Herfindahl concentration index.8 Thirdly, I control formal rules and administrative procedures. The dependent
for bureaucratic capacity, as districts with greater bureau- variable in columns 1 and 2 is the total score on all the eight
cratic capacity may just do better at following the formal PMs; that in columns 3 and 4 is the compliance score on
rules and procedures than those with limited capacity. I procurement only. Columns 1 and 3 report estimates of the
use a measure of per capita locally generated revenues effect of split-ticket voting on total compliance and pro-
from the FOAT results to measure bureaucratic capacity. curement compliance scores respectively without any
Fourthly, I control for population density (logged) as a covariates. In both models, the effect is statistically signifi-
proxy for urbanization. Finally, I control for voter turnout cant. Without accounting for any covariates, the results
in each district in the 2004 presidential elections. Turnout show that on average, the total compliance score on all PMs
in national elections has been shown elsewhere to influ- is about six points higher in districts that voted for candi-
ence the behavior of incumbent politicians (Fleck, 1999; dates of different parties in at least one of the two prior
Horiuchi and Saito, 2009). general elections compared to those that voted straight
ticket in those elections. Similarly, split-ticket districts
score about one point higher on procurement compliance
Empirical model than straight ticket districts.
I estimate a simple ordinary least squares (OLS) model that In columns 2 and 4, I control for all the relevant covari-
takes the form below and includes region fixed effects in all ates as well as region fixed effects. In both models, the
specifications, since the districts are nested within the 10 effect of split-ticket voting remains positive and statisti-
regions cally significant. Local governments in districts that have
experienced split- ticket voting in prior elections are sig-
Compliancei = b0 + b1 Attached i + b2 Ethnic.Fraci nificantly more likely to stick to the formal rules and
administrative procedures governing development policy
+ b3 Educationi + b4 Bureau.Capacityi implementation. In these districts, the total score on all
+ b5log ( Pop. Densityi ) + b6Turnouti + ε i eight compliance indicators is about four points higher
Asunka 5

Table 2.  Electoral volatility and local governments’ compliance with formal rules and administrative procedures in Ghana.

VARIABLES Dependent variable: Total FOAT Dependent variable: Procurement


score (Range: 0–100) score (Range: 0–9)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4


Index of electoral volatility 0.485** 0.347** 0.105*** 0.078**
  (0.189) (0.173) (0.035) (0.032)
Ethnic fractionalization 14.152*** 3.213***
  (3.436) (0.633)
Percent over high school −10.465 −2.056
  (13.803) (2.542)
Bureaucratic capacity 1.379*** −0.034
  (0.474) (0.087)
Pop density (logged) 4.918*** 0.996***
  (1.829) (0.337)
Average turnout 1.403 4.736*
  (14.715) (2.710)
Constant 41.113*** 18.004 5.144*** −1.481
  (1.878) (12.181) (0.350) (2.243)
Region fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 130 130 130 130
R-squared 0.216 0.405 0.120 0.347

Standard errors in parentheses.


***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1.
FOAT: Functional Organizational Assessment Tool.

compared to districts that voted straight ticket in the two procurement).9 Since each rule or procedure is designed to
prior elections. These effects are quite large given the prevent rent seeking behavior and corruption in specific
design of the indicators. Most of the indicators are dichoto- areas, the results suggest that officials in electorally volatile
mous—taking a value of 1 if the district fulfils a particular districts are relatively more likely to constrain their own
formal rule or administrative procedure and 0 otherwise. ability to extract private rents.10
This means that on average, split-ticket districts comply The other important determinants of public officials’
with about four more formal rules and/or administrative compliance with formal rules and procedures are ethnic
procedures than straight ticket district. The results on pro- diversity and population density. Both variables are statisti-
curement are similar. Districts with a history of split-ticket cally significant in all specifications, suggesting that local
voting score, on average, about half a point higher on pro- governments in ethnically heterogeneous and densely popu-
curement compliance than those with no such experience. lated districts are more likely to stick to the rules and thus
This translates approximately to compliance with one more relatively less likely to engage in rent seeking and corrup-
procurement rule or procedure. tion. Firstly, the effect of ethnicity is to be expected given
the nature of Ghana’s ethnic geography. The two ethnic
Alternative specifications of main groups that identify strongly with, and consistently vote
straight ticket for candidates of the two major parties in both
independent variable the presidential and legislative elections, are concentrated in
Table 2 presents the results using the second operationaliza- only two of the 10 regions. Voting behavior in the remaining
tion of voter attachments to political parties: the Pedersen eight regions, which are relatively more ethnically diverse,
index of electoral volatility. Similar to the preceding analy- is driven by factors other than ethnicity (Fridy, 2007). High
sis, I find that higher voter volatility is associated with ethnic diversity means that no single ethnic group can mobi-
greater compliance with formal rules and procedures. Based lize and win an election on its own and the performance of
on the results in models 2 and 4, a 10 percentage-point incumbents would matter in those settings. Secondly,
switch between the two parties, which is just around the densely populated areas, which are essentially the urban
average, is associated with about a 4-point increase in the areas, are home to relatively wealthier and perhaps better-
total FOAT score (i.e. compliance with roughly four more informed voters. Economically empowered voters are more
formal rules and procedures) and about 1 point increase likely to demand efficient management and use of public
in the procurement compliance score (i.e. compliance resources and they may punish incumbent politicians
with approximately two more rules and procedures on who engage in rent seeking and corruption. This result is
6 Research and Politics 

consistent with studies that show that politicians are more   3. It is necessary that I touch on the role of ethnicity, which
likely to engage in clientelism and other corrupt electoral is arguably the most important factor in the political life of
practices among the poor (e.g. Magaloni et al., 2007; Africa (Carlson, 2010; Ferree, 2006; Ichino and Nathan,
Wantchekon, 2003) and thus less likely to do so in wealthy 2013; Kanyinga, 1994; Posner, 2005, 2007). It is possible
that patterns of partisan attachments are shaped by ethnic
areas (Weitz-Shapiro, 2012).
identities and potentially the results presented in this paper.
Although ethnicity plays an important role in voting behav-
Conclusion ior in Africa, recent research suggests that elections are
more than just ethnic censuses (Bratton, 2013; Lindberg and
This paper examines the impact of voter attachment to
Morrison, 2008). Increasingly, many voters in the region
political parties on public officials’ compliance with formal
base their voting decisions on the performance of incumbent
rules and administrative procedures designed to eliminate politicians (Lindberg and Morrison, 2005). More importantly
or reduce opportunities for rent seeking and corruption. The in the case of Ghana, the relationship between ethnicity and
evidence shows that compliance with formal rules and pro- partisan affinities is very weak. The ethnic groups that iden-
cedures is significantly higher in districts where voters tify strongly with, and vote en bloc for the two major par-
demonstrate weak commitments to political parties. ties, are concentrated in only two of Ghana’s 10 regions. The
Because unattached or weakly attached voters are more vast majority of voters in the remaining eight regions, who
responsive to the performance of incumbent officials, poli- usually determine the outcome of national elections, vote on
ticians in these districts risk undermining their own politi- issues other than ethnic identities (Fridy, 2007).
cal futures if they exploit public resources for immediate   4. The four donors are the French Development Agency, the
Canadian International Development Agency, the Danish
personal gain. This association is robust to controls for a
International Development Agency, and the German
range of potential confounding covariates, including fac-
Development Bank.
tors unique to each region. These findings thus advance our  5. The nine PMs are as follows: (1) “Management and
understanding of the conditions under which politicians Organization”; (2) “Transparency, Openness and
would play by the rules and potentially limit their ability to Accountability”; (3) “Planning System”; (4) “Human
extract private rents. Using the case of Ghana, where the Resource Management”; (5) “Relations with substruc-
formal legal system is relatively weakly institutionalized, tures”; (6) “Financial Management and Auditing”;
has allowed insight in particular into a context where politi- (7) “Fiscal Capacity”; (8) “Procurement”; and (9)
cians have significant opportunity to engage in corruption, “Environmental Sanitation and Management”. The
given the relatively low chance of legal sanction. The baseline assessment did not include the measure on
results suggest that when voters are less committed to polit- Environmental Sanitation and Management.
  6. This is why audit results may be less helpful for evaluating
ical parties, rent seeking behavior and other administrative
the behavior of local politicians.
malpractices are likely to decline.
  7. To provide a more complete picture, I run the same analysis
for each of the remaining PMs and graph the main effects.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests The results are presented in Figure A1 and Figure A2 in the
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect online appendix. The results show that higher electoral vola-
to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. tility is associated with greater compliance with the formal
rules and procedures governing financial management and
Funding planning. I find no effect on the other PMs. I also find no
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial support effect on the individual PMs using the dichotomous version
for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: of my measure of voter attachment to parties.
UCLA dissertation year fellowship; UCLA International Institute;  8. If a district is composed of K ⩾ 2 ethnic groups and pk
and UCLA Charles and Sue Young Fellowship. denotes the share of group k in the population, then the
Ethno-Linguistic Fractionalization (ELF) is computed as
K
Notes follows: ELF = 1 −
∑p 2
k
.
 1. This is usually referred to as “skirt and blouse voting” in k =1
  9. It is important to note here that a 10-percentage point switch
Ghana.
between the two major parties is not extraordinary in Ghana.
 2. For each district, I compute electoral volatility using the
In fact it is quite common.
results of the two presidential elections that preceded the
10. An additional analysis using the 2005 Afrobarometer opin-
2006 fiscal year. These were the elections of 2000 and 2004.
ion survey data for Ghana yields very similar results. In each

∑ survey, the Afrobarometer asks respondents whether they


n
pit − pi(t +1)
Volatility = i =1 where p is the vote share feel close to any party. For each district that was included
2 it in the 2005 survey, I compute the proportion of voters who
report that they do not feel close to any party as a meas-
of party i in election t.
ure of the degree of voter attachments to political parties.
This index takes values between 0.485 and 23.62 percent, The results, presented in Table A1 in the online appendix,
with a mean of 6.25 and standard deviation of 4.28 percent. show that compliance with formal rules and administrative
Asunka 7

procedures is significantly higher in districts with larger Kanyinga K (1994) Ethnicity, Patronage and Class in a Local
concentrations of voters who report that they do not feel Arena: High and Low Politics in Kiambu, Kenya, 1982–92.
close to any political party. Johannesburg, South Africa: University of the Witwatersrand.
Kayser MA and Wlezien C (2011) Performance pressure: Patterns
Supplementary material of partisanship and the economic vote. European Journal of
Political Research 50(3): 365–394.
The online appendix is available at: http://rap.sagepub.com/
Keefer P and Khemani S (2009) When do legislators pass on pork?
content/3/1
The role of political parties in determining legislator effort.
The American Political Science Review 103(1): 99–112.
Carnegie Corporation of New York Grant Ladd EC (1992) Political Parties, ‘reform’ and American democ-
The open access article processing charge (APC) for this article racy. In: White JK and Mileur JM (eds) Challenges to Party
was waived due to a grant awarded to Research & Politics from Government. Carbondale, IL: Southern Illinois University,
Carnegie Corporation of New York under its ‘Bridging the Gap’ pp. 22–39.
initiative. Lehoucq FE and Molina I (2002) Stuffing the Ballot Box: Fraud,
Electoral Reform, and Democratization in Costa Rica.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
References Lindberg SI and Morrison MKC (2005) Exploring voter align-
Anderson CJ (2000) Economic voting and political context: ments in Africa: Core and swing voters in Ghana. The
a comparative perspective. Electoral Studies 19(2–3): 151– Journal of Modern African Studies 43(4): 565–586.
170. Lindberg SI and Morrison MKC (2008) Are African voters
Besley T (2007) Principled Agents? The Political Economy of really ethnic or clientelistic? Survey evidence from Ghana.
Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Political Science Quarterly 123(1): 95–122.
Bratton M (2013) Voting and Democratic Citizenship in Africa. Magaloni B, Diaz-Cayeros A and Estévez F (2007) Clientelism
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. and portfolio diversification: A model of electoral invest-
Carlson E (2010) Great Expectations: Ethnicity, Performance, ment with applications to Mexico. In: In Patrons, Clients,
and Ugandan Voters. Working Paper, UCLA Department of and Policies: Patterns of Democratic Account- ability and
Political Science, Los Angeles. Political Competition. Cambridge University Press. Available
Eggers AC (2014) Partisanship and electoral accountability: from: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511585869.008
Evidence from the UK expenses scandal. Quarterly Journal (accessed 25 August 2012).
of Political Science 9(4): 441–472. Moehler DC and Lindberg SI (2009) Narrowing the legitimacy
Ferree KE (2006) Explaining South Africa’s racial census. gap: Turnovers as a cause of democratic consolidation. The
Journal of Politics 68(4): 803–815. Journal of Politics 71(04): 1448–1466.
Finkel JS (2008) Judicial Reform as Political Insurance: Persson T and Tabellini GE (2000) Political Economics:
Argentina, Peru, and Mexico in the 1990s. 1st ed. Notre Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Posner DN (2005) Institutions and Ethnic Politics in Africa.
Fleck RK (1999) The value of the vote: A model and test of the Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.
effects of turnout on distributive policy. Economic Inquiry Posner DN (2007) Regime change and ethnic cleavages in Africa.
37(4): 609–623. Comparative Political Studies 40(11): 1302–1327.
Fridy KS (2007) The elephant, umbrella, and quarrelling cocks: Wantchekon L (2003) Clientelism and voting behavior: Evidence
Disaggregating partisanship in Ghana’s fourth republic. from a field experiment in Benin. World Politics 55(03):
African Affairs 106(423): 281–305. 399–422.
Geddes B (1991) A game theoretic model of reform in Latin Weghorst KR and Lindberg SI (2013) What Drives the swing
American democracies. The American Political Science voter in Africa? American Journal of Political Science 57(3):
Review 85(2): 371. 717–734.
Hellwig T and Samuels D (2008) Electoral accountability and the Weitz-Shapiro R (2012) What wins votes: why some politicians
variety of democratic regimes. British Journal of Political opt out of clientelism. American Journal of Political Science
Science 38(1): 65–90. 56(3): 568–583.
Horiuchi Y and Saito J (2009) Rain, Elections and Money: The World Bank (2003) Ghana-Country procurement assessment
Impact of Voter Turnout on Distributive Policy Outcomes report (Vol. 4): Annex 8-Public Procurement Act (English).
in Japan. Canberra, Australia: Australian-Japan Research Available from: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/
Centre, Australian National University, Crawford School of en/2003/06/3582686/ghana-country-procurement-assessment-
Economics and Government. report-vol-4-5-annex-8-public-procurement-act (accessed 3
Ichino N and Nathan NL (2013) Crossing the line: Local ethnic October 2013).
geography and voting in Ghana. American Political Science Youde J (2005) Economics and government popularity in Ghana.
Review 107(02): 344–361. Electoral Studies 24(1): 1–16.

You might also like