You are on page 1of 22

Journal of Small Business Management 2010 48(2), pp.

258–279

Social Networks: Effects of Social Capital on


Firm Innovation* jsbm_294 258..279

by Francesc Xavier Molina-Morales and María Teresa


Martínez-Fernández

This paper aims to introduce some specific insights regarding social networks and
the geographical proximity of firms in order to investigate factors involved in the
innovation of firms. In particular, this study reviews ideas from the industrial district
literature by analyzing the role played by the dimensions of social capital, that is,
social interactions, trust, shared vision and involvement of local institutions, in the
process and product innovation of firms inside the district. This paper draws on an
analysis comparing district members and nonmembers based on a sample of 220
manufacturing firms in the Valencia Region (Spain). Findings suggest a positive
association between district affiliation, social capital and involvement of local insti-
tutions and innovation that can offer relevant prescriptions for policy makers and
individual entrepreneurs.

firms. Concepts such as the Industrial


Introduction District have analyzed the content and
Territorial agglomerations of firms nature of these externalities. The indus-
have received a significant amount of trial district is a concept that defines the
attention from researchers from diverse territorial agglomeration of firms. For the
disciplines. Externalities from physical purposes of this research, we have used
proximity have been described as a jus- the definition by Becattini (1990, p. 39),
tification of the potential benefits for who defined it as a “socioeconomic entity

*This research was supported financially by Spanish Ministry of Education and Science research
project number ECO2008-04708/ECON. Thanks to Editor and anonymous JSBM referees for
their helpful suggestions.
Francesc Xavier Molina-Morales is an associate professor at the Universitat Jaume I in
Castellon, Spain.
María Teresa Martínez-Fernández is an associate professor at the Universitat Jaume I in
Castellon, Spain.
Address correspondence to: F. Xavier Molina-Morales, Department of Business Administra-
tion & Marketing, AERT Research Group (CSIC-Associate Unit), Campus Riu Sec, 12080
Castellón, Spain; Tel: +34 964387117; Fax: +34 964728629; E-mail: molina@emp.uji.es.

258 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


characterized by the active presence of a an explanation for the level of innovation
community of people and a population of capacity of district firms and it may be
firms within a natural and historically useful to explain differences both among
bounded area.” firms within the internal district and
Broadly speaking, firms in territorial- between districts or different territorial
based networks develop a set of relation- contexts.
ships in the form of “untraded We have structured the paper as
interdependencies” (Storper and Scott follows: first, we explain the bases of the
1989), which benefit their innovation notion of social capital, and then we
and competitive capabilities in different describe its characteristics and potential
ways (Meeus, Oerlemans, and Hage benefits and apply it to the analysis of
2001). Territorial networks, consisting of the industrial district. Our research
a number of nodes and their respective hypotheses are then formulated and
direct or indirect relations, are used as a finally we use a sample of 220 Spanish
metaphor to represent the actors firms to analyze the causal relation
involved in the innovation process in a between social capital factors and inno-
territory. The use of this metaphor vation outcomes.
emphasizes an integrated approach and
the systemic vision of the process. Theoretical Framework
In this context, previous research has Our aim is to analyze the impact of
sought to apply and describe the territo- particular factors on innovation at both
rial agglomeration of firms with a social the individual firm and district levels.
component, using developments from
the social capital and embeddedness Determinants of Innovation
concept (Lam 1997). However, attempts A primary perspective was constituted
to determine the real potential of this by authors who emphasized organiza-
approach in the field of territorial net- tional variables as being relevant if firms
works are scarce. As social capital theo- are to be innovative (Whitley 1999). For
rists argue, social networks are an instance, Sternberg and Arndt (2001)
important part of the learning process in found evidence that firm-specific deter-
which firms discover new opportunities mining factors for innovation were more
and obtain new knowledge. They also important than either region-specific or
have the opportunity to improve the external factors.
knowledge they already possess by inter- However, other authors (Geroski
acting with one another (e.g., Tsai 2000; 1995) argue that the reduction to purely
Kogut and Zander 1992). individualistic competition fails to take
According to Cooke, Clifton, and into account organizational variables,
Oleaga (2005) social capital affects firms’ such as cooperation between firms,
performance. In particular, the analysis research institutes, and clients. Some
looks at SMEs but it is also extended to particular externalities have been pro-
the individual firm and regional levels. posed by the literature. For instance,
Findings supported the positive effect of public research is often considered to be
social capital at the individual level but it essential in the technological change
was not so conclusive at a regional level. process. Moreover, these externalities
Our research aims to introduce and are not widespread and are in fact geo-
operationalize a model based on the graphically localized (Autant-Bernard
social capital perspective by including a 2001). Moreover, Anselin, Varga, and Acs
set of factors such as social interactions, (1997) evidenced the confirmation of
trust, shared vision, and the involvement earlier findings that academic externali-
of local institutions. This model provides ties are not only uniform across sectors

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 259


but also indicate important differences requires spatial proximity, codified
across sectors in terms of agglomeration knowledge is ubiquitous. The authors
effects (Varga 2000). have introduced the idea that even in
Previous research has explained how long-distance relations actors can feel
industrial districts and clusters represent they are in the same space.
local configurations that are high in A recent approach analyzes the com-
social capital and are characterized by munities of practice as mechanisms to
mutual trust, cooperation, and an entre- support individual and organizational
preneurial spirit, as well as by a multi- learning processes (Benner 2003). The
tude of small local firms (as opposed to need to access and exploit knowledge in
large firms) with complementary special- order to innovate is also affected by
ized competencies (Trigilia 2001; social structures. The so-called commu-
McEvily and Zaheer 1999). nities of practice are cross-firm associa-
The literature on the National System tions included in the territory that
of Innovation (Edquist 1997; Lundvall connect people beyond business rela-
1992) was focused on the national tions. These associations enforce the cre-
(regional) institutional environment. This ation of social capital values such as
literature offers a more complex and trust, shared vision, or social interac-
interactive framework with which to tions. At the core of this concept is the
understand the dynamics of the innova- argument that the fundamental process
tion process in a particular environment. by which people learn is through their
A further step may be the introduction of engagement in social practices (Brueck-
the territory in the discussion. Geo- ner 2006).
graphic concentration should be taken It is critical for an area or region to
account in the analysis particularly in the build its own intellectual and knowledge
case of knowledge-based industries resources and to avoid being dependent
(Audretsch and Feldman 1996). Regions on imported resources (Saxenian 1994).
are becoming focal points for knowledge This author presented evidence that a
creation and learning in the knowledge more open and decentralized industrial
society as they actually become learning system provided Silicon Valley’s entre-
regions. Learning regions function as col- preneurs with advantages in emerging
lectors and repositories of knowledge sectors, despite comparable technologi-
and ideas, and as an infrastructure which cal capabilities (in comparison with
facilitates the flow of knowledge, ideas, Route 128). It is also important to con-
and learning. sider the knowledge structure in the
Finally, we propose a social network context of the district. For instance,
approach based on geographic proxim- variety and coherence enforce the capac-
ity. Hakansson (1987) spelled out the ity of the firm the exploit new ideas and
advantages that technical development opportunities (Rantisi 2002).
could benefit from when generated In short, we have mentioned
within a network of actors. Nevertheless, firm-specific determinants and we have
networks can have a geographical also described external determinants.
dimension when they refer to a geo- We have introduced some examples
graphically bounded locality (De Propris (public research) and then we have
2002). Amin and Cohendet (2004) ana- used the National System of Innovation
lyzed the role of spatial proximity and framework. We have emphasized the
territorial embeddedness in the process role played by the territory and
of knowledge formation. These authors finally we have proposed a social
also consider learning based on relations network approach based on geographic
at a distance. Whereas tacit knowledge proximity.

260 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Social Capital and Innovation The function of social networks is to
Innovation refers to the conversion of enable the circulation of information and
knowledge into new products, services, trust both in terms of credit and relations
or processes to be introduced on the between firms, which in turn leads to
market (or the introduction of significant economic consequences for develop-
changes into existing ones). More spe- ment due to the exchanges that are fos-
cifically, innovation and firms’ capacity tered (Gambetta 1988). Information and
to innovate can be associated with the trust are referred to in terms of qualities
capacity to combine and exchange that would restrict opportunism as a
knowledge resources (Kogut and Zander resource that prevents cheating or fraud
1992). Resources in networks include in business (Trigilia 2001). As Yli-renko,
information, products, and personnel, as Autio, and Sapienza (2001) argue that the
well as support for these resources. degree to which firms use their external
Moran and Ghoshal (1996) have argued networks to acquire and exploit knowl-
that new sources of value are generated edge is regulated by the amount of social
by means of new exploitations of capital they possess. Through social
resources and, more particularly, interaction, firms may increase the
through new ways of exchanging and depth, breadth, and efficiency of the
combining resources. Either way, since mutual exchange of knowledge (Lane
the pieces of knowledge to be combined and Lubatkin 1998). Thus, the social
may reside in different parties, the network, as a strategic resource, exerts
exchange of information becomes a req- an influence on the future capabilities of
uisite for combination and thus for firms, and hence, it is an explanatory
knowledge creation (Cabrera and factor of their performance (Andersson,
Cabrera 2002). Forsgren, and Holm 2002).
Undoubtedly, knowledge and innova-
tion come from both internal and exter- Dimensions of Social Capital
nal sources, yet in the recent strategy and For the purposes of this paper, social
innovation literature, a great deal of capital is defined as the norms and social
emphasis has been placed on determi- relations embedded in the social struc-
nants that are external to the firm. These tures of society that enable people to
factors refer to the positive externalities coordinate action and to achieve desired
firms receive in terms of knowledge from goals. People in firms form part of the
the environment in which they operate different societal groups that determine
(Van Waarden 2001). More specifically, attitudes, beliefs, identities, and values,
interorganizational relationships create as well as access to resources and
opportunities for knowledge acquisition opportunities—and ultimately to power.
and exploitation (Lane and Lubatkin Since most of the organizations are not
1998). homogeneous, they differ in the access
As the embeddedness perspective they have to resources and power. There
argued, access to external innovation may be high social capital within a group
sources is associated with the character- (“bonding” social capital) which helps
istics of the interactions of the firm with members, but they may be excluded
other actors in the social networks. This from other groups (they lack “bridging”
perspective views economic action as social capital). The two types of social
embedded networks of ties, which firms networks we distinguish correspond to
maintain even with nonmarket actors Putnam’s (2000) concepts. He defines
(Oliver 1996). As an extension of this “bridging social capital” as bonds of con-
view, a firm embedded in social struc- nectedness that are formed across
tures is endowed with social capital. diverse social groups, whereas “bonding

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 261


social capital” cements only homogenous explain how concentration is the main
groups. Bridging social capital has a cause of success (Martin and Sunley
positive effect on growth, whereas 2003). For the purposes of this research,
bonding social capital has a negative the district concept is far more precise
effect on the degree of sociability outside and adequate to define the social
the closed social circle. We find evidence network. The district provides a number
for Fukuyama’s claim that the strength of of characteristics that condition the
the family bond implies a certain weak- dense and strong tie network.
ness in ties between individuals not
related to one another (Fukuyama 1995). The Effect of the Territory (District) on
Coleman (1990) stressed the positive Social Capital. Proximity can be
effect exerted by the cohesive or dense expected to shape social networks by
structure of the networks on the produc- producing a dense structure and strong
tion of social norms and sanctions ties. Therefore, firms benefit from effi-
that facilitate trust and cooperative ciency by exploiting existing opportuni-
exchanges. In the same vein, the strong ties through sharing high-quality
tie argument suggests that it provides information and tacit knowledge as well
organizations with two primary advan- as through cooperative exchange. If geo-
tages, namely, exchanges of high-quality graphical dispersion prevents or hinders
information and tacit knowledge, and it the generation of routines and redundan-
serves as a mechanism of social control cies of the interactions, face-to-face inter-
that governs the interdependencies in actions between actors induce the
partnerships (Uzzi 1996). In contrast, the frequency and redundancy of the ties
disperse characterization proposes the (McEvily and Zaheer 1999). In short,
structural holes approach (Burt 1992) as proximity provides frequent, repeated,
an alternative perspective that defines nonmarked, informal contacts, all of
social capital in terms of the information which facilitate strong ties and the
and control advantages of being the density of the network of ties. There may
broker in relations between otherwise be high-bonding social capital which
disconnected people within social struc- helps members, but they may be
tures. Moreover, Granovetter (1973) excluded from other groups because
argued in favor of the strength of the they lack bridging social capital.
weak tie, emphasizing how weak ties In the context of territorial networks
enable an actor to access new, exclusive we suggest that rather than creating this
information. portfolio of ties internally, firms can use
external parties (but which are still
Social Capital and Industrial within the district network) to connect
District themselves to disperse and weakly tied
Industrial District. We have deliber- networks. Among possible third parties,
ately avoided the discussion on the defi- we focus on local institutions. The exist-
nition of a cluster or district (see among ence of local institutions in industrial dis-
others: Maskell and Kebir 2005; Martin tricts has been widely discussed in the
and Sunley 2003; Maskell 2001). Our aim literature. In general, beyond providing
is to gain a better understanding of how firms with specific support services and
individual firms can explore and exploit other resource benefits (Baum and
the external resources that the agglom- Oliver 1992), local institutions act as
eration produces. The cluster cannot repositories for knowledge and opportu-
provide a universal model of how nities involving competitive capabilities.
agglomeration is related to regional and Although a great variety of arrangements
local economic growth and it cannot exists, in general, there is a set of both

262 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


private and public institutions within the nizational literature. Hence, the pro-
industrial district that carry out support- cesses of combination and exchange of
ing activities. For the purposes of this resources may be associated with inno-
research, we define local institutions as vation and may serve as an indicator of
locally oriented organizations that the creation of value. We have added the
provide firms in the local area with a role of the local institutions as a specific-
host of collective support services. ity of territorial clusters. Local institu-
Examples of local institutions include tions can act as intermediary agents
universities, research institutes, voca- between firms and external disperse net-
tional training centers, technical assis- works, in the way suggested by Burt
tance centers, and trade and professional (1992) and investigated by McEvily and
associations. Zaheer (1999).
In a very different context, other
authors have provided evidence of the Social Interactions and Innovation.
impact of local institutions on firm per- The intensity of the social interactions of
formance. An inventory of experiences one organization can be used as an indi-
can be found in Cooke and Morgan cator of social capital (Nahapiet and
(1998), and Cooke (2002), where the Ghoshal 1998). Social interactions are
authors reported different cases involv- channels through which information and
ing experiences that point to the exist- resources flow and enable an actor to
ence of an unwritten social constitution gain access to other actors’ resources.
which encourages firms, their associa- Social interactions dissolve the bound-
tions, and local public bodies to support aries between organizations and stimu-
their interests through joint solutions to late the formation of a common interest.
common problems. Social interactions connect managers,
technicians, and employees from differ-
Hypotheses ent firms. These interactions occur at
Tsai and Ghoshal (1998), among social events held for reasons to do with
others, have examined how social capital the family or friendships and include
contributes to the ability of the organiza- activities performed by the so-called
tion to create value in the form of inno- “communities of practice.” In this
vations. A good way to gain a better context, information and ideas, which
understanding of the potential benefits are knowledge resources, can be
of social capital is to use its different accessed, interpreted, and transmitted
dimensions (Nahapiet and Ghoshal through these networks. In conse-
1998). To conceptualize these dimen- quence, the absence of these interactions
sions of social capital, we used the social reduces the sources of knowledge firms
interactions, trust, and shared vision can access and, in particular, they run
hypotheses. into difficulties when it comes to access-
In general, we have used the Moran ing tacit knowledge or finding high-value
and Ghoshal (1996) argument that new information.
sources of value are generated through Several studies (of both intra and
new exploitations of resources and, more interorganizational relationships) have
particularly, through new ways of com- stated the importance of social interac-
bining and exchanging resources. To tions for the creation and diffusion of
create new and better products, firms innovation (Ibarra 1993). Consequently,
need to reallocate resources, combine if an organizational firm develops a
new resources, or produce new combi- greater number of social interactions
nations of already existing resources. with other firms, it will have more oppor-
Similar propositions appear in the orga- tunities to exchange and combine

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 263


resources in the network and, as a result, one actor can probably obtain the help
this will have a positive effect on inno- needed to attain goals from other actors
vation. These advantages include obtain- to a degree that is not possible in a
ing information and access to specific situation where trust does not exist.
resources (Powell, Koput, and Smith- Relational trust appears when two
Doer 1996). Consequently, a firm with an parties begin to trust each other and they
abundance of social interactions is likely become more willing to share their
to have a greater capability to combine resources without worrying about being
and exchange resources with other taken advantage of by the other party.
actors, and so enhance its innovation Thus, cooperative behavior may emerge
capacity (Tsai and Ghoshal 1998). We which involves the exchange or combi-
can hypothesize this as follows: nation of resources. Following Nahapiet
and Ghoshal (1998), where relationships
H1: Social interactions of the firm are high in trust, people are more willing
will be positively associated with to engage in social exchange in general
innovation. and cooperative interaction in particular.
Moreover, trust promotes the exchange
Trust and Innovation. Trust acts as of a range of resources that are difficult
mechanism of control over the to put a price on, but which enrich an
exchanges between actors in the organization’s ability to compete and
network; it is a subtle dimension of solve problems. Trust is fundamentally a
social capital. Trust acts as a mechanism social process, as these mechanisms and
governing embedded relationships (Uzzi expectations are emerging features of a
1996), thus facilitating innovation and social structure that creates and repro-
learning (Meeus, Oerlemans, and Hage duces them over time.
2001). Actors that trust and are trusted by When an actor creates a reputation for
others give and receive information and trustworthiness, this is important infor-
knowledge resources freely without fear mation for other actors in the network. It
of being cheated or misled. Absence of is reasonable therefore to expect that a
these mechanisms gives rise to difficul- unit with greater trustworthiness is more
ties in understanding each other, or to likely to be a frequent exchange partner
costly monitoring of the exchanges, for other actors in the network. The
which can even include legal contracts or firm’s trustworthiness may act as a signal
the legal resolution of conflicts. to other parties. Several recent studies
Previous researchers have argued that have emphasized the role of trustworthi-
trust in interorganizational settings may ness in governing social and economic
foster innovation (Dakhli and De Clercq exchange (Tsai 2000). Trustworthiness
2004). A high level of trust among orga- not only constrains opportunistic behav-
nizations facilitates the exchange of con- ior but also reduces the costs of finding
fidential information by diminishing the an exchange partner (Deroïan 2002).
risk that one party will opportunistically Hence, it can be argued that different
exploit this information to the other’s levels of perceived trust and trustworthi-
disadvantage (Knack and Keefer 1997). ness may result in different levels of both
Trust also facilitates social exchange by exchange and combination of resources
reducing the need for time consuming between firms in the same network, thus
and costly monitoring, and therefore enhancing innovation in the organiza-
makes it possible for people and organi- tions. Accordingly, we propose:
zations to devote additional time to ben-
eficial actions and endeavors (Blau H2: The level of trust of a firm is posi-
1964). Since trust induces joint efforts, tively associated with innovation.

264 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Shared Vision and Innovation. Shared Both aspects are present in district firms
vision is a final mechanism to make it and may be a feature that differentiates
possible for knowledge resources to flow them from external or isolated firms. We
through the network. Sharing vision can therefore view shared vision as being
allows for more fluent transmission; a mechanism that helps different organi-
since the actors share vision they use zations to integrate or to combine
“the same language,” which is a subtle resources, thus enhancing firms’ level of
dimension of social capital. Shared vision innovation. We formulate the hypothesis
is identified as a shared code or para- as follows:
digm, which facilitates a common under-
standing of the collective objectives and H3: Sharing the firm’s vision with the
the proper ways to act within a social rest of the firms will be positively asso-
system (Nahapiet and Ghoshal 1998). ciated with innovation.
This common understanding can be
appropriated by the collective as a Local Institutions and Innovation. Lo-
resource (Portes and Sensenbrenner cal institutions are significant actors in
1993). networks that provide specific knowl-
Shared vision includes collective goals edge as a consequence of their position
and aspirations of the members of the as intermediaries. Institutions are in
network. When the members of the contact with many diverse, external
network have the same perceptions circles and at the same time are close to
about how to act with the others, they the internal district firms; as a result they
can avoid possible misunderstandings in can explore and transfer new, exclusive
their communications and have more information, knowledge, and opportuni-
opportunities to freely exchange their ties. Institutions use two mechanisms to
ideas and resources; this in turn helps provide firms with knowledge and inno-
them to see the potential value of com- vation. As intermediaries, local institu-
bining and exchanging resources (Tsai tions facilitate the acquisition of
and Ghoshal 1998). It can be shown that competitive capabilities by compiling
shared vision allows organization bound- and disseminating knowledge and by
aries to be crossed and access to reducing search costs. We have backed
resources from other units. our argument with previous research
According to the specific literature, to such as Baum and Oliver (1992) or
some extent firms in districts share some McEvily and Zaheer (1999).
of the characteristics described in the Local institutions that have links with
notion of shared vision in a similar way external networks may supply the indus-
to what happens in the individual corpo- trial district with new ideas and concepts
ration (Piore 1990). The district is char- that are continually refined because of
acterized as a group of firms working internal redundancy, proximity, and
together and there is an interfirm rather transactional intensity. Consequently,
than an intrafirm division of labor firms can take advantage of having net-
(Becattini 1990). This notion was based works of ties with local institutions that
on two aspects, one referring to a provide a feasible source of information
common perception about how to inter- on the options to enhance the firms’
act with one another, and the other capabilities. Beyond providing local
involving common goals or interests. The firms with specific support services and
first aspect is related to previous experi- other resource benefits, local institutions
ence or repeated interactions and the also act as repositories for knowledge
latter has to do with common interests and opportunities involving innovations.
beyond the individual firm’s interests. Because these institutions interact with a

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 265


large number of firms in the geographi- firms. Hence, it can be argued that the
cal district, they are exposed to a wide involvement of local institutions has a
variety of solutions to organizational direct effect on the capacity of district
challenges. firms to innovate. Accordingly, we
There are several ways in which local propose:
institutions may facilitate the creation of
value for firms. (1) Local institutions offer H4: Firm involvement in local institu-
specific support services, such as techno- tions will be positively associated with
logical services (standardization, control innovation.
of products or control of quality systems).
These services enable firms’ quality man- District Affiliation and Innovation.
agement to be improved (McEvily and Proximity facilitates the redundancy of
Zaheer 1999). (2) Local institutions orga- relationships and face-to-face contacts,
nize training activities for district firm and also facilitates the building of
employees. These activities enhance the common norms and values. It can be said
human capital in firms. In general, their that district membership is associated to
training programs are about specific or sharing attitudes, beliefs, identities, and
applied knowledge or skills that would values, and in consequence, bond capital
otherwise be difficult to obtain. (3) Local arises. However, how to gain bridging
institutions interact with many internal social capital in order to connect with
and external firms and institutions. This external and diverse networks is a much
variety provides institutions with a spe- greater challenge. Social interactions,
cific capacity to compare and evaluate trust, and shared vision (as indicators of
different solutions to problems since they bonding social capital) are expected to be
are members of broader scale associa- higher inside the district than outside it.
tions, participate in congresses, or carry We agree that district membership
out joint projects with external partners, probably affects firms in a systemic or
and so on. In this way, district firms not global manner rather than acting on just
only save search costs but also receive a one individual factor. Frost (2001) estab-
feasible source of information on the lished the link between exploitation/
options they have available to enhance exploration, on the one hand, and the
their capabilities. (4) They frequently location of firms’ external knowledge
undertake research projects with local sources, on the other. This idea fits into
firms and joint research projects are often what may be described as the strategic
carried out between researchers from perspective on external sources of inno-
both institutions and firms. Internal spill- vation (Powell, Koput, and Smith-Doer
overs occur through formal and informal 1996). A rather different line of thinking
channels of communication, thus allow- emphasizes the emergent properties of
ing district firms to increase their capacity such networks and their embeddedness
to innovate. (5) These organizations also (Granovetter 1985) in the social relations
promote products and firms in national of technological innovation. Saxenian
and international markets, and in this (1994), for example, noted that school,
way local institutions enable district firms career, and friendship ties are important
to explore new markets while minimizing mechanisms through which external
the risks they take. Moreover, by moni- technical knowledge is located, accessed
toring international trade fairs, local insti- and assimilated. Bianchi and Bellini
tutions generate economies of scale for (1991, p. 488) argued that innovation
firms. Part of the common promotion is networks are underpinned to an impor-
conducted through the development of a tant extent by “social solidarity” and best
district/country brand that benefits all sustained through constant interaction

266 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


and geographical proximity. An impor- resources, extensive Mediterranean coast
tant question refers to the fact that including significant tourist resorts.
although membership gives firms access Finally, the traditional agricultural sector,
to knowledge resources endowment, this which was important in the past, has
does not mean that all members benefit declined dramatically in recent years.
to the same extent. On the contrary, each Manufacturing firms are basically
of the actors has a particular and unique SMEs; in fact, according to official statis-
network of relationships, and specific tics, 48 percent of the firms had less than
characteristics such as knowledge struc- six employees, and only 1 percent of the
ture, degree of complementary, or simi- firms employed more than 100 workers.
larity of knowledge endowment, and so The basic tool for promoting innovation
on. In consequence, although all in the Valencia region is the Instituto de
members of the district may enjoy advan- la Pequeña y Mediana Industria Valenci-
tages, the extent to which they are used ana (IMPIVA), which depends on the
may vary. Consequently, the industrial regional government and is responsible
district may combine both strategic for developing the innovation policy in
requirements to reach higher levels of the region by focusing on SMEs. The
innovation in comparison to external and IMPIVA offers a variety of services and
isolated firms. From the foregoing, we organizes action programs addressed to
formulate the following hypothesis: support industrial SMEs, and at the same
time foster a network of technological
H5: District affiliation will be positively infrastructures to lend support to inno-
associated with a firm’s innovation. vations. This activity is manifested in two
networks, namely, Technological Insti-
Research Methodology tutes and a network of European Busi-
The Empirical Setting ness and Innovation Centres.
Valencia Region. The empirical
research drew upon a sample of Spanish Collecting Data. The identification
industrial firms located in the Valencia drew on previous research. For instance,
Region. Valencia has a population of Ybarra (1991) has identified as many as
about 4.5 million inhabitants, represent- eleven different industrial districts in the
ing about 10 percent of both the Spanish Valencia region. Moreover, the Spanish
population and GDP. The industrial struc- Ministry of Industry has recently pub-
ture of the region is based on a number of lished a map of districts using a quanti-
industrial districts, such as ceramic tiles, tative criterion (Trullen and Boix 2005).
shoes, furniture, toys, textiles, etc. Both sources have been used for us to
Mention must be made of a Ford car- distinguish between district members
manufacturing plant in the region that has and nonmembers. The firms selected for
fostered an important network of supplier our empirical research were intended to
firms in its vicinity. A significant tourism be representative examples of the manu-
industry is also well established, which is facturing firms in the Valencia region. By
a consequence of the region’s natural using a public database (ARDAN 2000),1

1
The ARDAN is a public database published by IMPIVA, a regional industrial policy agency, and
it provides productive and financial information about all manufacturing firms except those that
have an annual revenue below Euros 240,000. We used firms from up to 18 different industrial
segments or SIC epigraphs and, in order to define the sample, we used a random stratified
selection process to choose firms, with assignation in proportion to their size and product
segments.

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 267


we were able to identify the address and nature. It is said that the existence of
four-digit Standard Industry Classifica- more interactions between actors facili-
tion (SIC) of the companies involved in tates access to the information and
the study. knowledge of others. An actor (a firm)
Data were collected using a question- that maintains a larger number of inter-
naire distributed among firms. These actions with other firms in the district is
were administered in face-to-face inter- more likely to be able to manage more
views addressed to the general manager flows of knowledge resources. We used
of each firm. We contacted 400 firms and as reference Tsai and Ghoshal (1998).
obtained 220 complete and correct
responses, of which 129 were district Trust. The variable trust refers to the
member respondents and the remaining degree to which an actor or a firm is
91 were nondistrict member firms. Since considered to be fair and honest in the
few precedents were available to guide exchange of any kind of resources
the development of indicators, fieldwork degree an actor or a firm is considered as
helped to refine the choice of constructs to be fair and honest in the interchange
and identify the most relevant items. of whatever resource. Firms build a repu-
Item selection was also based on the tation of trust (or on the contrary, mal-
feedback obtained from a pilot question- feasance), probably on the basis of
naire. For the sake of simplicity, we previous experience. This perception can
employed a five-point Likert scale. affect the intensity and the quality of
Two sample controls were run. With flows of resources firms allow to be
regard to the bias due to nonrespondent shared and exchanged with another firm.
firms, we checked for possible differ- Moreover, as it is well known in the
ences between sample and nonrespon- literature, trust as interexchange control
dent firms, and no significant differences mechanism can substitute more formal
in terms of size and technological or contractual controls as a mechanism
attributes were observed. Once firms had to control exchange. We based ourselves
been classified as belonging to one of on Tsai and Ghoshal (1998) and Blum-
two clusters according to their industrial berg (2001).
district affiliation, they were checked for
the presence of significant differences Shared Vision. Shared vision refers
with respect to size and product seg- to an attribute that people and firms may
ments. However, none were found. A full have that can facilitate and offer them
description of the items used to define certain benefits. Shared vision is about
variables can be seen in Appendix I. the cognitive perception of others; it is
about beliefs or common fate. It
Research Design involves, for instance, a common lan-
Independent Variables guage, common cultural-based values of
Social Interactions. A social interac- the business success and risk aversion,
tion is any contact or relation that an and so on. Although organizations
actor or employee from one firm keeps pursue individual goals, they may under-
with other actors or employees from stand that they share their fate with other
other firms in the community which can organizations in the same ambit (or dis-
affect their access to and use of knowl- trict). This is to be expected since at the
edge resources of the firm. The variable same time organizations pursue their
“social interactions” refers to intensity in own individual strategies, they are also
terms of the number of times actors part of a collective strategy. However,
share time in any kind of event including this attribute or ability is not developed
those of a social, familiar, or other to the same extent by all organizations.

268 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


We used Tsai and Ghoshal (1998) as a (1998), and Meeus, Oerlemans, and Hage
reference. (2001).

Involvement of Local Institutions. Control Variables. In order to isolate


Not all organizations in the district (or the effect of the variables included in our
outside it) have the same ability or will- model, we selected two control variables,
ingness to interact with local institutions. the size of the firm (Hitt, Hoskisson, and
For instance, this may depend on how Kim 1997) and R&D efforts (Hagedoorn
complementarity or similarity of the and Duysters 2002). The size variable
structure of the internal endowment of allows us to control for economies and
knowledge resources of the organization diseconomies of scale at firm level. Addi-
is with respect to what local institutions tionally, R&D investments have tradition-
are offering, In consequence, involve- ally been used to control innovation in
ment may vary from one organization to individual firms (Cohen and Levinthal
another. We based ourselves on McEvily 1990).
and Zaheer (1999).
Analysis Techniques
Industrial District Affiliation. Al- First, we classified firms in two clus-
though there are different methods to ters according to their industrial district
identify a district and district members, affiliation. We then calculated separate
in our opinion the one that best reflects descriptive statistics (mean and standard
what they really mean is the “perceptual” deviation) for all multiple-item variables
identification. This involves collecting and, in order to find the validity of the
the actors’ opinions about whether they aggregation, we calculated the value of
belong to a district or not. This is also the Cronbach’s alpha for the same variables.
most faithful to Becatinni’s original defi- In order to test hypotheses 1, 2, 3, and 4
nition. When we collected data from we used the estimated model of multiple
managers, we provided them with a list linear regression analysis (similar to
of industrial districts. Based on Becattini Hagedoorn and Duysters 2002). To see
(2002), we asked managers directly how much additional variance was
whether their firms belonged to one of explained by the district affiliation vari-
the listed industrial districts or not; able (hypothesis 5), we tested our
responses were controlled using firms’ hypotheses with a hierarchical regres-
addresses. Dummy variables have been sion analysis, entering independent vari-
used to identify affiliation in similar ables in the first step, the district variable
studies, such as those by Hundley and in step 2, and tracing changes in the
Jacobson (1998), and Geringer, Tallman, multiple-squared correlation coefficient
and Olsen (2000), among others. (R2) from step to step (in a similar
manner to the methods used in previous
Dependent Variables research, for instance).
Innovation. Innovation in the
context of research is understood as any Results
idea, practice, or object that is perceived Since it was not possible to use cen-
as new by an organization and that is trality measures in our sample, we were
implemented and used successfully in faced with reliability concerns. In
the market. To measure this variable, we general, construct data depend on
asked for the number of product and respondents’ ability to assess the ties
process innovations that had been pro- accurately (Marsden 1993). On reviewing
duced in their firm. This measurement of some material, we found similar con-
innovation is based on Tsai and Ghoshal cerns in previous research and adopted

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 269


similar solutions to control for them. For Table 2 shows the results of the hier-
this reason, we evaluated the validity of archical regression analysis conducted in
answers using data gathered from a order to estimate the effects of district
second knowledgeable respondent who affiliation on innovation. Hypotheses 1,
was able to provide an accurate report. 2, 3, and 4 predicted that social interac-
This study surveyed the contacts of 25 tions, trust, shared vision, and involve-
randomly selected second respondents. ment of local institutions are likely to
Drawing on these analyses, it is reason- make firms more innovative, both in
able to conclude that the validity of the product and process innovation. The
measures is acceptable since no signifi- coefficients for all these relationships are
cant mean differences were found. positive and significant, indicating that
Table 1 shows descriptive statistics they do indeed contribute to innovation.
and Cronbach’s alpha for the multiple- Hence, hypotheses are supported.
item variables, and Pearson’s correlation Hypothesis 5 predicts a direct effect of
for all combinations of variables. The district affiliation on firm innovation. The
least favorable Cronbach’s alpha value coefficient for district affiliation is posi-
corresponded to the multiple-item scale tive and significant (p < .05; p < .01),
measuring process innovation, with a which indicates that firms belonging to
score of 0.61. Bearing in mind that the the district are likely to be more innova-
scale had not been used before, the tive. Hypothesis 5 is therefore confirmed.
values of the alpha were within the limits Moreover, the introduction of the district
of tolerance suggested in the literature affiliation variable in the second step of
(Malhotra 1997). the regression analysis enables us to
As can be seen in Table 1, social determine the improvement of the
capital indicators were significantly explanatory capacity of the model (D
higher for district firms. As also Adjusted R2), which is reflected in a
expected, our dependent variables (both change in the Adjusted R2 value from
product and process innovation) showed 0.314 to 0.325 for product innovation,
significantly higher values for district and from 0.231 to 0.323 for process inno-
members. This is to be expected from vation. Differences exist between the
our theoretical reasoning. Finally, with social capital variables of district and
regard to control variables, neither size nondistrict firms. Among independent
nor R&D investments showed any signifi- variables, the local institution involve-
cant differences between member and ment variable was the most significant
nonmember firms. This can be explained when the district affiliation variable is
by the fact that belonging to a district introduced. This means that for district
cannot determine any of the dimensions. members, the role played by local insti-
These results, however, may contradict tutions is much more relevant than for an
certain district literature assumptions, external nondistrict member. Thus, dis-
such as the lower the size of the district trict firms are heavily dependent upon
firms, the less internal R&D effort they their institutions.
make. Control variable results can be
Tolerance and variance inflation explained. Size, for example, is not asso-
factor (VIF) statistics were run to deal ciated with innovation as can be
with concerns about multicollinearity. expected since internal division of labor
However, the least favorable values for in the district allows economies of scale
the Tolerance (0.857) and VIF (1.116) throughout the territory. R&D, also as
statistics for the Local Institutions vari- expected, is associated with innovation
able are considered to be satisfactory in since it is an indication of the absorptive
order to avoid multicollinearity. capacity of the firms.

270 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Table 1
Descriptive Statistics, Means, Standard Deviation, Cronbach’s Alpha, and Comparison
of Means
Variables Mean (District Members) S.D. a Mean (No District S.D. a F
N = 129 Members) N = 91

(1) Product Innovation 1.72 1.28 0.63 1.55 1.25 0.63 2.572*
(2) Process Innovation 1.74 0.97 0.61 1.21 0.82 0.61 3.216*
(3) Social Interactions 3.84 0.69 0.75 3.21 0.79 0.78 12.684**
(4) Trust 3.43 0.93 0.79 2.86 0.93 0.78 15.259**
(5) Shared Vision 3.67 0.77 0.68 2.98 0.97 0.69 14.604**
(6) Local Institutions 3.45 0.75 0.85 2.87 0.94 0.85 15.259**
(7) Size 1.26 0.47 — 1.25 0.51 — 0.002 (a)
(8) R&D 5.02 5.75 — 5.23 9.69 — 0.037 (a)

Accompanied by (a) indicates nonsignificance.


a = Cronbach’s alpha for all multiple-item variables.

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ


*Difference between district members and nonmembers significant at p < .05.
**Difference between district members and nonmembers significant at p < .001.

271
272
Table 2
Results of Hierarchical Regression Analysis: Effects of District Affiliation on
Firm Innovation
Firm Innovation

Product Innovation Process Innovation

Variable
Constant 1.949† (0.113) 1.879† (0.163) 3.004† (0.181) 2.990† (0.165)
Size 0.006 (0.031) 0.017 (0.064) 0.064 (0.051) 0.115 (0.064)
R&D 0.025* (0.006) 0.121† (0.033) 0.077* (0.022) 0.119** (0.059)
Social Interactions 0.157† (0.030) 0.153*** (0.047) 0.240* (0.059) 0.278*** (0.024)
Trust 0.117** (0.058) 0.110** (0.048) 0.218** (0.060) 0.217** (0.032)
Shared Vision 0.115* (0.120) 0.147† (0.035) 0.113* (0.066) 0.159** (0.065)
Local Institutions 0.114** (0.052) 0.160* (0.038) 0.180* (0.109) 0.364† (0.039)
District Affiliation 0.131** (0.079) 0.217*** (0.030)
R2 Adjusted 0.314 0.325 0.231 0.323
F 13.419† 17.279† 7.833† 14.257†
D R2 Adjusted 0.011 0.092
DF 3.86 6.424

JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


N = 220.
Nonstandardized regression coefficients (errors within brackets).
*p < .10.
**p < .05.
***p < .01.

p < .001.
heterogeneity and questioning the tradi-
Discussion tional industrial district model (Rabellotti
Findings of the research are useful to and Schmitz 1999). According to Lazer-
discern some issues to be discussed in son and Lorenzoni (1999), larger firms
greater detail. One the most relevant frequently organize production among
refers to the mechanisms that a firm can groups of smaller firms, introduce tech-
use to be connected to external firms and nological innovations, and expand exist-
the role that intermediary agents can ing markets. Moreover, Bellandi (2001)
play in this process. proposed that involvement in knowledge
We assume that linkages with firms exchange and institutional building and
outside the district were produced therefore the identification of develop-
mostly using “bridging” actions by an mental embeddedness, are more prob-
intermediary actor. Several explanations able where and when local factors are
for the barriers that prevent firms from neither too weak nor too strong, and in
gaining direct access to external net- the presence of contextual policies fos-
works can be suggested. First, one tering the developmental role of large
primary reason refers to the small size of units. In fact, some authors try to
the firms in districts. Indeed, in most combine leadership, institutions, and
cases, these firms do not have significant large firms (Cooke 2002). Finally, Malipi-
R&D and marketing departments. Thus, ero et al. (2005) analyze the role of focal
for instance, they cannot afford to make firms in industrial clusters as “gatekeep-
the large financial investments required ers” that introduce external technological
for research projects. The second reason novelties in the cluster and enact useful
concerns the need for an intensive new knowledge production locally, thus
exchange and combination of resources enhancing the capabilities to be competi-
in the innovation process, and conse- tive on the international scene of all the
quently, an important interfirm coordina- firms in the cluster.
tion effort is also required. In the
industrial district, there is a high degree Conclusions
of specialization, and hence, knowledge Findings support the idea that social
and innovation involve efforts by other capital variables affect the innovation of
groups of firms. Finally, the high trans- firms. This means that knowledge
action cost of knowledge transfer in the exchanges required for innovation were
open external markets is also observed. favored under certain relational condi-
The barriers can be justified since search- tions. However, study findings went
ing for new opportunities to improve the even further since they offered a more
innovation capabilities of firms implies precise view of the extent to which these
high levels of uncertainty and risk. Firms social capital indicators can explain inno-
can avoid risks by using intermediaries vation. In consequence, they provide
to provide a feasible source of informa- useful information for firms in order to
tion about the existing options. Regard- know how their particular relational net-
ing the transmission of tacit knowledge works must be designed.
between two organizations, difficulties in By using the social capital theory to
the formalization of these resources explain innovation, we can give a com-
make transmission through market rela- prehensive and complete explanation
tionships more complicated. that enables us to understand the rela-
Recently, some industrial district theo- tions between firm-specific and regional
rists have reviewed the presence and factors explaining innovation. In the lit-
role of the large firm within the district. erature, many works have attempted to
This has involved reconsidering internal prove the so-called district or territory

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 273


effect. Rather than simply justifying the ditions (Molina-Morales and Martínez-
competitive superiority of the district Fernández 2004). Dynamics between the
firms, our model can also be used to formation of tacit and codified knowl-
analyze differences among firms within edge and other elements of innovation
the district and external differences processes call for a reassessment of insti-
among districts. tutional arrangements. A full explanation
Firms inside in industrial district may of the benefits of the systemic effects
combine diverse types of ties and links in probably comes from the perspective of
order to establish connections and thus individual firm capabilities. The distinct
enhance their innovative capacity. We capabilities of the firm may be based on
argue that firms’ embeddedness in net- specific resources for exploiting the local
works of social, economic, and profes- environment or on fitting characteristic
sional ties is an important, if somewhat organizational features to the district
neglected, perspective in strategy environment. These capabilities allow
research. synergies to be obtained from the use of
In the industrial district tradition, different shared resources (Lam 1997).
most authors have considered the district
as a whole, analyzing only aggregate Limitations of the paper
data and results. According to the litera- and future research
ture, the geographically “bounded” Finally, mention must be made of
agglomerations may yield a number of some of the limitations of our research.
beneficial nontraded interdependencies. Because of the use of district affiliation
These interdependencies are significant as a control variable, we are cautious
factors in explaining why some geo- about inferring any degree of causality
graphically bounded entities may among the key constructs. Although we
prosper or lag behind other entities. This have presented hypotheses in a manner
perspective does not take into account that implies certain independence among
the fact that firms may present significant variables, it is possible that district affili-
internal (that is, within the district) dif- ation explains other variables, such as
ferences in terms of characteristic fea- the dimensions of social capital and
tures and performance. involvement of local institutions. Conse-
The main contribution made by our quently, further research is needed to
work is to the existing body of research elaborate the relationship between the
linking industrial districts with innova- different elements of the model. More-
tion. This established stream of research over, in order to capture social capital
contains a number of works worth men- elements in the interactions between
tioning, such as McEvily and Zaheer actors within the district, future research
(1999) or Capello (1999a, 1999b). In both should also take additional cultural
these studies, social or relational capital issues into account.
is analyzed as a factor for creating inno- As a matter for further discussion, we
vative capacity in firms. However, suggest that in order to access external
according to our findings, it can be sources of new and exclusive knowl-
shown how there are significant differ- edge, firms in districts should use indi-
ences between the effects of these factors rect rather than direct ties by means of
on internal and external firms. intermediary agents (Molina-Morales and
Our proposition supported a number Martínez-Fernández 2004). In particular,
of prescriptions for firms’ strategies. We local institutions are relevant actors in
argue that firms should interact with territorial networks that provide specific
local institutions and other participants knowledge as a consequence of their
in order to improve environmental con- position as intermediaries.

274 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Another question may be raised as to Populations,” American Sociological
the diversity of the local institutions. Review 57, 540–559.
Since local institutions may be predomi- Becattini, G. (1990). “The Marshallian
nately from the same industry, the infor- Industrial District as a Socio-Economic
mation accessed by local firms may be Notion,” in Industrial Districts and
less diverse. Thus, a deeper analysis is Local Economic Regeneration. Eds. F.
needed of how local institutions vary in Pyke, G. Becattini, and W. Sengen-
terms of the scope of the activities they berger. Geneva: International Institute
carry out. Finally, it could be interesting for Labour Studies, 37–51.
to investigate on the limits of the positive ——— (2002). “Industrial Sectors and
effect of the social capital. Decreasing Industrial Districts: Tools for Indus-
returns could occur when all firms in a trial Analysis,” European Planning
network are connected through embed- Studies 10, 483–493.
ded ties. In fact, the decreasing impact of Bellandi, M. (2001). “Local Development
social capital beyond a certain level of and Embedded Large Firms,” Entre-
social interactions and trust results in preneurship and Regional Develop-
parochialism and inertia. ment 13, 189–210.
Benner, C. (2003). “Learning Communi-
ties in a Learning Region: The Soft
References Infrastructure of Cross-Firm Learning
Ash, A., and P. Cohendet (2004). Archi- Networks in Silicon Valley,” Environ-
tectures of Knowledge: Firms Capabili- ment and Planning A 35, 1809–1830.
ties and Communities. Oxford, UK: Bianchi, P., and N. Bellini (1991). “Public
Oxford University Press. Policies for Local Networks of Innova-
Andersson, U., M. Forsgren, and U. Holm tors,” Research Policy 20(5), 487–497.
(2002). “The Strategic Impact of Exter- Blau, P. M. (1964). Exchange and Power
nal Networks: Subsidiary Performance in Social Life. New York: Wiley.
and Competence Development in the Blumberg, B. F. (2001). “Cooperation
Multinational Corporation,” Strategic Contracts between Embedded Firms,”
Management Journal 23, 979–996. Organization Studies 22(5), 825–852.
Anselin, L., A. Varga, and Z. Acs (1997). Brueckner, J. K. (2006). “Friendship Net-
“Local Geographic Spillovers between works,” Journal of Regional Science
University Research and High Tech- 46(5), 847–865.
nology Innovations,” Journal of Burt, R. S. (1992). “Social Structure of
Urban Economics 42, 422–448. Competition,” in Networks and Orga-
ARDAN (2000). Comunidad Valenciana nizations: Structure, Form and
(2000). Directorio e Informe Action. Eds. N. Nohria and R. G.
Económico-Financiero. Vigo, Spain: Eccles. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
Consorcio de la Zona Franca de Vigo. School Press, 57–91.
Audretsch, D. B., and M. P. Feldman Cabrera, A., and E. Cabrera (2002).
(1996). “Innovative Clusters and the “Knowledge-Sharing Dilemmas,”
Industry Life Cycle,” Review of Indus- Organization Studies 23(5), 687–710.
trial Organisation 11, 253–273. Capello, R. (1999a). “Spatial Transfer of
Autant-Bernard, C. (2001). “Science and Knowledge in High-Technology
Knowledge Flows: Evidence from the Mileux: Learning versus Collective
French Case,” Research Policy 30(7), Learning Processes,” Regional Studies
1069–1078. 33(4), 353–368.
Baum, J. A. C., and C. Oliver ——— (1999b). “A Measurement of
(1992). “Institutional Embeddedness Collective Learning Effects in
and Dynamics of Organizational Italian High-Tech Milieux,” Réveu

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 275


d’Economie Régionale et Urbaine 3, tional Diversification among Japanese
449–468. Multinational Firms,” Strategic Man-
Cohen, W. S., and D. A. Levinthal (1990). agement Journal 21, 51–80.
“Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspec- Geroski, P. A. (1995). “Markets for Tech-
tive on Learning and Innovation,” nology: Knowledge, Innovation and
Administrative Science Quarterly 35, Appropiability,” in Handbook of Eco-
128–152. nomics of Innovation and Technologi-
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundation of cal Change. Ed. P. Stoneman. Oxford,
Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: UK: Blackwell, 90–131.
Harvard University Press. Granovetter, M. S. (1973). “The Strength
Cooke, P. (2002). Knowledge Economies. of Weak Ties,” American Journal of
Clusters, Learning and Cooperative Sociology 78, 1360–1380.
Advantage. London: Routledge. ——— (1985). “Economic Action and
———, N. Clifton, and M. Oleaga (2005). Social Structure: The Problem of
“Social Capital, Firm Embeddedness Embeddedness,” American Journal of
and Regional Development,” Regional Sociology 91, 481–510.
Studies 39(8), 1065–1077. Hagedoorn, J., and G. Duysters (2002).
———, and K. Morgan (1998). The Asso- “Learning in Dynamic Inter-Firm Net-
ciational Economy: Firms, Regions works: The Efficacy of Multiple Con-
and Innovation. Oxford, UK: Oxford tacts,” Organization Studies 23(4),
University Press. 525–548.
Dakhli, M., and D. De Clercq (2004). Hakansson, H. (1987). Industrial Tech-
“Human Capital, Social Capital, and nological Development. A Network
Innovation: A Multicountry Study,” Approach. London: Croom Helm.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Devel- Hitt, M. A., R. E. Hoskisson, and H. Kim
opment 16, 107–128. (1997). “International Diversification:
De Propris, L. (2002). “Types of Innova- Effects on Innovation and Firm Perfor-
tion and Inter-firm Cooperation,” mance in Product-Diversified Firms,”
Entrepreneurship and Regional Devel- Academy of Management Journal 40,
opment 14(4), 337–353. 767–798.
Deroïan, F. (2002). “Formation of Social Hundley, G., and C. K. Jacobson (1998).
Networks and Diffusion of Innova- “The Effects of Keiretsu on Export
tions,” Research Policy 31, 835–846. Performance of Japanese Companies:
Edquist, C. (1997). Systems of Innova- Help or Hindrance?,” Strategic Man-
tion. Technologies, Institutions and agement Journal 19, 927–937.
Organizations. London: Pinter. Ibarra, H. (1993). “Network Centrality,
Frost, T. S. (2001). “The Geographic Power and Innovation Involvement:
Sources of Foreign Subsidiaries’ Inno- Determinants of Technical and
vations,” Strategic Management Administrative Roles,” Academy of
Journal 22, 101–123. Management Journal 36, 471–501.
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The Social Knack, S., and P. Keefer (1997). “Does
Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. Social Capital Have an Economic
New York: The Free Press. Payoff? A Cross-Country Investiga-
Gambetta, D. (1988). “Can We Trust tion,” Quarterly Journal of Economics
Trust?,” in Trust: Making and Break- 112, 1251–1288.
ing Cooperative Relations. Ed. D. Kogut, B., and U. Zander (1992). “Knowl-
Gambetta. New York: Basil Blackwell, edge of the Firm, Combinative Capa-
213–238. bilities and the Replication of
Geringer, J. M., S. Tallman, and D. M. Technology,” Organization Science
Olsen (2000). “Product and Interna- 3(3), 383–397.

276 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Lam, A. (1997). “Embedded Firms, hagen. [WWW document]. URL http://
Embedded Knowledge: Problems of www.druid.dk/wp/pdf_files/05-
Collaboration and Knowledge Trans- 09.pdf
fer in Global Cooperative Ventures,” Meeus, M. T. H., L. A. G. Oerlemans, and
Organization Studies 18(6), 973–996. J. Hage (2001). “Patterns of Interactive
Lane, P. J., and M. Lubatkin (1998). Learning in a High-Tech Region,”
“Relative Absorptive Capacity and Organization Studies 22(1), 145–172.
Interorganizational Learning,” Strate- Molina-Morales, F. X., and M. T.
gic Management Journal 19, 461–477. Martínez-Fernández (2004). “Factors
Lazerson, M., and G. Lorenzoni (1999). That Identify Industrial Districts. An
“The Firms That Feed Industrial Dis- Application in Spanish Manufacturing
tricts: A Return to the Italian Source,” Firms,” Environment and Planning A
Industrial and Corporate Change (EPA) 36, 111–126.
8(2), 235–266. Moran, P., and S. Ghoshal (1996). “Value
Lundvall, B.-A. (1992). National Systems Creation by Firms,” Academy of Man-
of Innovation: Toward a Theory of agement, Best Paper Proceedings,
Innovation and Interactive Learning. 41–45.
London: Frances Pinter. Nahapiet, J., and S. Ghoshal (1998).
McEvily, B., and A. Zaheer (1999). “Social Capital, Intellectual Capital,
“Bridging Ties: A Source of Firm Het- and the Organizational Advantage,”
erogeneity in Competitive Capabili- Academy of Management Review
ties,” Strategic Management Journal 23(2), 242–266.
20, 1133–1156. Oliver, C. (1996). “The Institutional
Malhotra, N. K. (1997). Marketing Embeddedness of Economic Activity,”
Research: An Applied Orientation. in Advances in Strategic Management.
New York: Prentice-Hall. Eds. J. A. C. Baum and J. E. Dutton.
Malipiero, A., F. Munari, and M. Sobrero. Greenwhich, CT: JAI Press, 163–187.
(2005). Focal Firms as Technological Piore, M. (1990). “Work, Labor and
Gatekeeperswithin Industrial Dis- Action: Work Experience in a System
tricts: Knowledge Creation and of Flexible Production,” in Industrial
Dissemination in the Italian Packag- Districts and Inter-Firm Cooperation
ingMachinery Industry, DRUID in Italy. Eds. F. Pyke, G. Becattini, and
Working Paper 05-05. http:// W. Sengenberger. Geneva: Interna-
www2.druid.dk/conferences/ tional Institute for Labor Studies,
viewpaper.php?id=2580&cf=17. 10–19.
Marsden, P. V. (1993). “The Reliability of Portes, A., and J. Sensenbrenner (1993).
Network Density and Composition “Embeddedness and Immigration:
Measures,” Social Networks 15, 145– Notes on the Social Determinants of
161. Economic Action,” American Journal
Martin, R., and P. Sunley (2003). “Decon- of Sociology 98, 1320–1350.
structing Clusters: Chaotic Concept or Powell, W. W., K. W. Koput, and L.
Policy Panacea,” Journal of Economic Smith-Doer (1996). “Interorganiza-
Geography 3, 5–35. tional Collaboration and the Locus of
Maskell, P. (2001). “Knowledge Creation Innovation: Networks of Learning
and Diffusion in Geographic Clus- in Biotechnology,” Administrative
ters,” International Journal of Inno- Science Quarterly 41(1), 116–145.
vation Management 5(2), 213–225. Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling Alone:
———, and L. Kebir (2005). “What The Collapse and Revival of American
Qualifies as a Cluster Theory?,” Community. New York: Simon &
Working Papers 05–09, Druid, Copen- Shuster.

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 277


Rabellotti, R., and H. Schmitz (1999). Tsai, W. (2000). “Social Capital, Strategic
“The Internal Heterogeneity of Indus- Relatedness and the Formation Inter-
trial Districts in Italy, Brazil and organizational Linkages,” Strategic
Mexico,” Regional Studies 33, 97– Management Journal 21, 925–939.
108. ———, and S. Ghoshal (1998). “Social
Rantisi, N. (2002). “The Local Innovation Capital and Value Creation: The Role
System as Source of ‘Variety’: Open- of Intrafirm Networks,” Academy of
ness and Adaptability in New York Management Journal 41(4), 464–478.
City’s Garment District,” Regional Uzzi, B. (1996). “The Sources and Con-
Studies 36, 587–602. sequences of Embeddedness for the
Saxenian, A. L. (1994). Regional Advan- Economic Performance of Organiza-
tage: Culture and Competition in tions,” American Sociological Review
Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cam- 61, 674–698.
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Van Waarden, F. (2001). “Institutions and
Sternberg, R., and O. Arndt (2001). “The Innovation: The Legal Environment of
Firm or the Region: What Determines Innovating Firms,” Organization
the Innovation Bbehavior of European Studies 22(5), 765–795.
Firms?” Economic Geography 77(4), Varga, A. (2000). “Local Academic
364–382. Knowledge Transfers and the Concen-
Storper, M., and A. Scott (1989). “The tration of Economic Activity,” Journal
Geographical Foundations and Social of Regional Science 40(2), 289–309.
Regulation of Flexible Production Whitley, R. (1999). “The Institutional
Complexes,” in The Power of Geogra- Structuring of Innovations Strategies:
phy: How Territory Shapes Social Life Firm Type and Innovation Patterns in
Social Reproduction. Eds. J. Wolch Different Business Environment,”
and M. Dear. Boston, MA: Unwin and NIAS Workshop, Wassenaar, June 16.
Hyman, 21–40. Ybarra, J. A. (1991). “Industrial Districts
Trigilia, C. (2001). “Social Capital and and the Valencian Community,”
Local Development,” European OIT, Discussion Papers DP/44. New
Journal of Social Theory 4(4), 427– Industrial Organisation Programme,
442. Geneva.
Trullen, J., and R. Boix (2005). “Knowl- Yli-renko, H., E. Autio, and H. J. Sapi-
edge, Networks of Cities and Growth in enza (2001). “Social Capital, Knowl-
Regional Urban Systems,” paper pre- edge Acquisition, and Knowledge
sented at the Knowledge and Regional Exploitation in Young Technology-
Economic Development. Open Con- Based Firms,” Strategic Management
ference 2005, Barcelona, 9–11 June. Journal 22, 587–613.

Appendix I
Operationalization of Variables
Social interaction: (1) People from your company spend a considerable amount
of time on social occasions with people from other firms; (2) People from your
company spend a considerable amount of time on social events organised by the
local community; (3) A local origin and common academic background of the
employees at local firms allow social interactions to take place; and (4) There is an
informal network among customers, suppliers and competitors. Responses were
scored on a 5-point Likert scale, where 1 = fully disagree and 5 = fully agree. To
measure the variable, we obtained an average of all the items for each firm and
Cronbach’s alpha was run to validate the aggregation of items.

278 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Trust: (1) Other firms can rely on your company without any fear that you will
take advantage of them, even if the opportunity arises to do so; (2) In general your
company will always keep the promises it makes to others; (3) Suppose your
company is seeking to be a business partner in a joint project. You are confident that
you will do what is required in the agreement (i.e., what partners believe you should
do) even without a written contract that clearly specifies your obligations; and (4)
You consider that other firms feel a special duty to stand behind you in times of
trouble, so you consider it only fair that your company should also give support to
other firms. Responses were scored on a 5-point Likert scale where 1 = fully disagree
and 5 = fully agree. To measure the variable we obtained an average of all the items
for each firm and Cronbach’s alpha was run to validate the aggregation of items.
Shared vision: (1) You and the people in your company share the same ambitions
and vision as other companies in your local area; (2) People in your company are
encouraged and motivated to pursue the collective goals and mission of the whole
local area; (3) You consider that your company’s future is related to other firms in the
area; and (4) There is some kind of collective strategy or plan for firms in the whole
area. Responses were scored on a 5-point Likert scale where 1 = fully disagree and
5 = fully agree. To measure the variable we obtained an average of all the items for
each firm and Cronbach’s alpha was run to validate the aggregation of items.
Involvement of local institutions: (1) Your company has received significant
support for R&D activities from local institutions; (2) You or your employees have
received specific training by local academic institutions; (3) Your company has
received considerable information about products and markets from local institu-
tions; and (4) You consider that you cannot receive support from external firms
directly, instead of through local institutions. Responses were scored on a 5-point
Likert scale where 1 = fully disagree and 5 = fully agree. To measure the variable we
obtained an average of all the items for each firm and Cronbach’s alpha was run to
validate the aggregation of items.
Industrial district affiliation: We used a dummy variable to represent affiliation
to Valencian districts or the absence of such affiliation.
Product innovation: (1) Number of developments or introductions of new mate-
rials; (2) Number of developments or introductions of new intermediate products; (3)
Number of developments or introductions of new components; and (4) Number of
developments or introductions of new attributes of the products. To measure the
variable, we added up the number of innovations reported for each item over the
period of time under consideration and Cronbach’s alpha was run to validate the
aggregation of items.
Process innovation: (1) New developments or introductions of new equipment;
(2) Improvements in the level of automation; (3) Number of new organizational
methods of the productive activities; and (4) Use of new energy sources. To measure
the variable, we added up the number of innovations reported for each item over the
period of time under consideration and Cronbach’s alpha was run to validate the
aggregation of items.
R&D expenditure: It is frequently argued that the absorptive capacity of firms can
be operationalised through their investment in R&D (Cohen and Levinthal 1990). The
percentage of investment in R&D over the total sales of the firms was used as an
indicator.
Size: Size was operationalised as the number of employees (1 = 11–50 employees;
2 = 51–250 employees; 3 = +250 employees).

MOLINA-MORALES AND MARTÍNEZ-FERNÁNDEZ 279

You might also like