You are on page 1of 20

CHAPTER

Economic Optimization
2
Managers make tough choices that involve benefits and costs. Until recently, however, it was
simply impractical to compare the relative pluses and minuses of a large number of managerial
decisions under a wide variety of operating conditions. For many large and small organizations,
economic optimization remained an elusive goal. It is easy to understand why early users of personal
computers were delighted when they learned how easy it was to enter and manipulate operating
information in spreadsheets. Spreadsheets were a pivotal innovation because they put the tools for
insightful demand, cost, and profit analysis at the finger tips of decision makers. Today’s low-cost
but powerful PCs and user-friendly software make it possible to efficiently analyze company-specific
data and broader information from the Internet. It has never been easier or more vital to consider the
implications of managerial decisions under an assortment of operating scenarios.

Effective managers must collect, organize, and process relevant operating information. However,
efficient information processing requires more than electronic computing capability; it requires a
fundamental understanding of basic economic relations. Within such a framework, powerful PCs
and a wealth of operating and market information become an awesome aid to effective managerial
decision making.

This chapter introduces fundamental principles of economic analysis. These ideas form the basis
for describing all demand, cost, and profit relations. Once basic economic relations are understood,
optimization techniques can be applied to find the best course of action.1

ECONOMIC OPTIMIZATION PROCESS


Effective managerial decision making is the process of arriving at the best solution to a
problem.1

Optimal Decisions
Should the quality of inputs be enhanced to better meet low-cost import competition?
Is a necessary reduction in labor costs efficiently achieved through an across-the-board
decrease in staffing, or is it better to make targeted cutbacks? Following an increase in

1 See Dianah Wisenberg Brin, “UnitedHealth Net Rises on Efficiency,” The Wall Street Journal Online,
October 18, 2007, http://online.wsj.com.

23
24 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

product demand, is it preferable to increase managerial staff, line personnel, or both?


These are the types of questions facing managers on a regular basis that require a careful
consideration of basic economic relations. Answers to these questions depend on the
objectives and preferences of management. Just as there is no single “best” purchase
decision for all customers at all times, there is no single “best” investment decision for all
managers at all times. When alternative courses of action are available, the decision that
Optimal Decision produces a result most consistent with managerial objectives is the optimal decision.
Choice alternative A challenge that must be met in the decision-making process is characterizing the
that produces
a result most desirability of decision alternatives in terms of the objectives of the organization. Decision
consistent with makers must recognize all available choices and portray them in terms of appropriate
managerial costs and benefits. The description of decision alternatives is greatly enhanced through
objectives.
application of the principles of managerial economics. Managerial economics also
provides tools for analyzing and evaluating decision alternatives. Economic concepts and
methodology are used to select the optimal course of action in light of available options
and objectives.
Principles of economic analysis form the basis for describing demand, cost, and profit
relations. Once basic economic relations are understood, the tools and techniques of
optimization can be applied to find the best course of action. Most important, the theory
and process of optimization gives practical insight concerning the value maximization
theory of the firm. Optimization techniques are helpful because they offer a realistic
means for dealing with the complexities of goal-oriented managerial activities.

Maximizing the Value of the Firm


In managerial economics, the primary objective of management is assumed to be
maximization of the value of the firm. This value maximization objective was introduced in
Chapter 1 and is again expressed in Equation (2.1):
n n

Value  ∑ (1  i)t  ∑ _________________________


t=1
Profit t
_______ Total Revenue t  Total Cost t
t=1 (1  i) t
2.1

Maximizing Equation (2.1) is a complex task that involves consideration of future


revenues, costs, and discount rates. Total revenues are directly determined by the
quantity sold and the prices obtained. Factors that affect prices and the quantity sold
include the choice of products made available for sale, marketing strategies, pricing and
distribution policies, competition, and the general state of the economy. Cost analysis
includes a detailed examination of the prices and availability of various input factors,
alternative production schedules, production methods, and so on. Finally, the relation
between an appropriate discount rate and the company’s mix of products and both
operating and financial leverage must be determined. All these factors affect the value of
the firm as described in Equation (2.1).
To determine the optimal course of action, marketing, production, and financial
decisions must be integrated within a decision analysis framework. Similarly, decisions
related to personnel retention and development, organization structure, and long-term
business strategy must be combined into a single integrated system that shows how
managerial initiatives affect all parts of the firm. The value maximization model provides
an attractive basis for such integration. Using the principles of economic analysis, it is
also possible to analyze and compare the higher costs or lower benefits of alternative,
suboptimal courses of action.
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 25

REVENUE RELATIONS
Effective production and pricing decisions depend upon a careful understanding of
revenue relations.

Price and Total Revenue


Tables are the simplest and most direct form for presenting economic data. When these
data are displayed electronically in the format of an accounting income statement or
Spreadsheet balance sheet, the tables are referred to as spreadsheets. When the underlying relation
Table of between economic data is simple, tables and spreadsheets may be sufficient for analytical
electronically
stored data. purposes. In such instances, a simple graph or visual representation of the data can
provide valuable insight. Complex economic relations require more sophisticated
Equation methods of expression. An equation is an expression of the functional relationship or
Analytical connection among economic variables.
expression
of functional The easiest way to examine basic economic concepts is to consider the functional
relationships. relations incorporated in the basic valuation model. Consider the relation between
Total Revenue output, Q, and total revenue, TR. Using functional notation, total revenue is
It is a function of
output.
TR  f(Q) 2.2

Equation (2.2) is read as, “Total revenue is a function of output.” The value of the
dependent variable (total revenue) is determined by the independent variable (output).

Managerial Application 2.1


The Ethics of Greed Versus Self-Interest
Capitalism is based on voluntary exchange between self- customers to complain or seek alternate suppliers, seek
interested parties. Market-based exchange is voluntary; out ways of helping before they become obvious. When
both parties must perceive benefits, or profit, for market customers benefit, so do you and your company. Take the
transactions to take place. If only one party were to benefit customer’s perspective, always. Similarly, it’s best to see every
from a given transaction, there would be no incentive for the business transaction from the standpoint of the person on
other party to cooperate and no voluntary exchange would the other side of the table.
take place. A self-interested capitalist must also have in mind In dealing with employees, it’s best to be honest and
the interest of others. In contrast, a truly selfish individual is forthright. If you make a mistake, admit it and go on. When
only concerned with himself or herself, without regard for the management accepts responsibility for its failures, they gain
well-being of others. Self-interested behavior leads to profits the trust of employees and their help in finding solutions for
and success under capitalism; selfish behavior does not. the inevitable problems that always arise. In a job interview,
Management guru Peter Drucker has written that the for example, strive to see how you can create value for a
purpose of business is to create a customer—someone who potential employer. It’s natural to see things from one’s own
will want to do business with you and your company on a viewpoint; it is typically much more beneficial to see things
regular basis. In a business deal, both parties must benefit. from the perspective of the person sitting on the other side
If not, there will be no ongoing business relationship. of the table.
The only way this can be done is to make sure that you
continually take the customer’s perspective. Can customer See: Peter Berkowitz, "Ethics 101,” The Wall Street Journal Online, October 8, 2007,
demand be met better, cheaper, or faster? Don’t wait for http://online.wsj.com.
26 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

Dependent The variable to the left of the equal sign is called the dependent variable. Its value
Variable depends on the size of the variable or variables to the right of the equal sign. Variables on
Y-variable
determined by the right-hand side of the equal sign are called independent variables. Their values are
X values. determined independently of the functional relation expressed by the equation.
Independent
Equation (2.2) does not indicate the specific relation between output and total
Variable revenue; it merely states that some relation exists. Equation (2.3) provides a more precise
X-variable expression of this functional relation:
determined
separately from
the Y-variable. TR  P  Q 2.3

where P represents the price at which each unit of Q is sold. Total revenue is equal to
price times the quantity sold. If price is constant at, say, $3.50 regardless of the quantity
sold, the relation between quantity sold and total revenue is

TR  $3.50  Q

In agricultural commodity markets, small producers are able to sell as much output
as they can produce at the going price. If the going price of corn is indeed $3.50 per
bushel, the total revenue derived by an individual farmer from corn sales would simply
be TR  $3.5Q, where Q is the number of bushels of corn produced and sold. In most
instances, however, firms face a downward-sloping demand curve. This means that
prices must be cut to increase the quantity sold. The following illustration shows how
linear demand curves can be easily estimated, and how companies can profitably use
such information.
Suppose that the quantity sold rises as price is reduced, as shown in Table 2.1. Notice
that 4 units of output (in 000) are sold at a price of $18, and the quantity sold rises to
7 units per month when price is reduced to $13.50. This is enough information to allow
the firm to estimate a linear demand curve for its product. When a linear demand curve
is written as

P  a  bQ 2.4

Table 2.1 Revenue and Price Relations

Quantity Sold Total Revenue Marginal Revenue


(000 per month) Price ($) TR  P  Q MR  ∂TR/∂Q
0 24.00 $0.00 —
1 22.50 22.50 22.50
2 21.00 42.00 19.50
3 19.50 58.50 16.50
4 18.00 72.00 13.50
5 16.50 82.50 10.50
6 15.00 90.00 7.50
7 13.50 94.50 4.50
8 12.00 96.00 1.50
9 10.50 94.50 1.50
10 9.00 90.00 4.50
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 27

a is the intercept and b is the slope coefficient. Because 4 units were sold at a price of $18,
and 7 units were sold at the price of $13.50, two points on the firm’s linear demand curve
are identified. It is possible to identify the firm’s linear demand curve by solving for the
two unknowns, a and b:

18  a  b(4)
minus 13.5  a  b(7)
4.5  –3b
b  –1.5

By substitution, if b   1.5, then:

18  a  b(4)
18  a  1.5(4)
18  a  6
a  24

In this case, the firm’s demand curve can be written:

P  $24  $1.5Q

This functional relation between price and output, shown in Figure 2.1, implies the
following relation between total revenue and the quantity sold:

TR  P  Q
 ($24  1.5 Q)  Q
 $24Q  $1.5Q 2

Figure 2.1 Relation Between Price and Output

30.00

25.00

20.00
Price = f (Q) = $24 – $1.5Q
Price ($)

15.00

10.00

5.00

0.00
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Output per time period (000 units)
28 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

To be sure, such relations are only useful approximations within the range of price-output
combinations used to derive them. For example, the firm could use such a demand curve
to estimate quantity demanded during a given period for prices ranging from $24 to
$9 per unit. It should not be used to estimate the number of units that might be sold at
exceptionally low prices like $5, or at exceedingly high prices, like $30. The firm has no
market experience at such extreme prices, and the estimated linear demand curve should
not be presumed outside its range of experience.

Marginal Revenue
Precise information about the effect of a change in output on total revenue is given
by the marginal relation between revenue and output. Total, average, and marginal
relations are very useful in optimization analysis. Whereas the definitions of totals and
averages are well known, the meaning of marginal relations needs some explanation. A
marginal relation is the change in the dependent variable caused by a 1-unit change in an
Marginal Revenue independent variable. Marginal revenue (MR) is the change in total revenue associated
Change in total with a 1-unit change in output:
revenue associated
with a 1-unit change
in output. MR  ∂TR/∂Q 2.5

where the large Greek letter delta is used to express the word “change.” Thus, the
expression MR  ∂TR/∂Q is read as follows: “Marginal revenue is the change in total
revenue caused by a 1-unit change in the number of units sold (Q).”
As shown in Table 2.1 and Figure 2.2, total revenue rises from $72 to $82.50 when
units sold rises from 4 to 5 units. This means that marginal revenue is $10.50 over the
range from 4 to 5 units. Similarly, marginal revenue is $7.50 over the range from 5 to
6 units. Notice that marginal revenue is positive so long as total revenue is increasing,

Figure 2.2 Relations Among Price, Total Revenue, Marginal Revenue, and Output

120.00
Maximum total revenue at Q = 8

100.00

TR = P × Q = $24Q – $1.5Q 2
80.00

60.00
Price ($)

40.00
P = $24 – $1.5Q
20.00 MR = 0

MR = $24 – $3Q
0.00
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

–20.00
Output per time period (000 units)
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 29

as is true over the range from 1 to 8 units sold. Notice also that total revenue begins
to decrease beyond 8 units sold, where marginal revenue turns negative. In general,
marginal revenue is positive when total revenue is increasing, but marginal revenue
becomes negative when total revenue is decreasing.
When a linear relation exists between price and the number of units sold, a linear
relation also exists between marginal revenue and units sold. In such instances, both
price and marginal revenue relations begin at the same point, but marginal revenue falls
twice as fast as price with respect to output. In the present example,

P  $24  $1.5Q
TR  $24Q  $1.5Q 2
MR  ∂TR/∂Q  $24  $3Q

As shown in Table 2.1, marginal revenue is 1.50 when the number of units sold rises over
the range from 7 to 8. When the number of units sold continues to rise over the range from
8 to 9, marginal revenue becomes negative, or  1.50. In general, marginal revenue shows
the rate of change in total revenue that occurs with change in the number of units sold.

Revenue Maximization Example


At every output level, the marginal revenue relation can be used to precisely identify
the change in total revenue that occurs with a 1-unit change in the number of units sold.
Revenue Revenue maximization occurs at the point of greatest total revenues. For example, to
Maximization find the revenue-maximizing output level, set MR  0, and solve for Q:
Activity level
that generates the
highest revenue, MR  0
MR  0.
$24  $3Q  0
3Q  24
Q8

From this marginal revenue relation, MR  0 when Q  8 because MR  $24  $3(8)  0.


When Q  8, total revenue is maximized at $96 because

TR  $24Q  $1.5Q 2
 $24(8)  $1.5(8 2)
 $96

As shown in Figure 2.2, if fewer than 8 units are sold, total revenue can be increased with
an expansion in output. If more than 8 units were sold, total revenue would decline from
$96 and could be increased with a reduction in volume. Only at Q  8 is total revenue
maximized.
In some instances, savvy firms employ a short-run revenue-maximizing strategy
as part of their long-term profit maximization. Enhanced product awareness among
consumers, increased customer loyalty, potential economies of scale in marketing and
promotion, and possible limitations in competitor entry and growth are all potential
advantages of short-term revenue maximization. To be consistent with long-run profit
maximization, such advantages of short-run revenue maximization must be at least
sufficient to compensate for the corresponding loss in short-run profitability.
30 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

Managerial Application 2.2


Do Firms Really Optimize?
Have you ever been at a sporting event when a particular Although the term optimization may be foreign to such
athlete’s play became the center of attention, and wondered: individuals, the methodology of optimization is familiar to
“Where did that woman study physics?” or “Wow, who each of them in terms of their everyday business practice.
taught that guy physiology?” Nobody asks those questions. Adjusting prices to avoid stock-out situations, increasing
Discussion usually centers on the players’ skill, finesse, or product quality to “meet the competition,” and raising
tenacity. Natural talent must be developed through long salaries to retain valued employees all involve a practical
hours of dedicated training and intense competition before understanding of optimization concepts.
one can become an accomplished athlete. But if you think The behavior of both the successful athlete and the
about it, successful athletes must also know a great deal successful executive can be described as consistent with a
about angles, speed, and acceleration. process of optimization. The fact that some practitioners learn
While success in sports requires that one understand managerial economics through hands-on experience rather
the basic principles of physics and physiology, most athletes than in the classroom doesn’t diminish the value of the formal
develop their “feel” for their sports on the tennis court, golf educational experience. Useful theory describes and predicts
course, baseball diamond, or gridiron. Similarly, some very actual business decisions. The old saw, “That may be okay in
successful businesses are run by people with little or no theory, but it doesn’t work in practice,” is plainly incorrect.
formal training in accounting, finance, management, or Economic theory is useful for one simple reason—it works.
marketing. These executives’ successes testify to their ability
to develop a feel for business in much the same way that See: Phred Dvorak, “Eureka: Inventor Finds Bottom Line Seals the Deal,” The Wall
Street Journal Online, August 20, 2007, http://online.wsj.com.
the successful athlete develops a feel for his or her sport.

COST RELATIONS
Meeting customer demand efficiently depends upon a careful understanding of cost
relations.
Cost Functions
Relations between
cost and output.
Total Cost
Short-run Cost
Proper use of relevant cost concepts requires an understanding of various relations
Functions between costs and output, or cost functions. Two basic cost functions are used in
Cost relations managerial decision making: short-run cost functions, used for day-to-day operating
when fixed costs
are present; used
decisions, and long-run cost functions, used for long-term planning. In economic
for day-to-day analysis, the short run is the operating period during which the availability of at least
operating decisions. one input is fixed. In the long run, the firm has complete flexibility with respect to
Long-run Cost input use.
Functions Total costs are comprised of fixed and variable expenses. Fixed costs do not vary
Cost relation when
with output. These costs include interest expenses, rent on leased plant and equipment,
all costs are variable;
used for long-term depreciation charges associated with the passage of time, property taxes, and salaries for
planning. employees not laid off during periods of reduced activity. Because all costs are variable
Short Run in the long run, long-run fixed costs always equal zero. In economic analysis, the short
Operating period run is the operating period during which the availability of at least one input is fixed.
during which the In the long run, the firm has complete flexibility with respect to input use. In the short
availability of at
least one input is run, operating decisions are typically constrained by prior capital expenditures. In
fixed. the long run, no such restrictions exist. For example, a management consulting firm
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 31

Long Run operating out of rented office space might have a short-run period as brief as a few
Period of complete weeks, the time remaining on the office lease. A firm in the hazardous waste disposal
flexibility with
respect to input use. business has significant long-lived assets and may face a 20- to 30-year period of
operating constraints. Variable costs fluctuate with output. Expenses for raw materials,
Total Costs
Fixed and variable
depreciation associated with the use of equipment, the variable portion of utility
expenses. charges, some labor costs, and sales commissions are all examples of variable expenses.
In the short run, both variable and fixed costs are often incurred. In the long run, all
Fixed Costs
Expenses that costs are variable.
do not vary with A sharp distinction between fixed and variable costs is neither always possible nor
output.
realistic. For example, CEO and staff salaries may be largely fixed, but during severe
Variable Costs business downturns, even CEOs take a pay cut. Similarly, salaries for line managers and
Expenses that supervisors are fixed only within certain output ranges. Below a lower limit, supervisors
fluctuate with
output. and managers get laid off. Above an upper limit, additional supervisors and managers
get hired. The longer the duration of abnormal demand, the greater the likelihood that
some fixed costs will actually vary.
In equation form, total cost can be expressed as the sum of fixed and variable costs:

TC  FC  VC 2.6

As shown in Table 2.2, total cost is the simple sum of the variable cost and fixed cost
categories. With respect to the cost figures shown in Table 2.2, the fixed and variable cost
categories can be expressed in equation form as

FC  $8
VC  $4Q  $0.5Q 2

Notice that fixed costs are constant at $8 and do not depend upon the level of output,
whereas variable costs rise with the amount of production. In this example, variable
costs rise faster than output because the variable cost function is quadratic in nature; it

Table 2.2 Cost Output Relations

Quantity
Sold (000 per Fixed Variable Total Marginal Cost Average Cost
month) Cost ($) Cost ($) Cost ($) MC  ∂TC/∂Q AC  TC/Q
0 8.00 0.00 8.00 — —
1 8.00 4.50 12.50 4.50 12.50
2 8.00 10.00 18.00 5.50 9.00
3 8.00 16.50 24.50 6.50 8.17
4 8.00 24.00 32.00 7.50 8.00
5 8.00 32.50 40.50 8.50 8.10
6 8.00 42.00 50.00 9.50 8.33
7 8.00 52.50 60.50 10.50 8.64
8 8.00 64.00 72.00 11.50 9.00
9 8.00 76.50 84.50 12.50 9.39
10 8.00 90.00 98.00 13.50 9.80
32 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

involves output squared, or Q2, because total cost equals fixed cost plus variable cost, the
total cost function can be expressed in equation form as:

TC  $8  $4Q  $0.5Q 2

Because total cost is the sum of fixed plus variable costs, and variable costs rise with
output, total costs rise with the amount produced.

Marginal and Average Cost


Marginal Cost Marginal cost is the change in total cost associated with a 1-unit change in output.
Change in total cost
associated with a
1-unit change in MC  ∂TC/∂Q 2.7
output.
where the large Greek letter delta is again used to express the word “change.” Thus, the
expression MC  ∂TC/∂Q is read as follows: “Marginal cost is the change in total cost
caused by a 1-unit change in the number of units produced (Q).”
As shown in Table 2.2 and Figure 2.3, total cost rises from $24.50 to $32.00 when the
number of units produced rises from 3 to 4 units. This means that marginal cost is $7.50
when output rises over the range from 3 to 4 units. Similarly, marginal cost is $8.50 over
the range from 4 to 5 units. Notice that marginal cost is positive and increasing over the
range from 1 to 10 units produced. Marginal cost is almost always positive because almost
all goods and services entail at least some labor and/or materials. It is also common for
marginal costs to rise as output expands, but this in not universally true.
Average Cost Average cost (AC) is simply total cost divided by the number of units produced:
Total cost divided by
the number of units
AC  TC/Q 2.8
produced.

Figure 2.3 Relations Between Total Cost, Marginal Cost, Average Cost, and Output

120.00

100.00

80.00
Cost ($)

60.00 TC = $8 + $4Q + $0.5Q 2

40.00
MC = $4 + $1Q
Minimum AC at Q = 4 where MC = AC
20.00

AC = $8/Q + $4 + $0.5Q
0.00
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Output per time period (000 units)
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 33

In Table 2.2, notice that average cost is falling when MC AC. Also notice that average cost
is rising when MC AC. This is always true. Whenever the marginal is less than the average,
the average will fall. Whenever the marginal is greater than the average, the average will rise.
If the marginal is equal to the average, the average is at either a minimum or a maximum.
Distinguishing maximums from minimums is easy with a simple numerical example. If
MC  AC, and average cost falls with an expansion in output, then AC is at a maximum.
If MC  AC, and average cost rises with an expansion in output, then AC is at a minimum.

Average Cost Minimization Example


At every output level, the relationship between marginal cost and output indicates the
change in total cost that will occur with a 1-unit change in the number of units produced.
Similarly, the relationship between marginal cost and average cost can be studied to
determine the change in average cost that will occur with a 1-unit change in the number
of units produced. For example, the total cost and marginal cost relations described by
the data in Table 2.2 can be written as2

TC  $8  $4Q  $0.5Q 2
MC  ∂TC/∂Q  $4  $1Q

Because average cost is total cost divided by the number of units produced, the average
cost relation is

AC  TC/Q
 ($8  $4Q  $0.5Q 2)/Q
 $8/Q  $4  $0.5Q

Average Cost With average cost minimization, the lowest possible average cost is achieved. To find the
Minimization average-cost minimizing output level, set MC  AC, and solve for Q:
Activity level
that generates the
lowest average cost, MC  AC
MC  AC.
$4  $1Q  $8/Q  $4  $0.5Q
0.5Q  __
8
Q
Q 2  ___
8
0.5
Q  √16
4

Notice that when Q  4, MC  AC  $8. Moreover, from Table 2.2 and Figure 2.3 it is
obvious that average cost is rising when Q  4, so Q  4 indicates a point of minimum
(rather than maximum) average cost.

2 Both marginal and total cost relations can be expressed as a function of output, or inferred by inspection
of underlying data, such as that contained in Table 2.2. As appropriate, both marginal and total relations
will be explicitly expressed throughout this text to make easier the process of necessary manipulation.
Some instructors and their students take advantage of elementary calculus to help find optimal solutions
for economic problems. The appendices to this chapter illustrate how calculus concepts can be used
to clarify relations among marginals, averages, and totals and the importance of these relations in the
optimization process.
34 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

From a strategic point of view, the point of minimum average cost is important
because it shows the level of output necessary to achieve maximum productive efficiency.
In some cases, small firms find that in order to be competitive, they need to “get big,
or get out” of a particular market. At the same time, it is important to recognize that
average-cost minimization involves consideration of cost relations only; no revenue
relations are considered in the process of minimizing average costs. To determine the
profit-maximizing activity level, both revenue and cost relations must be considered.

PROFIT RELATIONS
Profit maximization involves a careful comparison of revenue and cost relations.

Total and Marginal Profit


Total Profit Total profit is simply the difference between total revenue and total cost. Because the
Difference between letter “P” is used to describe price, economists often use the lower case Greek letter π
total revenue and
total cost. (read pi) to signify profit. Therefore,

π  TR  TC 2.9

Managerial Application 2.3


Market-Based Management
A native of Wichita, Kansas, Charles G. Koch received a • Virtue and Talents: Helping ensure that people with the
bachelor’s degree in general engineering and masters right values, skills, and capabilities are hired, retained, and
degrees in nuclear and chemical engineering from the developed.
Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Since 1967, Koch has • Knowledge Processes: Creating, sharing, and applying
been the chairman of the board and CEO of Koch Industries, relevant knowledge to discover how employees and
Inc., a diverse group of companies engaged in refining and practices can become more profitable.
chemicals, process equipment and technologies, fibers • Decision Rights: Ensuring the right people are in the
and polymers, minerals, commodity and financial trading, right roles with the right authority to make decisions
and forest and consumer products. Familiar Koch brands and holding them accountable. Focus on comparative
include Dixie® cups, Georgia-Pacific®, LYCRA® spandex, Quilted advantage and proven ability to create long-term
Northern® tissue, and STAINMASTER® carpet. Based upon value.
2006 sales of over $90 billion, Forbes magazine calls Koch • Incentives: Rewarding people according to the value
Industries the largest privately held company in the world. created for the organization.
With enviable profit margins, Koch Industries is also one of
In 2007, Charles Koch and his brother David ranked
the most successful business organizations, public or private.
#9 and #10, respectively, on Forbes annual list of the
The amazing success of Koch Industries can be traced
400 richest Americans. Sandwiched between Dell founder
to the company’s development and implementation of
Michael Dell (#8) and Microsoft cofounder Paul Allen
Market-Based Management (MBM), a business philosophy
(#11), the Koch brothers are each worth an estimated
that fosters principled, entrepreneurial behavior among its
$17 billion. Their business success is powerful testimony
employees. MBM is organized and interpreted through five
to the value of applying basic economic principles in
dimensions:
business.
• Vision: Determining where and how the organization
can create the greatest long-term value based upon See: The Market Based Management Institute Web site is at http://mbminstitute.
competitive advantages. org/index.cfm.
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 35

Marginal Profit Marginal profit is the change in total profit due to a 1-unit change in output:
Change in total
profit due to a 1-unit
change in output. Mπ  ∂π/∂Q 2.10
Mπ  MR  MC.

Once again, the large Greek letter delta is used to express the word “change.” Thus, the
expression Mπ  ∂π/∂Q is read: “Marginal profit is the change in total profit caused by
a 1-unit change in the number of units sold (Q).” Equivalently, marginal profit can be
thought of as the difference between marginal revenue and marginal cost:

Mπ  MR  MC 2.11

Table 2.3 combines the revenue and cost data described in Tables 2.1 and 2.2 to show
how total and marginal profits vary with output (the number of units sold). When
Q  0, total revenue is zero, and fixed costs represent the money loss for the firm. When
Q  0,π   $8. Given that Mπ  0, total profit rises as output expands over the range
from Q  1 to Q  5. However, beyond Q  5, the increase in total cost associated with
an expansion in output exceeds the increase in total revenue, and total profit begins to
decline.
In general, total profit will rise if Mπ  0. Total profit will fall whenever Mπ  0.
Similarly, total profit will rise so long as MR  MC because that means Mπ  0. Total
Profit profit will fall if MR  MC because that means Mπ  0. The profit maximization rule
Maximization states that total profit will be maximized when marginal profit equals zero, provided
Rule
Profit is that profit declines with a further expansion in output. In functional form, profit is
maximized when maximized only if
Mπ  MR  MC  0
or MR  MC,
assuming profit Mπ  0 2.12
declines with
further expansion
in Q. and profit falls with a further increase in output. Because Mπ  MR  MC  0 at the profit-
maximizing activity level,

MR  MC 2.13

Once again, profit maximization requires that profit falls with any further increase in
output.

Profit Maximization Example


Table 2.3 and Figure 2.4 show the profit and marginal profit implications of the revenue
relations described in Table 2.1, and the cost relations depicted in Table 2.2. In Table 2.3,
notice that profit is rising over the range from Q  1 to Q  5 where marginal profit is
positive. Profit is falling over the range from Q  6 to Q  10 where marginal profit is
Breakeven Points negative. Zero profits are achieved at the lower and upper breakeven points. In equation
Output levels with form, the relevant profit relation can be expressed as
zero profit.

π  TR  TC
 $24Q  $1.5Q 2  ($8  $4Q  $0.5Q 2)
  $8  $20Q  $2Q 2
36
Table 2.3 Quantity, Revenue, Cost, and Profit Relations

Total Marginal Marginal Average


Quantity Revenue Revenue Total Cost Cost Cost Total Profit Marginal
Sold (000 Fixed Variable Price P  $24 TR  P Q MR  ∂TR/ TC  $8  $4Q MC  ∂TC/ AC  TC/ π  TR  TC Profit
per month) Cost Cost ($)  $1.5Q ($) ($) ∂Q  $0.5Q2 ($) ∂Q Q ($) Mπ  MR  MC
0 8 16.00 24.00 0.00 — 8.00 — — 8.00 —
1 8 14.50 22.50 22.50 22.50 12.50 4.50 12.50 10.0 18.00
2 8 13.00 21.00 42.00 19.50 18.00 5.50 9.00 24.0 14.00
3 8 11.50 19.50 58.50 16.50 24.50 6.50 8.17 34.0 10.00
4 8 10.00 18.00 72.00 13.50 32.00 7.50 8.00 40.0 6.00
5 8 8.50 16.50 82.50 10.50 40.50 8.50 8.10 42.0 2.00
6 8 7.00 15.00 90.00 7.50 50.00 9.50 8.33 40.0 2.00
7 8 5.50 13.50 94.50 4.50 60.50 10.50 8.64 34.0 6.00
8 8 4.00 12.00 96.00 1.50 72.00 11.50 9.00 24.0 10.00
9 8 2.50 10.50 94.50 1.50 84.50 12.50 9.39 10.0 14.00
10 8 1.00 9.00 90.00 4.50 98.00 13.50 9.80 8.0 18.00

Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics


Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 37

Figure 2.4 Relations Between Total Profit, Marginal Profit, and Output

120
Upper breakeven point Q = 9.58

100
Total revenue

80
Lower breakeven Total cost
point Q = 0.42
60
Total profit maximized at Q = 5
Dollars

40 Total profit

20
Marginal profit

0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Marginal profit = 0 at Q = 5
–20

–40
Output per time period (000 units)

Similarly, the relevant marginal profit relation can be expressed as

Mπ  MR  MC
 $24  $3Q  ($4  $1Q)
 $20  $4Q

At every output level, the marginal profit relation can be used to precisely identify the
change in total profit that occurs with a 1-unit change in the number of units sold. To find
the profit-maximizing output level, set Mπ  0, and solve for Q:

Mπ  0
$20  $4Q  0
4Q  20
Q5

From this marginal profit relation, Mπ  0 when Q  5. Also observe that MR  MC at


this point bec-ause MR  $24  $3(5)  $9 and MC  $4  $1(5)  $9 when Q  5. As shown
in Figure 2.4, when Q  5, total profit is maximized at $42 because

π   $8  $20Q  $2Q 2
  $8  $20(5)  $2(5 2)
 $42

If fewer than 5 units were sold, total profit could be increased with an expansion in
output. If more than 5 units were sold, total profit would decline from $42 and could be
increased with a reduction in volume. Only at Q  5 is total profit maximized.
38 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

At the profit-maximizing activity level, MR  MC and the added amount of revenue


brought in by the last unit produced (marginal revenue) is just sufficient to offset added
cost (marginal cost), and profit would fall with an expansion in production. Because
almost all goods and services entail the use of at least some labor and raw materials,
MC  0 in all but the most unusual circumstances. This fact has important implications
for profit versus revenue maximization. With a downward-sloping demand curve, both
price and marginal revenue decline following an increase in the number of units sold,
and MR  MC will occur at a lower level of activity than where MR  0. The amount
produced and sold at the profit-maximizing activity level will be the same as the amount
produced and sold at the revenue-maximizing activity level only in the unlikely event
that MR  MC  0. The profit-maximizing activity level will also tend to differ from the
average-cost–minimizing activity level where MC  AC. Recall that finding the point of
lowest average costs involves a consideration of marginal cost and average cost relations
only, no revenue implications are considered. The point of profit maximization can be less
than, equal to, or greater than the point of average cost minimization.

INCREMENTAL CONCEPT IN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS


When economic decisions have a lumpy rather than continuous impact on output, use of
the incremental concept is appropriate.

Marginal Versus Incremental Concept


It is important to recognize that marginal relations measure the effect associated with
unitary changes in output. Many managerial decisions involve a consideration of changes
that are broader in scope. For example, a manager might be interested in analyzing the
potential effects on revenues, costs, and profits of a 25 percent increase in the firm’s
production level. Alternatively, a manager might want to analyze the profit impact
of introducing an entirely new product line, or assess the cost impact of changing an
entire production system. In all managerial decisions, the study of differences or changes
is the key element in the selection of an optimal course of action. The marginal concept,
although correct for analyzing unitary changes in output, is too narrow to provide a
general methodology for evaluating all alternative courses of action.
The incremental concept is the economist’s generalization of the marginal concept.
Incremental analysis involves examining the impact of alternative managerial decisions
or courses of action on revenues, costs, and profit. It focuses on changes or differences
Incremental among available alternatives. The incremental change is the change resulting from a
Change given managerial decision. For example, the incremental revenue of a new item in a
Change resulting
from a given firm’s product line is measured as the difference between the firm’s total revenue before
managerial and after the new product is introduced.
decision.

Incremental Profits
Incremental Incremental profit is the profit gain or loss associated with a given managerial decision.
Profit Total profit increases so long as incremental profit is positive. When incremental profit
Gain or loss
associated with a is negative, total profit declines. Similarly, incremental profit is positive (and total profit
given managerial increases) if the incremental revenue associated with a decision exceeds the incremental
decision. cost. The incremental concept is so intuitively obvious that it is easy to overlook both its
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 39

Managerial Application 2.4


Behavioral Economics
Economic theory is built on the premise that men and Behavioral economists argue that perfect knowledge never
women are capable of conducting the sometimes complex exists, and that all economic activity involves uncertainty
calculations necessary to productively seek wealth and and risk.
avoid unnecessary labor. As a result, material and financial Behavioral economics differs from more traditional
transactions among individuals and organizations reflect approaches by arguing that
rational, self-interested human behavior. During the late
• People tend to make decisions based on approximate
nineteenth century, respected and highly influential
rules of thumb (using “bounded rationality”), not fully
economists built sophisticated mathematical models to
informed rational analyses.
describe “economic man,” a person who acted rationally out
• The way problems are presented (“framed”) affects
of self-interest with complete knowledge and the desire
economic decisions.
for wealth. While the economic man concept was originally
• Observed market outcomes often vary from rational
intended as a necessary abstraction from economic and
expectations and market efficiency.
human realities, the study of economics evolved during
the twentieth century toward the view that actual human Some traditional economists are skeptical of the
behavior closely parallels that of homo economicus experimental and survey-based methods used by behavioral
(economic man). economists, and stress the importance of preferences
Recently, a new and exciting branch of economics, revealed through market transactions (revealed preferences)
called “behavioral economics,” has emerged to question the rather than simply declared in surveys or experimental
descriptive and predictive capability of the economic man settings (stated preferences). Proponents of behavioral
concept. Critics argue that utility maximization requires a economics note that neoclassical models sometimes fail to
complex understanding of human emotions and economic predict real-world outcomes and that behavioral insight can
phenomena that is far beyond the cognitive ability of most be used to improve upon traditional approaches.
economic agents. Economic decisions are thought to reflect
widespread uncertainty, rather than the precise calculations See: Ann Davis and Neil King, “Bears Smell Oil Bubble as Price Soars,” The Wall
of fully informed and dispassionate decision makers. Street Journal Online, October 19, 2007, http://online.wsj.com.

significance in managerial decision making and the potential for difficulty in correctly
applying it.
For this reason, the incremental concept is sometimes violated in practice. For
example, a firm may refuse to sublet excess warehouse space for $5,000 per month
because it figures its cost as $7,500 per month—a price paid for a long-term lease on
the facility. However, if the warehouse space represents excess capacity with no current
value to the company, its historical cost of $7,500 per month is irrelevant and should be
disregarded. The firm would forego $5,000 in profits by turning down the offer to sublet
the excess warehouse space. Similarly, any firm that adds a standard allocated charge
for fixed costs and overhead to the true incremental cost of production runs the risk of
turning down profitable business.
Care must also be exercised to ensure against incorrectly assigning overly low
incremental costs to a decision. Incremental decisions involve a time dimension that
cannot be ignored. Not only must all current revenues and costs be considered, but any
likely future revenues and costs also must be incorporated in the analysis. For example,
assume that the excess warehouse space described earlier came about following a
downturn in the overall economy. Also, assume that the excess warehouse space was
40 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

sublet for 1 year at a price of $5,000 per month, or a total of $60,000. An incremental
loss might be experienced if the firm later had to lease additional, more costly space to
accommodate an unexpected increase in production. If $75,000 had to be spent to replace
the sublet warehouse facility, the decision to sublet would involve an incremental loss of
$15,000. To be sure, making accurate projections concerning the future pattern of revenues
and costs is risky and subject to error. Nevertheless, expectations about the future cannot
be ignored in incremental analysis.
Another example of the incremental concept involves measurement of the incremental
revenue resulting from a new product line. Incremental revenue includes not only
the revenue received from sale of a new product, but also any change in the revenues
generated over the remainder of the firm’s product line. Incremental revenues rise
when revenues jump for related products. Similarly, if a new item takes sales away from
another of the firm’s products, this loss in revenue must be accounted for in measuring
the incremental revenue of the new product.

Incremental Concept Example


To further illustrate the incremental concept, consider the financing decision typically
associated with business plant and equipment financing. Suppose a buyer has its $100,000
purchase offer accepted by the seller of a small retail facility. The buyer must obtain
financing to complete the transaction. The best rates are at a local financial institution
that offers a renewable 5-year mortgage at 9 percent interest with a down payment of
20 percent, or 9.5 percent interest on a loan with only 10 percent down. In the first case,
the buyer is able to finance 80 percent of the purchase price; in the second case, the
buyer is able to finance 90 percent. For simplicity, assume that both loans require interest
payments only during the first 5 years. After 5 years, either note could be renewable at
then-current interest rates and would be restructured with monthly payments designed
to amortize the loan over 20 years. An important question facing the buyer is: What is the
incremental cost of additional funds borrowed when 90 percent versus 80 percent of the
purchase price is financed?
Because no principal payments are required, the annual financing cost under each
loan alternative can be calculated easily. The 80 percent loan requires a 20 percent down
payment and has annual financing costs in dollar terms of

80% Loan Financing Cost  Interest Rate  Loan Percentage  Purchase Price
 0.09  0.8  $100,000
 $7,200

The corresponding annual financing cost for the 90 percent loan involving a
10 percent down payment is

90% Loan Financing Cost  Interest Rate  Loan Percentage  Purchase Price
 0.095  0.9  $100,000
 $8,550

To calculate the incremental cost of added funds borrowed under the 90 percent
financing alternative, the borrower must compare the amount of incremental financing
Chapter 2: Economic Optimization 41

costs incurred with the incremental amount of funds borrowed. In dollar terms, the
incremental financing cost per year is

Incremental Financing Cost  90% Loan Financing Cost  80% Loan Financing Cost
 $8,550  $7,200
 $1,350

These incremental financing costs must be compared to the incremental amount


borrowed, where

Incremental Amount Borrowed  90% Loan Amount  80% Loan Amount


 $90,000  $80,000
 $10,000

In percentage terms, the incremental cost of the additional funds borrowed under the
90 percent financing alternative is
Incremental Financing Cost
Incremental Financing Cost Percentage  ____________________________
Incremental Amount Borrowed
$1,350
 _______
$10,000
 0.135 or 13.5%

The incremental cost of funds for the last $10,000 borrowed under the 90 percent
financing alternative is 13.5 percent, not the 9.5 percent interest rate quoted for the entire
loan. Although the high incremental cost of funds for loans that reflect relatively little
down payments may be surprising to some borrowers, it is not unusual. Lenders demand
high rates of interest for loans that involve substantial risk, and the chance of default is much
higher when 90 percent, as opposed to 80 percent, of the purchase price is financed. When it
comes to low down payment mortgages, both borrowers and lenders need to beware!
The incremental concept is important for managerial decisions because it focuses
attention on relevant differences among available alternatives. Revenues and costs
unaffected by a given choice are irrelevant to that decision and should be ignored in the
analysis.

SUMMARY
Effective managerial decision making is the process of are displayed electronically in the format of an
finding the best solution to a given problem. Both the accounting income statement or balance sheet, the
methodology and tools of managerial economics play tables are referred to as spreadsheets.
an important role in this process. • An equation is an expression of the functional
• The decision alternative that produces a result most relationship or connection among economic
consistent with managerial objectives is the optimal variables. For example, total revenue (sales) is a
decision. function of output. The value of the dependent
• Tables are the simplest and most direct form variable (total revenue) is determined by the
for presenting economic data. When these data independent variable (output). The variable to
42 Part 1: Overview of Managerial Economics

the left of the equal sign is called the dependent produced. The lowest possible average cost is
variable. Its value depends on the size of the achieved at the point of average cost minimization.
variable or variables to the right of the equal To find the average-cost–minimizing output level,
sign. Variables on the right-hand side of the equal set MC  AC, and solve for Q.
sign are called independent variables. Their values • Total profit is simply the difference between total
are determined independently of the functional revenue and total cost. Marginal profit is the
relation expressed by the equation. change in total profit due to a 1-unit change in
• Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue output. Equivalently, marginal profit can be thought
associated with a 1-unit change in output. Revenue of as the difference between marginal revenue and
maximization occurs at the output level that marginal cost, Mπ  MR  MC. Total profit will rise
generates the greatest total revenue. To find the if Mπ  0. Total profit will fall whenever Mπ  0.
revenue-maximizing output level, set MR  0, and The profit maximization rule states that total
solve for Q. profit will be maximized when Mπ  0. Because
• Proper use of relevant cost concepts requires an Mπ  MR  MC  0 at the profit-maximizing
understanding of various relations between costs activity level, MR  MC. Zero profits are achieved
and output, or cost functions. Two basic cost at the lower and upper breakeven points.
functions are used in managerial decision making: • When economic decisions have a lumpy rather
short-run cost functions, used for day-to-day than continuous impact on output, use of
operating decisions, and long-run cost functions, the incremental concept is appropriate. The
used for long-term planning. In economic analysis, incremental change is the change resulting
the short run is the operating period during which from a given managerial decision. Incremental
the availability of at least one input is fixed. In the profit is the profit gain or loss associated with
long run, the firm has complete flexibility with a given managerial decision. The incremental
respect to input use. concept focuses attention on relevant differences
• Total costs are comprised of fixed and variable among available alternatives. Revenues and costs
expenses. Fixed costs do not vary with output. unaffected by a given choice are irrelevant to that
Variable costs fluctuate with output. In the decision and should be ignored.
short run, both variable and fixed costs are often Each of these concepts is fruitfully applied in the practical
incurred. In the long run, all costs are variable. analysis of managerial decision problems. As seen in
• Marginal cost is the change in total cost associated later chapters, economic analysis provides the underlying
with a 1-unit change in output. Average cost is framework for the study of all profit, revenue, and cost
simply total cost divided by the number of units relations.

QUESTIONS
Q2.1 In 2007, Chrysler Group said it would cut the best of both characteristics by allowing managers
13,000 jobs, close a major assembly plant, and reduce to determine and communicate the optimal course
production at other plants as part of a restructuring of action.” Discuss this statement and explain why
effort designed to restore profitability at the auto maker computer spreadsheets are a popular means for
by 2008. Its German parent, DaimlerChrysler, said it expressing and analyzing economic relations.
is looking into further strategic options with partners Q2.3 For those 50 or older, membership in AARP,
to optimize and accelerate the plan as it seeks the formerly known as the American Association of
best solutions for its struggling U.S. unit. Does this Retired Persons, brings numerous discounts for
decision reflect an application of the global or partial health insurance, hotels, auto rentals, shopping, travel
optimization concept? Explain. planning, and so on. Use the marginal profit concept to
Q2.2 “The personal computer is a calculating device explain why vendors seek out bargain-priced business
and a communicating device. Spreadsheets incorporate with AARP members.

You might also like