You are on page 1of 10

Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Utilities Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jup

Adaptive planning for climate resilient long-lived infrastructures


Thierry Giordano
Development Bank of Southern Africa and France Expertise Internationale, PO Box 1234 Halfway House, Midrand, Gauteng 1685, South Africa

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Climate change is a particular threat to long-lived infrastructures as many existing and planned infra-
Received 1 March 2012 structures will still be in use by 2030 or 2050 when climate change might have far more substantial
Received in revised form impacts then today. Consequently, to avoid financial losses and service disruption, the infrastructure
9 July 2012
planning process has to be entirely redefined to be able to successfully integrate climate change
Accepted 11 July 2012
uncertainties. This paper explores the relationships between climate change and long-lived infrastruc-
ture according to the different types of direct and indirect uncertainties surrounding climate change,
Keywords:
demonstrates the importance of acknowledging climate change as one of the components of the
Infrastructure
Climate change
infrastructure planning process and explains how this same process could be reviewed to make it more
Planning responsive to the many uncertainties surrounding our future. It points out the different measures which
Uncertainties could be undertaken to improve the planning process.
Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introdution the short term, especially because of their high demonstration


effects, these interventions are insufficient in the long term: they
How concerned should utilities be about the consequences of constitute but a limited contribution to carbon emission reduc-
climate change and its impact on their investments in long-lived tions; furthermore climate adaptation measures also need to be
infrastructures, i.e. infrastructures planned and built to provide anticipated in order to increase infrastructure’s climate resilience.
a dedicated service over a long period, often amounting to several Consequently there is a crucial need to rethink the planning of
decades? What changes should these concerns trigger about the process for long-lived infrastructure investment to take heed of
way investors have been hitherto making decisions? These ques- climate change challenges.1
tions might be seen as rather theoretical as many utilities do not Climate change places such new conditions on the global
fully grasp what climate change really implies. However, climate development pattern of individual countries that first movers
change consequences are far-reaching enough to question the already display massive advantages over their competitors. For
many angles of the investment process in long-lived infrastruc- instance, China has become the world leader for solar water
tures, ranging from risks and uncertainties related to a specific heaters, while European countries have built comparative advan-
project to the long term planning of infrastructure needs and their tages for wind technologies. This is strikingly evident for industrial
design. Indeed, not only utilities, but the whole range of actors development where many countries are convincingly supporting
involved in long-lived infrastructure development have to integrate green sectors as new growth opportunities. It seems far less
climate change in their business, especially governments who are obvious for what still constitute the mainstay of long term devel-
responsible for infrastructure planning. opment, sustained economic growth and poverty alleviation: long-
Most stakeholders are still adopting a careful stance on the lived infrastructures. Many infrastructures have a lifespan of at
concept itself rather than on its potential consequences, thereby least 20 years and more. Thereby, many existing and planned
leading to an underestimate of the required reforms of the infrastructures will still be in use by 2030 or 2050 when climate
investment decision-making process. As a consequence, most change might have far more substantial impacts than today (IPCC,
interventions around climate change target “easy-wins” or “low 2007). Furthermore, the different spheres of governments, along
hanging fruits” which require less capital, little institutional and with private investors and utilities, have been and will remain both
regulatory changes, and thereby can be implemented rapidly.
Energy efficiency measures are good examples. While relevant in
1
Climate change is the main focus of this paper. However, there is a crucial need
to include broader environmental concerns in the planning process, the efficient
E-mail address: thierryg@dbsa.org. use of resources so as to decouple economic growth from natural resource usage.

0957-1787/$ e see front matter Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2012.07.001
T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89 81

planners of and major investors in long-lived infrastructures.


Consequently, climate change must be a primary concern at both
national and local levels for devolved issues, when they come to
plan, design, build, operate and maintain infrastructures.
This paper does not directly address this very complex question
but simply tries to unravel the additional layer of complexity rep-
resented by climate change uncertainties. It argues that, while
climate change uncertainties are essential elements to be incor-
porated into the infrastructure planning, it cannot only be seen as
an addition to the current planning practices. Quite the reverse: the
planning process has to be entirely redefined to be able to
successfully integrate climate change uncertainties. It must be
noted that this paper, while presenting the necessary changes for
a more efficient infrastructure planning process, does not address
the governance issues related to integrated infrastructure planning
despite being a critical dimension for an efficient plan.
The next section explores the relationships between climate
change and long-lived infrastructure according to the different
types of direct and indirect uncertainties surrounding climate
Fig. 1. The universe of climate change impacts. Source: Author.
change. Section 3 addresses the importance of acknowledging
climate change as one of the components of the infrastructure
planning process and explains how this same process could be are simply irreducible; but they are needed to identify the universe,
reviewed to make it more responsive to the many uncertainties get a better understanding of the vulnerability of any climate-
surrounding our future, and climate change uncertainties in influenced decision, and subsequently guide actions. Consequently,
particular. Section 4 draws some policy implications to facilitate the any quest for certainty around climate change impacts might be
implementation of adaptive planning. Section 5 concludes on the elusive if the purpose were to stick to the current predict-and-act
various degrees of applicability of adaptive infrastructure planning approach (Lempert et al., 2004). As a consequence, this quest for
over the short to medium term. certainty should not delay actions; what is needed is to act now while
acknowledging these uncertainties.
2. Climate change uncertainties and infrastructure The second element which needs to be taken into account is the
time-lag. The ability to estimate and acknowledge the universe of
What is the relationship between long-lived infrastructures and possible changes is crucial, because of the time-lag between
climate change? Basically, the longer their lifespan, the higher the investment in infrastructures and the reduction of climate change
climate change’s impacts, and the lower the certainties about what uncertainties. Table 1 gives example of sectors potentially affected
these impacts will be and when they will happen. Indeed, we know by climate change where well-functioning infrastructures are key
that in the coming years and decades, sea levels will rise, extreme factors for efficient economic, social or environmental service
events will become more frequent and of higher magnitude, delivery: water, energy transport are but a few examples of sectors
temperature and rain patterns will evolve. But we do not really know which already are and will be impacted by climate changes albeit in
when all these changes are going to happen and with what intensity. different ways and at different levels.
For any infrastructure investment related to these sectors, the
2.1. Understanding the problem main question is: is the planned infrastructure going to be able to
deliver the level of services it has been built for in the long run, or is
Understanding the relationships between climate change and it going to suffer from climate change impacts up to the point of
long-lived infrastructure is crucial to be able to address the chal- becoming obsolete? Consequently, any decision of commissioning
lenges they entail. The first element to be underscored is the
difficulty to apprehend climate change uncertainties. Let’s assume
Table 1
it is possible to summarize climate change impacts using a single Long lived infrastructure and their vulnerability to climate change.
index. Then, Fig. 1 shows the range of possible impacts, as repre-
sented by the area between two arrows for each period T. Once the Sectors Time scale (years) Exposure

first period T has elapsed, a new range is estimated for the next one Economic and social buildings >20 þ
(e.g. factories, schools, hospitals)
T þ 1, i.e. each universe is approximated after taking into account
Water infrastructures (e.g. dams, 20e300 þþþ
new sets of information accumulated during previous periods. reservoirs, distribution networks)
Let’s take the first interval, from T1 to T2. We can see that the Land-use planning (e.g. in flood >100 þþþ
universe of potential impacts estimated in T1 is far too conservative, plain or coastal areas)
leading to a recorded climate change index for T2 out of the universe Coastline and flood defenses >50 þþþ
(e.g. dikes, sea walls)
foreseen at T1. This represents the worst scenario as it means that the Buildings (e.g. insulation, windows) 30e150 þþ
impacts occurring in T2 have not been anticipated at all. Now, looking Transportation infrastructure 30e200 þ
at T3 as another example, we can see that the angle between the two (e.g. port, bridges, roads,
arrows is wider than at T1 or T2. This expresses the possibility for railways, train stations)
Urban forms (e.g. urban >100 þ
additional information to increase the range of uncertainties around
density, parks)
potential climate change impacts. As mentioned by Dessai et al. Energy production and 20e70 þ
(2009: 112), “3 decades of research on climate sensitivity [.] have transportation (e.g. power
not reduced, but rather have increased, the uncertainty surrounding plants, cooling system,
the numerical range of this concept”. Additional information and distribution network)

modelling exercise will never eliminate uncertainties because many Source: Adapted from Hallegatte (2009: 241); Shalizi and Lecocq (2009: 4).
82 T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89

new infrastructure or retrofitting/repairing old ones should face one of the most carbon intensive economies in the world, Australia,
climate change uncertainties to be economically and socially sound. introduced a price on carbon. While there is no certainty about the
What are these uncertainties? generalization of carbon pricing, it appears highly likely that this
measure will spread across countries, especially because of the
2.2. Sources of climate change uncertainties growing concerns over the potential implementation of border tax
adjustments on imports of energy intensive goods by countries
Because of their highly visible consequences, extreme events imposing carbon pricing domestically.
tend to be the main concern of many stakeholders, be they inves- However, the real difficulty stems from the carbon market itself
tors, owners, service providers or users. However, extremes events which seeks to deal with an externality while a tax would be more
are but one dimension of the different uncertainties related to appropriate. It is then “a proxy market for an artificial commodity”
climate change. Other sources of uncertainties should not be since the price does not depend only on supply and demand but
overlooked. Fay et al. (2010) distinguish three different types of also on the regulations which define the parameters of the market
climate change related uncertainties: 1/those related to the impacts (Shalizi and Lecocq, 2009: 25). This new market is difficult to
of climate change on infrastructures, leading potentially to service comprehend fully for several reasons: the absence of long past
disruptions and damage to infrastructure; 2/uncertainties related price records, the uncertainties about policy options (tax vs
to the carbon intensity (building and/or operation) of infrastruc- market based price), the existence of different national and
tures, ultimately influenced by the price of fossil fuels and the price regional markets, or the incompleteness of the market itself (e.g.
of carbon; 3/those dealing with the technologies progressively futures market not deep enough) as the uncertainty about the
developed to address both carbon emission reduction and adap- future of the Kyoto protocol illustrates. Consequently, investors are
tation challenges. To these 3 sources, we add here another one engaging in a learning process at the same time as they have to
following Hallegatte et al. (2011): 4/the socio economic determi- make projections about the evolution of the market or the level of
nants, like the amount of greenhouse gas (GHG) emitted in the the tax, i.e. they have to speculate about future climate change
future or the capacity of societies to adapt. policies.
This is characteristic of the environment in which long term
2.2.1. Impacts of climate change investment decisions have to be made. Because climate change is
As mentioned before, traditional infrastructure investment an international issue, the only option to reduce policy uncertainty
decision making was based on the stationarity of the climate: the at national levels would be to have a long commitment period
characteristics of climate variables which impact on an infrastruc- (higher than 30 years) under the UNFCCC to properly include the
ture do not change over time, i.e. they will be the same in the future carbon constraint into long lived infrastructure investments
as they were in the past. Therefore, it was possible to calculate (Shalizi and Lecocq, 2009: 26).
tolerances, capacities and probabilities for extreme events, and This is particularly relevant for infrastructures with high carbon
then to craft a climate risk profile for any specific infrastructure. It content,2 as carbon price will have a direct financial impact, mainly
was deemed a reasonable assumption according to the lifespan of on the rate of return and the pay-back period. Consequently,
an infrastructure. Technical decisions were then made to make different perceptions on the future price of carbon might lead to
these infrastructures resilient to some of the risks according to their different strategies. For instance, utilities anticipating an increase in
likelihood and the costs of risk-proofing them. However, recent future carbon prices might favour low-carbon infrastructures, and
climate records prove that stationary is not an adequate assump- spurn high carbon ones, or at least add a premium related to the
tion anymore. “Stationarity is dead” stated Milly et al. (2008) who carbon content.
for instance showed that the stationary hypothesis can no longer be Another dimension should not be neglected: carbon intensive
used for water management decisions. This is true for the frequency infrastructure contributes to green house gas emissions, thus
and magnitude of extreme events but more broadly for any past sustaining the offsetting demand, leading to an increase of the price
climate pattern. of carbon. The spin-off effect will then affect the financial results of
Consequently, the first category of uncertainties refers to the the project by raising the long term price of carbon. The conse-
stochastic nature of climate patterns, and implies adaptation quences might be dramatic as the supply function is more likely to
measures to be developed and implemented. While climate change be exponential than linear.
is a global phenomenon, its impacts are local. What we know is The results of these uncertainties about the price of carbon
that, globally, temperature will increase, despite decreasing in might well be to make sure that long-lived infrastructures depend
some part of the world, with increased fluctuations over the as little as possible on carbon, be they in their construction or their
seasons, rainfall and temperature patterns will be modified, operation. Finally, while not mentioned by Fay et al. (2010), carbon
extreme events (floods, droughts, heat wave, frost, hurricanes, etc.) might not be the only issue. The price of all natural resources might
will be more frequent and of higher magnitude. However, what we be at stake, be they oil, coal, water, land, etc. Long-live infrastruc-
do not know is how, where, when and with what intensity these ture planning will have to take this into account, to make sure that
general features will translate at the local level. resources are used as efficiently as possible and with restraints to
make them last in the long term (UNEP, 2011).
2.2.2. Carbon price and natural resources
The introduction of a new commodity exclusively related to 2.2.3. Technology innovations
climate change is responsible for another source of uncertainties Innovations in climate friendly technology are another source of
about its short term volatility and its long term value: carbon. uncertainty. New technologies will probably emerge and influence
Carbon is already priced in some countries, either through a dedi-
cated market or through a taxation system. For instance, the
European Union launched its Emissions Trading Scheme in 2005,
2
which currently garners 30 countries, including 3 non member We here consider as part of the carbon content of an infrastructure, both carbon
emissions related to the construction of the infrastructure, including the use of high
countries, and represents the biggest carbon market in the world; carbon content materials, and carbon emissions related to the operation of the
while other countries, like Finland, Sweden, Norway, or New Zea- infrastructure, including high carbon content fuels. Consequently, capital and
land have chosen a carbon tax (Lin and Li, 2011: 5138). In July 2012, operational expenditures depend on both carbon price and content.
T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89 83

the demand for infrastructure. This raises several issues about the
strategy to adopt. Some technologies seem promising (e.g. hydrogen
technologies, enhanced geothermal systems, or tidal and wave
energy systems), but estimating their associated learning curve, and
thereby their deployment remains very difficult; some appear more
difficult to implement, but a breakthrough could change their
dissemination at any point in time (e.g. carbon capture and storage);
others do not exist today but may be discovered tomorrow. On the
contrary, current efficient technologies might become uncompeti-
tive in delivering a service, making the corresponding infrastructure
obsolete. If such a situation emerges before its economic life is over,
then massive financial losses could be recorded.
However, the relationship is highly asymmetric and investing in
low-carbon technology is often deemed riskier than investing in
carbon intensive projects because of the uncertainty around reli-
ability and deployment of low carbon technologies. While this lack
of track record encourages cautiousness about investing in low- Fig. 2. Relationships between adaptation, mitigation and the four sources of uncer-
tainties. Source: Author.
carbon technology, it is not clear whether we should differentiate
clean technology innovations from the current innovation dynamic
in other sectors. The answer lays in the stimuli for innovation. One efforts on climate change outcomes as part of this decision-making
of them should be the long term price of carbon. It should influence process. However, this trade-off is almost impossible to estimate
the rate of clean technology innovation (Fay et al., 2010: 38), if only because:
it were not so difficult to estimate in the long run.
1. as alluded to above, the global level of GHG depends on the
2.2.4. The socio-economic and environmental determinants global efforts and not only on those of the country;
Societies have already started to adapt to climate change and its 2. estimating adaptation costs is tremendously difficult due to
consequences, voluntarily or under compulsion. In Europe, the uncertainties about local impacts of climate change;
automotive sector has no choice but to develop increasingly lower 3. both adaptation and mitigation costs depend on technology
emitting vehicles following the introduction by the European innovations, which is the second source of uncertainty, and the
Parliament of regulations aiming at limiting pollutant emissions of socio-economic conditions;
motor vehicles; in China, green sectors like solar water heater 4. because of the different categories of uncertainties and the
production have taken off, pulled mainly by the domestic market, need to minimize conflicts between adaptation and mitigation,
to make China first in the world producer and now exporter of this some adaptation actions could be highly energy intensive, and
technology. The mass development of such technologies in turn therefore costly if the price of carbon increases (Hallegatte,
modifies the future emission profile of the country. These socio- 2009: 246);
economic determinants e mainly the capacity to adapt and the 5. the price of carbon, third source of uncertainty, might be an
future GHG emissions e are driven by many factors, be they incentive for further mitigation efforts, and at the same time,
demographic, economic, technologic, social or cultural, all of which for developing more efficient and less costly mitigation
are difficult to anticipate (Hallegatte et al., 2011). technologies;
6. as highlighted above, the socio-cultural and political impacts of
2.3. Uncertainties, interdependencies and planning decisions are hard to estimate given the uncertainties involved;
7. finally, all these dimensions are embedded into the socio-
2.3.1. Articulating climate change uncertainties economic determinants which determine the capacity to
The four uncertainties e impacts of climate change, price of adapt and to mitigate. These determinants are highly difficult
carbon, technology innovations and socio-economic determinants to anticipate and thereby constitute the fourth source of
e cannot be seen independently, quite the reverse. They interact in uncertainty.
a quite complex manner to influence mitigation and adaptation
efforts as shown in Fig. 2.3 As a result, these uncertainties e and the way they are dealt
The starting point is often the mitigation efforts, especially with e affect the decision making process at the project level, but
because it was the main focus of the UNFCCC international nego- first and foremost, the entire infrastructure planning process. It
tiations from the onset. These efforts determine the global level of underlines how important it is for the plan to be integrated. There is
future GHG emissions responsible for climate change e although no a two-way relationship between climate change and infrastructure:
clarity exists about the extent or occurrence of local impacts e first, how infrastructures are responsible for climate change;
which in turn affects adaptation requirements. At country level, the second, how climate change impacts on infrastructures. For
government should carry out an arbitrage operation between instance, lots of infrastructures are responsible for direct or indirect
today’s mitigation efforts and tomorrow’s adaptation efforts based emission, reduction or capture of green house gases. Coal power
on the marginal costs of each intervention, which itself depends on stations or fossil fuel-based transport infrastructures are examples
today’s and tomorrow’s socio-economic conditions. Countries of infrastructures leading to CO2 emissions. Public transports,
would most likely wish to estimate the impact of local mitigation energy efficient buildings, or renewable energy power stations are
examples of infrastructures responsible for a reduction of CO2
emissions compared to business-as-usual scenarios. Parks, forests
3
Adaptation is defined as an “adjustment in natural or human systems in conservation, and capture and storage facilities contribute to the
response to actual or expected climatic stimuli or their effects, which moderates
harms or exploits beneficial opportunities”, while mitigation corresponds to “a
decrease of CO2 concentration in the atmosphere. They are all part
human intervention to reduce the sources or enhance the sinks of greenhouse and parcel of mitigation/adaptation framework and should not be
gases”. http://unfccc.int/essential_background/glossary/items/3666.php. seen separately. The then crucial planning questions which need to
84 T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89

be answered are what to do and when, in terms of both mitigation poorly as a result, and unplanned ad-hoc adaptations are needed to
and adaptation. rectify this” (Kwakkel and van der Pas, 2011: 2). Indeed, this
method has worked well enough up-to-now as the traditional
2.3.2. Planning long-lived infrastructure under climate change uncertainties e such as the future of the economy, external shocks
uncertainties or technology changes just to name a few e have barely led to swift
Utilities do not always operate in isolation where public interest or large enough changes to substantially question the efficiency of
long-lived infrastructures are concerned. They mainly respond to the investments, and thereby the very nature of the long-lived infra-
vision set by the government in terms of what and when services structure planning process (Lempert and Groves, 2010: 961).4
should be provided, and what and when infrastructure must be In classic predict-and-act approach, climate was paradoxically
maintained, repaired or (re)built to provide the desired level of considered as one of the rare stable parameters which could be used
services. Consequently, the planning process is a crucial first step. for planning. However, now, climate change is a worldwide
And this process must take into consideration climate change phenomenon with potential dramatic effects. There is no way the
uncertainties identified earlier. This is particularly true in developing infrastructure planning process can ignore it (Lempert and
and emerging countries and regions where infrastructure needs are Schlesinger, 2000). As a consequence, climate change can be seen
huge, where resources are scarce, and where investments must as a real opportunity to move towards new planning approaches
happen immediately or in the very near future. As shown by Shalizi capable of integrating any kind of uncertainties, including climate
and Lecocq (2009: 5e6), at the national level most of the long-lived change related ones. This section seeks to unravel how the inte-
investments happen in a very short period of time e what they call grated planning process could heed of climate change uncertainties
the lumpiness of capacity installation. This leads to path dependency for greater efficiency in service delivery for long-lived infrastructure.
or lock-ins, be they in terms of GHG emissions and/or vulnerability to
climate change impacts of the technology used. The reasons might
be the high costs of retrofitting, of premature retirement or of 3.1. Creating information to grasp uncertainties
switching to another facility once one is installed. Furthermore,
future investments might be compelled by these initial disburse- There is no doubt that the climate is changing; we are just
ments, thus further strengthening the lock-in process. struggling to anticipate how these changes will translate at the
Countries ought to get their infrastructure investment plan right local level and what their impacts will be in the coming days,
to lay down the foundations of their sustained development: weeks, months and years. As a result, the actual impacts of climate
priorities must be set, trade-offs and decision made for critical change might well be overlooked (Hallegatte, 2007). That is why
infrastructure investments, in an external environment fraught with the level and quality of information which might contribute to
climate uncertainties which do not get along with long-lived capital closing uncertainty gaps become crucial.
stocks such as infrastructure investments. What is to be done? Two Information gathering and utilisation take different forms
extreme situations can be identified (PWC, 2010: 17). One would be depending on which one of the previously described four climate
to delay the decision to a point where sufficient evidence exists for change related uncertainties are considered. First, to be able to
the decision to be considered well-informed. The other option would reduce uncertainties about the impacts of climate change and
consist in ignoring the uncertainties, because of the lack of knowl- determine new probability distributions for climate patterns and
edge or tools to incorporate these uncertainties in the decision events implies a better understanding of 1/the potential changes in
making process. An alternative would be to over-engineer tolerances occurrence and magnitude of extreme events; 2/the changes in the
for a variety of potential outcomes at greater expense. None of them pace/speed of incremental changes. Many climate change models
are actually conceivable. Delaying the decision is impossible in have been developed around the world (IPCC, 2007) to improve
emerging countries where the needs for new infrastructure are huge information around the local consequences of climate change, and
and represent a crucial prerequisite for poverty reduction, service new generations of models are underway.5 Thereby, identification
delivery and future growth. Not taking into account climate change of climate change variables, and historic data can be used as
uncertainties might have disastrous consequences for any invest- a benchmark with the inclusion of widening deviation from the
ment in long-lived infrastructure. Overspending is not an option benchmark overtime, which captures direct, interdependent and
either in countries where public resources are already scarce. systemic risks (related to the weakest link within systems) like
Consequently, the entire planning process for infrastructure devel- rising sea level, droughts/water scarcity/water saving, floods, heat
opment has to face these uncertainties. waves, frosts, air acidification/corrosion, etc.
Secondly, and probably even more difficult to address, are the
3. Innovative solutions for better planning climate technology risks. What will the climate technologies of
tomorrow be? At stake is the creation of knowledge about what is
Climate change brings to the fore new uncertainties which just technically possible today and what will be possible tomorrow for
add up to an already challenging infrastructure planning process both mitigation and adaptation. Several initiatives are underway to
fraught with many other social, economic and environmental try to fill this gap.
uncertainties operating in a complex world. In the past, all these Thirdly, the evolution of carbon price depends on too many
uncertainties have been largely ignored by planners due to the unknowns to be forecast. For instance, the introduction of a carbon
difficulty to integrate them in the planning process. Instead, past tax is a move in the right direction to avoid reliance on external
records have been used to evaluate the likelihood of diverse events, price setting mechanisms, such as border carbon tax adjustments
thereby transforming uncertainties into risks. Consequently, the on imports. However, while this tax is set to internalize an envi-
planning process was, and in many cases still is, based on the ronmental externality, it should also correct another market
predict-and-act approach which generates a recommended
optimum response: the estimated future values of a set of param-
4
This is not true for more short-sighted planning processes, especially for
eters are used to predict what the future will be, and the optimum
business activities, where uncertainties caused a lot of ink to flow. See for instance
infrastructures are defined according to this forecasting model. Schwartz (1998), Taleb (2008) or Goodwin and Wright (2010).
“Any infrastructure plan designed on the basis of one or a few 5
See for instance Moss et al. (2010) for a summary of past climate change
forecasts or a small set of assumptions about the future performs modelling exercises and new prospects.
T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89 85

weakness: its short-sightedness. The carbon tax ought to be clear sanitation, energy, education, health, land, financial services). This
about the future: is the tax transitory or long-lasting? What will be strategic vision will allow anticipating infrastructure needs to
taxed and how? When will it be revised and how? etc. In other facilitate and support the development process.
words, a carbon tax should be established as an adaptive policy as Notably, the national government should clearly isolate what
described in Section 3.3 below, with simple and transparent sign- the critical long term infrastructures are. In doing so, it should
posts which might trigger mitigation, hedging, corrective and differentiate between existing and new infrastructures. These two
defensive actions, as well as criteria for reassessment. categories cannot be treated in the same way. While every new
Of course, one cannot expect these new knowledge, information infrastructure should seek an acceptable level of climate resilience,
and modelling results to eliminate uncertainties. Indeed, improved this is not necessarily the case for the existing one for at least two
knowledge does not necessarily mean a narrower projection. This is reasons: 1/the costs of climate-proofing these infrastructures might
true for climate impacts because: 1/“the projections of different be extremely high compared to the services this infrastructure is
climate models do not seem to be diminishing with time” [.], 2/ expected to provide overtime; 2/economic, social and environ-
“Climate models are based on a set of common assumptions. The mental services vary considerably between different infrastruc-
range of their results underestimates the full range of uncertainties” tures, some being more critical than others, i.e. economic, social
[.], 3/“observations can be dangerously misleading: worst-case and environmental consequences following a disruption of opera-
scenarios can arise from difficulty in attributing observed changes tion differ between infrastructures, according to their type, local-
to climate change” (Hallegatte, 2009: 242). This is also true for the isation, size, etc. Consequently, the assessment process should
other sources of uncertainties. Furthermore, “gathering information identify, according to a fairly precise timeframe:
incurs a cost, and given the high level of uncertainty around climate
change, significant investment in information gathering does not - Infrastructures to be maintained to ensure their full operation
ensure the complete resolution of uncertainty” (PWC, 2010: 20). in the long term (avoid deficiencies);
Finally, the many methods that exist to reduce uncertainties and - Infrastructures to be retrofitted to accommodate an increase of
thereby anticipate unexpected events (be they extreme weather the demand of services they need to provide (avoid
events, rollout of new technologies, fluctuations of carbon price, or deficiencies);
economic downturns) do not seem capable of obtaining well- - Infrastructure to be built to respond to new needs (avoid gaps).
calibrated probabilities (Goodwin and Wright, 2010).
Consequently, generating and making use of information are The timeframe issue is here crucial, knowing that building
necessary conditions for improved planning that countries need to infrastructures could take up to ten years and more, and that new or
pursue, but they are surely not sufficient. What these new models retrofitted infrastructure must provide the right level of service at
and observations ought to do is to help the planners to better the right time:
understand the range and feature of these uncertainties, and
integrate them into the planning process. Being able to grasp these - too early a move into operation is responsible for over-capacity,
uncertainties will only make a difference if decision makers are able leading to extra-costs in term of maintenance, while the
to amend the planning process and make it capable of heeding infrastructure is under-utilized; being operational too late is
these uncertainties (Hallegatte, 2009: 242). responsible for hampering the development process.
- An under-calibrated infrastructure acts as a break on the
3.2. Acknowledging climate change as part of the planning process development process, while over-calibrating leads to
economic, social and environmental inefficiencies.
In developing countries where infrastructure needs are impor-
tant, where governments are committed to invest massively in Furthermore, infrastructures cannot be seen in isolation as their
infrastructure development, there is little room for manoeuvre to full effectiveness depends on the adequate operation of the many
influence the way new infrastructures will be designed: as under- others surrounding it. These interdependencies, on which effi-
lined by Shalizi and Lecocq (2009: 2) “this highlights the impor- ciencies in service delivery are based, command a special attention
tance of limited windows of opportunity to shift from high-carbon to to the spatial distribution of these infrastructures. This implies that
low-carbon long-lived capital stock where appropriate alternatives interdependent infrastructures should be located at the right place,
are or can be made available.” and be operational at the right time. Thus, the spatial dimension
becomes especially important as it will frame the distribution of
3.2.1. Defining a long term strategic vision economic activities, the use of natural resources, the development
“Long-term infrastructure planning is commonly deployed of markets, the efficiency of the socio-economic system (Turok,
throughout regulated utilities, whereby incremental infrastructure 2011); and consequently the sustainability of a society.
follows a Long-Term Investment Plan (LTIP) which provides
a framework for investment over a period of 20e40 years into the 3.2.2. Impacts of climate change uncertainties
future” (PWC, 2010: 20). Consequently, making infrastructure Once the needs have been identified in terms of both quantity
resilient to climate change is tightly connected to development and localization, decisions have to be made about the best way to
planning: one needs to understand and put forward a strategic respond to these needs. Critical infrastructures ought to be iden-
vision of what the development dynamic is going to be in the tified and a build and maintenance program planned. The main
coming years, so as to identify what the infrastructure needs will difficulty is that climate change influences the entire framework, at
be, including their spatial distribution. each and every stage of the planning process, including the needs.
The starting point of the planning process is for governments, Consequently, climate change uncertainties have to be part and
whether national or local, to set the strategic vision for the future of parcel of the strategic vision. The task is highly complex: “Infra-
their country, province, or municipality. They need to be clear about structures are a complex web of public and private assets, created
what kind of medium and long term development path they fore- and operated within layers of government that have varying
see (e.g. structure of the economy, poverty and inequality targets, jurisdiction over their locations, design, pricing, accessibility and
natural capital protection, urban vs rural population), and what general operation. How can anyone coherently address such real-
developmental goals they seek to achieve (e.g. access to water and world complexity?” (Hansman et al., 2006: 148).
86 T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89

Fig. 3 uses the assessment process for infrastructure planning classic planning from the outset to introduce flexibility and adap-
recently used by the Australian Government to illustrate this tiveness/correctability into the process itself.
complexity (GoAus, 2009, 2010). Climate change impacts the
planning process at different stages: 3.3.1. Dynamic adaptive planning in theory
Such an approach is based on the work developed around the
- Climate change must be embedded into the long-term strategic concept of adaptive policy. Defining policy as adaptive means that
vision of the Government. Lots of developed and emerging this policy “is devised not to be optimal for a best estimate future,
countries are looking towards green growth as one option for but robust across a range of plausible futures” and “responds to
long term development, placing the transition to a low-carbon changes over time and makes explicit provision for learning”
economy at the heart of their vision. The direct implication is (Walker et al., 2001: 283). It acknowledges the “high degree of
decoupling their growth trajectory from the use of any natural interconnectedness and dynamic consequences” in a world where
resources, including fossil fuels (Winkler and Marquand, 2009; “unpredictability and the presence of unknown unknowns are the
UNEP, 2011). The degree of integration of climate change underlying traits” (Swanson et al., 2010: 926).
concerns into the strategic vision of the government shapes the These new planning methods call for different kinds of infor-
demand for infrastructure, and therefore influences the defi- mation compared to what a probabilistic optimization process
nition of goals; requires. What is at stake is not to translate uncertainties into risks,
- Climate change uncertainties are additional to the traditional but to “provide the range of what is possible and of what is
sources of uncertainty which influence the way the problem is probable, and quantitative information about when observations
framed, and probably the most important one: “climate change will be able to discriminate between several scenarios” (Hallegatte,
might result in irreversible damage. Due to uncertainty over 2009).
tipping points (after which climate stresses have irreversible Drawing heavily on Walker et al. (2001: 285e287) and their
consequences) and low-probability catastrophic events, delay- concept of adaptive policy, we can outline how an adaptive plan-
ing decisions might lead to irreversible damage” (PWC, 2010: ning process could be designed and lead to a dynamic adaptive plan
20). However, as previously mentioned, they are not the only for infrastructure development, i.e. a plan which can evolve over
ones; many uncertainties are actually overlooked during the time according to the permanent flow of information generation
planning process. Climate change can be seen as an opportunity that feeds the planning process. Fig. 4 presents a five-stage adaptive
to review how the problem assessment is conducted. planning process which can be described as follows. The first two
- The options coming out of the analysis have numerous impli- stages have been developed in previous sections and are merely
cations in terms of location of the infrastructures, their design, skimmed over:
the way they are going to be built, their operational capacity
and efficiency, and the level of maintenance required. For each 1. Long-term vision: the starting point is the long-term vision the
of them, the potential impact of climate change should be government has defined for the country taking into account,
taken into account and the timing of the intervention should be among others, new uncertainties created by climate change.
determined. Consequently, “the analysis requires a good 2. Evidence-based assessment: from this vision, infrastructure
understanding of when the cut-off points will occur. An inac- requirements are determined. Several options can be defined to
curate estimate of these points would ultimately affect the meet these requirements; the government will then decide
outcomes of the appraisal” (PWC, 2010: 20). which one seems the most appropriate.
- Finally, the solutions identified ought to integrate different 3. Implementation plan: the expected outcomes are clearly
mitigation and adaptation options. framed, and the plan is implemented.
4. The implementation plan includes a contingency plan with
3.3. Introducing flexibility and adaptiveness into the planning different types of adaptive measures to ensure the infrastruc-
process ture requirements are met (Walker et al., 2001: 285). They

Once the uncertainties around climate change have been


acknowledged, the planning process needs to move away from

Fig. 3. Infrastructure need assessment and the influence of climate change Source: Fig. 4. A dynamic adaptive integrated infrastructure planning process. Source:
Adapted from GoAus (2010). Adapted from Walker et al. (2001: 286).
T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89 87

must be explicit from the outset to avoid any forced review planning method and what could be an extremely complex
process happening on an ad hoc e and therefore uncertain e dynamic adaptive planning approach, it is possible to identify
basis. These measures will then be triggered as and when several thrusts which could be followed both by national and local
needed, according to the availability of information: governments.
a. Mitigation actions: actions taken in advance to reduce First, despite many endeavours to gather observations and
certain adverse effects which were anticipated but not design more accurate models, the four sources of uncertainties will
certain at the planning stage; persist in the coming decades. As a consequence, what any infra-
b. Hedging actions: actions taken in advance to reduce the risk structure plan should do is to acknowledge these uncertainties,
of possible adverse effects that have newly been identified; identify the resulting vulnerabilities, and anticipate what should be
c. Defensive measures: actions taken after a risk materialized done when these uncertainties materialise. Mainstreaming climate
but the damages are such that the plan does not need to be change into the three spheres of government is a means to put
modified; pressure on decision makers and force them to consider climate
d. Corrective actions: actions taken after a risk materialized change uncertainties.
but the damages are such that part of the plan has to be Secondly, because identifying vulnerabilities requires an
modified; assessment of a variety of futures, scenario planning becomes an
e. Reassessment: the plan is clearly not working and needs to important tool to introduce adaptiveness and flexibility into the
be reassessed. The government has no options than to planning process. Scenario planning is a complex matter which has
redefine its vision and the new infrastructure requirements. known many developments over the past decades and many
5. Monitoring, continuous learning and improvement: signposts methodologies have emerged (Bradfield et al., 2005). The core steps
e defined as unintended social economic and environmental of the scenario planning process remain the identification of
impacts e and outcomes are monitored to identify successes, (Schwartz, 1998: 101e117; Swanson et al., 2010: 928e929):
vulnerabilities and failures. They are responsible for triggering
adaptive measures if the recorded impacts fail to meet the - the driving forces or most important factors influencing the
expected outcomes. planning process (society, economics, technology, politics, and
environment);
Thereby, adaptive integrated infrastructure planning moves - the predetermined factors that are most certain and can be
away from the mere prediction and control paradigm to embrace treated as risks if necessary;
a “learning by judicious doing” approach to avoid any catastrophic - the critical uncertainties which will constitute the focus of the
and irreversible error (Swanson et al., 2010: 925). As a result, scenario analysis.
because of the deep uncertainties about climate change and the
impossibility to get a consensus around them, the contingency Scenario planning appears to be a dedicated tool for national
plan becomes the crucial element to which decision makers integrated infrastructure planning: critical infrastructure needs
will converge and place their confidence in since it is designed must be identified; major risks, uncertainties and vulnerabilities
to respond to any kind of future climate (Lempert and Groves, assessed; technology choices set; spatial build and maintenance
2010: 961). programmes defined; contingency plans drawn; learning process
Robust decision-making (RDM) seems a promising tool to define included. The government should send clear signals about how
adaptive strategies. The basic idea is to confront a policy to a large important a climate resilient infrastructure is. This has to be
variety of different future scenarios to evaluate its performance, translated into regulations, policies, guidelines and operating
making RDM a synthesis between scenario planning and quanti- frameworks to facilitate the planning process at local level.
tative analysis (Lempert and Schlesinger, 2000: 391). Lempert and Once the national plan is well-established, the tasks of local
Groves (2010: 961) define RDM as follows: “RDM is a particular authorities could become much easier as the main concerns will
approach of a broader class of robust decision methods. In contrast then be related to uncertainties around climate impacts. A well-
to many decision analytic approaches, these methods treat uncer- defined accompanying programme would be a crucial asset to
tainty with multiple, rather than single, views of the future and facilitate the inclusion of adaptation plan into local infrastructure
evaluates alternative strategies with a robustness, rather than an development plans. According to Ford et al. (2011: 336), institu-
optimality, criterion.” Lempert and Groves (2010) applied this tional guidelines and governmental mechanisms are the most
methodology to a water utilities agency in the US. They identified common programmes implemented in developed countries to
a set of long term uncertainties, including climate change, and used facilitate adaptations at local levels.
them to define numerous plausible scenarios. They then ran the The real challenge is then to make sure that local authorities
scenarios against the initial static capital improvement plan of the will actually consider both climate change uncertainties and its
agency, and against different adaptive strategies. They demon- consequences, and the available tools to deal with them.
strated that adaptive strategies significantly reduced the occur- Reviewing the literature on adaptation actions undertaken by
rence of both high water supply and water shortage costs over time developed countries to cope with climate change, Ford et al. (2011:
compared to the initial static plan, and were able to identify 334e335) found that discourses are seldom translated into
a strategy specific to this water utilities agency able to eliminate concrete action: “A major challenge highlighted in a number of
most of the vulnerabilities. articles concerns the lack of political will to meaningfully address
climate change impacts, particularly at local levels where
3.3.2. Operationalising adaptive planning a mismatch between national statements on adaptation and local
New planning methods which seek to address deep uncer- action has been noted. In such cases adaptation interventions have
tainties such as those related to climate change are very appealing preferred short term risk reduction over long term strategic
on paper, but rarely applied in practice. Several reasons could be planning, potentially increasing vulnerability and making future
put forward such as the limited assessment of the validity and adaptation more difficult. Institutional barriers along with limited
applicability of these new planning approaches (Kwakkel and van consideration of future climate scenarios in adaptation interven-
der Pas, 2011: 2) or the limits of forecasting methods (Goodwin & tion, create potential for maladaptation.” Such challenges must
Wright). However, between a too simplistic predict-and-act not be overlooked.
88 T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89

3.4. Climate resilient decision making options

Ultimately, the adaptive planning process leads to investment


decisions. Several options are available to cope with uncertainties
related to climate change (Hallegatte, 2009: 244e246; PWC,
2010: 42) as pictured in Fig. 5:

- No (or low) regret options: the purpose is to find solutions


which are not climate sensitive or which are “judged to provide
sufficient or alternative benefits regardless of the outcome of
the climate scenario measures” (PWC, 2010: 42). While
appealing in theory, there are not many options in practice.
- Reversible and flexible options: this strategy is closely linked to
the decision pathway or “real option approach” (ROA) which
emphasizes the possibility to delay a decision. “Adopting
a decision pathway or having a ‘real option’ means building in
the possibility at a certain period in the lifetime of a project to
make a decision without committing to this at the beginning. In
practice, the decision pathway approach and ROA incorporate
a dynamic learning mechanism which provides the opportu- Fig. 5. Generic climate resilient planning process and climate resilient options. Source:
nity to phase investments and stage key decisions, to assess the Author.
costs and benefits of options at a later stage, for example by:
B Investing now and making follow-up investments later, 4. Policy implications
subject to the progress of the original project (a growth
option); Planning methods for long-lived infrastructure have to be
B Abandoning the project if losses outweigh the benefits revisited to take heed of the different sources of uncertainty related
(an exit option); and to global warming. Policy makers have important roles to support
B Waiting and learning before investing (a timing option).” the progressive implementation of climate resilient planning
(PWC, 2010: 43) approaches. The first one refers to the ability of national govern-
- Safety margin options: these strategies are based on the fact ments to set an integrated strategic vision for the country and thus
that the costs of integrating climate concerns during the design identify the long-term needs for public services. Critical infra-
phase of an infrastructure project might be far lower than structures could then be identified as priorities for maintenance,
modifying it once it has been built. The cost of including this retrofitting and construction. To sustain long-term service delivery,
security margin is the key determinant of the decision, and the these uncertainties, together with more classical planning deter-
trade-off has to be between this cost and the reversibility of the minants, should influence investment choices at all levels, whether
decision, i.e. one might accept a higher cost when the decision these investments are the responsibility of national, provincial, or
is irreversible. local departments, or national or local utilities.
- Soft options with limited hard consequences: it relates to the This is why a second crucial task for policy makers is to main-
use of institutional and financial tools instead of heavy stream climate change into the different spheres of government
investments. Insurance and early warning and evacuation and to sensitize regulators and utilities to the importance of inte-
systems are the two most common soft options; only insurance grating climate uncertainties into the planning process. Govern-
can actually be applied to infrastructure. The main advantage is ments should foster the provision of relevant information to help
the flexibility of the system as insurance premium are defined stakeholders better understand the real challenges of climate
every year and can be adjusted accordingly. The trade-off for change in an integrated manner, and make sure that remaining
using a soft option is between the economic, social and envi- uncertainties are fully acknowledged. Efforts are underway to close
ronmental consequences of having an infrastructure damaged these knowledge gaps (on both the level and quality of informa-
and the service disrupted to which the insurance premium tion), and thereby improve the characterisation of climate uncer-
must be added, and the costs of protecting this infrastructure. tainties. However, information provision is not sufficient.
- Reduced investment’s lifetime option: the level of uncertainty Guidelines, operating frameworks, regulations or policies might be
about climate change increases with time. Building infrastruc- required to boost the implementation of adaptive planning, and
ture which will provide a service for only ten years might be make sure that short-term risks are not favoured and long-term
more interesting than building another infrastructure designed climate uncertainties neglected.
to provide the same service for 50 years but which might fail. Finally, policy makers ought to send the right signals about the
- ‘winewin’ options: the objective is to respond to climate importance of climate change for the country. This implies to mini-
change while, at the same time, providing one or several other mize uncertainties on which they have some influence. For instance
services. Thereby, the cost of climate change actions is miti- setting a price for carbon e through a carbon tax for instance e forces
gated by the costs of not having to provide the joint services, decision makers to take into account the carbon content of their
rendering these climate change measures more acceptable. infrastructure. However, at the same time, policy makers ought to
Another winewin situation occurs when infrastructure clarify the different options about the long term evolution of this tax
changes act both as mitigation and adaptation options. so has to reduce long term uncertainty around carbon pricing.
Hallegatte (2009: 246) mentions building insulation as both an
adaptation measure to temperature changes (long lasting frosts 5. Conclusion
or heatwaves) and a mitigation measure as it will lead to
energy savings, especially when this energy has high carbon Adaptive planning is quite a recent field of work. Further
content. research is needed to fully understand how such an approach could
T. Giordano / Utilities Policy 23 (2012) 80e89 89

be efficiently adapted and used. Nevertheless, it is true to say that GoAus (Government of Australia), 2009. National Infrastructure Priorities e Infra-
structure for an Economically, Socially, and Environmentally Sustainable Future,
climate change is posing a great challenge to long-lived infra-
Canberra, May, 38 p. http://www.infrastructureaustralia.gov.au/publications/
structure investments, as the level of uncertainty surrounding its files/National_Infrastructure_Priorities.pdf.
impacts cannot be compared to any other source of uncertainty. As GoAus (Government of Australia), 2010. Better Infrastructure Decision-Making:
a consequence, the infrastructure planning process has to be Guidelines for Making Submissions to Infrastructure Australia’s Infrastructure
Planning Process, through Infrastructure Australia’s Reform and Investment
profoundly revisited. We have highlighted the different sources of Framework, October, 24 p. http://www.infrastructureaustralia.gov.au/reform_
uncertainty related to climate change and explained why the classic investment/files/Better_Infrastructure_Decision_Making_Guidelines.pdf.
predict-and-act approach appears highly questionable. Goodwin, P., Wright, G., 2010. The limits of forecasting methods in anticipating rare
events. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 77, 355e368.
Several measures could be taken to improve the planning Hallegatte, S., 2007. Do current assessments underestimate future damages from
process. First, there is a need to gather as much information as climate change? World Economics 8 (3), 131e146.
possible, at national and local level, to determine what we know Hallegatte, S., 2009. Strategies to adapt to uncertain climate change. Global Envi-
ronmental Change 19, 240e247.
and what we don’t know about climate change, and thereby Hallegatte, S., Przyluski, V., Vogt-Schlib, A., 2011. Building world narrative for
capturing the different sources of uncertainties. climate change impact, adaptation and vulnerability analyses. Nature Climate
Secondly, once characterised, the importance of dealing with Change 1, 151e155.
Hansman, R.J., Magee, C., de Neufville, R., Robins, R., Roos, D., 2006. Research agenda
these uncertainties must be acknowledged as an integral part of the for an integrated approach to infrastructure planning, design and management.
planning process and therefore be part and parcel of the strategic International Journal of Critical Infrastructures 2 (2/3), 146e159.
long-term vision for the country. Scenario planning forms the IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change), 2007. Climate Change 2007,
Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
mainstay for evaluating policies according to several plausible
Cambridge University Press.
futures. Robust decision-making, which couples scenario planning Kwakkel, J., van der Pas, J.W.GH.M., 2011. Evaluation of infrastructure planning
and quantitative analysis might then be a powerful tool to measure approaches: an analogy with medicine. Futures 43 (9), 934e946.
the performance of various investment plans and to design coping Lempert, R.J., Groves, D.G., 2010. Identifying and evaluating robust adaptive policy
responses to climate change for water management agencies in the American
strategies. west. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 77, 960e974.
Thirdly, the planning process ought to demonstrate a high level Lempert, R.J., Schlesinger, M.E., 2000. Robust strategies for abating climate change.
of flexibility over time to be able to respond to these uncertainties. Climatic Change 45, 387e401.
Lempert, R.J., Nakicenovic, N., Sarewitz, D., Schlesinger, M., 2004. Characterizing
Such an aspiration could easily turn out to be too complex to be climate-change uncertainties for decision-makers. Climatic Change 65, 1e9.
fully operationalised in the short term; what is actually reasonable Lin, B., Li, X., 2011. The effect of carbon tax on per capita CO2 emissions. Energy
to expect as first steps has to be highlighted. Policy 39 (9), 5137e5146.
Milly, P.C.D., Betancourt, J., Falkenmark, M., Hirsch, R.M., Kundzewicz, Z.W.,
Finally, this adaptive plan should translate into concrete climate Lettenmaier, D.P., Stouffer, R.J., 2008. Stationarity is dead: whither water
resilient investment decisions to limit potential negative impacts or management? Science 319, 573e574.
exploit potential positive impacts of climate change on the quality Moss, R.H., Edmonds, J.A., Hibbard, K.A., Mannong, M.R., Rose, S.K., van Vuuren, D.P.,
Carter, T.R., Emori, S., Kainuma, M., Kram, T., Meehl, G.A., Mitchell, J.F.B.,
and level of services that long-lived infrastructures have been Nakicenovic, N., Riahi, K., Smith, S.J., Stouffer, R.J., Thomson, A.M., Weyant, J.P.,
planned to provide. Wilbanks, T.J., 2010. The next generation of scenarios for climate change
However, policy makers have a crucial role to play in supporting research and assessment. Nature 463, 747e756.
PWC (PricewaterhouseCoopers), 2010. Adapting to Climate Change in the Infra-
the inclusion of climate change uncertainties into long term
structure Sectors e Maintaining Robust and Resilient Infrastructure Systems in
infrastructure planning. From information provision to the defini- the Energy, Transport, Water and ICT Sectors. http://archive.defra.gov.uk/
tion of appropriate policies, they should send the right signals for environment/climate/documents/infrastructure-pwc-full.pdf.
other stakeholders responsible for service delivery, whether public Schwartz, P., 1998. The Art of Long View e Planning for the Future in an Uncertain
World. John Wiley & Sons Ltd, Chichester.
or private, to progressively adopt adaptive planning approaches: an Shalizi, Z., Lecocq, F., 2009. Climate Change and the Cconomics of Targeted Miti-
efficient climate change mainstreaming strategy among the three gation in Sectors with Long-lived Capital Stock, World Bank, Policy Research
spheres of government, an adapted institutional framework, and Working Paper 5063, Background Paper to the 2010 World Development
Report, 39 p. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/84797-
a comprehensive set of regulations and guidelines would greatly 1257266550602/Lecocq.pdf.
facilitate the inclusion of climate change concerns into planning Swanson, D., Barg, S., Tyler, S., Venema, H., Tomar, S., Bhadwal, S., Nair, S., Roy, D.,
processes for local infrastructure. Drexhage, J., 2010. Seven tools for creating adaptive policies. Technological
Forecasting and Social Change 77 (6), 924e939.
Taleb, N.N., 2008. The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable. Pinguin
References Books, London.
Turok, I., 2011. The Case for a National Spatial Vision. Mimeo. February 1st.
Bradfield, R., Wright, G., Brut, G., Cairns, G., van der Heijden, K., 2005. The origins UNEP (United Nations Environment Programme), 2011. Decoupling Natural
and evolution of scenario techniques in long range business planning. Futures Resource Use and Environmental Impacts from Economic Growth. A Report of
37, 795e812. the Working Group on Decoupling to the International Resource Panel. Fischer-
Dessai, S., Hulme, M., Lempert, R., Pielke, R., 2009. Do we need better predictions to Kowalski, M., Swilling, M., von Weizsäcker, E.U., Ren, Y., Moriguchi, Y., Crane, W.,
adapt to a changing climate? Eos 90 (13), 111e112 31 March. Krausmann, F., Eisenmenger, N., Giljum, S., Hennicke, P., Romero Lankao, P.,
Fay, M., Limi, A., Perrissin-Fabert, B., 2010. Financing greener and climate-resilient Siriban Manalang, A. http://www.unep.org/resourcepanel/decoupling/files/pdf/
infrastructure in developing countries e challenges and opportunities. EIB Decoupling_Report_English.pdf.
Papers 15 (2), 35e58. http://www.eib.org/attachments/efs/eibpapers/ Walker, W.E., Rahman, S.A., Cave, J., 2001. Adaptive policies, policy analysis, and
eibpapers_2010_v15_n02_en.pdf#page=36. policy making. European Journal of Operational Research 128, 282e289.
Ford, J.D., Berrang-Ford, L., Paterson, J., 2011. A systematic review of observed Winkler, H., Marquand, A., 2009. Changing development paths: from an energy-
climate change adaptation in developed nations. Climatic Change 106, intensive to low-carbon economy in South Africa. Climate and Development
327e336. 1, 47e65.

You might also like