You are on page 1of 10

Vol.

1  |  Issue 3 August 2012

An explanatory note on issues relevant to public-private partnerships

Compulsory Acquisition
of Land and Compensation in
Infrastructure Projects
By Jonathan Mills Lindsay, Senior Counsel, Environmental and International Law, Legal Vice-Presidency, World Bank.

I. INTRODUCTION
Compulsory acquisition is the power of govern- Although the compulsory acquisition
ment to acquire private rights in land for a public power is deeply rooted in virtually all legal
purpose, without the willing consent of its owner systems, the establishment of efficient and fair
or occupant (Keith, 2008). This power is known legal and institutional frameworks for exercising
by a variety of names depending on a country’s this power remains unfinished business in many
legal traditions, including eminent domain, countries around the world. From Brazil and
expropriation, takings and compulsory purchase. China to Ghana and the United States, the task of
Regardless of the label, compulsory acquisition is better defining the principles and processes that
a critical development tool for governments, and govern compulsory acquisition powers is one that
for ensuring that land is available when needed is very much alive and at the heart of current land
for essential infrastructure—a contingency that policy debates.
land markets are not always able to meet. An important dimension of evolving law
Yet despite being a core and necessary and practice relates to the deployment of govern-
governmental power, compulsory acquisition ment taking powers in respect of public-private
has always attracted controversy, both in theory partnerships (PPP’s). The extent to which private
and practice. The reasons for this are unsurpris- end-users of property should be allowed to be
ing. Whenever people are displaced, the human beneficiaries of compulsory government land
costs in terms of disruption to community cohe- acquisition has long been an issue, and national
sion, livelihood patterns and way of life, may laws vary in how they define and circumscribe
go beyond what can be fully mitigated through the potential involvement of the private sector.
standard compensation packages, however The issue has become more acute as governments
generous those may be. Such inevitable costs are and their development partners increasingly
compounded, sometimes many times over, where emphasize the importance of leveraging private
the process is designed or implemented poorly— investment for activities that have traditionally
tenure insecurity is exacerbated, land markets are fallen within the public domain.
weakened, investment incentives are undermined, This Note is intended to summarize for
corruption is facilitated, and communities and development professionals and policy makers
livelihoods may be destroyed. some key considerations in the design of com-
pulsory acquisition mechanisms, particularly in

PPP in Infrastructure Resource Center for Contracts, Laws and Regulation (PPPIRC)www.worldbank.org/ppp

www.worldbank.org/ppp
2 PPP Insights

the context of infrastructure projects and public Bank’s Policy on Involuntary Resettlement (OP
private partnerships and to highlight some areas 4.12); however, the main emphasis of this Note is
of continuing controversy. Brief reference will on lessons that emerge from reviewing develop-
be made to norms promoted at the international ments in national legislation and practice.
level, such as those embodied in the World

II. PUBLIC PURPOSE

Definition and may fail to provide for the full range of public
National constitutions and laws typically refer to needs: the government may eventually need to
compulsory acquisition being used for “public acquire land for a public purpose that was not
purposes”, for “public uses” and/or in the “public anticipated when the law was written (Keith 2008).
interest.” In some jurisdictions, these terms have Despite the variations that exist on this point,
distinct if overlapping meanings. In other cases, an overarching principle in most cases is that a
these distinctions are blurred or non-existent. In government’s taking powers are extraordinary
this Note, the term “public purpose” will be used powers that are intended to meet public needs
for convenience. that are not well-addressed through the operation
When it comes to defining public purposes, of the market. Hence, it is not typical for laws to
there is great variety among national laws in the allow governments to use compulsory acquisition
extent of specificity. In some countries, laws pro- as the normal means of assembling land for pur-
vide an itemized list of land uses that fall within poses that are clearly for commercial, industrial
the definition of public purpose. Such lists typi- or other profitable private uses alone.
cally include uses such as (Keith, 2008):
• Transportation uses including roads, Private sector initiatives
canals, highways, railways, bridges, wharves Yet the task of drawing credible lines can be dif-
and airports; ficult and is the focus of considerable controversy.
• Public buildings including schools, libraries, Many national laws have long contemplated
hospitals, factories, religious institutions and the possibility that the initiative for a particular
public housing; compulsory acquisition may come from a private
• Public utilities for water, sewage, electricity, actor—in most countries, the private identity of a
gas, communication, irrigation and drainage, proponent does not disqualify it from benefiting
dams and reservoirs; from the exercise of government power provided
• Public parks, playgrounds, gardens, sports the end purpose can be characterized as “pub-
facilities and cemeteries; lic.” In the United States for example, eminent
• Defence purposes. domain has been one tool at the disposal of
local governments engaged in assembling land
In contrast to this approach, some countries instead for urban renewal, even when the ultimate end
leave the definition of public purpose open ended, use is private low-cost housing or a commercial
providing much greater space for the exercise of building intended to stimulate economic revival in
discretion and interpretation. Both approaches have a blighted area. A hotly debated instance of this
their advantages and disadvantages. An exclusive came before the US Supreme Court in Kelo vs. City
list of purposes provides a degree of certainty and of New London, which held that the city’s use of
works to prevent the creeping expansion of govern- eminent domain in order to facilitate private eco-
ment powers into areas that are arguably beyond nomic redevelopment met the public purpose test
the proper theoretical limits of eminent domain— because it would increase the city’s tax base.1
limiting discretion is seen as key to preventing There are numerous examples of the exten-
some of the governance abuses often associated sion of the public purpose/use concept to support
with compulsory acquisition. On the other hand,
exclusive lists may suffer from excessive inflexibility 1 Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005).

www.worldbank.org/ppp
C o m p u l s o ry A c q u i s i t i o n o f L a n d a n d C o m p e n s at i o n i n I n f r a s t r u c t u r e P r o j e c t s 3

private activities on the basis that they may Public Private Partnerships
contribute to national economic growth—as These types of issues are not new—but they are
opposed to the more specific and tangible public increasingly coming to the fore in the context
benefits usually associated with eminent domain. of public-private partnerships, particularly in
A topical illustration can be found in the case countries where jurisprudence on the subject has
of investment by foreign firms in large-scale not been as expansive as that found in the United
agricultural holdings in developing countries. This States. In such contexts, governments may find
phenomenon has attracted a lot of international that the exercise of compulsory acquisition at
attention, promoted by some as key to unleash- times encounters public scepticism, particularly
ing the agricultural potential of regions such as where the claimed public benefits are indirect or
sub-Saharan Africa, while others characterize it speculative. Some laws or proposed laws currently
as “land grabbing” bringing few benefits to host under consideration deal with this by provisions
communities and putting local livelihoods at risk. intended to “raise the bar” when private actors
Whatever the merits of the various sides in this are involved. A draft bill under consideration in
debate (and those merits are likely to be highly India4, for example, would limit the exercise of
context specific and depend on the nature of government acquisition on behalf of a private or
the investment), it is noteworthy that a number PPP proponent to a relatively small fraction of the
of countries have included commercial agricul- overall land needed for the enterprise—the rest
ture amongst the public purposes justifying the would need to be acquired through private nego-
exercise of compulsory acquisition, and have used tiation leading to voluntary sales. In such cases,
that power as a tool for assembling land for large- the eminent domain power can be seen as a tool
scale investments.2 Some countries, by contrast, to deploy where the majority of landowners have
have tended to eschew this approach in favor willingly consented to a land transfer, and only a
of encouraging voluntary negotiations between few holdouts remain.
investors and local communities.3
China provides a particularly interesting case Legislative mechanisms to limit scope of
of compulsory acquisition used for channelling ‘public purpose”
land into ultimately non-public uses. Although There are other tools that legislators have used to
the law stipulates that the state can acquire try to ensure that the public purpose limitation
collectively-owned rural land only in the public has some “teeth”, whether the ultimate user of the
interest, this term is not defined. Under law, rural land is a public, private or PPP entity. In Kenya,
land can only be converted to urban uses if it has for example, the proponent of a compulsory acqui-
first been acquired by the state—although there is sition is required to provide credible evidence
now an active market for urban land use rights in that the benefit to the public of the acquisition
China, the options for rural users to sell to urban will outweigh the hardships to those affected. A
users are extremely limited. As a consequence, number of countries try to restrict subsequent
the exercise of compulsory acquisition is wide- transfers and land use changes of land taken for a
spread on the edges of China’s exploding cities as specific public purpose, in order to ensure that the
local governments struggle to find land for urban public purpose justification was genuine, and not
expansion. The public interest in such situations simply a disguise for facilitating future commercial
is implicitly defined to include actions deemed to transfers. Thus, some laws or proposals require
be necessary to support rational urban growth. As governments to offer the land back to the original
part of China’s ongoing efforts to address a wide owners if it is not used for the purpose for which
range of problems associated with compulsory it was acquired5, or allow the original owners to
acquisition, however, ways of limiting the concept share in the profits if acquired land is transferred
of public interest are being considered. to an unanticipated private use.6

2 See Tanzania, Land Acquisition Act, 1967, section 4(1)(g). 4 India, Draft National Land Acquisition and Rehabilitation
3 Although not specifically reflected in national law, this and Resettlement Bill, 2011.
approach has been adopted by the Government of Ghana in 5 See for example, Cambodia’s Law on Expropriation,
the context of the Ghana Commercial Agriculture Project, 2010, Article 9, which gives the original owner priority to
recently approved for financing by the World Bank. See repurchase expropriated property that is not used for the
World Bank, Ghana Commercial Agriculture Project, Project intended purpose.
Appraisal Document, at 100. 6 India, supra. Note 4, section 70.

www.worldbank.org/ppp
4 PPP Insights

III. COMPENSATION
Issues surrounding compensation for losses suf- a. Identifying compensable
fered—who-gets-what when government acquires interests and those who
a piece of land—are typically the most complex hold them
and controversial aspects of compulsory acquisi-
tion. A long-standing principle in many jurisdic- Under the classical model, a government acquires
tions is that compensation should be guided by an entire land parcel from a private owner and
the objectives of “equity” and “equivalence”—that compensates the owner for the ownership interest
is, the adequacy of compensation should be mea- in the parcel, along with other elements of com-
sured against the goal of ensuring that people are pensation discussed below. Yet in many places,
neither impoverished nor enriched (Keith, 2008). particularly in developing countries, this simple
A variation on this standard view argues model encounters a wide range of exceptions
that it may be appropriate in some cases, particu- and complications, often poorly or incompletely
larly where a taking is occurring in the context addressed in national legislation.
of a development project or program, to aim
beyond equivalence to improving the position Private rights over state land
of those affected wherever possible. This is the In many countries, full private ownership of
principle articulated in the World Bank Policy on land does not exist, and instead people hold
Involuntary Resettlement: “Displaced persons land under long-term leaseholds, certificates of
should be assisted in their efforts to improve their occupancy, concessions or other arrangements
livelihoods and standards of living or at least while the state retains ownership of the land. In
restore them, in real terms, to pre-displacement some such cases, state ownership is nominal, and
levels or to levels prevailing prior to the beginning private rights over state land are held and trans-
of project implementation, whichever is higher.”7 acted for all practical purposes as if the land were
In either case, applying the principles of privately owned. In other cases, the nature of the
compensation in practice has always been an retained state interest may be more significant. In
extremely complex challenge. Appreciation of any event, in applying the principles of compul-
this complexity has deepened as fuller and more sory acquisition, it is important to focus on the
nuanced views of the rights that people hold over private rights to land that will be terminated as
land have taken root in many parts of the world. a result of a taking, whether or not such rights
Indeed, one key insight supported by compara- amount to a narrow definition of ownership.
tive analysis is that legal approaches developed in
the context of Europe or North America—where Multiple layers of rights
land rights are generally standardized and well- There may be multiple layers of rights held by
defined, land markets function, and land records any number of rights holders. A privately owned
are reliable—have proven to be ill-equipped for parcel may be subject to leaseholds, mortgages,
dealing with many developing country contexts rights of way for utilities or transportation, con-
where such attributes are less common. cessions, rights of traditional or other uses, rights
Compensation issues can be conveniently to forest products, etc. Ownership of land, trees,
grouped according to two overlapping sets of buildings and other improvements may all be
questions: who should receive compensation for separately held. Each of these separate interests
what kind of loss; and how should the quantum may represent a significant loss to its holder if the
and type of compensation be determined? land parcel is acquired by government and the
right is terminated. Existing compulsory acquisi-
tion laws and practices may not be well adapted
to “catching” all relevant interests in a land par-
cel. Some laws may target land owners without
mentioning the array of other potential rights that
may also be relevant and affected by the acquisi-
7 World Bank Operational Policy 4.12 on Involuntary
tion. A more frequent scenario is that even where
Resettlement, paragraph 2(c). the legal framework clearly recognizes subsidiary

www.worldbank.org/ppp
C o m p u l s o ry A c q u i s i t i o n o f L a n d a n d C o m p e n s at i o n i n I n f r a s t r u c t u r e P r o j e c t s 5

or secondary rights, the processes put in place for wrongly define the size or location of the parcel,
identifying, notifying and compensating interest and that legal data lists the wrong person as the
holders are not well-designed to discover the exis- holder of the land right.
tence of such rights in a particular context, or to
bring the holders of those rights into the discus- Customary rights
sion of compensation. This is particular the case The issue of how customary land rights—present
with respect to customary rights, discussed below. in many countries in Africa, Latin America, Asia
and the Pacific and elsewhere—should be treated
Unregistered or inaccurately in relation to compulsory acquisition shares some
documented rights of the same features of issues outlined in the
It is not unusual for compulsory acquisition laws preceding paragraphs. Land within a customary
to presume a level of documentation of rights tenure regime may be held according to various
that may in fact not exist—once again perhaps a rights configurations, with the group collectively
legacy of legal approaches from developed land holding some rights alongside an array of indi-
market economies not being sufficiently adapted vidual or household rights to individual parcels
to the realities of less developed contexts. Some or resources.
laws, for example, tie eligibility for compensation Recent decades have witnessed a growing
narrowly to whether the land right is registered willingness on the part of a number of national
in accordance with the country’s land registration governments to accord some formal recognition
legislation. This can be problematic where, as to customary rights. A clear example of this is
is frequently the case, only a fraction of a given Ghana, where up to 80% of all land is recognized
country’s land has actually been registered. Many in accordance with the Constitution as owned by
countries have modern registration laws on the traditional communities. In a range of other coun-
books, but implementation frequently suffers from tries, including Mozambique, Tanzania, Uganda,
financial or other capacity constraints or a lack Burkina Faso, Mali, Philippines, Cambodia, Peru
of political will. And in many cases registration and elsewhere in Latin America, land laws have
systems may not capture all important secondary been adopted that provide for the recognition of
rights that are present. In such contexts, too strict customary tenure regimes to varying degrees.
application of a “registered-interests-only” rule In short, the distinction between customary and
to compensation would result in many interests statutory tenure is in a number of places less
going uncompensated or under-compensated. significant than it used to be.
To deal with this problem realistically can On the one hand, this trend is encouraging
place additional burdens on government. In because it promises more robust and equitable
Albania, for example, it is reported that the treatment under law for land rights that govern-
Directorate of Roads devotes a significant amount ments have historically tended to ignore or only
of time and resources to assisting unregistered to acknowledge weakly. On the other hand, in
landowners to register their land, just so that the many countries, while the principle of recog-
land can then immediately be expropriated and nition of customary rights is proclaimed, the
the owners compensated in accordance with the legal framework for such recognition is vaguely
expropriation legislation. In practice, governments articulated and moves towards operationalizing it
may in fact rely on alternate forms of evidence in have been ambivalent. As a result, the situation
implementation of compulsory acquisition laws, on the ground is often one where rights remain
relaxing the rule to accommodate facts on the unclear and vulnerable. Compounding this is
ground. A more desirable approach would be to the fact that many compulsory acquisition laws
explore the possibility of building flexibility into on the books pre-date recent land law reforms
legislative design where needed. and are ill-suited to deal with issues such as the
The issue of registration touches upon the
broader problem of official records that are inac-
curate or out-of-date, again a common feature
in many countries. A frequent constraint to the
fair and efficient implementation of compulsory
acquisition laws is that geographic data may

www.worldbank.org/ppp
6 PPP Insights

valuation and compensation for customary rights for the most part include “squatters” and other
(as discussed below).8 informal occupants or users as among those enti-
tled to received resettlement assistance, but this is
Shared resources a frequent area in which international norms and
Land held by groups or under some sort of collec- national law diverge. Many governments object to
tive arrangement can pose special challenges to the idea that even those who are clearly occupy-
the application of the principles of compensation, ing land illegally are entitled to some level of
both in customary and some non-customary ten- compensation. This, it is argued, creates perverse
ure contexts. An example of the former is Ghana, incentives for people to ignore rules when they
where traditional authorities (referred to in some occupy land, and rewards illegal behaviour to the
parts of the country as “stools” or “skins”) hold detriment of the rule of law. These objections are
“allodial” (full) ownership to the land on behalf compounded when the illegal occupiers in ques-
of their communities. A non-customary law tion are not poor and vulnerable but are relatively
example is the ownership of rural agricultural well-off and well-connected investors. On the
land in China, where law recognizes the collective other hand, it needs to be recognized that a reset-
as owner. In such instances, the law treats the tlement approach that focuses only on those with
traditional authority or the collective entity as the formal legal rights to their occupation could have
holder of the compensable interest in land, and detrimental development consequences. Informal
relies on them—implicitly or explicitly, depend- occupation of land in many settings is not a mat-
ing on the country—to ensure that land rights ter of choice but of necessity, induced by poverty,
compensation is appropriately shared within exacerbated by inaccessible land markets and
the group. Yet in both contexts, there have been poorly functioning planning regimes, and in some
significant and growing concerns that deficiencies cases condoned and encouraged by authorities.
in intra-group governance structures have led to Hence, while a full legislative embrace of the
compensation not reaching the actually displaced notion that squatters should be compensated is
individual or household. This has received perhaps unlikely to occur in most countries, there
particular attention in recent years in China, is a growing trend on the part of governments to
where central government authorities have issued adjust law and practice to deal with the individual
increasingly strong policy statements designed and societal consequences associated with the
to ensure that land compensation paid under the displacement of informal occupants.
Land Administration Law actually reaches the
“land losing farmer.”
b. Defining the appropriate
Compensation for informal occupation quantum and form of
The payment of compensation for rights that are compensation
not legally recognized raises difficult policy ques-
tions. The policies of international organizations Market value is the benchmark found in most
compulsory acquisition laws when it comes to
the calculation of compensation for an acquired
8 See Government of Botswana, Land Policy Review (2003),
quoted in R. Knight, Statutory Recognition of Customary asset. Laws and constitutions may also refer more
Land Rights in Africa, FAO (2010). “The present policy, broadly to principles such as “just” or “fair” com-
under which holders of property rights under customary
law on tribal land are entitled to receive less compensation
pensation. Yet a key consideration that emerges
than holders of common law lease rights on state land when one surveys the wide variety of economic,
and tribal land is unjust. A unified and fair system of
social and cultural settings in which takings occur
land acquisition and compensation should be established
that is applicable to all land and all people with property is that there is no universally appropriate method
interests in land. …The scope of compensation offered for calculating loss. To design compensation pack-
and the rights of those to be compensated under the Tribal
Land Act should be extended to achieve parity with the ages that will genuinely approach the objective of
provisions of the Acquisition of Property Act… There is no ensuring that people are no worse off than they
justification for the continuance of two separate systems of
land acquisition and compensation—one for user rights in were before the taking requires careful tailoring to
tribal land and one for all other sorts of rights in tribal land, local realities. Thus, even laws from highly devel-
in state land and in freehold land. The operation of the dual
system penalizes the poor and benefits the well off.”
oped market economies generally recognize that
compensation needs to go beyond the value of

www.worldbank.org/ppp
C o m p u l s o ry A c q u i s i t i o n o f L a n d a n d C o m p e n s at i o n i n I n f r a s t r u c t u r e P r o j e c t s 7

land and other assets, and to varying degrees con- routine gap between stated values and actual val-
template compensation for losses associated with ues.10 Although admittedly easier to apply, none
disturbance, costs related to moving and transi- of the approaches are ideal, and may in some
tion, in some cases harm to business, etc9. Yet cases result in significant divergence between the
in many developing country settings, assembling “legal“ and “actual“ market value of land.
the right compensation package may encounter
an even more complex array of variables, as the Replacement cost vs. fair market value
following paragraphs will highlight. International norms such as those pro-
moted by the World Bank, IFC and others refer to
Assessing the fair market value of “replacement cost” as the appropriate benchmark
lost assets for valuation of assets. This is also a term found in
A common legislative approach is to define mar- a minority of national laws11. Where land markets
ket value as the amount a willing buyer would are robust, replacement cost and fair market value
pay a willing seller on the open market where should be roughly equivalent. But as noted above,
some choice exists. There are several reasons this fair market value may be defined at the national
calculation might be difficult to make in a given level in a way that does not ensure that com-
setting (particularly when it comes to land values pensation will be adequate to acquire equivalent
as opposed to other non-land assets). In some assets. In such contexts, a focus on “replacement
areas, formal land markets may be non-existent costs” at least in theory shifts attention usefully
or extremely thin, especially in rural areas. Some to the calculation of what it would really take in a
legal systems disallow the sale of particular given market to replace lost assets. When it comes
categories of land or place severe limits on such to non-land assets such as housing and other
sales. Underlying rights, as we have seen, may improvements, a replacement cost approach also
be poorly defined in terms of content or dura- ensures that the depreciation of lost assets are not
tion. In some cases, active informal markets may taken into account in the calculation of compensa-
exist that, if studied, could in theory reveal what tion, and that transaction costs associated with the
land is selling for in the area, but governments purchase of new assets are covered.
are generally reluctant to acknowledge officially
the existence of such markets. And even where Land-for-land vs. cash compensation
formal land markets may exist, the absence of The complexities associated with assigning
an established, independent valuation profession realistic monetary values to lost assets and
and the tendency of buyers and sellers to under- displaced rights is symptomatic of the difficulties
state prices in order to minimize taxation can of applying a “standard” compulsory acquisition
conspire to make the ascertainment of market legal framework to social situations in which
value very difficult. land is valued differently than it is in function-
In the face of these constraints, laws may ing market economies. In developed countries,
rely on a variety of proxies for land value. In modern takings law is predicated on the assump-
China, for example, the value of agricultural tion that land is a fungible commodity. While this
land is determined by applying a multiplier assumption does not always hold true even in
(which varies from place to place) to the average such countries, it encounters numerous excep-
productivity of the land over a three year period. tions in the developing world, particularly in rural
In Albania and Ghana values are assigned to dif- areas. Some land rights that are critical to rural
ferent categories of land on the basis of schedules livelihoods, such as rights of pasture or access to
and maps prepared periodically by government. forest resources, may simply not be susceptible to
India’s proposed land acquisition bill defines monetization—their loss may only be genuinely
market value by reference to the amounts stated addressed through the provision of alternatives.
in recent deeds for comparable land, but includes
a multiplier as a frank acknowledgement of the
10 Supra note 4, section 20.
11 See for example Tanzania, Village Land Regulations, section
10. These regulations are also notable for listing a range of
losses beyond land and other asset values that may need to
9 See for example South Australia, Land Acquisition Act, be compensated in a particular situation, including loss of
1969. profits and disturbance.

www.worldbank.org/ppp
8 PPP Insights

More generally, where markets for land are of exploring different approaches. In periurban
weak or severely distorted, cash compensation areas, for example, at the interface of urban and
based on fair market value may be insufficient agricultural land, the taking and compensating of
to compensate for the disruption to livelihoods land is frequently fraught with tension because
and social cohesion caused by a taking. For of the steep appreciation in value that often
example, if communities are seeking a solution occurs when land is converted to higher value
where they can remain geographically together, urban uses. Local populations compensated for
they may prefer to receive land as compensation their land at agricultural land rates may watch
rather than money. The offer of alternative land with considerable resentment as the value of
as compensation may also avoid problems that their former land skyrockets. To some extent, this
can arise “when financial compensation is paid to might be addressed by including a compensatory
people who are unused to handling large amounts increment designed to represent a share in the
of money and who may soon after receiving presumed future value increase, but generally
compensation, find themselves with no land to this is disfavored by national law and valuation
farm, no income stream to support themselves, standards.
and no job skills to compete in a non-agricultural Other approaches, instead, focus on trying
economy.” (Keith, 2008) Hence, the World Bank to design the end-use of the land in a way that
Policy on Involuntary Resettlement stresses the allows for participation by those who would
provision of alternative and equivalent land as a ordinarily have been displaced. These approaches
preferred solution where livelihoods are land- can take a variety of different forms. There is, for
based. A number of countries have also explicitly example, a renewed interest in urban centers of
included such a concept in their laws12, and in the developing world in the land readjustment
other cases legal frameworks are flexible enough approaches pioneered after World War II in Japan
to accommodate the provision of “in kind” com- and Korea, whereby land targeted for investment
pensation where appropriate. There are, of course, is first pooled, and individual holdings are con-
constraints that limit the application of such an solidated within a portion of the area and offered
approach, particularly in rapidly changing areas to existing residents. Though often downsized,
where suitable alternative land may be difficult to the values of the plots or housing that existing
find in light of population pressures. residents receive are expected to increase, often
many-fold, by virtue of the adjacent development.
Alternatives to land takings In other examples, displaced people are
In light of the difficulties and hardships often offered equity shares in the acquiring enterprise,
associated with compulsory acquisition, there thus again allowing for participation in rising
has been increasing attention in recent years to land values. This approach, while promising in
identifying possible alternatives to the standard theory, can be risky in practice, depending on
compulsory acquisition approach. In addition to the economic soundness of the enterprise, and
the considerations outlined above, a number of on whether governance mechanisms are in place
other factors have underscored the desirability to ensure that unsophisticated participants are
not victimized by corruption or asymmetries in
12 See for example Tanzania, supra, note 10, section 25, which knowledge or access to information.
presents a list of potential forms of compensation that may
be appropriate depending on the circumstances, including
land-for-land.

IV. PROCESS
The procedural aspects of compulsory acquisi- discussions of process, the desire for efficiency
tion may play a very significant part in the cost to and speed on the one hand (prized especially
government and its private sector partners on the by the acquiring entity and the private sector),
one hand, and to displaced people and the com- and the objective of safeguarding the interests of
munities of which they are a part on the other. In affected people are sometimes seen as co-existing

www.worldbank.org/ppp
C o m p u l s o ry A c q u i s i t i o n o f L a n d a n d C o m p e n s at i o n i n I n f r a s t r u c t u r e P r o j e c t s 9

in a state of tension—the latter ‘bogging down’ and use of local, targeted and accessible bodies to
the former, while speed is assumed to work to deal with grievances, at least as a first step. This
the detriment of social justice. It is clear, how- reduces the problem of complaints being imme-
ever, that the two work in complementary ways. diately funnelled into court systems, which often
Endlessly drawn out processes disadvantage those have a reputation for being slow, backlogged
who are being displaced, not only those who are and expensive. Properly constituted, a grievance
waiting to use the land. At the same time, cutting mechanism would involve representation from
corners on procedures designed to address the amongst the affected community, some govern-
needs and aspirations of affected people can have ment representation from institutions not directly
severe debilitating effects on the success of the involved in the acquisition and other independent
eventual investment, by creating long-standing experts. This needs to be accompanied by clear
local resentments and other negative legacies. communication channels and proactive measures
Generally speaking, there is significant room to improve the legal literacy of affected people.
for improvement in process, both in terms of how
it is spelled out in national legislation and in how Ensuring that compensation is provided
it is administered in practice. Key areas that are in a timely manner
likely to need attention are: The timing of the payment of monetary compen-
sation, or the provision of other types of compen-
Including greater emphasis on sation (such as land) is of critical importance. In
participation and consultation many parts of the world, failure of governments
Most national laws would benefit from provisions to provide compensation in a timely fashion has
that enhance participation and more explicitly left dispossessed people in limbo, and without
require consultation with affected people at key even the leverage that comes from still occupying
decision points, ensuring for example meaningful the property that was the subject of the expro-
discussion about site selection, and the amount priation. This outcome is facilitated by some
and form of compensation, and a greater empha- national laws that vest ownership of land in the
sis on ensuring that people know what their government from the moment an expropriation
rights are and what the process entails. decree is issued, leaving compensation as a post-
taking obligation of government only. A sounder
Improving information delivery approach found in a number of countries is to
requirements require full provision of compensation as a pre-
Often notification of an impending expropria- requisite for government taking possession of the
tion is done through general announcements and land in question, and a showing by the acquir-
direct notification is required only to registered ing entity that the funds for compensation have
owners. This is a problem if an owner or third been set aside before the taking is approved by
party right-holder is not registered, or the registra- government decision makers. To prevent the pos-
tion data is incorrect or not current. Attention sibility of development being stalled indefinitely
should be given to devising proactive ways for by affected people challenging the compensation
ensuring that people are genuinely informed of in court, a number of laws (as well as the World
a process that may affect their interests, whether Bank’s Involuntary Resettlement Policy) pro-
or not those interests are formally recognized vide for the possibility of establishing an escrow
and registered rights. Notification periods need account for the payment of compensation when
also to be long enough for people to be able, disputes have been finally adjudicated.13
realistically, to understand the situation and react
appropriately.

Putting in place appropriate and


accessible grievance mechanisms
Although perhaps not necessary where only a few
landowners are affected, where projects involve
large-scale resettlement, international practice 13 Ghana, State Land Act, No. 125 of 1962, section 6. http://
and some national laws encourage the creation ghanalegal.com/?id=3&law=63&t=ghana-laws.

www.worldbank.org/ppp
10 PPP Insights

V. Further reading:
1.  orld Bank Operational Policy on
W
Involuntary Resettlement (OP 4.12).
2. Voluntary Guidelines on the Responsible
Governance of Tenure of Land, Fisheries
and Forests in the Context of National Food
Security.
3. S. Keith, P. McAuslan, R. Knight, J. Lindsay,
P. Munro-Faure and D. Palmer. Compulsory
acquisition of land and compensation. (FAO
Land Tenure Series, 2008)
4. J. Bruce et. al. Land law reform: achieving
development policy objectives. (World Bank
Law, Justice and Development Series, 2006).

PPP In Infrastructure Resource Center


For Contracts, Laws, and Regulation (PPPIRC)
www.worldbank.org/ppp

PPP Insights are brief notes on topics


relevant to public private partnership
projects. PPP Insights are a publication of
the PPP in Infrastructure Resource Center for
Contracts, Laws and Regulations (PPPIRC) and
can be found at www.worldbank.org/ppp. The PPP in Infrastructure Resource Center
views expressed in this note are those of the for Contracts, Laws and Regulation (PPPIRC)
authors and do not necessarily reflect the views c/o The World Bank
or policy of the PPPIRC website project team, the 1818 H Street, NW, MC-6-428
PPPIRC project donors, the World Bank, or any Washington, D.C. 20433
other affiliated organization. Email: ppp@worldbank.org
1301500

PPP in Infrastructure Resource Center for Contracts, Laws and Regulation (PPPIRC)www.worldbank.org/ppp

www.worldbank.org/ppp

You might also like