You are on page 1of 7

Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco

The economics of new nuclear power plants in liberalized electricity markets


Pedro Linares a,b,c,⁎, Adela Conchado a
a
U. Pontificia Comillas, Instituto de Investigación Tecnológica, C/Alberto Aguilera 23, 28015 Madrid, Spain
b
Economics for Energy, Spain
c
MR-CBG, Harvard Kennedy School, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Available online 20 September 2013 Even after Fukushima, the nuclear debate is strong in many countries, with the discussion of its economics being a
significant part of it. However, most of the estimates are based on a levelized-cost methodology, which presents
JEL Classification: several shortcomings, particularly when applied to liberalized electricity markets. Our paper provides results
Q41 based on a different methodology, by which we determine the break-even investment cost for nuclear power
Q47
plants to be competitive with other electricity generation technologies. Our results show that the cost
L94
competitiveness of nuclear power plants is questionable, and that public support of some sort would be
Keywords: needed if new nuclear power plants are to be built in liberalized markets.
Nuclear power © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Economics
Liberalized electricity markets

1. Introduction second, its higher security of supply and lower price volatility compared
to fossil fuel alternatives.2 These have been joined recently by an
The nuclear industry has been riding a roller coaster lately. After additional one, cost. Although cost has usually been considered to be
much talk of a “renaissance”, both in popular (e.g. Crumley, 2009) and one of the four “problems” of nuclear power plants, together with safety,
academic sources (Nuttall, 2009; Nuttall and Taylor, 2009), the accident proliferation, and waste (e.g. MIT, 2003), some studies recently put nu-
at Fukushima triggered a backlash that has resulted in proposed phase- clear power plants as a competitive alternative for electricity generation,
outs in Germany or Switzerland, and even talks about them in nuclear- particularly when introducing a price for carbon emissions (e.g. Joskow
heavy France. Davis (2012) concluded recently that the prospects for and Parsons, 2009; Nicholson et al., 2011). This has prompted some
nuclear power plants in the US were quite bleak. to formulate the nuclear debate as a trade-off question: either we have
However, as Joskow and Parsons (2012) point out in their review of nuclear, or we must pay more for our electricity. In turn, others argue
the nuclear prospects after Fukushima, although a full-blown “renais- that nuclear electricity needs some kind of support by governments
sance” was probably not realistic (particularly in developed countries), (e.g. Newbery, 2010).
the accident's effects will likely be modest at a global level. Indeed, We find this discussion about costs very relevant for energy policies
Steven Chu, the former US Secretary of Energy, declared recently that worldwide: if nuclear energy is required for achieving a low carbon
“I think nuclear power is going to be a very important factor in getting future, or for having more stable electricity prices, we should ascertain
us to a low carbon future”. The recent European Energy Roadmap whether this will take place spontaneously, that is, if firms will invest
2050 (EC, 2011a, 2011b) also considers that nuclear power plants will in new nuclear plants just out of its cost competitiveness; or if we rather
be needed to achieve the ambitious decarbonization targets imposed. need some degree of public support — and, in this case, if this support
Even Japan seems to be reconsidering their decision to phase-out nuclear is justified or not.
power plants after Fukushima. Most recently, the UK has cleared one of Therefore, a careful analysis of the cost of new nuclear power plants,
the last administrative hurdles for building a new nuclear power plant and of its comparison with other electricity generation alternatives
in Hinckley Point. seems more than warranted. However, most of the studies looking at
This possible renaissance for nuclear power plants is fueled basically the costs of nuclear power do so by using a levelized-cost methodology,
by two arguments: one, its relatively low carbon emissions1; and which in turn depends critically on assumptions of investment cost,

⁎ Corresponding author. Universidad Pontificia Comillas. Alberto Aguilera 23, 28015


2
Madrid, Spain. These arguments do not seem to have had much impact on improving public accep-
E-mail addresses: pedro.linares@upcomillas.es (P. Linares), tance of nuclear power plants, at least in the UK, where a recent study found that “concern
adela.conchado@iit.upcomillas.es (A. Conchado). about climate change and energy security will only increase acceptance of nuclear power
1
See Sovacool (2008) or Beerten et al. (2009) for surveys of lifecycle assessments of under limited circumstances — specifically once other (preferred) options have been
greenhouse gas emissions for nuclear power plants. exhausted” (Corner et al., 2011).

0140-9883/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2013.09.007
S120 P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125

and is also of limited application for deregulated markets (which are their costs, but also on their income. And this income will be basically
currently the standard in Europe and also in many states in the US). the electricity market price, which is in turn determined by the cost
The objective of this paper is to try to contribute to a better under- of the marginal unit.4 Since these are usually gas or coal power plants,
standing of the cost competitiveness of new nuclear power plants in the price will be determined by gas, coal, and carbon allowance prices.
liberalized electricity markets, by using an improved methodology to Again, this affects differently baseload technologies – nuclear – and
undertake the analysis. Our results can be read in two ways: from a pri- marginal technologies — coal or gas.
vate perspective, if nuclear power is competitive in a purely monetary These two latter problems are further complicated by the general
basis; and also, if deemed appropriate due to other reasons, if it will inability of LEC methodologies to account for different electricity load
require economic support from governments for private companies to levels (and therefore different prices and operating hours). Joskow
invest. Section 2 presents a review of some of the current studies and (2011) has already pointed out this problem for renewables, although
discusses their shortcomings. Section 3 describes the methodology, the argument can easily be extended to other non-baseload technolo-
data used in the paper, and the results obtained. Finally, Section 4 offers gies such as natural gas: it is not only how many hours a plant operates,
some conclusions and recommendations. but which hours.
We would like to make clear before going on that we acknowledge We also mentioned before that the LEC methodology is not
that a nuclear policy should not only take into account economic well suited for liberalized electricity markets. First, in these markets
costs: all advantages and disadvantages of nuclear power plants should cost recovery is not guaranteed, and new, cheaper technologies may
also be considered to make a final decision: whether to allow new easily displace existing investments before the end of their expected
investments or forbid them, whether to penalize nuclear power plants lifetime (Linares and Isoard, 2001), therefore reducing their cost
or support them. In order to do that a full cost-benefit analysis or competitiveness. Second, the LEC methodology does not handle
at least a quantification of the externalities to be considered should be well the risks underlying liberalized electricity markets (Kessides,
carried out — see e.g. Kennedy (2007) as an example of this approach. 2010). Real options approaches have been developed (Roques
However, we believe that the discussion of monetary costs is rich et al., 2006; Rothwell, 2006) to address, at least partially, these con-
enough as to focus just on it in this paper. cerns. Unfortunately, these methods also suffer from similar short-
comings regarding the assumptions to be made about costs and
operating hours.
2. Assessing the costs of nuclear power
Finally, LEC studies only take into account costs, but not the volume
of new investment in an electricity market: other constraints coming
As mentioned before, most of the studies looking at the cost of new
from energy policy (renewable energy promotion, for example), the
nuclear power plants are based on a levelized-cost (LEC) methodology.
shape of the load curve (with no requirements for new baseload
Koomey and Hultman (2007) offer a fine example of this approach, as
power) or the extension of the license of existing power plants – as
well as a review of previous studies. Rothwell (2004) also discusses
has been the case for over half of US nuclear plants (Davis, 2012) –
the fundamentals of the costs of nuclear. The most relevant and updated
may not allow for new investments in nuclear plants.
study may be the update of the MIT report “The future of nuclear”
Therefore, we believe that the analysis of the cost competitiveness
(Du and Parsons, 2009). Other up-to-date study worth citing is Cooper
of new nuclear power plants would be improved by using a different
(2009). The LEC methodology has become very popular, since it pro-
methodology such as the one presented in this paper. This method
vides a single indicator of the competitiveness of the different electricity
assesses the cost competitiveness of new nuclear power plants by
generation technologies. However, it also has several shortcomings,
inquiring whether there would be any spontaneous (that is, based on
particularly for liberalized markets, which we discuss below.
cost competitiveness alone) investments in the electricity system studied,
First, it is critically dependent on the assumption of investment cost.
and which should be the investment cost required to allow for these in-
Of total costs for nuclear electricity, approximately 70% come from
vestments to take place.
investment cost (20% from O&M costs, and 10% from fuel). However,
To do that, we simulate the behavior of the electricity market in the
as Joskow and Parsons (2009) correctly point out, the lack of reliable
long term, with a generation-expansion model. The model optimizes in-
contemporary data for the actual construction costs of real nuclear
vestment and operation decisions for the power system until 2054,
plants make very uncertain any estimate of future construction – and
based on the existing fleet, and on the expected demand growth, in-
therefore electricity generation – costs. Indeed, some of the studies
vestment costs, fuel prices, and technical constraints. The model also
pointing to cost competitiveness for nuclear were based on the MIT
includes a representation of carbon and renewable energy support
(2003) figure of $1500/kW, which was not a real construction cost but
policies (although it considers RES production as deterministic, not
just a target to be attained. Therefore, it would be better to use a method
stochastic). It has a large level of load block detail. Although the
that does not require assuming an investment cost ex-ante.
model allows for representing oligopolistic conditions, for this exer-
Another critical assumption in LEC studies is the number of hours of
cise we have run it as a cost-minimization, linear version due to the
operation for the different technologies. Since investment costs are dis-
computational constraints. A full description of the model can be
tributed among all operating hours to calculate the final cost of generat-
found in (Linares et al., 2008a), or can be requested from the authors.
ing electricity, the more hours a plant is assumed to operate, the cheaper
We leave the investment cost for nuclear power plants as a decision
it will be. However, the number of hours a plant operates also depends on
variable, and iterate until we find the break-even investment cost, that
its cost, and therefore this becomes endogenous to the problem. Although
is, the investment costs that makes it profitable to build new nuclear
this is not usually a critical issue for nuclear3 – since nuclear plants usu-
power plants.
ally provide baseload power, and therefore run continuously –, it is for
This allows us to solve most of the problems related to LEC: we do
marginal units such as gas combined cycles or coal power plants, that
not have to assume ex-ante any investment cost for nuclear or operating
is, the alternatives against which nuclear should be compared.
hours for all technologies, since these are outputs of the model; we
Another endogeneity issue is the correlation between fuel prices,
account not only for costs, but also for income, since the price of the
carbon prices, and electricity prices — more salient in liberalized
electricity market is endogenously determined by the model — even
markets. The competitiveness of power plants will depend not only on
considering the effect of market power, since the model allows for
3
This clearly changes in a system with a large penetration of intermittent renewables.
4
In this case, nuclear power plants must regulate production to accomodate the variable We are assuming here a uniform pricing auction. However, although less common, lib-
production of renewables, and therefore will reduce the number of hours it operates eralized markets might also be organized around a pay-as-bid scheme, in which this con-
according to the amount of renewables in the system. nection between income and marginal unit bid is removed or at least mitigated.
P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125 S121

simulating oligopolistic behavior; we simulate the evolution of liberal- other studies are overnight costs, so this is the unit we will use for our
ized electricity markets, by allowing for new technologies to retire ear- assessment.
lier investments even if their costs have not been recovered; and we As for the investment and operation costs for the alternative tech-
take into account other possible constraints of the system, such as re- nologies: the relevant ones are the investment cost for gas combined
newable energy promotion, or demand growth. In addition, we are cycles and that for coal power plants, together with the cost of operating
able to compare all the possible electricity-generation technologies si- coal power plants. As will be explained below, the price of gas will be a
multaneously in an easier way. variable parameter, and the cost of renewables is not relevant for this
Although the paper is clearly focused on liberalized markets, our analysis because their contribution will be set as a quota — that is,
results can also be applied to regulated ones, although with caution: we will not compare nuclear and renewables on a cost basis, although
the impact of uncertainty would be clearly mitigated under a fixed separate analysis show that wind energy will be competitive with
rate-of-return scheme in which income is decoupled from market prices nuclear energy under most of the scenarios.
and risks are transferred from generators to consumers. We have assumed an investment cost for gas combined cycles
of 700 €/kW, and 1610 €/kW for coal power plants, and efficiencies of
58% and 48% respectively (IEA, 2012). These figures are close to those
3. An application to the Spanish electricity market by Du and Parsons (2009), which facilitates the comparison of results.
The price of coal is set at 2.6 US$/MMBtu. We have assumed 2 years
We have applied the method presented above to the Spanish elec- for building a gas combined-cycle, and 2 years – possibly a bit optimis-
tricity system, since we consider it is a good representative of liberalized tic, here we follow Du and Parsons (2009) – for a coal power plant.
European and US power markets and therefore some of our results may A relevant issue here is carbon capture and sequestration. We have
be easily extrapolated to them. not included this technology in the analysis basically because it is not
The 2012 Spanish electricity mix is basically 10–15% hydro expected to become commercial in the following ten years (the scope
(depending on rainfall), 22% nuclear, 20% coal (both imported and do- in which we have looked for new nuclear investments). In addition, at
mestic, the latter including black and brown lignite), and 15% combined the carbon prices considered (see below), it would probably not become
cycles. Renewables (not including hydro) contribute to 20% of the total competitive (Al-Juaied and Whitmore, 2009).
demand, and are expected to grow up to 40%. The market is a rather Finally, some caveats, and their consequences on results: we take
concentrated one, with two larger firms covering a large part of the fuel prices as fixed (although they will probably be volatile, which
generation market and only four more small firms with some genera- would be positive for nuclear), we do not consider intermittency in
tion capacity, which cover the rest of the market. More information renewable energy production (this makes our results more favorable
about the Spanish electricity system and its expected evolution may for nuclear energy, since nuclear power plants cannot follow well the
be found e.g. in Linares et al. (2008b). changes in intermittent renewable energy production and therefore
In addition, we believe that this type of study is very relevant for would need to reduce operation), and we do not account for financial
Spain, in which a very strong debate is being held about the future issues. We are also not taking into account other economic issues out-
role of nuclear in the electricity mix. The recent government decisions side the scope of the model, such as the possible capacity constraints
over the extension of the operating license for the oldest nuclear (human and manufacturing infrastructure) due to an increased demand
power plant in Spain illustrate this fact: the previous government for nuclear power plants, which in turn might result in higher costs
denied it, and afterwards the current government approved it. In any (Joskow and Parsons, 2009). Although of course incorporating all
case, the debate does not seem to be closed. these issues would certainly improve the validity of our results, we
think that they should not change much the overall picture, at least in
the short term.
3.1. Basic assumptions
3.2. Uncertain parameters
We will assess the competitiveness of the construction of new
nuclear power plants in the next twelve years (2012–2024).5 We have Of course, we would not attempt to carry out an analysis of the com-
chosen twelve years as the relevant period to be assessed because it petitiveness of nuclear power plants under a single scenario. There are
is short term for construction purposes, and therefore we can safely many uncertainties surrounding the economics of nuclear power plants
assume that the technology will be very much the same as the current (Nuttall and Taylor, 2009; Rothwell, 2004) and here we have selected
one, and also to remove much of the long-term uncertainties. the ones which we consider more relevant: the growth of demand,
We do not include dismantling or waste management costs — except the development of renewable energy – which will basically result in
for the current fees being charged for low- and medium-level waste a lower demand for conventional sources, but also on a change in the
management. At the discount rates used (see below), costs such as net load curve –, the discount rate (or hurdle rate) for the investment,
these, which take place 40 years or more in the future, are not relevant. the price of natural gas, the price of carbon allowances, the construction
We also do not consider inflation. Therefore, all our costs are real duration of nuclear power plants, and the availability of nuclear power
2012 euros. We believe the impact of inflation should not be very plants. For all of them, we have selected a baseline figure, and a reason-
relevant, since it should affect similarly all technologies (capacity con- able range. In this sense, we have tried to follow the recommendations
straints aside, see below). Indeed, the only relevant impact might from Koomey and Hultman (2007), in that assumptions that deviate
come from the difference in construction duration between the differ- significantly from historical experience need careful justification.
ent technologies, particularly concerning nuclear. However, we try to
deal with this by using overnight costs as our reference investment 3.2.1. Annual demand growth
cost for nuclear power plants. We agree with Koomey and Hultman We assume as our baseline figure a 1% annual demand growth. This
(2007) in that installed costs give a more acceptable picture of actual is quite low compared to the pre-crisis figures for Spain (around 4% for
capital costs than do the overnight costs by incorporating capital costs the last years). However, the recent recession has resulted in a change
and inflation. However, most of the real costs quoted in industry and in this trend, and in fact energy officials and utilities do not expect
to return to 2007 levels until at least 2020. Therefore, choosing 1% as
the average annual growth for the entire period considered seems like
5
This requires us to simulate more years, to cover the economic lifetime of the power a reasonable assumption, moreover given the emphasis given by the
plants. We have simulated therefore a period from 2012 until 2054. European Union to energy conservation programs.
S122 P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125

The lower value for the range has been set a 0.5% as a conservative follow a very spiky trend and therefore it is difficult to agree on a
estimation, whereas the higher value has been set at 2% (which again reasonable range. Currently, prices in Europe are around 7 $/MMBtu,
seems reasonable given the long term implied). which were also the average prices before the oil price crisis. Therefore,
we have chosen that figure as our baseline assumption. The lowest
3.2.2. Contribution of renewables bound is set at 4 $/MMBtu (close to current prices in the US), and
Given that in most electricity markets in Europe renewables do not the highest one at 14 $/MMBtu, taken from historical records. However,
enter the market based on cost, but based on public support, and that and in order to account for the expectations of much higher oil
this support is usually determined based on a volume quota – although prices in the future, we have also considered an “extreme” scenario of
it may sometimes be instrumented through a subsidy –, we have formu- 20 $/MMBtu.
lated the scenarios for the contribution of renewables as targets for the
specific technologies, as proposed by most governments in Europe. 3.2.5. Price of carbon allowances
These targets are 42,000 MW for onshore wind, 3000 MW for offshore Carbon allowance prices are also very variable in nature, and in addi-
wind, 5300 MW for solar thermal, 8000 for solar PV, 3200 for biomass, tion, this variability comes from regulatory decisions (the targets for
and 5500 MW for small hydro. These targets have been set for 2020– carbon emissions reductions). This makes them quite difficult to predict,
2030, and, although there is currently a moratorium on new renewable so again, we have relied in those values most used in the literature. The
energy in Spain, satisfying the European Union mandated targets will baseline value has been set at 18.75 €/tCO2 (equivalent to 25$), with the
require achieving this installed power. Indeed, the European Union lower and higher ends set at 10 and 40 €/tCO2. The lower and mid
Energy Roadmap 2050 (EC, 2011a) requires an even more ambitious values are consistent with the prices observed at the EU ETS, with the
share of renewables, so we have accounted for that by assuming a pos- higher value trying to represent the expected price for 2020–2030.
sible increase of 25% of these targets. We also consider the possibility of These seem reasonable estimates for the time frame considered
the targets not being met (quite possibly for biomass and solar thermal, (2012–2054). But again, we should not exclude higher allowance prices
but also for the rest if the subsidy is not high enough or if the moratori- in the future, if climate negotiations are successful and more stringent
um is extended), and therefore we also analyze a 25% decrease in these targets are set. Therefore, we also consider an “extreme” scenario of
targets. 100 €/tCO2. However, in view of the current trends in the EU ETS in
As mentioned before, the amount of renewables in the system can which carbon allowances are reaching very low prices, we also consider
not only affect the room for new investment, but also the shape of the it necessary to include a scenario of 0 €/tCO2.
net load curve, and therefore the must-run nature of nuclear power
plants. 3.2.6. Construction duration
The baseline scenario assumes 6 years for the construction of a
3.2.3. Discount rate nuclear power plant, from the start of the licensing period – when the
This is possibly one of the most critical parameters of this type of first costs are incurred – to the start of the operation phase. This number
analysis. Given the large weight of investment costs for nuclear, the has been taken from Du and Parsons (2009), and is considered too low
rate at which these costs are written off will determine to a large extent by Koomey and Hultman (2007), who cite 9 years as the median
the competitiveness of this technology. Here the most relevant question duration for the US nuclear fleet. However, as cited in this latter paper,
is whether the discount rate for nuclear power plants has to be different “construction duration in the historical sample was influenced by a
from that of gas or coal power plants. complex set of interrelated factors, including rapid regulatory changes
Under a merchant power plant model, such as the one followed in (both before and after the Three Mile Island accident), quality control
Du and Parsons (2009), it seems reasonable to allocate a risk premium problems in construction, increased reactor size, reduced electricity
for nuclear. Both the large contribution of investment costs and the demand growth, and utility financial constraints”. This, together with
risks for delays and cost overruns, together with the variation in market the recent efforts to streamline the licensing procedure, would make it
prices, are reasons enough for this (Ramana, 2009). Indeed, Roques et al. reasonable to assume a certain reduction of construction times, as we
(2006) calculate a risk premium between 3 and 5.2% for merchant do here. In fact, the IAEA database shows that construction times since
plants. It could be argued that investing in nuclear power plants reduces 1991 range from 4 to 8 years, with a median of 5.2, as cited in Roques
a company's overall exposure to fossil fuel and gas prices. However, the et al. (2006).
higher correlation between gas, carbon allowance, and electricity prices However, and particularly after the Fukushima disaster triggered
reduces the intrinsic riskiness of these investments to a lower level than extensive reviews of safety procedures, we also include a more pessi-
nuclear plants (Newbery, 2010; Roques et al., 2006). mistic scenario of 9 years to assess its impact on the results, and because
But it is not clear whether the merchant model would be viable in a of the historic risk of delays — also shown more recently in the Olkiluoto
liberalized environment. As has been shown by the recent bids in the power plant. On the optimistic side, we assume 5 years as the construc-
UK, utilities seem to be thinking about financing investments from tion duration.
their own balance sheet. Although that severely limits the number of
investments to be undertaken – since only the more powerful players 3.2.7. Availability of nuclear power plants
have enough financial muscle and expertise to do it –, it seems that The availability of nuclear power plants has improved very much
this is currently the only realistic alternative, and therefore it is the recently, partly because of the incentives of a liberalized electricity mar-
one we will consider. We acknowledge of course that this improves ket (Davis and Wolfram, 2012; Zhang, 2007). Recent figures for the US
the competitiveness of nuclear power plants in our analysis, and that are around 90%, compared to 71% in 1992. Spanish nuclear power plants
should be taken into account in the results. also feature availabilities higher than 90%. However, as Joskow and
Therefore, we will use a reasonable weighted average cost of capital Parsons (2009) correctly point out, it is the lifetime capacity factor
(WACC) measure as the hurdle rate. Our baseline assumption is a WACC that should be used, since new plants must recover their investment
of 9%, with a range between 6 and 12%. This is pretty consistent with the over their economic lifetime. Only Finland has a lifetime capacity factor
references in the literature (Cooper, 2009; Du and Parsons, 2009). higher than 90% for its nuclear fleet. The lifetime factor for the US is 78%,
and the global capacity factor in the last decade is 82%. Therefore,
3.2.4. Price of natural gas it seems reasonable to use a baseline figure of 85%, within a range of
Natural gas prices are probably the most volatile of the parameters 80–90%, as a lifetime capacity factor for new nuclear power plants.
considered. Their linking to oil prices – although it seems that this is A summary of all the values considered for the uncertain parameters
becoming less so, moreover with the advent of shale gas – make them is presented in Table 1.
P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125 S123

Table 1 cost is 3779 €/kW. We also try a scenario with zero carbon price and
Values for the uncertain parameters. obtain a break-even overnight cost of 1679 €/kW.
Low Baseline High

Annual demand growth 0.5% 1% 2%


3.4. Discussion: comparison with current overnight costs
Contribution from Decrease 25% Wind: 42,000 MW Increase 25%
renewables Offshore wind: 3000 MW
Solar thermal: 5300 MW Our final step to assess the economic competitiveness of nuclear
Solar PV: 8000 MW power plants should be then to compare the break-even overnight
Biomass: 3200 MW
costs obtained with the current overnight costs as declared by the
Small hydro: 5500 MW
Discount rate 6% 9% 12%
industry.6 First we rely on the exhaustive work carried out by Du and
Gas price 4 $/MMBtu 7 $/MMBtu 14 $/MMBtu Parsons (2009), who put on comparable terms the most recent cost
Carbon allowance price 10 €/tCO2 18.75 €/tCO2 40 €/tCO2 filings in the US, Japan and South Korea. These are shown in Tables 3
Construction duration 5 yr 6 yr 9 yr and 4. Costs have been translated from US$ to euro using a 0.7 rate.
for nuclear
However, real costs revised recently for the two nuclear plants under
Availability of nuclear 80% 85% 90%
construction in Europe are less optimistic: 3500 €/kW for Olkiluoto
Source: own elaboration.
Finland (compared to initial previsions of 2100 €/kW), and 3650 €/kW
for Flamanville in France (Rangel and Lévêque, 2012). In the UK,
the cost estimations for Hinckley Point C are even higher, around
3.3. Break-even cost for nuclear 5100 €/kW (Reed, 2013).
As may be observed, the break-even overnight cost obtained in our
Once we have determined all the parameters for our model, we pro- analysis (2609 €/kW for the mid estimate) is below the average of the
ceed to run it. As explained before, we run the generation-expansion costs proposed for new nuclear power plants in the US, and only beyond
model iteratively until we find the break-even investment cost for one of them. That would mean that nuclear could be competitive only
new nuclear, that is, the maximum investment cost that will allow for for the nuclear projects with the lowest projected costs, and only if
investing in this technology in a profitable way. the parameters considered remain at their set values (particularly the
For the baseline scenario (the mid values in the ranges of variable most critical parameters described before), and most importantly, if
parameters), the break-even overnight cost that should be attained by there are no cost overruns. If we use as a reference the $4000 figure
new nuclear plants is 2,609 €/kW. For the rest of the scenarios consid- employed by Du and Parsons, or if we take the 3500–5100 €/kW
ered the break-even overnight cost is presented in Table 2. We present cost expected for the nuclear plants under construction or planned in
the results for the optimistic and pessimistic values (from the nuclear Europe, then nuclear energy becomes clearly not competitive.
point of view). When more optimistic scenarios are considered (basically, higher
As may be seen, nuclear energy becomes more competitive, expect- gas and carbon prices, or lower discount rates), nuclear energy gets a
edly, when: bit closer to the range of competitiveness depending on the region
(estimated break-even costs of 2600–3100 €/kW compared to real
– Demand increases, or renewable energy targets are reduced. costs of about 2800 €/kW in the US, 3500–5100 €/kW in Europe),
– The discount rate is lower. again if there are no cost overruns. However, there is also the possibility
– Carbon prices are higher. of finding less optimistic scenarios: if gas prices are not high enough
– Gas prices are higher. (one possibility is the large supply of shale gas translating into lower
– Nuclear plants availability increases. global gas prices), carbon prices are not high enough (because of loose
– Construction duration is reduced. carbon targets, or competitiveness concerns), interest rates are higher
It may also be observed that the most critical parameters are the dis- (either global, or due to a risk premium for nuclear), or there are signif-
count rate, the gas and carbon price, and also the construction duration. icant delays in construction times (as experienced before), then, even
Demand growth and the contribution from renewables show a moder- without cost overruns, nuclear power plants would not be competitive,
ate influence in the break-even cost. sometimes by a large margin. This would be further accentuated in a
We have also considered it interesting to run two extreme scenarios scenario with a large penetration of intermittent renewable energy,
(those in which both the pessimistic and optimistic values are combined, since, as mentioned before, nuclear cannot provide the flexibility
respectively) to have a worst- and best-case estimation of the overnight required in that scenario.7
cost to be attained by new nuclear power plants. Under the worst-case Finally, another reason that makes the scenario for nuclear power
scenario, the overnight cost should be lower than 1097 €/kW. Under plants less appealing is the marginal character of our analysis. It should
the most favorable one, the overnight cost should be lower than be remarked that what our model is estimating is the break-even cost
4038 €/kW. for a new nuclear power plant. But, if this plant is built and starts
We also ran an extreme “climate” scenario, in which carbon prices operating, it will bid at very low prices (corresponding to its variable
reach 100 €/tCO2, and gas prices reach 20 $/MMBtu. The rest of param- cost), and therefore will reduce the wholesale electricity price, making
eters remain at their baseline values. Here the break-even overnight additional capacity not competitive.8 Therefore, the same effect on

Table 2
6
Break-even overnight costs for new nuclear (€/kW). Note that current expectations to lower the costs of nuclear in the near future are very
limited. On the one hand, since cost reductions are not a major goal of present RD&D in nu-
Pessimistic Optimistic clear energy (Anadón et al., 2012), learning-by-searching potential is very limited
(Kahouli, 2011). On the other hand, learning-by-doing potential is not very clear: empir-
Annual demand growth 2560 2616
ical evidence from France shows that scaling-up may result in negative learning effects
Contribution from renewables 2557 2609
(Grubler, 2010), whereas standardization seems to result in some positive learning
Discount rate 2289 2989
(Rangel and Lévêque, 2012).
Gas price 1665 2835 7
In some cases, nuclear power plants can be designed to be able to regulate to some ex-
Carbon allowance price 2303 3113
tent their production, and therefore to provide some flexibility. However, this comes at an
Construction duration for nuclear 2285 2653
added cost that would therefore reduce competitiveness.
Availability of nuclear 2469 2758 8
Indeed, this merit-order effect, as is usually called, will also affect the returns on all
Source: own elaboration. other existing power plants, creating a kind of windfall loss for all of them.
S124 P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125

Table 3 Table 4
Overnight costs for recent nuclear power plants in Japan and S. Korea (2004–2008). Overnight costs for proposed nuclear power plants in the US.

Type of reactor Capacity (MW) Date Overnight cost (€/kW) Type of reactor Capacity (MW) Date Overnight cost (€/kW)

ABWR 1325 2004 2069 ABWR 1371 N/A 2198


BWR 1067 2005 2513 ESBWR 3040 2018–2020 2648
ABWR 1304 2006 1768 AP1000 2212 2016–2017 3155
OPR 995 2004 2518 AP1000 2234 2016–2019 2840
OPR 994 2005 2207 AP1000 2200 2016–2017 3559

Source: Du and Parsons (2009). Source: Du and Parsons (2009).

prices induced by this new power plant will prevent the attaining of a There are also other significant uncertainties. As mentioned before,
large market share for nuclear energy, unless its income is guaranteed the more critical are: construction durations, gas prices, carbon prices,
(see later). and interest rates (including risk premiums for nuclear). Therefore,
Our results are clearly more pessimistic towards nuclear power the final decision will have to be based on risk analysis, with many
plants than those of the European Commission (EC, 2011a) or Nicholson of the parameters difficult to fit in a probability distribution. This will
et al. (2011). They are also more pessimistic than the MIT (2009) study, probably require an analysis of the robustness of the decisions under
partly because of the more favorable numbers for coal and gas power an uncertain environment (as in Linares, 2002), which is outside the
plants: we find that nuclear power plants could just barely be competitive scope of this paper.
under the no risk-premium, carbon allowance price scenario, whereas the An important issue is that these uncertainties affect differently
MIT study for that scenario finds that nuclear energy is clearly more com- public and private decisions: because of the reasons mentioned before
petitive than gas and coal (6.6 cents/kWh for nuclear, 7.3 cents/kWh for (Roques et al., 2006), higher gas and carbon prices do not result in
gas).9 However, we have also run the model with the same efficiencies significantly higher chances for nuclear power plants in liberalized mar-
and investment costs for gas and coal power plants used in the MIT kets, whereas the other uncertainties are likely to be resolved negatively
study (which are more favorable for nuclear power plants than the ones for nuclear power plants. Therefore, even under favorable cost scenarios
in (IEA, 2012) that we have used), and this conclusion still applies. This it seems unlikely to expect a spontaneous decision by utilities in liberal-
is even more interesting when we learn that the average capacity factor ized markets to invest in new nuclear power plants, unless either the
in our model for combined cycles is about 75%, compared to the 85% nuclear industry itself, or the government, steps in to change the current
assumed in the MIT study. We believe that the difference in this case situation and reduce the uncertainties involved. Indeed, this seems to
(using similar parameters) comes from the change in the methodology, have been proven in the case of the UK, where in a context of political
which in turn should solve some of the shortcomings of the LEC method- support for nuclear power plants but no subsidies, utilities suggested
ology (see Section 2). that they would need some form of support if they were to build
Finally, we should remind readers that these results could also be new nuclear power plants (Thomas, 2010) — as already anticipated
used for regulated power systems, in which the objective is also to by some (Citi, 2009). The promoters of the Hinckley Point C nuclear
minimize costs. However, the impact of uncertainty is much lower power plant, for example, are requesting a guaranteed price between
in these systems (for generators, that is, since the risk is transferred to 80 and 120 euros/MWh, clearly above wholesale prices (Reed,
consumers) and therefore the decision to invest may be easier (and 2013).
the break-even cost required higher). The nuclear industry might have a role to play here in two directions:
reducing the cost of nuclear investments; and reducing the risks of
cost overruns and construction delays — by standardizing designs and
4. Conclusions projects, better project management, good financial and risk planning,
or modular, downsized construction (see e.g. Kessides, 2012). In the
A first conclusion of our analysis is similar to the conclusion of latter direction, many risk-hedging instruments are already available:
Joskow and Parsons (2009) and Davis (2012), in that the cost competi- PPA contracts, O&M contracts, turnkey contracts, insurance, or financial
tiveness of nuclear energy in liberalized markets is not at all clear: under instruments.
our baseline scenario, results are mostly negative, depending on the ref- Governments might also want to support nuclear power plants:
erence used for current investment costs. And then, there are several although private companies are not concerned about high gas or carbon
uncertainties surrounding them. prices, price volatility, or dependence on fossil fuels, governments may
The first of these uncertainties is the possibility of a cost overrun. In be so. In addition, some of the risks of nuclear power plants may be
that sense, some argue that the nuclear industry has an observed ten- socially diversifiable, thus constituting a market failure to be corrected.
dency to forecast overconfidence (Koomey and Hultman, 2007). Data In that case, a result from our study is that probably the most effective
shown by MIT (2003) point to significant historic overruns of up to way to support nuclear power plants is by reducing risks. The current
300%. And our results show that even in the most favorable scenario, US policy on loan guarantees for nuclear power plants is a good example
the cost overrun should be lower than 15% in order for nuclear power of this, although it has only been designed for a limited number of
plants to be competitive when comparing to US estimates. Looking at plants. Instruments to promote diversity in the energy mix would also
the past history of nuclear energy, or at a post-Fukushima future with probably help nuclear power plants (Nuttall and Taylor, 2009), as well
increased safety regulations, would then result in one concluding that as long-term contracts such as those proposed by Newbery (2010).
nuclear power plants will probably not be competitive on a purely eco- Another important role for governments is the streamlining of
nomic basis. Therefore, cost will not be a plus for nuclear energy, but licensing procedures. Navarro (1988) found evidence that a streamlined
will still be one of its problems. To put it in other words, the possible licensing process, and standardized reactor designs reduced construc-
trade-off between more nuclear power plants and higher electricity tion duration and construction costs in Japan compared to the US.
prices implied in the nuclear debate would not be such. The same conclusion has been reached by Rangel and Lévêque (2012).
However, and as shown by the current phase-out of nuclear power
9
However, when these estimates by MIT (2009) are updated considering higher con- plants in many countries, it is not clear whether governments would
struction costs (according to more recent estimates from US DOE, 2010) and changes in
fuel prices since 2009 (particularly, cheaper natural gas thanks to shale gas exploitation),
be interested in pursuing this route. First, even from the social point of
the results change significantly making nuclear clearly less competitive than natural gas view, the cost competitiveness of nuclear power plants is not clear.
(Davis, 2012). And second, if finally the development of nuclear power plants requires
P. Linares, A. Conchado / Energy Economics 40 (2013) S119–S125 S125

some degree of economic support, then a higher level question comes Joskow, P.L., Parsons, J.E., 2012. The future of nuclear power after Fukushima. Econ. Energy
Environ. Policy 1, 99–113.
forward: given the scarcity of public funds, which technology should Kahouli, S., 2011. Effects of technological learning and uranium price on nuclear cost:
be supported, and to what level? This is because we may also be inter- preliminary insights from a multiple factors learning curve and uranium market
ested in supporting renewable energy, and energy conservation. Here modeling. Energy Econ. 33, 840–852.
Kennedy, D., 2007. New nuclear power generation in the UK: cost benefit analysis. Energy
the discussion would have to move then to a cost-benefit analysis Policy 35, 3701–3716.
of all three options. And it is not at all clear that nuclear energy would Kessides, I.N., 2010. Nuclear power. Understanding the economic risks and uncertainties.
be the winner, especially compared to conservation. But that remains Energy Policy 38, 3849–3864.
Kessides, Ioannis N., 2012. The future of the nuclear industry reconsidered: risks, uncer-
for another paper. tainties, and continued promise. Energy Policy 48, 185–208.
Koomey, J., Hultman, N.E., 2007. A reactor-level analysis of busbar costs for US nuclear
Acknowledgments plants, 1970–2005. Energy Policy 35 (2007), 5630–5642.
Linares, P., 2002. Multiple criteria decision making and risk analysis as risk management
tools for power systems planning. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 17, 895–900.
We thank, without implicating, William Nuttall, Marcel Coderch Linares, P., Isoard, S., 2001. Effects of energy markets de/reregulation onto EU's technology
and Jean-Marc Moulinier, as well as three anonymous referees for portfolio: conventional and emerging technologies. Report EUR 19829 EN. European
Communities.
their comments on earlier versions. The research assistance by Nathalie
Linares, P., Santos, F.J., Ventosa, M., Lapiedra, L., 2008a. Incorporating oligopoly, CO2
Ormazabal and Cesar Vispo is also gratefully acknowledged. All views emissions trading and green certificates into a power generation expansion
expressed here, as well as any errors, are the sole responsibility of the model. Automatica 44, 1608–1620.
authors. Linares, P., Santos, F.J., Pérez Arriaga, I.J., 2008b. Scenarios for the evolution of the Spanish
electricity sector: is it on the right path towards sustainability? Energy Policy 36
(2008), 4057–4068.
References MIT, 2003. The Future of Nuclear Power.
MIT, 2009. Update of the MIT 2003 Future of Nuclear Power.
Al-Juaied, M., Whitmore, A., 2009. Realistic costs of carbon capture. Belfer Center Discussion Navarro, P., 1988. Comparative energy policy: the economics of nuclear power in Japan
Paper 2009–08. and the United States. Energy J. 9, 1–15.
Anadón, L.D., Bosetti, V., Bunn, M., Catenacci, M., Lee, A., 2012. Expert judgments about Newbery, D., 2010. A nuclear future? UK government policy and the role of the market.
RD&D and the future of nuclear energy. Environ. Sci. Technol. 46, 11497–11504. EPRG Working Paper 1011 — Cambridge Working Paper in Economics 1019.
Beerten, J., Laes, E., Meskens, G., D'haeseleer, W., 2009. Greenhouse gas emissions in the Nicholson, M., Biegler, T., Brook, B.W., 2011. How carbon pricing changes the relative com-
nuclear life cycle: a balanced appraisal. Energy Policy 37, 5056–5068. petitiveness of low-carbon baseload generating technologies. Energy 36, 305–313.
Citi, 2009. New nuclear — the economics says no. Nuttall, W.J., 2009. Nuclear energy in the enlarged European Union. EPRG Working Paper
Cooper, M., 2009. The Economics of Nuclear Reactors: Renaissance or Relapse? Institute 0904. U. of Cambridge Electricity Policy Group.
for Energy and the Environment. Vermont Law School. Nuttall, W.J., Taylor, S., 2009. Financing the nuclear renaissance. Eur. Rev. Energy Mark. 3
Corner, A., Venables, D., Spence, A., Poortinga, W., Demski, C., Pidgeon, N., 2011. (2), 187–202.
Nuclear power, climate change and energy security: exploring British public attitudes. Ramana, M.V., 2009. Nuclear power: economic, safety, health, and environmental issues
Energy Policy 39, 4823–4833. of near-term technologies. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 34, 127–152.
Crumley, B., 2009. Areva's field of dreams. TIME Magazine, August 5th. Rangel, L.E., Lévêque, F., 2012. Revisiting the cost escalation curse of nuclear power: new
Davis, L.W., 2012. Prospects for nuclear power. J. Econ. Perspect. 26, 49–66. lessons from the French experience. Working Paper 12-ME-08, Interdisciplinary
Davis, L.W., Wolfram, C., 2012. Deregulation, consolidation, and efficiency: evidence from Institute for Innovation, MINES Paris Tech.
US nuclear power. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 4 (4), 194–225. Reed, S., 2013. Britain approves construction of new nuclear power plant. The New York
Du, Y., Parsons, J.E., 2009. Update on the Cost of Nuclear Power. CEEPR Working Times, March 19th.
Paper 09-004. Roques, F.A., Nuttall, W.J., Newbery, D.M., de Neufville, R., Connors, R., 2006. Nuclear
EC, 2011a. Energy roadmap 2050. Communication (2011) 885/2.European Commission. power: a hedge against uncertain gas and carbon prices? Energy J. 27 (4), 1–24.
EC, 2011b. Energy roadmap 2050: impact assessment. SEC(2011) 1565/2, Part 1/2, Rothwell, G., 2004. Nuclear power economics. Encycl. Energy 4, 383–394.
accompanying document to Communication (2011) 885/2. European Commission. Rothwell, G., 2006. A real options approach to evaluating new nuclear power plants.
Grubler, A., 2010. The costs of the French nuclear scale-up: a case of negative learning by Energy J. 27 (1), 37–54.
doing. Energy Policy 38, 5174–5188. Sovacool, B.K., 2008. Valuing the greenhouse gas emissions from nuclear power: a critical
IEA, 2012. Energy Technology Perspectives 2012: Pathways to a Clean Energy System. survey. Energy Policy 36, 2950–2963.
International Energy Agency, Paris. Thomas, S., 2010. Competitive energy markets and nuclear power: can we have both,
Joskow, P.L., 2011. Comparing the costs of intermittent and dispatchable electricity do we want either? Energy Policy 38, 4903–4908.
generating technologies. Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 100, 238–241. Zhang, F., 2007. Does electricity restructuring work? Evidence from the U.S. nuclear energy
Joskow, P.L., Parsons, J.E., 2009. The Economic Future of Nuclear Power. industry. J. Ind. Econ. 55, 397–418.

You might also like