You are on page 1of 4

University of Puget Sound

Sound Ideas
All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship

12-1-1985

Review of: The Second Industrial Divide:


Possibilities for Prosperity by Michael J. Piore and
Charles F. Sabel
Leon Grunberg
University of Puget Sound, grunberg@pugetsound.edu

Follow this and additional works at: http://soundideas.pugetsound.edu/faculty_pubs

Citation
Grunberg, Leon. "Book Review: the Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity." The American Political Science Review.
79.4 (1985): 1220-1221. Print.

This Review is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Sound Ideas. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty
Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Sound Ideas. For more information, please contact soundideas@pugetsound.edu.
The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity by Michael J. Piore; Charles F. Sabel
Review by: Leon Grunberg
The American Political Science Review, Vol. 79, No. 4 (Dec., 1985), pp. 1220-1221
Published by: American Political Science Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1956301 .
Accessed: 06/10/2014 17:33

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The American Political Science Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 207.207.127.233 on Mon, 6 Oct 2014 17:33:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1220 The American Political Science Review Vol. 79
ment, the structure and orientation of the two sometimesas resultof politicalstruggles.For ex-
Korean political systems show a remarkable ample, they claimthat the assemblyline, the legal
degree of similarity that has been shaped by frameworkof the New Deal years,and the rise of
military competition, their peripheral position in mass industrialunions, were a product of some
the world economy, a common political culture, combinationof experimentation,expediency,or
and popular demands for stability, moderniza- fairlyrandomevents(likethe GreatDepressionor
tion, and democracy. WorldWarII) and not of any logic of capitalism.
Although the chapters are of uneven quality, Much of the supportfor this view comes from a
Kihl's Politics and Policy in Divided Korea is an revisionist reconstruction of U.S. economic
evenhanded, thorough, and sophisticated com- historyand from a comparisonof the experiences
parison of the political systems of North and of France, Italy, West Germany, and Japan. I
South Korea. The book will be useful to anyone found the historical reconstructiontoo meager
interested in Korean politics and American policy and too conjecturalto be convincing.However,
towards Korea, as well as to those concerned with the comparisonsclearly indicate that the same
divided nations and political change in the Third mass productiontechnology can operate within
World. different labor-control systems. Even here,
however,Piore and Sabel are forced to concede
JOHN MERRILL
that thereare greatsimilaritiesbetweenadvanced
Lafayette College capitalistcountries,and one mighthave expected
this acknowledgmentto temper their absolute
dismissalof deterministicmodelsof development.
The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for In the substanceof theirargumentsthe authors
Prosperity.By MichaelJ. Piore and CharlesF. relegatethe ideas of Adam Smith and KarlMarx
Sabel. (New York: Basic Books, 1984. Pp. to the sidelines.It is the neglectedPierre-Joseph
335. $21.95.) Proudhon who is resurrectedand given center
stage. Indeed, in their advocacy for craft-based
It has by now become a commonplaceamong production("flexiblespecialization"is the phrase
political economiststhat we are living througha they prefer), one finds a repetitionof many of
crisis that marks a transition in the history of Proudhon's arguments.In the world of flexible
capitalism.MichaelJ. Piore and CharlesF. Sabel specializationthey envision,thereis no unbridled
join in the chorus arguingthat we are in such a and cut-throatcost and pricecompetition,for this
transitionperiod, what they call a "second in- wouldstifle innovationand encouragesweatshop
dustrialdivide." However,what is novel in their conditions.Insteadthereis a benignform of com-
workis theirreluctanceto engagein deterministic petitionwherefirmsseek to best each otherin in-
thinking and to predict, as if there were some novationsand yet consent to shareamong them-
necessaryor unilinearunfoldingto socioeconomic selvesskillsand technologicalknowledge.Nor do
development,what the next stage will be like. In- Piore and Sabel have much use for entrenched
stead, they arguethat we face a choice about the classconflictin this best of all possibleworlds,for
directionwe can move in, and that the choiceis in the strugglebetween capital and labor produces
many ways similar to the choice faced by our rigiditiesin productionand divisions within the
ancestors at the beginnings of the industrial community.Insteadthey foreseecooperationand
revolution. The choice is between continuing bargainingbasedon trust, or, as Proudhonput it,
along a courseof developmentfoundedon mass- based on respect.Thus capitalistswould not take
productiontechnologyand its relatedinstitutions advantageof their greaterpotential mobility to
or rechartingour course in the directionof craft extract unfair concessions from labor because
production. Their preferenceis clearly for the communitypressurewould remindcapitalistsof
latter. their responsibilities.
The book makes strange reading to one ac- Piore and Sabel see evidencethat versionsof
customed to the dominantlines of argumentin flexible specializationcan flourishin the new in-
the current discourse in political economy. It tensely competitive conditions of the eighties.
breaksradicallywith both the form and substance Theypoint to the dynamismof the textiledistricts
of prevailinganalyses of the crisis. Piore and in northernand centralItaly, to the successof the
Sabel reject completely systemic models of the mini steel mills in the United States, and to the
economy and their attendant laws or logics of federatedconglomerateenterprisesof Japan. All
development.Rather they opt for a contingent point in the directionof localismand regionalism;
model of historical developmentwherein tech- of federationsof enterpriseslinked together in
nologies, market strategies, and labor control communities of respect, with harmony main-
policies are adopted, sometimes accidentally, tainedwherenecessaryby the centralgovernment.
sometimesdue to the exigenciesof events, and This happy state may or may not follow this

This content downloaded from 207.207.127.233 on Mon, 6 Oct 2014 17:33:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1985 Book Reviews: Comparative and Other Area Studies 1221
period of transition. It all "depends on a thou- federal structure, designed to limit nationalist
sand imponderables of international politics" (p. discontent, itself restrictsthe courses of action
281). that might be taken to amelioratethe sourcesof
Although there is much to admire in this pro- ethnic hostility. Finally, Ramet discovers that
vocative book (here I think especially of the com- interrepublicanalliances are fluid, which con-
parative case studies), the overall argument rests trastswith the conventionalwisdomthat believes
on very fragile supports, and the case made for a wealthierrepublicsnormallyform one bloc and
"republic of small holders" seeks to dissolve, as if their poorerneighborsanother.
by magic, too many concrete contradictions. One Ramet's approach suffers from some of the
is reminded of Marx's assessment of Proudhon: same pitfalls evident in internationalrelations
"he wants to be the synthesis-he is a composite theory:the units of analysisare not unifiedactors
error." but comprise a range of policy demands and
desires.Indeed,a groupof Croatianconservatives
LEON GRUNBERG
opposed the nominalinterestsof theirrepublicin
University of Puget Sound the crisisfrom 1967to 1972.In addition,although
accountsof the crisisin Kosovo and descriptions
of the economicproblemsfacedby Yugoslaviaare
Nationalismand Federalismin Yugoslavia,1963- interestingin themselves, at times Ramet loses
1983. By PedroRamet.(Bloomington:Indiana sightof the connectionbetweenthe detailsand his
University Press, 1984. Pp. xviii + 299. analyticalframework.
$27.50.) As Rametpoints out, controversiesyet exist as
to whetherYugoslaviais essentiallyfederalistor
Theoriesformulatedin one sphereof learning unitarist.The volumeunderreviewweighsheavily
can often be modified to illuminatethe subject in favor of the latter judgment. The book pro-
matter of another. In this stimulatingvolume, vides a wealthof informationon the policy issues
Pedro Ramet uses internationalrelationstheory faced by the Yugoslavs,interethnicrivalries,and
to analyzeethnicproblemsin postwarYugoslavia. a seriesof hypothesesthat attemptto accountfor
Ramet argues that "if the federal units of the problemsthe Yugoslavpolitical system faces
Yugoslaviaenjoyedeven half as much autonomy in trying to come to grips with the complexities
as the system'sapologistsmaintained,the pattern posed by the nationaldivisionsin its society. This
of interactionamong those units would resemble book should be read by all studentsof contem-
the patternof behaviorof other collective units poraryYugoslavia,as well as those interestedin
operating within a regional system," and "it the phenomenaof ethnicityand nationalism.
shouldbe possibleto comparethe behavioralpat- STEPHEN R. BuRANT
terns of Yugoslavfederalunits and states in the
internationalsystem" (p. xi). Consequently,the TheLibraryof Congress
behavior of federal republics and the central
government(yet anotheractor)will be a function
of the distributionof power within this system. World RevolutionaryLeaders.By Mostafa Rejai
Ramet derives a set of hypotheses elaborating and Kay Phillips. (New Brunswick, N.J.:
upon these assumptionswith the use of Morton RutgersUniversityPress, 1983. Pp. x + 237.
Kaplan's typology of systems of international $29.00.)
behavior, specifically the balance of power
system. This volume describesa sampleof 135 revolu-
After descriptionsof Yugoslavia'sfederal in- tionaryleadersof 31 violent politicalrevolutions
stitutional structure, the history of Communist from the English Revolution of the 1640s to
party nationalitiespolicy in Yugoslavia,and the severalrevolutionsin progressin 1978, including
policymakingpowers enjoyed by the republics, revolutionsfrom all world regions. It continues,
Rametundertakesa seriesof case studiesof inter- updates, and expands Rejai's 1979 Leaders of
republicanand interethnic conflict since 1963. Revolution(Sage). To gatherthe necessarydata,
These studies include the economic reform from the authors had to overcome problems of lan-
1963 to 1971, the emergingeruptionof Croatian guage, official and revolutionarysecrecy,and the
nationalistand secessionistsympathiesfrom 1967 determinedmyth-makingof both revolutionaries
to 1972, and outbreaksof Bosnianand Albanian and their opponents.
nationalismin the 1970sand 1980s. Despite the importanceof the topic of study
Not surprisingly,Ramet finds that contraryto and the labor involved, the volume has serious
Yugoslav claims, nationalism remains alive practical,theoretical,and methodologicalflaws,
among the country'sminorities.More interesting and so contributes little to our knowledge of
is analysis that demonstratesthat the Yugoslav revolutionaries. Practically, even taking the

This content downloaded from 207.207.127.233 on Mon, 6 Oct 2014 17:33:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like