You are on page 1of 5

Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

N o t e s o n t h e H i s t o r y . of t h e H a n d l o o m W e a v i n g

I n d u s t r y of I n d i a

Mary Milewski

The de-industrialization school of Indian historiography has traced the "underdevel-


opment"of India to the destruction of the handicraft textile industry by machine-made im-
ports from England. The argument is largely confined to the cotton textile industry and by
and large draws on the experience of Bengal and Bihar (Eastern India). An all India pers-
pective however reveal's a different picture. In Western India the handicrafts textile in-
dustry not only was not destroyed, it in fact continued to grow in the twentieth century.
It is true that the artisans lost their independence and came to be dominated by the
local capitalists of Gujerat. Yet the labor process remained the same. Capitalists made
their profits by cutting the wages of the weavers who were forced to work for any wage that
they could get by the sheer force of economic circumstances.
Even if one were to theorize the collapse of the Bengal cotton textile handicraft in-
dustry, one must take into account not only the protectionist policies of the British (which
prevented Indian textiles from reaching England): a favorite theory of the nationalists, but
also the collapse of the internal demand due to the anarchy and wholesale destruction follow-
ing the demise of Mughal authority in Bengal. A s a recent historian has pointed out, in-
ternal demand for luxury items was a key to the "flourishing" textile industry (Mitra 1978,
160-161). However since this was a luxury demand, and no internal market sufficient to
spur industrial development actually existed at any stage, the masses, who lived in self-
sufficient villages, were outside the circuit of the "industrial" economy. In this sense
we are still talking about a pre-industrial economy and not an industrial economy. Hence
de-industrialization is more a polemical point than a historically accurate one. In fact,
the handicraft textile industry grew in the colonial period, because the local capitalists
who controlled the artisans found no compelling reason to change the labor process. Instead
like the rural capitalists (see preceding paper by Kaiwar) they literally starved the
formerly independent direct producers to maintain their profit margins.

The production and export of cotton l a w which prohibited even the wearing of
cloths has been an important feature of printed or colored calicoes.
Indian history from earliest recorded times. The traditional or pre-modern hand-
Originally the cloth was produced entirely loom industry was organized around the in-
by hand in India, and then sold, both local- dividual family unit and was apparently
ly and in various ports, first on the Red Sea only a part-time occupation for the bulk of
and the Indian Ocean and later, following the the people involved. In the villages it
establishment of the East India Company, to provided clothing, a little income, and
European cities as well. The sale of Indian occupation to agriculturists during the off-
cloths to England was so successful that the season. In the urban areas, weaving was
woolen cloth industry there protested loudly organizea by caste and was hereditary, but
until Parliament enacted a law prohibiting the hereditary nature of occupational sta-
the importation of colored calicoes from India tus did not inhibit individuals from cross-
into England in 1700 and in 1720, and another ing caste lines when the market for cotton
cloths was good (Venkatraman 1 9 4 0 , 12).
Before the appearance of mill-spun
SOUTH ASIA BULLETIN yarn, the preparation of yarn for weaving
VoZ. I. No. 2. was an important function of the weaver's
Swnmer 1981.
15

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

extended family. Exclusive of the spinning on the decline, the volume of exports from
of the yarn from raw cotton, it has been India carried on by the English totalled
estimated that the preparation of the yarn an estimated 1.5 million pieces of cloth
for weaving cost fifty percent more to do valued at b 2.9 million (Venkataraman 1940,
than the weaving itself. This preparation 14).
includes winding, warping, and sizing of Another factor which affected the
the yarn (Buchanan 1 9 3 4 , 79). The bulk of Indian handloom industry was increased ship-
this preparatory work would have been ac- ments of raw cotton to England which produ-
complished by the women and children of ced a relative shortage in India. A s capi-
the family, some of the work I'put-out'I to tal increasingly took control over India's
widows in the neighborhood, and some of it cotton growing industry, the individual ar-
taken on by the weaver himself as a respite tisan began to lose control over a portion
from the tedious job of operating a loom. of his means of production and finally over
In this pre-modern period, the spe- the labor process itself. The introduction
cialization and delegation of tasks which of British made machine-spun yarn, and in
included the spinning of cotton into yarn 1818, Indian production of machine-spun
by the women (a traditional female chore yarn, undermined the artisan's ability to
in many societies) along with other pre- control access to his primary raw material,
paratory tasks shared by the family as a cotton. It now became increasingly diffi-
whole, and the weaving and the selling of cult for the artisan to survive in his trade
the cloth by the male head of the family without the backing of a local merchant who
who controlled and maintained the means not only provided capital to buy mill-spun
of production, places the weaving family yarn but also monopolized access to this
in the same situation as the peasant agri- yarn and the markets for the finished pro-
culturalist. The produce of the weaver's duct.
family was sold by the weaver directly to D.B. Mitra, in his study of the Bengal
the consumer in the local market. weaving industry, discusses the antagonisms
In the urban areas, this organisation which arose between artisans and merchants
was augmented by a guild system roughly in the period from 1752 to 1837 and descri-
similar to that of medieval European b e s various acts of resistance to this new
guilds. Venkataraman describes this peri- form of exploitation, which could be under-
od just prior to the appearance of British stood as the emergence of class conscious-
manufactured yarn as being characterised ness and class struggle within the cotton
by small-scale production, guild organi- industry in India. Thus, by the middle of
sation, and few intermediaries between the nineteenth century, the handloom weaving
producers and consumers (Venkataraman industry in India had undergone some funda-
1940, 12). mental changes, especially in the social or-
The next stage in the history of ganization of labor, but also in market or-
the Indian handloom industry began when ientation and in the development of a class
the individual artisans began to come structure.
increasingly under the control of mer- By the 1880's, this domestic system had
chants (mahajans, chettis) who provided developed into the system commonly referred
capital and acted as a link between to as the kharkhana system. This involved
producers and consumers. This has been the setting up of small shops with anywhere
called the "domestic system" (Venkataraman upto fifty looms operating in it. The
1940, 12). It seems to have developed as smaller shops were owner-operated with hired
a result of the increased market for Indian weavers to run extra looms or occasional
cotton cloths in the early period, then labor to help prepare the yarn. Women and
the increased demand for Indian cotton to children were still engaged for preparatory
supply the British cotton spinning and help, but in the larger shops, hired labor
later weaving industries. was the norm. It is fairly obvious that the
In the sixteenth century, before average weaver could not afford to organize
exports of Indian cotton t o the Westwere such a shop. Weavers were constantly in

16

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

debt to the merchants who controlled the 1940 ----- 2,193,000


supplies and the markets. The Ratnagiri 1950 ----- 2,861,000
District Report from the Bombay Presidency (figures are estimates from a variety of
Gazetteer of 1880 states that ninety per- census' listed in Mehta 1953, 106).
cent of the weavers there earned less than Protectionist policies (to an extent), aes-
Rs.lOO (b10) per annum, while in Satara in thetic, religious or traditional preferen-
1885 the average earnings of the weavers ces, the specialized nature of some hand-
there were estimated to be Rs. 60-150 loom weaving and other factors may have
(L6-15) per annum. By 1908, in Bengal, helped the Indian handloom industry to
which was once world-renowned for its pro- survive. Governments, both colonial and
duction of fine calicoes, weavers were independent, have realized the importance
said to be "all poor and live from hand of supporting an industry which provides
to mouth, and their work is on the decline." employment (no matter how marginal) to so
(Bengal District Gazetteer for Angul 1908) many peolpe. In 1921 it was estimated
What should have dealt the death-blow that nearly 1.5 million people were invol-
to the Indian handloom production was the ved with the preparation and weaving of
increase in competition from British manu- cotton cloth. In 1926 the cotton textile
factured and Indian manufactured cloths. industry as a whole, including cleaning,
During the first half of the nineteenth cen- ginning, pressing, carding, spinning, sizing,
tury exports from India to England declined weaving, bleaching dyeing and printing
from 1,266,608 pieces in 1814 to 306,086 provided employment for approximately 3
pieces in 1846, while British exports to million workers in India and only 530,000
India increased from 818,208 yards in 1814 of these worked in factories. (1921 figures
to 213,840,000 in 1864 (Venkataraman 1940, Buchanan 1934,75; 1926 figures Venkataraman
17). But, in fact, the Indian handicraft 1940, 4 ) . At this time it was also said
textile industry did not die out. Various that a weaver could not earn more than 6
district officials in India reported that annas (13% c ) per day in Bengal (Buchanan
the weaving industry in India was primarily 1934, 78 >.But as has been mentioned already,
oriented towards the internal Indian market the Bengal industry seems to have been par-
or inter-district trade , and not foreign ticularly hardpressed due to the collapse
trade as has been generally suggested. of the internal market for the fine muslins
During the nineteenth century, the favored by the royalty and limited supplies
number of looms in Ahmednagar District rose of raw cotton which was now being exported.
from 213 in 1820 to 1,200 in 1884. In (Mitra 1978, 160-161). (See Editors' Note).
Pathardi the number rose from 500 in 1850 The position of the weavers and other work-
to 1000 in 1884 (for these and other figures ers in the handloom industry is clearly mar-
see Joshi 1936, 43-44). These figures are ginal, although the government has been
not meant to be representative of the Indian attempting during the latter part of this
industry as a whole but merely to demon- century to improve the situation, especial-
strate that it was possible for weavers to ly by trying to break the power of the mer-
subsist in the face of competition from chants through the organization of co-oper-
cheaper manufactured goods. In fact, the atives for purchasing yarn, renting space
industry seems to have succeeded better in and marketing of the goods. (For a dis-
some areas, such as Madras and Bombay, while cussion of similar problems of handloom
it was more severely affected in Bengal, weavers in Somalia and that government's
for various reasons, some of which are attempt to improve conditions, see Alpers,
indicated below. 1981).
In the twentieth century, the total An important factor in the survival of
number of handlooms operating in India this industry in India as elsewhere seems
continued to increase: to be the industry's concession to "the
1921 ----- 1,458,000 universal method of competing ......(
i.e.)
1931 ----- 1,806,000 ...... reduction in labor costs by reducing
wages......" in the case of the hired

17

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

artisan or by increased self-exploita- BIBLIOGRIIPHY


tion by the individual artisan or artisanal
family unit. (Mehta 1953, 95).
The years from 1900 to 1939 saw an Alpers, E.A.
increase in handloom production from 646.4 1981 "Futa Benaadir: Continuity and
million yards to 1,703,Z million yards, a Change in the Traditional Cotton
threefold increase, while mill production Textile Industry of Southern
of cloth increased nine times during the Somalia c. 1840-1980"
same period (Naidu 1951, 128). Considering Paper to be presented to the
the increase in the Indian population as a Colloque Internationale, Univer-
whole, the introduction of new technology site de Paris VII, Paris.
such as the fly-shuttle loom and powerlooms,
and increased government support, the survi- Buchanan, D.H.
val of the Indian handloom industry into 1934 The Development of Capitalistic
this century may not seem spectacular in EnterDrise in India
~~

quantitative terms. However, the tedious- New York: MacMillan Company.


ness of the work and the low rewards ( in
1950 in Dharwar, average wages for weavers Joshi, N.M.
were Rs.588 per annum,see Bombay Gazetteer 1936 Urban Handicrafts of the Bombay
for Dharwar 1950) indicate that the tenac- Deccan
ity with which the handloom industry has Gokhale Institute of Politics and
survived in the face of competition from Economics, Publication no. 5.
manufactured cloths is based on an economic
reality : few alternative sources of live- Mehta, S.D.
lihood, especially alternatives which offer 1953 The Indian Cotton Textile Indus-
at least a semblance of maintaining control trv: An Economic Analvsis
over one's own labor power and the means of Bombay: Indian Printing Works.
production.
It also appears that as long as the Mitra, D.B.
Indian people continue to prefer the feel, 1978 The Cotton Weavers of Bengal
design and quality of hand -woven cloths 1757-1853
over the somewhat cheaper manufactured fac- Calcutta: Firma KLM Private Ltd.
similes, the traditional sector will con-
tinue to survive. This was the thrust of Naidu, B.V.N.
the Swadeshi movement in the first decade 1951 "The Handloom Industry in India"
of the twentieth century when the nation- in M.P.Gandhi (ed.) The Indian
alist movement encouraged consumption of Cotton Textile Industry 1851-1950
indigenous handicrafts (thus giving a boost Bombay:
to the handicraft industry) which has to
this day remained an indicator of "high Venkataraman, K.S.
taste" and status among the elite. 1940 The Hand-Loom
-- Industry in South
India
Madras: Diocesan Press.

Editor's Note: It is quite apparent that in connection with the decline of the cotton in-
dustry in Bengal certain aspects need to be researched further: I. There is no available
literature on the pre-colonial cotton industry and the plight of the workers under that
system. Since weavers were often idle and lived in extreme poverty in the 18th century
(Mitra 1978, 217), it is debatable whether the opening up of new and expanded possibilities
like indigo and sugar did not provide employment, however harsh, t o unemployed weavers.
Mere statistics showing decrease in the total number of weavers in the 19th century are
therefore inadequate.

18

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

11. While the production of luxury cloths certainly decreased after the 19th century in
Bengal, items of daily use for common people continued to be produced by local weavers
(Mitra 1978, 211).
111. The development of the silk industry in Bengal, which not only coincided with the
decline of the cotton industry but also developed in areas previously renowned f o r their
cotton textiles, must have had profound implications for the local economy. It is im-
portant to know whether the export oriented silk industry with higher profits did not
prompt putting-out capitalists to switch their investment to silk rather than cotton.

19

Published by Duke University Press

You might also like