You are on page 1of 11

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/254088301

Getting land for housing; what strategies work for low-income groups?

Article  in  Environment and Urbanization · September 2009


DOI: 10.1177/0956247809346402

CITATIONS READS

21 264

1 author:

David Satterthwaite
International Institute for Environment and Development
266 PUBLICATIONS   12,990 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Urban Ark Research Project View project

Environment and Urbanization journal View project

All content following this page was uploaded by David Satterthwaite on 24 April 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


EDITORIAL

Getting land for housing; what strategies work for


low-income groups?

DAVID SATTERTHWAITE

I. INTRODUCTION • No emergency services if suddenly faced


with such fires or floods, or with acute illness
Most papers in this issue of Environment and or injury, and no insurance for homes and
Urbanization are about the urban poor themselves possessions lost or damaged.
as active agents in getting land for housing – • Often, a lack of a legal address means no
either negotiating tenure for land they occupy access to government schools and health care
or negotiating for new sites on which they can centres; in some places, this also means not
build. As Somsook Boonyabancha notes in her being able to get onto voter registers.
paper, the urban poor’s drive for change, their
energy and their capacity were never factored This is a life where the residents constantly
into official housing policies. When the poten- face discrimination because of where they live;
tial contribution of the urban poor in resolving being a squatter means being looked down on,
their land and housing issues is taken seriously, a being ignored, being exploited – and being bull-
great deal can be achieved, as the papers in this dozed when some government agency wants
volume indicate. their land, or that land has become sufficiently
valuable for real estate interests to press for its
“redevelopment”.
II. BACKGROUND
Houses or shacks built on illegally occupied land III. CITY LAND MARKETS DO NOT DELIVER
have become such a common feature of urban
NEEDED LAND FOR HOUSING
centres in low- and middle-income nations that
perhaps we forget the implications for their The simplest explanation for this illegality is
inhabitants: the gap between the cost of the cheapest “legal”
accommodation and what large sections of the
• Usually, little or no legal protection against population can afford to pay. In most nations,
eviction, no rule of law and no police pro- cities concentrate new investments and thus
tection against crime. also demand for labour. But legal urban land
• No access or only limited access to the infra- markets and the government regulations that
structure and services that we take for influence them make no provision for the land
granted – not only no safe, sufficient, reliable needed for housing for most of those who live
piped water supply to the home but also no or move to urban areas in response to economic
provision for sanitation, drainage and regular opportunities. In urban space, the land market
solid waste collection.
• No electricity – or electricity supplies that This editorial draws heavily on discussions at a seminar on
are illegal (and often unsafe). land for housing that took place in London in July 2008, at
which draft versions of papers in this issue were presented
• No possibility of a bank account. by Somsook Boonyabancha, Arif Hasan, Beth Chitekwe-Biti,
• Dangerous or inconvenient sites (the occu- Celine D’Cruz and Gordon McGranahan, Florencia Almansi,
pation of less dangerous or more convenient Jason Christopher Rayos Co, Allan Cain, Carole Rakodi and
sites would not be permitted), often with Sheela Patel. We are also grateful to Graham Bowden for his
help with the graphics and to Ernesto Jose Lopez and Alice
more accidental fires and more floods. Sverdlik for their help in preparing Book Notes.

Environment & Urbanization Copyright © 2009 International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). 299
Vol 21(2): 299–307. DOI: 10.1177/0956247809346402 www.sagepublications.com
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 21 No 2 October 2009

is structured by the state (either explicitly or im- where large sections of the urban population live
plicitly) because they determine the rules that in illegal settlements (see the discussion in the
govern land use; in so doing they define the scale paper on the Philippines by John Iremil E Teodoro
of the supply of land and heavily influence its and Jason Christopher Rayos Co). So the issue at
cost. In almost all cities, government agencies the centre of most of the papers in this volume
are also significant landowners. As the supply of is where and how is the need of low-income
formal, legal land for housing fails to provide for groups for land recognized by government and
much of the population, so a vibrant informal acted on.
land and housing market develops. But most of The paper by Arif Hasan on proposals to up-
what this provides is housing options that are of grade the Karachi Circular Railway makes clear
very poor quality, and often in house structures that the scale of evictions is greatly influenced
that are illegal or on land sites that are occupied by how government agencies choose to upgrade
or built on illegally.(1) The end results of this are this railway. There are many encroachments on
well known to readers of this journal, namely the land each side of the track that could be used
a high proportion of the population in most for laying another line – but it is mostly the in-
cities living in overcrowded tenements, cheap formal settlements within this encroachment
boarding houses and informal settlements, and that are threatened by the plans, even though
a high proportion of these residents spending a most of the encroachment is from formal sector
large part of their income on renting accom- construction, including apartment complexes,
modation. Perhaps not surprisingly, the second factories and commercial plazas. There are many
issue of Environment and Urbanization, in 1989, ways to design the (much needed) improvement
focused exactly on this – on the (mostly in- of this railway while minimizing dislocations
formal or illegal) housing and land sub-markets and evictions, but it is not clear whether the
through which those with limited incomes get government agencies involved actually have any
accommodation.(2) The pavement dwellers and interest in doing so. And any cost-benefit analysis
those who rent beds by the hour in dormitories will be greatly influenced by whether the huge
in Mumbai are simply some of the more extreme costs faced by those who are displaced are taken
manifestations of the mismatch between the into account when reviewing the different
physical concentration of economic opportun- options.(3)
ities (and the related high demand for urban The Karachi case also illustrates govern-
land) and the availability of affordable reason- ment use of cut-off dates as a way of limiting the
able quality accommodation. rights of those in illegal settlements. While many
governments have moved some way towards rec-
ognizing the importance to urban economies of
IV. GOVERNMENT LAND POLICIES DO NOT those living in illegal settlements, and their rights
ACT IN THE PUBLIC GOOD
1. For one well-documented example, see the Nairobi Slum
All governments influence land markets and Inventory published by Pamoja Trust, Urban Poor Fund
International and Shack/Slum Dwellers International (2008), which
access to land for housing in a great range of is described in the Book Notes section.
ways – they allocate and use land that is publicly 2. At least 60 papers published in previous issues of Environment
owned; they make land for housing available and Urbanization focus on land for housing. Go to http://eau.
through their infrastructure and service invest- sagepub.com/ to see the range of papers that are listed if you
click on “search for articles” for all papers with “land” in the title
ments; they influence land prices and availability or in the abstract; more defined sets of papers are provided if
through official rules and regulations, including the search is on “eviction” (19 papers), “land tenure” (11 papers),
building permits, land use specifications, plot “upgrading” (24 papers) or “invasion” (8 papers).
sizes and how efficiently and transparently these 3. This parallels the experiences in Nairobi and Mumbai, although
are applied. The gap between the need for land here agreements were reached that limited the number of
people who were displaced and provision was made to provide
for housing and its availability is matched by the alternatives for them. See Patel, Sheela, Celine D’Cruz and Sundar
gaps in official policy and what they deliver. The Burra (2002), “Beyond evictions in a global city; people-managed
wording of constitutions, laws and official decrees resettlement in Mumbai”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 14,
No 1, April, pages 159–172; also Weru, Jane (2004), “Community
often makes much of social justice and the social federations and city upgrading: the work of Pamoja Trust and
aspects of property rights, and of government Muungano in Kenya”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 16, No 1,
commitment to meeting needs even in nations April, pages 47–62.

300
EDITORIAL

relating to housing and services, they often use and Thailand, and a case study of an upgrading
cut-off dates as a way of limiting this recognition. programme in Argentina that transferred land
In Karachi, the Pakistan Railway Authorities have tenure to the inhabitants of informal settle-
recognized that the informal settlements on their ments. What is noticeable, compared to struggles
land have some legitimacy, but claim that only recorded some decades ago, is recognition by the
those formed before 1985 are legitimate. In the urban poor that government needs to be brought
late 1970s, when the state government set up a into the solution. The focus is no longer on large
special agency to regularize informal settlements carefully organized land invasions – which, in
on government land, initially this applied only particular nations or cities for particular periods,
to settlements formed by 1978; the cut-off date did allow large numbers of low-income groups
was later changed to 1985. to get land for housing.(5) Two other papers focus
Another device used by governments to more on land market changes brought about by
limit entitlements to land is the waiting list – as urban development – one in a village on the peri-
explained in the paper on Zimbabwe by Beth phery of the booming city of Gurgaon in India,
Chitekwe-Biti. Local authorities are meant to the other in inner-city Lahore in Pakistan.
manage land allocations for residential develop-
ments, and local residents are meant to register to
get a plot. In theory, allocations are then meant to b. Some successes to report
be influenced by those who have been longest on
the list and those with secure employment. But Perhaps surprisingly, several of these papers re-
it is difficult and time consuming to obtain the port success in urban poor groups’ negotiations
necessary documentation to get on the waiting for land or land tenure – despite their very limited
list, and payment and annual re-registration are incomes and thus capacity to pay. In the cases in
required to remain on it. It is also clear that there Thailand, Zimbabwe, the Philippines, Sri Lanka
is corruption in the assignment of land alloc- and Indonesia, success is related in part to the
ations. In another case of housing queue manage- organization of the urban poor groups (through
ment in Botswana, young people asked if they federated savings groups). This also explains the
could inherit their parents’ place on the queue many successful initiatives in Cambodia, as de-
to improve their own housing opportunities – a scribed in the paper by Somsak Phonphakdee,
reminder of the length of this process for many.(4) Sok Visal and Gabriela Sauter, on how the Urban
Poor Development Fund supports a growing
number of community-based savings groups and
V. STRUGGLES BY THE URBAN POOR provides loans and grants for land acquisition as
well as for upgrading, house building, income
a. The struggle for housing is most often generation and food production. This fund also
a struggle for land supports community organizations to develop
better relations with government agencies.
The struggle for shelter by low-income groups is The community organizations and their fed-
often a struggle for land – either getting land on erations usually need a lot of tenacity to cope
which to build or getting tenure of land already
occupied. Most papers in this issue are about such 4. Kalabamu, Faustin T (2006), “The limitations of state regulation
a struggle – that of the Homeless People’s Federa- of land delivery processes in Gaborone, Botswana”, International
tion in Zimbabwe in negotiations with local gov- Development Planning Review Vol 28, No 2, pages 209–233.

ernments; of the residents of a long-established 5. See Cuenya, Beatriz, Diego Armus, Maria Di Loreto and Susana
Penalva (1990), “Land invasions and grassroots organization:
riverside community in Surabaya threatened the Quilmes settlement in Greater Buenos Aires, Argentina”,
with relocation; of the Karachi residents whose Environment and Urbanization Vol 2, No 1, April, pages 61–73;
homes are threatened by the expansion of the also Peattie, Lisa (1990), “Participation: a case study of how
invaders organize, negotiate and interact with government in Lima,
Circular Railway system; and of the Homeless
Peru”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 2, No 1, April, pages
People’s Federation of the Philippines to avoid 19–30; Arévalo T, Pedro (1997), “May hope be realized: Huaycan
displacements as a result of market pressures, self-managing urban community in Lima”, Environment and
infrastructure development and disasters. There Urbanization Vol 9, No 1, April, pages 59–79; and Barbosa, Ronnie,
Yves Cabannes and Lucia Moraes (1997), “Tenant today, posseiro
are also papers on urban poor organizations’ ne- tomorrow”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 9, No 2, October,
gotiations for land or land tenure in Sri Lanka pages 17–41.

301
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 21 No 2 October 2009

with the many setbacks and delays; it often takes appropriate and affordable (or available through
years of negotiation for agreements to be reached. negotiation), and detailed maps and household
This tenacity is illustrated very strongly by the enumerations in informal settlements, which are
Homeless People’s Federation in Zimbabwe, as needed for upgrading and land tenure transfer.
described in Beth Chitekwe-Biti’s paper. Despite All this also required urban poor organizations
all the economic and political difficulties their to convince local governments, local politicians
members have had to face, including mas- and civil servants that they should work together.
sive eviction programmes, the federation has Once organized, the groups were able to identify
continued to present government with an alter- strategies that proved more successful in getting
native and practical way of dealing with land their voice heard and their proposals accepted.
and housing issues. The federation recognizes Organized urban poor groups can also work
that it has to demand a different set of relation- in the market – combining their savings and
ships with the state – not paternalistic policies financial skills to negotiate an affordable price
with very little real consultation but rather, an with the owner of the land they currently occupy,
agenda they develop and determine. What the or searching for legal land sites that they can buy
federation and the local NGO that supports them and on which they can build their homes. Here,
(Dialogue on Shelter) have learnt is to manage what narrows the gap between what they need
this set of relationships, build a collective co- and what they can afford is a whole range of ways
herent voice across its membership, build and to cut costs – smaller plot sizes (although this
manage alliances with other organizations that often has to be negotiated with the authorities),
are working towards the same goals and construc- incremental building (so costs are spread over
tively engage government in a set of very tangible time), negotiating credit to allow land and
outcomes as opposed to abstract demands for building costs to be spread over a number of
rights. This has enabled the federation to build a years, and careful use of subsidies. Sometimes it
non-confrontational relationship with the state requires forms of tenure that are not ideal but
that has allowed it to interact more equally in that bring down the price – for instance, nego-
partnerships with local authorities, where the pol- tiating 20–30 year leases rather than ownership.
itics are less contested. The federation recognizes The paper by John Iremil E Teodoro and Jason
that the situation in Zimbabwe is in a state of Christopher Rayos Co, looking at how savings
flux, and when greater stability is achieved these groups from the Homeless People’s Federation
alliances might have to be renegotiated. But this of the Philippines find and purchase land, de-
renegotiation can be carried out from a platform scribes how usufruct arrangements can have ad-
that is informed by current experiences and some vantages over leases. Somsook Boonyabancha’s
successes. paper on Thailand is particularly interesting in
Of course, being organized is no guarantee of this regard, in that the national government
success. The groups in Karachi threatened with agency that she headed (the Community Organ-
eviction by the railway expansion are organ- izations Development Institute) supported and
ized through the Network of Railway Colonies empowered hundreds of savings groups formed
(which, in turn, is a member of the All Pakistan by those living in illegal settlements to find
Alliance for Katchi Abadis (informal settlements). and negotiate the solution that worked best for
But in all the cases mentioned above, the urban them. Sometimes this involved returning part of
poor organizations and federations are organ- the land they occupied to the owner in return
ized. They are also actively engaged in offering for tenure of the rest of the land. This involved
local government (and sometimes landowners) considerable inconvenience as a proportion of
partnerships to address land or land tenure house structures were lost, and agreement had to
issues and clear (costed) plans for what needs be reached among all the inhabitants of how to
doing. Again, this is no guarantee of success, re-block and rebuild on the land they did get. But
but it certainly proved important in many in- it enabled them to get secure tenure and much
stances where urban poor groups did get land improved infrastructure. In this particular case,
or land tenure. Developing these plans may this was done within a citywide process in which
also require considerable research by the urban all urban poor communities were engaged.
poor organizations – for instance, careful surveys Much greater scale is achieved where this kind
of vacant land to see what might be both of engagement is supported by flexible finance,

302
EDITORIAL

not through ever larger-scale initiatives but landowners. So location, building design and
rather, by the multiplication of hundreds of loc- cost implications were based on their choices.
ally specific, community-driven solutions. Infrastructure subsidies were available to sup-
All initiatives to upgrade informal settle- port the upgrading.
ments or find land on which to build new houses In the Philippines, as John Iremil E Teodoro
involve trade-offs between what is desired and and Jason Christopher Rayos Co describe, there
what is possible (and affordable). In the case of has also been support from national government
externally financed upgrading programmes, de- for residents of illegal settlements to negotiate
cisions about these trade-offs and what can be the purchase of land from the owners through
afforded are so often made by professionals, the Community Mortgage Programme. This has
thinking that they know best. But so much of the certainly benefited very large numbers of low-
failure or limitations of upgrading and new site income residents, although long waiting lists
development is because the trade-offs did not suit to secure funding have delayed local improve-
the residents. In the Baan Mankong programme ments; furthermore, as the programme is also
in Thailand, and in the other papers in this issue targeted at communities at risk of eviction, there
that concern initiatives developed by the urban are many others left with insecure tenure and
poor federations and local governments, it is no source of funding to purchase the land. The
the residents and their organizations that make paper describes a range of community-led land
the trade-offs. They also manage the upgrading acquisition initiatives by homeowners associa-
process, which helps address the incoherence of tions that belong to the Homeless People’s
many upgrading programmes where respons- Federation of the Philippines, including direct
ibility is divided between many different govern- purchase and usufruct, as well as one funded by
ment agencies that never coordinate their work. the Community Mortgage Programme.
Another issue raised by several papers is
how to protect residents from market pressures
VI. UPGRADING AND LAND TENURE when their settlement has been upgraded. The
upgraded home with good infrastructure and
In some nations, there now seems to be wide- secure tenure brings multiple benefits, but it can
spread recognition within local and national also mean increased costs for services (such as
government that “slum and squatter upgrading” water and electricity) and, in some cases, liability
is an important and legitimate way to improve for local taxes that low-income households have
housing and living conditions for low-income difficulties affording. In addition, successful up-
groups. This often includes provision to support grading programmes boost the value of homes,
the transfer of land tenure to the occupants – as especially if they are in a valuable location and
described in the papers on Argentina, Thailand, the inhabitants get legal tenure. This will make
Indonesia, Sri Lanka and the Philippines. Per- the housing attractive to higher-income groups
haps the possibilities for the community organ- and perhaps encourage residents to sell. One pos-
ization formed by the residents in Surabaya to sibility is to vest land ownership with the whole
negotiate support for upgrading rather than re- community – but this could prevent residents
location were in part due to a 40-year history of who need to move elsewhere from doing so and
support for upgrading in Surabaya.(6) may discourage their investment in their home.
The upgrading and land tenure programme In the Thai programme described above, where
in Thailand is notable for its scale and for the land was purchased, land tenure must remain
extent of government support for low-income collective for the 15-year period during which
groups to develop their own solutions and nego- the communities are repaying their land and
tiate with landowners to achieve this. Between housing loans. Where land tenure was achieved
2003 and 2008, this national upgrading and through leasing public land, this will continue to
secure tenure programme supported 512 initia- be a collective lease. This does not prevent people
tives involving 1,010 communities. Community from choosing to move, but they have to sell
organizations that formed around savings
groups could draw on soft loans to develop 6. Silas, Johan (1992), “Environmental management in Surabaya’s
their own local solutions in terms of location, kampungs”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 4, No 2, October,
price and tenure, and to negotiate with the pages 33–41.

303
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 21 No 2 October 2009

their land and housing through the cooperative contracts with builders and financing through
and in doing so, they get back their investment collective loans. In addition, in this instance,
in their home but not any speculative profit. the government was only willing to transfer land
Somsook Boonyabancha’s paper discusses ownership to the community if they vacated a
the importance of collective land ownership quarter of the plot and returned it to the govern-
for these schemes – although in cases where land ment. It is likely that, increasingly, governments
tenure is owned by the community they can will be attracted to “upgrading schemes” in valu-
choose to shift to individual ownership once the able locations, which allow a proportion of the
loans are repaid. This collective ownership, under- costs to be met by allocating part of the site to
pinned by the collective capacity developed by commercial developments. The redevelopment
the residents, also provides lower-income groups plan for Dharavi, which sought to allocate devel-
with some protection from market forces. It opment rights to international companies, with
protects them through the vulnerable period no consultation with residents and with no
during which they have to afford utility bills and guarantee that everyone would be rehoused (or
loan repayments. Cooperative land tenure also provision made for their livelihoods), is simply
supports equal relations between all members an extreme example of this. Not surprisingly,
– each has an equal share in the land. The agree- there was energetic opposition from residents
ment reached among all the inhabitants in de- (and many professionals) and fairer upgrading
veloping the housing also allowed the design to solutions were sought. Papers in recent issues
reflect innovative mixes of private and shared space, of Environment and Urbanization have reported
especially where space was very constrained. on this struggle(8) and as this issue of the journal
One other market-related issue is the choice was going to press, an open letter to the chief
of housing form. The two upgrading initiatives minister of the state of Maharashtra was once
in Moratuwa described in the paper by Celine again pointing to the disastrous implications for
D’Cruz, Gordon McGranahan and Upali Sumithre Dharavi’s residents of the proposed redevelop-
includes one that involves the construction of ment plan.(9)
multi-storey housing. This is unusual in that
most upgrading schemes have been on sites
where existing housing located on existing plots VII. TENURE AS THE SOLUTION?
could be upgraded – with incremental improve-
ments to the housing (which also makes it more The many cases noted above, where residents of
affordable for those with low incomes). As the illegal settlements obtained tenure, add to a long
paper discusses, for informal settlements in areas history of examples of governments providing
with high land values, one increasingly common secure tenure to the residents of particular illegal
proposal has been redevelopment by commercial settlements – or of the inhabitants of these settle-
builders, with the former inhabitants rehoused in ments negotiating such tenure. Over the last four
part of the new housing stock. For many informal decades, there has also been growing recogn-
settlements, densities are too high to allow the ition that upgrading needs to sort out tenure
upgrading of existing shelters and plots with- for the inhabitants – many of the earliest initia-
out displacing a proportion of the population tives did not – although as the Argentine case
(especially the tenants). For instance, Dharavi in studies highlight, this can be a slow, difficult and
Mumbai has a density that will need multi-storey expensive process. But with a growing number of
housing if everyone is to be rehoused and space
provided for livelihoods (although this need not 7. Patel, Sheela and Jockin Arputham (2007), “An offer of
imply high-rise; this could be accommodated partnership or a promise of conflict in Dharavi, Mumbai?”,
Environment and Urbanization Vol 19, No 2, October, pages
within a mix of 2–5 storey buildings).(7) The paper 501–508; also Patel, Sheela and Jockin Arputham (2008), “Plans for
on Moratuwa discusses the implications for cost Dharavi: negotiating a reconciliation between a state-driven market
and for community control and management redevelopment and residents’ aspirations”, Environment and
Urbanization Vol 20, No 1, April, pages 243–254; and Patel, Sheela,
that the construction of multi-storey buildings Jockin Arputham, Sundar Burra and Katia Savchuk (2009), “Getting
implies. It need not involve a loss of community the information base for Dharavi’s redevelopment”, Environment
control, although it is far more demanding with and Urbanization Vol 21, No 1, April, pages 241–252.
regard to the need for agreed collective decis- 8. See publications in reference 7.
ions by all residents in (for instance) managing 9. For the full text of the letter, see www.dharavi.org/.

304
EDITORIAL

positive experiences of upgrading from the 1970s this organization is around community-managed
onwards, the importance of “secure tenure” savings in which women have central roles. They
came to be accepted. This reached the point develop a collective capacity to come up with
where it was promoted as “the solution” to urban proposals and to seek better deals – either within
poverty by Hernando de Soto.(10) The extrava- the market or with local governments (or often
gant benefits that he claimed would result from with both). In particular, the benefits of savings
the provision of land title both to those who are demonstrated when these organizations se-
got the title (as this released dead capital) and to cure land or land tenure, as they are then able
the wider economy (and government revenues), to develop the site and their homes – sometimes
and the apparent simplicity of this “solution”, with the help of development assistance. This
led to glowing endorsements of this approach shows government agencies what they are cap-
from many world leaders.(11) The fact that there able of, and may lead to partnerships and more
were 30 years of experience with land titling land allocations,(13) or more agreements on trans-
programmes that lent little support to de Soto’s ferring tenure for land already occupied. As noted
claims went unnoticed. So did the more careful earlier, there is also a range of other methods
commentaries on the benefits of land titling through which they develop their proposals –
and tenure that went back to the 1960s.(12) The for instance, surveys of land sites suitable for
review of land titling programmes by Geoffrey housing and enumerations, and maps of the
Payne, Alain Durand-Lasserve and Carole Rakodi settlements for upgrading. It is neither easy nor
describes how most have not produced the automatic that they will get positive responses
benefits that de Soto claimed they would. Invest- from government; but where they do get positive
ment in land and housing, access to formal credit, responses, the scale of what can be achieved
and municipal revenues have not increased no- increases dramatically, especially where govern-
ticeably more than under other tenure regimes, ment agencies can learn how to support this
including those that permit many unauthorized process (as they have in Thailand through CODI
settlements, and there is no significant evidence and in part in the Philippines through the Com-
of poverty levels being reduced. Titling does munity Mortgage Programme). This also sug-
provide increased tenure security – but many gests routes for international funders, who could
alternative forms of tenure, including those in provide the kind of support that CODI provides
many informal settlements, also provide high to low-income communities in Thailand direct
levels of security. In addition, in many nations, to urban poor organizations and federations;
land titles do not necessarily protect people from most such federations have set up their own
eviction and expropriation of their land. Land urban poor funds through which such funding
titling often fails to increase access to credit, and could be channelled (as described in the paper
low-income households that obtain titles are on the Urban Poor Fund in Cambodia). Of
often as reluctant to take out loans as banks are course, the similar tools and methods used by
to lend to them. Titling also does not necessarily the different federations is no coincidence, as
improve infrastructure and services provision, they have long learned from each other and
and many settlements have obtained improved supported each other and are part of Shack/Slum
provision without titles. One puzzle is why de Dwellers International.(14)
Soto’s book and ideas received such acclaim from
so many world leaders (and may indeed con-
10. de Soto, Hernando (2001), The Mystery of Capital, Black Swan,
tinue to do so). Perhaps because the “solution” London, 276 pages.
he promoted appeared so simple and universal? 11. See, for instance, the list of endorsements at http://www.ild.org.
pe/books/mystery.
12. See, for instance, Turner, John F C (1968), “Housing priorities,
VIII. NECESSARY AND SUFFICIENT settlement patterns and urban development in modernizing
countries”, Journal of the American Institute of Planners Vol 34,
CONDITIONS pages 354–363; also Turner, John F C (1976), Housing By People
– Towards Autonomy in Building Environments, Ideas in Progress,
The papers in this issue, and many in previous Marion Boyars, London, 162 pages.
issues, suggest that the best route to a better 13. Manda, Mtafu A Zeleza (2007), “Mchenga – urban poor housing
deal on urban land (and housing) for the urban fund in Malawi”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 19, No 2,
poor is through representative organizations. October, pages 337–359.
In most of the cases elaborated in this volume, 14. For more details, see http://www.sdinet.co.za.

305
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 21 No 2 October 2009

Oddly enough, drawing on these experiences David Satterthwaite, considers the implications of
results in some recommendations for develop- population growth and urbanization for climate
ment assistance that are almost as simple as change. It finds that there is little association
those of de Soto – that international agencies between nations with rapid population growth
find ways to listen to, work with and support the and nations with high greenhouse gas emissions
urban poor groups’ own organizations as they and rapid emissions growth. It is not the growth
develop their capacity to undertake initiatives in population but the growth in the number of
and develop better relations with local govern- consumers and in their levels of consumption
ment. Also, to support urban poor groups to that drives the growth in greenhouse gas emis-
learn from each other and to provide finance that sions worldwide. A significant proportion of
they can draw on as and when they need it. It the world’s urban (and rural) populations have
would be nice if the world leaders who rushed to consumption levels that are so low that they con-
endorse de Soto moved to endorse this position. tribute little or nothing to such emissions. If life-
Certainly, as most of the papers in this issue time personal contributions to greenhouse gas
show, there is a stronger evidence base to support emissions can vary by a factor of more than 1,000,
its effectiveness. depending on the circumstances into which
individuals are born and their life possibilities
and choices, it is misleading to see population
IX. CLIMATE CHANGE MYTHS growth as a driver of climate change.

Three papers in this issue address climate change


issues, and each challenges widely held myths. REFERENCES
The first, by Cecilia Tacoli, explains that mi-
gration should be understood as adaptation (i.e. Arévalo T, Pedro (1997), “May hope be realized: Huaycan
sensible, thought-out responses by individuals, self-managing urban community in Lima”, Environ-
ment and Urbanization Vol 9, No 1, April, pages
households and communities to climate change)
59–79.
not as “a problem” to be avoided (as it is so often
Barbosa, Ronnie, Yves Cabannes and Lucia Moraes
portrayed). Of course, this parallels how rural to (1997), “Tenant today, posseiro tomorrow”, Environ-
urban migration should be understood within ment and Urbanization Vol 9, No 2, October, pages
development – not as an “urban problem” but 17–41.
rather, as a logical response to where economic Cuenya, Beatriz, Diego Armus, Maria Di Loreto and
opportunities are concentrated, as economies Susana Penalva (1990), “Land invasions and grass-
become wealthier. The second paper, by Tom roots organization: the Quilmes settlement in
Chance, shows the enormous progress that has Greater Buenos Aires, Argentina”, Environment and
been made in our capacity to de-link high quality Urbanization Vol 2, No 1, April, pages 61–73.
de Soto, Hernando (2001), The Mystery of Capital, Black
homes with large carbon footprints for heating,
Swan, London, 276 pages.
cooling, hot water and appliances. He describes
Kalabamu, Faustin T (2006), “The limitations of state
the Beddington Zero Energy Development in regulation of land delivery processes in Gaborone,
London, a high density residential development Botswana”, International Development Planning
that accommodates a mix of income groups and Review Vol 28, No 2, pages 209–233.
combines homes and workplaces. This building Manda, Mtafu A Zeleza (2007), “Mchenga – urban poor
not only dramatically reduces carbon dioxide housing fund in Malawi”, Environment and Urban-
emissions per person but also reduces water use ization Vol 19, No 2, October, pages 337–359.
and the carbon footprint of materials used in Pamoja Trust and Shack/Slum Dwellers International
its construction. But as the paper describes, this (2008), Nairobi Slum Inventory, Pamoja Trust,
Urban Poor Fund International and Shack/Slum
alone does not reduce residents’ carbon foot-
Dwellers International, Nairobi, 175 pages.
prints to a “fair share” level (the average per capita
Patel, Sheela and Jockin Arputham (2007), “An offer of
emissions worldwide that would stop dangerous partnership or a promise of conflict in Dharavi,
climate change), as this is also influenced by Mumbai?”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 19,
choices and behaviours outside their homes (for No 2, October, pages 501–508.
instance, the choice to fly on holiday) and by Patel, Sheela and Jockin Arputham (2008), “Plans for
the provision (or lack) of lower carbon transport Dharavi: negotiating a reconciliation between a
modes in the larger city. The third paper, by state-driven market redevelopment and residents’

306
EDITORIAL

aspirations”, Environment and Urbanization Vol 20, Turner, John F C (1968), “Housing priorities, settle-
No 1, April, pages 243–254. ment patterns and urban development in modern-
Patel, Sheela, Jockin Arputham, Sundar Burra and Katia izing countries”, Journal of the American Institute of
Savchuk (2009), “Getting the information base for Planners Vol 34, pages 354–363.
Dharavi’s redevelopment”, Environment and Urban- Turner, John F C (1976), Housing By People – Towards
ization Vol 21, No 1, April, pages 241–252. Autonomy in Building Environments, Ideas in Pro-
Patel, Sheela, Celine D’Cruz and Sundar Burra (2002), gress, Marion Boyars, London, 162 pages.
“Beyond evictions in a global city; people-managed Weru, Jane (2004), “Community federations and
resettlement in Mumbai”, Environment and Urban- city upgrading: the work of Pamoja Trust and
ization Vol 14, No 1, April, pages 159–172. Muungano in Kenya”, Environment and Urban-
Peattie, Lisa (1990), “Participation: a case study of how ization Vol 16, No 1, April, pages 47–62.
invaders organize, negotiate and interact with gov- www.dharavi.org/.
ernment in Lima, Peru”, Environment and Urban- www.ild.org.pe/books/mystery.
ization Vol 2, No 1, April, pages 19–30. www.sdinet.co.za.
Silas, Johan (1992), “Environmental management in
Surabaya’s kampungs”, Environment and Urban-
ization Vol 4, No 2, October, pages 33–41.

307
E N V I R O N M E N T & U R B A N I Z AT I O N Vol 21 No 2 October 2009

308

View publication stats

You might also like