You are on page 1of 14

American Economic Association

Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental Approach


Author(s): Colin Camerer and Dan Lovallo
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 1 (Mar., 1999), pp. 306-318
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/116990 .
Accessed: 25/06/2014 08:47

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Overconfidence and Excess Entry:An Experimental Approach

By COLIN CAMERER AND DAN LOVALLO*

Psychological studies show that most peo- ple, using plant-level data from the U.S. Cen-
ple are overconfident about their own relative sus of Manufacturers spanning 1963 -1982,
abilities, and unreasonably optimistic about Timothy Dunne et al. (1988) estimated that
their futures (e.g., Neil D. Weinstein, 1980; 61.5 percent of all entrants exited within five
Shelly E. Taylor and J. D. Brown, 1988). years and 79.6 percent exited within ten years.
When assessing their position in a distribution Most of these exits are failures (see also Dan-
of peers on almost any positive trait-like iel Shapiro and R. S. Khemani, 1987; Dunne
driving ability (Ola Svenson, 1981), income et al., 1989a, b; Paul A. Geroski, 1991; John
prospects, or longevity-a vast majority of R. Baldwin, 1995).
people say they are above the average, al- Some possible explanationsfor the high rate
though of course, only half can be (if the trait of business failure are reviewed below. In this
is symmetrically distributed).' paper we consider the hypothesis that business
This paper explores whether optimistic bi- failureis a result of managersacting on the op-
ases could plausibly and predictablyinfluence timism about relative skill they exhibit in sur-
economic behavior in one particularsetting- veys (e.g., James March and Zur Shapira,
entry into competitive games or markets. 1987). This hypothesis is wortthexploring be-
Many empirical studies show that most new cause it is consistentwith so muchpsychological
businesses fail within a few years. For exam- evidence, and because optimisticoverentrywill
persistif the perfornance feedbacknecessaryto
correctit is relativelynoisy, infrequent,or slow.
* Camerer:Division of the Humanities and Social Sci- The idea that overconfidencecauses business
ences 228-77, California Institute of Technology, Pasa- entry mistakes has, of course, been suggested
dena, CA 91125 (e-mail: camerer @hss.caltech.edu); before (e.g., Richard Roll, 1986) but has not
Lovallo: Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, been directlytested by measuringeconomic de-
Philadelphia, PA 19104. Help and comments were re-
ceived from Daniel Kahneman, Marc Knez, Matthew cisions and personal overconfidence simulta-
Rabin, David Teece, Dick Thaler, participants at the neously. To link the two we created an
MacArthur Foundation Preferences Group, the 1995 JI experimentalsettingwith basic featuresof busi-
DM Society, workshops at the Universities of Chicago ness entrysituations.In the experiments,the suc-
and Colorado, UCLA, Harvard Business School, and
cess of entering subjects depends on their
Wharton,and several anonymous referees. Gail Nash pro-
vided superbsecretarialhelp and RobertoWeber provided relativeskill (comparedto otherentrants).Most
research assistance. The research was funded by National subjects who enter think the total profit earned
Science Foundation GrantNo. SBR 95-11001. by all entrantswill be negative, but their own
'There are interesting exceptions-most people de-
profit will be positive. The findings are consis-
murely say they are not in the very top decile or quintile,
but merely above average; for many traits, women are less tent with the prediction that overconfidence
optimistic than men (and even overly pessimistic; e.g., leads to excessive business entry.
Eleanor E. Maccoby and Carol N. Jacklin, 1974); and The experiments also develop a paradigm
clinically depressed patients are not optimistic (e.g., in which business entry and other skill-based
Lauren B. Alloy and Anthony H. Ahrens, 1987). The lat-
ter finding calls into question the common psychiatricpre-
competitions (e.g., labor-market tourn-
sumption that "realistic" people are well adjusted and aments) could be studied further. The
happy, and also raises the question of whether unrealistic paradigm extends typical economics exper-
optimism might be evolutionarily adaptive (e.g., Lionel iments by including a potentially potent
Tiger, 1979) or socially beneficial (Giovanni Dosi and psychological variable-relative skill per-
Lovallo, 1997). Michael Waldman (1994) shows how
such optimism could be evolutionarily stable, and men- ceptions-and also extends typical psychol-
tions conditions under which gender differences like those ogy experiments on overconfidence by
observed empirically could arise. adding financial incentives for judging one's
306

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. ] CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS EN'TRY 307

skill accurately and a clear definition of the of occupational choice provide a clear life-
skill one is judging.2 cycle predictionbased on this sampling motive
Of course, experimentaldata are hardlycon- for entry, since people should bear the risk of
clusive evidence that overconfidence plays a failure early in their careers, but not later (e.g.,
role in actual entry decisions by firms. A big- Robert A. Miller, 1984).
ger scientific payoff comes when experimental The third explanation is that many entry
observations suggest a new phenomenon that decisions are mistakes, made by boundedly ra-
might be studied in the field. Our data suggest tional decision makers. Firms could mistak-
a new phenomenon we call "reference group enly enter too often for two differentreasons-
neglect." Excess entry is much larger when they know their own skills but fail to appre-
subjects volunteered to participate knowing ciate how many competitors there will be
that payoffs would depend on skill. These self- (they have "competitive blind spots"), or
selected subjects seem to neglect the fact that they forecast competition accuratelybut over-
they are competing with a reference group of confidently think their firm will succeed while
subjects who all think they are skilled too. most others will fail.
(Neglecting the increased level of competition In a natural setting it is difficult to distin-
is like the neglect of adverse selection which guish between these three explanations for
leads to the "winner's curse" in bidding.) high failure rates. The overconfidence expla-
nation is particularlyhard to establish because
L. PossibleExplanationsfor EntrantFailure it predicts that firms will enter even if they
expect negative industry profits. But even if
There are three primaryexplanations for the cumulative industry profits are actually nega-
frequency of entrant failure. The first expla- tive at some point in time, it is possible posi-
nation is that failures are frequentbecause en- tive returns will roll in later (or the industry
trants have only brief opportunities to make simply made a large unpredictableforecasting
money. In this view, failures are actually hit- mistake). So it is hard to imagine how to es-
and-runentries that are profitablebut brief. tablish conclusively that expected industryre-
A second explanationis thatbusiness entries turns were negative.
are expensive lottery tickets with positively While more field research is surely worth-
skewed returns. In this view, although most while, some progress might be made in the
firms expect to lose money and fail, entry still laboratory. In an experiment, everything
maximizes expected profits because the pay- needed to distinguish the three theories-
offs to success are very large. There are two entry decisions, forecasts of industry profits,
variants of this argument: First, if small- and forecasts of the numberof total entrants-
business owners are risk preferringor get psy- can be measured. If subjects forecast positive
chic income from runningbusinesses, then the industry profits and enter, the rational-entry
expected utility from entering might be high theories appear correct. If subjects forecast
even if expected profit is low. Second, it is positive industry profits, but they underesti-
well known from multiarmedbandit problems mate the amount of entry and industry profit
that when sampling from unknown distribu- turns out to be negative, then the blind spots
tions of possible payoffs (such as careerpaths story appears correct. If subjects accurately
or profitable industries), it may pay to sample forecast negative industry profits, and enter
from "arms" with negative expected payoffs anyway, then the overconfidence explanation
if the possible payoffs from those arms is large appears correct.
(because sampling provides informationabout
which arms to choose in the future). Models II. ExperimentalDesign

Our experiments extend a paradigm first


used by Daniel Kahneman (1988), Jim
2
Earlier studies showed that overconfidence is larger
when traitsare defined ambiguously-"driving ability" is Brander, and Richard Thaler, then explored
more ambiguousthan "ability to brakequickly to avoid an more throughly by Amnon Rapoport and
accident" (David Dunninget al., 1989; Lovallo, 1996). colleagues.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
308 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

In their game, N players choose simulta- TABLE 1-RANK-BASED) PAYOFFS


neously, and without communicating, whether
to enter a market or not. The market "capac- Payoff for successful entrants
ity" is a preannouncednumber, c. If players as a function of "c"
stay out they earn a payment K. If the total Rank 2 4 6 8
numberof entrantsis E, the entrantseach earn 1 33 20 14 11
K + rK(c - E) (with rK > 0). The optimal 2 17 15 12 10
behavior is simple: Players want to enter only 3 10 10 8
4 5 7 7
if the number of expected entrants (including 5 5 6
themselves) is less than the capacity c. If they 6 2 4
do enter, players prefer the numberof entrants 7 3
to be as small as possible. The interesting 8 2
questions are whether the right number of
players enter (is E around c?), whether E
changes with c, and how players figure out
whether to enter or not. 1986). Besides being more realistic, differ-
Kahneman(1988) was surprisedto see that ences in payoffs based on skill allow the pos-
the numberof entrants,E, was typically in the sibility that overconfidence will lead to excess
range [c - 2, c + 2] even though subjects entry.
could not communicate or coordinate their de- Table I shows how payoffs depend on a
cisions in any explicit way. "To a psycholo- subject's rank and on the market capacity c.
gist," he wrote, "it looks like magic." The top c entrants share $50 proportionally,
Rapoport (1995) replicated the results using with higher-rankingentrantsearning more. All
Ph.D. students playing for much larger stakes. entrantsranking below the top c lose $10. For
He also found that subjects entered a bit too examnple,if the marketcapacity c = 2, then the
frequently at first, but gradually E converged highest-ranked entrant receives $33, the sec
very close to c. E and c were highly correlated ond highest-ranked entrant receives $17, and
across trials. Extensions by James Sundali et any lower-rankedentrantloses $10. (Subjects
al. (1995) and Rapoport et al. (1998a) repli- are staked $10 initially.) Notice that if the
cated the earlier findings. Rapoport et al. number of entrants is exactly c + 5 then the
(1998b) introduced probabilistic payoffs and total payoff to all entering subjects ("industry
showed that deviations from equilibriumentry profit") is zero; if there are more than c + 5
could be parsimoniously explained by nonlin- entrants,the average entrantloses money.
ear transformationsof entry probabilities. Actual ranks are assigned in two different
Our experiments extend this paradigm in ways: Each subject is ranked by a random
four ways: Payoffs depend on a subject's rank drawing, and also ranked according to his rel-
(relative to other entrants); ranks depend on ative performanceon a skill or trivia task. Skill
either a chance device, or on a subject's skill; ranks are determined by how many questions
subjects in some experiments are told in ad- subjects answer correctly on a sample of 10
vance that the experiment depends on skill logic puzzles (sessions 1-2) or trivia ques-
(and hence, more skilled subjects presumably tions about sports or current events (sessions
self-select into the experiment); and subjects 3-8). It is important to stress that subjects'
forecast the numberof entrantsin each period. ranks were not determineduntil the end of the
Skill-dependent payoffs are the crucial new experiment, after they made all their entry de-
design feature. The early experiments capture cisions in both the skill and random
an importantaspect of entry-tacit coordina- conditions.
tion among potential entrants to avoid excess Here are the steps in ea ch experimental
entry - but all entrants earned the same session:
amount. In naturally occurring settings, somne
entrantswin and others lose, due at least partly I. Before the experiment, subjects were re-
to differences in managerialskill (see Kenneth cruited using either standardrecruiting in-
R. MacCrim-monand Donald A. Wehrung, structions or "self-selection" instructions.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. I CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS ENTRY 309

TABLE 2-MARKET CAPACITY "C" VALUES

Rounds Experiment 1 Experiment 2 Experiments 3-6 Experiments 7 & 8


1 2 8 2 4
2 4 4 6 2
3 8 2 4 6
4 6 6 4 8
5 4 4 2 6
6 2 2 6 4
7 8 8 4 2
8 6 6 6 8
9 4 4 2 6
10 6 2 6 4
11 8 8 4 2
12 2 6 2 8

In the self-selection condition, subjects $0.25 for each forecast that was correct.
were asked if they would like to volunteer These forecasts distinguish the hypothesis
for an expeliment in which performanceon that too many subjects enter because they
sports or currentevents trivia would deter- underestimate the numnberof competitors
mine their payoff, and people who were ("blind spots") from the hypothesis that
very good might earn a considerable sum subjects forecast entry accurately, but en-
of money. (They were also remindedin the trants all think they are above average.
experimental instructions that all subjects 5. Subjects made their entry decisions pri-
were recruitedthis way.) vately and simultaneously.3
2. Subjects were seated in a large classroom 6. Entry decisions were recorded and subjects
where they could not see each other's ma- were told how many total entrants there
terials. The instructions were read aloud were in the round. Thus, the only feedback
and a comprehension test was given to that subjects received after each round is
guarantee understandingof the payoff ta- the total numberof entrantsfor each period.
ble. The two types of ranking systems were 7. At the end of the experimental session, af-
explained and subjects were shown exam- ter all of the rounds in both conditions were
ples of the skill questions, along with sam- played, subjects either solved puzzles or
ple answers. Subjects were informed that took the trivia quiz, and their skill rank was
there would be two sequences of 12 rounds determined and announced. Then one of
for each condition -one for the random the subjects randomly chose one of the 24
rank and anotherfor the skill rank.Subjects rounds and subjects' eamings from that
were also informed that the decisions they round were computed and paid to them.
made for one of the rounds, chosen ran-
domly, would determine their payoff. It is importantto reiteratethat the only feed-
back subjects got throughoutthe session of 24
Individual rounds proceed as follows: rounds was the total number of entrants per

3. Subjects were told whether skill or random


ranks are being used in that round, and the
3 In one session, not reported here, we allowed deci-
capacity c. Table 2 shows the capacities sions to be made sequentially. This means that a subject
used in each round. The same sequence of moving after c + 5 entrants have already entered knows
capacities was used in the two consecutive for sure that the total payment to subjects will be negative;
conditions within a session. entering in that condition is the strongest possible evi-
dence that subjects are relatively overconfident. Roughly
4. Subjects privately forecasted how many en- the same number of subjects entered in that session, but
trantsthey expected would enter (including too few data are available from the single session to draw
themselves) in the round. They earned firmerconclusions.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
310 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

TABLE3--DESCRIPTION
OFEXPERIMENTS

Experiment# Sample n Selection procedure Rank order


1 Chicago, undergraduates 12 random RJS
2 Chicago, undergraduates 14 random S/R
3 Wharton,undergraduates 16 random R/S
4 Wharton,undergraduates 16 random S/R
5 Wharton, undergraduates 16 self-selection RIS
6 Wharton,undergraduates 16 self-selection SIR
7 Chicago, M.B.A.'s 14 self-selection R/S
8 Wharton, M.B.A.'s 14 self-selection S/R

round.This design was chosen to model initial see how they might arise without communi-
entry behavior by firms that do not learn much cation or some coordinating device, like his-
about their competitive advantage until after tory, sequential moves, or public labels
they incur substantial nonsalvageable fixed distinguishing subjects. There is also a unique
costs. The question of how post-entry feed- symmetric mixed-strategy equilibrium in
back about performance impacts subsequent which (risk-neutral) players enter with a prob-
behavior is interesting, of course-it is cer- ability close to (c + 5)/N (see Lovallo and
tainly likely that overconfidence would be di- Camerer, 1996).
minished if subjects were given a separateskill Relaxing the assumption of risk neutrality,
test and told their ranks after each round. But there is no way to determine the equilibrium
it is natural to begin by establishing whether numberof entrantswithout measuringor mak-
overconfidence is present in the first place, be- ing specific assumnptionsabout subjects' risk
fore turning to the question of what forces preferences.S The random-rank condition
make it go away. gives an empirical estimate of observed equi-
The procedures described above were used librium without having to impose any a priori
in eight sessions. Table 3 summarizes differ- assumption about risk preferences. Since sub-
ences in treatment variables across sessions.4 jects participatein both random-and skill-rank
In half of the experimental sessions the conditions, their decisions in the random-rank
random-rankcondition roundswere conducted condition act as a within-subject control for
first; in the other half the skill-rank rounds risk preferences. The difference in the number
were first. Four sessions involved self-selected of entrantsin the random and skill conditions
subjects (who knew trivia skill would help) is the primary measure of interest.
and four sessions did not.
IlLoResults
A. EquilibriumPredictions
A. Does OverconfidenceAbout Skill
Assuming risk neutrality, there are many Increase Entry?
pure-strategyNash equilibria in which c + 4
or c + 5 subjects enter (the fifth subject is Table 4 lists the total amount of money
indifferent since he or she expects to earn zero earned by subjects ("industry profit") per
from entering). Since the pure-strategyequi-
libria are necessarily asymmetric, it is hard to
5An alternative is to try to induce risk neutrality (or
some other specific degree of risk aversion) by paying
subjects in units of probability (see Joyce E. Berg et al.,
4 Business students, especially M.B.A.'s, are an appro- 1986). We chose to use the random-rankcondition be-
priate sample because many go on to start businesses or cause the probability procedure does not induce risk neu-
participate in corporate entry decisions (e.g., entrepre- tralityreliably (see ReinhardSelten et al., 1995; cf., Vesna
neurship is the fifth most popular major among Wharton Prasnikar, 1996), and the random-rank condition is
M.B.A.'s). equally theoretically valid, and simpler.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. 1 CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS ENTRY 311

TABLE4-INDUSTRYPROFIT
BYROUND

Profit for random-rankcondition


Rounds
Experiment# n 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Total
1 12 50 50 20 30 40 30 20 50 30 40 20 40 420
2 14 0 -10 10 20 -10 10 20 10 0 0 30 20 100
3 16 10 50 20 40 10 20 30 40 20 40 30 20 330
4 16 0 10 10 20 10 -10 0 10 20 10 0 20 100
5 16 20 10 10 10 0 0 30 20 -10 0 0 0 90
6 16 30 20 10 0 -10 30 20 10 10 30 10 20 180
7 14 10 20 40 20 30 40 -30 40 10 0 0 20 200
8 14 20 10 0 30 30 0 10 10 20 10 20 40 200
Profit for skill-rank condition
Rounds
Experiment# n 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Total
1 12 50 0 20 10 30 10 20 10 40 10 10 30 240
2 14 0 -10 10 20 --10 10 20 10 0 0 30 20 100
3 16 10 20 10 20 0 10 20 10 10 30 20 10 180
4 16 0 0 20 20 10 -30 10 -10 -10 10 -20 0 0
5 16 -30 -20 -20 -10 -40 -10 -30 0 -30 -10 -20 0 -220
6 16 10 -40 -20 -30 -10 -30 -10 -20 -20 -10 0 0 -180
7 14 -40 -10 -10 0 -20 -10 -40 0 0 0 -10 0 -140
8 14 10 -10 -10 -10 -20 -20 -20 0 -20 10 -20 -20 -130

round in each experimental session, by rank ditions is $18.43, which is about two extra en-
condition. Recall that if c subjects enter, total trantsper round in the skill c,onditions(about
industryprofitis $50. If c + 5 enter, total prof- a third of the number expected to not enter).
its are 0. A powerful statisticaltest of significance ex-
The main question is whether there is more ploits the yoked design by comparing industry
entry (and lower industry profit) when people profit in each pair of skill-rank and random-
are betting on their own relative skill rather rank periods in exactly the same periods of
than on a random device. The answer is experimental sessions t and t + 1 (for t = 1,
"Yes": In the majority of the random-rank 3, 5, 7). In this comparison, each pair of pe-
rounds (74/96 or 77 percent) industry profit riods has exactly the same location in experi-
is strictly positive6 and total profit is negative mental time and the same value of c, and differ
only six times (6 percent). Average industry only in whether ranks were due to skill or
profit across rounds is $16.87. In contrast, in chance. (Fixed effects of periods, self-
the skill-rank rounds industry profit is strictly selection, and subject pool are all controlled
positive in only 37 rounds (40 percent) and for by this comparison.) A miatched-pairt-test
negative in 41 (42 percent). Average profit using these comparisons yields t = -7.43
across the skill-rank rounds is -$1.56. The (dof = 95,p < 0.0001). Industryprofitsunder
difference in average profits between the con- skill-based entry are clearly lower.
The next question is whether reference
group neglect produces a larger skill-random
entry differential in the experiments with self-
6 This is also consistent with tacit collusion among risk-
selected subjects. The answer appears to be
neutralplayers, since having exactly c entrantsis the col-
lusive solution (but is not a Nash equilibrium), or with "Yes." In sessions without self-selection (1 -
some degree of risk aversion or (more likely) loss 4), the average per-period industry profit is
aversion. $19.79 and $10.83 for the random and skill

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
312 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

TABLE 5-AVERAGE DIFFERENCEIN EXPECTEDPROFITSPERENTRANTBETWEENRANDOMAND SKILLCONDITIONS

Experiment Experiment Experiment Experiment Experiment Experiment Experiment Experiment


Measure 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Total
nl, - Fl, 1.635 0.477 -1.19 0.24 1.62 2.49 3.16 1.80 1.31
(1.98) (1.41) (1.72) (2.41) (1.32) (1.27) (1.61) (1.20) (2.04)
# of S's with 10/12 10/13 3/11 7/14 12/13 12/13 13/13 11/12 78/101
nL,- nLI< 0 (83) (77) (27) (50) (92) (92) (100) (92) (77)
(percent)
# of S's with 0/12 0/13 0/12 2/15 12/15 15/16 12/14 11/14 52/111
nLI< 0 (0) (0) (0) (13) (80) (94) (86) (79) (47)
(percent)

conditions, respectively-a difference of players underforecasting how many others


$9.14, or about one extra entrant in the skill- will enter.
based rounds. In sessions with self-selection To test this hypothesis, we use subjectj's
(5-8) profitis $13.96 in the randomcondition forecast Fijtto compute the profit that subject
and -$13.13 in the skill condition, which re- j expects the average entrant to earn in round
sults in an entry differential of $27.10- about t of experiment i. If the capacity is cit in that
three times as large as in the sessions without particular period, then the "expected aver-
self-selection. Furthermore,in the experiments age profit" -the amount of profit subject j
with self-selection, industry profits are posi- thinks the average entrant will earn-is
tive in only 3 of the 48 skill-rankperiods, com- (50-10*(Fijt ci- - )Fijt, which we denote
pared with 34 of 48 in the non-self-selected by Ej(flijt). This method effectively sepa-
sessions. A matched-pairstest comparing the rates the blind spots hypothesis from the
skill-random profit differentials for matched overconfidence hypothesis. Suppose, for ex-
periods between sessions 1-4 and 5-8 ample, that in skill conditions subjects are
strongly rejects the hypothesis that differen- more apt to enter because they think fewer
tials are the same in sessions with and without people will enter, not because they feel they
self-selection (t(94) = -4.08, p < 0.001). are more skilled. Then their Ej(H1ijt)values
Reference group neglect clearly makes the will be larger in the skill condition. Includ-
overconfidence effect stronger. ing Ej(Hlijt)in an entry regression will then
wipe out the effect spuriously attributed to
B. Expected Earnings Differences in Skill skill.
and Random Rounds If entering subjects are more overconfident
in the skill rounds, then their expected average
The matched-pairstests illustrate the effect profits E(IIijt) will be smaller than in random
of overconfidence on entry and demonstrate rounds because the skilled subjects expect to
that self-selection makes the effect stronger. earn more than the average entrantand, hence,
But these tests do not carefully control for all are willing to enter even when the expected
alternative explanations.7 For example, the average profit is low. To test this prediction,
blind spots hypothesis suggests that excessive Table 5 reports the difference between ex-
entry in the skill conditions may be due to pected average profits in random rounds (de-
noted Hr) and the same statistic in skill rounds
(ITs), using only the rounds in which a subject
entered. The table shows three different mea-
7 Gender could be confounded with self-selection, too, sures for each session: The mean difference
since women may be less likely to volunteer for tasks nr- 1I averaged across entering subjects, the
which reward expertise in sports trivia (and are usually number and percentage of subjects who have
found to be less overconfident than men, in general). We
controlled for this by only recruitingmale subjects in ses-
a negative mean (i.e., who expect less average
sions 3-8. Thus, the logit analysis of sessions 3-8 effec- profit in skill periods), and the number and
tively controls for gender. percentage of subjects whose expected aver-

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. ] CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS ENTRY 313

age profit is negative, on average, across skill positively but the MBA *Skill interactiondoes
periods. not.
In sessions without self-selection ( 1-4) the Most importantly,the effect of the Skill con-
mean difference 171- II1 is generally positive dition variable is significantly positive (t =
and modestly significant-60 percent of the 2.48) in the full model but the interaction
subjects expect to earn less in skill periods, but of self-selection and skill, RNG*Skill, is in-
only a few subjects (4 percent) actually expect significant. The middle column drops the un-
losses in skill periods. In the sessions with self- interesting variables MBA, MBA*Skill, and
selection (4-8) the statistics are more strik- the insignificant main effect of RNG. Then
ing: There are large, modestly significant RNG*Skill becomes significant (t = 1.90),
average differences I - II, in all four ses- confirming that self-selection significantly in-
sions (almost all subjects expect to earn less creases the tendency to enter more frequently
in skill periods than in random periods), and when payoffs depend on skill.10The right col-
85 percent of the subjects have negative ex- umn excludes the RNG*Skill interaction,
pected average profits in skill periods. The which increases the estimated coefficient and
large majority of subjects in the self-selection significance of the pure skill effect (t = 4.83).
sessions seem to be saying, "I expect the av- Comparing the log-likelihoods with and with-
erage entrantto lose money, but not me!" out RNG*Skill also shows that including it
improves fit significantly (X2 = 3.6, p =
C. Regression Estimates of the 0.05), corroboratingthe results of the t-test.
OverconfidenceEffect
D. Additional Analyses: Forecasts and
Another way to see the size and significance EquilibriumBehavior
of all the variables' effects at once is a logit
regression in which the dependent variable is Since subjects forecasted the number of en-
subject j's 0-1 entry decision (enter = 1) in trantsin each period, we can test whether their
round t of experimenti, Dij,. The logit includes forecasts reflect rational use of available in-
controls for period-specific intercepts (to cap- formation (see Lovallo and. Camerer [1996]
ture any period-by-period influences on en- for more details). Forecasts are slightly bi-
try), a subject pool dummy (MBA = 1), a ased: In random conditions subjects forecast
self-selection condition dummy (RNG = 1), about 0.30 entrantstoo high, and in skill con-
capacity c, and a skill-rank dummy (Skill - ditions they forecast 0.50 entrantstoo low (the
1). latter bias is significantly negative at p <
Table 6 shows the results of the logit re- 0.05). We have no explanation for these small
gression of entry decisions.8 Period-specific
dummy variables were never significant and
are not reported.Curiously,E(fij) enters with
a negative sign, implying that when subjects and between E( ij,) and c. None of these specifications
expect high average profit they enter less of- improved the fit substantiallyor eliminated the significant
ten. This odd result is robust to several speci- negative coefficient on E(nij,). We suspect the result oc-
curs because when subjects plan to enter, they also fore-
fications but it does not disrupt inferences cast a lot of entry, so the expected average profit E( HV)
about skill.9 The dummy variable MBA enters is lower when they enter. This could be due to a "false
consensus" in which subjects use their own decision as a
clue about what others will do (and, because of optimism,
they do not let their forecast inhibit their own entry).
0 Excluding the RNG *Skill interaction from the sec-
8 The regression uses only data from sessions 3-8 be- ond model raises the estimatedcoefficient and significance
cause sessions 1-2 used a different task (logic puzzles of the pure skill effect (0.450, t = 4.83), which suggests
ratherthan trivia) and did not include self-selection as a that the precision of the estimates of skill and RNG*Skill
treatment,so including it does not give much extra power in the middle-column specification are a lot lower because
for estimating the effect of RNG. of the colinearity between skill and RNG*Skill. Compar-
' We also included capacity c as a series of dummy ing the log-likelihoods with and without RNG*Skill also
variables (to capture nonlinearityin the effect of c on en- shows that including it improves fit significantly (X2 =
try), and included interactionsbetween E(Fij,) and Skill, 3.6,p= 0.0.5).

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
314 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

TABLE 6-LOGIT ESTIMATION OF ENTRY EQUATION (SESSIONS 3-8, n 2,204)

Dependent variable:Entry (= 1)
Variable Estimate (t-statistic) Estimate (t-statistic) Estimate (t-statistic)
Intercept -0.887 (-3.28) -0.855 (-3.40) -0.865 (-3.21)
c 0.233 (6.93) 0.257 (7.99) 0.258 (8.06)
E(x j) -0.129 (-6.93) -0.126 (-6.65) -0.144 (-8.72)
Skill 0.375 (2.48) 0.286 (2.26) 0.450 (4.83)
MBA 0.283 (1.76)
RNG 0.011 (0.01)
MBA*Skill 0.196 (0.83)
RNG*Skill 0.078 (0.35) 0.299 (1.90)
Log-likelihood -1366.8 -1372.5 -1374.3
Percent correct 64.84 64.02 64.34

biases and do not attach much economic sig- models assume those deviations drop with the
nificance to them. For most subjects, forecasts reciprocal or reciprocal square root of the pe-
pass the standardrationalitytests because fore- rod number. The three techniques yield esti-
cast errors are not predicted by observable in- mated differentials of 1.96, 1.79, and 1.34 (all
formation (i.e., by previous errors, or by the of which are highly significant).
current forecast level). When errors are pre- These numbers suggest that even if the ex-
dictable, they tend to flip in the opposite di- perimentwas repeatedfor a much longer time,
rection of previous errors, and errors are one or two more subjects would enter when
positively correlated with levels (i.e., when their payoffs depend on skill, relative to the
forecasts are high, they are too high so the number who enter than when payoffs are ran-
forecast error is positive). dom. Keep in mind that an average of five or
Compared to other economics experiments six subjects are predicted to stay out in each
in which paid forecasts have been gathered period (depending on the design). Two extra
(cf., Camerer, 1995 pp. 609-12), the infor- entrants means that more than a third of the
mational rationality of these forecasts is quite number who are predicted to stay out actually
good. This fact is importantbecause it means enter.
subjects are not generally irrational in pro-
cessing information and they do not overenter IV. Discussion
because they underforecast the amount of
competition. They arejust overconfidentabout Empirical studies show a high rate of busi-
their relative skill. ness failure. We explored whether overconfi-
The time series of matched-pair skill- dence about relative ability is part of the
random differentials in entry has a slight explanation for excessive failure by creating
downwardtrend across periods. This raises the experimental entry games in which entrants'
important question of whether the effect of payoffs depend on their skill.
overconfidence on entry would disappearif the When subjects' post-entrypayoffs arebased
experiment were run longer. A helpful way to on their own abilities, individuals tend to over-
forecast the answer is to fit a time-series model estimate their chances of relative success and
which estimates the long-run differential by enter more frequently (compared to a condi-
extrapolating from 12 periods of data to what tion in which payoffs do not depend on skill),
would happen if the experiment were run for- The more surprising finding is that overconfi-
ever (see Camerer, 1987). Our working paper dence is even stronger when subjects self-
reports estimates from three different models. select into the experimental sessions, knowing
One model assumes partial adaptation of de- their success will depend partly on their skill
viations from long-run equilibrium.Two other (and that others have self-selected too). In

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. I CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS ENTRY 315

these sessions, there is so much entry that the professions where overconfidence is likely
average subject loses money in 34 out of 48 to be largest, industry profits or total wages
periods, and earns money in only four periods. (including costs of training) may be nega-
This result suggests a new phenomenon spe- tive. This brings us full circle to the empir-
cific to competition, "reference group ne- ical facts about business failure, and the
glect" -the tendency to underadjust to difficulty of clearly establishing negative in-
changes in the reference group one competes dustry profit. The key to empirical tests
with. which distinguish overconfidence from other
Reference group neglect is one byproductof explanations is to find variables which pre-
a psychological phenomenon called the "in- dict levels of overconfidence and see if they
side view" (Kahneman and Lovallo, 1993). correlate with the tendency for overall profit
An inside view forecast is generatedby focus- to be negative. For example, when the cri-
ing on the abilities and resources of a partic- terion for success is more vague, people or
ular group, constructing scenarios of future firms should be more likely to overcompete,
progress, and extrapolating current trends. In since ambiguity permits excess optimism.
contrast, an "outside view" ignores special This implies that in professions where suc-
details of the case at hand, constructs a class cess can be achieved by different types of
of cases similar to the currentone, and guesses people, or industries with highly differenti-
where the current case lies in that class (cf., ated products, excess entry is more likely.
Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). The inside For example, the skills required to be a suc-
view tells a colorful story; the outside view cessful model seem to be narrower than the
recites statistics. In the inside view, there is no skills required to be a successful actor. If so,
special role for anticipation of the number of your waiter at a Los Angeles restaurant is
competitors or their abilities. In the outside more likely to be an aspiring actor than an
view, the fact that most entries fail cannot be aspiring model.
ignored. The overconfidence hypothesis also pre-
Reference group neglect was nicely ex- dicts that people will prefer performance-
pressed by Joe Roth, chairman of Walt based incentives schemes more often than
Disney Studios, when he was asked why so standard theory predicts. Standard theory
many expensive big-budget movies are re- predicts that as output variance rises, prin-
leased on the same weekends (such as Me- cipals who can bear risk should offer less
morial Day and Independence Day). Roth output-sensitive contracts to agents (who
replied: presumably dislike risk). Overconfidence
predicts that agents will be relatively insen-
Hubris. Hubris. If you only think about sitive to risk; indeed, when risk is high their
your own business, you think, "I've got overconfidence might lead them to prefer
a good story department,I've got a good riskier contracts because they think they can
marketingdepartment,we're going to go beat the odds. There is some evidence from
out and do this." And you don't think
that everybody else is thinking the same sharecropping that the standard prediction is
way. In a given weekend in a year you'll wrong, and the overconfidence prediction
have five movies open, and there's cer- may be right. Crops with larger yield varia-
tainly not enough people to go around. tion are more likely to be farmed with cash
(Emphasis ours; Los Angeles Times, leases, where farmers pay a fixed fee to lease
1996 p. F8.) the land and bear all the crop risk themselves
(e.g., Douglas W. Allen and Dean Lueck,
A. Some Testable Economic Implications 1995). Other evidence from franchising and
mining show that risk variables play a small
Experimental results are especially useful role in contract determination; the existence
when they suggest implications which are of overconfidence may explain why.
testable with naturally occurring data. If Reference group neglect predicts that when
people are generally overconfident about agents compete based on skill, they will be
their relative abilities, then in industries or insufficiently sensitive to the quality of

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
316 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

competition. This has at least three testable to college) and the effect will get stronger if
implications. they go to graduate school. Promotion tracks
First, people will gather too little data about in businesses could produce the same pattern
the nature of their competitors when deciding of snowballing overconfidence: Perhaps as
whether to enter.11 cream rises to the top, hubris does too.
Second, reference group neglect predicts Reference group neglect predicts an oppo-
that people will be insensitive to whether their site bias when workers lose toumaments and
competitors are forced to compete or choose consider whether to enter "consolation" tour-
to compete. Empirical tests could compare a naments with other losers. Losing workerswill
situation in which entry is dictated by regula- be underconfidentif they neglect how easy the
tion or law, with a similar situation in which new competition is. For example, recently
people can opt in or out. Reference group ne- fired workers will have unusually long spells
glect predicts a higher failure rate in the latter of unemployment (compared to the spell
cases. 12 length predicted by optimal search theory), if
Third, in hierarchical tournaments where they lick their wounds rather than compete
''winners" at one level advance to the next with other recently fired workersby searching.
level, reference group neglect predicts that In addition to reference group neglect and
overconfidence will get stronger and stronger its testable implications, an important impli-
as people advance.1"As workers win each cation of our study is methodological. In some
level of the tournament, their success is cer- settings with uncertainty,it is sensible to char-
tainly a positive signal of ability relative to the acterize economic agents as making decisions
tournamentlosers left behind, but every other about random events, and use chance devices
winner has received the same positive signal in the lab to mimic suich events. However,
too. If winners neglect the fact that competi- when agents are betting on their own abilities,
tion increases at each level, they will become assuming that random luck and skill are the
more overconfident at each new level. Edu- same is a mistake (cf., Linda Babcock and
cational attainment might be an example. George Loewenstein, 1997). Indeed, we reach
Freshmanstudents at a highly selective college different conclusions about equilibrium pre-
will be overconfident (neglecting the large in- dictions when we use skill-based payoffs in-
crease in competition from their high school stead of random payoffs-they enter more
when betting on their skill. This is not to say
that the subjects behave irrationally-indeed,
they forecast the number of competitors quite
" For example, prospective doctoral students often do well, and most pass tests of expectational ra-
not ask about exam failure rates or what jobs all graduates tionality. They are simply overconfident; and
get, and academics are surprisinglyunfamiliarwith accep- the inside view which creates that confidence
tance rates of different journals they submit articles to.
These "outside view" statistics only make cameo ap- leads them to neglect the quality of their
pearances in the success stories people project for competition.
themselves.
12 An example is the difference between an army that REFERENCES
drafts citizens to serve and a regime in which soldiers
volunteer. Reference group neglect predicts that soldiers
who aspire to become high-ranking officers will be too Allen,DouglasW. and Lueck,Dean. "Risk Pref-
optimistic about their chances when they volunteer (be- erences and the Economics of Contracts."
cause many volunteers will share,the same ambition). A American Economic Review, May 1995
similar test could turnon differences between compulsory (Papers and Proceedings), 85(2), pp.
and voluntary education, or differences between required
core courses and electives (students will be more over- 447-5 1.
confident about their success in the,latter courses). Alloy, LaurenB. and Aherns,AnthonyH. "De-
" Possible examples include political competition,s rat pression and Pessimism for the Future:
races" in professional firms, athletic competition, educa- Biased Use of Statistically Relevant Infor-
tional competition for entrance into elite colleges and
graduateschools, and entertainmentindustrieswhere entry
mation in Predictions for Self and Others."
is easy and a few "superstar' workers earn large rewards Joumal of Personalt and Social Psychol-
(such as acting and screcnwriting). ogy, February 1987, 52(2), pp. 366-78.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 89 NO. 1 CAMERERAND LOVALLO:OVERCONFIDENCEAND EXCESS ENTRY 317

Babcock, Linda and Loewenstein, George. "Ex- Geroski,Paul A. "Some Data-Driven Reflec-
plaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of tions on the EntryProcess," in Paul A. Ger-
Self-Serving Biases." Journal of Economic oski and J. Schwalbach, eds., Entry and
Perspectives, Winter 1.997,11 (1 ), pp. 109- market contestability: An international
26. comparison. Oxford:Basil Blackwell, 1991,
Baldwin,John R. The dynamics of industrial pp. 282-96.
competition. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- Kahneman,Daniel. "ExperimentalEconomics:
versity Press, 1995. A Psychological Perspective," in R. Tietz,
Berg, Joyce E.; Daley, Lane A.; Dickhaut, John Wulf Albers, and Reinhard Selten, eds.,
W. and O'Brien, John R. "Controlling Pref- Bounded rational behavior in experimental
erences for Lotteries on Units of Experi- games and markets. New York: Springer-
mental. Exchange." Quarterly Journal of Verlag, 1988, pp. 11-18.
Economics, May 1986, 101 (2), pp. 281 - Kahneman,Daniel and Lovallo, Dan. "Timid
306. Choices and Bold Forecasts: A Cognitive
Camerer,Colin F. "Do Biases in Probability Perspective on Risk Taking." Manage-
Judgment Exist in Markets? Experimental ment Science, January 1993, 39(1), pp.
Evidence." American Economic Review, 17-31.
December 1987, 77(5), pp. 981-97. Kahneman,Daniel and Tversky,Amos. "Intui-
_ _ - "Individual Decision Making," in tive Prediction: Biases and Corrective Pro-
John H. Kagel and Alvin E. Roth, eds., cedures," in S. Makridakis and S. C.
Handbook of experimental economics. Wheelwright, eds., Forecasting. TIMS
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, Studies in Management Science, 1979, pp.
1995, pp. 587-703. 313-27.
Dosi, Giovanni and Lovallo, Dan. "Rational En-Los Angeles Times. "Going After the Big
trepreneurs or Optimistic Martyrs? Some One." December 31, 1996, pp. Fl, F8.
Considerations on Technological Regimes, Lovallo, Dan. "Essays on the Psychology of
Corporate Entries, and the Evolutionary Competition." Ph.D. dissertation, Univer-
Role of Decision Biases," in R. Garud, P. sity of California, Berkeley, 1996.
Nayyar, and Zur Shapira, eds., Technolog- Lovallo,Dan and Camerer,Colin F. "Overcon-
ical innovation: Oversights and foresights. fidence and Excess Entry:An Experimental
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Approach." Working Paper No. 975, Cali-
1997, pp. 41--70. fornia Institute of Technology, 1996.
Dunne, Timothy; Roberts, Mark J. and Maccoby,EleanorE. and Jacklin, Carol N. The
Samuelson,Larry. "Patterns of Firm Entry psychology of sex differences. Stanford,
and Exit U.S. Manufacturing Industries." CA: Stanford University Press, 1974.
Rand Journal of Economics, Winter 1988, MacCrimmon,KennethR. and Wehrung,Donald
19(4), pp. 495-515. A. Taking risks. New York: Free Press,
____ "'Firm Entry and Postentry Perfor- 1986.
mance in the U.S. Chemical Industries." March, James and Shapira, Zur. "Managerial
Journal of Law and Economics, October Perspectives on Risk and Risk Taking."
1.989a, 32(2), pp. 233-71. Management Science, November 1987,
. "The Growth and Failure of U.S.
_ 33(11), pp. 1404-18.
ManufacturingPlants." Quarterly Joumrnal Miller,RobertA. "Job Matching and Occupa-
of Economics, November 1.989b, pp. 671- tional Choice." Journal of Political Econ-
98. omy, December 1984, 92(6), pp. 1086-
Dunning, David; Meyerowitz, Judith A. and 120.
Holzberg, Amy D. "Ambiguity and Self- Prasnikar, Vesna. "Binary Lottery Payoffs:
Evaluation: The Role of Idiosyncratic Trait The Degree of Controlling Risk Aversion."
Definitions in Self-Serving Appraisals of Working paper, University of Pittsburgh,
Ability." Journal of Personality and Social 1996.
Psychology, December 1989, 57(6), pp. Rapoport,Amnon. "Individual Strategies in a
1,082-90. Market-EntryGame." Group Decision and

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
318 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH 1999

Negotiation, March 1995, 4(2), pp. 117- Sundali, James; Rapoport, Amnon and Seale,
33. Darryl A. "Coordination in Market Entry
Rapoport,Amnon; Seale, Darryl. A.; Erev, Ido Games with Symmetric Players." Organi-
and Sundali,JamesA. "Equilibrium Play in zational Behavior and Human Decision
Large Group Market Entry Games." Man- Processes, November 1995, 64(2), pp.
agement Science, January 1998a, 44(1), 203-18.
pp. 129-41. Svenson, Ola. "Are We All Less Risky and
Rapoport,Amnon;Seale,DarrylA. and Ord6inez, More Skillful Than Our Fellow Drivers?"
Lisa."WeightedProbabilitiesin LargeGroup Acta Psychologica, 1981, 47(2), pp. 143-
Coordination:ExperimentalEvidence from 48.
Market Entry Games." Discussion paper, Taylor, Shelly E. and Brown, J. D. "Illusion and
University of Arizona, Departmentof Man- Well-Being: A Social Psychological Per-
agement and Policy, 1998b. spective on Mental Health." Psychological
Roll, Richard. "The Hubris Hypothesis of Cor- Bulletin, March 1988, 103(2), pp. 193-
porate Takeovers." Journal of Business, 210.
April 1986, 59(2), pp. 197-216. Tiger,Lionel.Optimism: The biology of hope.
Selten, Reinhard;Sadreih, Karim and Abbink, New York: Simon and Schuster, 1979.
Klaus. "Money Does Not Induce Risk Neu- Waldman, Michael. "Systematic Errors and the
tral Behavior, but Binary Lotteries Do Even Theory of Natural Selection." American
Worse." Discussion Paper No. B-343, Uni- Economic Review, June 1994, 84(3), pp.
versity of Bonn, 1995. 482-97.
Shapiro,Danieland Khemani,R. S. "The Deter- Weinstein, Neil D. "Unrealistic Optimism
minants of Entry and Exit Reconsidered." About FutureLife Events." Joumnalof Per-
International Journal of Industrial Organi- sonality and Social Psychology, November
zation, March 1987, 5(1), pp. 15-26. 1980, 39(5), pp. 806-20.

This content downloaded from 91.229.229.101 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 08:47:01 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like