You are on page 1of 88

Regional Impact

Models
by

William A. Schaffer
Professor of Economics
Georgia Institute of Technology
July 1999

© 1999 Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University.


No portion of this document may be reproduced on paper or electronically without
express permission from the Regional Research Institute.
PREFACE

This survey of regional input-output models and their use in impact analysis has evolved from
over twenty years of experience in constructing regional economic models and in teaching about
them. My objectives are to present this family of models in an easily understood format, to show
that the models we use in economics are well-structured, and to provide a basis for understanding
applications of these models in impact analysis. I have tried to present the models in such a way
that understanding the logic and algebra of the simplest economic-base model leads to an
understanding of the only slightly more complex regional and interregional input-output models in
common use today. The advanced models become matrix-algebra extensions of the simple models.
I have greatly benefited from the guidance of Professor Kong Chu over the years. He first
introduced these models to me in 1967 and has helped with interpretations and tedious explanations
of mathematical points until only recently; now he teaches me about life and philosophy. I am in
debt to a number of Georgia Tech students as well. While they have been assistants and students in
title, they have been my best teachers as well. To name a few: Richard Dolce was my first
programmer; Malcolm Sutter spent three years with me programming models in Hawaii and for
Georgia; Clay Hamby maintained Sutter's programs and helped with several impact studies; Larry
Davidson, now Professor of Economics at Indiana, has remained a colleague for over 25 years;
Ross Herbert spent two summers in Nova Scotia thrashing out a completely new system; Steve
Stokes had the pleasure of reconstructing both the Hawaii and Nova Scotia models; and John
McLeod continues to improve my computing skills and graphics and managed data collection and
organization in a recent study of amateur sports in Indianapolis with Davidson. In addition, John
converted this document to its HTML format. Thanks to all of these, to a set of astute but
anonymous reviewers, and to Scott Loveridge, the Regional Research Institute, and West Virginia
University for making this experiment in electronic publication possible.
I would appreciate your reporting of all errors of communication and expression in this
document.

William A. Schaffer
June 1999

© 1999 RRI, WVU i July 1999


TABLE OF CONTENTS

PREFACE.............................................................................................................................. I
TABLE OF CONTENTS................................................................................................. II
LIST OF FIGURES ..........................................................................................................V
LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS .........................................................................................V
LIST OF TABLES.............................................................................................................V
1 INTRODUCTION............................................................................................................... 1
2 REGIONAL MODELS OF INCOME DETERMINATION: SIMPLE
ECONOMIC-BASE THEORY ......................................................................................... 2
ECONOMIC-BASE CONCEPTS ....................................................................................................2
Antecedents............................................................................................................................... 2
Modern origins .......................................................................................................................... 3
THE STRUCTURE OF MACROECONOMIC MODELS....................................................................3
THE "STRAWMAN" EXPORT-BASE MODEL ...............................................................................5
THE TYPICAL ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL ...................................................................................6
TECHNIQUES FOR CALCULATING MULTIPLIER VALUES ..........................................................8
Comparison of planner's relationship and the economist's model ......................................................... 8
The survey method ..................................................................................................................... 8
The ad hoc assumption approach ................................................................................................... 9
Location quotients...................................................................................................................... 9
Minimum requirements ............................................................................................................. 10
"Differential" multipliers: a multiple regression analysis................................................................. 10
CRITIQUE: ADVANTAGES, DISADVANTAGES, PRAISE, CRITICISM...........................................11
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................11
3 INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES AND REGIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTS ...................14
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................14
THE REGIONAL TRANSACTIONS TABLE ..................................................................................14
INCOME AND PRODUCT ACCOUNTS .......................................................................................17
SUMMARY ..............................................................................................................................19
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................19
APPENDIX 1 CD-ROM DATA SOURCES.................................................................................20
APPENDIX 2 MEASURES OF REGIONAL WELFARE ................................................................21
The problem with GSP estimates ................................................................................................ 21
The widespread use of personal income estimates............................................................................ 21
4 THE LOGIC OF INPUT-OUTPUT MODELS ..............................................................22
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................22
THE RATIONALE FOR A MODEL: ANALYSIS VS. DESCRIPTION...............................................22
PREPARING THE TRANSACTIONS TABLE: CLOSING WITH RESPECT TO HOUSEHOLDS ..........22
THE ECONOMIC MODEL ..........................................................................................................23

© 1999 RRI, WVU ii July 1999


Identities: the transactions table.................................................................................................. 23
Technical conditions: the direct-requirements table ......................................................................... 24
Equilibrium condition: supply equals demand................................................................................. 25
Solution to the system: the total-requirements table........................................................................ 26
ECONOMIC CHANGE IN INPUT-OUTPUT MODELS ...................................................................29
Causes vs. consequences of change .............................................................................................. 29
Structural change...................................................................................................................... 29
Changes in final demand............................................................................................................ 30
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................30
5 REGIONAL INPUT-OUTPUT MULTIPLIERS ...........................................................33
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................33
THE MULTIPLIER CONCEPT ....................................................................................................33
An intuitive explanation ............................................................................................................ 33
The iterative approach ............................................................................................................... 34
MULTIPLIER TRANSFORMATIONS ..........................................................................................37
Output multipliers.................................................................................................................... 37
Employment multipliers............................................................................................................ 37
Income multipliers ................................................................................................................... 39
Government-income multipliers .................................................................................................. 39
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................39
APPENDIX 1 MULTIPLIER CONCEPTS, NAMES, AND INTERPRETATIONS...............................43
Introduction............................................................................................................................. 43
Income multipliers ................................................................................................................... 43
Employment multipliers............................................................................................................ 46
Output multipliers.................................................................................................................... 47
Observations and summary......................................................................................................... 47
Further extensions.................................................................................................................... 47
6 INTERREGIONAL MODELS ........................................................................................50
INTERREGIONAL ECONOMIC-BASE MODELS ..........................................................................50
Review of one-region models...................................................................................................... 50
Two-region model with interregional trade..................................................................................... 50
EXTENSIONS AND FURTHER STUDY .......................................................................................52
Interregional interindustry models................................................................................................ 52
Economic-ecologic models......................................................................................................... 52
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................52
7 COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS: THE NOVA
SCOTIA INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES ............................................................................53
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................53
A SCHEMATIC SOCIAL-ACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK ..............................................................53
Commodity accounts ................................................................................................................ 53
Industry accounts...................................................................................................................... 56
Final accounts ......................................................................................................................... 56
AGGREGATED INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES ...................................................................................56
The commodity flows table........................................................................................................ 59
The commodity origins table ...................................................................................................... 59
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................59
8 COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY INTERINDUSTRY MODELS: THE LOGIC
OF THE NOVA SCOTIA INPUT-OUTPUT MODEL ................................................62
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................62
THE DATA ...............................................................................................................................62
TECHNICAL CONDITIONS ........................................................................................................62

© 1999 RRI, WVU iii July 1999


The constant-imports assumption ................................................................................................ 63
The constant market-share assumption.......................................................................................... 63
The constant-technology assumption............................................................................................ 65
Equilibrium condition: supply equals demand................................................................................. 67
Solution: the total-requirements table ........................................................................................... 67
ECONOMIC CHANGE IN COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY MODELS ...............................................68
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................69
APPENDIX 1 THE MATHEMATICS OF THE UNITED STATES INPUT-OUTPUT MODEL..............72
9 BUILDING INTERINDUSTRY MODELS....................................................................74
THE BASIC MODEL ..................................................................................................................74
ESTIMATING TECHNIQUES ......................................................................................................74
Survey-only techniques.............................................................................................................. 75
The supply-demand pool procedure............................................................................................... 75
Export-survey method ............................................................................................................... 76
Selected-values method.............................................................................................................. 77
COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY PROCEDURES ............................................................................77
RIMS .................................................................................................................................... 77
IMPLAN................................................................................................................................ 77
IO7........................................................................................................................................ 77
IOPC ..................................................................................................................................... 77
Others.................................................................................................................................... 77
STUDY QUESTIONS .................................................................................................................77
ANSWERS TO SELECTED QUESTIONS ......................................................................78
REFERENCES .....................................................................................................................80

© 1999 RRI, WVU iv July 1999


LIST OF FIGURES

FIGURE 3.1 THE TRANSACTIONS TABLE AS A PICTURE OF THE ECONOMY ..................................15


FIGURE 4.1 ALGEBRAIC TRANSACTIONS TABLE............................................................................24
FIGURE 5.1 THE ACTIVITY EFFECT OF $100 SALE TO FINAL DEMAND BY THE MANUFACTURING
SECTOR ....................................................................................................................................34
FIGURE 5.2 THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT OF $100 SALE TO FINAL DEMAND BY THE
MANUFACTURING SECTOR ......................................................................................................35
FIGURE 5.3 THE RIPPLE EFFECT OF A $100 EXPORT OF MANUFACTURING OUTPUT..................36

LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS

ILLUSTRATION 2.1 THE SIMPLE KEYNESIAN MODEL .....................................................................4


ILLUSTRATION 2.2 THE PURE EXPORT-BASE MODEL .....................................................................6
ILLUSTRATION 2.3 THE PURE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL ................................................................7
ILLUSTRATION 4.1 THE SIMPLE INPUT-OUTPUT MODEL ..............................................................32
ILLUSTRATION 7.1 SCHEMATIC INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE FOR NOVA SCOTIA................................54
ILLUSTRATION 7.2 SCHEMATIC INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE FOR NOVA SCOTIA EMPHASIZING THE
COMMODITY ACCOUNTS .........................................................................................................55
ILLUSTRATION 7.3 SCHEMATIC INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE FOR NOVA SCOTIA EMPHASIZING THE
INDUSTRY ACCOUNTS .............................................................................................................57
ILLUSTRATION 7.4 SCHEMATIC INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE FOR NOVA SCOTIA EMPHASIZING THE
FINAL INCOME AND EXPENDITURE ACCOUNTS ......................................................................58
ILLUSTRATION 8.1 THE SIMPLE COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY INPUT-OUTPUT MODEL FOR A
REGION.....................................................................................................................................70

LIST OF TABLES

TABLE 3.1 HYPOTHETICAL INTERINDUSTRY TRANSACTIONS......................................................14


TABLE 3.1 HYPOTHETICAL INTERINDUSTRY TRANSACTIONS......................................................14
TABLE 3.2 INCOME AND PRODUCT ACCOUNTS FOR GEORGIA, 1970 ...........................................18
TABLE 4.1 HYPOTHETICAL INTERINDUSTRY TRANSACTIONS WITH ENDOGENOUS HOUSEHOLD
SECTOR ....................................................................................................................................23
TABLE 4.1 HYPOTHETICAL INTERINDUSTRY TRANSACTIONS WITH ENDOGENOUS HOUSEHOLD
SECTOR ....................................................................................................................................23
TABLE 4.2 HYPOTHETICAL DIRECT-REQUIREMENTS TABLE ........................................................25
TABLE 4.3 TOTAL REQUIREMENTS (WITH HOUSEHOLDS ENDOGENOUS).....................................27
TABLE 4.4 INDUSTRY-OUTPUT MULTIPLIERS (WITH HOUSEHOLDS ENDOGENOUS).....................27

© 1999 RRI, WVU v July 1999


TABLE 4.5 TOTAL REQUIREMENTS (WITH HOUSEHOLDS EXOGENOUS) .......................................28
TABLE 4.6 A COMPARISON OF OUTPUT MULTIPLIERS UNDER DIFFERENT HOUSEHOLD
ASSUMPTIONS..........................................................................................................................28
TABLE 5.1 HYPOTHETICAL DIRECT-REQUIREMENTS TABLE ........................................................33
TABLE 5.2 THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT OF $100 IN MANUFACTURING OUTPUT TRACED IN ROUNDS
OF SPENDING THROUGH THE HYPOTHETICAL ECONOMY .......................................................35
TABLE 5.3 OUTPUT, EMPLOYMENT, INCOME, AND LOCAL AND STATE GOVERNMENT REVENUE
MULTIPLIERS FOR HYPOTHETICAL ECONOMY ........................................................................38
TABLE 5.4 SUMMARY OF MULTIPLIER NAMES AND FORMULAS FROM MILLER AND BLAIR,
INPUT-OUTPUT A NALYSIS.......................................................................................................49
TABLE 7.1 AGGREGATED COMMODITY FLOWS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984..........................................60
TABLE 7.2 AGGREGATED COMMODITY ORIGINS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984........................................61
TABLE 8.1 AGGREGATED COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY PROVINCIAL FLOWS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984
.................................................................................................................................................64
TABLE 8.2 DOMESTIC MARKET-SHARE COEFFICIENTS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984.............................65
TABLE 8.3 PROVINCIAL INTERINDUSTRY TRANSACTIONS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984 ........................66
TABLE 8.4 DIRECT REQUIREMENTS PER DOLLAR OF GROSS OUTPUT, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984......67
TABLE 8.5 TOTAL REQUIREMENTS (DIRECT, INDIRECT, AND INDUCED), NOVA SCOTIA, 1984....68
TABLE 8.6 INDUSTRY-OUTPUT MULTIPLIERS, NOVA SCOTIA, 1984 ............................................68

© 1999 RRI, WVU vi July 1999


1 INTRODUCTION
This document introduces the reader to This is the format in which data is now
what has come to be known as "regional currently available at the national level.
impact analysis." This form of analysis Chapter 8 builds the input-output model in
typically emphasizes the regional benefits industry-by-industry terms from the tables
associated with changes in structure of a presented in Chapter 7. These two chapters
regional economy and is normally based on parallel Chapters 3 and 4 in developing the
demand-oriented models of local economies. logic of the model.
Our intention is to introduce the reader to Finally, Chapter 9 provides a brief
the family of models known as regional discussion of ways to build input-output
input-output models. And a primary objective models using nonsurvey techniques. It is
is to show that the models we use in relatively generic and has not yet been
economics are well-structured. I have tried to extended to cover the various commercially
present the models in such a way that available systems.
understanding the logic and algebra of the
simplest economic-base model leads to an
understanding of the only slightly more
complex regional input-output models and
interregional models. The advanced models
become matrix-algebra extensions of the
simple models and are remarkably painless to
understand.
Chapter 2 starts with the simplest model in
regional economics -- the economic-base
model -- and develops a pattern of model
construction which will be followed in all
succeeding models.
Chapter 3 presents the regional input-
output table as a description of the economy
using on simple accounting conventions.
Chapter 4 develops the logic of input-
output models in an easily understood
extension of the logic of economic-base
models.
Chapter 5 focuses on regional input-output
multipliers and thus is the chapter of most
concern for analysts interested solely in
interpretation of impact analyses.
Chapter 6 is a brief extension into
interregional models. Here the methods of
input-output analysis are applied to economic
base models to point toward the interpretation
of interregional input-output models.
Chapter 7 lays out the commodity-by-
industry format in common use in
constructing input-output tables since 1970.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 1 Draft July 28, 1999


2 REGIONAL MODELS OF INCOME
DETERMINATION: SIMPLE ECONOMIC-BASE
THEORY
builders, productive and sterile workers,
Economic-base concepts necessary and surplus labor, etc. The
Economic-base concepts originated with following notes trace obvious antecedents.1
the need to predict the effects of new Mercantilistic thought is a prime example.
economic activity on cities and regions. Say a During the period in which the mercantilists
new plant is located in our city. It directly were dominant, normally considered to be
employs a certain number of people. In a from 1500 to 1776, the nation-states of
market economy these employees depend on Europe were consolidating their power and
others to provide food, housing, clothing, gaining strength to resist or conquer others.
education, protection and other requirements The writers who documented the times
of the good life. The question which city emphasized a philosophy not unlike that of a
planners and economists need to answer, then, modern merchant or chamber of commerce.
is "what are the indirect effects of this new
activity on employment and income in the The mercantilists stressed accumulating a
community?" With these estimates in hand, supply of gold with which to pursue the
we can work toward planning the social nation's political and military objectives. The
infrastructure needed to support all of these economic base of a nation included the
people. sectors which created a favorable balance of
trade. Goods were produced for export
Economic-base models focus on the despite the needs of a poor population, export
demand side of the economy. They ignore of unprocessed materials was prohibited,
the supply side, or the productive nature of shipping in local bottoms was forced
investment, and are thus short-run in whenever possible, and colonies were
approach. In their modern form, they are in exploited as a source of raw materials.
the tradition of Keynesian macroeconomics.
In an introductory economics course, we Thomas Mun, a merchant in the Italian and
might start with a simple model of a closed Near Eastern trade and a director of the East
economy, usually with some unemployment. India Company, was probably the most
In regional economics we deal with an open famous of these writers. His exposition of
economy with a highly elastic supply of mercantilist doctrine in England's Treasure
labor. by Foreign Trade, written in 1630, explained
how "… to enrich the kingdom and to
It is appropriate to start this chapter first encrease our Treasure." He emphasized a
with a look at the place of economic-base surplus of exports as the key:
theory in the history of economic thought and
then twith a review the simple Keynesian Although a Kingdom may be enriched by gifts
model and the elementary economic-base received, or by purchase taken from some other
Nations, yet these are things uncertain and of small
models. We will then look at methods of consideration when they happen. The ordinary
estimating the values of multipliers. means therefore to encrease our wealth and treasure
is by Forraign Trade, wherein wee must ever
Antecedents observe this rule; to sell more to strangers yearly
It is common to divide economies into two
parts. In action, it's us against them; in
primitive life, it is hunters and gatherers; in 1 This section is based on (Oser 1963) and (Kang and
analysis, it will be primary against secondary, Palmer 1958). Oser's The Evolution of Economic
productive and nonproductive, basic and Thought is one of the best short histories of economic
nonbasic, export and support, fillers and thought in print.
© 1999 RRI, WVU 2 Draft July 28, 1999
Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

than wee consume of theirs in value.(from Oser commercial activities were unproductive –
1963 p.14) they added nothing to total value.
The Physiocrats, led by François Quesnay Others of the nineteenth century were more
and briefly prominent in France in the second generous. Jean Baptiste Say in his Treatise
half of the 18th century prior to the French on Political Economy (1803) popularized
Revolution, responded to the excesses of the Adam Smith in France. Say's famous Law of
mercantilists with several points important to Markets, paraphrased as "supply creates its
later thought. They considered society own demand," required that all work be
subject to the laws of nature and opposed productive, that all compensated activity
governmental interference beyond protection creates utility.
of life, property, and freedom of contract.
They opposed all feudal, mercantilist, and Nevertheless, we can see a strong line of
government restrictions. "Laissez faire, thought dividing economic activities into two
laissez passer," the theme phrase for the free parts, and we can see economic-base concepts
enterprise system, is from the Physiocrats. as fitting into a centuries-old pattern.
They opposed luxury goods as interfering
with the accumulation of capital. Modern origins
But, for our purposes, they were Modern literature on the economic base
precursors of economic-base thought in two has been voluminous, but plagued
ways. First, they were important in their occasionally by scholastic sloppiness in
treatment of the sources of value. To the appropriate citations.
Physiocrats, only agriculture was productive. It seems that Werner Sombart, a German
The soil yielded all value; manufacturing, economic geographer writing in the early part
trade, and the professions were sterile, simply of this century, should receive major credit for
passing value on to consumers. This modern concepts.1
classification of productive and sterile
activities is similar to the basic and service Sombart was responsible for the
classification in economic-base discussions. distinction between "town fillers" and "town
builders," ("Städtegründer" and
And second, the Physiocrats visualized “Städtefüller") which appeared in Frederick
money flowing through the economic system Nussbaum's A History of the Economic
in much the same way as blood flows through Institutions of Modern Europe (with full
the living body. Quesnay's tableau permission). But in a series of articles in the
economique was a predecessor of the early 1950's, Richard B. Andrews quoted
circular-flow diagrams popularized in extensively from Nussbaum without
Keynesian macroeconomics. mentioning the fact that Nussbaum had based
Adam Smith, writing in 1776, and heavily his book on Sombart's work. Andrew's work
influenced by these French authors, took a was widely circulated and became the
less extreme but nevertheless strong position. standard reference.
He emphasized production of material or
tangible goods and considered service and The structure of macroeconomic
government as unproductive. models
Karl Marx, in das Kapital, also divided the It is convenient to begin with a review of
economy into two parts. To Marx, necessary the basic elements of model building. We
labor was the source of wealth and was paid can start with the simplest of all
for with a wage barely sufficient to maintain macroeconomic models, the Keynesian model
its provider. Surplus labor was also provided of a closed economy. This model is
by workers but its value was appropriated by presented algebraically in Illustration 2.1 and
the capitalists in the form of surplus value.
Workers had to produce not only what they
consumed but also a surplus for the capitalist.
Menial servants, landlords, the Church, and 1 I rely on Günter Krumme for this statement (Krumme
1968).

© 1999 RRI, WVU 3 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

follows the standard format we will use in all solution. Since this is a process we will
of our models: we outline definitions, follow with each new model considered, it
behavioral or technical assumptions, may be worthwhile to review the nature of
equilibrium conditions, and finally the these model elements.

Illustration 2.1 The simple Keynesian model

Definitions or identities:
Planned Expenditures ≡ Consumption + Investment (Planned sources of income)
(1) E≡ C + I
Actual Income (output) ≡ Consumption + Savings (Actual disposition of income)
(2) Y ≡ C + S
Behavioral or technical assumptions:
Consumption = A linear function of income (Both planned and actual)
(3) C = a + cY (c < 1 = the marginal propensity to consume)
Investment = Planned investment (an exogenously determined value)
(4) I = I'
Equilibrium condition:
Income = Expenditures, or actual income is equal planned expenditures
(5) Y=E
or, with C + I = C + S, we can subtract C from both sides to form an equivalent equilibrium condition:
Drains = Additions
(6) I=S
Solution by substitution:
Y=C+I Substitute (1) into (5)
Y = a + cY + I' Substitute (3) and (4)
Y - cY = a + I' Gather the Y, or income, terms
(1 - c)Y = a + I' Factor out Y
Y = {1/[1 - c]}*(a + I') Isolate Y through division
The simple Keynesian investment multiplier is:
dY/dI = 1/[1 - c]

A definition is a statement of fact. By consumption and savings. We, as recipients


definition, it is always true. In mathematics, of incomes, either spend our incomes or we
the proper term is identity. One of the more save (don't spend). This identity can also be
important identities in macroeconomics is the taken as a definition of saving as the
national income identity: realized national difference between income and consumption.
income (actual expenditures) is the sum of Behavioral assumptions are equations
realized consumption and realized investment. describing the behavior of certain groups, or
In the simple national model, this has to be a actors, in the economy. In this case, the key
true statement—it is a tautology. Actual behavioral relationship is the consumption
expenditures have to equal their sum! function, which postulates consumption as
Another important identity in the simple dependent on, or caused by, income:
model is that income (which is another term C = f(Y)
for 'output') is equal to the sum of

© 1999 RRI, WVU 4 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

which in its linear form may be expressed as: all texts on the Principles of Economics. A
good reference is (Case and Fair 1994).
C = a +cY
where a represents autonomous consumption The "strawman" export-base model
and c is the marginal propensity to consume
(dC/dY). The parameters of the equation are It is common in economics to construct a
a and c. Recall that if a>0, dC/dY<C/Y. "strawman" against which to rail and argue.
Nowhere is this practice more common than
An incidental but important result of this in the regional literature. The "export-base"
assumption is that saving is also a function of model, in which the sole determinant of
income: economic growth is exports, is often built to
S ≡ Y - C = -a + (1 - c)Y represent the arguments of other practitioners.
However, you can seldom find an "export-
The other important behavioral assumption base" theorist who is not also an "economic-
in this simple model is that investment, I, is base" theorist who admits to many other
determined outside the system. It is planned. determinants of growth than exports alone.
In terms common to model building, it is an
exogenous variable in contrast to Now let us construct this strawman and see
consumption, which is determined how a pure export-base stance is untenable.
endogenously (that is, 'within the system'). We move into an open economy and make
exports the sole exogenous factor. If any
(An example of a technical assumption is autonomous expenditure is included (the
the production function. A production easiest is for consumption), then regional
function describes the relations between income can exist even when exports are zero
inputs and outputs. A familiar example is (Ghali 1977).
Q=F(K,L), commonly used to describe how
capital and labor are combined to produce The model differs only slightly from the
output.) simple Keynesian model. With Keynes, the
key leakage was savings. He explained the
Equilibrium is a condition in which the underemployment of a depressed economy as
expectations (plans) of decision-makers resulting when planned investment fell below
(actors) in the system are met. In this simple full-employment equilibrium levels due to a
model, the equilibrium condition is that lack of confidence in investment markets.
income equals planned expenditures, or, what His endogenous variable was consumption,
is the same thing, that saving (which sets the through which most income flows
limits on actual investment) equals planned occurred—the flows became disconnected in
investment. the saving-investment path.
The point is that planned investment and In the export-base model, the endogenous
saving do not have to be equal (even though flow remains consumption, redefined now as
in the end, actual saving has to equal actual “domestic expenditures.” We completely
investment—this is a fundamental principle of ignore saving and hide investment
accounting). When they are equal, then all expenditures within domestic expenditures
parties are satisfied. When they are not, (we are concerned not about explaining
forces are at play which will take income to a depression in the whole economy but about
lower or higher level, bringing saving into explaining changes in regional income). The
equality with planned investment. function of saving in creating a leakage from
Good introductions to the art of model- the economy is now assumed by imports,
building can be found in several readily which is defined as a function of income.
available books (e.g. Bowers and Baird 1971; The function of investment is now assumed
Kogiku 1968; Neal and Shone 1976). The by exports, the driver of the export-based
simple Keynesian model is outlined in almost economy.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 5 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

Illustration 2.2 The pure export-base model


Definitions or identities:
Total expenditures ≡ domestic production + exports (inflows)
(1) E ≡ D + X
Income ≡ Domestic expenditures +Imports
(2) Y ≡ D + M, or D ≡ Y - M
Behavioral or technical assumptions:
Imports = a linear function of income
(3) M = mY (m<1,the marginal propensity to import)
Exports = an exogenously (outside-region) determined value
(4) X = X'
Equilibrium condition:
Income = Total expenditures
(5a) Y = E
or
Drains = Additions
(5b) M = X
Solution by substitution:
Y=Y-M +X Substitute (1) and (2) into (5a)
Y = Y - mY + X' Substitute (3), and (4)
Y - Y + mY = X' Gather the Y, or income, terms
mY = X' Factor out Y
Y = (1/m)*X' Isolate Y through division
The export-base multiplier is:
dY/dX = 1/m

This model obviously stresses openness exogenously determined investment can be


and dependence of the region on events added back into the system. Illustration 2.3
beyond its reach. includes these to develop an almost typical
economic-base model. Only minor
The typical economic-base model interpretive comments are required.
To make the model slightly more realistic
(or, rather, less simplistic!), saving and

© 1999 RRI, WVU 6 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

Illustration 2.3 The pure economic-base model

Definitions or identities:
Total expenditures ≡ Domestic production + Exports + Investment
(1) E ≡ D + X + I
Income ≡ Consumption + Saving
(2) Y ≡ C + S
Consumption ≡ Domestic expenditures + Imports
(3) C ≡ D + M, or D ≡ C - M
Behavioral or technical assumptions:
Consumption = a linear function of income
(4) C = cY (c = the marginal propensity to consume)
Imports = a linear function of income
(5) M = mY (m = the marginal propensity to import)
Exports = an exogenously (outside-region) determined value
(6) X = X'
Investment = an exogenously (outside-system) determined value
(7) I = I'
Equilibrium condition:
Income = Total expenditures
(8a) Y = E
or
Drains = Additions
(8b) M + S = X + I
Solution by substitution:
Y=C-M +X+I Substitute (1) and (3) into (8a)
Y = cY - mY + X' + I' Substitute (4), (5), (6) and (7)
Y - cY + mY = X' + I' Gather the Y, or income, terms
(1 - c + m)Y = X' + I' Factor out Y
Y = {1/[1 - (c - m)]}*(X' + I') Isolate Y through division
The economic-base and investment multipliers are:
dY/dX = 1/[1 - (c - m)], and dY/dI = 1/[1 - (c - m)]

© 1999 RRI, WVU 7 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

The missing element is autonomous T/B = 1/(B/T) = 1/((T-NB)/T)) = 1/(1-NB/T)


consumption (which appeared in the simple = 1/(1-APCL)
Keynesian model). Whether or not it is
included seems to me to be a matter of Here, the ratio of nonbasic activity to total
personal preferences. On the one hand, it activity (NB/T) is the equivalent of the average
might be nice to be complete and consistent propensity to consume locally produced
with the Keynesian model. In addition, it goods.
serves to warn us that the consumption So, if we can obtain values of total and
function is probably curvilinear, originating at basic variables over a period of years, we can
the origin and rising at a decreasing rate with estimate marginal export-base multipliers by
respect to income. The marginal propensity regressing the total on the basic values. With
to consume at the range of incomes over the regression line formulated as T = a +bB,
which we might work is less than the average the slope b is the marginal multiplier (∆T/∆Β)
propensity to consume. A positive for the region.
autonomous consumption permits us to
simulate this case. The survey method
On the other hand, we already have one Of course, the most straight-forward
exogenously determined nonexport variable, method is simply to ask businesses in the
investment. The investment multiplier is area to specify how much of their revenues is
identical to that which would be calculated for basic and to use their responses to accurately
autonomous consumption—we have the divide local business activities into basic and
results without the bother. While this is a service components. In practice, this is
logic which might reduce a model to pulp if seldom done.
pursued too rigorously, I have left
autonomous consumption out of this The neglect of the survey approach is easy
illustration. to explain. It is the most expensive and time-
consuming of approaches. Questionnaires on
sensitive issues such as revenues,
Techniques for calculating employment, and markets are seldom
multiplier values answered freely; to obtain even a smattering
of responses the study team must resort to
Comparison of planner's relationship personal interviews. And even then, the
and the economist's model interviewers must be skilled and persuasive.
Concentrating purely on the practical need In addition, if the area is of any size, the
to develop an easy way to forecast community survey would require careful planning. A
change, early planners developed economic- canvass would be prohibitive and the sample
base ratios (T/B for the average ratio, and must be carefully stratified and selected to
∆T/∆Β for the marginal ratio, where the letters represent the broad spectrum of activities
represent total (T) and basic (B) income or represented in modern communities. Such
employment) by pure observation as rules of care and expense would meet the test of
thumb. By 1952, economists (Hildebrand rationality only if data collection were in the
and Mace 1950) had developed export-base context of a much larger study. The limit to
models in the same analytic framework as the the value of a simple export-base ratio is
Keynesian macroeconomists, with multipliers fairly low, in the hundreds of dollars.
expressed as (1/(1-PCL), where PCL
A final argument against this simple
represents either the average propensity to approach is that the survey would probably
consume locally produced goods (APCL) or yield data for only one year, leading to
the marginal propensity (MPCL). Could calculation of an average multiplier when a
these approaches be equivalent? Yes. marginal multiplier is the most appropriate.
Charles M. Tiebout showed us how (Tiebout
1962). Tracing the metamorphosis for
average propensities,

© 1999 RRI, WVU 8 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

area and the "necessary" employment in the


The ad hoc assumption approach area.
The easiest and least expensive of methods In fact, then, excess employment can be
is simply to rely on arbitrary assignment of computed without reference to location
activities to basic or nonbasic categories. quotients through this reduction of the
This could be done by assignment of, say, formula:
employment or payrolls for entire industries
into categories, or it could be accomplished EXi = ei - (Ei/E)*e
with a little more finesse by estimating
proportions of employment involved in basic It is convenient to retain the initial formula as
activities. a reminder of the logic, and to compute
location quotients as reminders of the
Needless to say, the chance of errors is strengths of exporting industries.
large even for experienced analysts, and the
multiplier will again be an average one with Now it is easy to estimate export
limited use in analyzing the effect of change. employment for each industry in the area and
to sum these estimates to yield a value for
Location quotients export employment for the area in some
particular year. With this number and total
The location quotient is probably employment, an average multiplier for the area
responsible for the long-life and continuing can be computed. With a set of these values
popularity and use of economic-base over 10-20 years, the more acceptable
multipliers. These quotients provide a marginal multiplier can be estimated by
compelling and attractive method for simple regression.
estimating export employment (or income).
While it is common to use employment as
A location quotient is defined as the ratio the primary basis for these calculations, other
LQi = (ei/e)/(Ei/E), measures such as wages and salaries are just
as appropriate. Indeed, wage data is more
where ei is area employment in industry i, e is accessible electronically, especially on CD-
total employment in the area, Ei is ROM. County Business Patterns, a standard
employment in the benchmark economy in source of employment and payroll data, is
industry i, and E is total employment in the available for years since 1986, two years per
benchmark economy. Normally, the disk. In considerable detail, this is the best
"benchmark" economy is taken to be the data for recent years, but skill with mainframe
nation as the closest available approximation computers, tapes, and programming is
to a self-sufficient economy. required to gain access for earlier years.
The Regional Economic Information System
Assuming that the benchmark economy is (REIS), updated on CD-ROM annually by the
self-sufficient, then a location quotient greater U.S. Department of Commerce with a two-
than one means that the area economy has year lag, includes a relatively aggregated 10-
more than enough employment in industry i category employment series for the years
to supply the region with its product. And a 1969-96 as well as a more detailed earnings
quotient less than one suggests that the area is series for every county in the nation. This
deficient in industry i and must import its data makes earnings-based location quotients
product if the area is to maintain normal a snap, especially if historic estimates are
consumption patterns. desired.
Surplus or export employment in industry Location quotients have been in use by
i can be computed by the formula regional analysts for over 40 years now, and
EXi = (1 - 1/LQi)*ei , LQi > 1, have been commented on at length. We
should look at the assumptions involved in
which is easily shown to be the difference their use as well as the advantages and
between actual industry employment in the disadvantages.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 9 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

The literature records at least three specific Minimum requirements


assumptions: (1) that local and benchmark
consumption patterns are the same, (2) that In the 1960's, when available computing
labor productivity is a constant across technology favored frequent use of economic-
regions, and (3) that all local demands are met base models, one of the alternatives to the use
by local production whenever possible. The of location quotients was the minimum-
first assumption is not serious: not only can requirements approach (Ullman and Dacey
we not discern differences in consumption 1960). This variation involved a slight
patterns without extraordinary expense but we revision of the location-quotient formula to
can suspect that differences in production min
patterns are more important. Purchases of EXi = ei - (Ei/E) *e ,
intermediate goods by producers differ for min
regions depending on industry mix. (It turns where (Ei/E) is the minimum employment
out that we can account for industry mix with proportion for industry i in cities of size
input-output models, so this difference has similar to the subject city. You can readily
been accounted for by the march of time.). see that we have substituted a varying
benchmark employment proportion for a
The constant-labor-productivity constant one:
assumption is difficulty to avoid. Its impact min
can be ameliorated slightly through using LQi = (ei/e)/(Ei/E) .
earnings data, which can be assumed to reflect
regional productivity variation through While still appearing in various forms in
differences in wage rates. (This assumption the literature, the method suffers from two
could in turn be attacked if wages vary more major criticisms. One is that, if enough cities
by area cost-of-living than by productivity.) are included in the selected set, all regions will
be exporting and none may be importing.
The assumption that local demands are met The other is similar in that, if we use data
first by local production is the more tenuous defined in a fine level of detail (which seems
of the three. It is obviously not true, as any an improvement, and was one in location-
visit to a grocery or clothing store will attest. quotient estimates) we may reduce local needs
But it is common, and a better alternative is to near zero and make almost all production
hard to come by. for export (Pratt 1968).
In addition to the disadvantages accruing At any rate, the method is not commonly
from these assumptions, another major fault used now. The location-quotient method
is that the method is dependent on the degree remains the virtually sole survivor as a simple
of aggregation of the data, making means of identifying export industries.
comparisons among various studies of little
value. To illustrate the problem, consider the "Differential" multipliers: a multiple
food and kindred products industry in regression analysis
Atlanta. The location quotient computed for
this broad industry should be less than one, Another approach which has been used in
and if excess employment were computed estimating economic-base multipliers is to fit
based on this classification, none would be a multiple regression equation to regional
credited to the food industry. But if the data. The first of these studies arose in a
classification were more detailed, the soft- study of the impact of military bases on
drink industry would show a large number of Portsmouth, New Hampshire in 1968 by
excess employees, since the headquarters of Weiss and Gooding (Weiss and Gooding
Coca-Cola is in the city. 1968).
The overpowering advantages of using Simple economic-base models ignore the
location quotients are that the method is possibility that different industries may have
inexpensive and the exercise of computing different impacts on their community. The
excess employment may give the analyst an regression technique eliminates this
opportunity to gain insights of interest in simplifying assumption. Weiss and Gooding
themselves. set up an equation

© 1999 RRI, WVU 10 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

S = Q + b 1 X1 + b 2 X2 + b 3 X3 , Pits the area against the rest of the world, showing


no interdependence between regions
where S represents service employment, Q is
a constant, and the X terms are, in order, Multiplier varies with size of region. (As a region
private export employment, civilian grows it diversifies, importing less and so
employment at the Portsmouth Naval increasing local consumption and the multiplier
Shipyard, and employment at Pease Air Force (Sirkin 1959)). Also, larger regions tend to
influence neighbors more and so to enjoy larger
Base.
feedback effects (Richardson 1972)
With data fitted from 1955-64, their results
An employment multiplier is often used to discuss
were income changes. (But this assumes that
S = -12905 + .78 X1 + .55 X2 + .35 X3 employment and per capita income are perfectly
(.31) (.23) (.14) correlated -- in a simple economy with perfectly
elastic supplies of labor this might be the case
The multipliers are 1+ bi for each sector. although, of course, the world is not simple.)
Weiss and Gooding used a mixture of Assumes that exports are the sole determinant of
assumption and location quotient methods in economic growth. (It is not reasonable for us to
allocating export employment and assumed take the rap for this.) Any rational person can see
that the export sectors were independent and that the determinants of growth are many -- the
that workers in the export sectors demanded simple model just emphasizes one determinant.
similar services. Perhaps the fault lies in early attempts to formulate
multipliers and the ease with which the simple
This variation on economic-base modeling multipliers could be constructed. (Ghali 1977;
has not fallen into widespread use for several Sirkin 1959))
reasons: its flexibility (in number of Direction of dependence may be questionable:
exogenous sectors) is limited by the number which comes first, export growth or a strong
of observations available, otherwise the service sector, or interdependence? Should we be
coefficients may not be significant; concerned with preconditions for export growth
determining the export content of industry (setting up an attractive service sector) in this
employment remains a demanding chore; and simple model? Are we planning growth or
with the rise of desktop computing, input- explaining the true basis?
output models are better sources of industry- Although castigated for decades, the
specific multipliers and are similar in cost. economic-base model has survived as a very
succinct expression of the power of demand
Critique: advantages, in regional income determination. The most
disadvantages, praise, criticism current, and perhaps the clearest and most
complete, statement of its status is found in a
Economic-base models suffer from old recent review by Andrew J. Krikelas (1992),
age: they have been built by so many available from the Federal Reserve Bank of
analysts with varying levels of quality and Atlanta or in .pdf format from the School of
they have been criticized so often that little Economics web site at Georgia Tech
remains except the concept. (http://www.econ.gatech.edu/faculty/schaffer/.
The indictment would include the
following phrases:
Short run Study questions
Nonspatial 1. Outline a simple export-base model and compare
Simple adaptations of national models it with the simple Keynesian model of national
income determination.
Data is normally available for administrative units
2. Criticize the export-base model, then note its
(counties) which may be poorly defined as
virtues.
economic regions.
3. Justify classifying the minimum-requirements
Ignores capacity constraints method for computing export-base multipliers as
Assumes perfect elasticity of supply for inputs

© 1999 RRI, WVU 11 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

a special variation of the location-quotient 7. Construct the economic model on which the
method. equation estimated to determine "differential
4. Outline the methods commonly used in multipliers" is based.
estimating export-base multipliers, noting their 8. Rebuild the models in Illustrations 2.1-3 with
advantages and disadvantages. the equilibrium condition stated as "Drains =
5. The "pure economic-base model" outlined in Additions."
Illustration 2.3 does not include any reference to 9. Build the economic model behind the estimating
autonomous consumption. Assume that total equation T = a - bB.
expenditures include autonomous consumption 10. Which should be the best, an average multiplier
expenditures, that the marginal propensities or a marginal multiplier?
remain linear, and that imports are a linear
function of total expenditures. Rebuild the 11. In Illustration 2.3, the alternative formulation of
"pure" model as a "typical" model under these the equilibrium condition is M+S=X+I. Lay out
assumptions. How has the multiplier changed? the full model using these variables.
6. Collect data from an electronic source for 12. Complete the exercise on the following page.
available years and use location quotients to
estimate export employment in a county.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 12 July 1999


Economic-Base Theory Chapter 2

Exercise
EXPORT-BASE MULTIPLIER CALCULATIONS

You are the planner/economist for a simple 3-industry community and need to produce a multiplier
estimate for a report due this afternoon. Answer the following questions and do the calculations.

State the formulas for the location quotient and export employment for an industry:

LQi =

EXi =

Data and calculations

Employment Empl. proportions Location Export


Industry Local National Local National quotient employment

Year 1

1 10 80 ______ ______ ______ ______


2 4 20 ______ ______ ______ ______
3 2 60 ______ ______ ______ ______
Total 16 160 1.00 1.00

Year 2

1 16 100 ______ ______ ______ ______


2 6 25 ______ ______ ______ ______
3 2 75 ______ ______ ______ ______
Total 24 200 1.00 1.00

Multipliers
Concept In words In numbers Value
Average multiplier, year 2 = ___________________ = ____________ = _______

Marginal multiplier, years 1-2 = ___________________ = ___________ = _______

© 1999 RRI, WVU 13 July 1999


3 INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES AND REGIONAL INCOME
ACCOUNTS
with final demand sectors. The central
Introduction element in this model is a regional
This chapter presents the input-output table transactions table such as that shown in Table
as an accounting system for an economy. 3.1. This table records transactions between
Labeled “hypothetical”, the numeric example five broad industries, three final-payments
is actually a 5-industry aggregation of the sectors, and three final-demand sectors. (The
detailed table for Georgia in 1970 (Schaffer original presentation was of transactions
1976). (Although out-of-date, it fits the style between 50 industries, six final-payments
of most regional input-output tables in current sectors, and 6 final-demand sectors.)
use in the United States. It also fits the text, Each row in this table accounts for the
which is a slight revision of that used to sales by the industry named at its left to the
explain the Georgia system.) First we look at industries identified across the top of the table
the table as a whole; then we examine in more and to the final consumers listed in the right-
detail the quadrant of the table which reports hand section of the table. Intermediate goods
the income and product accounts for this are sold to local industries for use in
regional economy. producing other products while finished
goods are sold to final consumers. Goods
The regional transactions table exported from the region to other parts of the
nation and the world are listed under exports
A regional input-output model traces the in the final-demand section, regardless of
interactions of local industries with each their stage of production. The sum of a row
other, with industries outside the region, and is the total output or total sales of an industry.

Table 3.1 Hypothetical interindustry transactions


Buying Con- Manu- Total Household Other lo- Total
Industry Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- industry expendi- cal final final Total
Selling tion tion turing Trade vices demand tures demand Exports demand demand
industry (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
Extraction (1) 183 31 599 6 73 892 99 88 596 782 1674
Construction (2) 14 1 43 14 293 364 0 1803 353 2155 2520
Manufacturing (3) 142 414 1390 110 356 2412 1275 1130 9344 11750 14162
Trade (4) 52 224 520 72 257 1126 2563 161 970 3695 4820
Services (5) 102 221 862 558 1990 3733 4262 523 2828 7613 11347
Total local inputs (6) 493 891 3415 760 2969 8527 8199 3705 14091 25995 34523
Households (7) 595 665 3696 2385 4603 11944 100 2524 0 2623 14567
Other payments (8) 261 191 1624 1365 2402 5 8 4 2 (3789.2) (943.2) 1097.5) 0 5842
Imports (9) 325 773 5428 311 1372 8209 3778 1057 -12994 -8159 50
Total final payments ( 1 0 ) 1181 1629 10747 4060 8378 25995 3878 3581 -12994 -5536 20459
Total inputs (11) 1674 2520 14162 4820 11347 34523 12077 7285 1097 20459 54982

© 1999 RRI, WVU 14 Draft July 28, 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

Thus, sales by the extraction industry (a produced in quantities insufficient to meet


combination of agricultural, forestry, fishing, local needs. The sum of the entries in each
and mining industries) are shown in row one column represents the total purchases by the
of Table 3.1. Of the total output worth $1,674 industry in question. Since profits, losses,
million, over 35 percent is sold to light depreciation, taxes, etc., are recorded in the
manufacturing (which processes it for further table as final payments, the total purchases
sale), and over 35 percent is sold outside the and payments must equal total sales. Inputs
region. The remaining sales are largely to equal outputs; hence the term "input-output."
other industries within the broad extractive For example, the purchases and payments
industry itself. of the extractive industry are shown in
Each column in Table 3.1 records the column 1 of Table 3.1. Since this industry is
purchases, or inputs, of the industry identified almost 90 percent agriculture, the column
at the top of the column from the industries reflects large intraindustry transactions
named at the left. Payments by the industry (purchases of feeder stocks, baby chicks,
to employees, holders of capital, and grains, etc.), substantial purchases from light
governments are contained in the first two manufacturing (feeds), and a large payment to
rows of the final-payments section of the households for labor and proprietors' income.
table. These payments constitute the "value Local farmers also import from outside the
added" by the industry in question. state large amounts of feeds and other
Purchases from industries outside the region supplies. Notice that the total inputs is the
are identified in the last row of the final- same as the total outputs identified in row 1.
payments section and are called "imports."
These imports may be either of goods not
produced at all in the region or of goods
Figure 3.1 The transactions table as a picture of the economy
Production Final Demands

II I
Interindustry Consump-
t ion
s truct ure
pat terns

III IV

Incomes Nonmarke t
t ransfers

Total inputs

© 1999 RRI, WVU 15 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

Now, with this brief introduction to a regional and their payments to households and
transactions table, let us look at the table as an intergovernmental transfers. The quadrant
accounting system for an economy. Figure also typically includes purchases by final-
3.1 shows an input-output table in skeleton demand sectors from industries outside the
form and divided into four quadrants. region.
Quadrant I describes consumer behavior, Now, to make a major point about the
identifying consumption patterns of hazards of aggregation, let's look at the table
households and such other local final users of as originally presented, as a picture of the
goods as private investors and governments. Georgia economy in 1970. Out of a total
Another important part of Quadrant I is the output of over $34 billion, Georgia's
export column, which shows sales to other manufacturing output in 1970 was valued at
industries and consumers outside the regional over $14 billion and its service output at over
economy. Since these goods would not $11 billion, indicating that Georgia's
normally reappear in the region in the same economy was dominated by the
form, these sales are regarded as final. manufacturing and service industries. Even
According to economic-base theory, in which so, Georgia was not a major manufacturing or
final demand is the motivating force in an service economy by national standards, as can
economy, we would look in this quadrant for be seen in the following comparison of the
activity-generating forces and we would industrial origins of value added in Georgia
especially examine the government and export and the United States (Schaffer 1976)
sectors.
Percent of value added
Quadrant II depicts production Sector Georgia U.S.
relationships in the economy, showing the
ways that raw materials and intermediate Agriculture, mining 4.2 5.2
goods are combined to produce outputs for Construction 4.4 5.6
sale to other industries and to ultimate Manufacturing 26.0 28.9
consumers. This is the most important Transportation, utilities 7.7 8.1
quadrant in an input-output table. For Trade 18.3 14.6
regions, it typically ranges in size between 30 Services 25.6 26.9
and 500 industries. Quadrant II is the basis Government 13.7 10.7
for the input-output model itself.
Quadrant III shows incomes of primary Georgia had larger contributions to value
units of the economy, including the incomes added from trade and government than did the
of households, the depreciation and retained nation, and smaller contributions from the
earnings of industries, and the taxes paid to extractive industries, construction,
various levels of government. These manufacturing, utilities, and services. This
payments are also called value added; since deviation from the national pattern is an
they are so hard to identify individually, these expression of the region's modest stage of
incomes are frequently recorded as one value- development and its central position in the
added row. The quadrant also includes Southeast.
payments to industries outside the economy But this observation also shows that the
for materials and intermediate goods which "importance" of an industry is completely
are imported into the region. Since all of dependent on the definitions and aggregation
these payments to resource owners and to patterns employed in constructing a table. By
outsiders leave the industrial system of the enlarging the table and altering sector
region, they are called "final payments." definitions, we could change the apparent
Quadrant IV identifies primarily importance of industries. For example, by
nonmarket transfers between sectors of the combining the agricultural industries with the
economy and might properly be labeled the food-processing industry (normally in
"social transfers" quadrant. Here we see manufacturing) we could make the
gifts, savings, and taxes of households; we "agriculture-based" industry larger than any
see the surpluses and deficits of governments of the components of the "trade" or "service"

© 1999 RRI, WVU 16 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

industries. In fact, in the 29-industry version Table 3.2 is the transactions table rearranged
(not shown here) of the Georgia table, the five to emphasize Quadrant IV, the sector in which
largest industries in terms of output are: 1) social accounts are traced. This social-
trade, 2) finance, insurance and real estate, 3) accounts table completely ignores the flows
services, 4) textile mill products, and 5) of intermediate products through the
transportation equipment. production quadrant and suppresses the
details of the other quadrants. It emphasizes
A second interesting item in Table 3.1 is (1) the total final payments to resource
the gross product of Georgia. Analogous in owners for their contributions to production,
concept to the gross national product, gross (2) the aggregate demand for final products,
regional product (GRP) can be defined as and (3) the transfers which take place between
total production without duplication, or as the primary units of the economy.
economic product of all factors of production
residing in the region. It can also be seen as We have slightly rearranged the table. The
the total final payments (adjusted for imports) row showing purchases from nonlocal
in the region, 20.459 billion dollars. industries (imports) has been moved above
Alternatively, it is also the total final demand the final-payments rows. A row for transfers
by ultimate consumers of the region's to households has been added to account for
products (net of imports). nonproductive money transfers to persons.
And the one row for other payments in Table
In summary, an input-output table traces 3.1 has been expanded into four to show the
the paths by which incomes flow through the details of final payments and transfers.
economy. Quadrant I is where the spending
cycle begins and is where finished goods go Six accounts are outlined in the table. The
to satisfy the needs of final consumers. receipts side of the household account is
Quadrant III is where the production cycle shown in the household-income and
starts, with households and other resource household-transfers rows, which total to be
owners, including governments, receiving personal income; the payments side is
payments for their contributions to the detailed in the household-expenditures
production process. Quadrant II traces column. The saving and investment account
production relationships, describing the is shown in the capital-residual row (retained
technology of production in the economy. It earnings, depreciation, savings) and the
outlines the market sector of the economy. investment column. Local, state, and federal
Quadrant IV identifies nonmarket flows of government accounts are shown in their rows
money, showing purchases of labor inputs by and columns. And the rest-of-the-world
governments, taxes paid by households, account is shown in the row labeled
surpluses and deficits of governments, and "purchases from nonlocal industry" and the
transfers between governments and other column "net exports." By placing these
governments and people. accounts into one matrix, we gain both
economy in presentation and a feeling for
Income and product accounts their commonality.
The input-output table embodies not only Gross state product (GSP) may be
measures of gross regional product but also a measured in two ways, the incomes approach
summary set of social, or income and product, and the expenditures approach. Let us start
accounts for the region. Like the input-output with the expenditures approach.
table itself, these accounts are part of a
double-entry accounting system for the
economy. In the same way that a
businessman uses his accounts to develop a
consolidated income statement for his firm,
the economist uses income and product
accounts to measure the performance of the
economy and to compare the behavior of
parts of the economy against other standards.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 17 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

Table 3.2 Income and product accounts for Georgia, 1970


Sales to House-
Account pro- hold Private Expenditures of governments Total
receiving\making cessing expendi- invest- Federal, Federal, Net final Total
payment sectors tures ment Local State defense other exports demand receipts
Purchases from
local processors 8,527.2 8,199.3 1,400.4 460.9 432.3 1,057.0 353.9 14,091.3 25,995.1 34,522.3
Purchases from
nonlocal industry 8,159.3 3,777.8 802.1 138.8 115.8 -12,993.8 -8,159.3 0.0
Total purchases
from industry 16,686.5 11,977.1 2,202.5 599.7 548.1 1,057.0 353.9 1,097.5 17,835.8 34,522.3
Household
income 11,882.6 99.7 790.7 372.7 671.0 689.3 2,623.4 14,506.0
Total purchases of
goods and services 28,569.1 12,076.8 2,202.5 1,390.4 920.8 1,728.0 1,043.2 1,097.5 20,459.2 49,028.3
Household
transfers 61.0 51.3 190.7 209.0 848.0 1,299.0 1,360.0
Capital
residual 3,019.1 871.6 -1,688.2 -816.6 2,202.5
Local govern-
ment income 480.3 377.9 445.9 47.3 112.4 983.5 1,463.8
State govern-
ment income 858.8 341.9 22.1 408.8 -55.2 717.6 1,576.4
Federal govern-
ment income 1,533.9 2,197.8 19.1 533.5 2,750.4 4,284.3
External
transfers
Total
outlay 34,522.2 15,866.0 2,202.5 1,463.8 1,576.5 1,937.0 2,347.3 0.0 25,393.1 59,915.3

Using expenditures, we define GSP as Including business transfer payments


state output at market value as measured (primarily bad debts) and social security
through the expenditures of final consumers. contributions, this amounts to $14,567
This approach accounts for the final demand million, or 71.2 percent of GSP; the
for Georgia's product by four groups of corresponding national figure is 75.2 percent.
consumers: households, investors, The "capital residual," or gross business
governments, and private units outside the saving, of processors is $3,019 million and
state economy. In Table 3.2, GSP is seen as comprises 14.8 percent of GSP, which
total purchases of goods and services for final corresponds to 9.4 percent in the nation. The
consumption, $20,459 million. In 1970, this capital-residual row of Table 3.2 includes two
was 2.1 percent of GNP. In comparison to transfers worth noting: one is personal
expenditures for GNP, Georgia spent less of savings; the other is a negative entry of
her gross product on personal consumption $1,688 million in the exports column. This
(59.0 percent in contrast to 62.9 percent for "export" accounts for the surpluses and
the nation), less on private investment (10.7, deficits of the various governments and the
13.5), and less on local and state government outside world. Much of it represents flows of
(11.3, 12.2); she made up for this in terms of retained earnings and capital consumption
federal defense expenditures (8.4, 7.5), other allowances to the nonresident owners of
federal expenditures (5.0, 3.6), and net private branch plants in Georgia.
exports (5.3, 0.4). The third receipt to be added to GSP is
Using incomes, we can arrive at a similar local government income from the processing
GSP by adding the "income receipts" of the sector. At $480 million, this figure accounted
various accounts. The major receipt is earned for 2.3 percent of GSP. The next largest
household or personal income, which consists income of local governments in Georgia was
of wages and salaries, other labor income, a set of intergovernmental transfers from the
proprietors' income, and property incomes. state government (much of which is offset by

© 1999 RRI, WVU 18 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

a similar transfer from the federal government must be constructed on a regular basis by
to the state). The deficits of local state agencies.
governments are shown as an "export"
(primarily bonds) worth $112.4 million. Study questions
The fourth receipt to be counted as part of 1. Why should regional economic accounts be
GSP is state government income from the constructed?
processing sector of $859 million.
2. Define gross regional product.
Combined state and local revenues from
industrial sources are 6.5 percent of GSP, 3. Construct a social accounting matrix like Table
compared to 8.5 percent on the national level. 3.2 for the standard economic base model of
Note that the state had a surplus in 1970 of Chapter 2.
$55 million, entered as a negative value in the 4. Contrast personal income and gross regional
exports column. product as measures of a region's economic
performance.
The final receipt to be included in GSP is
federal government income from the
processing sectors. Totaling $1,534 million,
this income was 7.5 percent of GSP,
compared with 6.9 percent on the national
level. Notice that the federal government still
spent $534 million more in Georgia than it
received in taxes, accounted for largely
through defense expenditures.
In sum, total receipts and payments by
each of the six final sectors in the economy
were $25,393 million. This figure is $4,934
million in excess of GSP. Where quadrant II
shows intermediate transactions in the
processing sector, the transfers quadrant
records duplicative transactions in the social
or political sector.

Summary
A state input-output table accounts for
flows of monies through the state, showing
details regarding consumer behavior, the
technology of production, incomes, and social
transfers. The transfers quadrant of a table
can be slightly modified to show the details
presented in the more traditional income and
product accounts.
The social accounts are useful in two ways.
One is in comparisons between economies; a
brief contrast of the Georgia and U.S.
economies has been sketched here and
Georgia has been found to be strong in trade
and government and slightly below the
national pattern in manufacturing and
services. The other way is in comparisons
over time. But to show performance over
time, social accounts and input-output tables

© 1999 RRI, WVU 19 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

from the national income and product accounts


Appendix 1 CD-ROM data sources (NIPA's). Estimates of constant-dollar GSPO are
made using GDP by industry implicit price
One of the best sources of regional data is deflators.
the Regional Economic Information System
(REIS), produced by the Regional Economic BEA prepares GSPO estimates in 61-industry
Measurement Division of the Bureau of detail. For each industry, estimates of gross product
Economic Analysis. is composed of four components (estimated in
current-dollars only): (1) Compensation of
Many Web sites have information from employees; (2) proprietors' income with inventory
REIS available for downloading, but the most valuation adjustment (IVA) and capital
common source for the heavy user is the CD- consumption allowances; (3) indirect business tax
ROM disk. Published annually in May, it and nontax liability (IBT); and (4) other, mainly
contains data for states, regions, and counties capital related, charges. Most of the compensation
and proprietors' income components of GSP are
from 1969 forward, with a two-year lag. (The primarily based on BEA's estimates of earnings by
May 1998 disk contains data from 1969 to place of work, an aggregate in the State personal
1996.) income series. The IBT component of GSP reflects
For counties, the disk provides data on liabilities charged to business expense, most of
personal income and its sources, employment which are sales and property taxes levied by State
and local governments. The capital charges
(in broad industry categories), an economic component of GSP comprises corporate profits
profile, transfer payments, and agricultural with IVA, corporate capital consumption
output. In addition it contains data on the allowances, business transfer payments, net
journey to work between counties in 1970, interest, rental income of persons, and subsidies
1980, and 1990, as well as annual estimates of less current surplus of government enterprises.
gross commuter incomes. For Georgia, the disk yields the following
For states, all of the above are available as data for 1990:
well as estimates of Gross State Product for Value
each state from 1977 to 1996. The following Item (in $ billion)
description comes from the "readme.doc" on Gross state product 136.875
the 1994 disk: Indirect business taxes 10.061
Current and constant-dollar estimates of gross Compensation of employees 83.861
state product(GSP) by industry for States and Proprietor's income 11.405
regions for 1990 and revised estimates for 1977-89 Current capital charges 31.547
are presented. The 1987 Standard Industrial
Classification (SIC) is incorporated, beginning
with the estimates for 1987. Estimates for 1977-86 With budget reductions, the 1998 disk yields
are on the 1972/77 SIC code. The current dollar the following abbreviated data:
estimates are published in the December 1993
Survey of Current Business and update and extend Value
those published in the December 1991 Survey. The Item (in $ billion)
estimates for 1977-90 are consistent with the Gross state product 183.042
revised estimates of gross product by industry for Indirect business taxes 13.951
the Nation that were published in the May 1993 Compensation of employees 107.959
Survey. Other GSP 61.132
For a State, gross state product originating
(GSPO) by industry is the contribution of each
industry--including government-- to GSP. An
industry's GSPO, often referred to as its "value
added," is equal to its gross output (sales or receipts
and other operating income, plus inventory change)
minus its intermediate inputs (consumption of
goods and services purchased from other industries
or imported). GSP measured as the sum of GSPO
in all industries is the State counterpart of the
Nation's gross domestic product (GDP) by industry

© 1999 RRI, WVU 20 July 1999


I/O Tables and Regional Accounts Chapter 3

Appendix 2 Measures of regional EQUALS GROSS REGIONAL


PRODUCT
welfare
GROSS REGIONAL PRODUCT is the
The problem with GSP estimates total value of goods and services produced by
factors of production owned by residents of
Gross state product accounts have been the region; GROSS DOMESTIC
established for a number of states and using a REGIONAL PRODUCT is the total value of
variety of methods. In Hawaii, with a long production in the region.
history of independence, accounts have been
constructed along exactly the same lines as a In the United States, GNP is greater than
nation (in fact, some of the people involved in GDP -- we own more abroad than others do
these accounts were close associates of here. In Hawaii, GRP is less that GDRP --
members of the accounts team in the U.S. natives own less abroad than others own in
Bureau of the Census. Hawaii. In other states, the question has not
been answered.
In most other states, however, the method
has been a short-cut method known as the The point of this is that, since people
Kendricks-Jaycox method and involves always confuse lengthy titles, we just go
estimates based on ratios. ahead and confuse things to begin with and
rename gross domestic state product as gross
The estimates of Gross State Product state product!
described in Appendix 1 have been assembled
from all sources available to the Regional
Economic Measurement Division. One nice
GSP = GDSP
thing about this central source is that the The widespread use of personal income
accounts for the 50 states are consistent with estimates
the accounts for the nation as a whole.
The problems associated with estimating
The following statement shows the formal flows of capital income from one area to
difference between "Gross Regional Product" another are severe. We just can't develop
(GRP) and "Gross Domestic Regional accurate statistics on ownership of large
Product," (GDRP) which parallels the multi-state and multi-national corporations
difference between GNP and GDP. This and thus on the flows of dividends and
equation shows development of GRP as interest across state boundaries.
GDRP adjusted for net factor payments
(including profits). As a result of this handicap, we normally
consider personal income as a better measure
GROSS DOMESTIC REGIONAL of individual welfare. Considerable data on
PRODUCT journey to work and commuting across
county boundaries over the last three
LESS INTEREST AND decennial censuses has permitted the
DIVIDENDS TO Regional Economic Measurement Division to
NONRESIDENTS estimate adjustments for residency, which
solves part of the GRP/GDRP problem.
PLUS INTEREST AND
DIVIDENDS FROM
REST OF WORLD

LESS WAGES EARNED BY IN-


COMMUTERS

PLUS WAGES EARNED BY


OUT-COMMUTERS

© 1999 RRI, WVU 21 July 1999


4 THE LOGIC OF INPUT-OUTPUT MODELS
Such analysis requires an economic model,
Introduction which we now proceed to construct.
The logic of input-output models is
analogous to that of economic-base models, Preparing the transactions table:
and requires only an extension of closing with respect to households
mathematical sophistication from simple
algebra to matrix algebra. A piece of cake. As we shall see, it is important to include in
The complexities of input-output models the interindustry structure (Quadrant II) all
come in devising schemes to manage the economic activities which make buying
massive data sets required to build them. decisions primarily on the basis of their
incomes. These activities are called
We proceed here to repeat the process endogenous since their behavior is
evolved in Chapter 3 to develop the simplest determined within the system. Other
of models, a plain, square, industry-by- activities, such as federal government
industry model. In the next chapter, we will expenditures or exports, are based on
develop the multiplier system associated with decisions made outside the system and so are
this model. After this work on the model and called exogenous activities. Activities which
its uses, we will return to the process of are labeled "industries" are normally
building an input-output system. By then we considered endogenous and those which are
will have manipulated the system sufficiently labeled "final-demand sectors" are normally
to easily understand the more complex considered to be exogenous. But sometimes
commodity-by-industry accounting system it is not so easy to classify activities.
now in current use by the United States and
The household sector is a case in point.
recommended by the United Nations.1 While traditionally classified as a final-
demand sector, it is frequently treated in
The rationale for a model: analysis regional economic models as an "industry."
vs. description Households sell labor, managerial skills, and
privately owned resources; they receive in
While the transactions table describes the return wages and salaries, dividends, rents,
economy and yields interesting bits of proprietors' income, etc. And to produce
information for a particular point in time, in these resources, they buy food, clothing,
itself it has no analytic content. That is, it automobiles, housing, services, and other
does not permit us to answer questions consumer goods. Exceeded in total
concerning the reaction of the economy to expenditures only by the manufacturing
change. Let the transactions table represent sector, the household sector is obviously a
the economy in equilibrium and subject it to a critical part of the Georgia economy or of any
shock, say an increase in tourism or a cutback area economy, for that matter. So we move
in defense expenditures. When the the household row and column into the
repercussions of the shock have moved interindustry part of the transactions table and
through the economy, what will be its new treat households as another industry. The
"equilibrium position?" In other words, which household sector becomes the sixth
industries will be larger or smaller and whose "industry" in the aggregated table repeated as
income or employment will have changed? revised in Table 4.1.

1 My favorite source for this logic is the dominant


book on input-output models of the 1960’s (Chenery and
Clark 1959). It contains almost all we needed until the
advent of commodity-by-industry accounts. I
recommend it.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 22 Draft July 28, 1999


Logic of I/O Models Chapter 4

Table 4.1 Hypothetical interindustry transactions with endogenous


household sector
Buying Con- Manu- Household Total Other lo- Total
sector Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- expendi- industry cal final final Total
Selling tion tion turing Trade vices tures demand demand Exports demand demand
sector (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (7) (6) (8) (9) (10) (11)
Extraction (1) 183 31 599 6 73 99 991 88 596 684 1674
Construction (2) 14 1 43 14 293 0 364 1803 353 2155 2520
Manufacturing (3) 142 414 1390 110 356 1275 3687 1130 9344 10474 14162
Trade (4) 52 224 520 72 257 2563 3689 161 970 1131 4820
Services (5) 102 221 862 558 1990 4262 7996 523 2828 3351 11347
Households (7) 595 665 3696 2385 4603 100 12043 2524 0 2524 14567

Total local inputs (6) 1088 1556 7110 3145 7572 8299 28770 6228 14091 20319 49090

Other payments (8) 261 191 1624 1365 2402 3789 9632 (943.2) 1097.5) 0 5842
Imports (9) 325 773 5428 311 1372 3778 11987 1057 -12994 -11937 50

Total final payments ( 1 0 ) 586 964 7051 1675 3775 7567 21619 3581 -12994 -9413 20459
Total inputs (11) 1674 2520 14162 4820 11347 15866 50389 7285 1097 20459 54982

The state and local government sectors Georgia industries in terms of the following
(included in "other final demand" and "other equations:
final payments" in our aggregated table) also x 11+ x12 + x13 + x14 + x15 + x16 + y1 ≡ z1
are difficult to classify. While we leave them
in the exogenous part of the table now, x 21 + x22 + x23 + x24 + x25 + x26 + y2 ≡ z2
primarily for simplicity, they are occasionally x 31 + x32 + x33 + x34 + x35 + x36 + y3 ≡ z3
included in the endogenous part of the table x 41 + x42 + x43 + x44 + x45 + x46 + y4 ≡ z4
in detailed forecasting models. x 51 + x52 + x53 + x54 + x55 + x56 + y5 ≡ z5
x 61 + x62 + x63 + x64 + x65 + x66 + y6 ≡ z6
The economic model This set of identities can be seen symbolically
As is now familiar, an equilibrium model is in the top six rows of Figure 4.1 and
based on three sets of relations: (1) numerically in the five industry rows and in
definitions or identities, (2) technical or the household row (now "industry" six) of
behavioral conditions, and (3) equilibrium the transactions table (Table 4.1). Since we
conditions. A model thus uses a set of are now primarily concerned with Quadrant
assumptions to extend a description of an II, we have reduced Quadrant I to one column
economy so that it can be used to trace the in these tables and we have dropped the
effects of disequilibrating forces. In the case various intermediate totals.
at hand, each set of relations can be easily
identified. In a more concise formulation, the
equations may be summarized as:
Identities: the transactions table zi ≡ Σj xij + yi (4-1)
The state transactions table as extended where the operator Σj sums sales by industry
above provides our set of identities: it defines
the economy for the base year. Now let's i over all industries j.
express these relations in simple algebra. Let As can be seen, Figure 4.1 and the above
xij be the sales of industry i to industry j, yi set of equations differ in only two ways: (1)
the sales of industry i to final demand the arithmetic operators are implicit in the
(ultimate consumers), and zi the total sales of table; and (2) the table includes values for
industry, or total demand for the output of the other final payments (vj) and imports (mj),
industry. Then we can define the sales of completing the accounting framework.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 23 July 1999


Logic of I/O Models Chapter 4

While the above set of equations six equations and 48 variables, of which only
(identities) are our basic concern, a second set six (the y's) now have assigned values. The
may reveal insight into our equilibrium minimum requirement for a solution to this
problem. For the economy to be in a state of system is that the number of equations equals
equilibrium, row and column totals must the number of unknowns; therefore, we must
agree. (A simple fact of double-entry reduce the number of unknown variables by
accounting.) We can now define total output, 42.
or supply, for industry j as qj , the sum of all
To do this, we introduce a set of technical
intermediate purchases, local payments to conditions. Assume that the pattern of
factors of production, and imports: purchases identified in the base year is stable.
qj ≡ Σixij + vj + mj , (4-2) We can now define a set of values called
"direct requirements," or "production
where Σi sums purchases by industry j over coefficients:"
all industries i. aij = xij /qj (4-3)
Technical conditions: the direct- Table 4.2 records these aij coefficients for
requirements table the hypothetical model. We have simply
Now, recall that the final-demand vector (y) divided each value in a column by the total
is exogenous. The y’s are free to change, inputs (output) of the industry represented in
outside of our control. We wish to know the the column. These numbers show the
effects of such change on the economy as proportions in which the establishments in
expressed by changes in output. It is obvious each industry combine the goods and services
that little additional information can be which they purchase to produce their own
gleaned from the transactions table. We have products.

Figure 4.1 Algebraic transactions table

Buying Con- Manu- Final de-


sector Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- House- mand and Total
Selling tion tion turing Trade vices holds exports demand
sector (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Extraction (1) x1 1 x12 x1 3 x14 x15 x16 e1 z1
Construction (2) x2 1 x22 x2 3 x24 x25 x26 e2 z2
Manufacturing (3) x3 1 x32 x3 3 x34 x35 x36 e3 z3
Trade (4) x4 1 x42 x4 3 x44 x45 x46 e4 z4
Services (5) x5 1 x52 x5 3 x54 x55 x56 e5 z5
Households (6) x6 1 x62 x6 3 x64 x65 x66 e6 z6
Final payments ( 7 ) v1 v2 v3 v4 v5 v6 - - - -
Imports (8) m1 m2 m3 m4 m5 m6 - - - -
Total inputs (9) q1 q2 q3 q4 q5 q6 - - - -

© 1999 RRI, WVU 24 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

Table 4.2 Hypothetical direct-requirements table

Con- Manu- Household


Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- expendi-
Industry tion tion turing Trade vices tures
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Extraction (1) 10.9 1.2 4.2 0.1 0.6 0.6
Construction (2) 0.8 0.0 0.3 0.3 2.6 0.0
Manufacturing (3) 8.5 16.4 9.8 2.3 3.1 8.0
Trade (4) 3.1 8.9 3.7 1.5 2.3 16.2
Services (5) 6.1 8.8 6.1 11.6 17.5 26.9
Households (6) 35.5 26.4 26.1 49.5 40.6 0.6
Total local purchases 65.0 61.7 50.2 65.2 66.7 52.3
Other payments 15.6 7.6 11.5 28.3 21.2 23.9
Imports 19.4 30.7 38.3 6.4 12.1 23.8
Total final payments 35.0 38.3 49.8 34.8 33.3 47.7
Total inputs 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

Notice that we can define xij, the sales by Symbolically, the regional production
industry i to industry j, in another way. It can coefficient is
be written as xij = aij*qj. That is, if the aij = pij *rij
manufacturing sector purchases 6.1 percent
of its inputs from the service sector (a53), and aij = (txij/qj )*(txij - mij )/txij (4-4)
if manufacturing purchases a total of $14,162 Here, txij is purchases from industry i by
million worth of inputs (q3), then its industry j without regard to the location of
purchases from the service sector would have industry i,,and mij is imports of the products
to amount to $862 million, or 6.1 percent of of industry i by industry j. This point is
$14,162 million. If the proportions in which expanded upon both in the summary included
industries buy their inputs remain reasonably in Illustration 4.1 and in the section below on
stable over time, then we can define purchases economic change.
by industry i from industry j in the future as
xij = aij*qj' As we shall see, this simple Equilibrium condition: supply equals
assumption solves our problem. demand
A second assumption is hidden within the Note that along the way we have implicitly
definition of xij in that it is already defined as stated the equilibrium condition. This
purchases from local industry i by local condition is that anticipated demand equals
industry j. This is best seen by looking at the supply, or that the sales of an industry equal
derivation of the regional production its gross output:
coefficients, aij . Each regional production
coefficient is the product of a "technical q j = zj (4-5)
production coefficient," pij , which shows the for all industries. Over any long period of
proportion of inputs purchased from industry time in a market economy, it is irrational to
i by industry j without regard to the location produce more than is used and impractical to
of industry i, and a "regional trade consume more than is produced. Under
coefficient," rij, which shows the proportion normal conditions, an economy faced with a
of that purchase made in the region. change in demand will react by changing

© 1999 RRI, WVU 25 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

supply. When anticipations are fulfilled, the (I - A)*q = y (4-9)


economy is in a state of equilibrium.
and multiply both sides by the inverse of
Solution to the system: the total- (I - A) to get
requirements table (I - A)-1*(I - A)*q = (I - A)-1*y, (4-10)
We can now rewrite the equation system to or, since a matrix multiplied by its inverse
meet the obvious conditions for its solution. yields an identity matrix,
Two substitutions are required: 1) since we
assume the production coefficients are stable, q = (I - A)-1*y, (4-11)
aij*qj can be substituted for xij , and 2) since
inputs must come back into balance with the solution for q in terms of y. Here, I is the
outputs, qj is substituted for zj. Thus, identity matrix, which is the matrix equivalent
to the number 1 and the exponent (-l) shows
a 11 q 1 '+a 12 *q 2 '+a 13 *q 3 '+a 14 *q 4 '+a 15 *q 5 '+a 16 *q 6 '+ y1 '= q1 '
that the parenthetic expression is inverted, or
a 21 q 1 ’+a 22 *q 2 '+a 23 *q 3 '+a 24 *q 4 '+a 25 *q 5 '+a 26 *q 6 '+ y2 '= q2 ' divided into another identity matrix. The term
a 31 *q 1 '+a 32 *q 2 '+a 33 *q 3 '+a 34 *q 4 '+a 35 *q 5 '+a 36 *q 6 '+ y3 '= q3 ' (I - A) is sometimes called the "Leontief
a 41 *q 1 '+a 42 *q 2 '+a 43 *q 3 '+a 44 *q 4 '+a 45 *q 5 '+a 46 *q 6 '+ y4 '= q4 ' matrix" in recognition of Wassily Leontief,
the originator of input-output economics;
a 51 *q 1 '+a 52 *q 2 '+a 53 *q 3 '+a 54 *q 4 '+a 55 *q 5 '+a 56 *q 6 '+ y5 '= q5 '
(I-A)-1, of course, is called the "Leontief
a 61 *q 1 '+a 62 *q 2 '+a 63 *q 3 '+a 64 *q 4 '+a 65 *q 5 '+a 66 *q 6 '+ y6 '= q6 '
inverse." A more descriptive title is "total-
The prime applied to each variable indicates requirements table.”
"future" value. Table 4.3 shows the total-requirements
The power of our assumption that the matrix for the hypothetical economy. Each
technology of production is constant is now entry shows the total purchases from the
clear. With it, we have reduced the number of industry named on the left for each dollar of
unknowns from 48 to six, the q’s, and can delivery to final demand by the industry
proceed to solve the system and thus to numbered across the top. This sentence is
determine the outputs of industries in our complex and should be read carefully. While
economy in the future. the direct requirements matrix recorded
purchases from the industries named at the
Compressed, the system is expressed as left for each dollar's (or hundred dollars' if
q i' ≡ Σ ja ij*q j' + yi'. (4-6) expressed in percentages) worth of output by
the industry numbered across the top, this
A full explanation of the solution to this table reports all of the purchases due to
system can be easily expressed in matrix delivery to final demand. As the title shows,
algebra and, in this case, is analogous to the the table records both direct and indirect
one in simple algebra used with economic- flows.
base models. Say we wish to solve the
following equation for q, where q represents Now, let's insert summing rows into the
the vector of qi ' on the right side of the table and add another meaning to it. The
equation system above, A represents a matrix result is shown here as Table 4.4 and
of the aij's on the left side of the system, and renamed as a table of "industry-output
multipliers". The key row is labeled "total
y represents the column vector of yi 's also on industry outputs" and included the sum of
the left side of the above system: industry outputs required for the industry
q = A*q + y (4-7) named at the top to deliver one dollar's worth
of output to final demand (that is, to export
We subtract Aq from both sides of the this amount). Thus, in exporting a dollar's
equation, worth of output the manufacturing sector
q - A*q = y (4-8) would cause production by other industries
amounting to $1.67. This seems magical if
factor q from the terms on the left, not impossible until you recall the lessons of
economic-base theory. The total double-

© 1999 RRI, WVU 26 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

counts the values of outputs bought and For many years, the total of both industry
rebought as materials move from one outputs and household incomes in this total-
processor to another, acquiring more value requirements table was discussed as an
each time. We will pursue this in a little more "output multiplier." This was incorrect,
detail in the next chapter. however, and most analyst avoid this error.
The sum in Table 4.4 is labeled as "total
Since the household sector is not really an activity," but it has no real meaning beyond
'industry' but has been included to assure that noting the rippling of money through the
all internal flows related to production are economy.
counted, we exclude it from the summation of
industry outputs. Later, we will treat entries
in the household row as "household-income
multipliers."

Table 4.3 Total requirements (with households endogenous)


Con- Manu- Household
Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- expendi-
Industry tion tion turing Trade vices tures
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Extraction (1) 1.14 0.03 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.02
Construction (2) 0.02 1.01 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.01
Manufacturing (3) 0.19 0.26 1.18 0.12 0.13 0.15
Trade (4) 0.17 0.21 0.14 1.16 0.17 0.25
Services (5) 0.35 0.35 0.28 0.43 1.49 0.50
Households (6) 0.69 0.60 0.52 0.80 0.75 1.38

Table 4.4 Industry-output multipliers (with households endogenous)


Con- Manu- Household
Extrac- struc- fac- Ser- expendi-
Industry tion tion turing Trade vices tures
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Extraction (1) 1.14 0.03 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.02
Construction (2) 0.02 1.01 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.01
Manufacturing (3) 0.19 0.26 1.18 0.12 0.13 0.15
Trade (4) 0.17 0.21 0.14 1.16 0.17 0.25
Services (5) 0.35 0.35 0.28 0.43 1.49 0.50
Total industry outputs 1.86 1.86 1.67 1.75 1.86 0.93
Households (6) 0.69 0.60 0.52 0.80 0.75 1.38
Total "activity" 2.54 2.46 2.19 2.55 2.60 2.32

Now that we have developed the logic of a go back and examine the effect of closing the
regional input-output model and can see that model with respect to households. Recall that
it is a means for tracing the effects on local we have included the household sector as the
industries of changes in the economy, let us sixth industry in the model. Under these

© 1999 RRI, WVU 27 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

conditions, the total-requirements table traces Table 4.5 reports a total-requirements table
the flows of goods and services required to which is based on a five-industry version of
accommodate changes in final demand Table 4.2, the direct-requirements matrix.
through all industries and through Examination of the column sums in the rows
households as well. What if the household entitled "total output" in each table reveals the
sector had been left in final demand? What if importance of the household sector in
we had continued to treat it as exogenous to generating new activity in the economy.
the system rather than endogenous?

Table 4.5 Total requirements (with households exogenous)

Extrac- Construc- Manufac-


Industry tion tion turing Trade Services
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Extraction (1) 1.13 0.02 0.05 0.00 0.01
Construction (2) 0.01 1.00 0.01 0.01 0.03
Manufacturing (3) 0.11 0.19 1.12 0.03 0.05
Trade (4) 0.04 0.10 0.05 1.02 0.03
Services (5) 0.10 0.14 0.09 0.15 1.23
Total outputs 1.40 1.46 1.32 1.21 1.35

Table 4.6 A comparison of output multipliers under different household


assumptions

Output mutipliers with: Increase due to Percent


households households household increase due to
Industry exogenous endogeous inclusion household
(1) (2) (3) inclusion
Extraction (1) 1.40 1.86 0.46 33
Construction (2) 1.46 1.86 0.40 27
Manufacturing (3) 1.32 1.67 0.35 26
Trade (4) 1.21 1.75 0.54 44
Services (5) 1.35 1.86 0.50 37

© 1999 RRI, WVU 28 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

Table 4.6 compares these tables. Just technology or changes in marketing patterns
including the household sector in the inverted or both. Let us see what this means in terms
table leads to increases in output by the of the direct-requirements matrix, or the A
processing industries (1 through 5) of 27 to matrix of our earlier discussion. Recall that
44 percent. (When we include households as aij is the proportion of total inputs purchased
an industry and count the flows through it as from industry i by industry j in the region.
“industry output,” the percent increase in We can treat this regional production
output rises from 66 to 111 percent of the coefficient as the product of two other
flows based on a table excluding coefficients and write it symbolically as
households.) As we shall see later in a more
detailed discussion of multipliers, income aij = pij*rij.
flows induced by households are important to The "technical production coefficient," pij ,
a regional input-output analysis, but we must shows the proportion of inputs purchased
be careful to distinguish increases in from industry i by industry j without regard
houshold incomes from increases in industry to the location of industry i, while the
outputs.). "regional trade coefficient," rij, shows the
proportion of that purchase made locally.
Economic change in input-output A change in technology, or a change in pij,
models could be illustrated by a shift from glass
bottles to metal cans by the soft-drink
Causes vs. consequences of change industry. But a change in location of
An input-output model is designed to trace purchase, or a change in rij, would be
the effects of changes in an economy which illustrated by a shift from metal cans made in
has been represented in an input-output table. another area to metal cans produced in our
Such models show the consequences of region.
change in terms of flows of monies through The above changes are couched in terms of
an economy and in terms of incomes existing industries. Another way in which
generated for primary resource owners. The change can take place is through the
models themselves do not show the causes of introduction of new plants or even new
change; these causes are exogenous to the industries. The introduction of a new plant
system. into an existing industry has the effect of
Economic change as traced through an changing the production and trade patterns of
input-output model can take two forms: (1) the aggregated industry to reflect more of the
structural change or (2) change in final transactions specific to the detailed industry
demand. Changes in the economic structure of which the new plant is a member. For
of an area can be initiated in several ways. It example, consider the manufacturing sector of
can be through public investment in schools, our highly aggregated five-industry model.
highways, public facilities, etc., or it can be As presented, it reflects the combination of all
through private investment in new production manufacturing activities in the region. The
facilities, or it can be through changes in the introduction of new plants in the
marketing structure of the economy. transportation-equipment industry would
Changes in final demand are basically change the combination of purchases
changes in government expenditure patterns presently made in the manufacturing sector.
and changes in the demands by other areas The same statement might be made
for the goods produced in the region. concerning the purchase pattern displayed by
the transportation equipment industry if a new
Structural change aircraft-producing plant were established (or
an old one were to cease operation).
Structural change in an input-output
context can be interpreted to mean it changes The addition of a completely new industry
in regional production coefficients." In turn, to the system means adding another row and
this can be interpreted as either changes in column to the interindustry table to represent

© 1999 RRI, WVU 29 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

the new industry. This is done in a manner household-income coefficient of .4136,


similar to that involved in closing the table meaning that the additional carpet sales would
with respect to households. have increased local household incomes by
$41,360.
To account for structural changes which
are caused by changes in technology or in The example can be pursued on a more
marketing requires a revision of the gross level by looking at Table 4.3 and
interindustry flows table and is best assuming a $100,000 increase in the output
accomplished when a biennial revision is of the manufacturing sector. The output
made. multiplier in manufacturing is 1.67, meaning
that the $100,000 change in export demand
Changes in final demand yields $167,000 in additional business to
local firms. The household-income
Accounting for structural changes in an coefficient of .52 means that household
input-output model requires substantial skill incomes increase by $52,000. The
and familiarity with the mechanics of the differences between these figures and those in
model on the part of the analyst. This is not the above paragraph show the consequences
the case when accounting for the effects of of aggregation, which conceals a substantial
changes in final demand. It can easily be amount of variation in the detailed tables.
accomplished with the inverse matrix, or the
total-requirements table, Table 4.3 in this We discuss the multiplier model in more
chapter or, more appropriately, with its detail in the next chapter.
detailed equivalent.
Two kinds of changes can be traced. One
form is a set of long-run changes in the
demands for the outputs of all industries.
This set takes the form of a vector of
predicted exogenous demands (the y' vector
discussed above) and represents our best Study questions
judgment of the export demands for the
products of our industries in some later year. 1. Why is an interindustry table sometimes called
an input output-table?
Using the formula
2. Outline the form of an input-output table.
q' = (I - A)-1y' 3. Describe the four quadrants of an input-output
we can easily derive projections of the table.
expected gross outputs (q') of industries in 4. How would you derive gross regional product
the later year. from a regional input-output table?
The other form which change in final 5. What is the rationale for constructing a model
from an input-output table?
demand might take is an assumed change in
the final demand for the output of one 6. Of what use is a regional input-output table in
industry. Say we wish to know the effect on itself?
the economy of a $100,000 change in the 7. Outline the steps involved in constructing an
demand for floor coverings. We would input-output model from a transactions table.
simply go to the detailed tables and look for 8. How can the effect of structural changes be traced
the column sum for the floor-covering through an input-output model?
industry in the total requirements matrix. 9. Clearly show the relationship between regional
Using the detailed table for our hypothetical input-output models and economic-base theory.
economy (not shown here), this entry is 10. Given the interindustry transactions matrix (X)
1.8094; multiplied by $100,000, it shows that and the gross outputs vector (z), calculate values
these additional export sales of carpets would for the final-demand (y), final-payments (v), and
increase regional outputs by a total of input (q) vectors.
$180,940. A look at the household row in
that same column would have yielded a

© 1999 RRI, WVU 30 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

400 180  1000 


X= , z= 
250 120   600 
11. Using the system in question 10, calculate A and
then estimate (I -A)-1 using determinants (to two
digits).

© 1999 RRI, WVU 31 July 1999


The Logic of Input-Output Models Chapter 4

Illustration 4.1 The simple input-output model


Definitions or identities: z = Az + y + e
Inputs = Sum of purchases from other local z - Az= y + e
industries and from final-payment
(I - A)z = y + e
sectors
q1= x11 + x21 + v1 + m1 z = (I - A)-1(y+e)
Output multipliers:
q2= x12 + x22 + v2 + m2
dzi/dej = rij , where rij is an element of R =
or, in matrix terms,
(I - A) -1.
q = XT i + v + m
Each of these partial output multipliers
where X T is a transpose and i represents the shows the change in local output i associated
summing vector with a change in exports by industry j.
Their sum over i is the total output
Outputs = Sum of sales to other local industries multiplier for industry j.
and final users
Income multipliers:
z1= x11 + x12 + y1 + e1
incomei = Sum(rij*vi(h)/qi), where vi(h) is
z2= x21 + x22 + y2 + e2 household income.
or, in matrix terms, Each of these income multipliers shows the
change in household income caused by a
z = Xi + y + e
change in exports by industry j.
Behavioral or technical assumptions:
Constant production coefficients
pij = txij/qj
or txij = pijqj
Constant regional trade coefficients
rij = (txij - mij)/txij
Equilibrium condition:
Inputs = Outputs
qi = zi
Solution by substitution:
Problem: given final demands (y and e), reduce
the number of unknowns to equal the
number of equations.
Let aij = pij •rij.
Then aij = (txij/qj)•((txij - mij)/txij)
= (txij - mij)/qj = xij/qj or
xij = aijqj
Substituting into the output equations,
z1= a11z1 + a12z2 + y1 + e1
z2= a21z1 + a22z2 + y2 + e2
Or, continuing in matrix terms,

© 1999 RRI, WVU 32 July 1999


5 REGIONAL INPUT-OUTPUT MULTIPLIERS
indirect, and induced changes in industry
Introduction outputs required to deliver units to final
As noted in Chapter 5, a regional input- demand. A table of this type is the basic
output model can be used to provide a set of element used in estimating multipliers.
economic multipliers with which to trace the To better understand the meaning of a
effects of changes in demand on economic total-requirements table and the multipliers
activity in the region. After explaining more derived from it, let us go back and trace the
graphically the multiplier concept, this chapter flow of outputs induced by a $100 purchase
formulates employment, household-income, from the manufacturing sector through the
and government- income multipliers and direct requirements table (repeated as Table
presents examples. 5.1). The result of this step-by-step tracing is
illustrated in Figure 5.1 and reported in Table
The multiplier concept 5.2. First, $100 enters the state economy
through manufacturing. (My convention is to
Input-output models are most commonly label this initial round as “round zero” -- this
used to trace individual changes in final is the “insertion” before the rounds of
demand through the economy over short circulation begin. It is also consistent with
periods of time. In this function, they are the exponents in the solution based on the
called impact models, or multiplier models. sum of an infinite series.) To produce output
Let us now look more closely at these worth $100, firms in manufacturing purchase
models. First, we take an intuitive approach inputs from other industries in the economy.
to understanding the meaning of the total- According to column 3 in the direct-
requirements table, illustrating the multiplier requirements table, $4.20 goes to agriculture
effect with a two-dimensional chart. Then we and mining, $0.30 goes to construction, an
solve the model using the formula for the sum additional $9.80 goes to other firms in
of an infinite series and present the results in manufacturing, $3.70 goes to trade, $6.10
three dimensions. goes to services, and $26.10 is paid to
households in wages and salaries (This is
An intuitive explanation round one.). Capacity permitting, each of
A total-requirements table for the these industries must expand its output to
aggregated six-industry model was presented accommodate this additional production load.
in Table 5.3. This table shows the direct,

Table 5.1 Hypothetical direct-requirements table

Household
Extrac-C onstruc-Manufac- expendi-
Industry tion tion turing Trade Services tures
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Extraction (1) 10.9 1.2 4.2 0.1 0.6 0.6
Construction (2) 0.8 0.0 0.3 0.3 2.6 0.0
Manufacturing (3) 8.5 16.4 9.8 2.3 3.1 8.0
Trade (4) 3.1 8.9 3.7 1.5 2.3 16.2
Services (5) 6.1 8.8 6.1 11.6 17.5 26.9
Households (6) 35.5 26.4 26.1 49.5 40.6 0.6

© 1999 RRI, WVU 33 Draft July 28, 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Thus, in producing additional output valued at This chain of purchases continues for all
$4.20, firms in agriculture and mining buy industries until the economy is again in
output worth $0.46 (10.9% of $4.20) from equilibrium. The initial $100 purchase from
others in this sector, $0.03 (0.8% of $4.20) manufacturing has led to money flows
from construction, $0.36 (8.5% of $4.20) throughout the regional economy valued at
from manufacturing, and so on, for a total of $219, as shown in Table 5.4. Notice that if
$2.72. At the same time, each of the other the value of additional output is summed
industries is purchasing the additional inputs through round six, most of the effect of the
required to produce the output requested of initial purchase has already been realized: as
them. The results are summarized in Figure seen in Table 5.2, $214 has been spent at this
5.1 as the second round of purchases. Other point. The total-requirements table just
purchases follow in succeeding rounds, each counts the rounds of spending to infinity and
smaller as money flows out of the adds them up. The total appears in Table 5.4
interindustry sector into the hands of the as the column sum for manufacturing, and is
owners of primary inputs (excluding labor), labeled "total activity." The column itself has
into government coffers, and for the purchase elements which show the output impact of the
of imported materials. initial expenditure on each industry in the
system.

Figure 5.1 The activity effect of $100 sale to final demand by the
manufacturing sector

100
90
80
Households
70
Services
Dollars

60
Trade
50
Manufacturing
40
Construction
30
Extraction
20
10
0
(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Round of spending

Now, before we go on to explore occurs in all regional models which I have


mathematically this alternative approach to encountered.)
solution by inversion, let us reduce the
"activity effect" to a "multiplier effect" The iterative approach
focusing on industries. This reduction is This intuitive explanation may be
accomplished simply by excluding the expressed in a more concise mathematical
household row in the table of rounds of form as a “solution by iterations.” This
spending. Now we count only the effects on process uses the sum of an infinite series to
industries. This leads to Figure 5.2. The approximate the solution to the economic
striking thing about the contrast of these two model. In matrix algebra, the process is:
effects is the importance of the household in a
2 3 n
regional economy. (The same relative pattern T = IX + AX + A X + A X + ... + A X

© 1999 RRI, WVU 34 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Here, T is the solution, a column vector of results approximating those obtained when n
changes in each industry's outputs caused by approaches infinity. (For this and most other
the changes represented in the column vector cases, n = 6 is high enough to capture over 97
X. A is the direct-requirements matrix. n is percent of the flows; eight rounds capture
the number of rounds required to produce over 99 percent.)

Table 5.2 The multiplier effect of $100 in manufacturing output traced in


rounds of spending through the hypothetical economy
-----Round of spending-----
Industry (0) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Total
Extraction (1) 0.00 4.23 1.09 0.40 0.20 0.11 0.07 6.09
Construction (2) 0.00 0.30 0.23 0.28 0.14 0.09 0.05 1.09
Manufacturing ( 3 ) 100.00 9.82 3.74 1.60 1.05 0.57 0.35 117.13
Trade (4) 0.00 3.67 4.93 1.87 1.48 0.73 0.48 13.16
Services (5) 0.00 6.09 9.39 4.84 3.29 1.79 1.11 26.51
Total industry outputs 100.00 24.11 19.38 8.98 6.15 3.30 2.06 163.98
Households (6) 0.00 26.10 8.60 7.72 3.57 2.47 1.32 49.77
Total "activity" 100.00 50.21 27.97 16.71 9.72 5.77 3.38 213.76

Figure 5.2 The multiplier effect of $100 sale to final demand by the
manufacturing sector

100
90
80
70 Services
Dollars

60 Trade
50 Manufacturing
40 Construction
30 Extraction
20
10
0
(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Round of spending

The multiplier-effects, or "rounds-of- the identity matrix, which is operationally


spending," table (Table 5.2) lays out the equivalent to the number 1 in ordinary
results of applying this equation to the algebra). Round 1 is AX, the result of
problem of tracing direct expenditures. In multiplying the matrix A by the vector X. It
this table, the total column is T. Round 0 is answers the question: what are the outputs
IX, the initial expenditures to be traced (I is required of each supplier to produce the

© 1999 RRI, WVU 35 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

goods and services purchased in the initial Round 1 of this chain of events? Round 3 is
2 3 2
change under study? Round 2 is A X, which A X, which is the same as A(A X); and the
is the same as AAX, or A(AX); it is the result story repeats, round after round. Each of
of multiplying the matrix A by Round 1 (or columns 1 through 6 in the multiplier-effects
AX). It answers for Round 2 the same table represents a term in the continuing but
question as was applied to Round 1: what are diminishing chain of expenditures on the
the outputs required of each supplier to right side of the equation.
produce the goods and services purchased in

Figure 5.3 The ripple effect of a $100 export of manufacturing output

100

90
80

70
60
Dollars

50 Round 0
Round 1
40
C Round 2
30
Round 3
20
Round 4
10
Round 5
0
Round 6
Households

Manufacturing

Services

Extraction

Trade

Construction

The tracing of these rounds in Table 5.2 of a $100 export sale of manufacturing goods
can also be presented in three dimensions by our economy. Notice the large flow
with a spreadsheet program (I used Excel.). through households, especially in round 1,
Figure 5.3 shows once again the multiplier and note how quickly circulation falls off.
effects (now it might be proper to join the This economy is pretty leaky!
newspapers in discussing the "ripple effect")

© 1999 RRI, WVU 36 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

This process has several advantages to of vector multiplication by summing over


recommend it over the inversion solution. industries (five rows) and not over industries
The analyst builds a direct impact vector and households (six rows).
(Round 0) through survey or assumption and QMULTj = Σi INVij
then sets the iterative process in motion on a
desktop computer. He can see clearly the where i counts through the number of
paths taken by indirect rounds of spending industries.
and can perform a check both on his direct
impact vector and on the input-output model The third output multiplier reported in
itself. Further, he has the material available to Table 5.3 is sometimes called a "gross output
make a graphic presentation of his results multiplier." It is the sum over both industries
which is easily understood by a reader. and the household row of a column in the
inverse matrix. To emphasize its mixed
Before the advent of microcomputers, the origin we label it as an "industry and
typical input-output study included lengthy household multiplier" and herewith declare it
sets of inverse matrices and multiplier tables as improper to use. It mixes double-counted
in which the analyst looked up multipliers outputs and final incomes and has no
which applied to his problem. These meaning.
numbers were then applied blindly and with
faith. Although we have arrived at this point with
little mention of earlier practice in input-
output analysis, note that it was common
Multiplier transformations practice several decades ago to produce a
Now let us go back to the solution of the "Type 1" model, with households excluded
input-output model by inversion as presented from the A matrix, and a “Type 2" model,
in the previous chapter. This has the with households included. Output multipliers
advantage of permitting us to generalize and were appropriate with the Type 1 models and
produce the various kinds of multipliers inappropriate with the Type 2 models.
possible in an input-output system. Analysts frequently became confused.
Now, almost all regional input-output
Output multipliers analysts have abandoned Type 1 models and
The first thing to note about Table 5.3 is concentrate on the augmented models
that the elements of the inverse are now described here. If output multipliers are to
relabeled as "partial output multipliers." That have any meaning, they should be based on
is, in multiplier terminology, they are to be industrial activity alone.
interpreted as stating the total impact on a row The more appropriate multipliers, however,
industry's output of one dollar brought into are those transformed into terms of
the economy by a column industry. The employment and final incomes. They
sums of these columns are output multipliers. represent jobs and incomes to people, two
Note that we report three kinds of output important measures of the importance of
multipliers. The first is the "direct output industrial activities.
multiplier," which is simply 1.0, the direct
sales by the industry in question (sort of Employment multipliers
obvious, but included just for parallelism). The next question is how to estimate the
The second is a total "industrial activity impact on employment of new export activity.
multiplier", which is the sum for each column To answer this question, we must transform
industry of the vector of partial output output impacts into employment impact. We
multipliers multiplied by direct output impacts use employment/output ratios for this.
(the 1's). To avoid considering the household
as a true "industry", we violate the principles

© 1999 RRI, WVU 37 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Table 5.3 Output, employment, income, and local and state government
revenue multipliers for hypothetical economy
Indust r y t it le Agr ic, Cons- Manu- Tr ade Ser v ice House-
mining t r uct ion f act ur ing holds
1 2 3 4 5 6

Par t i al Out put M ul t i pl i er s ( el ement s of i nv er se)


Agr icult ur e, mining 1 1.139 0.033 0.062 0.015 0.023 0.021
Const r uct ion 2 0.019 1.011 0.012 0.015 0.040 0.014
Manuf act ur ing 3 0.184 0.253 1.173 0.092 0.128 0.146
Tr ade 4 0.165 0.207 0.138 1.159 0.166 0.245
Ser v ice 5 0.346 0.351 0.280 0.428 1.494 0.498
Households 6 0.684 0.593 0.516 0.785 0.745 1.381

Out put mul t i pl i er s


Dir ect out put 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
Indust r ial act iv it y 1.853 1.855 1.664 1.708 1.850 0.924
Ind & households 2.538 2.448 2.180 2.494 2.595 2.305

I ncome mul t i pl i er s
Dir ect income 0.355 0.264 0.261 0.495 0.406 0.006
Tot al income 0.684 0.593 0.516 0.785 0.745 0.381

Empl oy ment ( per $ mi l l i on)


Dir ect employ ment 30 12 16 30 25 5
Tot al employ ment 54 35 34 51 49 30

Local gov er nment


Dir ect r ev enue 0.020 0.010 0.009 0.014 0.024 0.023
Tot al r ev enue 0.051 0.038 0.032 0.046 0.057 0.049

St at e gov er nment
Dir ect r ev enue 0.001 0.004 0.008 0.120 0.016 0.021
Tot al r ev enue 0.042 0.049 0.041 0.163 0.061 0.068

To keep the numbers reasonable, we and can be restated in matrix terminology for
denominate the ratio in employees per million all industries as
dollars of output. Total employment
EMULT = eq ^ -1(I - A)-1.
multipliers for an industry, then, are produced
by multiplying the row vector of direct where e is now a vector of industry
employment multipliers (which are the employment and the other symbols are as
employment/output ratios) by the appropriate defined previously.
column vector in the inverse matrix. The
formula for the employment multiplier for Note that we have approximated current
industry j can be stated as: employee/output ratios to avoid results you
would consider outlandish if we had used the
EMULTj = Σi (ei /qi)* INVij

© 1999 RRI, WVU 38 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

original 1970 ratios. In fact, application of an are in fact organized as businesses, and we
input-output model which is usually a couple hope they produce outputs in response to
of years old (almost by definition) to a their incomes. This anomaly means that they
current or future statement of impact requires should be interpreted as yielding excess
that we develop current or future estimates of revenue in some short-run period (in which
employment/output ratios. excess capacity exists in streets, protection,
utilities, etc.), but, in the long run, the piper
Income multipliers must be paid and new capacity must be
financed. Interpretation depends on your
Transformation from output terms to time horizon.
income terms is similar. Here, the direct
income multiplier is simply the ratio of
household income to output and is taken
directly from the household row of the direct
requirements matrix. The total income
multiplier is produced by converting total Study questions
changes in output to total changes in income 1. Discuss multipliers as "transformers" of data
using these ratios. from one form to another.
Symbolically, the household-income 2. Why do output multipliers "double-count" while
multiplier is written as a transformation employment multipliers do not?
almost identical to that used for the 3. How can multipliers be used in developing a
employment multiplier: strategy for regional development? Discuss.
HMULTj = Σi (hi /qi)* INVij 4. Discuss the simulating of regional development
with an input-output model.
Here, hi represents the household income of 5. It can be demonstrated that small regional
industry i. coefficients lead to quick convergence in an
Income multipliers are most useful iterative input-output solution and that large
compared to output multipliers. Output coefficients lead to slow convergence. In words,
multipliers are "gross" in that they double- explain why.
count transactions. One of the problems with 6. Express the calculation of income multipliers
economic-base multipliers was this double- completely in matrix algebra
counting, which led naive audiences to believe 7. Complete the following exercise.
that we could magically get more stuff out of
an economy than we put in, and it led
sophisticated audiences into disbelief in the
analyst's results. Income multipliers report
the money that drops into the hands of
owners of resources as income. In this case,
the owners happen to be workers.

Government-income multipliers
The same process can be applied to
government incomes, simply by substituting
"local-government revenue" or "state-
government revenue" for "household income"
in the transformation formula. The resulting
multipliers are relatively low because the
revenue/output ratios are low.
Government-income multipliers suffer in
interpretation because, while we generally
consider governments as owners of resources
and so treat them as we do households, they

© 1999 RRI, WVU 39 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Exercise
Input-output model manipulation and solution

Consider the following interindustry transactions matrix (X) and total outputs vector
(z) for a two-sector economy.

 500 350  1000 


X=  , z= 
320 360   800 
a. What are the two elements in the final demand (fd) vector?

_ _ _ 
fd =  
_ _ _ 
Show your calculations.

b. Consider the following interindustry transactions matrix (X) and total outputs
vector (z) for a two-sector economy.

 500 350  1000 


X=  , z= 
320 360   800 
What are the two elements in the total inputs vector (q) and in the final-payments
(fp) vector?

_ _ _  _ _ _ 
q=  fp =  
_ _ _  _ _ _ 
Show your calculations. What does the complete transactions table look like now?

© 1999 RRI, WVU 40 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

c. Consider again the following interindustry transactions matrix (X) and total
inputs vector (q) for a two-sector economy.

 500 350  1000 


X=  , q =  800 
320 360   
What is the algebraic representation of the A matrix, where aij = xij/qj?

Calculate the numeric values for this A matrix and for (I-A):

A= (I - A) =

d. Using your hand-held calculator, what is the inverse of the Leontief matrix?

© 1999 RRI, WVU 41 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

e. With this A matrix and the following new final-demand vector (now y), calculate
the first 3 rounds of spending which would occur in seeking the new outputs which
would satisfy the new final-demand.

.500 .438   200 


A=  , fd = y =  
.320 .450  100 
What is the equation for this 'rounds of spending' solution to the model?

Round 0:

Round 1:

Round 2:

f. How would the solution using the inverse compare with that using rounds of
spending as above?

© 1999 RRI, WVU 42 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

output multipliers. The serious literature on


Appendix 1 Multiplier concepts, regional input-output multipliers starts with
names, and interpretations Frederick T. Moore in a now-classic article
on "Regional Economic Reaction Paths" in
Introduction 1955 (Moore 1955). And this is where I
begin.
This appendix examines the development
of input-output multiplier concepts and the Income multipliers
evolution of their names. It is included to
show the evolution of the concepts over the Origins of Types I and II income
last several decades. I will restrict this multipliers
statement to regional input-output models
mostly in North America and to multipliers Reporting on models of California and
commonly used in impact analysis, pointing Utah developed in association with James W.
out some preferred alternatives.1 Petersen, Moore defines "... the 'simple'
income multiplier as the ratio of the direct-
It is traditional to start such an exposition plus-indirect income effects to the direct
with salutes both to R. F. Kahn, who alone" (Moore and Petersen 1955). His
introduced the employment multiplier to formula is well-known:
describe the effect upon unemployment of a
net increase in home investment (Kahn 1931), ∑a d hj jk
and to John Maynard Keynes, who elaborated =
j

on and expanded the concept as an income M k


(1)
multiplier in support of his arguments on
a hk

national income and employment (Keynes where Mk is the simple income multiplier for
1936). These are familiar beginnings for industry k, ahj is the household income
economics students. coefficient for industry j, and djk is the
While the concept of economic-base element in the inverse showing direct and
analysis had been at play in geography and indirect purchases from industry j associated
planning for a couple of decades, the with a unit exogenous sale by industry k.
economic-base multiplier did not seriously Moore explains his caution in using the
enter the literature in economics until 1950, term "simple" with a note that the Utah study
with estimation of an employment multiplier reports multipliers based on an inverse
for Los Angeles County by George H. derived from a coefficient matrix closed with
Hildebrand and Arthur Mace, Jr. (Hildebrand respect to households (but he fails to use an
and Mace do credit M. C. Daly, writing in the adjective in describing these other
Economic Journal in 1940 for their multipliers). In addition, he discusses "... one
approach.(Hildebrand and Mace 1950)) more type of relationship: the effects upon
From this start, economic-base multipliers investment induced by the changes in income
thrived in regional economics. Theodore and consumption. These effects he calls
Lane provides an excellent review of "accelerator coefficients," and he calculates
economic-base industry into its last great them with a modification of the numerator of
decade (Lane 1966). his simple income multiplier:
The early literature on input-output
analysis contained relatively few references to
multipliers, although the inverse or
R = ∑b d
k
j
j jk
(2)

interdependence matrix was well known and Rk is the accelerator coefficient, and bj is the
used with national tables. Essentially, it was
left to regional economists to develop input- capital-output ratio for industry j. This
coefficient has apparently disappeared from
the literature, probably due to data
1 This appendix is based on a paper presented at the deficiencies.
North American meetings of the Regional Science
Association in 1990.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 43 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Moore and Petersen report an interindustry Isard, pays scant attention to them, seven
model of Utah which remains a monument to pages out of over 700, devoted almost
scholarship. They go beyond Leontief's exclusively to the income and employment
earlier-described "balanced regional model" multipliers of the Utah study (Isard 1960).
(Leontief 1953) to develop a transactions Hollis B. Chenery and Paul G. Clark, in their
table with pure regional transactions, albeit Interindustry Economics, long the
transactions estimated with what Schaffer and comprehensive reference in the field, cite the
Chu later (1969) called the "supply-demand term "multiplier" only twice in their index
pool" technique, or the commodity-balance (Chenery and Clark 1959). Chenery and
approach. Clark do build inverses for Model I and
Model II tables, as did Hirsch, with the Model
They proceed with development of three II tables including households as
sets of income multipliers. Interestingly, endogenous.
especially given the problems we have faced
over the years in terminology, they give these But in 1965, William H. Miernyk devoted
multipliers no specific names. The first 14 pages of over 150 to multiplier analysis,
income multiplier was the one named earlier and 8 of these to income multipliers. Simple,
by Moore as the "simple income multiplier." clear, and easily understood, Miernyk's
Its numerator was "income reactions to Elements of Input-Output Analysis (Miernyk
changes in demand," or the direct and indirect 1965) became a virtual bible to budding
income effects of a unit change in final regional input-output analysts. Interest in
demand. The second was derived from regional input-output studies was intensifying
"income reactions including induced via in the sixties, and with this interest came a
homogeneous consumption functions," or the need to present in study reports some of the
direct, indirect, and induced income effects of tools which might help others in using
change. The third multiplier was based on models produced at substantial expense and
"income reactions including induced via effort.
nonhomogeneous consumption functions. Miernyk based his table illustrating
This third multiplier was computed using the "income interactions" on a similar table from
marginal coefficients in consumption Hirsch. But he changed column headings
functions estimated from national data for describing multipliers for models I and II to
only three aggregations of the seven-industry be "Type I multiplier" and "Type II
model used to illustrate the study. Moore and multiplier." To my knowledge, this is the
Petersen felt that the induced effect is beginning of the line for these names, which
overstated by the homogeneous consumption are still in use today. My suspicions are
functions implied by the closure of the model confirmed by P. Smith and W. I. Morrison,
with respect to households. who calculated income multipliers "... using
Werner Z. Hirsch, in his model of St. methods developed by Hirsch and discussed
Louis, moved beyond Moore and Petersen in further by Miernyk, ... described (after
three ways: he built the model from company Miernyk) as type 1 and type 2 income
records, he prepared a detailed exports matrix, multipliers" (Smith and Morrison 1974, p.
and he treated the household and local 57).
government sectors as endogenous parts of
the economy (Hirsch 1959). But he remained Type III multipliers
consistent in his treatment of income Moore and Petersen as well as Hirsch
multipliers, although he developed only two developed crude consumption functions for
sets and gave them parenthetic names. sets of industries in an attempt to reduce the
Moore's simple income multiplier became impact of average propensities to consume (as
"multiplier (Model I)" and his second expressed in a household coefficients
multiplier became "multiplier (Model II)." column) on the induced income effect
At this point, little attention had been paid included in their type II multipliers. But the
to input-output multipliers in the literature. In resulting third set of multipliers was
his Methods of Regional Analysis, Walter unnamed. Miernyk obliged in his Boulder

© 1999 RRI, WVU 44 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

study by labeling these multipliers as "type People asked about the impact of new plant
III multipliers." Miernyk calculated investment (a problem for which no
consumption functions in Boulder and convenient multipliers have been constructed)
applied estimated marginal propensities to and about the impact of export sales, but none
consume instead of household coefficients in would ask about the effect of a payroll
computing income multipliers. As he increase. So we added an "income
expected, the resulting type III multipliers coefficient," showing the total income effect
were lower than type II multipliers by slightly associated with a unit change in export sales.
more than 10 percent. (Miernyk et al. 1967) The format of the table was Hirsch's (1959, p.
366), with a total column added.
A second definition of type III multipliers
is in use in Canada in the Atlantic Provinces In documenting the 1970 Georgia input-
and Nova Scotia (See Jordan and Polenske output model, (Schaffer 1976), the traditional
1988 for a clear summary.). Following the definition became "... awkward and
lead of Kari Levitt and a team at Statistics inconsistent with the approach taken in most
Canada, I used three levels of closure to interpretations. Therefore, we ... defined the
develop output, income, and employment 'household-income multiplier' for industry j to
multipliers for the 1974, 1979, and 1984 be the addition to household incomes in the
Nova Scotia input-output models (DPA economy due to a one-unit increase in final
Group Inc. and Schaffer 1989). Model I is demand for the output of industry j." The
the traditional open model, yielding direct and footnote explaining this move is a clear
indirect effects; model II is closed with summary of the twisted path described thus
respect to households, yielding direct, indirect, far:
and induced effects; model III is closed with The notion of an income multiplier as first
respect to local and provincial government introduced to the regional literature by Moore and
sectors as well, yielding direct, indirect, and Petersen (1955) was used to describe additional
extended effects. We devised the term household income attributable to unit change in
"extended effects" to include effects induced household income in the industry in question. This
both by households and by local and definition is far removed from the exogenous
provincial governments. changes which precipitate additional income
changes, and it forces its user to unnecessary
This treatment of type III multipliers as trouble in determining, e.g., the importance of an
reflective of greater closure seems a better use industry to its community. We have therefore
of the numbering system. switched ... . Although a similar concept appeared
in Moore and Petersen, ... our point is that the
Household-income multipliers label is confusing. We first saw this concept
discussed as 'income coefficients' in the Mississippi
Income multipliers are the most study by Carden and Whittington (1964) and used
troublesome of multipliers. When we the term to distinguish our multiplier from the one
documented the Hawaii input-output model seen in the literature as late as 1973. (p. 67)
for 1967 the problems became obvious
(Schaffer et al. 1972). Because it was by then Davis (1968, p. 33) makes the importance of this
distinction clear. Two old-style income multipliers
traditional to show income and output may have exactly the same values but may differ
multipliers, we did so, designating them as substantially in terms of income change per unit
"simple" and "total," feeling these terms more change in final demand. He suggests that an
descriptive than "type I" and "type II." (The emphasis on absolute changes ... rather than on
"simple" came from the income multiplier in relative changes, as in Moore and Petersen, be made
Moore and Petersen; the "total" came from to avoid the confusion. The caution was also
their employment multiplier.) But we could expressed by Miernyk (1967, p. 101) in his Boulder
not recall any instance in which the study, which reported old-style income multipliers.
Department of Planning and Economic But despite these problems, the old-style
Development or any other agency had been income multipliers live on. Two not-too-
asked to show the total effect on household distant uses are in the Delaware model
incomes of a specified direct income change produced by Sharon Brucker and Steve
due to exogenous forces on an industry. Hastings (1984) and in the 1984 Nova Scotia

© 1999 RRI, WVU 45 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Study, where the term 'income-generated In both the Nova Scotia studies and the
multiplier' substitutes for the above- Georgia model, I produce government-income
recommended 'household-income multiplier' multipliers. for local governments and for
and 'income multipliers' are defined in the provincial or state governments.
original way. In all these cases, the multipliers can be
unambiguously interpreted as changes in
Other income multipliers
incomes per change in exogenous demand. It
It became obvious early that other is only the income multiplier associated with
multipliers reflecting the total impact of households that is ambiguous.
changes in final demand on incomes could be
generated. Employment multipliers
The documentation of the 1963 Employment multipliers were developed by
Washington input-output (Bourque and Moore and Petersen at the same time as and
others 1967) reports only one multiplier, the analogous to their income multipliers. They
regional income multiplier, which includes the estimated a set of aggregated employment-
change in total state income per $100,000 production relationships and used the
change in final demand. The 1972 coefficients showing change in employment
Washington study (Bourque and Conway per change in output as the a's in equation (1),
1977), in one of the clearest expositions of transforming the multiplier from dollar terms
multiplier development yet written, defines into employment terms. Their multipliers
type I and type II value added multipliers, relate total employment change to direct
along with labor-income multipliers, and jobs employment change.
multipliers. In each case, the multiplier is
calculated as "... a simple transformation of Both Hirsch and Miernyk repeat this
the output multipliers given in the inverse definition. In his Boulder study, Miernyk
matrix ... ." Thus: built "type III" employment multipliers as
well, with a complete set of employment
functions. Later, in his West Virginia Study,
M k
= ∑v b ∑v b
kj ij kj ij
(3) Miernyk apparently used simple
i employment-output ratios to effect the
transformation from output terms to
where Mk is the income multiplier for the kth employment terms.
factor income, vki is the input coefficient for
The first employment multipliers produced
the kth factor in industry i, and bij is the in the Washington series were for 1972.
inverse coefficient. Bourque and Conway unwaveringly maintain
This view of the multiplier as an operator their devotion to defining multipliers
with which to transform changes in industry denominated with final demand changes,
output into impacts on incomes of factors of producing type I and type II versions to
production was well expressed by Hays B. reflect levels of closure.
Gamble and David L. Raphael (1966). In a In Georgia, I also denominated my simple
survey-based model of Clinton County, and total employment multipliers with final
Pennsylvania, they develop "residual income demand changes. In Nova Scotia, we
multipliers" by inverting a coefficient matrix produced both output-based employment
including vectors for the nonprofit sector, multipliers and employment-based
three local government sectors, and four employment multipliers for models with three
household sectors. Then by summing levels of closure, parallel to our other
elements in these rows of the interdependency multipliers. This was largely because of a
matrix (inverse) for each industry, they feeling that, in inflationary times, the shelf life
produced household multipliers, local of output-based employment multipliers was
government multipliers, and nonprofit much lower than that of employment-based
multipliers. ones.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 46 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Output multipliers Observations and summary


Output multipliers are an obvious starting It is useful to conclude these comments
point for multiplier analyses. They are with a look at Table 5.4, reporting the
simply the column sums of the industry part summary of general multiplier formulas
of an inverse matrix. These columns are the provided in the recent comprehensive
essential ingredients in the other multiplier compendium on input-output analysis by
calculations. Yet, output multipliers were Ronald E. Miller and Peter G. Blair (1985).
neither mentioned nor alluded to by either Multipliers have admittedly become a larger
Moore and Petersen or Hirsch or Miernyk. question than for earlier writers. Miller and
Blair devote over ten percent of their book to
Floyd Harmston in his 1962 Wyoming regional, interregional, multiregional, and
study used a “business and industry interrelation multipliers. (Only five percent is
multiplier” which was a type I output devoted to basic regional multipliers.)
multiplier under another name (Harmston
1962). I used output multipliers in both They resolve my concern regarding the
Georgia and Nova Scotia studies. But, after a denominating of income and employment
little note from Rod Jensen, Australia’a multipliers by relegating the terms "type I"
leading authority on input-output analysis, and "type II" exclusively to multipliers with
commenting on an early draft, I made explicit denominators in the same terms as the
a warning that output multipliers should be numerators. They then use the terms
used only as general indicators of industrial "simple" and "total" to identify multipliers
activity. While they represent the essence of based on pure industry transactions tables
interindustry models, the flows of and tables closed with respect to households.
intermediate transactions are not our basic They specify multipliers based on final
interests in summary multipliers. Effects on demand changes as "household" income
income and employment are our primary multipliers, or "household" employment
concerns. Nevertheless, these by-products of multipliers.
useful multiplier production are common These statements and the explanations
statements in many studies. accompanying them are helpful indeed. But,
In explaining why they did not produce an appropriate conclusion of this review is
aggregate output multipliers for the 1972 that analytic purposes determine the
Washington model, Bourque and Conway terminology to use. The problem which we
express this caution beautifully: might perceive comes from overall study
reports which suggest through terminology
... we have not specified aggregate output
multipliers. Although the output multipliers given the impacts which might be examined through
by the elements of the inverse matrix are at the root regional input-output models. When
of the multipliers ...[calculated] ... , it is not very particular questions are pursued, explanations
meaningful to sum these elements into aggregate should eliminate the ambiguities in impact
output multipliers for each industry ... . In other interpretations.
words, given the concepts that lie behind each
output measure, it does not make much sense, Further extensions
economically speaking, to combine, say, the
shipments of pulp mills with the margins of the The point of view taken above can be
insurance industry into an aggregate transactions described as that of an old-line traditionalist.
measure. Furthermore, users of the Washington More multipliers continue to evolve and
tables in the past have sometimes employed recirculate. I should mention two of them
aggregate output multipliers inappropriately, in at
least one case confusing them with income One is income-distribution multipliers. to
multipliers. For these reasons, we have chosen not my knowledge, efforts to develop income-
to present aggregate output multipliers. (Bourque distribution multipliers started with Roland
and Conway 1977, p. 48) Artle in his studies of the Stockholm
economy (Artle 1965) and in his efforts in the
early sixties to estimate such multipliers while
working with a research team in Hawaii.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 47 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

While he conceptualized a system with the sufficiently documented to permit some


household row divided into several income evaluation of its conclusions.
classes and with the household expenditure
column similarly divided, the effort failed due
to complex data problems.
An effort which has yielded more fruit is
that of Kenichi Mizyzawa documented in
several articles in the sixties and seventies and
in his book (Miyazawa 1976). His
“intersectoral income multipliers” have been
used on numerous occasions in the last two
decades. Since such studies are beyond the
realm of normal economic impact analyses,
we do not treat them further.
The second multiplier system that has been
resurrected is the “SAM-based multiplier.”
Social Accounting Matrices (SAMs) evolved
to a high level in the sixties in several streams
of literature. One is the work of Richard A.
Stone (leading to his Nobel Laureate in
Economics) and extended at great detail in the
United Nations social accounting literature.
Another is the work at Statistics Canada as
exemplified in the most exhaustive theoretical
and empirical analysis of social accounts by
Kari Levitt for the Atlantic Provinces (Levitt
1975a; 1975b). A third outstanding example
of social accounting was executed by the late
Jerald R. Barnard at the University of Iowa
(Barnard 1967).
Each of these streams resulted
interindustry studies augmented by social
accounts documenting incomes in various
sectors of the economy (detailed income and
product accounts of which the aggregated
regional accounting table in Chapter 3 is a
simple example) and yielding multipliers for
the various sectors.
A more recent example of SAM multiplier
models is the one in current use by IMPLAN,
the modeling system developed by MIG, Inc.
(Minnesota IMPLAN Group Inc. 1997)
A final comment is simply a caution. The
proliferation of multipliers over the years and
the complexity of extensions to input-output
analysis can lead to substantial confusion
among even knowledgeable analysts. Any
multiplier analysis intended for a broad
audience (or even an important decision-
making audience) should be reduced to the
simplest possible terms but should be

© 1999 RRI, WVU 48 July 1999


Regional Input-Output Multipliers Chapter 5

Table 5.4 Summary of multiplier names and formulas from Miller and
Blair, Input-Output Analysis

MULTIPLIER ALGEBRAIC MULTIPLIER ALGEBRAIC


CATEGORY DEFINITION CATEGORY DEFINITION

Output
Simple
n
Oj = ∑ αij
i=1
Total
n+1
Oj = ∑ α ij
i=1
Income Employment
Simple household Simple household
n n
Hj = ∑ an+1, iα ij Ej = ∑ W n+1, iα i j
i=1 i=1
Total household Total household

n+1 n+1
Hj = ∑ an+1, iαij Ej = ∑ W n+1, iα i j
i=1
i=1
Type I
Type I
Y j = Hj/an+1, j W j = Ej/Wn+1, j
Type II
Type II

Y j = Hj/an+1, j W j = Ej/Wn+1, j

© 1999 RRI, WVU 49 July 1999


6 INTERREGIONAL MODELS
Now we can easily combine the economic- or it may be purchases by consumers outside
base and interindustry concepts to yield a the region, as in the economic-base model.
quick feeling for multi-regional models.
While we stop with this introduction, Closed economy, no external trade
extensions to include transactions between Assumptions:
industries in different regions are immediately
obvious. In fact, a considerable literature has E = E(Y) = eY
developed on interregional interindustry A = A0
models and efforts have even been made to
relate such models to “other worlds” such as Equilibrium condition:
the environment delineating the interactions of Y=E+A
the human economy with the highly
interactive elements of our land, sea, and air Solution:
“economies.” Y = eY + A0
Y = [1/(1 - e)] A0
Interregional economic-base models
Multiplier:
In the following summary models, I have
left implicit the definitions and identities dY/dA = 1/(1-e)
which we labored over before. The common
glossary is as follows: Open economy, with trade leakage
Y: income Assumptions:
E: income-related expenditures E1 = E1(Y1) = e1Y1
Ei: income-related expenditures in region i X1 = X0
Eij: income-related expenditures in region i M1 = M1(Y1) = m1Y1
by residents of region j
A autonomous expenditures A1 = A0
e: marginal propensity to spend, Equilibrium condition:
dE(Y)/dY=e Y 1 = E 1 + A 1 + X 1 - M1
X: exports Solution:
M: imports
Y1 = e1Y1 + A0 + X0 - m1Y1
m: marginal propensity to import,
dM(Y)/dY=m Y1 = (A0 + X0)* 1/(1 - (e1 - m1))
i: subscript for region (A subscript of 0 is Multiplier:
for “autonomous value.” ) dY1/dX0 = dY1/dA0 = 1/(1-(e1 - m1))

Two-region model with interregional


Review of one-region models trade
The one-region models are the Keynesian What has been missing all along has been
and economic-base models. Their interaction between regions. Obviously this
distinguishing characteristic is that the value takes place in the real world; otherwise, there
of income is determined by some would be no regions. Exports by one region
autonomous activity out there. It may be have to be imports into another economy.
investor behavior, as in the Keynesian model,

© 1999 RRI, WVU 50 Draft July 28, 1999


Interregional Models Chapter 6

without producing page after page of


Partial solution, two-region interregional
model cumbersome calculations. Nevertheless, we
will work with a two-region system for
The system can more easily be presented simplicity of discussion. We proceed as
by laying out the system in the same form as follows:
above but stopping before the algebra
requires the theory of determinants, which has Assumptions:
either been forgotten or ignored by most of As above, but now for both regions 1 and 2.
us. We will limit the statement to region one
alone in this section. Ei = Ei(Yi) = eiYi
Assumptions: Xi = Mj = Mj(Yj) = mjYj
E1 = E1(Y1) = e1Y1 Equilibrium conditions:
X1 = M2 = M2(Y2) = m2Y2 E 1 + X 1 - M1 + A 1 = Y 1
M1 = M1(Y1) = m1Y1 E 2 + X 2 - M2 + A 2 = Y 2
A1 = A0 Rewrite to align purchases from the two
regions:
Equilibrium condition:
E 1 - M 1 + X1 + A1 = Y1
Y 1 = E 1 + X 1 - M1 + A 1
X2 + E2 - M2 + A2 = Y2
Solution:
Now, observing the following definitions, we
Y1 = e1Y1 - m1Y1 + m2Y2 + A0 can rewrite the equation system preparatory to
dY1 = e1dY 1- m1dY 1 + m2(dY2/dY1) dY1 + matrix manipulation:
dA0 E11 = E1 - M1 = e1Y1 - m1Y1 = e11Y1
dY1 = e1dY 1- m1dY 1 + E12 = M2 = M2(Y2) = m2Y2 = e12Y2
m2(dY2/dY1)dY1(dM1/dX2) + dA0
E21 = X2 = M1(Y1) = m1Y1 = e21Y1
dY1 = e1dY 1- m1dY 1 + m2 m1 (dY2/dX2) dY1
+ dA0 E22 = E2 - M2 = e2Y2 - m2Y2 = e22Y2
But this line of attack becomes unnecessarily Note that the e's now show double subscripts
complicated. We can't easily reduce the showing purchases from region i by region j.
interactive term without knowing the So the system becomes
multiplier for the other region (dY2/dX2)!
E11 + E12 + A1 = Y1
Multiplier:
E21 + E22 + A2 = Y2
dY1/d A0 = 1/(1-(e1 - m1 +m2 m1 (dY2/dX2))
or
dY1/d A0 = 1/(1-(e1 - m1 + interregional
effect)) e11Y1 + e12Y2 + A1 = Y1
Let us take a more familiar tack. (This e21Y1 + e22Y2 + A2 = Y2
approach originated with Alan Metzler which translates into matrices as
(Metzler 1950); Harry Richardson provides
the restatement on which the above is based  e11 e12 Y2 + A1= Y1
(Richardson 1969)  e21 e22 Y2 + A2= Y2
or
Matrix solution, two-region interregional
model eY + A = Y
This model can be more systematically where e is the matrix of eij. This solves
expressed with the matrix algebra developed exactly as would an input-output system:
for input-output analysis. Matrix algebra
permits us to immediately extend our logic Y - eY = A
from two regions as above to n regions

© 1999 RRI, WVU 51 Draft July 28, 1999


Interregional Models Chapter 6

(I - e)Y = A Both of these extensions are discussed in


(I - e)-1(I - e)Y = (I - e) -1A detail in the comprehensive input-output
reference by Ronald Miller and Peter Blair.
Y = (I - e) -1A (Miller and Blair 1985)
Now, to give the elements of this inverse a
designation, set
R = (I - e)-1 =  R11 R12 Study questions
 R21 R22 1. Outline a simple two-region interregional model,
rewrite the solution as convert it to matrix form, and solve the system.
2. Construct the model for a closed economy with
Y1 = R11A1 + R12A2 no external leakage in matrix form as in question
Y2 = R21A1 + R22A2 (1). Identify elements in the multiplier matrix.
3. Construct the model for an open economy with
The interregional multipliers are thus trade leakage but no interregional linkage in
dYi/dAj = Rij matrix form as in question (1). Identify elements
in the multiplier matrix.
for each ith row and jth column. 4. Compare the multipliers for (say region 1) in an
Now, it is a simple matter to expand the interregional economy, a closed economy, and an
system to treat n regions. The process is open economy with trade leakage. Which system
identical to that used in the two-region system has the largest multipliers? Which the smallest?
but with larger matrices!

Extensions and further study


Interregional interindustry models
The obvious extension is to expand the cell
entries to become interindustry transactions
matrices. Thus the E12 entries would become
klEij, showing purchases from industry k in
region i by industry l in region j; where i=j,
the regional transactions matrix for region i is
inserted, and where i is not equal j, a matrix
of imports is inserted.
The most commonly used multi-regional
interindustry model of the United States was
assembled by Professor Karen Polenske at
MIT. Her model includes transactions
generally for 50 industries in each of 44
states or sets of states.(Polenske 1980)

Economic-ecologic models
Economic-ecologic models append
matrices depicting interaction between sectors
in the natural environment and between those
sectors and the industrial ones. The concept
is similar to interregional interindustry
analysis but implementation becomes a
harrowing experience. The dominant
example of this was a complex model of the
Massachusetts Bay area. (Isard et al. 1972)

© 1999 RRI, WVU 52 Draft July 28, 1999


7 COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY ECONOMIC
ACCOUNTS: THE NOVA SCOTIA INPUT-OUTPUT
TABLES
My intention is to make the transition to the
Introduction more complex modern system easier as well
Now that we have the basic framework of as to economize on the writing chore.(DPA
input-output analysis in hand, let's move a Group Inc. and Schaffer 1989)
little closer to the format in which data is now The Nova Scotia input-output tables
accumulated at the national level and from represent a complete set of social accounts for
which we estimate the parameters of regional the Province. As is common with most social
models. accounts, it is double entry in nature, but it
This format was developed in the 1960s by has been organized in matrix form rather than
Richard A. Stone at Cambridge and adopted as the traditional T-accounts. This section
as a standard by the United Nations. Stone presents a brief schematic review of the
later received the Nobel Prize in Economics accounting framework. In addition, the
for his work in national income accounting interpretation of the Nova Scotia tables is
(which includes input-output accounting). demonstrated with a set of highly aggregated
Statistics Canada (the statistical agency in (five-industries) tables which duplicate the
Canada) pioneered in applying this format format of the more detailed tables produced in
starting with their 1960 table; the Input- the Nova Scotia Input-Output Study itself.
Output Division of the U.S. Department of
Commerce produced their 1972 table in the A schematic social-accounting
new format. As a result, most of the state and framework
regional models produced today are based on
this format and data source. The Nova Scotia input-output tables follow
the form of the Canadian tables. They are of
This format is called the "commodity-by- the "rectangular form" and show substantially
industry" format, and sometimes the more of the commodity detail of industry
"rectangular" system. It is rectangular in that purchases than do tables of the "square" form
the commodity dimension may be greater commonly used in the United States and
than the industry dimension (which poses a elsewhere. As shown in Illustration 7.1, the
problem when the direct-requirements matrix tables comprise six matrices. Three sets of
must be square to provide a solvable system). accounts are evident in these matrices and the
It originated with a realization that firms, comments which follow are intended to
grouped in industries, buy commodities and identify the accounts in the tables.
that we have trouble grouping commodities
into industries. Firms often produce several Commodity accounts
commodities. They are classified into
industries according to their primary For each commodity used and/or produced
products; their remaining products are in the Province, accounts representing supply
secondary. An accounting scheme has to and demand can be constructed. Thus, the
manage this problem. shaded row in Illustration 7.2 presents the
demand side of the supply-and-demand
I had the pleasure of building three input- equation for a particular commodity. It
output systems in Nova Scotia (1974, 1979,
and 1984) during the period when the
computing world moved from mainframes to
desktops. The system fits exactly with the
new U.S. system. Chapters 8 and 9 parallel
Chapters 4 and 5 in organization and content.
© 1999 RRI, WVU 53 Draft July 28, 1999
Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Illustration 7.1 Schematic input-output table for Nova Scotia

CONSUMING
USING INDUSTRIES SECTORS S
U
1 2 3 . . . n H C G . . . E M
1

TOTAL COMMODITY DEMAND


2 MATRIX 2 MATRIX 1

COMMODITIES
3
COMMODITY FINAL
.
USES OR DEMANDS
.
INDUSTRY BY
.
INPUTS CONSUMERS

COMMODITIES
1 2 3 . . . m
1

TOTAL INDUSTRY
2 MATRIX 5
PRODUCING
INDUSTRIES

OUTPUTS
3
. COMMODITY ORIGINS
.
. OR
INDUSTRY OUTPUTS
n

H
C
MATRIX 4

TOTAL FACTOR
MATRIX 3
PRIMARY INPUT

RECEIPTS
SECTORS

. NONMARKET
FACTOR USES
. TRANSFERS
.

VECTOR 6:
M COMMODITY IMPORTS

SUM TOTAL COMMODITY TOTAL INDUSTRY TOTAL FINAL


SUPPLY INPUTS OUTLAYS

© 1999 RRI, WVU 54 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Illustration 7.2 Schematic input-output table for Nova Scotia emphasizing


the commodity accounts

CONSUMING
USING INDUSTRIES SECTORS S
U
1 2 3 . . . n H C G . . . E M
1
MATRIX 2 MATRIX 1

TOTAL COMMODITY DEMAND


2

COMMODITIES
3
COMMODITY FINAL
.
USES OR DEMANDS
.
INDUSTRY BY
.
INPUTS CONSUMERS

COMMODITIES

1 2 3 . . . m
1

TOTAL INDUSTRY
2 MATRIX 5
PRODUCING
INDUSTRIES

OUTPUTS
3
. COMMODITY ORIGINS
.
. OR
INDUSTRY OUTPUTS
n

H
C
MATRIX 4

TOTAL FACTOR
MATRIX 3
PRIMARY INPUT

RECEIPTS
NONMARKET
SECTORS

.
FACTOR USES
. TRANSFERS
.
VECTOR 6:
M COMMODITY IMPORTS
.SUM TOTAL COMMODITY TOTAL INDUSTRY TOTAL FINAL
SUPPLY INPUTS OUTLAYS

© 1999 RRI, WVU 55 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

shows both the intermediate uses, or wages and salaries paid by households,
demands, expressed by domestic industries governments, and outside employers these
for the commodity, as recorded in Matrix 2, "transfers" are non-market in nature and
and the final uses, or demands, by consuming represent such items as taxes, savings, welfare
sectors for the commodity, as recorded in payments, intergovernmental transfers, and
Matrix 1. These consuming sectors include surpluses and deficits.
local consumers and investors, governments, In accounting for gross provincial product,
and non-local users. Total demand is the sum the row sums of Matrix 3 represent incomes
of total industry demand and total final of domestic factors as paid by the private, or
demand. industrial, sectors of the economy. The
The supply side of the equation for a addition of incomes earned by households
commodity is represented in Illustration 7.2 from the primary sectors in Matrix 4
by the shaded column, which traverses Matrix completes the income side of gross provincial
5 and Vector 6. In Matrix 5, this column product. This tabulation of incomes
identifies the domestic industrial origins of represents value added in the economy.
the commodity; Vector 6 identifies imports of The shaded column in Illustration 7.4
the commodity. The column sum is total represents the final expenditures by a
supply, which is equal to total demand. primary-input sector. In Matrix 1, the
commodity detail of such expenditures is
Industry accounts shown, and in Matrix 4, the transfers
The inputs and outputs of industries can (including wages and salaries) to other
also be traced in this system. Illustration 7.3 primary sectors are recorded. The sum of
moves the shaded column and row to these commodity purchases and transfers is
represent inputs and outputs of a particular total expenditures, which is equal to total
industry. The outputs of the industry can be receipts by the sectors.
seen in the shaded row. This row records the The expenditures side of the gross
values of the various commodities produced provincial product account consists of the
by the industry. The column in Illustration sum of total purchases of goods and services
7.3 records the production technology of the by domestic primary sectors, household
industry in terms of commodities purchased incomes received from these sectors, and
in Matrix 2 and of payments to "primary" gross commodity exports less industry
inputs (i.e., labor, return to capital, etc.), or imports (or net exports).
factors of production, in Matrix 3. Since the
payments to inputs include profits, or the
residual receipts by owners of establishments Aggregated input-output tables
in the industry, total inputs equal total outputs With this overall scheme in mind, consider
for the industry. now the format of the actual tables. Small,
highly aggregated (5-industry) versions of the
Final accounts tables are used as illustrations.
The incomes and expenditures of
"primary" sectors (e.g. household,
government, etc.) of the economy can also be
traced through the system. The shaded row
and column in Illustration 7.4 are illustrative.
The shaded row represents the incomes of a
"primary" sector such as households or a
government. As seen in Matrix 3, these
incomes are paid by industries which use the
services of the factors of production owned or
provided by the sector. In addition, transfers
of incomes from other "primary" sectors are
recorded in Matrix 4. With the exception of

© 1999 RRI, WVU 56 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Illustration 7.3 Schematic input-output table for Nova Scotia emphasizing


the industry accounts

CONSUMING
USING INDUSTRIES SECTORS S
U
1 2 3 . . . n H C G . . . E M
1

TOTAL COMMODITY DEMAND


2 MATRIX 2 MATRIX 1

COMMODITIES
3
COMMODITY FINAL
.
USES OR DEMANDS
.
INDUSTRY BY
.
INPUTS CONSUMERS

COMMODITIES
1 2 3 . . . m
1

TOTAL INDUSTRY
2 MATRIX 5

OUTPUTS
PRODUCING
INDUSTRIES

3
. COMMODITY ORIGINS
.
. OR
INDUSTRY OUTPUTS
n

H
C
MATRIX 4
MATRIX 3
PRIMARY INPUT

TOTAL FACTOR
G

RECEIPTS
NONMARKET
SECTORS

.
FACTOR USES
. TRANSFERS
.

VECTOR 6:
M COMMODITY IMPORTS

SUM TOTAL COMMODITY TOTAL INDUSTRY TOTAL FINAL


SUPPLY INPUTS OUTLAYS

© 1999 RRI, WVU 57 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Illustration 7.4 Schematic input-output table for Nova Scotia emphasizing


the final Income and expenditure accounts

CONSUMING
USING INDUSTRIES SECTORS S
U
1 2 3 . . . n H C G . . . E M
1

TOTAL COMMODITY DEMAND


2 MATRIX 2 MATRIX 1

COMMODITIES
3
COMMODITY FINAL
.
USES OR DEMANDS
.
INDUSTRY BY
.
INPUTS CONSUMERS

COMMODITIES
1 2 3 . . . m
1

TOTAL INDUSTRY
2 MATRIX 5
PRODUCING
INDUSTRIES

OUTPUTS
3
. COMMODITY ORIGINS
.
. OR
INDUSTRY OUTPUTS
n

H
C
MATRIX 4
MATRIX 3

TOTAL FACTOR
PRIMARY INPUT

RECEIPTS
NONMARKET
SECTORS

.
FACTOR USES
.
RECEIPTS
TRANSFERS
.

VECTOR 6:
M COMMODITY IMPORTS

SUM TOTAL COMMODITY TOTAL INDUSTRY TOTAL FINAL


SUPPLY INPUTS OUTLAYS

© 1999 RRI, WVU 58 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

requires that the domestic origins matrix and


The commodity flows table the imports vector be transposed from their
The commodity flows table combines the original form in Illustration 7.1.
use, final demand, and associated income
matrices (Matrices 1, 2, 3 and 4) of
Illustration 7.1. (In the national tables, the
two equivalent tables are described as the "use
matrix" (example Matrices 2 and 3) and the Study questions
"final demand matrix" (example Matrices 1 1. Why were commodity-by-industry accounts
and 4). Table 7.1 is the aggregated developed?
commodity flows table. The boundaries
between the various matrices are marked by a
row for total commodity inputs and a column
for total industry demands. This table is a
complete description of commodity purchases
by all Nova Scotia industries, all domestic and
government consumers, and all non-local
purchasers.
Note that the commodity flows table does
not distinguish between commodities
produced domestically and those imported
from outside the Province. The table which
embodies this distinction is called the
"provincial flows table" and is presented in
the next chapter as the first stage in
developing the input-output model.

The commodity origins table


The commodity origins table combines the
domestic origin matrix (5) and the imports
vector (6) of Illustration 7.1 (In the national
tables, the equivalent table is called the "make
matrix"). Table 7.2 is an aggregated
commodity origins table for Nova Scotia
which is consistent with the aggregated flows
table.
Note that the origins table records more
than just the origins of commodities. It also
includes a complete tabulation of supply and
demand for each commodity used in Nova
Scotia. The last seven columns of the table
summarize the commodity accounts of the
Province. The demands recorded here are the
same as the demand totals found in Table 7.1.
Also note that the industry accounts are
represented by the column totals found in
both tables. Total industry inputs are in Table
7.1 while total industry outputs are in Table
7.2.
For ease of production and in reading,
columns represent industries and rows
represent commodities. This convention

© 1999 RRI, WVU 59 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Table 7.1 Aggregated commodity flows, Nova Scotia, 1984


Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- Total
tion turing struc- tribu- vice industry
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. demand
1 Agricultural products 87 318 4 22 16 447
2 Primary fish 3 179 0 0 1 183
3 Minerals 6 1210 14 0 149 1379
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 154 648 86 85 737 1711
5 Durable manuf. goods 93 489 409 24 337 1352
6 Repair construction 10 25 1 7 225 268
7 Residential construction 0 0 0 0 0 0
8 Nonresidential const. 0 0 0 0 0 0
9 Transp., comm. and util. 80 160 11 106 735 1092
10 Distribution 36 117 81 20 182 436
11 Services 640 443 173 341 1109 2705
12 Total commodity inputs 1109 3589 779 604 3491 9573
13 Household receipts 535 899 391 877 2833 5535
14 Local and prov. govt rev 23 164 62 41 278 568
15 Capital residual 92 136 52 137 704 1120
16 Federal govt revenues 0 -10 29 23 62 104
17 External transfers -106 -79 109 151 -75 -1
18 Total primary inputs 545 1109 641 1230 3802 7327
19 Total inputs 1654 4699 1420 1834 7293 16900

House- Local and Capi- Federal Domestic Total


hold prov. tal for- govt final Total final Total
Commodity exp. govt exp. mation exp. demand exports demand demand
1 Agricultural products 115 5 0 1 121 79 200 646
2 Primary fish 2 0 0 0 2 84 85 268
3 Minerals 2 17 696 0 716 133 848 2227
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 1 6 7 9 139 147 60 2025 1639 3664 5374
5 Durable manuf. goods 810 18 611 114 1553 972 2525 3877
6 Repair construction 4 25 0 33 63 33 95 363
7 Residential construction 0 0 541 0 541 0 541 541
8 Nonresidential const. 0 0 600 11 610 40 651 651
9 Transp., comm. and util. 523 194 0 84 802 203 1005 2097
10 Distribution 1174 28 112 10 1324 0 1324 1760
11 Services 2874 560 121 524 4079 49 4128 6833
12 Total commodity inputs 7182 987 2828 838 11835 3231 15066 24639
13 Household receipts 302 1839 0 2630 4771 22 4793 10328
14 Local and prov. govt rev 921 1804 66 1230 4021 14 4035 4603
15 Capital residual 418 141 0 0 559 0 559 1679
16 Federal govt revenues 1499 12 -582 1248 2177 10 2187 2291
17 External transfers 17 0 0 0 17 0 17 16
18 Total primary inputs 3157 3796 -516 5108 11545 4 6 11591 18918
19 Total inputs 10339 4783 2312 5946 23380 3277 26657 43557

© 1999 RRI, WVU 60 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry-Economic Accounts Chapter 7

Table 7.2 Aggregated commodity origins, Nova Scotia, 1984


Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- Total
tion turing struc- tribu- vice industry
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. supply
1 Agricultural products 353 2 0 0 0 355
2 Primary fish 267 1 0 0 0 268
3 Minerals 1032 1 0 0 0 1033
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 1 3324 0 6 0 3331
5 Durable manuf. goods 1 1367 0 4 33 1404
6 Repair construction 0 0 363 0 0 363
7 Residential construction 0 0 406 0 0 406
8 Nonresidential const. 0 0 651 0 0 651
9 Transp., comm. and util. 0 0 0 0 1980 1980
10 Distribution 0 1 0 1598 13 1612
11 Services 1 3 0 226 5268 5498
12 Total inputs 1654 4699 1420 1834 7293 16900

Total Total dom-


Total Total industry estic final Total Total
Commodity imports supply demand demand exports demand
1 Agricultural products 291 646 447 121 79 646
2 Primary fish 0 268 183 2 84 268
3 Minerals 1194 2227 1379 716 133 2227
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 2044 5374 1711 2025 1639 5374
5 Durable manuf. goods 2474 3877 1352 1553 972 3877
6 Repair construction 0 363 268 63 33 363
7 Residential construction 135 541 0 541 0 541
8 Nonresidential const. 0 651 0 610 40 651
9 Transp., comm. and util. 117 2097 1092 802 203 2097
10 Distribution 149 1760 436 1324 0 1760
11 Services 1335 6833 2705 4079 49 6833
12 Total inputs 7739 24639 9573 11835 3231 24639

© 1999 RRI, WVU 61 Draft July 28, 1999


8 COMMODITY-BY-INDUSTRY INTERINDUSTRY
MODELS: THE LOGIC OF THE NOVA SCOTIA INPUT-
OUTPUT MODEL
a solvable form in industry-by-industry
Introduction dimensions on the basis of the fixed market-
This section develops an economic model share assumption. Finally, using the
from the accounting tables for Nova Scotia. constant-technology assumption, we can solve
The process parallels that used in the the system conventionally.
traditional regional format presented in
Chapter 4. It differs in that we now shift The data
from a world in which regional economists We start with two sets of tables defining
collect their own data into one requiring vast the economy: The commodity flows table
teams of statisticians. As seen in the previous and the commodity origins table. Both are
chapter, much new information and detail is described in the previous chapter and are the
now available. We need more assumptions to sources for the use and make matrices used
reduce it to a manageable format. below.
As the literature associated with the
Canadian and Atlantic Provinces input-output Technical conditions
studies suggests, and as demonstrated in the
appendix to this chapter describing the Now say that final demands have been
mathematics of the U.S. system, the model estimated for some future date and that we
could be phrased in terms of commodities. wish to identify the effect of this demand on
The procedures are similar, however, and the the Province. What are the gross outputs of
reader is referred to the earlier literature for industries in Nova Scotia at that time? It is
further details. Here we do a simple sketch. obvious that the system of flow equations is
not prepared for solution: in the flows table,
Essentially, we manipulate the new system there are 11 equations, one for each
of accounts until the number of variables in a commodity, and 82 variables of which only
set of simultaneous equations describing the 11, the final demands, have preassigned
economy equals the number of equations. values. Neither is the system of origins, or
The system differs slightly from the make equations, which consists of 5
traditional square regional matrices in that equations and 66 unknowns.
now we have not only more commodities (and
so more equations) than industries but also The minimum requirement for solution of
two equation systems to face! We must this system is that the number of equations
devise some way to redress this imbalance. equals the number of unknowns. One task,
therefore, is to reduce the number of
While the commodity-by-industry format unknowns. Further, the system is expressed
traditional to the Canadian and Nova Scotia in terms of both commodity outputs and
input-output systems opens up a variety of industry inputs, while our stated goal is to
possibilities for forming this model, the determine the effect of final-demand changes
approach employed here develops a solution on industries. So a second task is to express
to the model in terms of industries rather than the system in terms of industry variables
commodities. This means that, while the alone. This conversion will both reduce the
economy is described initially in terms of sets number of equations and, more importantly,
of equations representing the tables of permit us to establish a familiar equilibrium
commodity-by-industry flows and origins, we condition. The third and final task before
must convert them to regional flows (through solution is that of reducing the flows matrix
application of the constant-imports from a statement of production technology to
assumption) and then reduce the equations to
© 1999 RRI, WVU 62 Draft July 28, 1999
Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

one of regional trade. We proceed in reverse table, showing purchases of commodities


order. produced by local industries. Note that it is
very similar to Table 7.1, the commodity
The constant-imports assumption flows table. It differs in the values of
commodity purchases, which are now only
Few of the recent regional input-output local in origin. It also contains a row of
studies in this format have included survey- imports (the external transfers row). The
based, cell-specific import details. As a result, industry outputs and final demands remain
regional (or provincial, in this case) trade the same.
flows must be estimated by assumption. We
know imports for each commodity in the (Note here that imports were estimated at
system (Table 7.2) and we know total the detailed, 602-commodity, worksheet level
industry domestic final demands. And that is using uniform import coefficients for each
all, so the best way to estimate regional trade commodity. These detailed worksheets
is to assume that each industry purchases permit a level of realism not attainable when
imported commodities in constant estimates of imports are made at an
proportions: aggregated level.)
µk = mk/(Σjukj + ek) (8-1) The constant market-share assumption
where µk is the import coefficient for The matrix reported in the commodity
commodity k , mk is an element in m, the origins table (Table 7.2) provides data
imports vector, and the denominator is the necessary for converting from a commodity
sum of intermediate and local-final demands sales dimension to an industry one. If each
for commodity k. entry (vjk) in the make matrix is divided by the
Provincial flows of commodity k can thus appropriate total commodity output, the
be estimated as resulting coefficients can be used as weights
with which to aggregate commodity rows in
Pkj = ukj*(1 - µk) (8-2) the provincial flows matrix. Called "domestic
where uij is the purchase of commodity k by market-share coefficients", these weights are
industry j . This yields a set of equations for computed as
sales of locally produced commodities such djk = vjk/ qk (8-4)
as the following:
where djk is the market share of commodity k
P11 + P12 + ... + P1m + e1 + x1 = q1 (8- produced by industry j, and qk is the total
3) domestic output of commodity k . The
P21 + P22 + ... + P2m + e2 + x2 = q2 domestic market-share matrix, D, is
comprised of these djk.
. . ... . . . .
Now, assuming that market shares remain
. . ... . . . . constant, the provincial flows matrix P and the
. . ... . . . . vector h representing local final demand can
be aggregated to industry-by-industry
Pn1 + Pn2 + ... + Pnm + en + xn = qn dimensions by matrix multiplication:
where Pkj is local sales of commodity k to Z = D*P (8-5)
industry j, ek is sales of commodity k to final
demand, xk is export sales of commodity k, qk h = D*(e + x) (8-6)
is total local production of the commodity, This process means that each element zij in Z
and n and m are the number of commodities is a sum of weighted commodity sales,
and industries, respectively. In this example,
n is 11 and m is 5. zij = Σk (dik*Pkj ) (8-7)
The results of this process are reported in and that sales are in proportion to the industry
Table 8.1, the aggregated provincial flows product mixes. The provincial final-demand

© 1999 RRI, WVU 63 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Table 8.1 Aggregated commodity-by-industry provincial flows, Nova Scotia,


1984
E x t r a c - Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- Total
tion turing struc- tribu- vice industry
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. demand
1 Agricultural products 9 184 2 8 8 210
2 Primary fish 3 179 0 0 1 183
3 Minerals 4 20 12 0 148 185
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 113 195 42 47 350 746
5 Durable manuf. goods 22 93 118 8 50 291
6 Repair construction 10 25 1 7 225 268
7 Residential construction 0 0 0 0 0 0
8 Nonresidential const. 0 0 0 0 0 0
9 Transp., comm. and util. 76 155 11 95 689 1026
10 Distribution 33 58 75 17 168 351
11 Services 122 398 110 288 826 1744
12 Total commodity inputs 392 1307 370 471 2464 5004
1 3 Household receipts 535 899 391 877 2833 5535
1 4 Local and prov. govt rev. 23 164 62 41 278 568
1 5 Capital residual 92 136 52 137 704 1120
1 6 Federal govt revenues 0 -10 29 23 62 104
1 7 Imports and transfers 612 2203 517 285 952 4568
18 Total primary inputs 1262 3391 1050 1363 4829 11896
19 Total inputs 1654 4699 1420 1834 7293 16900

House- Local and Capi- Federal Domestic Total


hold prov. tal for- govt final Total final Total
Commodity exp. govt exp. mation exp. demand exports demand demand
1 Agricultural products 62 3 0 0 66 79 145 355
2 Primary fish 2 0 0 0 2 84 85 268
3 Minerals 2 17 696 0 715 133 848 1033
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 678 89 145 35 946 1639 2585 3331
5 Durable manuf. goods 41 3 80 17 140 972 1113 1404
6 Repair construction 4 25 0 33 63 33 95 363
7 Residential construction 0 0 406 0 406 0 406 406
8 Nonresidential const. 0 0 600 11 610 40 651 651
9 Transp., comm. and util. 496 176 0 79 751 203 954 1980
10 Distribution 1122 27 103 10 1261 0 1261 1612
11 Services 2705 445 119 436 3705 49 3754 5498
12 Total commodity inputs 5112 785 2149 620 8665 3231 11896 16900
13 Household receipts 302 1839 0 2630 4771 22 4793 10328
14 Local and prov. govt rev. 921 1804 66 1230 4021 14 4035 4603
15 Capital residual 418 141 0 0 559 0 559 1679
16 Federal govt revenues 1499 12 -582 1248 2177 10 2187 2291
17 Imports and transfers 2087 202 679 218 3187 -7755 -4568 0
18 Total primary inputs 5227 3998 163 5326 14715 -7709 7006 18902
19 Total inputs 10339 4783 2312 5946 23380 -4478 18902 35801

© 1999 RRI, WVU 64 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

matrix, presented as the summed vector e and proportion to their purchases in 1984, the
the commodity exports vector x may be number of variables can be reduced to
similarly aggregated, yielding the vector h. equality with the number of equations. On
the basis of this assumption, a set of
Table 8.2 reports domestic market-share provincial production coefficients is
coefficients as computed from the aggregated computed, defined as:
make matrix. That the transpose of this table
times the provincial flows matrices yields aij = zij/gj (8-9)
Table 8.3, the provincial interindustry where aij is the proportion of purchases from
matrices, may be verified through application local industry i by industry j. The direct-
of equation 8-7. requirements matrix, A, is composed of these
This process has yielded an industry-by- coefficients. For the aggregated system, this
industry provincial flows table and has matrix is reported in Table 8.4.
prepared the system for solution in terms of Note that equation 8-9 can be rewritten as:
industry outputs. But the number of variables
with unknown values, 30, is still in excess of zij = aij*gj (8-10)
the number of equations, 5. The equation If the aij remain reasonably stable over time,
system now takes the following form:
aij*gj can be substituted for zij in the equation
z11 + z12 + ... + z1n + h1 = t1 (8-8) system 8-8 with the needed result:
z21 + z22 + ... + z2n + h2 = t2 a 11*g 1 + a 12*g 2 + ... + a 1m*g m + h 1 = t1
. . ... . . =. a21*g1 + a22*g2 + ... + a2m*gm + h 2 = t2
. . ... . . =. . . ... . . .
. . ... . . =. . . ... . . .
zm1 + zm2 + ... + zmn + hm = tm . . ... . . .
where ti represents industry sales. am1*g1 + am2*g2 + ...+ amm*gm + hm = tm
(8-11)
The constant-technology assumption
Now if we assume that industries continue
to purchase inputs from other industries in

Table 8.2 Domestic market-share coefficients, Nova Scotia, 1984


Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- Total
tion turing struc- tribu- vice industry
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. supply
1 Agricultural products 0.9954 0.0046 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
2 Primary fish 0.9962 0.0038 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
3 Minerals 0.9990 0.0010 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
4 Nondurable manuf. goods 0.0002 0.9979 0.0000 0.0018 0.0000 1.0000
5 Durable manuf. goods 0.0004 0.9736 0.0000 0.0027 0.0232 1.0000
6 Repair construction 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
7 Residential construction 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
8 Nonresidential const. 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
9 Transp., comm. and util. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000
10 Distribution 0.0000 0.0008 0.0000 0.9913 0.0079 1.0000
11 Services 0.0001 0.0006 0.0000 0.0412 0.9581 1.0000

© 1999 RRI, WVU 65 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Table 8.3 Provincial interindustry transactions, Nova Scotia, 1984


Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- Total
tion turing s t r u c - t r i b u - vice industry
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. demand
1 Extraction 16 382 14 8 156 576
2 Manufacturing 134 287 156 55 399 1031
3 Construction 10 25 1 7 225 268
4 Distribution 38 75 79 29 201 421
5 Service 194 539 119 371 1483 2707
12 Total industry inputs 392 1307 370 471 2464 5004
13 Household receipts 535 899 391 877 2833 5535
14 Local and prov. govt rev 23 164 62 41 278 568
15 Capital residual 92 136 52 137 704 1120
16 Federal govt revenues 0 -10 29 23 62 104
17 Imports and transfers 612 2203 517 285 952 4568
18 Total primary inputs 1262 3391 1050 1363 4829 11896
19 Total inputs 1654 4699 1420 1834 7293 16900

House- Local and Capi- Federal Domestic Total


hold prov. tal for- govt final Total final Total
Commodity exp. govt exp. mation exp. demand exports demand demand
1 Extraction 66 20 696 1 783 295 1078 1654
2 Manufacturing 719 92 223 51 1085 2583 3668 4699
3 Construction 4 25 1005 44 1079 73 1152 1420
4 Distribution 1225 45 107 27 1405 8 1412 1834
5 Service 3098 603 117 497 4314 272 4586 7293
12 Total industry inputs 5112 785 2149 620 8665 3231 11896 16900
13 Household receipts 302 1839 0 2630 4771 22 4793 10328
14 Local and prov. govt rev 921 1804 66 1230 4021 14 4035 4603
15 Capital residual 418 141 0 0 559 0 559 1679
16 Federal govt revenues 1499 12 -582 1248 2177 10 2187 2291
17 Imports and transfers 2087 202 679 218 3187 -7755 -4568 0
18 Total primary inputs 5227 3998 163 5326 14715 -7709 7006 18902
19 Total inputs 10339 4783 2312 5946 23380 -4478 18902 35801

© 1999 RRI, WVU 66 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Table 8.4 Direct requirements per dollar of gross output, Nova Scotia, 1984
Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- House-
tion turing struc- tribu- vice hold
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. exp.
1 Extraction 0.010 0.081 0.010 0.005 0.021 0.006
2 Manufacturing 0.081 0.061 0.110 0.030 0.055 0.070
3 Construction 0.006 0.005 0.001 0.004 0.031 0.000
4 Distribution 0.023 0.016 0.056 0.016 0.028 0.119
5 Service 0.117 0.115 0.084 0.203 0.203 0.300
12 Total industry inputs 0.237 0.278 0.260 0.257 0.338 0.494
13 Household receipts 0.324 0.191 0.275 0.478 0.389 0.029
14 Local and prov. govt rev. 0.014 0.035 0.043 0.022 0.038 0.089
15 Capital residual 0.056 0.029 0.036 0.075 0.096 0.040
16 Federal govt revenues 0.000 -0.002 0.020 0.013 0.008 0.145
17 Imports and transfers 0.370 0.469 0.364 0.155 0.131 0.202
18 Total primary inputs 0.763 0.722 0.740 0.743 0.662 0.506
19 Total inputs 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

The system is now reduced to a set of 5 A*g' + h' = g' (8-13)


simultaneous equations in 10 unknowns and
can easily be reduced to solvable dimensions where A is the matrix of provincial production
by imposing the traditional equilibrium coefficients (aij) and g' is a column vector of
condition. gross industry outputs. h' is a column vector
of final demands for industry outputs (from
Equilibrium condition: supply equals equation 8-6)
demand The solution is analogous to that of
Equilibrium occurs when anticipated common algebra in its formulation.
supply equals demand, or when the gross Grouping the g' terms yields:
outputs of an industry equal its sales. So the g' - A*g' = h' (8-14)
condition is that
gj = t j (8-12) while factoring produces:
(The condition could also be stated in terms (I - A)*g' = h' (8-15)
of commodity outputs and demands.) Multiplying both sides of this equation by
the inverse of (I - A) produces a solution in
Solution: the total-requirements table terms of X':
The response of an economy in moving to (I - A)-1* (I - A)*g' = (I - A)-1* h''
another equilibrium position when faced with
a change in demand can be seen in the or
solution to the set of simultaneous equations
established in 8-11. In terms of matrix g' = (I - A)-1* h' (8-16)
algebra, this system may be rewritten as:

© 1999 RRI, WVU 67 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Table 8.5 Total requirements (direct, indirect, and induced), Nova Scotia,
1984

Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- House-


tion turing struc- tribu- vice hold
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. exp.
1 Extraction 1.052 0.081 0.010 0.005 0.021 0 . 0 0 6
2 Manufacturing 0.081 0.061 0.110 0.030 0.055 0 . 0 7 0
3 Construction 0.006 0.005 0.001 0.004 0.031 0 . 0 0 0
4 Distribution 0.023 0.016 0.056 0.016 0.028 0 . 1 1 9
5 Service 0.117 0.115 0.084 0.203 0.203 0 . 3 0 0
6 Household receipts 0.324 0.191 0.275 0.478 0.389 0 . 0 2 9

Table 8.6 Industry-output multipliers, Nova Scotia, 1984

Extrac- Manufac- Con- Dis- Ser- House-


tion turing struc- tribu- vice hold
Commodity ind. ind. tion tion ind. exp.
1 Extraction 1.052 0.081 0.010 0.005 0.021 0.006
2 Manufacturing 0.081 0.061 0.110 0.030 0.055 0.070
3 Construction 0.006 0.005 0.001 0.004 0.031 0.000
4 Distribution 0.023 0.016 0.056 0.016 0.028 0.119
5 Service 0.117 0.115 0.084 0.203 0.203 0.300
Total industry outputs 1.279 0.278 0.260 0.257 0.338 0.494
1 2 Household receipts 0.324 0.191 0.275 0.478 0.389 0.029
13 Total "activity" 1.603 0.470 0.535 0.735 0.726 0.524

The inverse, (I - A)-1, is called a "total-


requirements table" and shows the direct and Economic change in commodity-by-
indirect effects of a change in final demand. industry models
Table 8.5 reports such a table for the As discussed in chapter 5, economic
aggregated system closed with respect to change can take two forms in input-output
households . Table 8.6 converts these analysis: structural change or change in final
numbers to “multipliers,” properly demand. Changes in final demand are traced
recognizing the status of households as as discussed. Structural change can be
recipient of flows of final incomes. treated in a slightly different manner now.
Now, we are at the same stage as The following comments amend slightly the
completed in chapter 5, and can revert to its points made in chapter 5.
descriptive elements. Only a few comments Structural change normally manifests itself
remain on economic change in the new in changes in provincial production
system. coefficients (direct requirements) but there are
a number of ways in which it can occur. Let

© 1999 RRI, WVU 68 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

us look at these in terms of the coefficients in Fourth, new plants in existing industries
the model. may enter the provincial economy. A new
plant would have the effect of altering
First, a change in technology could occur. production coefficients and import patterns in
This would affect the relations underlying the its industry to the extent that its technology
use matrix contained in the commodity flows and market areas differ from that of
table; that is, it would change the relevant established producers. The significance of
technical production relations of the system. the alteration would depend on the size of the
Such a change could involve a shift from oil new plant relative to the rest of the industry.
to coal for industrial fuel needs or a shift But only in exceptional cases should the
from glass bottles to cans in the beverage impact of the structural change be more
industry. This is admittedly a restrictive important than the impact of its sales pattern.
interpretation of technological change in that
it only involves changes in current flows. Fifth, a completely new industry might
Changes in capital intensity, or technological appear in the province. This should normally
changes which essentially affect the man- be considered part of the new-plant alternative
machine relationship, are more difficult to discussed above.
trace through an input-output system. The In summary, structural change in input-
initial impact of new construction or output models is primarily a matter of
equipment expenditures may be traced as a changes in technical production coefficients,
change in final demand. And, if the increase in domestic market-share coefficients, or in
in output associated with a change in capacity import coefficients.
is sold to a final-demand sector, especially as
exports, its total effect may be traced through
the system. But many of the effects of capital
accumulation on economic activity are Study questions
transmitted through other means.
Technological changes in the broad sense are 1. Contrast the commodity-by-industry input-output
related to the dynamic questions of economic model with the industry-by-industry input-output
growth. The empirical resolution of these model.
questions involves far more than a static 2. In Illustration 8-1, provide the details in the
input-output model, and, in fact, far more than “manipulation to solution” from
any dynamic economic model in current.use. g = D(Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e) ) to
Second, a change in import patterns, or a g = (I - D(I - µ
^ )B)-1D((I - µ
^ )e + x).
change in mij, might occur. The discovery of
domestic oil or the entry of a major producer
of plastic containers might substantially
reduce imports of these commodities and thus
increase the provincial flows. A program of
import substitution might increase provincial
flows, delaying the inevitable leakage of
money flows from the economy and
increasing the multiplier effect of export
activity.
Third, alterations in the product mix of
local producers may change domestic market
shares in commodity outputs. These
coefficients determine the commodity content
of industry sales in the provincial
interindustry matrix and thus represent one
final, probably minor, cause of changes
expressed in terms of the existing plant
structure.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 69 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Illustration 8.1 The simple commodity-by-industry input-output model for a


region
Symbol definitions Definitions or identities:
^ on a vector produces a diagonal matrix with Industry outputs = Sum of commodities produced
values from the vector on the diagonal and
zeroes elsewhere. g = Vi (1)

e is a vector of the sum of domestic final Commodity supply = Commodity output +


demands for commodities. imports

g is a vector of the values of industry outputs. qs = q + m (2)

i is a unit (summation) vector containing all Commodity demand = Sum of intermediate


ones (Premultiplication by i sums columns; demands, final demands and exports
postmultiplication sums rows). qd = Ui + e + x (3)
i as a subscript counts producing industries. Behavioral or technical assumptions:
k as a subscript counts commodities. Constant production coefficients
j as a subscript counts buying industries.
B = Ug^ -1 or Ui = Bg (4)
q is a vector of the values of locally produced
(elements of commodity-by-industry B are
commodity outputs.
bij = uij/gj, so uij = bijgj )
x is a vector of commodity exports.
Constant market-share coefficients
m is a vector of commodity imports.
D = Vq^ -1 or g = Dq (5)
y is a vector of household incomes from
industries (elements of industry-by-commodity D are
dji = vji/qi , so vji = dijqi
B is a commodity-by-industry matrix showing
for each industry the commodity use per dollar Constant import coefficients
of industry output. It is the production-
coefficients matrix. µ^ = m(Ui + e)-1 or m = µ^ (Bg + e) (6)
D is an industry-by-commodity matrix showing (elements of commodity-by-commodity
for each commodity the proportion of the diagonal matrix of import coefficients are
total output of that commodity produced in mk/(Σjukj + ek) )
each industry. It is the market-share matrix.
Equilibrium condition:
I is the identity matrix (î)
Commodity supply = Commodity demand
U is a commodity-by-industry matrix showing
qs = qd, or
for each industry the amount of each
commodity used. q + m = Ui + e + x (7)
V is an industry-by-commodity matrix showing
for each commodity the amount produced by
each industry.

µ^ is a diagonal matrix of commodity imports


expressed as proportions of local industry and
final demands. It is the import-coefficients
matrix.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 70 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

Illustration 8.1 The simple commodity-by-industry input-output model for a


region (continued)
Solution by substitution: expressed (through premultiplication by D) in
industry terms.
Problem: given final demands (e' and x'),
reduce the number of unknowns to equal the
number of equations.
Output multipliers:
Substitute production (4) and import
δgi/δxj = rij , where rij is an element of
coefficients (6) into the equilibrium condition (7)
expressed in terms of q: R=(I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1.

q = Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e)
Multiply by D to eliminate q and express in Each of these partial output multipliers
terms of g (industry outputs) using equation (5): shows the change in local output i associated
with a change in exports by industry j.
Dq = D(Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e) ) Their sum over i is the total output
multiplier for industry j.
g = D(Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e) )
Income multipliers:
Expand, regroup, and manipulate to solution
in terms of g: δyi/δxj = rij*yi/gi), where yi is household
income earned in industry i.
g = DBg + D(e + x) - Dµ^ (Bg + e) )
Each of these partial income multipliers
g = DBg + De + Dx - Dµ^ Bg - Dµ^ e shows the change in household income in
industry i caused by a change in exports by
g = DBg - Dµ^ Bg +De - Dµ^ e + Dx industry j. Their sum over i is the total
income multiplier for industry j.
g = D(I - µ^ )Bg + D((I - µ^ )e + x)
Sources:
g - D(I - µ^ )Bg = D((I - µ
^ )e + x)
This summary is a variation on the U.S. model
(described in the following appendix) to include
(I - D(I - µ^ )B)g = D((I - µ
^ )e + x)
imports and to yield an industry-by-industry model.
(I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1(I - D(I - µ
^ )B)g = It also includes elements of the description of the
Canadian system from several sources such as
(I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1D((I - µ
^ )e + x) (Statistics Canada 1976). Both sources follow the
standard United Nations format and symbols.
g = (I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1D((I - µ
^ )e + x)

Note in coordination with text:


B is total production coefficients, or
proportional purchases without regard to location
of production, expressed in commodity-by-
industry terms.

(I - µ^ )B is regional production coefficients, or


proportional purchases of locally produced
outputs, expressed in commodity-by-industry
terms.

D(I - µ^ )B is regional production coefficients


expressed in industry-by-industry terms.

(I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1 is the inverse, the solution,


or the total requirements matrix equivalent to that
in the simple solution presented earlier.

D((I - µ
^ )e + x) is a vector of final demands
for locally produced commodities and exports

© 1999 RRI, WVU 71 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

h is a column vector in which each entry shows


Appendix 1 The mathematics of the total amount of each industry's production
the United States input-output of scrap. The estimate of h is contained in
column 81 of the make table. Scrap is
model separated to prevent its use as an input from
The following mathematics is taken from generating output in the industries in which it
the documentation of the 1987 U.S. originates.
Interindustry Study. It follows the standard
United Nations commodity-by-industry B is a commodity-by-industry matrix in which
entries in each column show the amount of a
system symbolically and logically.1 commodity used by an industry per dollar of
September 1, 1993 output of that industry. Matrix B is derived
from matrix U.
MATHEMATICAL DERIVATION OF
THE TOTAL REQUIREMENTS TABLES D is an industry-by-commodity matrix in which
entries in each column show, for a given
FOR THE INPUT-OUTPUT STUDY 1
commodity (excluding scrap), the proportion
of the total output of that commodity
produced in each industry. D is referred to as
The following are definitions: the market share matrix.
q is a column vector in which each entry shows p is a column vector in which each entry shows
the total amount of the output of each the ratio of the value of scrap produced in each
commodity. industry to the industry's total output.
U is a commodity-by-industry matrix in which W is an industry-by-commodity matrix in which
the column shows for a given industry the the entries in each column show, for a given
amount of each commodity it uses, including commodity, the proportion of the total output
Noncomparable imports (I-0 80) and Scrap, of that commodity produced in each industry
used and secondhand goods (I-0 81). I-0 81 is adjusted for scrap produced by the industry.
designated below as scrap. This matrix is the transformation matrix.
^ is a symbol that, when placed over a vector, The following are identities:
indicates a square matrix in which the
elements of the vector appear on the main q = Ui + e (1)
diagonal and zeros elsewhere.
g = Vi + h (2)
i is a unit (summation) vector containing only
l's; ^i is the identity matrix (I).
The following are assumptions:
e is a column vector in which each entry shows
the total final demand purchases for each Inputs are required in proportion to output and
commodity from the use table (table 2). the proportions are the same for an industry's
primary and secondary products (the industry
g is a column vector in which each entry shows technology assumption); then:
the total amount of each industry's output,
including its production of scrap.
U = Bg^ (3)
V is an industry-by-commodity matrix in which
the column shows for a given commodity the Each commodity (other than scrap) is produced
amount produced in each industry. V has by the various industries in fixed proportions (the
columns showing only zero entries for market shares assumption); then:
noncomparable imports and for scrap. The
estimate of V is contained in columns 1 - 79 V = Dq^ (4)
of the make table (table 1) plus columns of
zeros for columns 80 and 81. Scrap output in each industry is proportional to
total output of the industry; then:

© 1999 RRI, WVU 72 Draft July 28, 1999


Commodity-by Industry Economic Models Chapter 8

h = p^ g (5) also, Stone, R., Bacharach, M. and Bates, J., "Input-


Output Relationships, 1951-1966," Programme for
The model expressed in equations (1) through (5) Growth, Volume 3, London, Chapman and Hall,
thus involves three constants (B, D, p) and six 1963.
variables (U, V, h, e, q, g). The model solution is 2
derived as follows: Tables are prepared at the detailed and summary
levels of aggregation. For the summary tables, the
Substituting (3) into (1) gives: adjustments for secondary production were made at the
detailed level, then aggregated before calculation of
the total requirements tables.
q = Bg + e (6)

Substituting (4) into (2) gives:

g - h = Dq (7)

Substituting (5) into (7) and solving for g:

g - p^ g = Dq

(I - p)g = Dq

g = (I - p^ )-1Dq (8)

Let (I - p^ )-1D = W, then (8) becomes

g = Wq (9)

Substituting (9) into (6) and solving for q:

q = BWq + e

(I - BW)q = e

q = (I - BW)-1e (10)

Substituting (10) into (9) gives:

g = W(I - BW)-1e

(I - BW)-1 is the commodity-by-commodity total


requirements matrix, giving commodity output
required per dollar of each commodity delivered
to final users. 2
W(I - BW)-1 is the industry-by-commodity total
requirements matrix, giving the industry output
required per dollar of each commodity delivered
to final users.2

1
The notation and derivation of the tables presented
follow the System of National Accounts
recommended by the United Nations. See: A System
of National Accounts Studies in Methods, Series F
No. 2 Rev. 3, United Nations, New York, 1968;

© 1999 RRI, WVU 73 Draft July 28, 1999


9 BUILDING INTERINDUSTRY MODELS
Regional input-output models are, with few sectors. This is for simplicity, since we
exceptions, now produced with computer normally have more final-demand sectors
estimating techniques commonly called than final-payment sectors.
"nonsurvey" techniques. This phrase refers
to the fact that they are based on the Now assume that we have augmented the
technology embodied in the national input- interindustry portion of the system by treating
output-table and that imports are estimated the household sector as an industry, as in
based on some supplementary technique not Chapter 4. The aij matrix, written as A, is
involving extensive survey work. This called the regional interindustry coefficients
chapter briefly explains the most common of matrix and is a critical part of the system
these approaches. In this introductory since its constancy is a major technical
treatment, we specifically exclude assumption in input-output analysis. As is
mathematical procedures (such as the RAS clear from Chapter 4, the solution to the
balancing method) and we leave the equation system (10-1) may be written in
operations embodied in various commercially matrix form as
available packages to their literature.
(I - A)-1*(Y + E) = X (10-3)
The basic model We will use this form of the system to
avoid repetitive algebra in the discussion of
Let us start by restating the basic structure estimating techniques.
of the system.The equation system for a
regional input-output model may be written as The regional coefficients matrix, A, may be
regarded as the difference between a
n t

∑ aij q j + ∑ yif + ei = xi
technology matrix, P, and an imports matrix,
(i=1...n) (10-1) M:
j =1 f =1
A=P-M (10-4)
The aij represent purchases from regional
industry i by industry j (or xij) as a The technology matrix records purchases
proportion of the output of industry j (or xj), from industry i (regardless of location) by
industry j as a proportion of the output of
yif is the local final demand for the products industry j (pij). The imports matrix contains
of industry i by final-demand sector f, and ei the mij elements in equation (10-2). The
is the exports by industry i. The equation major problem confronting the regional
system might be illustrated with an algebraic analyst in constructing a transactions table is
table similar to that in Figure 5.1. obtaining the P matrix and dividing it into its
The system can also be outlined in terms component parts, A and M. We now turn to
of supply, describing the production this division problem.
technology of a region:
n t n Estimating techniques
∑ aij q j + ∑ v fj + ∑ mij q j =qj (j=1...n) (10-2)
i =1 f =1 i =1
Given the system described above, the
regional analyst has several procedures
Here vfj is the value added by final- available to him in constructing his empirical
payments sector f to the product of industry i, model. The choice between these techniques
and mij is the imports of the products of depends largely upon the resources available.
industry i by industry expressed as a This section briefly outlines these procedures
proportion of the output of industry j. (Note and describes the means by which an
that we have included t local final-payment inexpensive nonsurvey procedure may be
sectors to match the t local final-demand evolved into a survey-based technique to fit

© 1999 RRI, WVU 74 Draft July 28, 1999


Building Input-Output Models Chapter 9

whatever budget is available.(Schaffer 1972; same firms are especially concerned with where and
Schaffer and Chu 1969) to whom they sell their output. (Hansen and
Tiebout 1963)
Survey-only techniques This approach permits the analyst to avoid
Properly, an input-output model is based a complex data reconciliation. It produces
on a full survey of industries and final only one entry per cell in the transactions
consumers which documents both sales and table; the full-survey method forces the
purchases. Each respondent is asked to analyst to check his work by producing two
designate sales to regional industries (xij) and estimates of cell values.
to final users inside (yif) and outside (ei) the A second alternative to the full-survey
region. The respondents are also asked to approach is what is called the "columns-only"
designate their purchases from regional method. This approach assumes that
industries (aijqj), their purchases from business firms know their sources of supply
industries outside the region (mijxj), and their better than they do their customers.
final payments (vfj ) to primary resource Harmston and Lund argue that this approach
takes advantage of the detailed knowledge of
owners in the form of wages and salaries, expenditures required by businessmen for
profits, depreciation allowances, taxes, etc. control and tax purposes (Harmston and
These purchases and final payments outline Lund 1967). Producing data in the same
the production technology of each industry in simple form as that of the rows-only method,
a usable format, already separated into a the columns-only approach seems well-suited
regional flows matrix and an imports matrix. for use in small regions characterized by a
In acquiring data on both purchases and relatively large number of locally-owned
sales, the analyst has assembled the firms.
information required to produce a potentially
reliable table. But the table is also very The supply-demand pool procedure
expensive and its construction is very time- A nonsurvey technique commonly used in
consuming. Notice what happens if you don't the United States, the supply-demand pool
have a complete census of firms and perfect technique relies on the national input-output
reporting in each case. In this perfect case, the table as a reasonable estimate of the
row estimates of xij will be identical to the production-technology matrix, or P matrix, of
column estimates. Now notice what happens a region and proceeds to estimate regional
if you have sampled only a few firms: the row flows and imports using the concept of
estimates and the column estimates now vary regional commodity balances (Isard 1953).
widely. Sampling problems and reporting This method is sometimes called the Moore-
errors are substantial and the analyst is forced Petersen technique since it was first applied to
to achieve balance by tediously assaying the a study of Utah by Moore and Petersen
reliability of responses and by juggling (Moore and Petersen 1955). (The term
numbers until totals finally match. “supply-demand pool” actually originated in
A basic alternative to this full-survey discussions with a programmer in 1968 as we
approach is the "rows-only" method. First were developing tests of nonsurvey
used by Hansen and Tiebout, this method procedures (Schaffer and Chu 1969)).
assumes The only additional data assumed to be
... that firms know the destination of their outputs available are gross outputs for the n regional
far better than the origin of their inputs, especially industries, qj, and the gross purchases of t
where regional breakdowns are required. In other final-demand sectors. Now, to avoid more
words, in terms of input-output flows, information complex addition, let us assume that the P
for the "rows" is easier to obtain than information matrix includes both industries and final
for the "columns.” The reason for this is that the demand sectors, so A is of dimension
bundle of inputs is usually so varied and complex
that their origins are difficult even for firms
n*(n+t). Value added is three rows in the
involved to track down accurately. However, the national table and has been excluded from P.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 75 Draft July 28, 1999


Building Input-Output Models Chapter 9

Let di be the row sum of total demands for This approach requires that we simply
the products of industry i, computed from A canvass firms in the region, asking for three
as follows: bits of information: their industry
classification, value of sales for the year, and
n+t the proportion of their sales going to out-of-
di = ∑pijxj (10-5) region purchasers. The first two answers
permit the analyst to classify replies and to
j=1 properly weight export proportions in
Here, of course, the pij have been constructing the transactions table.
computed from the national input-output table The procedure, then, involves setting
and we have simply reduced national flows to exports of each industry i at the survey-
regional size. estimated value and simulating the remainder
A commodity-balance ratio comparing of the table. For the balance ratio used above,
regional production or supply (qi) with we simply substitute a ratio which excludes
exports from the supply available for local
regional demand can be computed as use:

bi = qi/di (10-6) e qi - ei
bi = (10-7)
and the P matrix can be divided into its A and di
M components through a simple set of rules.
If bi is greater than or equal to one, then all This approach satisfies export
inputs can be supplied by local producers and requirements first and then allocates the
we can set aij = pij, mij = 0, and ei = qi - di. remainder of local production to satisfying
local needs in proportion to requirements. If
If bi is less than one, inputs must be imported, e
so aij=bipij, mij = pij-aij and ei=0. bi is greater than one, the technology matrix
This pool procedure allocates local may have to be adjusted, but this proves to be
production, when adequate, to meet local a minor problem.
needs; when the local output is inadequate, it Two observations are appropriate. One is
allocates to each purchasing industry i a share that a procedure developed by the late Ben
of regional output qi based on the needs of Stevens, the Regional Purchase Coefficients
the purchasing industry itself (pijqj) relative (RPC) procedure, is an attempt to estimate
to total needs for output i (di). these balance ratios from a combination of
Census of Transportation data, other product
Export-survey method characteristics, and econometric equations.
RPC’s are in common use now.
One of the major characteristics of a
regional input-output model is its openness. The other observation regards the term
Exports and imports are substantial, if not “minor problem” in the previous paragraph.
dominant, parts of the typical regional Actually, that is an understatement. In the
transactions table. Since simulated exports Nova Scotia Study described in Chapters 7
are so greatly at variance with the survey- and 8, columns for imports and exports
based exports in the above comparison, it appear in the commodity origins table and
seems reasonable to believe that correction of accumulate the data required for estimating
this discrepancy could lead to a much better regional trade coefficients. This is great
estimate of regional transactions. conceptually, but recall that rows in the
origins table represent actual supply and
If we can afford neither of the more demand equations for each of 600
powerful alternatives to a full survey as commodities and all degrees of freedom are
discussed above, then an export survey gone – there is no room for error. Even
combined with a supply-demand pool though we had, in many cases, census data,
procedure may be an adequate substitute. none of the equations balanced and we had to

© 1999 RRI, WVU 76 Draft July 28, 1999


Building Input-Output Models Chapter 9

insert columns for estimated imports and IO7


exports for each commodity. The greater part
of a year was spent unraveling these estimates Guy West of the University of Queensland
(DPA Group Inc. and Schaffer 1989) provides software and data for construction
and analysis. Called IO7, it is available
Selected-values method through Randall Jackson at Ohio State
University (jackson.21@osu.edu). A
Now, if more trade information than just teaching version is available at no charge via
export estimates can be assembled, the anonymous ftp at:
method can be extended to permit a setting of
selected values in the transactions table. We ftp://lubra.sbs.ohio-state.edu/pub/io7
simply set observed values xig, xih, ..., xik and or
estimate the remaining regional flows using
an adjusted balance ratio: ftp://outback.sbs.ohio-state.edu/pub/io7
s qi − ei − xig − xih − ... − xik
bi = (10-8)
di − xig − xih − ... − xik IOPC
IOPC is a product of the Regional Science
Commodity-by-industry procedures Research Instutute and the late Benjamin H.
Stevens. It is software for manipulating
The above notes are sufficient to show the models produced by RSRI and is temporarily
general problem associated with constructing unavailable.
regional models from published data, that of
estimating imports and exports. It is beyond Others
the scope of this exposition to explore the
details of constructing modern input-output Data, software, and related reports will
models. To understand the process requires a soon be available at my web site:
thorough knowledge based on a standard http://www.econ.gatech.edu/faculty/schaffer/
reference such as Miller and Blair [, 1985
#190], on the current U.S. interindustry
tables, and on a recent exposition of problems
associated with regionalization [for example
,Jackson, 1998 #197]
Study questions
Several sources of assistance are available.
1. What is the major problem in constructing a
RIMS regional input-output table? Outline several
means by which it may be solved.
The Regional Economic Analysis Division 2. Discuss the statistical reliability of a regional
of the Bureau of Economic Analysis input-output coefficient estimated with a full
produces models of states, counties, and survey.
multi-county areas on request. These models 3. What are the major drawbacks to the nonsurvey
are available in detailed or aggregated format. techniques for estimating regional interindustry
Information can be obtained at their web site: transactions? How may their effects be
http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/regional/rims/ minimized?
4. Sketch the algebraic transactions table for
IMPLAN equations 1 and 2.
The Minnesota Implan Group, Inc.
provides a wide variety of services in impact
analysis, including software and data. Full
details are available at:
http://www.implan.com/index2.htm

© 1999 RRI, WVU 77 Draft July 28, 1999


ANSWERS TO SELECTED QUESTIONS
or
4-10
10. Given the interindustry transactions matrix (X)
and the gross outputs vector (z), calculate values
for the final-demand (y), final-payments (v), and
 a11 a12   x11 x12  1 / q1 0 
input (q) vectors. A= =
a 21 a 22   x 21 x 22   0 1 / q2 
400 180  1000 
X= , z= 
250 120   600  Calculate the numeric values for this A matrix and for
(I-A):
Answer: .500 .438
A= ,
420  .320 .450 
y= , v = [310 300] , −.438
230   .5
( I − A) =  
q = [1000 600] −.320 .550 
d. Using your hand-held calculator or a spreadsheet,
4-11 what is the inverse of this Leontief matrix?
4.074 3.241
5-6 R= 
EMULTj = e ^q -1(I - A) -1 2.370 3.704 
e. With this A matrix and the following new final-
demand vector (now y), calculate the first 3
rounds of spending which would occur in seeking
5-Exercise the new outputs which would satisfy the new
final-demand.
Consider the following interindustry transactions
matrix (X) and total outputs vector (z) for a two-
.500 .438 , 200 
sector economy. A=  fd = y =  
500 350  , 1000  .320 .450  100 
X=  z =  800 
320 360   
What is the equation for this 'rounds of spending'
a. What are the two elements in the final demand (fd) solution to the model?
vector?
It is the matrix equation for the sum of an
150  infinite series:
fd =  
120  T = A0y + A1y + A2y + A3y + ... + Any,
b. What are the two elements in the total inputs Where y is the vector to be traced and A0
vector (q) and in the final-payments (fp) vector? turns out to be the identity matrix.
1000  180  Round 0:
q=  fp =  90 
 800  ,   1 0  200  200 
Iy =   = 
What does the complete transactions table look like 0 1  100  100 
now? Round 1:
c. What is the algebraic representation of the A
.500 .438 200  144 
matrix, where aij = xij/qj? Ay =   = 
A = Xqˆ −1 .320 .450  100  109
© 1999 RRI, WVU 78 Draft July 28, 1999
Answers to Selected Questions

Round 2:

.500 .438 144  120 


AAy = A 2 y =    =  
.320 .450  109  95 
f. How would the solution using the inverse compare
with that using rounds of spending as above?
It would be identical. In this case, however, with
such high coefficients, convergence would take
over 20 rounds.

8-3
3. In Illustration 8-1, provide the details in the
“manipulation to solution” from
g = D(Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e) ) to g = (I - D(I -
µ )B)-1D((I - µ
^ ^ )e + x):

g = D(Bg + e + x - µ^ (Bg + e) )
Expand, regroup, and manipulate to
solution in terms of g:

g = DBg + D(e + x) - Dµ^ (Bg + e) )

g = DBg + De + Dx - Dµ^ Bg - Dµ^


e

g = DBg - Dµ^ Bg +De - Dµ^ e + Dx

g = D(I - µ^ )Bg + D((I - µ^ )e + x)

g - D(I - µ^ )Bg = D((I - µ


^ )e + x)

(I - D(I - µ^ )B)g = D((I - µ


^ )e + x)

(I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1(I - D(I - µ


^ )B)g =
(I - D(I - µ )B) D((I - µ
^ -1 ^ )e
+ x)

g = (I - D(I - µ^ )B)-1D((I - µ
^ )e + x)

© 1999 RRI, WVU 79 Draft July 28, 1999


REFERENCES
Artle, R. (1965). The Structure of the growth paths for Hawaii.” Studies in applied
Stockholm Economy (American Edition), regional science, Martinus Nijhoff Social
Cornell University Press, Ithaca. Sciences Division, Leiden.
Barnard, J. R. (1967). Design and Use of Harmston, F. K. (1962). A Study of the
Social Accounting Systems in State Resources, People, and Economy of Carbon
Development Planning, The University of County, Wyoming, 1962, Wyoming Natural
Iowa, Bureau of Business and Economic Resource Board, Cheyenne.
Research, Iowa City. Hildebrand, G. H., and Mace, A., Jr. (1950).
Bourque, P. J., and Conway, R. S., Jr. (1977). “The Employment Multiplier in an
The 1972 Washington Input-Output Study, Expanding Industrial Market: Los Angeles
University of Washington, Graduate School County, 1940-47.” Review of Economics and
of Business Administration, Seattle. Statistics, XXXII, 241-249.
Bourque, P. J., and others. (1967). The Hirsch, W. Z. (1959). “Interindustry
Washington Economy and Input-Output Relations of a Metropolitan Area.” Review of
Study, University of Washington, Graduate Economics and Statistics, 41, 360-369.
School of Business Administration, Seattle. Isard, W., Choguill, C. L., Kissin, J., Seyfarth,
Bowers, D. A., and Baird, R. N. (1971). R. H., and Tatlock, R. (1972). Ecologic-
Elementary Mathematical Macroeconomics, Economic Analysis for Regional
Printice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs. Development, The Free Press, New York.
Brucker, S. M., and Hastings, S. E. (1984). Isard, W. e. a. (1960). Methods of Regional
An Interindustry Analysis of Delaware's Analysis: an Introduction to Regional
Economy, University of Delaware, Science, The M.I.T. Press, Cambridge,
Agricultural Experiment Station, Bulletin 452, Massachusetts.
Newark. Jordan, P. G., and Polenske, K. R. (1988).
Carden, J. G. D., and Whittington, F. G. J. “Multiplier Impacts of Fishing Activities in
(1964). Studies in the Economic Structure of New England Nova Scotia.” Input-Output
the State of Mississippi, Mississippi Analysis: Current Developments, M.
Industrial and Technological Research Ciaschini, ed., Chapman Hall, London, 326-
Commission, Jackson. 366.
Case, K. E., and Fair, R. C. (1994). Principles Kahn, R. F. (1931). “The Relation of Home
of Economics, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Investment to Unemployment.” Economic
Cliffs. Journal, XLI, 173-198.
Chenery, H. B., and Clark, P. G. (1959). Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of
Interindustry Economics, John Wiley and Employment, Interest, Money, MacMillan,
Sons, New York. London.
DPA Group Inc., and Schaffer, W. (1989). Kogiku, K. C. (1968). An Introduction to
The Nova Scotia Input-Output System, 1984, Macroeconomic Models, McGraw-Hill Book
The DPA Group, Inc., Halifax. Company, New York.
Gamble, H. B., and Raphael, D. L. (1966). A Krikelas, A. C. (1992). “Why Regions
Microregional Analysis of Clinton County, Grow: A Review of Research On the
Pennsylvania, Volume II, The Pennsylvania Economic Base Model.” Economic Review of
State University, University Park. the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 16-29.
Ghali, M. (1977). “Tourism and regional
growth: An empirical study of the alternative
© 1999 RRI, WVU 80 Draft July 28, 1999
References

Lane, T. (1966). “The Urban Base Oser, J. (1963). The Evolution of Economic
Multiplier: An Evaluation of the State of the Thought, Harcourt, Brace and World, Inc.,
Art.” Land Economics, 42, 339-347. New York.
Leontief, W. (1953). “Interregional Theory.” Polenske, K. R. (1980). The U. S.
Studies in the Structure of the American Multiregional Input-Output Accounts and
Economy, W. L. a. others, ed., New York. Model, D.C. Heath and Company, Lexington,
Massachusetts.
Levitt, K. (1975a). Input-Output Study of the
Atlantic Provinces, 1965. Vol. I: Structural Pratt, R. T. (1968). “An Appraisal of the
Analysis Data Sources, Statistics Canada, Minimum Requirements Technique.”
Input-Output Division, Ottawa. Economic Geography, XLIV, 117-124.
Levitt, K. (1975b). Input-Output Study of the Richardson, H. W. (1969). Regional
Atlantic Provinces, 1965. Vol. I: Social Economics, Praeger Publishers, Inc., New
Accounting Matrix Models, Statistics Canada, York.
Input-Output Division, Ottawa.
Richardson, H. W. (1972). Input-Output
Metzler, L. A. (1950). “A Multiple-Region and Regional Economics, Weidenfeld and
Theory of Income and trade.” Econometrica, Nicolson.
18, 329-354.
Schaffer, W. A. (1976). On the use of input-
Miernyk, W. H. (1965). The Elements of output models for regional planning,
Input-Output Analysis, Random House, New Martinus Nijhoff, Leiden.
York.
Schaffer, W. A., and Chu, K. (1969).
Miernyk, W. H., Bonner, E. R., Chapman, J. “Nonsurvey Techniques for Constructing
H., Jr., and Shellhammer, K. (1967). Impact Regional Interindustry Models.” Regional
of the Space Program on a Local Economy, Science Association Papers, 23, 83-101.
West Virginia University Library,
Morgantown. Schaffer, W. A., Joun, R. Y., and others.
(1972). Interindustry Study of the Hawaiian
Miller, R. E., and Blair, P. D. (1985). Input- Economy, Department of Planning and
Output Analysis: Foundations and Economic Development, State of Hawaii,
Extensions, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Honolulu.
Cliffs, NJ.
Sirkin, G. (1959). “The Theory of the
Minnesota IMPLAN Group Inc. (1997). Regional Economic Base.” Review of
IMPLAN Professional, MIG, Inc., Stillwater, Economics and Statistics, 59, 426-429.
MN.
Smith, P., and Morrison, W. I. (1974).
Miyazawa, K. (1976). Input-Output Analysis Simulating the Urban Economy, Pion
and the Structure of Income Distribution, Limited, London.
Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
Tiebout, C. M. (1962). The Community
Moore, F. T. (1955). “Regional Economic Economic Base Study, Committee for
Reaction Paths.” American Economic Economic Development, New York.
Review, 45, 133-148.
Ullman, E. L., and Dacey, M. F. (1960).
Moore, F. T., and Petersen, J. W. (1955). “The Minimum Requirements Approach to
“Regional Analysis: An Interindustry Model the Urban Economic Base.” Regional
of Utah.” Review of Economics and Science Association Papers, 6, 175-194.
Statistics, 37, 368-383.
Weiss, S. J., and Gooding, E. C. (1968).
Neal, F., and Shone, R. (1976). Economic “Estimation of Differential Employment
Model Building, Macmillan Press Ltd, Multipliers in a Small Regional Economy.”
London. Land Economics, XLIV, 235-244.

© 1999 RRI, WVU 81 Draft July 28, 1999

You might also like