You are on page 1of 12

Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Technological Forecasting & Social Change


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/techfore

Sharing economy platforms: creating shared value at a business


ecosystem level
Ke Rong a, Boyi Li b, Wan Peng c, Di Zhou a, Xinwei Shi a, *
a
Institute of Economics, School of Social Sciences, Tsinghua University, Hai Dian District, Beijing 100084, PR China
b
Department of Management, London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London, UK
c
Department of International Relations, London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London, UK

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Sharing Economy Platforms (SEPs) are, in general, easily challenged by social ethics and culture, and are
Sharing Economy Platforms (SEPs) vulnerable to social and institutional uncertainties. Drawing from the Creating Shared Value (CSV) concept
Creating Shared Value (CSV) (Porter and Kramer, 2011), this article investigates whether CSV activities assist SEPs in retaining sustainable
Sharing Economy
innovation at a business ecosystem level. Based on the Polanyian embeddedness framework, we specifically
Business Ecosystem
examine how SEPs’ CSV co-evolves and aligns with virtue ethics and local culture across three growth stages:
Community stage, Scaling-up stage, and Legitimation stage. Data for this research were collected from multiple
case studies from two major sectors: the bike-sharing platform sector and the ride-sharing platform sector. Our
findings indicate that SEPs should co-create shared values by embedding virtue ethics and local culture into their
work with key ecosystem partners in order to preserve sustainable innovation. The research contributes to an
evolving understanding of CSV activities in the sharing economy literature on SEPs, as well as proposing some
practical implications for industrial practitioners and policymakers.

1. Introduction established organizations or lobbying groups, while also having to


address the tension between economic values and virtue ethics and
Nowadays, the people of China are accustomed to being part of the culture. If SEPs suffer greater financial loss due to the fall-out of unex­
sharing economy, by using platforms for sharing bicycles, rechargeable pected events (e.g., COVID-19), it might be difficult for them to pay
products and so forth (Chi et al., 2020). The so-called sharing economy is more attention to their CSRs.
defined as the “acquisition or distribution of a source coordinated by The pursuit of the modern economy, which balances wealth creation
people for a compensation or a certain fee” (Belk, 2014, p.1597). It also and the collective wellbeing and solidarity of society, has a longer his­
refers to social innovation activities that improve the collective effi­ tory in the realm of social and political philosophy, and may arguably
ciency of employing under-used or idle resources (e.g., labour, ma­ begin with Adam Smith’s seminal attempts to address the tension be­
chines, space, services, knowledge or information, and consumable tween the “invisible hand” (i.e., market, value) and the “moral senti­
resources) by creating a pool of common resources on digital platforms. ments” of economic actors (i.e., society, virtue ethics) (Kant, 1991;
As such, the sharing economy has great potential in corporate social Sandel, 1998; Sen, 2010; Smith, 2009). The former focuses on the eco­
responsibility (CSR) because it shares the common goal of reducing nomic mechanics of institutional arrangements, which are capable of
environmental impacts and focuses on the principles of reusing, recy­ internalizing certain transaction costs as a result of external pressures (e.
cling and sharing. Nonetheless, sharing economy platforms (SEPs) are g., regulation, cultural norms, or other forms of social concerns or col­
not only vulnerable to tax changes and the unexpected consequences of lective actions). The latter, in contrast, regards the social politics of
strict regulation, but also to macro-environmental uncertainties. For economic actors as the necessary motivation for economic activities in
instance, a recent study has shown that SEPs have been vulnerable enacting institutional change (i.e., in communities, cultural identities or
during the COVID-19 pandemic (Chen et al., 2020). Contrasting with the social movements). The former constitutes the crux of the economic
traditional sectors, SEPs are relatively lacking in support from conceptualization of CSR as a kind of rational choice, reducing the social

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: r@tsinghua.edu.cn (K. Rong), b.li2@lse.ac.uk (B. Li), w.peng4@lse.ac.uk (W. Peng), zhoud17@mails.tsinghua.edu.cn (D. Zhou), xinweishi@
mail.tsinghua.edu.cn (X. Shi).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.120804
Received 13 July 2020; Received in revised form 25 March 2021; Accepted 9 April 2021
Available online 4 May 2021
0040-1625/© 2021 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

concerns and moral sentiments of economic actors in their risk calcu­ policymakers in the sharing economy sectors.
lations (Arrow, 1973; Besley and Ghatak, 2007; Husted and Allen, 2007;
Orlitzky et al., 2011); while the latter sees a firm’s strategic agency in 2. Literature review
society as an opportunity to align economic interests with moral com­
mitments (Friedland and Alford, 1991; Selznick, 1953). The latter view 2.1. Sharing economy platforms and creating shared values
of understanding the tension between value and virtue ethics is less well
developed and largely lacks convincing theoretical accounts, despite the The sharing economy (e.g., Airbnb, Uber, DiDi), which is facilitated
huge potential of finding synergies between profit and social virtue by an online platform, has gradually changed customers’ consumption
ethics. There are two competing theories explaining how firms address behaviours from buying new products and services to sharing and
this tension: transaction cost economics (Barney, 1991; Coase, 1937; reusing (Jeon et al., 2020). While SEPs continue to grow and develop
Penrose, 1955), and the Polanyian notion of embeddedness (Beckert, into sustainable societies, there are conflicts arising between economic
2007, 2009; Krippner, 2001; Krippner and Alvarez, 2007; Polanyi, 1944, profits and social benefits (Mi and Coffman, 2019). The successful
1977). implementation of environmental CSR can enhance a service provider’s
Further, Porter and Kramer (2011) proposed the Creating Shared reputation (Marin et al., 2009), consumer-company identification and
Value (CSV) approach that highlights the connection between firms’ the perceived value of sustainability (Wang and Ho, 2017). As for digital
economic growth and societal benefits. Acquier et al. (2019) also argue platforms, Lobschat et al. (2019) argue that they need to meet the
that the sharing economy appears to have a great altruistic mission from relevant obligations and choose an appropriate CSR strategy that
the perspective of sustainability or shared-value creation. If ‘sharing’ matches their business model by redesigning value creation and value
indeed becomes a reliable alternative institutional arrangement to appropriation.
market and hierarchy, how should a strategist convert a firm’s relative Moreover, the sharing economy can increase employment (Belk,
advantages from longstanding institutional mechanisms (embedded­ 2014), nurture more sustainable business and consumption models
ness, market, and hierarchy)? Our efforts to explicate the strategic im­ (Cohen and Kietzmann, 2014), and expedite the green economy (Gri­
plications of a sharing economy can be framed thus: how SEPs offer a nevich et al., 2015). The UK and European Union had already begun to
realistic strategic option to align their aspiration for social leadership in comprehensively assess the legal, social, economic, and environmental
the community with the incentive of seeking competitiveness and impact brought about by the sharing economy (EPRS, 2016). Indeed, the
profitability in the era of digital economy. sharing economy was originally depicted as a social movement, which
Tan and Wang (2011) suggest that an ethical belief refers to a part of tends to be more ethical and sustainable, and largely facilitates new
institutional logics in a particular context (e.g., a given culture or forms of market or non-market exchange (Botsman and Rogers, 2010;
country). In the era of the sharing economy, Berkowitz and Souchaud Schor and Thompson, 2014). As discussed above, the sharing economy
(2019) support the notion that the multi-stakeholder meta-organization has great potential in CSR. Consequently, we may need to ask how SEPs
built by SEPs can effectively address governance gaps (i.e., virtue ethics) address the CSR issues while they are struggling with competition and
by means of collective legal, ethical, and utilitarian work. In this article, basic survival. Recently, CSR has transformed from the management’s
we respond to Porter and Kramer’s (2011) call for more theorizing ef­ idiosyncratic philanthropic activities to a common and valuable activity
forts to further the concept of CSV, which envisions a new way of of stakeholder management for measuring a company’s strategic busi­
reformulating CSR by tapping into the embedded potential of commu­ ness performance (Kolodinsky et al., 2010); that is, companies are more
nities and transforming sociality into economic values. As a result, CSV often required to create shared values for various stakeholders. Halal
can be somewhat regarded as Visser’s (2011) CSR 2.0 notion, which (2001) argued that the conflict between profitability and social re­
highlights the four factors of value creation, good governance, societal sponsibility can be dealt with when regarding stakeholders as critical
contribution, and environmental integrity. Differing from traditional partners who may contribute to the creation of economic and social
firms that create value within the boundaries of a supply chain, digital values as well as via the collaborative problem-solving approach. Dab­
platforms depend on an ecosystem of autonomous stakeholders to bous and Tarhini (2019) proved that perceived economic benefits can
co-create value (Hein et al., 2020). Moreover, the nature of platforms is facilitate sustainable consumption via the SEPs. Therefore, the CSV
changing as their surrounding communities and technologies drive them concept proposed by Porter and Kramer (2011) seems to provide a
(Cusumano et al., 2020). Furthermore, ecosystems can support business feasible solution.
model development via new creations and the appropriation of value Porter and Kramer (2011, p.66) defined the concept of CSV as
(Rong et al., 2018), and by addressing current issues in the sharing “policies and operating practices that enhance the competitiveness of a
economy (i.e., lack of regulation, tax obligations) (Leung et al., 2019). company while simultaneously advancing the economic and social
As a consequence, we further argue that SEPs’ shared values should be conditions in the communities in which it operates”. To some extent, the
co-created at a business ecosystem level with their key stakeholders, and CSV view is aligned with the nature of SEPs: the value depends on the
embedded into actionable guidelines for creating competitive and sus­ surrounding network or communities (Nadeem et al., 2020). SEPs can
tainable advantages. survive and enable value creation activities because of the social support
Above all, there is a large pool of literature on how digital platforms’ from platform participants. Existing studies on the sharing economy
CSR practices should be aligned or co-evolved with technology inno­ have revealed some similar CSV-oriented evidence, though no study has
vation. However, this article’s main research question is: “How do SEPs systematically explored CSV in the context of the sharing economy.
co-create shared values to make their innovation sustainable by Crane et al. (2014) articulated three ways of CSV: first, firms rec­
embedded virtues while co-evolving with their ecosystem partners?” We onceive products and markets by identifying social problems while
believe this article makes three contributions to extant literature on serving consumers; second, firms redefine the supply chain productivity
digital platforms, with particular implications on SEPs and the CSR while strengthening social, environmental, and economic capabilities of
accordingly. First, our findings contribute to the sharing economy supply chain members; third, firms enable local cluster development
literature by demonstrating that the SEP should co-create shared values while cooperating with suppliers and local institutions. As seen in
by embedded virtue ethics and culture with key ecosystem stakeholders Table I, the CSV concept leverages the resources and expertise of the
in order to keep innovation sustainable. Second, this article provides a firm to create economic value by creating social value. Nonetheless,
novel understanding of SEPs regarding how their CSR practices should critics of the CSV concept say that it is unoriginal because it ignores the
be aligned and co-evolved with the CSV activities across different tension inherent in responsible business activities; and that it is naive
growth stages. Third, this article also contributes to the literature by with regard to business compliance as it is based on a shallow concept of
identifying some practical implications for practitioners and related the corporation’s role in society (Crane et al., 2014).

2
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Table I separation of usage and property rights in a relatively low transaction


Dimensions of Creating Shared Values (CSV). cost via multi-sided market platforms increases the willingness of
Dimensions CSV collaborative consumption. The sharing economy also revealed a change
in trend from “adapted sharing”, a primary sharing pattern based on the
Economic • Co-create economic value with stakeholders including
Value governments, foundations, universities, NGOs and other existing idle resources, to “born sharing”, a more efficient and less un­
companies (Porter and Kramer, 2006; Pfitzer et al., 2013) certain sharing pattern based on the initial resource allocation (Rong
Social Value • Nutrition: provide inexpensive micronutrient-reinforced spices et al., 2017). From the perspective of consumers, social support can
in business (Porter and Kramer, 2011; Pfitzer et al., 2013; influence the ethical perceptions of SEPs and determine the value
Crane et al., 2014)
• Health: improve medical care through a social business model
co-creations (Nadeem et al., 2020). Accordingly, no SEPs will operate in
(Pfitzer et al., 2013) a vacuum, but exist in an ecosystem where various stakeholders may
• Sustainability: integrate environment protection and resource influence the co-creation activities, and societal conditions (i.e., insti­
conservation into business models (Porter and Kramer, 2006; tutional regulations, government policies) may restrict product or ser­
Pfitzer et al., 2013; Crane et al., 2014)
vice innovations. Moreover, a social movement called collective impact
• Education: turn education into profitable business (Porter and
Kramer, 2006; Pfitzer et al., 2013) (Kania and Kramer, 2011) largely determines firms’ collaborations in
• Employment: employ surrounding communities (Pfitzer et al., the social sector, which also encourages various actors (e.g., companies,
2013) government, community members) in their ecosystem to make business
• Social justice: enable local cluster development (Porter and adjustments in alignment with social development needs. The collective
Kramer, 2011; Moon et al., 2011; Pfitzer et al., 2013)
• Reputation: create social reputation and social impact (Porter
impact may not only stimulate companies’ social progress, but also bring
and Kramer, 2011; Pfitzer et al., 2013) more economic opportunities (Kramer and Pfitzer, 2016). CSV consists
Example • Joint value creation for firms and community of five mutually reinforcing elements: introducing a social purpose,
• Replace the firm’s energy with green energy rigorously defining the social need, measuring the social and business
• Encourage more employers to participate in the value co-
value, creating the optimal innovation structure, and co-creating with
creations
external stakeholders (Pfitzer et al., 2013).
The strand of organizational institutionalism literature suggests that
2.2. Sharing economy platforms: Three development stages firms actively intervene in fields of socio-political activities, and address
social concerns by consciously constructing an ideology, participating in
Economic explanations for the sharing economy can be found in the social movements, seeking alternative sources of legitimacy, and con­
theory of transaction cost (Coase, 1937), collaborative consumption structing new cultural identities (Edelman et al., 2017; Friedland and
(Felson and Spaeth, 1978) and two-sided markets (Rochet and Tirole, Alford, 1991; Greenwood, 2008; Greenwood and Hinings, 2017; Law­
2006). As for small and growing businesses, Lewis and Churchill (1983) rence and Suddaby, 2006; Selznick, 1953; Thorton and Ocasio, 1999).
identified five stages of a firm’s growth, including Existence, Survival, Polanyi highlighted two core meanings of embeddedness: first, markets
Success, Trade-off, and Resource Maturity. Kazanjian (1988) catego­ have been necessarily limited by institutional regulations; second, it
rized firms’ growth into four stages: Conception and development, indicates that the political or social reformist task is to stabilize a societal
Commercialization, Growth, and Stability. Similarly, the organizational organization through the institutional regulation of markets (Beckert,
lifecycles are also divided into four stages: Formation, Early Growth, 2007, 2009). In this context, firms are not just to change institutional
Later Growth, and Stability (Dodge and Robbins, 1992). Drawing from conditions but also change the logic of cultural values, which is known
Dodge and Robbins (1992), we can further simplify the traditional firms’ as institutional work (Lawrence et al., 2013). The embeddedness
growth stages as formation, growth, and stability. The sharing economy perspective suggests that firms’ strategic behaviour is regarded as an
has become a prevailing and ground-breaking economic phenomenon opportunity for leadership to change the institutional logic and enact
with the boom of the digital economy, and acts as a template for business social change by forging new ways of legitimation. Considering the three
model innovation in value co-creation (Belk, 2014). different stages discussed above, SEPs may experience the embedded­
The SEPs’ three growth stages can be elaborated on as follows. ness or dis-embeddedness of social virtue ethics.
Community stage: As for SEPs’ early development stage, the value There is an ongoing concern about the significance of the sharing
creation is critically important. For instance, Airbnb facilitates its value economy in the context of ubiquitous digital connectedness, particularly
creation activities via online communities in which user participation about the logic of strategy-reasoning in the digital age. At the core of
and interaction are encouraged (Cheng et al., 2020; Reischauer and such a discussion is the conceptualization of “sharing” as a new form of
Mair, 2018). Given the nature of SEPs, we redefine the formation stage trust-building and coordination in digital networks. Specifically, to
as the Community stage for this type of platform. make the embedded economic action comprehensible, three coordina­
Scaling-up stage: As for the growth stage, SEPs need to attract an tion problems have to be initially dealt with, including value, compe­
increasing number of users and expand their platform network base. We tition, and cooperation (Beckert, 2007, 2009).
redefine the growth stage as Scaling-up stage for SEPs.
Legitimation stage: SEPs also need to achieve legitimacy to maintain 2.4. Value
long-term relationships with various communities (Nasi et al., 1997).
Recently, some socially irresponsible practices are challenging SEPs’ The term “sharing economy” has been seen as an emerging new
legitimacy (Hwang, 2019). So, we call the traditional firms’ stability culture whereby people can share their belongings with others via online
stage the Legitimation stage for SEPs while emphasizing the most platforms (Bucher et al., 2016). Many theoretical models of the sharing
important concern faced by most traditional firms’ stability stage. economy have shown that a sharing mechanism can increase access to
highly valuable assets at a lower cost, which increases economic effi­
2.3. Co-creating shared values by polanyian embeddedness ciency and social welfare (Fraiberger and Sundararajan, 2015; Horton
and Zeckhauser, 2016; Jiang and Tian, 2015). In addition, the
From the perspective of evolution, social media first enabled code standard-setting of value is a social, cultural, and political process
sharing (e.g., Linux), then allowed us to share our daily lives (e.g., negotiated among actors of different agency in order to reach consensus,
Facebook), and also encouraged content sharing (e.g., YouTube) (Bots­ known as the cognitive process of commensuration (Beckert, 2007,
man and Rogers, 2010), and now it expands into service and asset 2009). For instance, IT company-sponsored education and training
sharing (e.g., Uber and Airbnb). The sharing economy can also be programmes (i.e., the vision campaigns) aim to cognitively influence a
described as the access economy (Eckhardt and Bardhi, 2015), and its client’s capability to understand and appreciate the value of information

3
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

systems (Swanson and Ramiller, 1997, 2004). Prahalad and Ram­ arrangements of industrial production. Firms based in Silicon Valley
aswamy (2004) suggest that value co-creation means a process in which have achieved such benefits where technical know-how and human
different parties collectively engage in the production of valued out­ have been shared through informal cooperative activities, including
comes. In short, the process of valuation is of a social nature. Similarly, local social networks, orchestrated by Stanford University and similar
the strategic moves of what Moore referred to as “the evangelic, institutional nexuses, as well as through the homogenous local culture of
visionary leadership” have also been documented in the business tech entrepreneurialism, and informal socializing (Kenney, 2000;
ecosystem literature (Moore, 1996; Rong et al., 2019; Parente et al., Saxenian, 1995). Likewise, the access to institutional resources is criti­
2019). cally important for SEPs to legitimize their sharing practices. Through
Rong et al. (2019) found that price is not a significant influencing an ecosystem lens, SEPs should make more effort to tackle the cooper­
factor in a digital platform’s user stickiness, but appropriability re­ ation problem by collaborating with their ecosystem stakeholders.
sources as inimitable values are critically important. In the context of the The following table presents the whole conceptual framework
sharing economy, the value of shared resources, which provide some (Table II).
utility to other people, may increase substantially when there is a
socio-technical system to categorize and match supply with demand. 3. Methodology
Such socio-technical systems (e.g., rating, ranking, search tokens,
feedback) would not take effect without a community in which leading To explore how to make SEP innovation sustainable through CSV by
users can share common understandings of social and economic values, embedding virtue ethics and culture, we chose to create multiple case
and ensure there is a social cue to motivate users to participate in the studies (Yin, 2014) primarily based in two sectors: the bike-sharing and
sharing practice (Foss, 2011). The markets have to be socially and ride-sharing sectors. We followed two criteria for choosing the repre­
culturally embedded to be feasible because the subjective valuation of sentative cases (Table III).
goods can ensure the emergence of stable markets (Beckert, 2007, First, the samples should be of leading firms in representative in­
2009). To some extent, the vision of SEPs (i.e., to be of value in society) dustries of the sharing economy. DiDi belongs to the sharing ride sector,
may depend on whether its economic activities are aligned with its CSV and OFO is from sharing bike sector. Second, we need to ensure access to
by embedding virtue ethics and culture into SEP behaviour. target research samples so as to achieve a comprehensive view of the
samples and the industries involved. We conducted semi-structured and
2.5. Competition in-depth unstructured interviews with OFO and DiDi managers in
different departments, along with platform users, and other relevant
Beckert (2007, 2009) found that markets can emerge when ecosystem stakeholders including economists, rivals (e.g., Mobike, Uber
embeddedness has been found in non-economic social and political China, Dida1), governments and so forth.
contexts. Embeddedness literature recognizes that the market has never DiDi was founded in 2012 and became the largest platform in China’s
been a utopian space of price-mediated competition, but is instead a peer-to-peer sharing ride market after merging with Kuaidi in February
place where entry barriers, norms of production, even pricing tactics are 2015 and acquiring Uber China in August 2016. OFO sharing bicycles,
under the control of incumbent institutions. The change of entry bar­ cofounded by five Peking University graduates in 2014, is a younger
riers, norms, and industrial relations are subject to the complicated online travel platform which was created to solve the problem of how to
political negotiations between incumbent institutional players (Beckert, complete the “last kilometer” of a trip where public transport could not.
2007, 2009). Notable examples of corporate strategy to tackle compe­ For the consumers who want to use the sharing bikes, they need only
tition include those firms whose platforms gain competitive advantage take a few seconds to scan the QR code on the bike and then use a
by embedding norms and rules to govern a controlled community of password to unlock it. Since June 2015, OFO has added more than 10
value co-creators, and deny access from potential competitors by the million sharing bikes to the market, and at least 200 million customers
platform infrastructure. As a result, the niche value creation becomes have enjoyed more than 4 billion rides with OFO.
possible and not only because of its monopoly on any resource. In the Drawing from Gibbert et al. (2010), the validity and reliability of
case of the competition between Microsoft and Netscape, Microsoft choosing a case study can be demonstrated in four main aspects: internal
created Internet Explorer and used its own existing platform (Windows validity, external validity, construct validity, and reliability. From an
OS) to attract a relatively controlled community of value co-creators, ecosystem perspective, we construct the conceptual framework through
thus gaining a competitive advantage over Netscape Communicator. the literature to ensure the internal validity of the study. We also follow
Likewise, to compete with Nokia, Apple created the iOS platform and a cross-case analysis method to compare not only the two major sharing
invited potential creators to develop more applications based on the iOS. companies, DiDi and OFO, but also to supplement our data and materials
As a consequence of tackling competition by governing a controlled with those of industry competitors so as to further ensure external val­
community of value co-creators, and denying access from potential idity. Finally, to ensure construct validity and reliability, the data was
competitors by the platform infrastructure, SEPs are more capable of collected from 2014 to 2018 based on the principle of data triangulation
creating competitive values and contributing to their online commu­ (Gibbert et al., 2010; Yin, 2014), including both interview and archival
nities through developing social movements that embrace virtue ethics data. We specify the process of data collection, including how the data
and culture, and align them to gain practical and economic advantages. was collected, the reliability of the data, and the data triangulation.
First-hand data was collected directly from interviews with high-
2.6. Cooperation level managers, starting in 2014. We visited DiDi and OFO on several
occasions from November 2014 to July 2018, conducting in-depth in­
The embeddedness theory in essence suggests that it is not just terviews with company executives, including co-founders, the chief data
economically rational but socio-culturally rational to develop regular officer and chief economist. The time period of the interviews covered
reciprocal relations with other stakeholders. The fact that actors are the rise to maturity of China’s sharing ride and sharing bike industries,
embedded in community relations has been found to lead to favourable allowing us to gain insight into the sharing economy at all three stages of
conditions, notably interpersonal trust, social reputation, altruism, its development, from the Community, the Scaling-up, and the Legiti­
empathy and fellowship, and common interpretive schemes for risk mation. We designed targeted interview questions relating to how DiDi
perception, conducive to cooperative actions (Beckert, 2007, 2009). For
instance, the patterns of cooperative actions, which may be based on
religion, culture rural neighbourhoods, or other forms of community 1
Dida is another Chinese sharing ride platform which is in competition with
life, are institutionalized to such an extent that they become legal DiDi; its official website is http://www.didachuxing.com/homepage/.

4
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Table II
The conceptual framework.
Value Competition Cooperation Creating Shared Value (CSV)

Community • Describe the goods or service • How do sharing platforms offer not • How do sharing platforms rule out • To co-create with key stakeholders and
Stage that become available via just value to users, but also better the possibility of low quality, provide platform users with shared
sharing platforms. How are values to users? opportunism, and asymmetry of social values of competitive differenti­
the meanings of goods or • How are the impacts of information problems? ation by embedding virtue ethics.
services being framed? community networks or social • How do community networks or
• What is the value proposition movements embedded in them social movement campaigns
as a small community with understood to be differentiating address these problems?
shared visions, norms, and from other competitors?
rules?
• Explain why the valuation
process is a social process.
Scaling-up • Explain why the value of • Explain why platforms use • How do larger scale sharing • To co-create with key stakeholders and
Stage goods or service increase as financing war and price war as platforms address the problems of provide platform users with the main
the platform expands its user competition tactics. low quality, opportunism, and shared economic values by embedding
base. • Are there other feasible tactics? asymmetry of information? local consumption culture.
Legitimation • Explain the institutional • Explain why a sharing platform • Explain why gaining legitimacy • To co-create with key ecosystem
Stage process of legitimating the that adheres to the social, cultural, (rule-making, ethical standards) stakeholders and provide platform
new goods or service offered and institutional norms of Chinese helps to deal with the problems of users with the shared social and eco­
by the sharing platforms. society tends to perform better in low quality, opportunism, and nomic values by embedding virtue
competition. asymmetry of information. ethics and culture in order to achieve
legitimacy.

Table III
Interview list.
Category Stage 1Community Stage 2Scaling-up Stage 3Legitimation Total Total
hours interviewees

DiDi Case Project manager Economist (4 hours) CDO (2 hours) 25.5 24


(2 hours) VP of public affairs (2 hours) PR director and manager (4
4 Drivers (2.5 hours) PR manager (2 hours) hours)
2 Users (1 hour) 4 drivers (2 hours) 3 drivers (1.5 hours)
2 users (1 hour) 3 users (1.5 hours)
OFO Case Co-founder (2 hours; 2-hour Director of operation manager 2 PR managers (2 hours) 17.5 13
workshop) (2 hours) VP of development
2 Users (1 hour) Supply chain manager (4 hours half-day workshop)
(2-hour workshop) 2 users (1 hour)
3 users (1.5 hours)
Mobike Main Rival of Director of North China (2hours) Meituan manager (2 hours) 6 3
OFO Meituan strategy officer
(2 hours)
Uber China Main Rival of Uber Shanghai Manager Uber China team engineer (3 Uber Greater China Policy 15 5
DiDi (4 hours) hours) director (4 hours)
Uber Greater China Policy Uber Greater China Policy director
director (2 hours) (2 hours)
DiDa Main Rival of DiDa Founder, CTO 5 1
DiDi (4-hour workshop and 1-hour
personal meeting)
Government Regulation Government agency Officer 4 2
(half-day workshop in Beijing) (2-hour workshop in Beijing)
Total 73 48

and OFO co-evolved CSV and supplemented the interviews with on-site historic and development activities of each individual case through data
visits and online communications with employees to continuously track collection via interview (Eisenhardt, 1989). Two of our co-authors
the two companies’ historic development. Overall, we conducted a total organized the recordings of each interview into slides, which we used
of 24 interviews over 25.5 hours with DiDi, and a total of 13 interviews to have an in-depth discussion to collate the important quotes, devel­
over 17.5 hours with OFO. To corroborate the data obtained in these opment timelines and key milestones for each case. After discussion, we
interviews, we also conducted interviews with DiDi and OFO’s industry merged the materials and developed a case roadmap for both DiDi and
rivals Mobike, Uber China, and DiDa to ensure the reliability of the OFO. We then started to match the summarized development timeline of
findings. each case to the three development stages of SEPs according to our
Second-hand data was mainly elicited from news outlets (about 60 framework. We placed into the Community stage all corporate strategies
pages), interview videos (over 2 hours), the reports from companies and or behaviours used to embed the platform virtue ethics into the original
research institutes (over 150 pages), and regulation documents from platform business model. We identified the business model innovation
government websites (about 70 pages). The third source of data came strategies that drive platform expansion and economic value creation,
from ecosystem partners, including competitors (e.g., Dida, Uber China, but which might also bring with them the expense of virtue ethics as the
Mobike), users, suppliers, employees, and government officers. Then we Scaling-up stage. Finally, any other strategies to balance the economic
followed a detailed data analysis processincluding a single case analysis, value creation and virtue ethics were categorized under the Legitimation
a cross-case analysis, and data triangulation (Miles and Huberman, stage. In doing so, we could then elaborate the story of each case ac­
1994; Ozcan and Eisenhardt, 2009). cording to the three development stages of SEPs.
As regards the single case analysis, we started by investigating the During the process of cross-case analysis, we attempted to identify

5
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

and summarize some common characteristics of the chosen cases from community consisted of the founders, the off-line sales team, and a
the perspective of the three coordination problems that SEPs may minority of taxi drivers. They shared the common practice of the sharing
encounter during the process of co-creating shared values. Then we re- ride and the vision that state-of-the-art technology would disrupt and
processed the interview materials based on the three coordination innovate the traditional way of travelling. The first drivers to join the
problems (i.e., value, competition, and cooperation). We then compiled platform stated,
the information into a table to compare and summarize different plat­
“We hold the belief that the peer-to-peer sharing ride will replace
forms’ strategies in each stage and each coordination problem (Miles
traditional taxis, because sharing ride represents advanced technol­
and Huberman, 1994). In the table, we set out the quotes relating to
ogy and convenience.”
platform strategies from different cases in order to search for potential
regularity of the business model logic of SEPs and better relate the The traditional taxi service faced complaints from both customers
theory to the data (Eisenhardt and Graebner, 2007). Moreover, we and drivers. Customers were not satisfied because of a series of prob­
highlighted the similarities and differences in SEPs’ behaviour in each of lems, such as regular rejection, detours, and overcharging. And drivers’
the stages when facing different coordination problems in order to complaints generally involved high gas prices, traffic jams, and high fees
iterate between the theory and data to summarize some general prac­ to be paid to taxi companies. The genesis community held the view that
tices illustrating why SEPs would better co-create shared value by the peer-to-peer sharing app would change the situation dramatically.
embedded virtues. In the early stages, very few taxi drivers were willing to use DiDi’s
In the data triangulation stage, we first conducted another nine in­ mobile app and the majority insisted on making transactions through
terviews from the industry competitors of DiDi and OFO to further verify taxi companies. Apart from subjective reasons, such as the lack of
whether the findings from the cross-case analysis complement other case smartphones, the key problem was the low quality of DiDi’s early
tests. In this stage, we also developed timelines of each case by using the version of the app, which was outsourced to external technology com­
case materials from those interviewees. Again, we organized and panies. On this note, the CDO recalled that,
collated these competitors’ materials according to our theory framework
to verify whether our propositions still worked. Lastly, we manually “There was nothing more important than launching the app at that
coded all second-hand data from various sources including news, in­ time.”
dustry reports, and related regulation documents as further supportive
After all, there were dozens of venture firms competing in the sharing
evidence. ride industry. By introducing professional technicians and accepting
constant feedback from the first drivers, the technical team of DiDi
4. Findings iterated their app rapidly, usually once a week, improving its usability.
DiDi’s project manager for Beijing stated:
The case study mainly shows findings that respond to questions
raised in the conceptual framework. According to one economist we “Firstly, our products provide a better customer experience. Sec­
interviewed, he believes that the sharing economy model (i.e., the sep­ ondly, the offline sales team works efficiently and thus occupies the
aration of ownership and use of idle resources) can contribute to market quickly. The person-to-person promotes increasing influence
improving people’s living standards. In the following, we present find­ among drivers.”
ings that demonstrate how our target SEP samples co-create shared
The positive interaction between users and improvements in the app
values with key stakeholders.
and algorithm helped to embed the social values into the platform’s
economic value. A growing group of drivers, passengers, and their social
4.1. Community stage networks joined the expanding community. Though most of them live
distant and distinct lives from each other, they adhere to the DiDi
In the Community stage, genesis communities in both cases community’s implicit and explicit rules and expectations, and shared
contribute to the formation of virtue ethics of platforms, where common common virtue ethics about independence and sociability. The genesis
practices unfold as well. As such, SEPs’ social and economic values can community contributed to the development of a new kind of social
be mutually transformed. This stage reflects the characteristic of custom centering around the use of online sharing ride services rather
embeddedness on SEPs. than taking a taxi.
Inspired by rush hours in Beijing, DiDi recognized the difficulties of As for OFO, the vision of its genesis community was clearer from the
hailing a taxi in the big cities in China, and began its peer-to-peer outset. The five initial founders were all members of Peking University
sharing ride business in 2013. Now DiDi successfully links surplus Cycling Association and were brought together by their vision of
vehicle resources with customers who need to take a ride, and is completing journeys by bicycle. Since its inception, OFO founders have
expanding its business into foreign markets. DiDi’s project manager clearly stated their vision of enabling people to have access to bicycles at
recalled, any time and any place. One of the co-founders stated during the
interview meeting:
“The initial reason for us to establish DiDi platform was that cus­
tomers always found it hard to call a taxi in the large cities such as “We hold the view we can satisfy people’s ‘last-kilometer’ needs by
Beijing. The advanced digital technology gave us the opportunity to connecting bicycles to our platform, and therefore promote the habit
research and to develop a platform which linked the vacant surplus of cycling all over the world.”
car resources and needs of customers together, and then we explored OFO’s business model also contributes to alleviating traffic conges­
the possibility to establish a sharing ride market in China.” tion and reducing environmental pollution by replacing cars with bikes
In early 2015, Uber seemed to have some unsurpassed competitive for short trips. Wei Dai, the principal founder and CEO of OFO, bought
advantages, such as better applications and more stable technology. To 200 bikes to put into circulation at the Peking University campus in June
build a genesis community in the sharing economy context, the forma­ 2015, and invited students to link their bikes to the OFO platform in
tion of virtue ethics is crucial. DiDi defined its core virtue ethics as in­ exchange for the right to use all bikes on the platform. In October 2015,
dependence and sociability, because individuals can choose to there were 4,000 daily rides on the platform at Peking University. The
participate or not. It built an incompact community in which users can founders and loyal users in Peking University constituted the genesis
even switch their identity between a passenger and a driver, which community of OFO, who shared common virtues about sustainability
greatly increases the values in the community. At that time, the genesis and civic virtue. All in all, users have no ownership rights over bikes on

6
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

the platform, and thus civic virtue and cooperative spirit play a signif­ Why did Uber lose the Chinese market? To respond to this question,
icant role in embedding the OFO business model. The social value we may have to look at the impacts of Chinese social, cultural, and
created by embedding the sharing virtue ethics and the cycling habit institutional norms. The sharing economy platform that better adapts to
into the economic value can accomplish positive mutual change via local culture and norms tend to perform better. Take the competition
SEPs. By lowering the consumption threshold and differentiating the between Uber China and DiDi as an example. People in big cities in
service level, the platform attracts a growing number of users and ac­ China are accustomed to mobile payment methods, such as Alipay or
cumulates increasing shared economic values as well. Wechat Pay. DiDi naturally chose the mobile payment method, while
However, unlike the traditional economy, the market mechanism of Uber insisted on using credit cards initially, which Chinese people are
value creation in SEPs heavily relies on the network externality (i.e., not in the habit of using. Further, the customer service at Uber was
indirect network effect), meaning that the growing community plays a conducted by e-mails while DiDi’s was mainly processed by phone. Most
core part in the sustainability of SEPs. Based on members’ (i.e., drivers’ Chinese people care more about time and working efficiencies, and
and customers’) feedback, the iteration of products and the algorithm is therefore are not used to using and checking e-mails. At this stage, DiDi
crucial for a platform to enlarge its user base. A co-founder of OFO created economic values by lowering the price for passengers and
mentioned how, increasing drivers’ income. Concerning shared social value, DiDi
decreased cross-side uncertainties for drivers and passengers, and cut
“Our products’ iteration is rapid, for instance, we design and put the
down resource wastage thanks to the increasingly precise algorithm. The
new bikes into use twice a month.”
rapid growth of sharing ride businesses also propelled the alteration and
In addition, the Uber CEO, Travis Kalanick, defined the sharing improvement of legal institutional development.
economy as one specific form of on-demand economy whereby pas­ Likewise, OFO were engaged in financing and price wars with its
sengers can call a car whenever they need it and drivers open the app opponents. From October 2016 to March 2018, OFO and Mobike were in
when they are ready for work and close the app when they finish work. a financing war in which around 20 investment institutions took part
He believes that the value of Uber is mainly about independence. On and spent about 2.5 billion dollars. Before the war, there were dozens of
balance, SEPs in the two sectors need to co-create the shared values with sharing bike platform firms, but no more than five survived.
key ecosystem stakeholders and meanwhile their business models The price war in the industry of sharing bikes was much fiercer and
should be embedded with virtue ethics. went beyond expectations. OFO adopted the strategy of low-cost prod­
ucts and high-renewal frequency, while another leading company,
Mobike, designed high-quality and high-cost products with low renewal
4.2. Scaling-up stage frequency. To address the low-cost product challenge from OFO, Mobike
decided to launch a new low-cost bicycle named Lite to compete with
In the Scaling-up stage, SEPs pursue the maximized expansion of the OFO, while OFO also learnt from Mobike in terms of digital lock and
user base. The majority of SEPs are driven by the business model location technology. The sharing bike platforms converged into almost
innovation, which can be easily imitated, and therefore price and the same type, which resulted in it all being down to pricing to win the
financing wars become the dominating approach to competition. war.
Consequently, most of the SEPs in this stage are preoccupied by price Due to massive subsidies, users of sharing bike platforms experienced
and financing wars while paying little attention to their virtues, visions, exponential growth. An increasing number of commuters developed the
and even daily business operations. It is in this stage that SEPs experi­ habit of using sharing bikes to travel the “last kilometer”. Out of all the
ence dis-embeddedness. In such a context, firms’ social value would sharing bike firms, only five main platforms survived the pricing war, of
experience a shrinkage. which OFO and Mobike are the biggest two. Therefore, in the Scaling-up
From January 2014 to August 2016, DiDi witnessed a period of rapid stage, SEPs may have to sacrifice some values through dis-embedding
growth in users and its price and financing wars with Kuaidi and Uber virtue ethics, but they must ensure that their business model is
escalated. Consequently, DiDi became the largest platform in the Chi­ embedded within local culture (e.g., consumption habits). Moreover,
nese peer-to-peer sharing ride market. The larger scale of its enterprise SEPs in this stage have to collaborate with key stakeholders (e.g.,
linked more drivers and passengers, and its larger scale of data signifi­ economist, investor) at an ecosystem level in order to maintain their
cantly increased the accuracy of its algorithm and dispatch, which also market position in fierce price or finance wars so as to create maximized
assisted in dealing with the problems of low quality, opportunism, and economic values. As for Mobike, the cofounder said he is committed to
asymmetry of information. pursuing a differential competition strategy and launching a high-tech
At the beginning of 2014, in order to increase the payment interface, smart bike.
Tencent, one of the biggest Internet firms, allowed passengers to pay on
the DiDi platform via Wechat (Pay), one of the biggest mobile payment 4.3. Legitimation stage
services and social platforms in China. In February 2015, DiDi and
Kuaidi merged after the long price war, and then faced direct competi­ In the Legitimation stage, SEPs realize there’s often a conflict when
tion from Uber. In May 2015, Cheng Wei, the CEO of DiDi, declared he creating more economic value at the cost of virtue ethics, or vice versa. A
would offer a subsidy of 1 billion Yuan to DiDi and invest 100 million balance between social value and economic value should be regained.
dollars in Lyft to begin the price war with Uber. The VP of public affairs Pressure from stakeholders, social supervision, and official regulation
of DiDi told us: promote the legitimation procedure quite significantly. SEPs in this
stage should attempt to operate as value-added service providers and
“It seemed like there were no alternative competition tactics for us,
support an open-system, or so-called business ecosystem, with clear
except for subsidy and financing war. Even till now, we always adopt
internal rules, and proactive cooperation and interactions with external
these two methods to compete with Uber in different markets. “
partners.
That is almost exactly what the Uber Shanghai manager said. Until As discussed above, the legitimacy of SEPs comes from the commu­
June 2016, to win the war against Uber, DiDi had obtained more than nity, social supervision, and official regulation. A community consists of
8.5 billion dollars of investment from Apple, Tencent, and other com­ members, including users, investors, suppliers and employers, who
panies. Accordingly, Uber, including Uber China, obtained 9.4 billion share common practices. Internal rules within a community ensure the
dollars. On 1 August 2016, DiDi acquired Uber China, and only then did efficiency of the “feedback and revision” process. Feedback from tradi­
the price and financing war in China finally end, but the war on market tional or new media, social network comments, and face-to-face feed­
occupation between Uber and DiDi continued in the overseas markets. back from the public can have a direct influence on SEPs’ reputation and

7
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

their internal regulations, which encourages management to take social “Take ‘tide phenomenon’ as an example: OFO can hire workers to re-
welfare into consideration. During this process, laws and regulations schedule the allocation of bikes in different periods of the day to
created by central and local legislators and government put direct provide sharing service more efficiently.”
constraint on SEPs’ operation. Appropriate official regulations can co­
With stable demand coming from sharing bike firms, upstream bi­
ordinate benefits from diverse social classes and parties, and therefore
cycle manufactures could also stabilize their employment and reduce
can adjust the social welfare distribution to ensure it is fairly distributed,
waste. Thirdly, the innovative and convenient business model enabled
and make sure that the economic and social value created by SEPs is
firms to rapidly bolster their reputation. To sum up, OFO embedded
delivered to a wider social group.
enlarged economic and social values into its products and business
After the second stage, DiDi achieved almost monopoly status in the
model, which both helped OFO achieve legitimacy.
sharing ride market, and naturally received attention from multiple
Another source of legitimacy for OFO was external pressures from
social classes (i.e., community, social supervision, official regulation).
public opinion and official regulations. It encountered problems around
However, DiDi did not deal well with the issue of legitimacy in the
the safety of riders and the deposit scheme during its development. In
beginning. With the desire for worldwide market occupation and profit,
Shanghai, an 11-year-old boy was in a traffic accident and died while
it neglected its virtues and pursued radical development. Then it
riding an OFO bike, which highlighted the absence of a complete safety
encountered more challenges in several respects, such as the implicit
system for OFO bikes. After the accident, OFO immediately paid
algorithm, the civil and criminal cases, the workload of drivers, and
compensation and improved its safety system which prevented children
exorbitant price premium during extreme weather, which hurt DiDi’s
under 12 years from riding a sharing bike.
reputation and legality. In addition, there were several sexual harass­
Another important problem it faced was cash deposits. OFO required
ment and criminal cases in DiDi’s hitchhiking business. In May 2017, the
an initial cash deposit of 99 Yuan and a further 199 Yuan after use. But
Ministry of Transport of China proposed a series of regulations with
the problem was that the platform did not own the deposit. The Ministry
regard to the peer-to-peer car sharing industry, including how drivers on
of Transport claimed that the sharing bike platforms had to set up a
the platform must have a local Hukou (resident certificate) and local
separate deposit account for that sole purpose, and they could not
vehicle licensing. The PR manager told us:
transfer customers’ cash deposits into other usages. Similar to the case of
“The policy had a tremendous impact on us. Many drivers on the DiDi, the process of appropriately dealing with external pressures
platform were not locals. But in order to operate legally, we had to endowed OFO with legitimacy. The government can now use the tag
clear all the non-local drivers by December 31st, 2018. However, it is “bike friendly” as an index for evaluating the quality of a city. “Bicycle
very very difficult. One possible solution for us was to cooperate with friendly” means that people in that city are willing to go out as opposed
local car rental companies. They had the certificates…” to staying in and understand the concept of environmental protection,
which also means that the city has good air quality.
Following two serious criminal cases for the platform, in September
All in all, in the Legitimation stage, SEPs in the two sectors must co-
2018, the Ministry of Transport and Ministry of Public Security made a
create the shared social and economic values by embedding virtue ethics
comprehensive safety inspection tour of DiDi, which was followed by
and consumption culture with key ecosystem stakeholders. To summa­
tougher measures. Among other edicts, DiDi was required to fold its
rize all the cases we used in the three stages, we give the summary of our
hitchhiking business, remove unqualified drivers and cars, and install a
case study in Table IV.
one-button alarm function on its app.
Faced with problems and critiques from various social classes, DiDi
5. Discussion and conclusion
itself also instigated a series of rectifications to ensure the safety of
passengers, especially for those who need to take cars at night, including
Mobike’s Co-founder said in a media interview that “it is an unrea­
making personal information only accessible to passengers, cancelling
sonable behavior for shared bicycles not to aim for profit”. Also, the nature
all the tags linked to passengers, removing the comment function for
of CSV is largely aligned with Acquier et al.’s (2019) suggestion about
messages from drivers to passengers, and improving the call-handling
the promise of SEPs in the aspects of sustainability or shared-value
capacity of customer services. During the process of dealing with
creation. Moreover, SEPs need to co-create shared values with all rele­
external pressures from the media, social networking, and official reg­
vant ecosystem partners. Parente et al. (2019) point out that ecosystems
ulations, DiDi obtained its legitimacy step by step.
refer to all relevant stakeholders that keep evolving while customers’
In the case of OFO, its legitimacy originated from the social value it
consumption preferences change and related technology advances. In
created and external pressures about safety and cash pledge problems.
addition, Leung et al. (2019) have attested that the ecosystem of the
From April 2018, OFO and Mobike wound down their free riding ac­
sharing economy in China is not yet in a mature shape. Therefore, in this
tivities and increased the price of monthly cards since the sharing ride
article, we argue that SEPs should co-create shared values with key
was almost an oligopoly market. As for social values, there were three
ecosystem partners so as to build a collaborative system for value
clear aspects associated with the business model. Firstly, taking sharing
co-creations. And this can be considered as a sustainable development
bikes to nearby places or completing the “last kilometer” to work or
activity for SEPs which is related to identifying needs, sharing values,
home became a habit for citizens in dozens of cities, and therefore a
and contributing to further growth.
sustainable lifestyle was popularized because of the sharing bikes. A PR
As mentioned, the CSR is mainly about considering the business in­
manager of OFO said that,
fluence on the local communities and environment, but the CSV tends to
“Urban travel by bike sharing can be considered as green travel and focus on the business growth as well as valuable contributions to local
bike sharing should be considered as a kind of public good that can communities (Gatley, 2016). According to the narrative findings above,
make up the deficiencies of the existing urban transportation we come back to the questions raised in the conceptual analysis
infrastructure.” framework (as seen in Table II). In the Community stage, SEPs originate
from some form of genesis communities, with a well-defined set of
Secondly, sharing bikes have a certain demand for off-line mainte­ common practices (or sharing culture), from which virtue ethics
nance workers to better relocate the bikes so that they increase develop. Then sample SEPs’ visions (i.e., value propositions) are created
deployment opportunities for some special communities and reduced as the byproduct of those members of genesis communities aim to
products and resource waste. The VP of OFO told us during the work­ achieve a higher standard of excellence. To be specific, the common
shop in Beijing: practice inspired by the virtue ethics lays the foundation for platform
and product iteration. Then their business experiences constant growth

8
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Table IV
Summary of case study.
Value Competition Cooperation

Community DiDiGenesis community: OFOGenesis community: DiDi and OFOThe competitive advantages DiDi and OFO
Stage Founders; off-line sales team; a Bike share clubs in of DiDi/OFO in its early stage come from the
minority of driversForms of PKUForms of practices: features of its user community: 1 Because their business initially operated in
practices: a small embedded community, the
1 Bikes pooling; 1 Users of ethical and social concerns – it coordination problems of low quality,
1 Cars pooling; 2 Promoting the vision of resembles more of a social movement than matching, and opportunisms can be
2 Reputation/ranking/rating bike sharing (future a business idea effectively tackled due to the existence of
scheme; urbanism) 2 Quality and influence of initial users social mechanisms (i.e. reputation, trust,
3 Promoting the vision of ride Goods and services (value): 3 The priority of virtue/solidarity/social fine-grained information sharing, and col­
sharing (future urbanism) Flexibility; new job networks over economic value extraction lective problem-solving etc.)
Goods and services (value): opportunities; sustainability; 4 The nature of saving resources or 2 Because DiDi and OFO are part of the
Cheaper ride; safe and low risk; forming a cycling habit increasing efficiency social movement to promote ride/bike
income for drivers; new job 5 Universities are similar to small sharing, there is a substantial amount of
opportunities; flexibility acquaintance societies effort in its networks that can be counted
as volunteering and peer production.
DiDi and OFO
Ride/bike share as social movement:
Vision; agenda of social change; key actors and key ally
Ride/bike share as business strategy:
Value propositions; risk control via social capital; value capture
Scaling-up DiDi and OFO DiDi and OFO DiDi and OFO
Stage The value–virtue tension rises as there is an increasing economic Price war and financing war: Different strategic responses to the problems
return on the platform scaling up both consumers and suppliers of Because of the loss of community sense and of low quality, lack of trust, and decline of
services. ethical motivations, most users become more social capital:
sensitive to price. Accumulating data is used to the increase
This situation gets worse when more accuracy of user portrait, algorithm, and
competitors join in and offer similar services dispatch.
at a cheaper price. Platform owners supply the service directly
To finance the price war firms need to attract to mass consumers in order to maintain high
more investment. quality of service.
Platform owners introduce sophisticated
rating mechanisms to prevent opportunism
and anti-social behaviour.
Legitimation DiDi and OFO DiDi and OFO DiDi and OFOWith clear rules, defined legal
Stage When the ride/bike sharing sector becomes a status, and government regulations, platform
1 Legitimacy of sharing economy firms comes from the newly defined and legitimized industry, companies turn to the dynamics of
community, social supervision and official regulations. more players join the competition by offering community spirits and social movements in
2 With clear rules, defined legal status and government similar but differentiated services. order to generate competitive advantages.
regulations, the number of drivers and customers increases, Competitive advantages for DiDi/OFO at this DiDi/OFO did these things in order to convert
offering greater value propositions in both price and quality. stage stems from its visionary leadership on social virtues to business values:
3 Third-party service providers are allowed to join the business the future evolution of this sector, offering
ecosystem to further expand the value horizons. consultation services to the government 1 General trust in its network.
4 A shift of sharing ethics from serving the community to serving regulators, and setting a good example in 2 Promoting sharing culture and the
the whole society, i.e., innovating for urban sustainability complying with the external institutional ideology of sharing for other economic
future. pressures of society. sectors.
5 Becoming a mission-oriented platform business. 3 More sophisticated governance
mechanisms via data analytics and
artificial intelligence.

which benefits from improving the user experience by means of product competition. Provided that most of the SEPs were the results of business
iteration, while an increase in the number of users further encourages model innovation rather than technological innovation, the majority of
the growth of the community and accelerates the iteration. A virtuous them would not have protective barriers with which to prevent other
cycle between virtue construction and business expansion emerges. competitors from entering, and thereafter price and financing wars
Existing literature (e.g., Nadeem and Al-lmamy, 2020) also proves that naturally become the dominating competition method in most cases.
the relationship between companies and consumers influences the lat­ Due to the characteristics of the platform economy, the value created by
ter’s intentions of co-creating values. Although ethics are critically the genesis communities has been easily magnified, expanded, and
important in forming and maintaining long-lasting relationships scaled up into the wider society, where most of the new users are mere
(Gundlach and Murphy, 1993), few scholars have attempted to inves­ consumers of the newly created values. Therefore, the economic value
tigate the extent to which ethics determine value creations in the sharing that platforms created for stakeholders expands rapidly, except to
economy (Nadeem and Al-lmamy, 2020). Thus, our first proposition can investors.
be reached: In the context of a sharing economy, more attention should be paid to
the linkage between customers’ consumption behaviours and firms’
Proposition 1. To achieve value upgrading in the Community stage, SEPs
socially responsible activities (Jeon et al., 2020). The CSV is concerned
should co-create the shared social values by embedding virtue ethics in key
about the relationship between firms’ strategy characteristics regarding
ecosystem partners.
their sustainable competitive advantage and their social behavior (Kang
In the Scaling-up stage, there was a trend of dis-embedding since and Na, 2020). In short, the core essence of the sharing economy can be
both SEPs focused on winning the financing and price wars against their understood as one consumption culture producing community values to
rivals while neglecting the core virtues they were built on. The imbal­ be shared by many people, rather than individual ownership. To some
ance between “virtue” and “value” lead to inefficiencies in CSV, which is extent, consumers are encouraged to consider the impact of their con­
reflected in resource waste and unprofitability caused by aggressive sumption via community-oriented perspectives. In this context,

9
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

sharing-economy companies can cooperate with consumers to satisfy institutionalization at a later stage – are essential for facilitating the
their consumption preferences, which eventually realize the purpose of interaction of social value and economic value via SEPs. In other words,
value co-creations. SEPs are able to maintain competitive positions embeddedness appears as a balance between the strategic consider­
because they co-create more great values than their rivals. For instance, ations of “virtue ethics” and “value” in SEPs, constituting the basis of
Autonavi in 2017 launched the Easy Travel platform, which connects a CSV.
group of car sharing and bike sharing companies including DiDi, Third, this article improves our understanding of the rise of Chinese
Mobike, and OFO, and means that Autonavi has upgraded itself from a SEPs by shedding light on the evolutions of their CSV activities. An EMS
navigation tool to a mainstream travel platform. This leads us to our scheme manager from the British Assessment Bureau argued that com­
second proposition, as follows: panies need to take CSV into account more because it would better
ensure business success in the coming 20 or 30 years (Gatley, 2016). We
Proposition 2. To maintain a competitive position in the Scaling-up stage,
also argue that the sharing economy has huge potential to have a great
SEPs should co-create shared economic values by embedding local con­
deal of positive social impact in China. The Chinese government has the
sumption culture with key ecosystem partners.
power to practically legitimize SEPs since the growth of the sharing
The growing popularity of SEPs cannot be explained from the economy contributes to the integral service industry. Our findings sug­
transaction-cost lens alone, but also has to be accepted and understood gest that the Polanyian framework of economy as embedded in society
in the social context in which the digital sharing platforms are perceived has offered a fruitful theoretical lens to explain the growth of SEPs in
as more legitimized (Belk, 2010). In the Legitimation stage, after scaling China for the first time.
up from a local club to a national marketplace via technological ap­
proaches, SEPs face the dilemma of creating more value at the cost of 7. Practical implications
virtue (sharing culture), or vice versa. Moreover, laws and regulations
were necessary to achieve legitimacy, for which “virtue” constituted a This study also has some practical implications for SEPs and the
solid safeguard against social criticism. Once the two SEPs acquired relevant stakeholders, including industry institutions and governments.
legitimacy, they owned the “moat” to reduce competition, t effectively First, regarding SEPs, given that virtue ethics are the basis of value
expanding employment, saving resources, and making profits. From the creation and accumulation, they should clarify their virtues and visions
perspective of business strategy, such a balance is beyond the traditional in the genesis community, and propagate them into a growing com­
consideration of balancing business strategy with CSR, because the most munity through explicit internal rules. Second, alternative measures on
innovative point of the sharing economy is in creating synergies between competition or diversified competition advantages should be explored to
community social benefits and the general value-creation and avoid the waste of resources in the Scaling-up stage. Even though firms
value-capture of the wider economy. The main benefits of such institu­ choose financing or price wars, they cannot do so to the detriment of
tionalization can be seen in the diversity of “species” as value-added their own business operations and virtue ethics must continue to be
service providers. As such, it is necessary to seek formal institutional embedded in social relations to create both social values and economic
resources to legitimize the sharing practices and convert them from values. Third, Hwang (2019) suggests that how to deal with legitimacy
cultural dispositions (“soft power”) into institutional frameworks (i.e., can be seen as one of the most challenging issues. SEPs should also notice
rule by law, or “hard power”). To address current problems and issues in that the appropriate treatment and response to external pressure is
the sharing economy, collaboration among ecosystem stakeholders such conducive to its legitimation, and it is not an obstacle for market
as platforms, partners, and government is absolutely imperative (Leung occupation or expansion. Last but not least, this article proposes that
et al., 2019). Moreover, the positive social embeddedness (including SEPs should actively build their own industry ecosystem or embed
culture and cognition) can contribute to the acquisition of organization themselves in related industry ecosystems so as to retain and enlarge a
legitimacy and sustainable development (Fan et al., 2019). Conse­ pool of social resources for achieving legitimacy and sustaining
quently, the third proposition can be established: innovation.
For governments, regulations are powerful measures to reduce
Proposition 3. To achieve legitimacy in the Legitimation stage, SEPs
resource waste and help platform firms achieve legitimacy. As for cur­
should co-create shared values and economic values by embedding virtue
rent SEPs, business models can be easily replicated. However, a market
ethics and local consumption culture with key ecosystem partners.
cannot accommodate so many duplicative and redundant similar firms.
When financing and price wars become the main trends for competition
6. Research implications
and market occupation methods, they may bring down an innovative
and sustainable business resulting in the enormous waste of capital and
Extant literature has discussed in depth the benefits of the sharing
other resources. To some extent, the government has to shoulder some
economy (Botsman and Rogers, 2010), but scant research concerns the
supervision responsibilities in this process to ensure that the competition
relevant ethical and legitimacy issues (Hwang, 2019). The research
itself is fair and to further curtail resource waste, as well as to achieve
mainly contributes to the sharing economy literature through refining
platform antitrust. It is the process of introducing official regulations
the CSV concept in order to sustain SEP innovation.
that makes sharing social practices legitimate. Also, SEPs need to
First, the research complements the existing sharing economy liter­
maintain good relationships with local governments and follow relevant
ature on SEPs. Unlike asset-light transaction platforms (e.g., eBay,
regulations so as to reach long-term viability (Mi and Coffman, 2019).
Expedia), bike sharing and ride sharing platforms are not completely
digital businesses because, while their payment transaction is digital,
8. Research limitations and future research
the service delivery is physical, offline. During this process, a sharing
economy platform can embrace social value and transform it into eco­
Our research is not without limitations. Data were collected from
nomic value creation, and thus the business naturally generates positive
OFO and DiDi, which may not be representative of SEPs in all other
externalities associated with sustainable development.
sectors, nor of sharing bike or sharing ride platforms in general in other
Second, our research goes beyond the discussion on SEPs’ CSR
countries. Moreover, another limitation is that the paper is focused on
practices, with particular attention on the co-evolving CSV activities of
the Chinese market alone. Therefore, it is recommended that future
SEPs. Being consistent with Nadeem et al.’s (2020) finding, we also find
research should examine a wider variety of SEPs in different sectors and
that social support affects the value co-creation activities of SEPs. From
in different countries, which may generate additional insights into how
our observations of two leading SEPs in China, there is a clear finding
SEPs remain competitive and sustainable through CSV by embedded
that social relations – from the mutual trust and community ethics to the
virtue ethics.

10
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Additionally, due to the limitation of argument, this article does not Chi, M., George, J.F., Huang, R., Wang, P., 2020. Unraveling sustainable behaviors in the
sharing economy: an empirical study of bicycle-sharing in China. J. Clean. Prod. 260,
go inside the “blackbox” of digital platforms, but we show how the
120962.
digital salience of sharable goods or services can create value as an Coase, R.H., 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 2 (1), 286–405.
alternative arrangement to market or hierarchy. Benkler (2002) pro­ Cohen, B.D., Kietzmann, J., 2014. Ride on! mobility business models for the sharing
vides a set of promising concepts (i.e., modularity, granularity of com­ economy. Organ. Environ. 27 (3), 279–296.
Crane, A., Palazzo, G., Spence, L.J., Matten, D, 2014. Contesting the value of “creating
ponents, and the cost of integration), which can be potentially shared value. California Manag. Rev. 56 (2), 130–153.
instrumental in analyzing the unique institutional mechanisms of gov­ Cusumano, M. A., Yoffie, D. B. and Gawer, A. (2020). The Future of Platforms. MIT Sloan
erning the resources of SEPs that are partly public (the digital platform) Management Review, Magazine Spring 2020 Issue, Disruption 2020, Research
Highlight.
and partly privately owned (the physical goods/services). Future Dabbous, A., Tarhini, A., 2019. Assessing the impact of knowledge and perceived
research needs to shed light on the hybrid feature of sharable goods as economic benefits on sustainable consumption through the sharing economy: a
both collective and private ownership to explore the strategic implica­ sociotechnical approach. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 149, 119775.
Dodge, H., Robbins, J., 1992. An empirical investigation of the organizational life cycle
tions of platform firms dealing with such a unique common pool of model for small business development and survival. J. Small Bus. Manag. 30 (1),
sharable resources. 27–37.
Future research also needs to pay attention to the institutional con­ Eckhardt, G.M., Bardhi, F., 2015. The Sharing Economy Isn’t About Sharing at All.
Harvard Bus. Rev. https://hbr.org/2015/01/the-sharing-economy-isnt-about-sharin
sequences of the digital materiality of the sharing economy as they g-at-all [Accessed 24 March 2021].
become comprehensive governance mechanisms (Kallinikos, et al., Edelman, B.G., Luca, M., Dan, S, 2017. Racial discrimination in the sharing economy:
2013), and seek to explain how digital representations connect value evidence from a field experiment. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 9 (2), 1–22.
Eisenhardt, K.M., 1989. Making fast strategic decisions in high-velocity environments.
creations with the sharing ethics of community users. Despite these
Acad. Manag. J. 32 (3), 543–576.
limitations, our research provides a starting point in studying a Eisenhardt, K.M., Graebner, M.E., 2007. Theory building from cases: opportunities and
contentious but important and researchable topic about the co-evolving challenges. Acad. Manag. J. 50 (1), 25–32.
CSV activities of SEPs. EPRS, 2016. The Cost of Non-Europe in the Sharing Economy; Economic, Social and
Legal Challenges and Opportunities. https://www.europarl.europa.
eu/RegData/etudes/STUD/2016/558777/EPRS_STU(2016)558777_EN.pdf
Author statement [Accessed 23 June 2020].
Fan, Y., Xia, M., Zhang, Y., Chen, Y., 2019. The influence of social embeddedness on
organizational legitimacy and the sustainability of the globalization of the sharing
We also declare that there is no conflict of interesting. This article economic platform: evidence from Uber China. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 151,
does not contain any studies with human or animals performed by any of 104490.
Felson, M., Spaeth, J.L., 1978. Community structure and collaborative consumption: a
authors. routine activity approach. Am. Behav. Sci. 21 (4) https://doi.org/10.1177/
000276427802100411. March/April.
Foss, N., 2011. Managing motivation for joint production: the role of goal framing and
Acknowledgement
governance mechanisms. Acad. Manag. Rev. 3 (6), 500–525.
Fraiberger, S.P., Sundararajan, A., 2015. Peer-to-Peer Rental Markets in the Sharing
This research is supported by the National Natural Science Founda­ Economy. NYU Stern School of Business Research Paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/s
ol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2574337 [Accessed 24 March 2021].
tion of China (Grant no. 71872098;71834006), Major Research Projects
Friedland, R., and Alford, R. R. (1991). Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices, and
of Philosophy and Social Sciences of the Ministry of Education Institutional Contradictions. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 232-
(No.17JZD018), Major Program of National Social Science Foundation 263 doi:10.4135/9781446262023.
(Grant No. 20&ZD075; Grant No.18ZDA149), Big data and intelligent Gatley, N., 2016. Creating shared value-a new way of doing business. British Assessment
Bureau. https://www.british-assessment.co.uk/insights/spotlight-introducing-conce
governance Lab open project, and the International Postdoctoral Ex­ pt-creating-shared-value/. Accessed 6 June 2020].
change Fellowship Program, National Postdoctoral Management Com­ Gibbert, M., Ruigrok, W., Wicki, B., 2010. What Passes as a Rigorous Case Study? Strat.
mittee, China. Manag. J. 29 (13), 1465–1474.
Greenwood, R., Hinings, C.R., 2017. Understanding strategic change: the contribution of
archetypes. Acad. Manag. J. 36 (5), 1052–1081.
References Greenwood, 2008. The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. Sage
Publications, London.
Grinevich, V., Huber, F., Baines, L., Eder, M., 2015. Upscaling in the Sharing Economy:
Acquier, A., Carbone, V., Massé, D, 2019. How to create value(s) in the sharing economy:
Insights from the UK. https://cdn.southampton.ac.uk/assets/imported/transfor
business models, scalability, and sustainability. Technol. Innov. Manag. Rev. 9 (2),
ms/content-block/UsefulDownloads_Download/F5AD726CE72044E8AE3ECD7C
5–24.
B910CE9D/finalreport-scaling-up-economy.pdf [Accessed 24 March 2021].
Arrow, K., 1973. Social Responsibility and Economic Efficiency. Public Policy 21,
Gundlach, G.T., Murphy, P.T., 1993. Ethical and legal foundations of relational
303–317.
marketing exchanges. J. Market. 57, 35–46.
Barney, J., 1991. Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. J. Manag.
Halal, W.E., 2001. The Collaborative Enterprise. J. Corporate Citizenship 2001 (3),
https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639101700108.
27–42, 16.
Beckert, J., 2007. The Great Transformation of Embeddedness: Karl Polanyi and the New
Hein, A., Schreieck, M., Riasanow, T., Setzke, D.S., Wiesche, M., Böhm, M., Krcmar, H.,
Economic Sociology. Paper presented at the MPIfG Discussion Paper.
2020. Digital platform ecosystems. Electron. Markets 30, 87–98.
Beckert, J., 2009. The great transformation of embeddedness: karl polanyi and the new
Horton, J.J., Zeckhauser, R.J., 2016. Owning, Using and Renting: Some Simple
economic sociology. Hrsg. In: Hann, C., Hart, K. (Eds.), Market and Society: The
Economics Of The" Sharing Economy. National Bureau of Economic Research. No.
Great Transformation Today. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 38–55.
w22029.
Belk, R., 2010. Sharing. J. Consum. Res. 36, 715–734.
Husted, B.W., Allen, D.B, 2007. Strategic Corporate social responsibility and value
Belk, R., 2014. You are what you can access: sharing and collaborative consumption
creation among large firms: lessons from the Spanish experience. Long Range Plann.
online. J. Bus. Res. 67 (8), 1595–1600.
40 (6), 594–610.
Benkler, Y., 2002. Coase’s penguin, or, linux and the nature of the firm. The Yale Law J.
Hwang, J., 2019. Managing the innovation legitimacy of the sharing economy. Int. J.
112 (3), 369–446.
Qual. Innov. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40887-018-0026-0.
Berkowitz, H., Souchaud, A., 2019. Self-)Regulation of sharing economy platforms
Jeon, M.M., Lee, S., Jeong, M., 2020. Perceived corprate social responsibility and
through partial meta-organizing. J. Bus. Ethics 159, 961–976.
customers’ behaviors in the ridesharing service industry. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 84,
Besley, T., Ghatak, M., 2007. Retailing public goods: the economics of corporate social
102341.
responsibility. J. Public Econ. 97 (9), 1645–1663. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Jiang, B., Tian, L., 2015. Collaborative consumption: strategic and economic implications
jpubeco.2007.07.006.
of product sharing. Manag. Sci. 64 (3) https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2647.
Botsman, R., Rogers, R., 2010. What’s Mine is Yours: The Rise of Collaborative
Kallinikos, J., Hasselbladh, H., Marton, A., 2013. Governing social practice. Theory Soc.
Consumption. HarperBusiness, New York, NY.
42 (4), 395–421.
Bucher, E., Fieseler, C., Lutz, C., 2016. What’s Mine is yours (for a nominal fee)-exploring
Kang, S., Na, Y.K., 2020. Effects of strategy characteristics for sustainable competitive
the spectrum of utilitarian to altruistic motives for internet-mediated sharing.
advantage in sharing economy businesses on creating shared value and performance.
Comput. Hum. Behav. 62, 316–326.
Sustainability 12 (4), 1397.
Chen, G., Cheng, M., Edwards, D., Xu, L., 2020. COVID-19 pandemic exposes the
Kania, J. and Kramer, M. (2011). Collective Impact. Stanford Social Innovation Review, htt
vulnerability of the sharing economy. Soc. Policy. https://doi.org/10.21203/rs.3.rs-
ps://ssir.org/articles/entry/collective_impact [Accessed 30 June 2020].
26460/v1.
Kant, I. (1991). Kant: Political Writings. 2nd edn. ( Reiss, H. S. (ed.), Nisbet, H. B. (trans.))
Cheng, M., Zhang, G., Wong, I.A., 2020. Spanning across the boundary of airbnb host
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
community: a network perspective. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 89, 102541.

11
K. Rong et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 169 (2021) 120804

Kazanjian, R.K., 1988. Relation of dominant problems to stages of growth in technology- Rochet, J.C., Tirole, J., 2006. Two-sided markets: a progress report. The RAND J. Econ.
based new ventures. Acad. Manag. J. 31 (2), 257–279. 37 (3), 645–667.
Kenney, M., 2000. Understanding Silicon Valley: The Anatomy of an Entrepreneurial Rong, K., Patton, D., Chen, W, 2018. Business models dynamics and business ecosystems
Region. Stanford University Press, Redwood City. in the emerging 3D printing industry. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 134, 234–245.
Kolodinsky, R., Madden, T., Zisk, D., Henkel, E., 2010. Attitudes about corporate social Rong, K., Wang, Y., and Luo, Y. N. (2017). Understanding Sharing Economy Evolution: from
responsibility: business student predictors. J. Bus. Ethics 91 (2), 167–181. Adapted Sharing (1.0) to Born Sharing (2.0). Tsinghua working paper.
Kramer, M.R., Pfitzer, M.W., 2016. The ecosystem of shared value. Harvard Bus. Rev. 94 Rong, K., Xiao, F., Zhang, X., Wang, J., 2019. Platform Strategies and User Stickiness in
(10), 80–89. the Online Video Industry. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 143, 249–259.
Krippner, G.R., 2001. The Elusive Market: Embeddedness and the paradigm of economic Sandel, M., 1998. Liberalism and The Limits of Justice. Cambridge University Press,
sociology. Theory Soc. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1013330324198. Cambridge.
Krippner, G.R., Alvarez, A.S., 2007. Embeddedness and the intellectual projects of Saxenian, A., 1995. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon. Harvard
economic sociology. Annu. Rev. Sociol. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev. University Press, Cambridge, MA.
soc.33.040406.131647. Schor, J.B., Thompson, C.J., 2014. Sustainable Lifestyles and the Quest for Plenitude:
Lawrence, Leca, B., Zilber, T.B, 2013. Institutional work: current research, new directions Case Studies of the New Economy. Yale University Press, New Haven.
and overlooked issues. Organ. Stud. 34 (8), 1023–1033. Selznick, P., 1953. TVA and the Grass Roots. University of California Press. https://doi.
Lawrence, T.B., Roy Suddaby, R., 2006. Institutions and Institutional Work. In: Clegg, S. org/10.1017/CBO9781107415324.004.
R., Hardy, C., Lawrence, T.B., Nord, W.R (Eds.), Sage Handbook of Organization Sen, A., 2010. Adam smith and the contemporary world. Erasmus J. Philos. Econ.
Studies, 2nd edn. Sage, London. https://doi.org/10.23941/ejpe.v3i1.39.
Leung, X., Xue, L., Wen, H., 2019. Framing the sharing economy: toward a sustainable Smith, A., 2009. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Penguin, London.
ecosystem. Tourism Manag. 71, 44–53. Swanson, E.B., Ramiller, N.C., 1997. The organizing vision in information systems
Lewis, V.L., Churchill, N.C., 1983. The five stages of small business growth. Harvard Bus. innovation. Organ. Sci. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.8.5.458.
Rev. 3 (3). https://hbr.org/1983/05/the-five-stages-of-small-business-growth Swanson, E.B., Ramiller, N.C., 2004. Innovating mindfully with information technology.
[Accessed 24 March 2021]. MIS Q. 28 (4) https://doi.org/10.2307/25148655. Doi.
Lobschat, L., Mueller, B., Eggers, F., Brandimarte, L., Diefenbach, S., Kroschke, M., Tan, J., Wang, L., 2011. MNC strategic responses to ethical pressure: an institutional
Wirtz, J., 2019. Corporate digital responsibility. J. Bus. Res. https://doi.org/ logic perspective. J. Bus. Ethics 98, 373–390.
10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.10.006. Thorton, and Ocasio, 1999. The Institutional Logics Perspective: A New Approach to
Marin, L., Ruiz, S., Rubio, A., 2009. The role of identity salience in the effects of Culture, Structure, and Process. Oxford University Press on Demand.
corporate social responsibility on consumer behavior. J. Bus. Ethics 84 (1), 65–78. Visser, W., 2011. The Age of Responsibility: CSR 2.0 and the New DNA of Business. Wiley,
Mi, Z., Coffman, D, 2019. The sharing economy promotes sustainable societies. Nat. London.
Commun. 10, 1214. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-019-09260-4. Wang, Y., Ho, C., 2017. No Problem! the value of sustainability: social capital drives the
Miles, M.B., Huberman, A.M., 1994. Qualitative Data Analysis: A Sourcebook of New relationship among customer identification and citizenship behavior in sharing
Methods, 2nd edn. Sage, CA. economy. Sustainability 9, 1–17.
Moon, H.C., Pare, J., Yim, S.H., Park, N., 2011. An Extension of Porter and Kramer’s Yin, R.K., 2014. Case Study Research: Design and Methods, 5th edn. Sage Publishing,
creating shared value (csv): reorienting strategies and seeking international London.
cooperation. J. Int. Area Stud. 18 (2), 49–64.
Moore, J.F, 1996. The Death of Competition: Leadership and Strategy in the Age of
Dr. Ke Rong is an associate professor in the Institute of Economics, School of Social Sci­
Business Ecosystems. Harper Paperbacks, New York.
ence at Tsinghua University in China. Ke has received the Ph.D. degree from University of
Nadeem, W., Al-lmamy, S., 2020. Do ethics drive value co-creation on digital sharing
Cambridge and obtained Bachelor degree in Tsinghua University. Before joining Tsinghua,
economy platforms? J. Retail. Consum. Serv. 55, 102095.
he was a senior lecturer in the University of Exeter and Bournemouth University in UK and
Nadeem, W., Juntunen, M., Shirazi, F., Hajli, N., 2020. Consumers’ value co-creation in
a visiting scholar in the Harvard Business School. His research interests include Platform
sharing economy: the role of social support, consumers’ ethical perceptions and
Market in Sharing Economy, and Business/Innovation Ecosystems. He also served as the
relationship quality. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 151, 119786.
editorial board member in leading strategic management journal- Long Range Planning.
Nasi, J., Nasi, S., Phillips, N., Zyglidopoulos, S., 1997. The evolution of corporate social
His research has been published in J. International Business Studies, International J.
responsiveness. Bus. Soc. 36 (3), 296–321.
Production Economics, J. International Management, Group and Organization Manage­
Orlitzky, M., Siegel, D., Waldman, D.A., 2011. Strategic corporate social responsibility
ment and Technological Forecasting and Social Change. His email is r@tsinghua.edu.cn.
and environmental sustainability. Bus. Soc. 50 (1), 6–27.
Ozcan, P., Eisenhardt, K.M., 2009. Origin of alliance portfolios: entrepreneurs, network
strategies, and firm performance. Acad. Manag. J. 52 (2), 246–279. Dr.Boyi LI is a fellow in management in the Information Systems and Innovation Group,
Parente, R, Rong, K, Geleilate, J-M, et al., 2019. Adapting and sustaining operations in Department of Management LSE. He is interested in ICTs for global development. He works
weak institutional environments: a business ecosystem assessment of a Chinese MNE on the relational approach to social innovation, and empirically studies the movements of
in Central Africa. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 50, 275–291. creative economy and sustainable practices in developing context. Boyi currently teaches
Penrose, E., 1955. Research on business firms: limits to the growth and size of firms. Am. the theoretical foundations of information systems, Innovating Organizational IT, and
Econ. Rev. 45 (2), 531–543. Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-seventh Annual Research Design for MISDI programs.
Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1955).
Pfitzer, M., Bockstette, V., Stamp, M., 2013. Innovating for shared value. Harvard Bus.
Miss Wan Peng is a Ph.D. student in London School of Economics and Political Science in
Rev. https://hbr.org/2013/09/innovating-for-shared-value [Accessed 30 June
UK. Her research interests are Global Governance and International Political Economy.
2020].
Polanyi, K., 1944. The Great Transformation: Economic and Political Origins of Our
Time. Rinehart, New York. Mr. Di Zhou is a Ph.D. student in the Institute of Economics, School of Social Sciences at
Polanyi, K., 1977. The Livelihood of Man. Academic Press, New York, San Francisco, and Tsinghua University in China. His research interests are Platform Economy and Business
London. Ecosystem.
Porter, M.E., Kramer, M.R., 2006. Strategy and society: the link between competitive
advantage and corporate social responsibility. Harvard Bus. Rev. 84 (12), 78–92. Dr. Xinwei Shi is a post-doc in the Institute of Economics, School of Social Science at
Porter, M.E., Kramer, M.R., 2011. How to reinvent capitalism and unleash a wave of Tsinghua University in China. His research interests are Platform Economy and Interna­
innovation and growth. Harvard Bus. Rev. 62–77. January-February. tional Business. His research has been published in J. Business Research. His Email is
Prahalad, C.K., Ramaswamy, V., 2004. Co-creation experiences: the next practice in xinweishi@mail.tsinghua.edu.cn
value creation. J. Interact. Market. 18 (3), 5–14.
Reischauer, G., Mair, J., 2018. How organizations strategically govern online
communities: lessons from the sharing economy. Acad. Manag. Discov. 4 (3),
220–247.

12

You might also like