You are on page 1of 689

The SAGE

Handbook of
Industrial Relations
The SAGE
Handbook of
Industrial Relations

Edited by
Paul Blyton
Nicolas Bacon
Jack Fiorito
and Edmund Heery

Los Angeles • London • New Delhi • Singapore


Introduction and Editorial Arrangement © Paul Blyton,
Nicolas Bacon, Jack Fiorito and Edmund Heery 2008
Chapters 1–34 © SAGE Publications Ltd 2008

First published 2008

Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of research or


private study, or criticism or review, as permitted under the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act, 1988, this publication may
be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any form, or by any
means, only with the prior permission in writing of the publishers,
or in the case of reprographic reproduction, in accordance with the
terms of licences issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency.
Enquiries concerning reproduction outside those terms should be
sent to the publishers.

SAGE Publications Ltd


1 Oliver’s Yard
55 City Road
London EC1Y 1SP

SAGE Publications Inc.


2455 Teller Road
Thousand Oaks, California 91320

SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd


B 1/I 1 Mohan Cooperative Industrial Area
Mathura Road
New Delhi 110 044

SAGE Publications Asia-Pacific Pte Ltd


33 Pekin Street #02-01
Far East Square
Singapore 048763

Library of Congress Control Number: 2007934979

British Library Cataloguing in Publication data

A catalogue record for this book is available from


the British Library

ISBN 978-1-4129-1154-2

Typeset by CEPHA Imaging Pvt. Ltd., Bangalore, India


Printed in India at Replika Press Pvt. Ltd
Printed on paper from sustainable resources
Contents

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

Notes on Contributors xi

Preface xviii

1 Introduction: The Field of Industrial Relations 1


Edmund Heery, Nicolas Bacon, Paul Blyton and Jack Fiorito

PART ONE PERSPECTIVES AND APPROACHES 33

2 The History of Industrial Relations as a Field of Study 35


Carola M. Frege

3 Industrial Relations and the Social Sciences 53


Peter Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson

4 System and Change in Industrial Relations Analysis 69


Edmund Heery

5 Values, Ideologies, and Frames of Reference in Industrial Relations 92


John W. Budd and Devasheesh Bhave

6 The Influence of Product Markets on Industrial Relations 113


William Brown

7 Varieties of Capitalism and Industrial Relations 129


Kerstin Hamann and John Kelly

8 New Forms of Work and the High Performance Paradigm 149


Stephen Procter

9 Changing Traditions in Industrial Relations Research 170


George Strauss and Keith Whitfield
vi CONTENTS

PART TWO THE ACTORS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 187

10 Trade Union Morphology 189


Jack Fiorito and Paul Jarley

11 Trade Union Strategy 209


Peter Boxall

12 Employer Organizations 225


Franz Traxler

13 Management Strategy and Industrial Relations 241


Nicolas Bacon

14 The State in Industrial Relations 258


Richard Hyman

15 The Legal Framework of Employment Relations 284


Simon Deakin and Wanjiru Njoya

16 The State as Employer 305


Marick F. Masters, Ray Gibney, Iryna Shevchuk, and Tom Zagenczyk

17 International Actors and International Regulation 325


Rebecca Gumbrell-McCormick

18 Works Councils 346


Jean Jenkins and Paul Blyton

19 The Evolution of Stakeholder Regimes: Beyond Neo-Corporatism 358


Charles Heckscher

PART THREE INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS PROCESSES 375

20 Union Formation 377


John Godard

21 The Changing Structure of Collective Bargaining 406


Robert J. Flanagan

22 The High Performance Work Systems Literature in Industrial Relations 420


Ann C. Frost

23 Employee Involvement and Direct Participation 434


Russell D. Lansbury and Nick Wailes

24 Resolving Conflict 447


David Lewin
CONTENTS vii

PART FOUR INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS OUTCOMES 469

25 Contingent Work Arrangements 471


Daniel G. Gallagher

26 The Theory and Practice of Pay Setting 491


Alex Bryson and John Forth

27 Working Time and Work-Life Balance 513


Paul Blyton

28 Worker Well-Being 529


David Guest

29 Industrial Relations Climate 548


Ali Dastmalchian

30 Equality at Work 572


Barbara Pocock

31 Conflict at Work 588


Gregor Gall and Robert Hebdon

32 Skill Formation 606


Irena Grugulis

33 Industrial Relations and Business Performance 623


John T. Delaney

34 Labor Market Institutions Around the World 640


Richard B. Freeman

Index 659
List of Figures

5.1 Defining ideology and frame of reference 93


11.1 The context of trade union strategy 211
11.2 Phases of industry evolution 213
11.3 Four patterns of trade union strategic choice in neo-liberal environments 216
11.4 Willman’s ‘Union Portfolio’ 217
16.1 IR systems framework of the state as employer 306
29.1 The industrial relations climate model and summary of relevant factors 554
29.2 Simplified model of organizational performance 561
31.1 US – strike days per 1,000 workers, 1948–2006 599
31.2 Canada – strike incidence and duration, 1946–2005 599
List of Tables

1.1 Levels of industrial relations analysis 7


4.1 Models of change underpinning theories of union revitalization 79
5.1 Four theories of the employment relationship 102
7.1 Union density (%) and density change in 20 OECD countries 1980–2000 138
7.2 Bargaining coordination index and rankings in 15 OECD countries 1973–77
and 1993–97 138
7.3 Collective bargaining coverage (%) in 20 OECD countries 1980–2000 139
7.4 Employment protection legislation in 19 OECD countries, late 1980s–2003 140
7.5 Gross earnings inequality (90:10 ratios) for full time employees in 19 OECD
countries 1980–1984 to 1995–1999 140
7.6 Industrial conflict in selected OECD countries 1985–2003 (days lost
per 1000 workers) 141
7.7 Standardized unemployment rates (%) in selected OECD countries 1985–2003 142
8.1 Classification device for studies linking HR practice and organizational
performance 154
9.1 Nature of papers published in main IR journals 180
9.2 Type of data and methods of analysis used 181
9.3 Industrial relations research methods 182
12.1 The largest employer peak organization: Basic data (1994–96) 228
12.2 The system of employer organization (1991–98) 234
13.1 Management style industrial relations typologies 244
13.2 Employment relations choices 246
16.1 Dimensions of governance 308
16.2 General government final consumption expenditure (percent of GDP) 311
16.3 Core government functions of selected OECD member countries 312
16.4 Public employment 313
16.5 Country breakdown of amounts raised by privatization (Billions of $US) 314
16.6 Privatization initiatives in selected countries 315
16.7 Union density, private and public sector (percent of unionized workers) 317
16.8 Characteristics of career-based, department-based, and position-based civil
systems 318
20.1 Major studies and data sets employed in voting propensity analyses 378
21.1 Bargaining structures in OECD countries, 1970–2000 414
21.2 Bargaining coordination in OECD countries, 1970–2000 414
26.1 Gross hourly earnings in the UK, Autumn 2005 493
28.1 Perspectives on the outcomes of contemporary employment relations 532
29.1 A summary of the six longitudinal case studies 559
33.1 Summary of meta–analyses of union effects 627
x LIST OF TABLES

34.1 Measures of the variation of labor institutions across advanced countries 642
34.2 Mean values of ranks of Anglo-American and other advanced economies labor
institutions (low value=market oriented) and t-tests of their statistical
significance 644
34.3 90/10 Wage differentials and Gini coefficients for advanced countries,
circa 2000 651
Notes on Contributors

Peter Ackers is Professor of Industrial Relations and Labour History at Loughborough


University Business School. During 2005–06 he was Leverhulme Visiting Fellow at the Indian
Institute of Management, Calcutta. His current research is on British Industrial Relations History,
including a biographical study of Professor Hugh Clegg, and Indian Industrial Relations. He
has edited Understanding Work and Employment: Industrial Relations in Transition (Oxford
University Press 2003) with Adrian Wilkinson and The New Workplace and Trade Unionism
(Routledge 1996) with Chris Smith and Paul Smith.

Nicolas Bacon is Professor of Human Resource Management at Nottingham University Business


School, UK. His current research on trade unions includes partnership agreements, negotiations
to change working practices and union learning representatives; the employment effects of
buyouts and shareholder value management; and employment practices in small and medium-
sized enterprises. He is currently editor of the Industrial Relations Journal.

Devasheesh Bhave is a PhD candidate in the Human Resources and Industrial Relations
department at the Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota. His research
interests include the areas of electronic performance monitoring, relational demography, and
employment relationships.

Paul Blyton is Professor of Industrial Relations and Industrial Sociology at Cardiff University,
UK. His research interests include employees’ experience of work restructuring, working time
developments, and work-life balance concerns. His recent publications include The Realities
of Work with Mike Noon (Palgrave Macmillan) and Key Concepts in Work with Jean Jenkins
(Sage).

Peter Boxall is Professor of Human Resource Management at the University of Auckland.


His research is concerned with both management and employee strategies in contemporary
workplaces and their respective outcomes. He is co-editor (with John Purcell and Patrick
Wright) of the Oxford University Press Handbook of Human Resource Management and co-
editor (with Richard Freeman and Peter Haynes) of What Workers Say: Employee Voice in the
Anglo-American Workplace (Cornell University Press).

William Brown is Professor of Industrial Relations in the Economics Faculty at Cambridge


University and Master of Darwin College. He was previously Director of the Industrial Relations
Research Unit at Warwick University. An active arbitrator, he was a member of the council of
the UK’s Advisory, Conciliation and Arbitration Service (ACAS), and was a founder member of
the Low Pay Commission which established, and maintains, the UK national minimum wage.
xii NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

His research interests include collective bargaining, pay systems, trade unions, and the effects
of legal intervention in the labor market.

Alex Bryson is a Research Director at the Policy Studies Institute. He has been at the institute
since 1991, during which time his research has focused on the evaluation of welfare-to-
work programs and industrial relations. Recently he has been applying techniques common
in the evaluation literature to problems in industrial relations. He is an editor of the British
Journal of Industrial Relations and the Manpower Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic
Performance.

John W. Budd is a Professor in the Industrial Relations Center at the University of Minnesota’s
Carlson School of Management. He is the author of Employment with a Human Face: Balancing
Efficiency, Equity, and Voice (Cornell University Press), Labor Relations: Striking a Balance
(McGraw-Hill/Irwin), and a co-editor of The Ethics of Human Resources and Industrial Relations
(Labor and Employment Relations Association). His current research interests include industrial
relations theory, employment-related public policies, and conceptualizations of work.

Ali Dastmalchian is Professor of Organizational Analysis and Dean, Faculty of Business,


University of Victoria, Canada. His recent research interests include organizational change,
organizational design in health care, and healthy organizations. His recent publications include
Work-Life Integration with Paul Blyton, Ken Reed, and Betsy Blunsdon (Palgrave Macmillan).
His work has appeared in journals such as the British Journal of Industrial Relations, Industrial
and Labor Relations Review and Human Relations.

Simon Deakin is Professor of Law at the University of Cambridge. He specializes in the


economics and sociology of law, focusing on labor, company and private law. His books
include The Law of the Labour Market (2005, with Frank Wilkinson). He is a member of
the editorial boards of the British Journal of Industrial Relations, the Industrial Law Journal,
and the Cambridge Journal of Economics.

John T. Delaney is Professor of Management and Dean of the Joseph M. Katz Graduate School
of Business and College of Business Administration at the University of Pittsburgh. His research
focuses on dispute resolution, high performance work practices, and labor relations. His recent
publications include Organized Labor’s Political Scorecard (with Marick Masters), Ethical
Challenges in Labor Relations, and Change to Win: Can Structural Change Revitalize the
American Labor Movement (with Jack Fiorito and Paul Jarley).

Jack Fiorito is J. Frank Dame Professor of Management at Florida State University and
Principal Research Fellow at the University of Hertfordshire. His research interests include
worker attitudes toward unions and employers, and how unions function as organizations. His
recent publications include ‘The State of the Unions in the United States’, Journal of Labor
Research (2007), and ‘Change to Win: Can Structural Reform Revitalize the American Labor
Movement?’ Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations (2007).

Robert J. Flanagan is the Konosuke Matsushita Professor of International Labor Economics


and Policy Analysis at the Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. His current
research interests include the relationship between globalization, working conditions, and labor
rights around the world and the economics of symphony orchestras. His most recent book is
Globalization and Labor Conditions (Oxford University Press, 2006).
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xiii

John Forth is a Research Fellow at the National Institute of Economic and Social Research.
He works on a range of labor market issues including employment relations, equality, and
skills. He is co-author of Inside the Workplace and All Change at Work?, both arising from his
involvement in the Workplace Employment Relations Survey series. Other recent publications
have focused on topics such as pay determination, ‘high involvement management’, and
productivity, with a particular emphasis on the role of trade unions.

Richard B. Freeman is Professor of Economics at Harvard University, Labor Studies Program


Director at NBER, and Professorial Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic Performance,
London School of Economics. His research interests include the growth and decline of
unions; self-organizing non-unions in the labor market; restructuring European welfare states;
international labor standards; Chinese labor markets; crime; employee involvement programs;
globalization; income distribution and equity in the marketplace; immigration and trade; and
the job market for scientists and engineers. His recent publications include What Workers Want
(Cornell 2nd edition), Can Labor Standards Improve Under Globalization? (IIE), and America
Works: The Exceptional Labor Market (Sage).

Carola M. Frege is a Reader in Employment Relations at the London School of Economics


and Political Science. She is the author of Employment Research and State Traditions (Oxford
University Press 2007) and co-editor of Varieties of Unionism (OUP, 2004). She has published
widely in academic journals and edited collections on comparative employment relations and is
the editor of the British Journal of Industrial Relations.

Ann C. Frost is Associate Professor at the Richard Ivey School of Business, University of
Western Ontario. Her main research focus has been in the area of workplace restructuring and
high performance forms of work organization. Articles from this research have appeared in
Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations, the British Journal of Industrial Relations, and the
Industrial and Labor Relations Review. Her current research interests include models of labor-
management co-operation, restructuring in the health care sector, the impact of recent changes in
work organization on the careers of low wage workers, and employment practices in Canadian
call centers.

Gregor Gall is Professor of Industrial Relations and Director of the Centre for Research in
Employment Studies at the University of Hertfordshire, UK. His research interests revolve
around trade unionism and worker mobilization. His recent books include Sex Worker Union
Organizing: An International Study (Palgrave Macmillan) and The Political Economy of
Scotland: Red Scotland? Radical Scotland? (University of Wales Press). Also, he is the editor
of two volumes on union recognition (with Routledge) and a forthcoming one (with Palgrave
Macmillan).

Daniel G. Gallagher is the CSX Corporation Professor of Management at James Madison


University in Harrisonburg, Virginia. His current research interests include a variety of topics
related to the study of independent contracting and other forms of work outside of the traditional
employer–employee relationship. He also has an ongoing interest in the study of union member
attitudes and behaviors. He is currently an Associate Editor of Human Relations, and serves on
the editorial boards of Industrial Relations and the Journal of Management.

Ray Gibney is an Assistant Professor of Management at the Pennsylvania State University at


Harrisburg. His primary research interests are positive and negative employee-collective social
xiv NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

exchange relationships. In addition, Ray is interested in labor unions in the political process and
employee self-service technology in organizations.

John Godard is Professor at the Faculty of Management, the University of Manitoba. His work
focuses on state policies and labor law, on comparative institutional environments, and on the
implications of work and human resource practices for workers and their unions. It has been
published in a number of edited books and in numerous academic journals, appearing most
frequently in the Industrial and Labor Relations Review and the British Journal of Industrial
Relations. He is a former editor of the British Journal of Industrial Relations, and serves on the
boards of a number of scholarly journals.

Irena Grugulis is Professor of Employment Studies and head of the HR/OB teaching group
at Bradford University School of Management. Her research interests cover most areas of
skill, particularly the impact that national and organizational systems have on the people who
experience them. Her latest book, published by Palgrave Macmillan in 2007 is Skills, Training
and Human Resource Development: A Critical Text. Her current projects include research
into employment in the film and TV industry and retail work in Britain. She is an associate
fellow of SKOPE and edits the Debates and Controversies section of Work, Employment and
Society.

David Guest is Professor of Organizational Psychology and Human Resource Management


at King’s College, London. His current research interests are the relationship between human
resource management, organizational performance, and employee well-being in the public and
private sectors; the individualization of employment relations and the role of the psychological
contract; flexibility and employment contracts; partnership at work; and the future of the
career.

Rebecca Gumbrell-McCormick is Lecturer in Management at Birkbeck, University of London,


UK. She is a former international trade union official and official of the ILO. Her main
research areas are international and European industrial relations and equal opportunities.
Her most recent publications include ‘Embedded Collectivism? Workplace Representation
in France and Germany’, in Industrial Relations Journal, 37(5), September 2006 (with
Richard Hyman) and ‘The ICFTU and the World Economy: A Historical Perspective’, in
R Munck (2003) (ed.) Labour and Globalisation: Results and Prospects (Liverpool University
Press).

Kerstin Hamann is Professor of Political Science at the University of Central Florida in


Orlando, US. Her research focuses on comparative political economy and industrial relations
in Western Europe, and on Spanish politics and labor unions. Her work has been published in
journals such as the British Journal of Industrial Relations, the European Journal of Industrial
Relations, Comparative Political Studies, and Industrial and Labor Relations Review. Her current
collaborative research with John Kelly analyzes the political dynamics of the origins of social
pacts in Western Europe.

Robert Hebdon is the Chair of the Faculty Program in Industrial Relations and Associate
Professor in the Desautels Faculty of Management of McGill University. His research interests
include public sector restructuring and workplace conflict. His recent publications include
articles on strike duration with Mike Campoletti and Doug Hyatt (Industrial and Labor
Relations Review), workplace conflict (Advances in Industrial Relations), and comparative local
government restructuring with Patrice Jalette (Environment and Planning C).
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xv

Edmund Heery is Professor of Employment Relations and Joint Director (with Peter
Fairbrother) of the Centre for Global Labor Research at Cardiff University. His primary research
interest in recent years has been union strategies of revitalization, which has included study
of union organizing, union representation of contingent workers, and union bargaining over
equality and work-life balance. His current research is a study of worker representation through
‘civil society organizations’; charities, advocacy, and campaigning organizations. His recent
publications include The Future of Worker Representation (edited with Geraldine Healy, Phil
Taylor, and William Brown), Palgrave MacMillan, 2004.

Charles Heckscher is a Professor at Rutgers University and Director of the Center for Workplace
Transformation. His research focuses on organization change and the changing nature of
employee representation. His books include The New Unionism, White-Collar Blues, and The
Collaborative Enterprise.

Richard Hyman is Professor of Industrial Relations at the London School of Economics


and Political Science (LSE) and is founding editor of the European Journal of Industrial
Relations. He has written extensively on the themes of industrial relations, collective bargaining,
trade unionism, industrial conflict, and labor market policy, and is author of many books,
including Strikes and Industrial Relations: A Marxist Introduction. He co-edited the 17-country
text Changing Industrial Relations in Europe (Blackwell, 1998). His comparative study
Understanding European Trade Unionism: Between Market, Class and Society was published
by Sage in 2001.

Paul Jarley is Professor of Management and Dean of the College of Business at the University
of Nevada Las Vegas. His research interests focus on trade union structures and strategies,
interest arbitration, and social capital at work. His recent publications include Unions as Social
Capital, Justice and Union Participation (with Nancy Brown Johnson), and Change to Win:
Can Structural Change Revitalize the American Labor Movement? (with Jack Fiorito and John
T. Delaney).

Jean Jenkins is Lecturer in HRM at Cardiff University. Her research interests center on
employment relations in the manufacturing sector, particularly in the clothing sector, and
employees’ experiences in the increasingly internationalized market for labor. Her recent
publications include Key Concepts in Work (with Paul Blyton), Sage 2007.

John Kelly is Professor of Industrial Relations in the School of Management Birkbeck College,
University of London. His main areas of research are comparative labor relations, labor unions,
and industrial relations theory and recent publications include Varieties of Unionism (OUP,
2004, co-editor), Union Organization and Activity (Routledge 2004, co-editor), and Rethinking
Industrial Relations (Routledge, 1998).

Russell D. Lansbury is Professor of Work and Organizational Studies and Associate Dean
(Research) in the Faculty of Economics and Business at the University of Sydney. He is
the current President of the International Industrial Relations Association. His major research
contributions have been in the fields of international and comparative studies of employment
relations and management.

David Lewin is the Neil Jacoby Professor of Management, Human Resources and Organizational
Behavior in the UCLA Anderson School of Management. His research interests include
workplace/organizational conflict, human resource management and business performance, pay
xvi NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

and rewards, and new challenges to old wage and hour law. His recent publications include
Contemporary Issues in Employment Relations (2006) and Advances in Industrial and Labor
Relations, Volume 15 (2007).

Marick F. Masters is a Professor of Business Administration and of Public and International


Affairs at the University of Pittsburgh, where he directs the Center on Conflict Resolution and
Negotiation. He has written more than 100 articles and several books. His current interests lie
in negotiations, conflict resolution, the role of interest groups in politics, and the management
of political campaigns. He is a senior partner with AIM Consultants, a management consulting
firm, with offices in New London, CT and Pittsburgh, PA.

Wanjiru Njoya is Lecturer in Law at Oxford University, and a Fellow of Wadham College
Oxford. Her publications include Property in Work: The Employment Relationship in the Anglo-
American Firm (Aldershot,Ashgate Publishing, 2007). She specializes in labor law and corporate
governance, and her research has appeared in the British Journal of Industrial Relations, the
Industrial Law Journal, and the Law Quarterly Review.

Barbara Pocock is Director of the Centre for Work + Life at the University of South Australia.
She has worked in a range of industries. Her past research includes analysis of trade unions,
gender politics at work, the regulation of industrial relations systems, and effects on inequality.
At present she is studying the changing nature of work and its intersections with changing
household and social life, with Australia as her primary focus. Her latest books are The Work/Life
Collision (2003) and The Labour Market Ate My Babies (2006), both published by Federation
Press.

Stephen Procter is Alcan Professor of Management and Director of Research at Newcastle


University Business School. His chief area of research interest is new patterns of work in the
public sector, particularly teamworking and workplace flexibility. He is currently involved in
projects looking at new working patterns in the mental health services workforce, multi-agency
working in public services, and the management of public sector mergers. He is co-founder and
co-organizer of the International Workshop on Teamworking, Chair of the Editorial Advisory
Board of Personnel Review, and, in 2007–08, Chair of the British Academy of Management
Special Interest Group on HRM.

Iryna Shevchuk is a PhD candidate at the University of Pittsburgh. Her research interests include
the employer–employee relationship, employee turnover, and quantitative research methods and
design.

George Strauss is Professor Emeritus at the Haas School of Management at the University of
California, Berkeley. He is also a member of the Institute for Research on Labor and Employment
(previously the Institute for Industrial Relations), also at UCB. He is the co-author (with Keith
Whitfield) of Researching the World of Work: Strategies and Methods of Studying Industrial
Relations (ILR Press).

Franz Traxler is Professor of Industrial Sociology at the University of Vienna. His research
focuses on comparative industrial relations and organized interests. Book publications include
National Labour Relations in Internationalized Markets (with S. Blaschke and B. Kittel)
(Oxford University Press 2001), and Handbook of Business Interest Associations, Firm Size
and Governance (with G. Huemer) (Routledge 2007).
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xvii

Nick Wailes is a Senior Lecturer in Work and Organizational Studies at the University of Sydney,
Australia. He teaches comparative industrial relations and strategic management. His two main
areas of research are the impact of globalization on national relations systems and the study of
organizational change associated with information and communications technology.

Keith Whitfield is Professor of Human Resource Management and Economics at Cardiff


University, UK. His research focuses on the impact of human resource policies and practices on
employee and organizational outcomes. He was recently a member of the steering group for the
Fifth British Workplace Employment Relations Survey, and is currently the principal investigator
for a project examining a quarter century of change in British Employment Relations.

Adrian Wilkinson is Professor of Employment Relations at Griffith University, Australia.


His research interests include employee participation, high performance workplaces, and
industrial relations and human resource management theory. Recent publications include Human
Resource Management at Work (CIPD) with Mick Marchington and Understanding Work and
Employment (OUP) with Peter Ackers.

Tom Zagenczyk is an Assistant Professor of Management at Clemson University. His


research interests include the employer–employee relationship, social influence processes in
organizations, developmental relationships, and the relationship between IT and employee
attitudes.
Preface

The purpose of this Handbook is to provide readers with an overview of current knowledge
from Industrial Relations scholarship, and consider what issues and questions still need to
be addressed. The scope of the different contributions is testament to a subject area that has
broadened its perspective far beyond what many in the past considered the central areas of
Industrial Relations interest: trade unions, collective bargaining, and strikes. It is now widely
recognized that the different aspects of the employment relationship are what define the field
of industrial relations: the various elements that comprise the employment relationship; the
bases and assumptions on which employment relationships are formed and modified; the
significance of different institutional arrangements within which those employment relationships
are situated; and the relevance of broader economic, social, and technological developments
that fundamentally affect contemporary society. Questions and concerns that first gave rise to
industrial relations enquiry have not disappeared, but have been augmented by the recognition
of a much broader set of issues and developments impacting on people’s experience of work.
The international group of contributors brought together here are the leading experts of their
fields and this provides them both with a solid base from which to review what is known about
their area of study, but also what we as yet do not sufficiently know: what questions we have
failed to answer satisfactorily to date, and what issues still clamor for attention.
It is a highly appropriate time to produce such a collection. With profound changes occurring
within industrial relations practice over the past two decades – not least, changes in trade
union presence, the coverage of union-management relations, and the state’s role within the
employment relationship – coupled with fundamental developments in national and international
product and labor markets, it is apposite to take stock of what these developments signify for
the field of industrial relations and what new questions and challenges they pose.
In bringing this collection to fruition, we wish to acknowledge the help we have had from
various different quarters. First, our thanks to all the contributors who not only agreed to fit
this task into their already busy schedules, but to respond willingly to comments on drafts that
helped create a more cohesive and comprehensive collection that otherwise wouldn’t have been
the case. Second, thanks to the administrative efforts of Sue O’Brien and Penny Smith at Cardiff
University who endeavored to keep a hold on where everything was, as drafts moved back and
forth. Third, our thanks to the team at Sage – Chris Rojek, Mila Steele, and Kay Bridger – for
putting the idea of the Handbook to us in the first place, for being patient as the delays that
are probably inevitable in a large project of this kind duly occurred, and for allowing us the
opportunity to work with such a thought-provoking group of academics.
1
Introduction: The Field of
Industrial Relations
Edmund Heery, Nicholas Bacon, Paul Blyton
and Jack Fiorito

INTRODUCTION what is now, a mature academic field and


its continuing relevance at the start of a new
The purpose of this Handbook is to profile century, very different from the old.
the academic field of industrial relations (IR) The purpose of this introduction is to
at the start of the twenty-first century. To this provide a platform for the 33 chapters that
end we have assembled an international roster follow. It does so by providing an overview
of subject experts to reflect on the multiple of three core aspects of contemporary IR
facets of IR scholarship, summarize bodies scholarship. We consider in turn the definition
of knowledge and theory and identify current and scope of academic industrial relations,
developments and likely future trends. IR was the multi-disciplinary nature of IR and the
a product of the great class compromise of the theoretical perspectives that shape its research
twentieth century between ruling elites and program, and the normative orientations of
the rising working class. Many of its founding IR scholars that provide a standard for
scholars were exercised by the ‘labor problem’ evaluating IR practice and underpin the
and the need for a practically oriented field advice to governments, employers, unions and
of study to support the creation of new others that issue from an applied, policy-
institutions that would regulate industrial oriented field. In each of these areas our
conflict and integrate the working population aim is to identify classic positions and
into liberal democratic societies (Kaufman, defining characteristics of IR but also point
1993: 4–9; Lyddon, 2003). Much of this to contemporary themes and developments.
impulse (though not all) has faded as the Our purpose is to show how the enduring
decades have passed but the field of IR features of the field continue to evolve.
continues to evolve and address a broad and To conclude the introduction, we also describe
continually shifting set of issues within the the structure of the Handbook and introduce
employment relationship. This collection we the separate chapters that comprise the
believe, attests to the continuing vigor of, volume.
2 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

DEFINITION AND SCOPE all forms of economic activity in which an


employee works under the authority of an
Twenty-five years ago Marsden (1982: 232) employer and receives a wage for his or her
declared that, ‘Everyone, instinctively it labor.’ Both authors state that ‘employment
seems, knows what industrial relations is relations’ is a more satisfactory label for the
about, even those who have never studied field, if only because it has less connotations
the subject. It is “about” trade unions, man- with smoke-stack industry, and in some parts
agers and collective bargaining.’Undoubtedly of the world IR has begun to yield to this newer
many outside the field, if pressed, would label.1 We are sympathetic to this change of
provide a similar definition and it is certainly usage but have retained the established term to
the case that the core of IR scholarship minimize possible confusion, as do Edwards
has focused, for a long time, on collec- and Kaufman.
tive industrial relations. Studies of trade Defining IR as the study of the employment
unions, collective employment law, collective relationship is only an initial step and the
bargaining and state–trade union relations next is to identify the component elements
continue to feature prominently in the field of the employment relationship in order to
(Frege, 2005). further specify IR’s domain. In our view, four
Definitions offered from within the field, elements can usefully be identified.
however, typically cast their net much wider
and effectively claim the non-union as well
Actors
as the unionized segment of the economy
as IR’s province. This was true of some Much IR research is focused on the parties
of the first attempts to specify the bounds to the employment relationship, typically
of IR as an academic subject. Thus, in labeled since Dunlop the industrial relations
Dunlop’s 1958 formulation of a ‘general ‘actors’. These include workers and their
theory of industrial relations’, the subject representative institutions, including trade
matter is defined as the ‘industrial relations unions and left political parties; employ-
system’, a distinct institutional domain within ers, their managerial representatives within
developed economies, comprising actors, the firm and their collective organizations,
processes, context and outcomes (Dunlop, employers’ associations; and the state and its
1993). Crucially, this definition includes but multiple agencies involved in the formation
is not confined to the examination of trade and regulation of employment relationships.
unions and collective bargaining; the roster of The latter includes legislatures, judicial and
actors embraces workers and their informal police authorities and specialist agencies
work groups as well as formal representative engaged in training and development and
institutions, the list of processes covers dispute resolution. As traditional, collective
management decision and legal regulation as actors have declined in significance in many
well as bilateral regulation by unions and countries so the field has begun to research
employers. ‘new actors in industrial relations’ (Heery
More recent attempts to designate the and Frege, 2006). With regard to employees
object of the study of IR have followed a there has been a growth of interest in
similar tack and tend to define the field as non-union representatives, including work
the study of the employment relationship. councilors elected or appointed under statu-
This is true of authoritative statements by tory provisions and representatives operating
Kaufman (2004a: 45), who states that IR is under voluntary arrangements established by
‘the study of the employment relationship and employers (Frege, 2002; Kaufman and Taras,
all the behaviors, outcomes, practices, and 2000). There has also been a growth of
institutions that emanate from or impinge on interest in identity-groups and social move-
the relationship’, and Edwards (2003: 1–2), ment organizations that campaign on behalf
who declares that the ‘focus is employment: of particular categories of employee, for
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 3

example, women, lesbian, gay and bisexuals, in the presence and power of specialist
migrants, the disabled or older workers (Fine, HR managers. But they are interested also
2006; Piore and Safford, 2006). A similar in management strategies of labor use and
trend is apparent on the employers’ side. the multiple initiatives pursued to secure
Here there has been a growth of interest in the compliance of workers or their active
organizations that can be regarded as forming commitment to employer goals (Purcell and
and expressing the collective interests of Ahlstrand, 1994).
employers, including management consul-
tants developing new practice, employment
Processes
agencies and other labor market intermedi-
aries, and organizations providing standards The second main focus of IR research is
and inspection in the field of corporate social the processes through which the employment
responsibility (Kuruvilla and Verma, 2006: relationship is governed. Again according
48–51; Logan, 2006; Osterman et al., 2001: to Dunlop, it is common to define these
144–6). processes in terms of rule-making or ‘job
IR research focused on actors deals with regulation’, with two primary types of rule
a broad range of substantive issues. If one being generated: substantive rules that specify
considers the classic subject matter of trade the content of the employment relationship
unions then the following main areas of (wages, hours of work, methods of working,
research can be identified: staffing levels, etc.) and procedural rules that
govern the interaction and behavior of the
1) the formation and reproduction of unions parties (bargaining, consultation, information
including trends in membership and the basis of disclosure and dispute resolution). Both
union joining; types of rule may be formal, inscribed in
2) the internal structure and functioning of unions company policies, collective agreements or
including union democracy, governance and statutes, or informal, enshrined in customary
management; expectations and relationships. The main way
3) the external structure of unions including the of classifying these regulatory processes is
nature of union ‘job territories’ (enterprise, in terms of their authorship – which actor or
occupation, industry or general) and the degree of
combination of actors is the creator of rules.
integration of the national trade union movement;
4) union functions and areas of activity including
It is usual to distinguish unilateral regulation
direct service provision to members, collective by employers (and less frequently) trade
bargaining and dispute handling, legal advocacy unions, joint regulation through collective
and political action; bargaining, legal regulation by the state and
5) union strategies particularly in the context of tripartite regulation, in which government,
union decline and attempts of renewal; and employers and unions formulate ‘social pacts’
6) union effects on business, economy and society that govern the economy, including wage
and their effectiveness in representing their growth, welfare expenditure and employment
members. (Hassel, 2006).
From this starting point theoretical and
Equivalent lists can be compiled readily for research work on IR processes has followed
other IR actors though perhaps in all cases the a number of avenues. One course has been
key distinction that can be drawn is between to identify the component elements of each
the organizational characteristics of any given rule-making process; to break it down into its
actor and the nature of its intervention within constituent elements. A classic venture of this
the IR system; that is between structure and kind was Clegg’s (1976) identification of the
strategy. Thus, for employers IR researchers structural components of national systems of
are interested in the degree of centralization or collective bargaining, which varied in terms of
decentralization of the management hierarchy bargaining coverage, level, depth, scope and
and its composition, with a particular interest degree of employer support for trade unions.
4 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

More recent contributions have identified the that specify those elements of the employment
elements of other IR processes. Sisson and relationship that are subject to collective
Marginson (2002), for example, have devel- bargaining and those that are regulated
oped a framework that is similar to Clegg’s through management decision (Sisson, 1987).
for analyzing ‘co-ordinated bargaining’, the A similar interface can be identified between
process through which discrete episodes of collective bargaining and employment law.
bargaining are linked in broader sectoral, In Anglophone countries the prime function
national or, indeed, international systems of of the latter through much of the twentieth
regulation. century was to serve as ‘auxiliary legislation’
A second development has been to identify (Davies and Freedland, 1993: 29), providing
separate forms of each process. Thus, with legal support for trade unions and collective
regard to legal regulation, it is common bargaining rather than directly regulating
to distinguish ‘hard’ and ‘soft’ forms of the terms of the employment relationship.
regulation (Kuruvilla and Verma, 2006). The In Britain, auxiliary legislation famously
former consists of rights and employment took the form of ‘statutory immunities’,
standards established by statute and enforced legal protection for trade unions from civil
both through application to courts and inspec- action under the common law if they
tion by government agencies. The latter, organized industrial action that disrupted
in contrast, consists of opinions, advice, employers’ business (Howell, 2005: 61–4,
guidance, charters and codes of practice, 149–50).
which are issued by legislative bodies and The decline of collective bargaining over
intended to encourage the adoption of good the past two decades in many countries,
practice but which are not reinforced by direct however, has generated a fresh interest in
sanctions. Scholars have further refined this the relationship between different forms of
typology, identifying other forms of legal job regulation. It is asked with increasing
regulation. In the European Union (EU), for frequency whether the rise of other forms is
instance, there has been a growth of what has implicated in the decline of bargaining and
been labeled ‘reflexive governance’ (Barnard researchers have focused on the interaction
and Deakin, 2002), in which employers can between joint regulation and both new forms
derogate from legal standards and tailor of management regulation and the expanding
regulations to their particular circumstances volume of employment law. The central ques-
provided this occurs through consultation tions have been whether alternative regulatory
with employee representatives. processes supplant bargaining or whether
A third line of development has been to collective bargaining and other forms can
explore the relationship between different hybridize and support one another? Answers
forms and the degree to which they sup- differ. For some writers the spread of human
plant or complement one another. National resource management and high-performance
economies contain multiple processes of work systems poses a threat to joint regulation
job regulation with management decision, and is implicated in the de-unionization of
collective bargaining, legal regulation and industrial relations, essentially because it
the inclusion of social partners, business realigns worker and management interests
and worker representatives, in government and provides the basis for ‘mutual gains’
policy-making existing alongside one another, (Dickson et al., 1988; Fiorito, 2001). For
applied variously to different issues, different others collective bargaining can support new
segments of the workforce or different work systems, union pressure serving to
industrial sectors. The separate processes may ensure that benefits are shared equitably
reinforce one another, with particular regu- between company and workforce and thereby
lations establishing boundaries and ensuring helping to sustain innovation (Bacon and
integration. Thus, collective agreements fre- Blyton, 2006; Frost, 2001). A similar debate
quently contain ‘management rights’ clauses has emerged over the ‘juridification’ of
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 5

the employment relationship, the growth of investment in the human resource and confirm
individual employment law. On the one hand, that good management practice can have a
it is argued that individual rights dimin- bottom-line pay-off.
ish worker need for collective bargaining Research on outcomes within IR research
(Metcalf, 2005: 114), while on the other hand has a number of dimensions. One marked fea-
it is suggested that new law can support ture is the emphasis on evaluating outcomes
collective bargaining, the platform of rights from the perspective of multiple stakeholders.
providing minima above which collective Unlike other subjects taught in business
agreements can build and the threat of schools, in IR there is no unreflexive adoption
union-sponsored legal action serving as a of the perspective of the employer and
lever to open up negotiations (Heery and research on business outcomes sits alongside
Conley, 2007). Whichever of these positions research on outcomes for workers and others.
is correct, the relationship between new and This is even apparent in the high-performance
old forms of job regulation has emerged paradigm, where a notable development has
as one of the central themes in current IR been the growth of research on the effect of
research.2 new work systems on employees, sometimes
from a highly critical perspective that seeks to
debunk the claim that all parties benefit from
Outcomes
innovation (Thompson and Harley, 2007).
IR is also, indeed increasingly, concerned In a related development researchers have
with assessing the outcomes of processes. also begun to apply ethical frameworks to
The classic expression of this concern can employment issues, using normative criteria
be seen in the very substantial body of drawn from moral philosophy to judge IR out-
research exploring the relationship between comes (for example Budd, 2004; Guest, 2007;
trade union presence and collective bargaining Legge, 2007). Another distinction that can be
and a broad range of economic, psychological drawn in outcomes research relates to the issue
and social phenomena. The latter include rates of scale. A great deal of work is focused on the
of productivity and profit, job satisfaction proximate effects of IR processes, such as the
and organizational commitment and levels of impact of work organization or union presence
income inequality (Turnbull, 2003). Although on job satisfaction. The distal effects of IR
a well-established research theme, devel- processes are also considered, however, and
opment continues with new datasets, new in a tradition that reaches back to the origins
theories, and new research techniques adding of the subject, there is a continuing interest in
to an established body of work (for example the contribution of IR to social integration and
Belman and Voos, 2006; Fairris, 2006). inclusion, the civilizing of the market order
Another area where outcomes research has and the reproduction of liberal democracy (for
blossomed in recent years is that concerned example Adams, 1995; Estlund, 2003; Green,
with the impact of HR practices on business 2006). IR scholars are not just concerned with
performance. This work lies at the center the minutiae of the workplace order, important
of what Godard (2004a) has termed the though these are, but with the contribution
‘high performance paradigm’ within current of IR institutions to the making of a good
IR research. Its distinguishing feature is the society.
use of large datasets and econometric methods A final point to note about research on
to establish a statistical relationship between IR outcomes is that it is often comparative,
measures of sophisticated human resource in the sense that it seeks to evaluate
management, often expressed as the use of the effects of different IR processes. Perhaps
‘high performance work systems’, and a the clearest example today can be seen in the
variety of indicators of business performance literature on gender equality. The outcomes
(Wall and Wood, 2005; Whitfield and Poole, of interest in this research include measures
1997). The broad aim is to validate employer of pay inequality, vertical and horizontal
6 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

job segregation and the degree to which industry or pattern bargaining. A particularly
employment systems remain predicated on a important branch of IR scholarship at this
male ‘norm’ of continuous, full-time employ- level has examined public sector industrial
ment (Blau et al., 2006). Researchers are relations and the distinctive patterns of worker
interested in the contribution to narrowing behavior and attitudes, union representation
these indicators of inequality of management and employer policy within public service
decision, persuaded by a ‘business case’ for organizations (for example Bach et al.,
equality, unions prioritizing the needs of 1999). At the national level key actors have
women workers through ‘equality bargaining’ been national labor movements and union
and equal opportunity and other bodies of confederations, peak-level business organi-
employment law (Dickens, 1999). For each zations and state policies and institutions,
process, moreover, researchers have tried to with a pronounced emphasis in European
identify the conditions under which it is more IR research on the relationship between
or less effective. Management policy may government and social partners (Teague,
be more developed and significant where 2006; Traxler et al., 2002). Finally, and
there is a professional HR function that increasingly, IR research has focused on the
includes equality specialists (Colling and supra-national level. There is an increasing
Dickens, 1998; Hoque and Noon, 2004), volume of regional research examining the
bargaining may be more effective when industrial relations of particular trading and
it is centralized or where women occupy political blocs, such as the EU and the North
negotiating positions (Colling and Dickens, American Free Trade Area (NAFTA) and
1989; Hunter and Rimmer, 1995) and law may a growing body of work that examines IR
be more effective when it imposes obligations at a global scale. The latter encompasses
on employers not to discriminate, backed up research on multi-national enterprises and
by inspection (Dickens, 2007). Whatever the their supply-chains, global trade unions and
precise question, however, the key thing is that non-governmental organizations (NGOs) that
in research of this stamp the central concern campaign for workers’rights and the activities
is comparative, to evaluate competing routes of international regulatory bodies, such as the
to the achievement of desired IR outcomes. International Labour Organization.
Throughout IR’s history as a field of study
each of these levels has attracted research and
Levels
scholarship. At different points in the subject’s
Another feature of IR research is that it development, however, certain levels have
is conducted at different scales or levels, attracted particular attention. In the 1960s and
stretching from the workplace to the global 1970s, for example, often regarded as a golden
and encompassing many points in-between age of IR scholarship in some countries,
(see Kochan et al., 1986: 15–20). Table 1.1 there was a pronounced focus on workplace
illustrates this range and identifies typical studies (Ackers and Wilkinson, 2003a: 11).
actors, processes and outcomes that are This was partly driven by the changing nature
researched at each of four analytical levels. of the ‘problem of order’. The growth of
Thus, at the workplace or enterprise level, IR workplace militancy, often beyond the control
researchers have focused on workplace rep- of official union representatives, prompted a
resentation, bargaining and dispute-resolution search for the origins of ‘disorder’ and for
and examined outputs such as productivity policy solutions that would more effectively
growth and innovation in working practices regulate workplace relations (for example
and work quality and employee well-being. Maitland, 1983). In addition, however, there
At the meso-level, encompassing studies of was a growing volume of left scholarship
particular industries, occupations or localities, in IR that was attracted to the rank-and-
researchers have examined industry and occu- file challenge and sought both to record and
pational unions, employers’ associations and identify the potential for social change of the
Table 1.1 Levels of industrial relations analysis
Levels Actors Processes Outcomes
Worker Employer State Management Joint decision State Business and Social and
decision regulation performance justice
Workplace and Work groups, shop Supervisory and Inspectorates, HR policies and Workplace and Third party Labor Work quality and
enterprise stewards and general mediators and practices; enterprise level mediation and productivity; employee
works councilors management; labor courts employee bargaining; arbitration innovation and well-being
HR function adjudicating involvement consultation quality
workplace and co- enhancement;
disputes determination financial
performance
Industry, Industry and Employers’ Industry and Public sector Industry-level Training, Diffusion of high Impact of
occupation occupational associations; occupational management; and pattern educational performance privatization
and locality unions; consultancy regulatory state as bargaining and economic practices and
professional firms and labor bodies; ‘model’ development within industry deregulation
associations; living market occupational employer programmes sectors on labor
wage and other intermediaries licensing standards
local coalitions authorities
National Union Peak-level National National systems Economy-wide National systems IR institutions Wage and
economy confederations; business legislature, of corporate bargaining and of labor law and national income
social movements organizations judiciary and governance the and vocational economic inequality;
addressing issues regulatory and their coordination education and performance gender, race
at work bodies impact on of bargaining training; social and other
labor outcomes partnership forms of
management across sectors and social identity-based
pacts inequality
Regional and Global unions and International European Union Diffusion of International Creation and Labor standards Diffusion and
global international union employers’ and other management framework enforcement of and economic effectiveness
federations; associations; supra-state policies within agreements; international development; of global labor
European and multinational institutions; MNEs; international labor varieties of standards
global works enterprises International corporate bargaining and standards capitalism and
councils; NGOs Labour social consultation relative
monitoring labor Organization responsibility within MNEs economic
standards within supply performance
chains
8 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

wave of workplace militancy that erupted at development. In this approach IR forms part of
the end of the 1960s (for example Beynon, a broader comparative political economy that
1984; Herding,1972). A feature of much of seeks to map and explain national sources of
this work was a claim that workplace research comparative advantage.
possessed greater authenticity and generated Another recent trend has been the growth
a deeper insight into the nature of capitalist of international IR research that examines
social relations.As such, it could be contrasted the employment relationship on a regional
with an earlier tradition that focused on formal or global scale. Much of this work is
institutions erected above the workplace motivated by the threat to national systems
level – trade unions, employers’ associations of job regulation posed by globalization and
and industry-wide collective agreements and the increasingly transnational scope of both
disputes procedures. As these institutions product and labor markets. In the developed
were challenged in the 1960s and 1970s world there has been an export of jobs in
so IR research switched focus and explored manufacturing and an erosion of the position
the source of that challenge at the point of of trade unions as previously sheltered
production. markets have been opened to competition.
In the intervening period the focus of The result has been a policy interest in
research has switched again and there has been re-building or extending job regulation at
a revival of work examining formal institu- an international level, which has generated
tions, particularly at national level.As the long academic research in its wake. There has been
post-war boom faltered in the 1970s and as a growth of research on international unionism
mass unemployment re-emerged, so academic (Anner et al., 2006; Gordon and Turner,
attention switched to the forces shaping 2000), international collective bargaining
national economic performance. There was (Lillie, 2006), the policies of multinational
a growth of research on ‘corporatism’ and enterprises, including corporate codes of
the systems of industrial relations in Northern conduct on labor standards (Ferner et al.,
Europe that co-ordinated wage bargaining and 2006; Tsogas, 2001: 61–85), and international
generated relatively low inflation and low regulatory bodies at regional and global
unemployment (Goldthorpe, 1985). Although levels (Marginson and Sisson, 2004; van
interest in corporatism has waned as the Roozendaal, 2002). Like the research on
performance of once successful economies gender equality described above, much of this
has faltered, the focus on national institutions work seeks to assess different ways of dealing
of industrial relations has survived (Baccaro, with the same basic problem – establishing
2003). This is most apparent in the ‘varieties effective international labor standards that
of capitalism’ literature (Hall and Soskice, limit downward pressure on employment
1998) and its attempt to identify different conditions from global competition.
types of national comparative advantage in a The shifting focus of IR research, moving
globalized economy. In this work a distinction from different levels of analysis, as different
is drawn between ‘liberal market economies’, types of ‘labor problem’ come into view,
such as the US, that excel at innovation underlines the nature of IR as an applied,
and the development of new industries, and policy-oriented field (Ackers and Wilkinson,
‘co-ordinated market economies’, such as 2003a: 11; Hyman, 2004: 272). The research
Germany and Japan, that dominate mature agenda for IR scholars has often been set
industries through incremental product and by policy-makers or by the labor movement,
process development. In both types of econ- seeking insight into pressing issues and help
omy, it is suggested, a complex of institutions with institution building or reform. This
embracing the financing and governance of is only one aspect of the field, however,
industry, skill formation and wage bargaining IR research is also driven by an evolving
reinforce one another and, in combination, theoretical impulse and the field contributes
underpin the trajectory of national economic to the application, testing, refinement and
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 9

development of social theory. It is to this different traditions within economics having


aspect of IR that we now turn. influence at different times. According to
Kaufman (1993: 30–5; see also Adams, 1993:
122), a key role was played in the foundation
THEORY AND EXPLANATION of IR by heterodox economists who rejected
the assumptions of neo-classical orthodoxy
IR is commonly described as an academic and favored instead realistic accounts and
field, rather than an academic discipline (for inductive theorizing of the institutions that
example Müller-Jentsch, 2004: 1). It has regulated the labor market. This branch
provided a territory that has been occupied of institutional economics focused on the
by different core disciplines, which have solution of practical ‘labor problems’ and
entered, exerted influence and occasionally was broadly sympathetic to trade unions and
withdrawn to be replaced by rivals. One way other regulatory institutions that tamed both
of telling the theoretical story of IR therefore employer power and market forces. In John
is to track the oscillating contribution of R. Commons, Selig Perlman, John T. Dunlop,
different core disciplines to the field. Indeed, Clerk Kerr and others it provided key figures
in several recent collections the contribution in the founding and development of the field
to the study of the employment relationship of (Kaufman, 1993: 84–91).
economics, psychology, sociology, law, geog- From the 1960s, however, the institutional
raphy and other subjects has been examined tradition lost ground within labor economics
and assessed (Ackers and Wilkinson, 2003b; and neo-classical orthodoxy reasserted itself.
Coyle-Shapiro et al., 2004; Korczynski et al., The focus of labor economics switched from
2006). Many scholars in the field, however, the analysis of labor problems to the analysis
identify themselves as ‘industrial-relationists’ of the labor market with an associated method-
or as employment specialists who have ological turn toward deductive theorizing
long abandoned their home-discipline address and the statistical testing of models using
(Adams, 1993: 128–31). A second way of secondary datasets. The earlier sympathy with
telling IR’s theoretical history, therefore, the regulation of management and market
is to identify the theoretical positions that diminished (Kaufman, 1993: 121–5). It is
IR specialists have developed or made on economics on this conventional model that
their own, regardless of their disciplinary now exerts influence over IR. Particularly in
provenance. This option necessarily takes us the US, IR journals are replete with articles
to the ground of middle-range theory and based on conventional neo-classical assump-
an attempt to categorize the models that IR tions that examine core issues within the
specialists have used to analyze trade unions, field (Kaufman, 2004b: 365; see also Machin,
management strategy, state policy and other 2006; Turnbull, 2003). Inter alia these include
areas of substantive inquiry (for example the economic effects of trade unions, the
Heery, 2003). Neither narrative strategy can impact of minimum wage regulation on
be fully attempted here but at the risk of earnings and employment, the gender pay gap,
over-heroic generalization we examine some the causes of rising income inequality and
of the current disciplinary influences on IR the basis of investment decisions in training
and the main types of explanatory argument and the returns to employers and employees.
developed by its practitioners. In a recent development economists have also
begun to enter territory once occupied by
psychologists, undertaking research on job
Disciplinary influences
satisfaction and the determinants of work
The academic discipline that has exerted quality (for example Clark, 2005; Green and
most influence over IR, at least in the US, Tsitisanis, 2005).
is economics. The relationship of IR to While economics is probably the strongest
economics is a complex one, however, with disciplinary influence in IR it is not the
10 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

only one and aspects of the field continue protest that embrace both the exertion of power
to be shaped by sociology, psychology, against opponents (for example strikes, boycotts,
law, political studies and history. These riots, harassment, media scrutiny) and the use of
non-economics influences are particularly symbols that generate emotional attachment to
apparent outside the US (Frege, 2005: 186–8). the movement among its adherents (for example
street theatre, costumes, songs, graffiti).
Other disciplines continue to be added to
the list. Corporate strategy and other applied
fields based alongside IR in business schools This set of ideas has begun to influence
now exert influence (for example Bacon et al., IR scholars, with a key bridge being sup-
2004; Purcell and Ahlstrand, 1994) while plied by Kelly’s (1998) landmark book on
there has been a recent surge of interest IR theory, Rethinking Industrial Relations:
in social geography and the analysis of the Mobilization, Collectivism and Long Waves.
spatial dimension of employment relations Kelly used what he termed ‘mobilization
(Ellem, 2002; Rainnie et al., 2007; Turnbull, theory’to analyze a broad set of developments
2006). in British industrial relations and others
It is not possible for us to trace these diverse have followed in his wake. The social
influences and show how they have added movement framework has been applied to
to IR theory. What we can do, however, is studies of union organizing, union partic-
demonstrate the continuing shaping of the ipation, employer counter-mobilization and
field by outside disciplines in two particular the changing internal politics of trade unions
areas. The first is the body of theory developed (for example Badigannavar and Kelly, 2004;
by political scientists and sociologists, which Brown Johnson and Jarley, 2004; Foley,
is variously labeled ‘contentious politics’ or 2003; Heery and Conley, 2007). It has been
‘social movement theory’ (McAdam et al., used to revitalize the study of workers’
1996; McAdam et al., 2001; Tarrow, 1998). collective action and to move beyond the
The purpose of this field is to understand and stale opposition between rank-and-file and
account for the origins of social movements, bureaucracy that for so long has underpinned
their development and degree of success in analysis of unions on the radical wing of IR
challenging political elites. Among the core scholarship.
propositions developed by scholars in this The second influence lies in the field
tradition are the following: of ‘political economy’ or ‘socio-economics’.
This is a field developed by a new wave
of institutional economists, political scientists
1) that social movements arise in response to
and economic sociologists that is concerned
a ‘political opportunity structure’, often char-
acterized by a division within the elite that with the institutional ‘embeddedness’ of cap-
reduces state capacity for repression and allows italist economies. Central themes include the
movements to form alliances with alienated elite formation and shaping of markets by state and
politicians; other institutions and the plasticity of the cap-
2) while movements have a spontaneous element italist economy, which assumes a wide variety
and emerge in deeply held grievances they of forms across and within nation states and
rely also on a ‘mobilizing structure’, an orga- which generates highly variable outcomes
nizational framework comprised of ‘movement (Coates, 2005). The Varieties of Capitalism
entrepreneurs’, activists and networks that builds school, described above, is one expression of
collective action amongst supporters;
this literature, which has attracted particular
3) the work of mobilization has a discursive
attention within IR (for example Godard,
component and movement leaders develop
ideological ‘frames’ that legitimate grievances, 2004b). A line of research that has emerged
attribute them to an oppressor and articulate under this influence has focused on the
means of redress; relationship between IR actors, processes and
4) movements often develop distinctive ‘repertoires outcomes and other (varying) institutions of
of contention’; that is forms of mobilization and the capitalist economy, including modes of
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 11

finance, corporate governance and different stages of development in the evolution of


types of business enterprise. The link between capitalist societies with each calling forth a
forms of governance and IR has been a set of matching IR institutions and practices.
particular focus of research (for example The current stage of capitalist development
Armour et al., 2003; Gospel and Pendleton, has been variously labeled, ‘post-industrial’,
2005; Konzelmann et al., 2006). Work of ‘post-Fordist’, ‘neo-Fordist’, ‘the network
this kind updates the classic interest of society’, ‘disorganized capitalism’ and an age
IR scholars in the institutions of the labor of ‘flexible specialization’. Assessments of
market but links it to a broader resurgence of its implications for IR diverge sharply. From
comparative political economy across several one perspective, the diffusion of new high-
social science disciplines. performance practices presents an opportunity
to recast IR on a more co-operative basis
within the ‘mutual gains enterprise’ (Kochan
Explanatory models
and Osterman, 1994). From another, the latest
The other way of looking at IR theory is to stage of capitalist development threatens
identify themes in the substantive, middle- many of the achievements secured by working
range theories scholars use to account for people in the twentieth century and the
IR phenomena. Of course, a colossal amount function of IR is to retard its evolution or
of theory of this kind has been accumulated mitigate its worst effects.Agroup ofAmerican
over the decades. Nevertheless, we feel that writers has argued that the defining feature
this can be sorted into different types of of ‘post-industrialism’ is the emergence of
explanatory model without doing excessive a more market-based system of employment
violence to the diversity of the subject and relations, characterized by the hollowing
below identify four of these. These are: 1) out of large corporations, sub-contracting,
societal models that account for IR devel- the erosion of internal labor markets, the
opments in terms of adaptation to long-run growth of contingent labor, de-unionization,
social and economic change; 2) institutional rising income inequality and the collapse of
models that offer explanations grounded in employment standards (for example Cobble,
the structural characteristics of the IR system 1991; Fine, 2006; Milkman, 2006).3 Faced
itself or the broader configuration of the with this challenge, it is believed there is
national political economy; 3) organizational a need to develop new institutions to re-
models that explain the behavior (strategy) regulate the labor market and take wages
of IR actors in terms of their organizational out of competition. Accordingly, researchers
characteristics (structure); and 4) agency have examined emerging practices, such as
models that develop typologies of IR strategy living wage ordinances, community-based
and explore the identities of agents who movements of low-wage workers and labor-
promote them (see Heery et al., 2004). market organizing by trade unions, seeking
to identify their potential to diffuse and
contribute to a broader regulation of the new
Societal
economy.
There is a long tradition in IR of explaining the
behavior of actors and shifting processes and
Institutional
outcomes as an adaptation to long-run change
in economy and society. Causal variables A second form of explanation stresses the
identified in this tradition range from technical role of institutional structures in shaping the
change, the globalization of product markets behavior of IR actors and the outcomes of
and the feminization of the workforce to less IR processes. A classic statement of this
tangible developments such as the emergence argument was Clegg’s (1976) comparative
of a more reflexive, individualistic population. analysis of trade unions, which claimed that
It is also common to identify discrete forms of union organization and patterns
12 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of activity, including internal democracy and their patterns of behavior and effects.
and involvement in industrial conflict, were A classic illustration can be seen in the long-
determined primarily by the structure of standing interest in the relationship between
collective bargaining. Contemporary analysts trade union democracy (and trade union
of trade unions continue to make this type oligarchy) and forms of union activity and
of argument, the best known example of effectiveness. Concern with this relationship
which is Fairbrother’s (1996) union renewal continues to feature strongly in research on
thesis with its claim that the decentralization trade unions. An example can be seen in
of bargaining can prompt the revitalization the examination of the link between union
of workplace unionism. Another example attempts to promote the interests of women
can be seen in comparative research on the and minorities – believed by many to be a
gender pay gap, which indicates that progress precondition for union revitalization – and
in narrowing the gap between female and the reform of union governance structures to
male earnings is a function of industry- allow for gender democracy and the clearer
wide pay bargaining and relatively strong expression of minority interests. There is a
minimum wage regulations (Almond and growing body of research on this linkage with
Rubery, 1998). These examples focus on different positions being adopted. In some
the relationship between the structure of contributions new democratic institutions
IR processes and patterns of actor behavior within unions, such as women’s committees
and outcomes. Other theoretical explanations and self-organized groups, remain marginal-
focus on institutional structures beyond IR ized and exert little influence over union
narrowly conceived. This is a feature of both bargaining and political activity (McBride,
of the new disciplinary influences outlined 2001). In others their effectiveness in pushing
above. Those influenced by social movement significant changes in union policy, which
theory, for instance, emphasize the role of in turn have fed through into legal change
broader political structures – the political and new collective agreements, is accepted
opportunity structure – in channeling union (Heery and Conley, 2007). The same type
behavior (Turnbull, 2006); those influenced of analysis, linking organizational charac-
by the Varieties of Capitalism school identify teristics to patterns of action, can be seen
a causal link between union strategies and in research on IR actors besides unions.
the institutional constraints imposed respec- Thus, in research on management there is an
tively by liberal- and co-ordinated-market interest in the influence of business structure
economies (Frege and Kelly, 2004: 37–9). and internal planning and control procedures
As these examples indicate, institutional mod- on the content of IR policies. The trend
els are frequently comparative, identifying toward the decentralization of collective bar-
differences in actor behavior and outcomes gaining in large, multi-divisional enterprises
across national boundaries and explaining has been explained by the spread of new
these in terms of distinctive national, insti- financial controls over operating divisions, in
tutional contexts. Unlike societal models, which corporate office monitors performance
which stress broad, underlying causes that through financial ratios while conceding
are universal in their effects (at least across autonomy over operational matters, including
developed societies), institutional models pay determination, to business unit managers
stress contingency and (particularly cross- (Purcell and Ahlstrand, 1994: 75–7). Another
national) variation. example can be seen in the theory of
corporatism, where it has long been argued
that the capacity of states to develop effective
Organizational
tripartite regulation of the economy depends
In the third type of model the central on the presence of strong, centralized and
interest lies in the causal relationship between encompassing peak organizations of business
the organizational structure of IR actors and labor (Baccaro, 2003). Whichever actor is
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 13

considered, however, the common feature of and ‘the black hole’ (non-union with poor HR
this type of model remains the same; patterns practice).
of activity and their effects within the IR The second avenue leads to an examina-
system are dependent on a particular form of tion of choice-makers and choice-making.
organization being adopted – strategy flows Explanation here is directed both at the
from structure. identities of those leading organizations and
deciding strategy and at the internal political
and discursive practices that lead to the
Agency
selection and legitimization of a particular
The final type of model departs from the strategic choice. The focus on choice-makers
structural argument common to the other is most readily apparent in research on trade
three and is voluntarist in its assumptions, unions, where there is a wealth of material that
holding that IR actors have scope for strategic explains patterns of union activity in terms of
choice (Kochan et al., 1986: 3–20). Choice the gender, generation or ideological stamp
is exercised within constraints but is not of union leaders and activists (see Heery,
reducible to an external and structured 2003: 290–5). There has been a particular
context. For adherents of this position, indeed, emphasis on gender, with the feminization
strategic choices themselves shape organi- of union policy and the recreation of union
zational and wider institutional structures. democratic and management structures to
Theory development within this strategic better represent diversity, being seen as depen-
choice tradition has followed two broad dent on the prior mobilization of feminist
avenues. The first has led to the elaboration activists within unions (Ledwith and Colgan,
of typologies of strategy; a listing of the 2002). Equivalent work on the employer side
options available to strategic actors. There are is perhaps less developed though analogous
many, many examples developed for all of explanations can be found. They exist, for
the main IR actors. Thus, Boxall and Haynes instance, in attempts to explain company
(1997) commenting on the renewal strategies cultures in terms of the imprint of charis-
of New Zealand trade unions identify two matic founding fathers or mothers, whether
underpinning, dimensions of choice. Unions Victorian Quakers or New Age entrepreneurs,
can adopt an adversarial or co-operative like Anita Roddick of Body Shop, contriving a
stance toward employers and an organizing deliberate informality and seeking employee
or servicing approach to members. From commitment to ethical standards (Purcell
this starting point a menu of four strategic and Sisson, 1983: 116–7). They can also
options can be identified: ‘classic unionism’ be seen in attempts to explain variation in
(adversarialism plus organizing); ‘partner- HRM within multi-nationals through a parent-
ship unionism’ (cooperation plus organizing); country effect; that HR is shaped by the
‘paper-tiger unionism’ (adversarialism plus transfer of a distinctive corporate identity
servicing) and ‘consultancy unionism’ (coop- from one national culture to another (Gunnigle
eration plus servicing). A well-known equiv- et al., 2006).
alent for employers is Guest and Conway’s Theories that focus on choice-making
(1999) typology of management strategy that allocate a central part to the (frequently
rests on the extent to which unions are conflictual) social processes through which
accepted and recognized and the degree to strategic choices are made. In a study of the
which managers follow a sophisticated, high emergence of social pacts in Ireland, Italy
commitment approach to HRM. Once again and South Korea, for example, Baccaro and
four options are identified: ‘the new realism’ Lim (2007) noted that the outcome of a
(sophisticated HRM plus union recognition); fierce dispute between moderates and more
‘traditional collectivism’ (union recognition radical elements in the labor movement was
with traditional HR practices); ‘individualized a crucial stage in each process. Decisive
HRM’ (non-union with sophisticated HRM) victories for the moderate, partnership wing
14 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

ensured the development of pacts in Ireland development within IR theory. Again, we can
and Italy, while a radical victory in South provide a single illustrative case. Baccaro and
Korea led to the pact’s instability. There Lim’s (2007) full explanatory model for the
are numerous other examples. To take one, emergence of social pacts combines different
Ledwith and Colgan (2002: 16–18) identify a types of explanation. The search for a pact
key stage of ‘usurpation’ in the feminization typically originates in a broad economic and
of unions, through which new activists social crisis, reflects a particular institutional
challenge and overcome the resistance of context defined by a weak government that
the incumbent, male-dominated elite. There needs allies to develop a response to crisis, and
is also an element in this body of work depends on a strategic choice to co-operate
that emphasizes discursive practice and the within the labor movement which, in turn,
deployment of legitimizing frames for new is the outcome of a choice-making conflict
strategic choices. Thus, Heery and Conley’s between moderates and radicals. The latter
(2007) study of union policy on part-time also has an organizational dimension and
work in the UK, stresses the significance of Baccaro and Lim (2007) emphasize the impor-
distinct ‘instrumental’ and ‘solidarity’ frames tance of balloting procedures in both Ireland
in garnering support for new policy and and Italy in registering union-member support
rendering opposition non-legitimate. for social pacts and isolating the opposition.
The four types of explanation we have Finally, social pacts become institutionalized
identified are in certain respects competing. if there is a subsequent buy-in by employers,
They offer different accounts of IR phenom- which depends on the authority of employ-
ena and many empirical studies in IR seek ers’ confederations (organizational), political
to weigh the explanatory power of different opportunities to shape pacts (institutional) and
structural explanations – societal, institutional calculations of strategic advantage amongst
and organizational – or the relative strength different employer groups (strategic choice).
of structural and strategic choice perspectives. The supporting conditions, Baccaro and Lim
An example of this type of contest can be seen (2007) note, were fully in place only in Ireland
in the different explanations put forward of a and it is in this single case that the social
widespread IR trend, the decentralization of pact has been institutionalized and become an
collective bargaining to enterprise and work- enduring feature of the IR system – in the other
place levels. On the one hand, this has been two cases the experiment faltered albeit after a
explained, as we have seen, as an artifact of period of success in Italy.4 The essential point,
the diffusion of new financial control systems however, is that a complex, abstract model,
within the management hierarchies of multi- combining different types of explanation, has
divisional firms – an organizational account. been devised to account for a significant IR
On the other hand, it has been explained development.
as an adjustment within IR to the diffusion
of more flexible forms of production that
require tailor-made, plant-specific systems of NORMATIVE ORIENTATION
job regulation – a societal account (Katz,
1993). If pushed to their extreme, neither The dominant normative orientation amongst
of these explanations can accommodate the IR scholars is one of pluralism. This ‘frame
other and much routine academic work of reference’ comprises core beliefs about
within IR involves assembling evidence to the nature of the employment relationship,
choose between seemingly equally plausible which provide a standard for evaluating IR
explanatory models. practice and serve as a guide to developing
If extremes are avoided, however, then policy advice, an essential component of an
the different types of explanation can be applied field. At the heart of the pluralist
combined; assembled in a complex, multi- position is a conviction that the employment
factor model. This is also a common relationship embraces two equally legitimate
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 15

sets of interests, those of employers and considerable body of IR research is critical


those of employees. It is further believed of employers and their practices, identify-
that, while these interests are congruent in ing unethical, exploitative, oppressive and
very large degree, there is an irreducible core inefficient aspects of management practice,
of conflict. A preparedness to acknowledge particularly in a context of light regulation
conflicting interests at work and accept that or non-unionism. Sisson’s (1993: 207) judge-
the expression of conflict is not a pathological ment on the non-union workplace in Britain
symptom has been held to be a defining feature as something of a ‘bleak house’ is indicative
of IR (Kochan, 1998: 37–9). A third core of a much wider orientation amongst IR
belief of pluralists is that there is an imbalance scholars.5 There is little faith in employers’
of power within the employment relationship capacity to manage the employment system
and that the dependence of workers on for the benefit of multiple stakeholders and
employers for the means of subsistence places IR commentators frequently identify market
them in a vulnerable position. A fourth failures that arise from employers pursuing
belief follows; that workers have the right sectional or short-term interests. Partly for this
to combine in trade unions and other types reason there is broad acceptance of the need
of collectivity in order to accumulate power, for intervention in both the market order and
provide a counterweight to the otherwise the order of management control within firms.
dominant position of the employer and pursue IR pluralists have a bias toward regulation
their separate, legitimate interests (Budd, of employer behavior through law but also
2004: 26). The final component of the through collective representation of workers
pluralist position is a conviction that collective and the joint regulation of the employment
organization by employees and the creation of relationship.
a pluralist IR system based on trade unionism, The classic policy position adopted by
collective bargaining and the regulation of IR pluralists, therefore, has been support
conflict serves not only the interests of for collective bargaining and the associated
employees but can also serve a wider, general auxiliary legislation that can underpin it
or public interest. The classic expression (Ackers, 2007). The main qualification to
of this belief in the twentieth century was this position has occurred when pluralists
the claim that the IR system was functional have identified a tension between collective
for the wider society, addressing the ‘labor organization and a putative general interest;
problem’ and successfully integrating the a tension that was particularly apparent in
working population into liberal democratic the long period of full-employment and
societies (Budd, 2004: 4). relatively strong trade unionism after the
Several features of IR flow from this Second World War. Pluralists have accepted
pluralist conception of the employment rela- constraints on collective action by employees
tionship. One is that the research agenda has to minimize general economic costs (for
often focused on the experiences, concerns example restricting collective bargaining to
and needs of workers and their institutions reduce inflationary wage pressure) or preserve
and has not slavishly reflected the interests state functions and sovereignty (for exam-
of employers. This aspect of IR, moreover, ple restricting strikes in essential services).
has persisted despite the fact that most of Indeed, much policy ink has been spilt
the field’s members now work in business designing IR systems that retain collective
schools. Research on the quality of work organization by employees while reducing
experienced by individual employees (for dysfunctional effects for the wider society.
example Barley and Kunda, 2004; Green, For much of the second half of the twentieth
2006) or exploring the revitalization strategies century IR pluralists were quintessential
of unions (for example Wheeler, 2002) is reformists, seeking to update and eliminate the
testament to the continuing vitality of the flaws from established IR institutions founded
pluralist tradition. Another feature is that a on collective bargaining.
16 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

points of challenge to capital beyond the


Challenge and critique
established institutions of IR. The policy
While pluralism has been the dominant prescription for Marxists is typically one
orientation, it has not gone unchallenged. This of militancy and support for rank-and-file
challenge has been threefold and has come movements that promise the renewal of trade
from Marxism, feminism and neo-liberalism. unionism from below (Darlington, 1994;
In each case, it should be noted, the critique Fairbrother, 2000). The challenge to pluralist
has been fundamental in that it has targeted IR from Marxists has diminished somewhat
the core beliefs of IR pluralists and offered a as Marxism has lost influence generally in
different interpretation of interests within the the social sciences since the 1980s. The
employment relationship. The main elements division between pluralists and Marxists is
of this three-headed critique are as follows. still an active front, however, and continues
to structure debate in IR. It is a particularly
Marxism notable feature of the field in Britain with
Marxism shares pluralism’s focus on the pluralists and Marxists offering competing
dyadic relationship between employers and interpretations of contemporary phenomena,
employees and a belief that interests are such as the vogue for labor-management
separate and conflicting, but it differs in one partnership agreements (cf. Samuel, 2005;
fundamental aspect. For Marxists there is Tailby et al., 2004) or the record of the Labour
only one set of legitimate interests, those Government elected in 1997 (cf. Brown, 2000;
of workers. Thus, in Kelly’s (1998: 4–15) Smith and Morton, 2006).
attempt to recast the field of IR around
mobilization theory the starting point are Feminism
the interests of workers, with main themes The distinctive feature of the feminist critique
being the accumulation of power resources is that it has not accepted the dyadic rela-
by workers and the strategies of counter- tionship between employer and employee as a
mobilization adopted by state and employers satisfactory basis for the subject. In particular,
in response. The other distinctive feature of it is argued that a focus on the gender-neutral
the Marxist normative position is a belief category of ‘worker’ obscures the fact that
that workers’ fundamental interest lies in the employment relationship is profoundly
challenging and overturning the capitalist gendered and that the experiences of men
mode of production. Two orientations flow and women employees are divergent and
from this belief. On the one hand, there their interests often conflicting.6 Accordingly,
is criticism of institutions that stabilize the the separate and gendered interests of male
economic order and integrate the working and female workers must be acknowledged
population into society. Unlike pluralists, and incorporated within the core research and
Marxists do not believe that a ‘balance is normative concerns of IR scholars. However,
best’ (Budd et al., 2004) and are typically feminist commentators have also problema-
highly critical of the regulatory institutions tized the category of ‘women’ and noted that
of capitalist societies that channel industrial ‘multiple “women” exist’ (Pocock, 1997a: 3),
conflict into compromise solutions while as a consequence of the ‘intersectionality’
leaving the broader configuration of the of gender and other forms of social identity
economy unchanged (Hyman, 1975). Thus, (Holgate et al., 2006: 310). A critique that
since Lenin, Marxists have sharply crit- started with a call to acknowledge distinct
icized trade unionism, recognizing it as gender interests, therefore, has progressed
an expression of worker rebellion against to encompass diversity of interests based in
capital but decrying its limited goals. On multiple identities: race, ethnicity, faith, age,
the other hand, there is a celebration of disability and sexuality.7 All of these must
industrial conflict (Darlington and Lyddon, now receive their due recognition within IR
2001) and a continual searching for new scholarship.
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 17

An extensive research agenda has devel- the superficial character of policies to deal
oped from this attempt to reorient the subject with it. Nevertheless, a body of work has
toward gender and minority interests. One been accumulated that can inform evidence-
course has been to map and seek explanations based policy-making. This work points to
of patterns of inequality at work. In many the conditions under which employment law,
cases this has focused on the strategies used by collective bargaining and management policy
men to maintain the subordination of women; are more or less likely to contribute to
whether male workers seeking to monopolize the narrowing of workplace inequality (for
skilled trades, male-dominated unions pri- example Grimshaw and Rubery, 2001).
oritizing a traditional bargaining agenda or A characteristic that feminist IR scholars
male employers designing low-skilled, part- share with the pluralist mainstream is a
time jobs for women workers (for example belief in the need for law and collec-
Beechey and Perkins, 1987; Cockburn, 1983; tive bargaining to shape the behavior of
Colling and Dickens, 1989). A second course employers. There is often a deep skepticism
has been to broaden the subject matter of IR in about the potential for employer policy
two distinct ways. On the one hand, feminist to secure significant advancement toward
researchers have noted that the gendered equality, which is expressed in a critique of
employment contracts of men and women the ‘business case’ for equal opportunities
reflect a prior ‘sexual contract’ and rest on an and the ‘diversity management’ programs
unequal domestic division of labor (Wacjman, to which it gives rise (Kirton and Green,
2000: 193–5). This has encouraged work on 2000). Effective external regulation (and
the interrelationship of the domestic sphere the mobilization of women and minority
and forms and experiences of paid work, a groups themselves against employers), are
theme that has been given added impetus by deemed necessary because business pressures
public policy interest in the issue of work- to eliminate inequality will only be felt by
life integration. On the other hand, there has a proportion of employers. The ugly fact
been a drive to examine questions of sexuality motivating much feminist comment on IR
and emotion at work that has encompassed policy is that many employers gain from
research on the design of jobs to incorporate unequal treatment and consequently cannot
emotional and sexual display and the issue be relied upon to act as agents for social
of sexual harassment (Forrest, 1993: 424; justice. Partly for this reason the main feminist
Wacjman, 2000: 192–3). orientation to policy stresses the continual
A third theme in feminist IR research strengthening of legal regulation in particular
has been to uncover women’s resistance to to make it more exacting from the employers’
oppression at work; to rediscover events, perspective. An international manifestation
actors and movements that have been ‘hidden of this orientation is the pressure to rewrite
from history’ and neglected systematically equality law so that it not only confers rights
by a male-dominated field (Forrest, 1993: not to suffer discrimination but imposes a
416). This concern has generated a substantial positive duty on employers to provide for
volume of work on women’s trade unionism, equality at work (McColgan, 1994).
which has emerged as a major theme in Feminist commentators differ in their
IR research in recent years (for example evaluation of trade unions but there is a
Briskin and McDermott, 1993; Cobble, 1993; strong current of belief that ‘social regulation’
Colgan and Ledwith, 2002; Pocock, 1997b). through unions and collective bargaining can
A fourth main area of research identified supplement law and indeed ensure that it
by feminist IR scholars is the evaluation is more effectively ‘mediated’ at workplace
of equality and diversity policies developed level (Dickens, 1999). The policy advocated
by states, unions and employers. Much of for unions is twofold. On the one hand, it
this work is highly critical, pointing to the is suggested that there must be more effec-
persistence of gender inequality at work and tive ‘external’ representation of women and
18 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

minorities by unions through the development subject and tried to erase the lines that
of ‘equality bargaining’(Colling and Dickens, separate IR from adjacent fields of (gendered)
1989); that is through the incorporation social life.
of issues of discrimination, equality and
diversity into the routine representative work Neo-liberalism
of unions. On the other hand, it is argued that The third challenge to pluralist orthodoxy has
there must be more effective ‘internal’ repre- come from the neo-liberal right and although
sentation of women and minorities through the its proponents constitute only a tiny minority
reform of union government systems to ensure of IR scholars the ideas they expound reflect
that their interests gain expression. Each type major themes in recent public policy in the
of reform can reinforce the other and both US, Britain, Australia, New Zealand and other
are deemed essential (Bercusson and Dickens, countries. In certain respects this normative
1996). orientation is the mirror image of Marxism,
Calls for legal and union-based regulation choosing to privilege the interests of employ-
have to do with the means to ends – how the ers rather than labor. This is not fully the case,
cause of equality can be advanced. Feminist however. Neo-liberals accept that employees
IR scholars have also written extensively have legitimate interests that they inevitably
on the objectives of policy. Several themes will pursue but suggest that inefficiencies will
stand out from this work. Perhaps the result and the interests of consumers suffer,
most fundamental is the need for policy to if they are not restrained by a combination
extend beyond mere equality of opportunity of competitive markets and management
and secure equality of outcome, if needs hierarchy. Competition and control, from this
be through positive/reverse discrimination. perspective, are the necessary disciplines that
Asecond theme derives from the identification must keep ‘producer’ interests in check. It
of the separate and distinct interests of women follows that, regulatory institutions which
and minorities, the corollary of which is the inhibit competition or which restrict the
need to tailor work and employment systems operation of management hierarchies are
and surrounding regulations to accommodate inevitably viewed with suspicion, if not
this diversity (for example Baird, 2006). hostility. The actions of the state in regulating
While feminists have developed a critique of the labor market and of trade unions in
‘diversity management’, there is nevertheless raising wages and challenging management
a common policy emphasis on difference prerogative have been particular targets. The
and the need to develop flexible systems of same institutions that are seen to offer
employment that accommodate the distinct solutions to labor market problems in pluralist
interests of women and minorities(Dickens, analysis are viewed as the source of problems
2005: 201–3).8 A third theme extends beyond by neo-liberals.
the world of work and targets the domes- Following Hirschman (1991), we can
tic sphere through policies that socialize identify the main types of argument that
childcare and either encourage or require neo-liberals have mounted against plural-
men to assume a greater domestic workload ist industrial relations. One response has
(for example through state paternity and been to question the severity of the social
family leave policies). As the origins of problems that are the target of regula-
workplace inequality have been located in a tory intervention by pluralists. Thus, it has
broader ‘sexual contract’, so IR policy has been suggested that there is less need for
leaned toward social and family policy and unions to redress the power imbalance in
sought to reconstruct domestic as well as the employment relationship when second
workplace relations. This, in turn, reflects jobs, self-employment and the ownership
an abiding theme of feminist IR scholarship; of shares and other private property render
in both its analysis and in its normative workers less dependent on wages earned
stance it has extended the scope of the from a single employer (Hanson and Mather,
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 19

1988: 36). An equivalent argument made is the case in the UK required to implement
against minimum wage legislation is to point European social policy directives, there is a
to the fact that many low-wage workers preference for ‘soft law’ or other, relatively
live in multi-income households and so are weak forms of regulation. Employment legis-
not solely dependent on their own income. lation is continually weighed in the balance to
A second response, labeled the ‘futility thesis’ identify potential costs and dysfunctional con-
by Hirschman (1991), questions the capacity sequences. An even closer scrutiny has been
of regulation to moderate market outcomes, directed at regulation stemming from trade
at least in the longer term. Examples of the unions and collective bargaining (Minford,
futility thesis include the claim that minimum 1985) and the weakening of union capacity
wage laws simply displace employment into to regulate labor markets has been a notable
the informal sector or Troy’s (1999: 24) feature of jurisdictions where neo-liberalism
argument that union pattern-bargaining can has shaped public policy. The long catalogue
never truly ‘take wages out of competition’ of anti-union reform in Britain under Margaret
and simply displaces employment into the Thatcher in the 1980s or the more recent Work
non-union economy. A third response, the Choices policy of John Howard’s government
‘perversity thesis’, states that regulation in Australia, provide examples. For some neo-
rebounds against the very group it is intended liberal commentators the only legitimate role
to help, in most versions of the argument for trade unions is in providing labor market
by destroying the jobs of unionized workers services to their members; that is in helping
or those protected by legal regulation. To the labor market to operate more efficiently
quote from Troy (2004: 70), ‘…high Franco- through the provision of skills and information
German unemployment, lower productivity, (Roberts, 1987; Shenfield 1986).
downsizing, and the export of production to If deregulation is the negative side of neo-
other countries…can be traced to an important liberal prescription for industrial relations,
extent, to the works councils (and unionism) what is the positive element? Perhaps the
that [pluralists] extol and urge [the USA] to clearest neo-liberal agenda for reconstruct-
impose on its own workplaces’. The final ing work relations focuses on the use of
argument, the ‘jeopardy thesis’, submits that financial incentives to alleviate principal-
regulation destroys other desirable states, agent problems and re-align the interests
such as national competitiveness. To quote of shareholders, managers and employees.
once more from Troy (2004: 72) the effect Thus, one of the reasons Troy inveighs
of strong trade unions in the American against the actions of educational unions
school system is to raise the costs of edu- in the US is because of their opposition
cation and impose ‘externalities’, including to incentive and merit pay. Many neo-
‘uneducated children who are ill-equipped liberals have a particular enthusiasm for
to compete in America’s labor markets…’ profit-sharing and employee share-ownership
For Troy, as for many neo-liberals, the (for example Bell and Hanson, 1987) and
effect of unionism is to create low quality the diffusion of neo-liberal ideas has been
and inefficiency by imposing work rules accompanied by an international trend to
on managers that elevate producer interests promote worker shareholding through tax
above those of the consumers of goods and incentives and other policy instruments (see
services. Vaughan-Whitehead, 1995). The objective of
The prescription which flows from this re-aligning worker and employer interests
analysis is for the deregulation of industrial was cogently expressed by the late President
relations. Neo-liberals routinely call for the Reagan, ‘Could there be a better answer to
withdrawal or weakening of legislation that the stupidity of Karl Marx than millions of
interferes with market forces or inhibits the workers individually sharing in the means of
capacity of managers to respond to market production?’ (quoted in Bradley and Gelb,
signals. Where regulation is unavoidable, as 1986: 22).
20 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

been greater recognition of gender and the


Pluralist responses
issue of equality in textbooks and research
Notwithstanding the challenge from Marx- literature (Healy et al., 2006). IR may still
ism, feminism and neo-liberalism, pluralism lag behind other fields of social inquiry
remains the dominant normative orientation in drawing from feminist theory and the
within academic IR. The mainstream has accommodation may be limited (and largely
stretched to accommodate aspects of each ignore the gendered experience of men) but
critique, however, and many recent develop- a shift has occurred. There remains a line
ments in the field have emerged from the of division, however, that has recently been
tension between pluralism and its opponents. sketched by Edwards (2003: 28–30). He
The classic pluralist response to the Marxist makes two key points. The first is that the
challenge has been to point to the effective- field of IR will lose its coherence if it extends
ness of IR reform in civilizing the market too far beyond the employment relationship
order, both in a material sense of raising to embrace the domestic sphere and the
workers’ living standards and in a procedural wider cultural expression of gender relations.
sense of protecting workers from arbitrary Edwards likens the walls of the workplace to
treatment and importing due process into a ‘semi-permeable membrane’, which ‘filters
the employment relationship. Thus, Flanders influences from outside and also shapes
(1970) defending UK unions in the 1960s how processes within the workplace affect
from the Marxist charge of economism, relations elsewhere’. Clearly relations at work
declared that, ‘by doggedly sticking to their are shaped by forces beyond, including the
immediate ends and refusing to be captured sexual division of labor within the home, but
and exploited by any political party, they have they are not reducible to them and for this
gradually transformed society’. This search reason the proper focus of IR scholarship
for evidence of reform, and for the capacity should remain the employment relationship.
of capitalist economies to undergo significant The second point is that the extent to
reform, continues within the pluralist tradi- which institutions involved in regulating the
tion. Its clearest contemporary expression can workplace are gendered is a matter of degree
be seen in the attraction of many IR scholars and to be established by empirical research.
to the Varieties of Capitalism literature. Edwards is at pains to concede that the use
Particularly for IR pluralists in Anglophone of gender-neutral categories by IR academics
countries, evidence of sustainable alternative has often shielded important features of
forms of capitalism, which are more receptive working life from inquiry, but holds that
to the interests of workers or which foster their use may be legitimate in particular
less adversarial relations between managers circumstances. A related theme has recently
and employees, is deeply appealing (for appeared in empirical work asking if gender
example Adams, 1995). In recent years the is of ‘declining significance’; that is, if sex
labor market institutions of ‘coordinated differences are becoming less apparent in the
market economies’ have served as a menu distribution of earnings and other indicators
for Anglophone IR reformists, a new set of workers’ experiences (Blau et al., 2006).
of recipes for civilizing capitalism. German If many pluralists have wanted to accom-
works councils, in particular, have been modate a feminist perspective, the typical
identified as an institution that can provide response to neo-liberalism has been defensive,
a model for reform, helping to create ‘the striving to rebut elements of the neo-liberal
mutual gains enterprise’ in the USA and attack. One important service discharged by
other ‘liberal market economies’ (Kochan and pluralist IR researchers has been to disprove
Osterman, 1994: 204–207).9 the wilder claims of free marketers that protec-
The response to feminism has been more tive regulation of the labor market generates
accommodating and, as some feminist critics perverse and other effects. For example, a
of mainstream IR acknowledge, there has series of careful studies of the UK’s cautious
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 21

experiment with minimum wage regulation studying contemporary industrial relations.


in recent years have shown little evidence of In Chapter 2, Carola M. Frege considers
significant job losses (Dickens and Manning, the historical development of industrial rela-
2003). A more offensive position has been tions research, examining to what extent
to develop ‘business case’ arguments in the approach and focus of that research
support of the regulatory institutions favored reflects particular national conditions. She
by pluralists. One of the earliest and best highlights significant variation in the influ-
known examples of this type of argument ence of particular disciplines in different
was Freeman and Medoff’s (1984: 162–80) countries (most notably the relative strengths
defense of US trade unionism, particularly of economic vs. sociological approaches
on the grounds that it stimulated higher to industrial relations) and the continuing
productivity. Since then other researchers influence of different academic structures,
have trod the same path, using empirical data epistemological traditions and political dis-
to make a positive case for trade unionism courses on the ways in which industrial
and employment law (for example Turnbull relations research is pursued. The theme of
et al., 2004). At a theoretical level pluralists the relationship of industrial relations to social
have also developed the concept of ‘beneficial science disciplines is developed further by
constraints’, as a counterweight to the neo- Peter Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson in Chapter
liberal predilection for perversity (Streeck, 3. They argue the case for a renewed dialogue
1997). Institutions that inhibit the market not only with economics, politics, sociology
or management decision, it is suggested, and history, but also with psychology, law and
promote long-term efficiency by shutting geography. A key contribution of industrial
off the low-road to cost-minimization and relations to this dialogue is seen to be
encouraging managers to forge long-term, an institutional analysis of the employment
co-operative relations with employees. The relationship that incorporates much more than
final and most ambitious pluralist response trade unionism and collective bargaining.
has been not to accept but to transcend the In Chapter 4, Edmund Heery considers
standards of evaluation employed by neo- different theoretical approaches to indus-
liberals. There has been a turn to ethical trial relations. He contrasts ‘cross-sectional’
reasoning and the revival of social justice models that specify the different elements
arguments as a basis for labor market comprising the industrial relations field, their
regulation, independently of economic effects interrelationships and outcomes, with other
(Budd, 2004). While many pluralists have models that focus more on types and rates
fought neo-liberals on their own ground, there of change occurring over time. Given evident
is a growing trend to reach beyond their shortcomings in the former approach, which
Gradgrind values to mount the case for decent has dominated the field in the past (mainly
conditions for working men and women. in the form of systems theory), Heery
identifies the need for an approach that
incorporates a sophisticated model of change,
THE STRUCTURE OF THE HANDBOOK combining elements of the different models
of change he outlines. In Chapter 5, John
The themes, developments and issues outlined Budd and Devasheesh Bhave explore the
above are reflected in the chapters that different underlying values, ideologies and
follow. In the first part, the contributors frames of reference held by those studying and
provide an overview of the theoretical and practicing industrial relations. They view the
ideological underpinnings of the field, its different frames of reference existing within
interconnections with other disciplines, links the field as both a weakness and strength of the
with developments taking place both within subject: a weakness when it leads to different
and outside the work organization and the groups ‘talking past each other’ and a strength
questions these raise for optimum ways of when it helps to interpret the complexity of the
22 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

world of work. For the latter to thrive however, the diffusion of human resource practices, or
Budd and Bhave emphasize the need for a more generally how management actions have
clearer exposure of the values and ideologies ‘effects’ on practice and performance.
within industrial relations discourse. In the final chapter in Part One, George
In Chapter 6, William Brown draws on Strauss and Keith Whitfield discuss recent
three decades of research into pay setting trends in research approaches by industrial
to examine the central influence of product relations scholars. Analyses of journal con-
market conditions on industrial relations. He tents are used to gauge the extent of change
explores the relationship between greater in industrial relations research: the trend
competition and increased unwillingness on toward more deductive and less inductive
the part of employers to reach the sort of approaches, for example and the growing use
agreements with unions that were widespread of large data sets and multivariate statistical
in the past. In the light of this, Brown notes methods. To avoid the danger of becoming too
the growing importance of other means for detached from the people and contexts they
workers to seek influence, including working are purporting to study, Strauss and Whitfield
to secure more state support for employment discuss the potential for designing studies that
standards and gaining consumer backing for benefit from both qualitative and quantitative
fair labor conditions. approaches.
In Chapter 7, Kerstin Hamman and John Part Two focuses on developments among
Kelly broaden the theme of influences on the different actors engaged in industrial
industrial relations systems by considering the relations, considering not only the ‘usual
links between different models of capitalism suspects’ of employers and management,
(focusing particularly on the Varieties of trade unions and national state institutions, but
Capitalism typology) and the characteristics also other relevant actors such as transnational
and trajectories of different national systems institutions, works councils and a range of
of industrial relations. While their analysis other actors whose activities have a bearing on
points to a number of identifiable clusters industrial relations processes and outcomes.
of industrial relations systems, they demon- In the first of two chapters on trade unions,
strate the inability of simple dichotomous Jack Fiorito and Paul Jarley consider in
classifications – such as between liberal Chapter 10 the main developments in union
market economies and co-ordinated market structure, including trends toward general
economies – adequately to categorize patterns unionism and how union governance and
and developments in industrial relations. administrative structures relate to outcomes.
Hamman and Kelly argue that systematic Implications of ‘organizing model’and ‘social
comparisons of industrial relations systems network’ conceptions of unions are also
need a greater sensitivity to, for example, the considered. In noting the difficulties facing
particular roles of national states, political many individual unions and national trade
parties and different welfare systems than union movements, Fiorito and Jarley advocate
is represented by the broad Varieties of greater investigation both of the relationship
Capitalism categories. between union structure and practice and the
In Chapter 8, Stephen Procter shortens relationship between local and national union
the horizon of analysis to consider changes structures and outcomes, together with a more
occurring within the workplace. This is one thorough evaluation of the consequences of
of a number of contributions in the volume different union choices. This latter aspect
that draw on current debates regarding human is considered in detail by Peter Boxall
resource practices and firm performance. In in Chapter 11, in which he examines the
exploring what is known (and less known) in strategic choices facing trade unions in the
this area, Procter argues that the employment difficult environments many now confront.
relationship has yet to be fully considered Drawing on the notion of organizational life
in questions such as the factors influencing cycles, Boxall argues the inappropriateness
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 23

of universal union renewal strategies, such industrial relations, each representing a dif-
as ‘organizing’ or ‘servicing’ strategies. He ferent balance of priorities in the weight
contends that different types of worker, facing attached to pursuing economic efficiency,
diverse conditions and working for employers social stability and the rights and standards
who have varying responses to trade union accorded to its citizens.
representation, require union revitalization In Chapter 15 Simon Deakin and Wanjiru
strategies that are capable of responding to Njoya reassess the position of labor law within
these different conditions. broader industrial relations inquiry. Drawing
In Chapter 12, Franz Traxler examines on the examples of several countries, they
the relevance of the changing structure of trace the development of labor law and the
employer organizations for the conduct of different interests and wide range of objec-
industrial relations. He notes the inevitable tives that it attempts to regulate. Identifying a
tensions that exist within employer organiza- continuing diversity across different national
tions, and the extent to which the incentives systems, Deakin and Njoya also point to
for employers to join such organizations common challenges facing established legal
have declined, reflecting not only widespread concepts and categories stemming from, for
reductions in union power, but also the inter- example, changes occurring in organizational
nationalization of markets and the reduced forms and the global spread of business
significance of multi-employer agreements. operations.
Traxler argues that broadening their range In Chapter 16, Marick Masters, Ray
of activities and developing roles in ways Gibney, Iryna Shevchuk and Tom Zagenczyk
encouraged by the state, could become focus on developments in the state’s role
increasingly significant for the maintenance as an employer. The picture drawn is again
of employer organizations in the future. one of substantial change, not least in
In Chapter 13 Nicolas Bacon explores man- the spread of different business practices
agement’s central position within industrial from the private into the public sector, and
relations and the scope for, and constraints increased pressures on public sector workers
upon management in developing particular to improve their performance. They anticipate
industrial relations approaches, such as those these pressures intensifying further, poten-
designed to build a ‘high commitment’ work- tially signaling important industrial relations
place. He emphasizes the need for greater implications regarding work pressure, and
understanding of the degree to which man- the nature of the work-effort bargain among
agement can exercise choice in their approach public sector workers. In Chapter 17, Rebecca
to industrial relations given the constraints Gumbrell-McCormick turns her attention to
imposed by, among other things, product the international regulation of the employ-
markets (and nature of competition), labor ment relationship, through the influence of
markets, financial systems and institutional such bodies as the International Labour
contexts. Organization, the World Bank and the World
In the first of three chapters examining Trade Organization, as well as international
different aspects of the state’s role in industrial federations of trade unions and employers’
relations, Richard Hyman in Chapter 14 organizations. She identifies significant areas
points to the peripheral way in which the of development of an international industrial
state has been investigated much in industrial relations system; such developments are
relations research. He argues that this has judged to have been restricted, however, by
acted to underplay the close interrelationship the limited powers ceded to organizations
between states and markets and the centrality such as international trade union federations
of the state within industrial relations, as by national constituent members concerned to
employer, legislator, economic manager and maintain their autonomy.
welfare provider. Hyman develops a three- In Chapter 18, Jean Jenkins and Paul Blyton
fold typology of the way that states shape examine the development and prospects for
24 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

works councils within industrial relations discussed within more localized industrial
systems. While they identify a number of relations. Pressures for decentralization are
factors potentially challenging the future of seen by Flanagan as continuing, giving rise
works councils, other developments appear to an expected greater industrial relations
to signal fresh impetus for the expansion focus on productivity issues, and more
of works council arrangements. However, generally signaling a degree of convergence
without active support from the different among industrial relations systems toward
industrial relations parties, the prospects more decentralized structures. In Chapter 22,
for the latest generation of works councils Ann C. Frost picks up the theme of high
exerting significant influence are seen to be performance work systems and considers the
limited. impact on the broader field of industrial
In Chapter 19, Charles Heckscher charts relations. In questioning the longevity and
the emergence of new industrial relations diffusion of such human resource initiatives,
actors, distinguishing between issue groups she points to the general lack of evidence
(such as consumers and environmentalists) of accompanying mutual gains relationships,
and identity groups (based on race, sex or or significantly greater worker autonomy
disability, for example). Though such groups over decisions, particularly in many low-paid
show a growing preparedness to press their service environments. Frost highlights the
own demands, for the most part he notes need for more research involving a broader
the lack of adaptation of existing industrial range of work sectors, better to reflect the
relations processes to integrate these different diversity of working environments and the
stakeholders. Heckscher identifies a need for growing scale of non-union settings.
improved internal and external organization The issue of employee involvement
among the new actors, as well as for increased in decision-making is also addressed in
attention by trade unions to building effective Chapter 23 by Russell D. Lansbury and
relations and coalitions with these emerging Nick Wailes, who consider the extent to
stakeholders. which certain institutional systems are
Part Three of the Handbook focuses more conducive to employee participation
mainly on processes of industrial relations. than others. They also cast doubt on
In Chapter 20, John Godard considers the the sustainability of work reorganization
factors influencing the formation of trade initiatives based on greater worker
unions, particularly what determines indi- participation, particularly in those (liberal
viduals to seek collective representation. He market) economies that otherwise do not
reviews the different evidence on individual provide an environment conducive to
predispositions, the role of trade unions and extending worker influence over decision-
employers, and the broader relevance of making. Looking to the future, Lansbury and
legal structures and economic and political Wailes note that even within coordinated
contexts. Godard’s analysis points to a long market economies, participation traditions
list of influencing factors, but also how may be more difficult to sustain as pressures
different national institutional environments – on firms increase for short-term financial
and the norms that these give rise to – shape returns.
the particular influence of specific factors in In Chapter 24, David Lewin examines
different circumstances. different theories of why employer-employee
In Chapter 21, Robert Flanagan assesses the conflict occurs and charts the changes taking
impact of changing bargaining structures on place in patterns of conflict resolution. He
the exercise of bargaining power. He consid- notes the significance of the shift away from
ers the widespread trend toward more decen- collective toward more individual expressions
tralized industrial relations arrangements, that of conflict, and the resulting expansion of con-
in turn have contributed to increased pay flict resolution methods outside collectively-
dispersion and a broadening of the agenda agreed grievance procedures. In reviewing
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 25

the different individual methods of conflict union presence and aspects of well-being, and
resolution, Lewin points to a need for notes that traditional industrial relations have
further evaluation of the effectiveness of rarely directly addressed questions of worker
different procedures, for individuals and well-being in the past. However, with growing
organizations. concerns over issues such as workplace
The contributors to Part Four primarily stress, Guest identifies worker well-being
address the outcomes of industrial relations. as a potential area for greater attention by
The nature of these outcomes varies consid- trade unions and industrial relations in the
erably and the ten chapters in this part reflect future.
this diversity. In Chapter 25 Daniel Gallagher In Chapter 29 Ali Dastmalchian reviews
reviews trends in workforce structure and how the research conducted on industrial relations
that structure is shaped by the system of indus- climates. Drawing insights on the climate con-
trial relations. He particularly explores the cept from organizational theory, he highlights
development of different forms of temporary a number of methodological issues which
work contract and the implications of these for remain unresolved. Dastmalchian nonetheless
our understanding of the ‘typical’ employer- identifies the influence of industrial rela-
employee relationship or indeed the ‘typical’ tions climate on the outcomes of union-
organization. One of the future research issues management relations, and notes the signifi-
identified is the need for further assessment cance of the research on climate for current
of different union strategies being adopted debates, including the question of whether
for increasing recruitment among temporary unions and management should pursue greater
workers. In Chapter 26 Alex Bryson and John ‘partnership’ relations. In Chapter 30 Barbara
Forth examine the different explanations of Pocock considers inequalities in employ-
wage determination. They identify the many ment outcomes. She emphasizes the multiple
variables that impact on pay setting, giving sources and manifestations of inequality and
rise among other things, to continuing wage the ways in which recent developments both
inequality between the sexes, full- and part- in industrial relations (such as decollectiviza-
time workers, and across occupations. Bryson tion and decentralization) and labor markets
and Forth emphasize the importance for those (for example increased casualization) have
researching pay determination, of incorporat- contributed to widening inequalities. Pocock
ing a sufficient degree of complexity into their highlights the importance of a perspective
analyses. that incorporates international as well as
In Chapter 27, Paul Blyton considers national and local comparisons; the chapter
another major focus of union-management also underlines the broader importance of
relations: the determination of working time maintaining a focus on inequality in a field
patterns. He examines the shifting influence where it is prone to being crowded out by other
of different forms of regulation over working issues such as economic performance.
time by the state, collective agreement, In Chapter 31, Gregor Gall and Robert
management and by employees themselves. Hebdon examine issues surrounding how
Blyton also assesses the centrality of working conflict is manifested at work. In reviewing
time within the current debate over work-life the range of forms that conflict can take, and
balance, and the way in which current trends in the widespread decline in strike levels that
working time potentially act both to facilitate has taken place over the past two decades,
and to inhibit workers achieving a successful they highlight the increased significance
work-life balance. In Chapter 28, David of more individualized conflict expressions
Guest broadens the discussion of industrial and the degree to which these are cur-
relations outcomes by considering worker rently substituting for other, more collective
well-being, with a particular focus on job forms. In considering the future, Gall and
satisfaction, insecurity, workload and stress. Hebdon anticipate the continuation of both
He identifies little relationship between trade collective and individual forms of conflict,
26 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and the possible further development of They identify too a series of questions about
cross-national conflict expression coordinated the future purpose and contribution of indus-
through international trade union campaigns. trial relations within contemporary society.
In Chapter 32, Irena Grugulis notes the cen- These questions underline the continuing
tral role that ‘skill’has played within industrial importance of the subject in a world of work in
relations, acting as a basis for union forma- which vital issues concerning the conditions
tion, wage demands and pay differentials, under which that work is undertaken, remain
among other things. She examines national to be resolved.
variations in skill formation systems, together
with firm-level and trade union influences.
Grugulis explores the factors that are putting
NOTES
established systems of vocational education
and training under pressure, and identifies the 1 Fiorito (2005) notes that although the term
dangers of weaker skill formation systems ‘industry’ or ‘industrial’ connotes heavy industry for
for continuing job quality. In Chapter 33, many, its use by IR scholars serves to differentiate
John Delaney considers the evidence on ‘industrial’ or developed societies, from agrarian
the relationship between industrial relations societies based largely on peasant production. Service
businesses, public services, small enterprises and,
and business performance. While noting indeed, contemporary agricultural production all
the overall lack of evidence that industrial exhibit industrial relations, to the extent that economic
relations enhance business performance, he activity rests on the hiring of formally free labor to
questions the significance of this in terms perform work tasks on the employer’s behalf. Fiorito
of measuring the contribution that industrial also notes that, while independent production for
the market by the self-employed falls beyond IR’s
relations actually makes. Rather than relying purview, bogus self-employment, in which dependent
on a yardstick of economic efficiency, he self-employed work for larger enterprises, and various
identifies the need for developing other forms of contingent labor, such as those based on the
measures of performance, such as worker supply of contractors to employers through agencies,
well-being or social justice, and poses the do not. In fact the study of contingent labor has
been a notable theme in recent IR literature (for
broader question of how industrial relations example Carré et al., 2000; Forde and Slater, 2005).
can be developed to make a more significant In developed economies the employment relationship
contribution in a rapidly-changing world. is the dominant institution through which work is
In the final chapter, Richard Freeman organized – Edwards (2003: 2) estimates that 88 per
questions to what extent differences in cent of the UK’s economically active population is
engaged in an employment relationship – a fact that,
economic performance between countries in principle, underlines the continuing relevance of the
can be attributed to differences in labor study of industrial relations.
market institutions. While he finds clear 2 Another case can be identified along the
evidence that centralized wage setting is boundary between state regulation and management
associated with narrower pay gaps, more decision. It is often suggested that managers (at least
in Anglophone liberal market economies) are now
generally the results on any broader rela- the dominant actor in employment relations with
tionships between labor institutions and, the freedom to design systems of human resource
for example, economic efficiency, growth management in a largely non-union context. Much
and employment, are inconclusive, despite of the prescriptive writing on HRM echoes this
previous pronouncements and even policy analysis with its emphasis on managers designing
HR policies and practices that complement particular
advice based on seeming consensus. Freeman business strategies (see Legge, 2005: 19–25). In
calls for more firm-level and other types of an important series of empirical articles, however,
evidence, together with the development of Dobbin and colleagues have cast doubt on this
more sophisticated theories concerning the interpretation (Dobbin et al., 1993; Dobbin and
contribution of labor institutions. Sutton, 1998; Kelly and Dobbin, 1999; Sutton et al.,
1994). They argue essentially that the development
Together the chapters provide a wide- of HR systems in US business since the early 1960s
ranging review of the issues currently shaping has been driven by the passage of equality law,
and challenging the industrial relations field. which prompted US corporations to strengthen
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 27

the HR function and formalize and professionalize globalization will in due course erode institutional
HR practice. The elaboration of HR systems, on this differences with an accompanying leveling down of
analysis, therefore, flowed from the interaction of employment standards (see Coates, 2000).
management decision with legal regulation (see also
Piore and Safford, 2006).
3 Stage-models seem to be used particularly by US
writers. The scale of the US, the size of its economy REFERENCES
and its dominance in the world system encourages
indigenous scholars to treat it as a paradigmatic case. Ackers, P. (2007) ‘Collective bargaining as industrial
In Europe, in contrast, a continent crammed full of democracy: Hugh Clegg and the political foundations
nation states each with their own traditions (Crouch,
of British Industrial Relations pluralism’, British
1993), there is more emphasis on comparative studies
Journal of Industrial Relations, 45 (1): 77–101.
and institutional analysis.
4 In Italy, although there was union support Ackers, P. and Wilkinson, A. (2003a) ‘Introduction:
secured by a moderate victory, employer buy-in the British industrial relations tradition – forma-
was limited and evaporated once Berlusconi’s strong tion, breakdown and salvage’, in P. Ackers and
right-wing government was elected. Italian employers A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work and Employ-
at that point had no need of a social pact to ment: Industrial Relations in Transition. Oxford,
secure their objectives: ‘When the 2001 elections Oxford University Press. pp. 1–27.
gave a right-wing government the strongest majority Ackers, P. and Wilkinson, A. (eds) (2003b) Understand-
of the post-war period, employers chose the more ing Work and Employment: Industrial Relations in
confrontational strategy of lobbying government
Transition. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
for labor market deregulation’. (Baccaro and Lim,
2007: 40).
Adams, R.J. (1993) ‘“All aspects of people at work”:
5 We note in passing, however, that despite this unity and division in the study of labor and
orientation there is little interest in IR amongst those labor management’, in R.J. Adams and N.M. Meltz
engaged in what has come to be labeled ‘critical (eds) Industrial Relations Theory: Its Nature, Scope
management studies’. and Pedagogy. Metuchen NJ and London, IMLR
6 Thus, Holgate et al. (2006: 325) note that, Press/Rutgers University and the Scarecrow Press.
‘…a dominant theme throughout has been the pp. 119–60.
way in which “mainstream” IR has often reduced Adams, R.J. (1995) Industrial Relations under Liberal
workers’ experiences to the manifestation of class
Democracy: North America in Comparative Perspec-
relations that are defined purely in economic terms,
tive. Columbia SC, University of South Carolina
or which are theorized in terms of a single conflict
between managers and employees’. Forrest (1993: Press.
410) similarly observes both pluralism and Marxism Almond, P. and Rubery, J. (1998) ‘The gender impact of
that, ‘…these diverse approaches share a world- recent European trends in pay determination’, Work,
view that discounts the importance of gender as Employment and Society, 12 (4): 675–93.
an analytical concept. Both presume that workers Anner, M., Greer, I., Hauptmeier, M., Lillie, N. and
and trade unionists are quintessentially male; neither Winchester, N. (2006) ‘The industrial determinants
analyzes the way in which social relations at work are of transnational solidarity: global interunion politics
rooted in gender relations’. in three sectors’, European Journal of Industrial
7 Healy et al. (2006: 293) describe the contri-
Relations, 12 (1): 7–27.
bution of feminist research within IR in terms of,
‘putting women, and gender, and more recently,
Armour, J., Deakin, S. and Konzelmann, S.J. (2003)
race/ethnicity, sexuality, disability and age, back in…’ ‘Shareholder primacy and the trajectory of UK
8 Dickens writes of the need to abandon the corporate governance’, British Journal of Industrial
‘Procrustean bed’ of full-time continuous employ- Relations, 41 (3): 531–55.
ment, designed to match the needs of male workers Baccaro, L. (2003) ‘What is alive and what is dead in
supported by a dependent care-giver. It must be the theory of corporatism’, British Journal of Industrial
pointed out, however, that feminist commentators are Relations, 41 (4): 683–706.
often critical of the actual work-life balance or family- Baccaro, L. and Lim, S-H. (2007) ‘Social pacts as
friendly policies employers develop to accommodate coalitions of the weak and moderate: Ireland,
diversity. Systems of flexible working time that allow
Italy and South Korea in comparative perspective’,
women better to integrate paid and domestic labor,
for instance, may simply reinforce a ‘sexual contract’
European Journal of Industrial Relations, 13 (1):
in which male interests are dominant. 27–46.
9 The response of Marxists, in turn, has been Bach, S., Bordogna, L., Della Roca, G. and Winchester, D.
to argue that differences between the ‘varieties of (eds) (1999) Public Service Employment Relations in
capitalism’ are exaggerated or that the force of Europe. London, Routledge.
28 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Bacon, N. and Blyton, P. (2006) ‘Union co-operation in Brown Johnson, N. and Jarley, P. (2004) ‘Justice
a context of job insecurity: negotiated outcomes from and union participation: an extension and test of
teamworking’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, mobilization theory’, British Journal of Industrial
44 (2): 215–38. Relations, 42 (3): 543–62.
Bacon, N., Wright, M. and Demina, N. (2004) ‘Man- Budd, J.W. (2004) Employment with a Human Face:
agement buyouts and human resource management’, Balancing Efficiency, Equity and Voice. London and
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (2): Ithaca NY, ILR Press.
325–47. Budd, J.W., Gomez, R. and Meltz, N.M. (2004)
Badigannavar, V., and Kelly, J. (2004) ‘Union ‘Why a balance is best: the pluralist industrial
organizing’, in J. Kelly and P. Willman (eds) relations paradigm of balancing competing interests’,
Union Organization and Activity. London, Routledge. in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical Perspectives on
pp. 32–50. Work and the Employment Relationship. University
Baird, M. (2006) ‘The gender agenda: women, work of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Industrial Relations
and maternity leave’, in M. Hearn and G. Patmore Research Association. pp. 195–227.
(eds) Rethinking Work: Time, Space and Discourse. Carré, F., Ferber, M.A., Golden, L. and Herzenberg,
Melbourne, Cambridge University Press. pp. 39–59. S.A. (eds) (2000) Nonstandard Work: The Nature and
Barley, S.R. and Kunda, G. (2004) Gurus, Hired Guns Challenges of Changing Employment Arrangements.
and Warm Bodies: Itinerant Experts in a Knowledge University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign IL, Industrial
Economy. Princeton and Oxford, Princeton University Relations Research Association.
Press. Clark, A.E. (2005) ‘Your money or your life: changing job
Barnard, C. and Deakin, S. (2002) ‘Corporate gov- quality in OECD countries’, British Journal of Industrial
ernance, European governance and social rights’, Relations, 43 (3): 377–400.
in B. Hepple (ed.) Social and Labour Rights in Clegg, H.A. (1976) Trade Unionism under Collective
a Global Context: International and Comparative Bargaining: A Theory Based on Comparisons of Six
Perspectives. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Countries. Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
pp. 122–50. Coates, D. (2000) Models of Capitalism: Growth and
Beechey, V. and Perkins, T. (1987) A Matter of Hours: Stagnation in the Modern Era. Cambridge, Cambridge
Part-time Work and the Labour Market. Cambridge, University Press.
Polity Press. Coates, D. (ed.) (2005) Varieties of Capitalism, Varieties
Bell, D.W. and Hanson, C.G. (1987) Profit-sharing and of Approaches. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.
Profitability. London, Kogan Page. Cobble, D.S. (1991) ‘Organizing the post-industrial
Belman, D. and Voos, P. (2006) ‘Union wages and union workforce: lessons from the history of waitress
decline: evidence from the construction industry’, unionism’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 60 (1): 67–87. 44 (3): 419–36.
Bercusson, B. and Dickens, L. (1996) Equal Opportunities Cobble, D.S. (ed.) (1993) Women and Unions: Forging
and Collective Bargaining in Europe: Defining a Partnership. Ithaca and London, ILR Press.
the Issues. Dublin, European Foundation for the Cockburn, C. (1983) Brothers: Male Dominance and
Improvement of Living and Working Conditions. Technological Change. London, Pluto Press.
Beynon, H. (1984) Working for Ford, 2nd edition. Colgan, F. and Ledwith, S. (eds) (2002) Gender, Diver-
Harmondsworth, Penguin. sity and Trade Unions: International Perspectives.
Blau, F.D., Brinton, M.C. and Grusky, D.B. (eds) (2006) London, Routledge.
The Declining Significance of Gender? New York, Colling, T. and Dickens, L. (1989) Equality Bargaining –
Russell Sage Foundation. Why Not? Equal Opportunities Commission Research
Boxall, P. and Haynes, P. (1997) ‘Strategy and trade Series, London, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office.
union effectiveness in a neo-liberal environment’, Colling, T. and Dickens, L. (1998) ‘Selling the case
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 35 (4): 567–91. for gender equality: deregulation and equality
Bradley, K .and Gelb, A. (1986) Share Ownership for bargaining’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Employees. London, Public Policy Centre. 36 (3): 389–411.
Briskin, L. and McDermott, P. (eds) (1993) Women Coyle-Shapiro, J. A-M., Shore, L.M., Taylor, M.S. and
Challenging Unions: Feminism, Democracy and Tetrick, L.E. (eds) (2004) The Employment Rela-
Militancy. Toronto, University of Toronto Press. tionship: Examining Psychological and Contextual
Brown, W. (2000) ‘Putting partnership into practice in Perspectives. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Britain’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 38 (2): Crouch, C. (1993) Industrial Relations and European
299–316. State Traditions. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 29

Darlington, R. (1994) The Dynamics of Workplace Trade Ferner, A., Qintanilla, J. and Sánchez-Runde, C.
Unionism. London and New York, Mansell. (eds) (2006) Multinationals, Institutions and the
Darlington, R. and Lyddon, D. (2001) Glorious Summer: Construction of Transnational Practices: Convergence
Class Struggle in Britain 1972. London, Chicago and and Diversity in the Global Economy. Basingstoke,
Sydney, Bookmarks. Palgrave MacMillan.
Davies, P. and Freedland, M. (1993) Labour Legislation Fine, J. (2006) Worker Centers: Organizing Communities
and Public Policy. Oxford, Clarendon Press. at the Edge of the Dream. Ithaca and London, ILR
Dickens, L. (1999) ‘Beyond the business case: a Press.
three-pronged approach to equality action’, Human Fiorito, J. (2005) ‘Industrial relations’, in S. Cartright (ed.)
Resource Management Journal, 9 (1): 9–20. The Blackwell Encyclopedia of Management, second
Dickens, L. (2005) ‘Walking the talk? Equality and diver- edition. Malden, MA, Blackwell. pp. 183–85.
sity in employment’, in S. Bach (ed.) Managing Human Fiorito, J. (2001) ‘Human resource management prac-
Resources: Personnel Management in Transition. tices and worker desires for union representation’,
Oxford, Blackwell Publishing. pp. 178–208. Journal of Labor Research, 22 (2): 335–54.
Dickens, L. (2007) ‘The road is long: thirty years of Flanders, A. (1970) Management and Unions: The
equality legislation in Britain’, British Journal of Theory and Reform of Industrial Relations. London,
Industrial Relations, 45 (3): 463–94. Faber and Faber.
Dickens, R. and Manning A. (2003) ‘Minimum wage, Foley, J.R. (2003) ‘Mobilization and change in a trade
minimum impact’, in R. Dickens, P. Gregg and union setting: environment, structures and action’,
J. Wadsworth (eds) The Labour Market under New Work, Employment and Society, 17 (2): 247–68.
Labour: The State of Working Britain. Basingstoke, Forde, C. and Slater, G. (2005) ‘Agency working
Palgrave MacMillan. pp. 201–13. in Britain: character, consequence and regulation’,
Dickson, T., McLachlan, H.V., Prior, P. and Swales, K. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (2): 249–72.
(1988) ‘Big Blue and the unions: IBM, individualism Forrest, A. (1993) ‘Women and IR theory: no room in the
and trade union strategy’, Work, Employment and discourse’, Relations Industrielles, 48 (3): 409–40.
Society, 2 (4): 506–20. Freeman, R. and Medoff, J. (1984) What Do Unions Do?
Dobbin, F., Sutton, J.R., Meyer, J.W. and Scott, R. New York, Basic Books.
(1993) ‘Equal opportunity law and the construction Frege, C.M. (2002) ‘A critical assessment of the
of internal labor markets’, American Journal of theoretical and empirical research on works councils’,
Sociology, 99 (2): 396–427. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 40 (2): 221–48.
Dobbin, F. and Sutton, J.R. (1998) ‘The strength of Frege, C.M. (2005) ‘Varieties of industrial relations
a weak state: the rights revolution and the rise of research: take-over, convergence or divergence?’,
human resource management divisions’, American British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (2):
Journal of Sociology, 104 (2): 441–76. 179–207.
Dunlop, J.T. (1993) Industrial Relations Systems, revised Frege, C.M. and Kelly, J. (2004) ‘Union strategies in
edition. Boston MA, Harvard Business School Press. comparative context’, in C.M. Frege and J. Kelly
Edwards, P. (2003) ‘The employment relationship and (eds) Varieties of Unionism: Strategies of Union
the field of industrial relations’, in P. Edwards (ed.) Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy. Oxford,
Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice, second Oxford University Press. pp. 31–44.
edition, Oxford, Blackwell Publishing. pp. 1–36. Frost, A. (2001) ‘Reconceptualising local union
Ellem, B. (2002) ‘Power, place and scale: union responses to workplace restructuring in North
recognition in the Pilbara, 1999–2002’, Labour and America’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Industry, 13 (2): 67–89. 39 (4): 307–33.
Estlund, C. (2003) Working Together: How Workplace Godard, J. (2004a) ‘A critical assessment of the high
Bonds Strengthen a Diverse Democracy. Oxford, performance paradigm’, British Journal of Industrial
Oxford University Press. Relations, 42 (2): 349–78.
Fairbrother, P. (1996) ‘Workplace trade unionism in the Godard, J. (2004b) ‘The new institutionalism, capitalist
state sector’, in P. Ackers, C. Smith and P. Smith (eds) diversity and industrial relations’, in B.E. Kaufman
The New Workplace and Trade Unionism. London, (ed.) Theoretical Perspectives on Work and the
Routledge. pp. 110–48. Employment Relationship. Champaign IL, Industrial
Fairbrother, P. (2000) Trade Unions at the Crossroads. Relations Research Association. pp. 229–64.
London and New York, Mansell. Goldthorpe, J.H. (1985) ‘The end of convergence:
Fairris, D. (2006) ‘Union voice effects in Mexico’, British corporatist and dualist tendencies in modern western
Journal of Industrial Relations, 44 (4): 781–800. societies’, in B. Roberts, R. Finnegan and D. Gallie
30 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

(eds) New Approaches to Economic Life. Manchester, Heery, E. and Conley, H. (2007) ‘Frame extension in
Manchester University Press. pp. 124–53. a mature social movement: British trade unions and
Gordon, M.E. and Turner, L. (eds) (2000) Transnational part-time work’, The Journal of Industrial Relations,
Cooperation among Labor Unions. Ithaca and 48 (1): 5–29.
London, ILR Press. Heery, E. and Frege, C. (2006) ‘New actors in industrial
Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (eds) (2005) Corporate relations’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Governance and Labour Management. Oxford, 44 (4): 601–4.
Oxford University Press. Heery, E., Healy, G. and Taylor, P. (2004) ‘Representation
Green, F. (2006) Demanding Work: The Paradox of at work: themes and issues’, in G. Healy, E. Heery,
Job Quality in the Affluent Economy. Princeton and P. Taylor and W. Brown (eds) The Future of Worker
Oxford, Princeton University Press. Representation. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.
Green, F. and Tsitsianis, N. (2005) ‘An investigation pp. 1–36.
of national trends in job satisfaction in Britain and Herding, R. (1972) Job Control and Union Structure.
Germany’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Rotterdam, University of Rotterdam Press.
43 (3): 401–29. Hirschman, A.O. (1991) The Rhetoric of Reaction:
Grimshaw, D. and Rubery, J. (2001) The Gender Pay Perversity, Futility, Jeopardy. Cambridge MA and
Gap: a Research Review. Research Discussion Series, London, The Belknap Press of Harvard University
Manchester, Equal Opportunities Commission. Press.
Guest, D. (2007) ‘HRM and performance: can partner- Holgate, J., Hebson, G. and McBride, A. (2006) ‘Why
ship address the ethical dilemmas?’ in A. Pinnington, gender and “difference” matters: a critical appraisal
R. Macklin and T. Campbell (eds) Human Resource of industrial relations research’, Industrial Relations
Management: Ethics and Employment. Oxford, Journal, 37 (4): 310–28.
Oxford University Press. pp. 52–65. Hoque, K. and Noon, M. (2004) ‘Equal opportunities
Guest, D. and Conway, N. (1999) ‘Peering into the Black policy and practice in Britain: evaluating the “empty
Hole: the downside of new employment relations in shell” hypothesis’, Work, Employment and Society,
the UK’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 37 (3): 18 (3): 481–506.
367–89. Howell, C. (2005) Trade Unions and the State: The
Gunnigle, P., Collings, D.C. and Morley, M.J. (2006) Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in
‘Accomodating global capitalism? State policy and Britain, 1890–2000. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton
industrial relations in American MNCs in Ireland’, in University Press.
A. Ferner, J. Qunitanilla and C. Sánchez-Runde (eds) Hunter, L.C. and Rimmer, S. (1995) ‘An economic
Multinationals, Institutions and the Construction of exploration of the UK and Australian experiences’,
Transnational Practices: Convergence and Diversity Gender, Work and Organization, 2 (3): 140–56.
in the Global Economy. Basingstoke, Palgrave Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist Intro-
MacMillan. pp. 86–108. duction. London and Basingstoke, The MacMillan
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (1998) ‘An introduction to Press.
varieties of capitalism’, in P.A. Hall and D. Soskice Hyman, R. (2004) ‘Is industrial relations theory always
(eds) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional ethnocentric?’, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical Per-
Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford, spectives on Work and the Employment Relationship.
Oxford University Press. pp. 1–70. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Industrial
Hanson, C. G. and Mather, G. (1988) Striking out Strikes: Relations Research Association. pp. 265–92.
Changing Employment Relations in the British Labour Katz, H.C. (1993) ‘The decentralization of collective
Market. Hobart Paper 110, London, The Institute of bargaining: a literature review and comparative
Economic Affairs. analysis’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
Hassel, A. (2006) Wage-Setting, Social Pacts and the 47 (1): 3–22.
Euro. Amsterdam, Amsterdam University Press. Kaufman, B.E. (1993) The Origins and Evolution of the
Healy, G., Hansen, L.L. and Ledwith, S. (2006) ‘Editorial: Field of Industrial Relations in the United States.
still uncovering gender in industrial relations’, Ithaca NY, ILR Press.
Industrial Relations Journal, 37 (4): 290–8. Kaufman, B.E. (2004a) ‘Employment relations and
Heery, E. (2003) ‘Trade unions and industrial relations’, the employment relations system: a guide to
in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding theorizing’, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical Per-
Work and Employment: Industrial Relations spectives on Work and the Employment Relationship.
in Transition. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Champaign IL, Industrial Relations Research Associa-
pp. 278–304. tion. pp. 41–75.
INTRODUCTION: THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 31

Kaufman, B.E. (2004b) The Global Evolution of Industrial Lillie, N. (2006) A Global Union for Global Workers:
Relations: Events, Ideas and the IIRA. Geneva, Collective Bargaining and Regulatory Politics in
International Labour Office. Maritime Shipping. New York and London, Routledge.
Kaufman, B.E. and Taras, D.G. (eds) (2000) Nonunion Logan, J. (2006) ‘The union avoidance industry in the
Employee Representation: History, Contemporary United States’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Practice and Policy. Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe. 44 (4): 651–76.
Kelly, E. and Dobbin, F. (1999) ‘Civil rights law at work: Lyddon, D. (2003) ‘History and industrial relations’, in
sex discrimination and the rise of maternity leave P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work
policies’, American Journal of Sociology, 105 (2): and Employment: Industrial Relations in Transition.
455–92. Oxford, Oxford University Press. pp. 89–118.
Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi- McAdam, D., McCarthy, J.D. and Zald, M.N. (eds) (1996)
lization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London, Comparative Perspectives on Social Movements:
Routledge. Political Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures, and
Kirton, G. and Greene, A-M. (2000) The Dynamics of Cultural Framings. Cambridge and New York,
Managing Diversity: A Critical Approach. London, Cambridge University Press.
Butterworth-Heinemann. McAdam, D., Tarrow, S. and Tilly, C. (eds) (2001)
Kochan, T.A. (1998) ‘What is distinctive about industrial Dynamics of Contention. Cambridge and New York,
relations research?’, in K. Whitfield and G. Strauss Cambridge University Press.
(eds) Researching the World of Work: Strategies and McBride, A. (2001) ‘Making it work: supporting group
Methods in Studying Industrial Relations. Ithaca and representation in a liberal democratic organization’,
London, ILR Press. pp. 31–45. Gender, Work and Organization, 8 (4): 411–29.
Kochan, T.A., Katz, H.C., McKersie, R.B. (1986) The Machin, S. (2006) ‘The economic approach to analysis
Transformation of American Industrial Relations. of the labor market’, in M. Korczynski, R. Hodson
New York, Basic Books. and P. Edwards (eds) Social Theory at Work. Oxford,
Kochan, T.A. and Osterman, P. (1994) The Mutual Gains Oxford University Press. pp. 182–207.
Enterprise: Forging a Winning Partnership among McColgan, A. (1994) Pay Equity – Just Wages for
Labor, Management and Government. Cambridge Women? London: The Institute of Employment
MA, Harvard Business School Press. Rights.
Konzelmann, S.J., Conway, N., Trenberth, L. and Maitland, I. (1983) The Causes of Industrial Disorder:
Wilkinson, F. (2006) ‘Corporate governance and A Comparison of a British and German Factory.
human resource management’, British Journal of London, Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Industrial Relations, 44 (3): 541–67. Marginson, P. and Sisson, K. (2004) European Integra-
Korczynski, M., Hodson, R. and Edwards, P. (eds) (2006) tion and Industrial Relations: Multi-level Governance
Social Theory at Work. Oxford, Oxford University in the Making. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.
Press. Marsden, R. (1982) ‘Industrial relations: a critique of
Kuruvilla, S. and Verma, A. (2006) ‘International labor empiricism’, Sociology, 16 (2): 232–50.
standards, soft regulation and national government Metcalf, D. (2005) ‘Trade unions: resurgence or
roles’, The Journal of Industrial Relations, 48 (1): perdition?’, in S. Fernie and D. Metcalf (eds)
41–58. Trade Unions: Resurgence or Demise? London and
Ledwith, S. and Colgan, F. (2002) ‘Tackling New York, Routledge. pp. 83–117.
gender, diversity and trade union democracy: a Milkman, R. (2006) L.A. Story: Immigrant Workers and
worldwide project?’, in F. Colgan and S. Ledwith the Future of the U.S. Labor Movement. New York,
(eds) Gender, Diversity and Trade Unions: Russell Sage Foundation.
International Perspectives. London, Routledge. Minford, P. (1985) ‘Trade unions destroy a million
pp. 1–27. jobs’, in W.E.J. McCarthy (ed.) Trade Unions: Selected
Legge, K. (2005) Human Resource Management; Readings. Harmondsworth, Penguin. pp. 365–75.
Rhetorics and Realities, anniversary edition. Müller-Jentsch, W. (2004) ‘Theoretical approaches to
Basingstoke and New York, Palgrave MacMillan. industrial relations’, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical
Legge, K. (2007) ‘The ethics of HRM in dealing Perspectives on Work and the Employment Rela-
with individual employees without collective rep- tionship. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign,
resentation’, in A. Pinnington, R. Macklin and Industrial Relations Research Association. pp. 1–40.
T. Campbell (eds) Human Resource Management: Osterman, P., Kochan, T.A., Locke, R.M. and Piore, M.J.
Ethics and Employment. Oxford, Oxford University (2001) Working in American: A Blueprint for the New
Press. pp. 35–41. Labor Market. Cambridge MA, The MIT Press.
32 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Piore, M.J. and Safford, S. (2006) ‘Changing regimes participation: an NHS case study’, Industrial Relations
of workplace governance: shifting axes of social Journal, 35 (5): 403–18.
mobilization and the challenge to industrial relations Tarrow, S. (1998) Power in Movement: Social Move-
theory’, Industrial Relations, 45 (3): 299–325. ments and Contentious Politics, second edition.
Pocock, B. (1997a) ‘Gender and Australian industrial Cambridge and New York, Cambridge University
relations theory and research practice’, Labour and Press.
Industry, 8 (1): 1–19. Teague, P. (2006) ‘Social partnership and local
Pocock, B. (ed.) (1997b) Strife, Sex and Politics in Labour development in Ireland: the limits to deliberation’,
Unions. St Leonards, Allen and Unwin. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 44 (3):
Purcell, J. and Ahlstrand, B. (1994) Human Resource 421–43.
Management in the Multi-divisional Company. Thompson, P. and Harley, B. (2007) ‘HRM and the
Oxford, Oxford University Press. worker: labor process perspectives’, in P. Boxall,
Purcell, J. and Sisson, K. (1983) ‘Strategies and J. Purcell and P. Wright (eds) The Oxford Handbook
practice in the management of industrial relations’, in of Human Resource Management. Oxford, Oxford
G.S. Bain (ed.) Industrial Relations in Britain. Oxford, University Press. 147–65.
Basil Blackwell. pp. 95–120. Traxler, F., Blaschke, S. and Kittel, B. (2002) National
Rainnie, A., Herod, A. and McGrath Champ, S. (2007) Labour Relations in Internationalized Markets:
‘Spatializing industrial relations’, Industrial Relations A Comparative Study of Institutions, Change, and
Journal, 38 (2): 102–18. Performance. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Roberts, B. (1987) Mr Hammond’s Cherry Tree: The Troy, L. (1999) Beyond Unions and Collective Bargaining.
Morphology of Union Survival. Eighteenth Wincott Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe.
Memorial Lecture, Occasional Paper 76, London, The Troy, L. (2004) The Twilight of the Old Unionism.
Institute of Economic Affairs. Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe.
Samuel, P. (2005) ‘Partnership working and the Tsogas, G. (2001) Labor Regulation in a Global Economy.
cultivated activist’, Industrial Relations Journal, Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe.
36 (1): 59–76. Turnbull, P.J. (2003) ‘What do unions do now?’, Journal
Shenfield, A. (1986) What Right to Strike? Hobart Paper of Labor Research, 24 (3): 492–526.
106, London, The Institute for Economic Affairs. Turnbull, P.J. (2006) ‘The war on Europe’s waterfront –
Sisson, K. (1987) The Management of Collective repertoires of power in the port transport industry’,
Bargaining: An International Comparison. Oxford, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 44 (2): 305–26.
Basil Blackwell. Turnbull, P.J., Blyton, P. and Harvey, G. (2004) ‘Cleared
Sisson, K. (1993) ‘In search of HRM’, British Journal of for take-off? Management-labor partnership in the
Industrial Relations, 31 (2): 201–10. European civil aviation industry’, European Journal of
Sisson, K. and Marginson, P. (2002) ‘Co-ordinated Industrial Relations, 10 (3): 287–307.
bargaining: a process for our times?’, British Journal Van Roozendaal, G. (2002) Trade Unions and Global
of Industrial Relations, 40 (2): 197–220. Governance. London and New York, Continuum.
Smith, P. and Morton, G. (2006) ‘Nine years of New Vaughan-Whitehead, D. (ed.) (1995) Workers’ Finan-
Labour: Neoliberalism and workers’ rights’, British cial Participation: East-West Experiences. Geneva,
Journal of Industrial Relations, 44 (3): 401–20. International Labour Office.
Streeck, W. (1997) ‘Beneficial constraints: on the Wacjman, J. (2000) ‘Feminism facing industrial relations
economic limits of rational voluntarism’, in in Britain’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
J.R. Hollingsworth and R. Boyer (eds) Contem- 38 (2): 183–201.
porary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Insti- Wall, T. and Wood, S. (2005) ‘The romance of HRM and
tutions. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. business performance, and the case for Big Science’,
pp. 197–219. Human Relations, 58 (4): 429–62.
Sutton, J.R., Dobbin, F., Meyer, J.W. and Scott, W.R. Wheeler, H.N. (2002) The Future of the American Labor
(1994) ‘The legalization of the workplace’, American Movement. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Journal of Sociology, 99 (4): 944–71. Whitfield, K. and Poole, M. (1997) ‘Organizing
Tailby, S., Richardson, M., Stewart, P., Danford, A. and employment for high performance: theories, evidence
Upchurch, M. (2004) ‘Partnership at work and worker and policy’, Organization Studies, 18 (5): 745–64.
PART ONE

Perspectives and Approaches


2
The History of Industrial
Relations as a Field of Study
Carola M. Frege

Industrial relations (IR) broadly defined as classical notion of the universality of scientific
the study of work and employment, was research. This chapter argues instead for the
established as an independent academic field embeddedness of IR research in national-
in the 1920s in the US and subsequently specific path dependencies.
after WWII in Britain and other Anglophone
countries.1 Though originally established by
US institutional economists it soon became
to be seen as an interdisciplinary field INSTITUTIONAL HISTORIES
incorporating labor economists, social psy- OF IR RESEARCH
chologists, personnel management scholars,
industrial sociologists, labor lawyers as well The industrial revolution and its social
as political scientists working on labor issues. consequences in Europe and the US in
In continental Europe and indeed in the rest of the nineteenth and early twentieth century
the world research on work and employment increasingly drew scholars from a variety
remained, however, a subject within those of emerging social sciences (for example
social science disciplines. law, economics, political science, sociology)
This chapter starts by outlining the different to engage in the analysis of the mechanics
historical developments of IR research in the of capitalism and the ‘social question’, in
US and Britain as two examples of Anglo- particular the ‘labor problem’ (poverty and
phone countries with the longest traditions social unrest related to the industrialization)
in IR research. It is then contrasted with (Katznelson, 1996). In the US and Britain (and
the developments in Germany as an example subsequently in other Anglophone regions) an
of continental Europe. A major finding is independent field of study of employment,
that research traditions and outcomes differ industrial or labor relations, developed at
from country to country and challenge the the beginning of the twentieth century.
36 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

As outlined before, this development did (Hodgson, 2001). One can argue therefore that
not occur in the rest of the world, in the ‘new political economy’ or institutional
particular not in continental Europe, where economics arose in reaction to the ascendance
IR research remained multi-disciplinary, of the laissez-faire perspective within eco-
conducted mainly by sociologists, political nomics. The institutional economists found in
scientists and lawyers. The different insti- IR a niche to pursue pragmatic, behaviorist,
tutional developments across countries are public-policy oriented research which took
accompanied by specific research traditions institutional constraints in the labor market
exemplified in different methods, theories and into account (Jacoby, 1990; Kaufman, 1993).
paradigms. Ideally, this perspective focused on the rules
In the following sections I will briefly and norms underpinning economic activity,
outline the historical development of IR viewing institutions of work and employment
research in the three countries.2 Generalizing as embedded within, and largely inseparable
and classifying national traditions is a poten- from, broader social, economic, and political
tially problematic task. Research is never institutions (Godard, 1994: 1).
homogeneous and there are always alternative One should note that these early theo-
lines of research. Note that this chapter does rists were not radical progressives however,
not attempt to achieve a complete coverage of but liberals and conservatives at the same
the field of study in each country but merely time. They were liberals in their desire
wishes to outline its main, comparatively for reforming some of the social processes
distinctive features. operating in the US society and conservatives
in their desire to preserve the contours
of a capitalist system and the parameters
United States
of wealth and power therein (DeBrizzi,
The first IR course in the US was created 1983: 8). As Commons would have put it,
at the University of Wisconsin in 1920. they wanted to preserve capitalism by making
Other universities such as the University of it good. It comes as no surprise that when
Pennsylvania (Wharton Business School, the IRAA was established in 1920 the top
1921) and Princeton (1922) and Harvard positions were taken over by pro-management
(1923) followed. In the same year the National conservatives. Their publication personnel
Association of Employment Managers became dominated by the conservatives and
changed its name to the IRAA (Industrial adopted a strident anti-communist tone that
Relations Association of America), which spilled over into more general anti-labor
was a forerunner of the current professional sentiments (in particular against militant
association, IRRA/LERA (Labor and workers) but continued to remain agnostic
Employment Relations Association), which on the question of collective bargaining
was created in 1947. After the end of (Kimmel, 2000: 197).
World War II IR became increasingly Moreover, the pioneers of the field in the
institutionalized as an independent field of Anglophone world, Commons in the US and
study in various US universities. the Webbs in Britain, were heavily engaged in
Historically IR as an academic field was the world of public policy (Hyman, 2001). IR
founded in the US by institutional or political was therefore developed as a policy-oriented
economists, such as Richard Ely, Henry Carter field of research, thus devoted to problem-
Adams and John Commons (the founder of solving (Kaufman, 2004: 117).
the Wisconsin School), who were heavily IR in the US arose as a relatively pragmatic,
influenced by the German historical school socially progressive reform movement, thus
of economics and felt increasingly alienated
occupying a position in the progressive centre to
in their economics departments which began moderate left on issues of politics and economics,
to turn towards neo-classical paradigms and spanning a diverse and not entirely consistent
at the beginning of the twentieth century range of opinion with liberal business leaders on the
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 37

more conservative side of the field and moderate employee welfare, for example (Commons,
socialists on the more radical side. (Kaufman, 1919: 167).
2004: 2)
The managerialists, on the other side of
The aim was to solve the labor problem the spectrum, embraced, according to Kimmel
without threatening capitalism. As Kaufman (2000), scientific expertise and objectivity as
(2004: 121) states ‘the goals of efficiency, the defining features of their profession and
equity and human self-development were assumed a harmony between employers and
mutually served by an active, broad-ranging employees. Their task was to discover the
program of social and industrial reform’. In source of problems in ‘sick’ companies where
other words, IR sought major change in the workplace relations were not harmonious
legal rights, management, and conditions of and then to cure them. They used scientific
labor in industry, but at the same time was techniques for ‘adjusting’ workers to industry,
conservative and non-Marxist in that it sought drawing in particular on industrial and
to reform the existing social order rather than social psychology. The idea was to improve
replace it with a new one. In fact, Marxists workplace relations by a special profession
were antagonistic to the new field of IR since which would apply in particular the new
it sought to save through reform what they science of psychology to the ‘human factor’
hoped to replace by revolution (Kaufman, in industry.
1993: 5). Over time, the more reform-oriented HR
At the same time, HR practitioners (or what members of the management profession
was formerly called personnel management) found themselves increasingly marginal-
and managerial scholars also became inter- ized (Shenhav, 2002: 187). The triumph
ested in the wider field of work and of managerialists meant a sharp split
employment (Kaufman, 1993: 19). Already between psychological approaches and polit-
in the 1910s there was increasing inter- ical and economic approaches to the study
est in the scientific engineering of human of IR. Managerialists favored psychologi-
capital, as symbolized in the work by cal approaches which were seen as more
Frederick W. Taylor (Principles of Scientific objective. Industrial psychology became very
Management, 1911). According to Kimmel popular during WWI and thereafter and was
(2000: 5), by the end of WWI, however, increasingly regarded as the solution to the
academic researchers and practitioners in labor problem (Shenhav, 2002: 183). This
personnel management split in two camps, shift of the new profession of personnel
the ‘reformists’ and ‘managerialists’. The management away from reform and toward
reformists adopted liberal values and contin- ‘science’ also entailed a move away from a
ued to support progressive ideas of capitalist broad treatment of work and employment as
reforms and saw a role for personnel managers involving economic and political, as well as
to meditate between workers and employers psychological and social factors, towards a
interests. ‘They defined their professional narrow treatment of IR/HR as a fundamentally
task as the regulation of labor relations psychological concern (Kimmel, 2000: 311).
in the public interest and the oversight This approach gained dominance during the
of collective dealings between employers 1930s and 1940s. In 1922 business leaders
and employees’ (Kimmel, 2000: 6). These even found their own rival organization to
scholars and practitioners would borrow from promote the field of employment/personnel
the theory and methods of the institutional management. The American Management
labor economists. They were part of a wider Association (AMA), as it was named, cam-
progressive group of policy makers and paigned vigorously for the open shop and
scholars from different disciplines who came against organized labor. Thus, increasingly in
to the joint conviction that modern industries the early twentieth century the rising academic
would need reform such as an employ- field of management excluded concerns with
ment department which would promote labor from their industry and personnel studies
38 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and pushed those reformist scholars interested (in the tradition of the Hawthorne experi-
to the evolving field of study of IR (Shenhav, ments) were clearly the leading disciplines in
2002: 187). the field of IR in the US.
As a consequence, institutional economists After WWII the split between the two
interested in IR and reformist HR scholars economic and psychological groups became
shared in the beginning a common interest larger and the field became increasingly
in pragmatic research leading to solutions dominated by labor economists and other
of the labor problems. However, over time institutionally oriented scholars interested
disagreements arose in particular over trade in collective bargaining (Jacoby, 2003;
unions and collective bargaining (as one Kaufman, 1993). Thus, the quasi-stable co-
possible regulatory solution) and the two existence of HR and IR started to disintegrate
factions eventually split but learnt to co- in the 1970s and 1980s when the New
exist and to divide the problem of work and Deal system of collective labor relations
employment between them, with personnel began to break down. Labor economists
types handling the ‘human element’ and IR have since then increasingly dominated the
experts handling the material and collective LERA activities and research programs as
aspects of labor relations (Kimmel, 2000: well as publications (Kaufman, 1993: 193).
312). For Kaufman (1993: 20), this divide According to Kaufman (ibid.: 155) it is no
remained a characteristic feature of the surprise that the past academic presidents
field over the following decades. These of the LERA were all labor economists.
complicated developments partly explain why Similarly, Mitchell (2001: 375) agrees that IR
today there are two sorts of HR scholars research in the US was always dominated by
in the US: the ones in the IR field under labor economic paradigms, and probably now
the umbrella of LERA and the HR and OB even more than in its high days, in the 1950s
scholars which belong to the Academy of and 1970s.
Management. Another reason may also be the As mainstream economics developed dur-
growing divide between business schools and ing the 1970s toward a sharply focused analyt-
free-standing schools of labor relations. ical discipline with a strong methodological
It comes as no surprise that the broad field of consensus centering on model-building and
IR was perceived as an interdisciplinary study on the statistical-empirical verification of
rather than a distinctive discipline (Kaufman, largely mathematical theoretical hypotheses
1993: 12). For example, as the director of (Solow, 1997) this unsurprisingly also had an
the IR section at Princeton 1926–1954, J. D. impact on labor economics and IR and ended
Brown, states, IR should include ‘all factors, up marginalizing the institutionalists. Thus,
conditions, problems and policies involved labor economics developed from an original
in the employment of human resources in institutional focus towards increasingly neo-
organized production or service’ (quoted in classical (rational choice) paradigms (Boyer
Kaufman, 1993: 201). However, interdis- and Smith, 2001; Jacoby, 1990). Strauss
ciplinarity was in reality pretty narrowly and Feuille (1978: 535) argue that ‘if
defined. The leading assumption was that the collective bargaining represents industrial
field should investigate a broad terrain by relations central core, then labor economics
combining economics as well as psychology has largely divorced itself from that core’.
(see for example the Committee on Industrial Labor economists are currently more inter-
Relations in their overview of the field of ested in micro level studies such as skill-
study in 1926, quoted in Kimmel, 2000: 304). wage differentials, labor contracts or training
Interdisciplinary research did not mean the (for example the leading Cambridge School
dynamic interplay of related disciplines such in US labor economics) than institutional
as political science, sociology or history and research. Thus, institutionalism may have lost
their different methodologies and paradigms. its theoretical link to labor economics (Jacoby,
Labor economics and social psychology 2003). This development can be linked to the
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 39

declining importance of institutions in the US London School of Economics (LSE) entitled


labor market such as trade unions or collective ‘Economic problems of industrial relations’.
bargaining. Only in the 1950s were academic appoint-
In sum, it comes as no surprise that ments in IR made, first at the LSE, and then
labor economics has dominated much of Manchester and Oxford. The British counter-
US IR research from its very beginning. part to LERA, BUIRA (British Universities
Not only are most authors of American IR Industrial Relations Association), was estab-
publications labor economists but research lished in 1950 and in the beginning only
methods, theories and paradigms of the targeted academics and hesitated to accept
majority of US publications are also shaped practitioners for a long time. This was very
by labor economics (Frege, 2005). As outlined different to LERA, respectively IRAA, of
above, this does not deny the existence of course which in the beginning was composed
a large contingent of US labor scholars largely of business people with an interest in
who use non-economic, multi-disciplinary HR (Kaufman, 1993: 5).
theories and methodologies, but compared to Scholarly work on IR issues in Britain
other countries the share of labor economists however started much earlier with Beatrice
dominates the field. Thus, mainstream Amer- and Sidney Webb, who wrote the first classics
ican IR research is commonly character- in the field (Industrial Democracy, 1897;
ized by empirical, quantitative, deductive History of Trade Unionism, 1920) with their
research with multi-variant statistics and mid- insights into the dynamics of unionism and
range hypotheses and focused on the micro- bargaining and which have been constantly
level (individual or groups of employees) referred to by later generations of IR scholars.
(Frege, 2005; Mitchell, 2001; Whitfields It could easily be argued that the Webbs were
and Strauss, 2000). Moreover, most IR the true founders of the Anglophone field of
theories are borrowed from economics or IR rather than Commons (Gospel, 2005: 5).
psychology and produce rational choice or Also G. D. H. Cole, the outstanding Fabian
strategic choice hypotheses or behavioristic, of the post-Webb generation (McCarthy,
social-psychological approaches (Cappelli, 1994: 201) had a huge influence on the
1985: 98; Godard, 1994). There is also field. Cole founded Labor Studies in Oxford.
evidence that research published in American Cole’s early ‘memorandum’ advocated public
IR journals, has increasingly focused on ownership and workers’ control (McCarthy,
HR rather than IR issues (Frege, 2005). 1994: 202). However, most of these scholars,
Finally, with regard to the underlying research though utterly political and interested in
paradigms it is commonly suggested that transforming the country by reforming the
mainstream US research has generally inter- institutions of capitalism ultimately stayed
preted IR as a labor market outcome and within the parameters of liberalism similar
has been driven by a paradigm of contractual to their counterparts in the US (Katznelson,
laissez-faire which was traditionally defined 1996: 27).
as free collective bargaining and is now In contrast with the US however, though
increasingly perceived as an individualistic British economists had an interest in the
contractual system (Finkin, 2002). field, IR as a more institutionalized study
was mainly developed by a heterogeneous
group of scholars who founded the so-called
Britain
Oxford School of Industrial Relations, such
British universities were initially more reluc- as Fox and Clegg who studied PPE (Politics,
tant than their US counterparts to welcome a Philosophy and Economics) in Oxford and
new field of social science research and the Flanders (who did not have an undergraduate
first university course in IR appeared in the degree at all). The field was characterized by
early 1930s when the Nobel-prize economist ‘a strong current of positivist Fabian social
John Hicks offered a lecture series at the engineering, common sense and Anglophone
40 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

empiricism’ not too dissimilar to the early What developed from this Marxist
US research (Ackers and Wilkinson, 2003: 8) approach were sophisticated ethnographic
though it stayed more inter-disciplinary and case studies mainly by industrial sociologists
kept its institutional and historical approach such as Batstone et al. (1977), for example,
to IR for much longer. Gospel (2005: 3) char- and studies of the ‘Labor Process’ school.
acterized this approach as mainly focused on Yet, this radicalization did not last. As Wood
the ‘institutions of job regulation’, especially (2000: 3) describes, ‘in the 1980s sociology
trade unions and collective bargaining. as the key discipline within IR tended to
There was no real split between IR and give way to economics. This partly reflected
HR scholars in Britain. This was partly the advent of neo-liberalism, as well as the
because the field was less under the control of past failings of the institutionalists to analyze
institutional economists than in the US, partly economic problems such as productivity’.
because behavioral sciences such as industrial Ackers and Wilkinson (2003: 12) put it into a
psychology were much less developed in political perspective:
British universities at that time. Moreover, the
the discipline’s best response to [Thatcher and] the
leading paradigm was a pluralistic approach New Right was a skeptical empiricism. Following
to IR, thus the acceptance of different political defeat, and in the absence of any new
interests between labor and capital and the ideas, there grew a highly quantitative new empiri-
conviction that conflict can be regulated cism, centered around the Workplace Industrial
Relations Surveys (Cully et al., 1998; Millward
benefiting both parties (positive sum game).
et al., 2000), a unique national, longitudinal data
This pluralistic perception of the labor market set on the state of British workplace relations.
and of industrial unrest became a defining IR spent much of the 1980s and early 1990s
characteristic of the academic field in Britain, counting, measuring, and at times denying, the very
more so than in the US. It was also more obvious dismantling of Clegg’s ‘system of industrial
relations’.
accepted by the wider British public.
The 1970s saw the rise of a more In a nutshell, British IR developed a co-
radical Marxist frame of reference which existence of sociological qualitative and
opposed the pluralist desire of reaching econometric quantitative studies, the latter
stable employment relations and focused being as exemplified in particular in the pub-
instead on class struggle and the subversion lications of the British Journal of Industrial
of the capitalist system. The radicalization Relations.
of the 1968 student revolution affected IR Finally, with regard to the research prac-
scholars and a new generation of academics, tices there is evidence to suggest that the field
in particular sociologists, rejuvenated the has been traditionally dominated by IR/HR
personnel of the discipline and added much scholars rather than by labor economists as
needed rigor to its theoretical and method- in the US but also that the field remains
ological approaches (Gall, 2003). Prominent more inter-disciplinary than in the US. Based
examples are Hyman’s Industrial Relations: on a longitudinal cross-country survey of
A Marxist Introduction (1975), or Fox’s later IR journal publications during the 1970s
work Beyond Contract: Work, Power and and 1990s authors publishing in the UK are
Trust Relations (1974). This Marxist stream mostly affiliated as HR/IR scholars rather than
was much less dominant in the US. The economists but that there is nevertheless a
general absence of Marxist social sciences wider range of other affiliations compared
in the US has been widely documented to the US (Frege, 2005). Also, there is no
(Ross, 1991) and British social sciences are evidence that the decline of traditional IR
commonly perceived as more progressive and institutions such as trade unions and collective
ideological than those in the US (but less bargaining in Britain has lead to a declining
progressive and more pragmatic compared academic interest. In contrast, research on
to continental Europe) (Katznelson, 1996: 18 IR issues such as unions has been stronger
and 40). during the 1990s in British publication
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 41

outlets compared to the 1970s, for example. industrial relations) the academic community
Moreover, the majority of British IR research directly associated with IR is still quite small.
has been characterized as mainly empirical but The German section of the IIRA (GIRA,
more qualitative, inductive and if quantitative established in 1970) counted 80 members in
then less based on econometrical analysis 1995 (verses 520 BUIRA members in Britain
compared to the US (Capelli, 1985). The or 3850 LERAmembers in the US in 1995). Of
major focus of research tends to be the level those members virtually all are affiliated with
of the firm rather than of the individual as in a department of sociology or another social
the US (Frege, 2005). Finally, IR has been science discipline.
traditionally defined as labor market outcomes Moreover, an overview of Industrielle
as in the US though over the years the state and Beziehungen, the only specialized IR journal
legislation became to be seen as increasingly in Germany, between 1994 (its founding date)
important in shaping IR. Moreover, there and 2004 reveals that published research
is a long tradition of analyzing workplace has been conducted by researchers with
relations in political terms (labor process a wide array of specializations: industrial
debate). The traditional research paradigm sociologists, labor lawyers, political scien-
can be described using Kahn-Freund’s famous tists, business administration scholars and
terminology ‘collective laissez-faire’ (Davies economists (Frege, 2005). Rarely does anyone
and Freedland, 2002) though individual call themself an IR scholar. Industrial sociolo-
employment contracts are increasingly taking gists are in the clear majority. One should also
over collective regulations. note that there is hardly any cross-disciplinary
communication. Business administration or
law scholars for example are rarely cited in the
Germany
industrial sociology literature and vice-versa
In Germany employment studies have a long (Muller, 1999: 468). The field is really multi-
tradition going back to Karl Marx, Max rather than inter-disciplinary.
Weber, Lujo Brentano and Goetz Briefs. Industrial sociology has made the most
During the twentieth century the field became significant contribution to the study of IR
dominated by law, political science, but (Keller, 1996). Its central focus are core IR
most prominently by sociology with the first issues such as bargaining policies, working
university institute specializing in industrial time, technical change and rationalization,
sociology in 1928 at the Technical University and their impact on work organization and
Berlin (Keller, 1996; Mueller-Jentsch, 2001). social structure, but not labor market issues
Despite the fact that the relationship between (Baethge and Overbeck, 1986; Kern and
capital and labor and the emergence of interest Schumann, 1984; Schumann et al., 1994).
institutions were discussed in German social From its very beginning industrial sociology
sciences from the mid-nineteenth century, IR included a much larger field of topics com-
was, however, not established as an indepen- pared to industrial sociology in Anglophone
dent academic discipline (Keller, 1996: 199). countries. German industrial sociology was
There is no IR department in any German closely connected to social philosophy and
university. The same is true for all other general sociology and in fact regarded as its
continental European countries. major sub-discipline (Mueller-Jentsch, 2001:
Research on work and employment issues 222; Schmidt et al., 1982). It positioned
remained the subject of various social science itself within the broader societal context of
disciplines. A few indicators should suffice industrialization, and focused in particular on
to support this observation. First, although the role of organized labor.
there have been increasing attempts in recent Max Weber initiated the first systematic
years to establish an IR discipline in Germany sociological research on German industry
(for example the establishment of Indus- under the patronage of the ‘Verein fuer
trielle Beziehungen – the German journal of Socialpolitik’ (first empirical research on
42 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

industrial work in large German firms) in (Mueller-Jentsch, 2001: 229). Industrial soci-
the late nineteenth century. The famous ology quickly became a major focus (Maurer,
‘Verein fuer Socialpolitik’, founded in 1872 2004: 7). In the early years after the war
by academics of the German historical school, sociologists were primarily concerned with
intended to establish social fairness between whether the political democracy introduced
capital and labor (Mueller-Jentsch 2001: by the Allies would stabilize in Germany.
223). Goetz Briefs developed the field of There was a common conviction that democ-
‘Betriebssoziologie’ (sociology of the firm), racy is not only about institutions but that
later subsumed under ‘Industriesoziologie’ it also needs a cultural basis in society.
(industrial sociology) which became a major According to v. Friedeburg (1997: 26) the
approach of research during the 1920s and fear was that class conflicts either become
1930s (Mueller-Jentsch, 2001: 222). Another too strong that they endanger the democ-
major research project of the ‘Verein’ was ratization process or that they become too
launched in the first decade of the twentieth weak and endanger the reform potential of
century on the selection and adjustment of the labor movement. Thus, the belief was
workers in different segments of German that only self-conscious workers could be
industry (1910–15). According to Mueller- a counterweight to the restorative forces in
Jentsch (ibid.: 224) this was the beginning post-war Germany. As a consequence many
of systematic industrial research in Germany. sociologists focused on exploring worker
The core question was what kind of men consciousness and beliefs, traditional IR
are shaped by modern industry and which topics.
job prospects (and indirectly life chances) do The first explicit project on IR after WWII
big enterprises offer them? Weber wrote a was conducted by industrial sociologists in
long introduction to the research project and the late 1970s at the Institute for Social
outlined various questions to be addressed: Research in Frankfurt (Bergmann et al.,
social and geographical origins of the work- 1979). The project entailed a large empirical
force; the principles of their selection; the project on trade unions in Germany from an
physical and psychological conditions of explicitly sociological point of view (Mueller-
the work process; job performance; pre- Jentsch, 1982: 408). In the same year IR
conditions and prospects of careers; how was first introduced as an official topic at
workers adjust to factory life; their family the German sociological congress (Berliner
situation and leisure time (Mueller-Jentsch Soziologentag, 1979). It is also symptomatic
ibid.: 224). Methodology was based on that the first German textbook on IR was
interviews and participant observation in written by an industrial sociologist, Walther
selected companies. Mueller-Jentsch (1986) and called Sociology
Mueller-Jentsch (2001) argues that indus- of Industrial Relations.
trial sociology at that time was heavily shaped To conclude, German IR research has
by the notion of workers exploitation and this traditionally been dominated by industrial
was advanced not just by Marxists but also by sociologists. Research focuses on IR rather
liberal scholars. Lujo Brentano, for example, than HR issues, is more theoretical or
was an early liberal economist and antipode essayistic than empirical and if empirical
of Marx and Engels but argued that ‘trade favors qualitative, inductive research (Frege,
unions play a constitutional role in capitalist 2005; Hetzler, 1995). The focus is on the
economies since they empower employees firm level like in Britain. The dominant
to behave like sellers of commodities. Only paradigm is to interpret IR as a socio-political
the unions enable workers to adjust their process, thus as being shaped by economic as
supply according to market conditions’ (ibid: well as political forces, and the emphasis is
225). on corporatist social partnership approaches
After WWII sociology was gradually rather than collective bargaining (Hyman,
(re)established as an academic discipline 1995: 39; 2004).
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 43

RESEARCH VARIATIONS AND THEIR patterns which seem, so far, astonishingly


NATIONAL EMBEDDEDNESS resistant to processes of universalization.
How then can we explain the ongoing
The above brief overview has revealed differ- diversity and persistence of national research
ent national developments in the IR research traditions? The chapter now turns to explore
field. In the US labor economics was, from the longstanding roots of national IR research
the early days, the leading discipline in IR profiles in specific structural, institutional and
research, initially with a strong institutional, political constellations within which social
policy orientation which was subsequently scientists have tried to develop discursive
taken over by a more neo-classical approach understandings of their IR systems. For
to labor markets. In Britain prominent social example, a theory may gain acceptance in the
reformers started the field and hence IR field not simply because it provides the most
developed a strongly pragmatic public policy ‘adequate’explanation for a phenomenon, but,
orientation which was less influenced by labor rather, because the explanation it does offer
economists. Moreover, it received a strong is in a form that is particularly attractive
Marxist influence during the 1970s which was to a specific national culture or a particular
unparalleled in the US. The field became more group of scholars who are leading in the
inter-disciplinary than its US counterpart and field.
became dominated by scholars who received Explaining research variation is of course
a degree in IR. Finally, Germany has a long an ambitious enterprise. No one single factor
intellectual (Marxist and liberal) tradition can explain the variations across the different
on researching work and employment issues research traditions. The inquiry seems to
which has been traditionally dominated by require a complex set of multiple factors,
industrial sociologists. Whereas the field has reaching into various disciplines, and in need
not established institutional independence in of a historical and comparative analysis. Thus,
Germany but remains multi-disciplinary, IR for the study of IR research, ideally, it seems
became an independent academic field in the one would need a comparative history of IR
US and Britain. and its ideas in Britain, Germany and the
At the same time it comes to no surprise that US, a history of knowledge production, a
all three countries reveal variations in their history of the relations between IR and related
research practices: their major methodologies, disciplines, a history of influential academics
theories and research paradigms. These vari- in the field and a social history (students
ations have been shown to be long-standing and their background). We would also need
national academic profiles (Frege, 2005; a theory to interconnect historical, structural
Kaufman, 2004; Whitfield and Strauss, 2000). and cognitive determinants and the actions
Such diversity of research styles undermines of scientific community (Weingart, 1976).
assumptions of a universal, linear evolution However, as Fourcade-Gourinchas (2001:
of social sciences and it also challenges 398) argues, we do not yet have a satisfactory
recent claims that globalization will evoke encompassing theory of knowledge formation
a convergence of scientific research to a that would allow us to account simultaneously
universal, if not US-led model. Thus, at for the social structures and institutions of
this stage there is evidence of a continu- knowledge production and for the latter’s
ing national embeddedness of IR research intrinsic, substantive ideational nature. And
despite the growing internationalization of we have no theoretical framework to ana-
academia (international conferences, cross- lyze cross-cultural variations between social
national research collaborations, exchange science disciplines.
programs etc.) and despite the increasing The remaining part of this chapter, there-
globalization of IR practices throughout the fore, introduces three preliminary approaches
advanced industrialized world. To conclude, which highlight the embeddedness of IR
there remains distinctive national research research in its national-specific context.
44 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

These are heuristic tools rather than a tight the- Thus, the traditional lack of academic interest
oretical framework, exploring interrelations in the state or in social partnership in the US
between variables rather than determining can be explained by the traditional absence
causalities. The first provides a substantive of the state and of workplace democracy
approach and focuses on how the subject in American IR, whereas their dominance
field of academic inquiry and national IR in German research mirrors their continu-
practices, shape research traditions. The ing relevance for the German employment
second approach highlights the institutional system.
embeddedness of IR research in national In a similar vein, scholars have highlighted
scientific traditions. The third and final that research follows changing policy ques-
approach discusses the relationship between tions (Derber, 1964; Dunlop, 1977; Strauss
national political traditions, in particular and Feuille, 1978). In particular, Capelli
the conception of political and industrial (1985) argues that shifts in research topics
democracy, and IR research. easily occur as a reaction to shifts in
government, union or employer policies.
For example, the increasing interest in HR
IR practices
issues in the US can be understood as a
This approach provides a contextual explana- reaction to the increasing number of non-
tion of cross-country research variations by union workplaces and anti-union employer
linking ‘external’ IR practices to ‘internal’ and/or state strategies. Moreover, should IR
research practices. It is assumed that in regulations and practices increasingly con-
particular research topics, author affiliations verge in a globalizing world (see Chapter 7)
and academic paradigms will mirror the one would expect a simultaneous convergence
development and practice of IR institutions in of research patterns across countries. So far
a specific country. This position is essentially however this does not seem to have happened
functionalist since it assumes an independent (Frege, 2005).
scientific space organized around specific self- There can be no doubt that this approach
referential understandings of the subject field, helps to explain research shifts over time
thus in our case IR practices (Wagner, 1990: in one particular country (for example the
478). In other words, academic disciplines decline of IR and the increase of HR topics
and specializations develop essentially as in the US) but also cross-country variations
structural reactions to changes in the external in research. Moreover, this approach provides
environment. an explanation of why different professions
This assumption is widely acknowledged get interested in researching IR topics. For
among social scientists today and is in example, the more legalistic and corporatist
stark contrast to the original positivist posi- IR systems in continental Europe attract more
tion which argued that scientific inquiry is legal scholars, political scientists and sociolo-
independent of the phenomenon observed gists whereas labor economists are primarily
(Delanty, 1997). Moreover, because IR is a attracted in Anglophone countries where mar-
problem-oriented field of study it is even ket forces play a larger and more accepted role
more likely to be shaped by the real world in determining IR outcomes. The substantive
of IR which differs from country to country. approach is not a sufficient explanation,
As Dunlop states, ‘different interests of however, and for example is not helpful in
academic experts seem largely a reflection of exploring the different development of the
their type of IR system’ (1958: 329). Hyman field of study, thus its institutionalization.
(2001) points out that the different national IR
systems provoke different research topics: for
Scientific traditions
example an emphasis of Anglophone research
on collective bargaining and in Germany A second approach is introduced which
on social partnership and co-determination. is historical in nature and embraces the
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 45

embeddedness of IR research within national The close relationship between knowl-


social science traditions. edge structures and research practices has
It is now widely recognized that social been widely accepted in the literature.
sciences and their disciplines are social Already Merton (1968: 521) observed that
constructs, embedded in specific historical research patterns are influenced by specific
contexts and shaped by national cultures forms of knowledge organization. Fourcade-
and philosophies (Levine, 1995: 100). They Gourinchas (2001: 400) points out that
are not just the outcome of a universal, ‘scientific discourses [research patterns] are
automatic progress of science, nor are they inevitably driven by broader, nationally con-
natural, pre-determined categories, but can stituted, cultural frameworks embodied in
vary from country to country. In Ross’ words specific institutions of knowledge produc-
(1991: 1), ‘the content and borders of the tion’. And Ringer (1992: 26) convincingly
disciplines that resulted in the beginning of the proposes that intellectual communities such
twentieth century were as much the product as academic disciplines cannot be adequately
of national cultures, local circumstances discussed without reference to the history of
and accidental opportunities as intellectual educational systems in each country which are
logic’. In particular, the development of heavily dependent on the specific relationship
social sciences was closely connected to between state and society.
the rise of modern universities and were Applied to our context, this trajectory links
shaped by national epistemological tradi- the existence or absence of the institution-
tions. alization of the IR field to the different
national university structures. Arguably, the
development of the German university struc-
University structures ture of professorial chairs enabled a broader
It is during the late-nineteenth century in research agenda for the individual professors
particular that universities were resurrected but hindered the institutionalization of inter-
as primary knowledge-producing institutions disciplinary fields. In contrast, the more for-
and that the idea of a research-oriented mal departmental structure as developed in the
university became predominant in Europe US in the early-twentieth century, which was
and the US (Wittrock, 1993: 305). This later also introduced to British universities,
development was closely related to the rise of narrowed the individual’s research area but
the modern nation-state and the new economic facilitated the creation of institutionalized
capitalist order. Universities therefore came inter-disciplinary fields.
to be key institutions both for knowl- In other words, the strict classification of
edge production, in particular technological disciplines in US universities, which became
progress and for strengthening a sense of more dominant than in Europe (Wagner, 1990:
national and cultural identity (ibid.: 321). 236), made it more difficult for individual
As we will see, however, they developed scholars to integrate IR topics into their
in different ways in different countries. own discipline but on the other hand created
Major questions which were debated in the opportunity to establish specific inter-
all countries were, for example, between disciplinary programs. US social science dis-
the pros and cons of a liberal versus ciplines tend to follow a strict methodological
vocational education and pure versus applied and theoretical canon and are more likely
research. to discriminate alternative views. In Ross’
The national-specific structures of univer- (1991: 10) words,
sities are useful in explaining the institutional
differences within IR research, thus its the importance of disciplines and disciplinary
professions to stabilize academic positions in the US
institutionalization as a field of study in the system lead frequently to an ontological purification
Anglophone world but not in continental of disciplinary discourses by excluding outside
Europe. factors to strengthen disciplinary identification
46 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

whereas in Europe disciplines were less inhibited to Epistemological traditions


use theoretical concepts from other disciplines. In addition to the university structures,
epistemological traditions also shaped the
The fact that in the US, IR institutes were first development and patterns of scientific dis-
created by institutional economists who felt ciplines in each country. These traditions
increasingly left out of their own discipline, help explain, for example, why a German
substantiates this point. and a US sociologist working on similar
In Germany, the Humboldtian reforms in labor issues may use different research tools,
the second part of the nineteenth century in particular different methodologies, despite
supported an organizational structure around their shared profession. And why a British
chairs which traditionally allowed a slightly economist and a British sociologist may have
less rigid definition of the disciplines. Individ- something in common despite their different
ual professors were more able to follow their professions. In other words, it may provide
own interests independent of the mainstream. an explanation as to why the US is gen-
Thus, a sociology or law professor interested erally leaning toward quantitative empirical
in labor found it easier to follow this research whereas German IR research is
research topic even if it did not fit completely usually characterized by qualitative research
with disciplinary boundaries. Therefore there and Britain exhibits traces of both; or why both
was less need to establish inter-disciplinary US and British IR research tend to produce
forums. An additional reason was that inter- intermediate, middle-range theories whereas
disciplinary, specialized or vocational fields Germany is biased toward more abstract,
had less chance to get accepted because of general social science theories (Bulmer,
the traditional German emphasis on general, 1991).
pure knowledge creation which was fostered Modern philosophies of knowledge devel-
by Humboldt. oped during the eighteenth and nineteenth
Finally, Britain is characterized by a less centuries and influenced the countries’ con-
rigid disciplinary structure than the US but ception of knowledge creation. In short, the
also by weaker professorial chairs than in idealist philosophy and humanistic university
Germany. Britain for a long time almost reforms during the nineteenth century in
exclusively focused on elitist undergradu- Germany were strongly oriented toward
ate education dominated by colleges and science for its own sake (‘pure science’)
neglecting the development of graduate or rather than to be an instrument for larger
professional schools like in the US (Fourcade- societal purposes (for example improving
Gourinchas, 2001: 165). The great British social conditions) as it became the norm in
universities in the nineteenth century were particular in the US. There was an empha-
strongly anti-professional. Professional edu- sis on holistic thinking in broad historical
cation was dominated by practitioners outside cultural categories and being informed by
universities (Burrage, 1993: 155). Moreover, a philosophy which rejected narrow-minded
British universities for a long time developed specialization which provided a challenge
as relatively insular, elitist institutions empha- to mechanistic and compositional thinking
sizing the classical subjects while neglecting prevalent in Europe at that time. As a con-
natural as well as social sciences. The first sequence, when social sciences (including the
social science research which arose out of academic treatment of work and employment)
a response to the increasing social problems were slowly established at the end of the
of industrialization developed outside the nineteenth century they became mostly con-
university such as in the famous Manchester cerned with elaborating a coherent theoretical
Statistical Society (1833) (Manicas, 1987: framework for societal analysis based on
196). Thus, all these factors help to explain philosophical foundations (Wittrock et al.,
why IR as an inter-disciplinary study was 1991: 41). Social sciences were originally
delayed for a long time in Britain. interpreted as historical sciences embedded
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 47

in the humanities. This shaped the tendency the social conditions of modern society. Thus,
of the social sciences toward descriptive, whereas British social sciences started as a
historical, qualitative and theoretical research fusion of analysis and (moral) prescription,
as we can still observe today, for example in the US eventually favored a more scientific,
the case of IR research. Efforts at empirical detached approach to social questions which
research were very fragmented as well as was modeled upon natural sciences (Bulmer,
policy-oriented research which could hardly 1991: 152). This ultimately induced a bias
develop in the shadow of formal theorizing toward an empiricist ideology with a focus
(Wittrock, ibid.). This may have induced the on quantitative scientific methods in the US
strong presence of hermeneutic and Marxist (Ross, 1991).
epistemological approaches and heuristic In sum, these national knowledge systems,
methodologies in German social sciences. In which originated in the nineteenth century,
a nutshell, one can argue that these traditions shape the different ways in which social
may have facilitated a more political and sciences and therefore IR research have been
critical awareness of social conditions and organized and practiced in the three countries.
problems. Social science was understood as British IR research, for example, always
a tool to explore the genesis of modern had a stronger public-policy agenda than the
society and it fostered the importance of US and was less interested in perfecting
academic freedom and supported the pursuit econometric tools for measuring IR practices
of pure knowledge rather than of instrumental, and outcomes. German IR research on the
pragmatic research. other hand has been heavily theory driven and
In Britain social sciences were caught in if empirical has mainly pursued hermeneutic,
the bind between the positivistic heritage descriptive methods.
of moralistic reformism and administrative
(empirical) knowledge (Delanty, 1997: 26).
Political traditions
Thus, they were characterized by a strong
positivist-utilitarian tradition, methodological The cross-national variation of subject fields,
individualism and a naturalistic morality. as well as, the scientific traditions are a
British social sciences essentially go back to necessary but not sufficient explanation for
Hobbes’ utilitarianism and his ideas based cross-national research variation. For exam-
on the methods of natural science (Halevy, ple, similar research topics can be researched
1966: 153). J. S. Mill for example, who was in very different ways. The fact that the US
heavily influenced by Hobbes, was critical of traditionally has a strong interest in HR policy
scientific politics and stood for a model of whereas German academics are more inter-
‘useful’ knowledge. Empiricism was praised ested in the labor process – both approaches
as an inductive science of general causal laws. look at the workplace – indicates the existence
On the other side, British social science was of different paradigms and aims of research.
characterized by a moral focus and science German social scientists have traditionally
was linked to the idea of moral improve- been more concerned about the labor process
ment and a humane secular ethic (Delanty, and its outcomes for workers as a social
1997: 26). As Manicas (1987: 197) highlights, class than their mainstream US counterparts
the social problems of the industrializing who are more interested in individual work
British Empire were interpreted by the British attitudes and workplace efficiency. These
academic elite as a moral problem and were, variations cannot be sufficiently explained on
accordingly, a problem of how to restore the the basis of different subject fields or scientific
morals of individuals. traditions.
The US developed in similar ways to A third and final factor then, is the political
Britain but with a more scientist, pragmatic embeddedness of the research field. The
approach to the sciences, in particular social assumption is that political traditions have a
sciences which was seen as a tool to improve certain independence of their subject matter
48 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and of their academic institutionalization and nationalize important industries and is in


can shape research patterns in different ways. general more committed to state intervention
In particular research paradigms, aims and than the US (Jacoby, 2003: 49).
also theories are likely to be influenced by In Germany, the main understanding was to
political ideas. perceive the firm as a ‘quasi-public affair’, as
I focus on the national political discourse a social community, a state within the state,
on work and democracy which originates a constitutional monarchy, where workers
in the nineteenth century. I argue that would receive certain democratic rights and
the philosophical traditions of idealism in the monarch/owner would not have absolute
Germany or of liberalism and positivism power as in a constitutional monarchy. ‘The
in Britain and the US shaped the political employment relationship is not seen as one
understanding and subsequent writings on the of free subordination but of democratization’.
state, democracy and the economy during the This was the declaration of the famous
nineteenth century. In particular, the relation- Weimar labor law scholar, Hugo Sinzheimer
ship between political and industrial democ- (Finkin, 2002: 621). One could also say
racy crucially influenced the development that the US and Britain focused on ‘private
of different research paradigms. The three contracts’ whereas Germany focused on a
countries developed during the nineteenth ‘social contract’ within the firm, to adopt
century rather different political traditions on Rousseau’s phrase.
the relationship between state, society and The distinction between a private and pub-
economy which shaped two different streams lic view of the firm has a clear reminiscence
of interpretations of industrial democracy: to the mechanic and organic state theories
an Anglophone and a German (conti- and to civil and common law traditions. The
nental European) stream. Germany devel- role of the entrepreneur is seen differently in
oped a legalistic, state-oriented approach both traditions. In the Anglophone common
(co-determination) whereas Britain and the law tradition the enterprise is the property
US developed a free collective bargain- of the entrepreneur with workers relegated
ing approach (and eventually voluntary, to contractual claims, at best, on the surplus
employer-led direct participation schemes). from production (Deakin, 2005: 12). The con-
Both constitutional traditions are based on tinental or in our case German entrepreneurs
two distinct concepts of industrial democracy are members of the enterprise community and
which I call ‘contractual’ and ‘communal’. share duties and privileges that this position
In essence, the US and Britain regarded entails.
the capitalist enterprise as a ‘private affair’ One can conclude therefore that democracy
(firm as private property) and the economy in the US and to a lesser extent in Britain
as an assembly of free individuals joining has been mainly conceptualized at a political
in contractual relationships. Private con- level and developed a much weaker place
tracts rule. Industrial democracy is therefore in economic life where democracy is limited
focused on the free bargaining between to certain individual rights and a minimum
employers and employees. Moreover, the law of collective rights (for example free labor
privileges individual rather than collective contracts and collective bargaining). In other
employment rights. One should note the words, the individual has only very limited
differences between Britain and the US: democratic rights at work, the main right being
between a social democratic and a liberal to be in a free contractual relationship and
divide on industrial democracy the US emerge therefore to be able to leave the contract.
virtually exclusively on the liberal side of the The focus of Anglophone labor law on
line (Katznelson, 1996: 40). Britain, on the individual rights therefore has a long tradition.
other hand, is slightly more infatuated with Today this is emphasized even more in the
markets and experienced times, in particular increasing decline of collective labor law and
after WWI and II, of socialist attempts to the dominance of identity-based employee
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 49

rights in particular in the US. In contrast, IR field, do not necessarily develop in similar
in Germany industrial democracy has been ways across countries but are embedded
much more linked to the development of in broader national-specific cultures. There
political democracy and has legally restrained is no reason to assume that these varying
managerial discretion. The focus of labor law research styles are deviations from a standard,
is on collective rights. or delays in reaching that standard. On
In sum, this approach highlights the impor- the contrary, the persistence of national
tance of linking national research patterns intellectual profiles over time undermines
to the historically embedded discourses on assumptions of a universal, linear evolution
democracy at work. The different state of the social sciences and instead highlights
philosophies as they developed in Germany, their national historical embeddedness.
Britain and the US during the nineteenth This chapter further explored the embed-
century shaped the perception of the capitalist dedness of these research patterns in their
firm and subsequently the conception of national contexts. On one hand it highlighted
industrial democracy. the significance of national institutions and
Applied to the context of IR the different practices of IR in shaping research outcomes.
intellectual traditions of political and indus- On the other hand, the chapter also reminded
trial democracy can explain certain cross- us to conceptualize IR research as a social
national research differences. For example, scientific field of study which is inevitably
the fact that German scholars traditionally embedded in long-standing national traditions
work on topics related to worker participation of scientific knowledge production, such
may not just be due to their labor institu- as university structures and philosophical
tions promoting democracy at work (‘subject traditions of knowledge creation. Finally, the
field’), but also because of a long-standing chapter outlined the importance of intellec-
intellectual tradition in German social sci- tual conceptions of political and industrial
ences to interpret industrial democracy as an democracy and to what extent and how the
important adjunct to political democracy and workplace was regarded as part of a wider
hence as a value itself. This also explains political democracy.
the interest of German political scientists and To conclude, IR research has developed
lawyers in IR research. In contrast, industrial differently in different countries and there is
democracy in the US for example has not reason to suggest that this will continue for
generally been seen as a precondition or some time. As of today there is no evidence
attribute of political democracy and has been of a significant convergence of research styles
traditionally perceived as individual rights, across countries. Sustained divergence is the
property rights on one side and no forced result so far. This also challenges predictions
labor on the other side. Recent discussions on of various globalization and convergence
employee voice (Freeman and Rogers, 1999) theories of the diminishing significance of
exemplify this individualistic conception of the nation state. This chapter argues instead
industrial democracy (but see exceptions such for the nation state’s enduring importance
as Derber, 1964). at least for the field of scientific knowledge
creation.
However, this does not mean that research
CONCLUSION patterns should be seen as historically
deterministic. They are potentially open for
This chapter has offered a brief description change. Scholars may have had good reasons
of the historical development of IR as a field for choosing their scientific path, which
of research in Britain, Germany and the US, was subsequently institutionalized, but there
which represent trends in the Anglophone were reasons consistently shaped by specific
world as well as in continental Europe. historical and cultural intentions (Ross, 1991).
It suggested that social sciences, such as the Given hindsight, we may find that there are
50 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

better reasons for choosing differently in Capelli, P. (1985) ‘Theory construction in IR and some
the future, in particular given the increasing implications for research’, Industrial Relations, 24 (1):
academic crisis of the IR discipline. Becoming 90–112.
aware of different national approaches, and Committee on Industrial Relations (1926) Advisory
thus of different research options, is a first committee on industrial relations, memorandum, ‘to
the Committee on Policy and Problems’, August 1926,
step. What should follow is a dialogue
Box 59, Folder 331. R.G. 1.8 SSRC. RAC.
between the research patterns; how one could Commons, J. (1919) Industrial Goodwill. New York:
benefit from each other to ensure the long- McGraw-Hill.
term viability of the discipline. Crouch, C. (2005) Capitalist Diversity and Change:
Recombinant Governance and Institutional
Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cully, M., Woodland, S., O’Reilly, A. and Dix, G. (1998)
NOTES
Britain at work: as depicted by the 1998 Workplace
Employee Relations Survey. London: Routledge.
1 For the purposes of this paper, I use this term to
refer to the following countries: Great Britain, Ireland,
Davies, P. and Freedland, M. (2002) ‘National styles in
United States of America, Canada, Australia and New labor law scholarship’, Comparative Labor Law and
Zealand (see Crouch 2005). Policy Journal, 23 (3).
2 For more detailed country overviews see Frege Deakin, S. (2005) ‘Coevolution of law and the economy:
(2007) and Kaufman (2004). industrialization and labor law in Britain and
Continental Europe’, conference paper, Workshop on
Making Markets Through the Law: Legal Claim and
Economic Possibility. Paris, June 2005.
REFERENCES DeBrizzi, J. (1983) Ideology and the Rise of Labor Theory
in America. Westport: Greenwood Press.
Ackers, P. and Wilkinson, A. (eds) (2003) Understanding Delanty, G. (1997) Social Science: Beyond Con-
Work and Employment: Industrial Relations in structivism and Realism. Minneapolis: Minnesota
Transition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. University Press.
Baethge, M. and Overbeck, H. (1986) Zukunft der Derber, M. (1964) ‘Divergent tendencies in IR Research’,
Angestellten. Neue Technologien und berufliche Industrial and Labor Relations Review, XVII, July:
Perspektiven in Büro und Verwaltung. Frankfurt: 598–616.
Campus. Dunlop, J. (1958) Industrial Relations Systems.
Batstone, E., Boraston, I. and Frenkel, S. (1977) Shop New York: Henry Holt & Co.
Stewards in Action: The Organization of Workplace Dunlop, J. (1977) ‘Policy decisions and research in
Conflict and Accommodation. Oxford: Blackwell. economics and industrial relations’, Industrial and
Bergmann, J., Jakobi, O. and Mueller-Jentsch, W. (1979) Labor Relations Review, April: 275–82.
Gewerkschaften in der BRD. Frankfurt am Main: Finkin, M. (2002) ‘Menschenbild: the conception of the
Suhrkamp. employee as a person in western law’, Comparative
Boyer, G. and Smith, R. (2001) ‘The development of the Labor Law and Policy Journal, 23 (2): 577–637
neoclassical tradition in labor economics’, Industrial Fourcade-Gourinchas, M. (2001) ‘Politics, institutional
and Labor Relations Review, 54 (2). structures, and the rise of economics: a comparative
Bulmer, M. (1991) ‘National context for the development study’, Theory and Society, 30: 397–447.
of social-policy research: British and American Fox, A. (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power and Trust
research on poverty and social welfare compared’, Relations. London: Faber.
in P. Wagner, C. Hirschon Weiss, B. Wittrock and H. Freeman, R. and Rogers, J. (1999) What Workers Want.
Wollmann (eds) Social Sciences and Modern States. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 148–67. Frege, C.M. (2005) ‘Varieties of industrial relations
Burrage, M. (1993) ‘From practice to school-based research: take-over, convergence or divergence?’,
professional education: patterns of conflict and British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (2):
accommodation in England, France and the United 179–207.
States’, in S. Rothblatt and B. Wittrock (eds) Frege, C.M. (2007) Employment Research and State Tra-
The European and American University Since ditions. A Comparative History of Britain, Germany,
1800: Historical and Sociological Essays. Cambridge: and the United States. Oxford: Oxford University
Cambridge University Press. Press.
THE HISTORY OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AS A FIELD OF STUDY 51

Gall, G. (2003) ‘Marxism and Industrial Relations’, in Kimmel, J. (2000) Creating A Real Science of Human
P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work Relations: Personnel Management and the Politics
and Employment. Oxford: Oxford University Press. of Professionalism, 1910–1940, PhD Thesis. John
Godard, J. (1994) ‘Beyond empiricism: towards a Hopkins University.
reconstruction of IR theory and research’, Advances Levine, D. (1995) Visions of the Sociological Tradition.
in Industrial and Labor Relations, (6): 1–35. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Gospel, H. (2005) ‘A British and historical perspective McCarthy, W. (1994) ‘The involvement of academics in
on workplace governance’. kaufman and ‘the British industrial relations’, British Journal of Industrial
global evolution of industrial relations’, Industrielle Relations, 32 (2).
Beziehungen, 12 (4): 1–10. Manicas, P. (1987) A History and Philosophy of the Social
Halevy, E. (1966) The growth of philosophical radicalism. Sciences. New York: Basil Blackwell.
Boston: Beacon press. Maurer, A. (2004) ‘Elend und Ende der Arbeits- und
Hetzler, H.W. (1995) ‘25 Jahre Deutsche Sektion Industriesoziologie’, Soziologie, 33 (4): 7–19.
der International Industrial Relations Association - Merton, R. (1968) Social Theory and Social Structure.
Erinnerungen, Erfahrungen und Erwartungen’, Indus- New York: Free Press.
trielle Beziehungen, 2 (3): 312–334. Millward, N., Bryson, A. and Forth, J. (1992) All
Hodgson, G. (2001) How economics forgot history. Change at Work?: British Employee Relations, 1980–
London: Routledge. 1998, Portrayed by the Workplace Industrial Relations
Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist Survey Series. London: Routledge.
Introduction. Basingstoke: MacMillan. Mitchell, D. (2001) ‘IR journal and conference literature
Hyman, R. (1995) ‘Industrial relations in Europe: from the 1960s to the 1990s: what can HR learn
theory and practice’, European Journal of Industrial from it? Where is it headed?’, Human Resource
Relations. 1 (1): 17–46. Management Review, 11: 375–93.
Hyman, R. (2001) Theorizing Industrial Relations: Anglo- Muller, M. (1999) ‘Enthusiastic embrace or critical
American Individualism versus the European Social reception?: The German HRM debate’, Journal of
Model. Working paper, London School of Economics. Management Studies, 35 (4): 465–82.
Hyman (2004) ‘Is Industrial relations theory always Mueller-Jentsch, W. (1982) ‘Gewerkschaften als inter-
ethnocentric?’ in B. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical mediäre Organisationen’, Kölner Zeitschrift für Sozi-
perspectives on Work and the Employment Rela- ologie und Sozialpsychologie, Sonderheft ‘Materialien
tionship. Champaign-Urbana: IRRA Publications. zur Industriesoziologie’, 34: 408–32.
pp. 265–92. Mueller-Jentsch, W. (1986) Soziologie der industriellen
Jacoby, S.M. (2003) ‘Economic ideas and the labor Beziehungen. Frankfurt: Campus.
market: Origins of the Anglo-American Model and Mueller-Jentsch, W. (2001) Germany, chp 11, in
prospects for global diffusion’, Comparative Labor D. Cornfield and R. Hodson (eds) Worlds of
Law and Policy Journal, 25 (1): 43–78. Work: Building an International Sociology of Work.
Jacoby, S.M. (1990) ‘The new institutionalism: what can New York: Kluwer.
it learn from the old?’, Industrial Relations, 29 (2): Ringer, F. (1992) Fields of Knowledge: French Academic
316–359. Culture in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge:
Katznelson, I. (1996) ‘Knowledge about What? Cambridge University Press.
Policy Intellectuals and the New Liberalism’, in Ross, D. (1991) The Origins of American Social Science.
D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol, (eds) States, social Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
knowledge, and the origins of modern social policies. Schmidt, G., Braczyk, H.J., Knesebeck, J.v.d., (1982)
Princeton: Princeton University Press Materialien zur Industriesoziologie’, Koelner
Kaufman, B. (1993) The Origins and Evolution of the Zeitschrift fuer Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie.
Field of Industrial Relations in the United States. Sonderheft 24.
Ithaca: ILR Press. Schumann, M., Baethge-Kinsky, V., Kuhlmann, M.,
Kaufman, B. (2004) The Global Evolution of Industrial Kurz, C. and Neumann, U. (1994) Trendreport Ratio-
Relations. Geneva: ILO. nalisierung. Automobilindustrie, Werkmaschinen-
Keller, B. (1996) ‘The German approach to industrial bau, Chemische Industrie 2nd edn. Berlin: Sigma.
relations: a literature review’, European Journal of Shenav, Y. (2000) Manufacturing Rationality: The Engi-
Industrial Relations, 2 (2): 199–210. neering Foundations of the Managerial Revolution.
Kern, H. and Schumann, M. (1984) Das Ende der Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Arbeitsteilung? Rationalisierung in der industriellen Solow, R. (1997) ‘How did Economics get that way and
Produktion, 3rd edn. München: Beck. what way did it get?’, in Th. Bender and C.E. Schorske
52 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

(eds) American Academic Culture in Transformation: Implications’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Fifty Years, Four Disciplines. Princeton: Princeton 38 (1): 141–52.
University Press. pp. 57–76. Wittrock, B. (1993) ‘The modern university: the three
Strauss, G. and Feuille, P. (1978) ‘Industrial Relations transformations’, in S. Rothblatt and B. Wittrock,
Research: A Critical Analysis’, Industrial Relations, (eds) The European and American University Since
XVII, October: 259–77. 1800: Historical and Sociological Essays. Cambridge:
Taylor, F. W. (1911) Principles of Scientific Management. Cambridge University Press. pp. 303–63.
Elibron Classics: Norwood, MA., USA: Plimpton Wittrock, B. and Wollmann, H. (1991) ‘Social science
Press. and the modern state: policy knowledge and
v. Friedeburg, L. (1997) ‘Kooperation und Konkurrenz’, political institutions in Western Europe and the
SOFI-Mitteilungen, 25, July: 25–32. United States’, in P. Wagner, C. Hirschon Weiss,
Wagner, P. (1990) Sozialwissenschaften und Staat. B. Wittrock and H. Wollmann (eds) Social Sciences
Frankreich, Italien, Deutschland 1890–1980. and Modern States: National Experiences and Theo-
Frankfurt/M: Campus. retical Crossroads. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Weingart, P. (1976) Wissensproduktion und soziale Press.
Struktur. Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp. Wood, St. (2000) ‘The BJIR and industrial relations in
Whitfield, K. and Strauss, G. (2000), ‘Methods matter: the new millennium’, British Journal of Industrial
changes in industrial relations research and their Relations, 38 (1): 1–5.
3
Industrial Relations and the
Social Sciences
Peter Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson

INTRODUCTION the old IR models appear almost everywhere


of decreasing policy relevance. Even for those
We begin with a paradox. The broad subject in the shrinking unionized sphere, the scope of
matter of Industrial Relations (IR) – the union influence has been much reduced and
regulation of work and employment – is as many of the things that matter to managers
topical today as it ever was. Yet IR as a and workers are left to state and employer
traditional academic field of study, centered regulation. As Mike Emmott (2005) of the
on trade unions and collective bargaining, British Chartered Institute of Personnel and
now touches only a very limited part of Development (CIPD) has argued, the central
contemporary working life (Ackers, 2004). As role of management in working life has
Gospel (2006) notes, it is important to keep in marginalized the traditional IR analysis of
mind the distinction between the real world joint regulation (see also Sisson’s dissenting
subject and the field of study, while recog- 2006 response).
nizing that there is a dynamic relationship How can we characterize in broad-brush
between the two. This is particularly true of terms the way that this real world subject has
the applied social sciences, where the dialogue changed, assuming that there are deeper soci-
between academic ideas and public policy is ological reasons for the global decline of trade
especially intimate. Just as social policy was unions and collective bargaining? The IR
shaped, as an academic field, by the post- community is justifiably uncomfortable with
war development of welfare systems, so in vague prophetic theories of post-modernity
western economies and beyond academic IR that are immune to empirical testing. How-
was developed in response to the growth of ever, there are other more grounded, historical
trade unions and collective bargaining. Today ways of stating the problem. The real world
that tide has ebbed and turned, such that much occasion for the birth of IR was the emergence
of the world’s working population are now of the organized working class, labor move-
well beyond the reach of joint regulation and ment in the late-nineteenth-century industrial
54 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

society of Britain and the US (Ackers and (Hall and Soskice, 2001), there remains
Wilkinson, 2003; Kaufman, 2004; Wilkinson, some sense of a neo-liberal consensus, which
2007). With the benefit of hindsight and has displaced the post-war social democratic
historical perspective, we can see this as a consensus. This has shifted the dominant
particular period of industrial society, which, economic policy emphasis from the state to
in America and Europe, has evolved into the the business enterprise and markets; while
post-industrial economy of recent decades. In within employment relations a combination
the private sector, large factory concentrations of employer regulation and ‘minimum’ legal
of male, manual workers have given way regulation has taken the central place formerly
to a predominantly service economy, which occupied by collective bargaining. Arguably,
is highly feminized and based on smaller this new policy emphasis reaches across the
work units in close contact with customers: global economy and embraces mainstream
a very different employment relationship social democracy, such that the range of
(Korczynski, 2003). By itself, this doesn’t government policy debate has contracted to
explain everything: not the survival of unions the political right’s ‘minimalist state’ versus
among public sector professionals, or the the political left’s ‘enabling state’ (Hennessy,
failure of unions to thrive in the new industrial 2006: 71).
economies like China, nor the uneven pattern Within these terms, this chapter is not a
of union decline. plea for the old IR to launch a counter-
Much of this seems to be accounted for offensive to recapture lost ground. Rather, we
by state politics and political choice, but argue that such a fundamental shift in ‘events’
still there appears to be an inexorable IR and ‘ideas’ (Ackers, 2005b; 2006a; Kaufman,
pattern emerging. The term neo-liberalism 2004) means that IR analysis can only be
best captures the conjuncture of global market reconstituted in dialogue with surrounding
pressures and ideological choices that is social science disciplines; not as institutional
driving this. The latter relates to the cul- analysis of a shrinking collective bargaining
tural decline of traditional social democratic ‘system’, but as a theory-and-policy paradigm
politics (and the collapse of Communism), that speaks to the wider business school and
so that while, in Britain, we still have a social science communities. Our discussion
Labour Party and a quarter of the workforce is centered on the British case, reflecting
are members of trade unions, it now sounds both the Anglo-Saxon origins of the subject
anachronistic and nostalgic to speak of the (Frege, 2004) and an attempt to take an
‘labor movement’ or ‘the working class’. Our alternative view to that of the American
assumption is that in advanced post-industrial approach; but we use this to illuminate
economies, we have reached ‘the end of labor broader themes for social scientists all over
history’, as traditionally understood, whereby the world.
the problem of labor has lost its former politi- IR has always centered on the study of
cal, institutional and international dimension. social institutions. It began with the Webbs
Governments everywhere think less and less as an administrative social science and, in
of improving workforce commitment, skills Britain, the work of the Oxford School carried
and training through a relationship with an forward this enthusiasm for accumulating
identifiable labor movement. Even a society historical detail about trade unions, collective
like India, with its huge working poor, seems bargaining and employers associations as the
to have moved in the same direction. While central realities of IR analysis. Even IR rad-
poverty and social strife continue, the labor icals, who have often expressed exasperation
movement and labor relations no longer with this conservative institutional agenda,
form the primary conduit through which have adopted many aspects of it. Today,
these problems are represented and resolved however, IR institutionalism is besieged, on
(Ackers, 2006b). Once we allow for the all sides, by an army of academic critics
persistence of different varieties of capitalism from neo-classical economics, managerial
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 55

psychology and post-modernist social theory. Relations, may remain for reasons of tradition
IR is criticized (or just ignored) not just for and inertia, while the content is hollowed-out
its obsession with a highly limited range and replaced by other disciplinary approaches,
of social institutions – trade unions and typically drawn from neo-classical economics
collective bargaining – which are becoming or managerial psychology. In the second case,
less and less central to the sociology of strongly represented in the British radical
contemporary society; but for its emphasis tradition, academics continue to write and
on institutions per se. According to ‘science teach exclusively about trade unions, strikes
building’ positivists, IR does not generate and collective bargaining; even though these
predictive theory, but only piles up description issues affect a declining number of employees
(see Kaufman, 2003). For post-modernists, IR and have become marginal subjects of wider
confuses the linguistically-constructed nature intellectual debate.
of our knowledge of society with something This chapter seeks a middle way between
much more solid and accessible (see Eldridge, these ultimately terminal cases. We begin by
2003). In both cases, institutional context recalling the social science genesis of Anglo-
is downplayed in the quest to understand American IR and assessing the academic dis-
organizational behavior (OB). ciplines that flowed into it. Next, we consider
The IR tradition has many faults. At times, the current dominant academic context of
it has accumulated description for its own IR scholarship, throughout the world: largely
sake, made a fetish of facts and confused the practised in business schools and intermingled
content of union agreements with the much with the new core curriculum of HRM and
richer social dynamics swirling around them. OB. Finally, we sketch a possible extended
However, the critics also have their Achilles future life for IR, through an engagement with
heel, and while they come from opposite a wider social science tradition of institutional
poles of social science – positivist and anti- theory; one which enables IR to continue
positivist, managerial and critical manage- drawing on its own disciplinary past while
ment – theirs is a shared intellectual weakness: moving forward confidently and combatively
the neglect of ‘real’ socio-economic context into a very different real world and academic
and the institutions which constitute it and, context.
crucially, can change it. Thus for us, IR’s
institutional analysis of the employment rela-
tionship needs to be re-thought and re-tooled, THE INTER-DISCIPLINARY
within a broader social science tradition GENESIS OF IR
of institutional theory and critical realism
(Ackroyd and Fleetwood, 2004; Edwards, Sidney and Beatrice Webb’s Industrial
2005) – rather than simply abandoned. This Democracy (1897) was the intellectual foun-
chapter concentrates on the former strand. dation stone of academic IR (see Ackers,
Viewed from within the academic IR 2005a). Characteristically, the Webbs’ tied
community, the twin dangers are that either the together IR theory and public policy at a
academic study of employment lifts entirely time when Economics, Politics and Sociology,
free from its old IR mooring, jettisoning a rich in particular, were in the early stages of
tradition of concepts and empirical studies; development (see Bulmer, 1985). The Webb’s
or alternatively that IR scholars continue to own career, as Fabian social democrats, as
work within the comfortable but shrinking formative figures in many of these new
walls of its established paradigm and ignore disciplines and as founders of the London
the changing outside world of work and ideas. School of Economics, embedded IR in the
These extreme options may be expressed as interdisciplinary movement for social reform.
liquidation versus anachronism. In the first After World War Two, British and American
case, already evident in American IR jour- social scientists, each in their own way,
nals and departments, the words, Industrial worked out a stable academic division of
56 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

labor – famously orchestrated by Talcott than hypothetical labor markets. In Britain, by


Parsons for the US – but this was also closely contrast, the Oxford IR school showed little
linked to the dynamics and requirement of interest in economic analysis – though this
public policy. The management of a post- was already a significant strand of academic
war social democratic consensus in a largely IR – and Clegg famously insisted that it would
industrial society threw up problems like contribute little to the understanding of labor
strikes and incomes policy. IR academics, market behavior. Important figures, such as
such as Hugh Clegg at Warwick, both built H. A. Turner, remained outside the pluralist
academic IR departments and sat on numerous mainstream and when Marxism became an
public enquiries and commissions (Ackers, influence, through the work of Vic Allen and
2007). Richard Hyman, it was animated more by
In Britain at least, the election of Margaret politics and sociology.
Thatcher in 1979 marked a fairly abrupt Since the early 1980s, however, institu-
end to the IR theory-public policy nexus. tional economics has exercised a growing
The combination of a post-industrial econ- influence on British IR, as witnessed both by
omy and neo-liberalism has disrupted the the contents of the British Journal of Indus-
interdisciplinary social science status quo. trial Relations and the key IR text by Edwards
Alongside the predictable rise of expansionist (2003). The Workplace Employment Relation
and individualistic academic traditions, such Surveys (WERS) have provided a focus for
as neo-classical economics and managerial this new quantitative emphasis challenging
psychology – closely attuned to the new the longstanding case-study approach (Wood,
public policy mood – have come the more 2000).Apromising strand of work on different
exotic cross-disciplinary growths associated varieties of capitalism has encouraged institu-
with post-modernism. As the old academic tional economists to move beyond traditional
division of labor unravels, it is worth reflecting labor market debates about trade unions
again on the interdisciplinary mix that went and collective bargaining to look at other
into the old IR and how this has changed – a intervening institutions. Some have called for
task we began in an earlier book (Ackers and IR to link to the fields of political economy and
Wilkinson, 2003). In our view, any attempt to socio-economics (Godard, 2004). This type of
identify a single disciplinary basis for IR is analysis provides us with new concepts such
misguided. Nor do we foresee a single model as path dependency, social embeddedness and
or integrative theory, as Kaufman (2003) does. institutional complementarities – all bulwarks
Instead, we regard one central theme and against neo-classical theory – even if there
approach, the study of society through social are dangers of institutional determinism, as
institutions, as the unifying force that can give Crouch (2001) has pointed out. This said
academic IR a new interdisciplinary social institutional economics alone cannot drive
science identity. the renaissance of IR because its theoreti-
In the US, the root discipline of IR cal development draws on sociological and
was economics, drawing especially on the political analyses of economic phenomena.
work of Commons (see Kaufman, 2004). In Britain, politics was the primary post-
Notwithstanding the growth of neo-classical war discipline, though this was not widely
economics, which focused on perfect com- recognized even within the field, once the
petition market models and either ignored political assumptions became an unspoken
institutional factors like trade unions and normative background to work for public
collective bargaining or deprecated the dis- policy reform and institutional analysis.
tortions to economic efficiency, Roosevelt’s Both Clegg and Flanders were driven by
New Deal and the central public policy role strong Fabian-style social democratic political
it gave trade unions, propelled a distinctive convictions forged out of their experience
tradition of Institutional Labor Economics of Fascism and Communism. For them,
(ILE) and the empirical study of real rather IR pluralism was primarily an exercise in
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 57

non-totalitarian industrial democracy – as it acted as a barrier to the development of any


became too in the US. This political analysis sociological analysis. Thus leading sociologi-
was pushed into the background during the cal figures in IR, such as Alan Fox and Richard
1960s and early 1970s, until Hyman’s (1975) Hyman, began within trade union history
New Left brand of Marxist political sociology and institutional IR and then developed their
forced it back to the surface. The IR academics own distinctive sociological analyses. Only
of the New Deal era in the US and the social from the 1970s did greater emphasis on
democratic consensus in Britain tended to take workplace conflict and bargaining open new
the political context for granted. space for the industrial sociologists like Eric
Following the 1980s rise of the New Right, Batstone. Today British IR is an integral
IR has not only been marginalized by neo- part of the empirical sociology of work,
liberalism in general; it has also lost contact as represented by the radical Labor Process
with ‘revisionist’ political developments in Conference and the journal Work Employment
social democracy as that movement has and Society. So far this seems a story
sought to adapt to global, post-industrial of belated success, as sociology overtakes
society. For example, the British IR com- politics in IR research from the late 1970s
munity has been reluctant to engage with onwards. There are problems, however. Much
the rethinking of Tony Blair’s Third Way, of radical IR sociology remains trapped in
largely because this explicitly recognizes a Braverman-style Marxist fundamentalism
the reduced role trade unions are likely in which all employers degrade, intensify
to play in the future (see Ackers, 2002). and de-skill work. At the same time, IR
Current British IR academics play a signif- pluralists have been slow to develop a
icant policy role in the areas of arbitration more convincing political sociology of how
and conciliation, minimum-wage setting and managers and employees establish, negotiate
equal opportunities. Even so, there are signs and change workplace rules that reaches
that a strongly normative and problem- across union and non-union workplaces and
solving field has become detached from beyond the narrowing band of union-centered
progressive left-of-center thinking and new joint regulation. There is plenty of scope here
policy solutions. The post-war IR generations to draw on the earlier work of Dahrendorf,
were influential in both academic and public Fox and Batstone or the classical theories of
policy terms because they offered credible, Durkheim and Weber.
policy solutions, such as incomes policy or the At the same time, work, economic analysis
reform of workplace bargaining, that seemed and empirical research has become deeply
relevant to mainstream political actors at unfashionable in British sociology, broadly
that time. Likewise, American ‘golden age’ defined. On the one hand, this means IR/HRM
IR was intimately involved with the New in Business Schools has become the center
Deal reform package (see Kaufman, 2004, for the empirical sociology of work. On
Chapter 4). Contemporary IR needs to engage the other, IR and the sociology of work
constructively with the new political reality, has virtually vanished from many Sociology
rather than remain nostalgic for a social departments, while even in Business Schools,
democratic consensus that has long gone. the field of OB is often dominated by either
Thus the renaissance of IR rests partly on psychologists or post-modern social theorists.
the development of a new realistic politics of Much early IR case study research was
employment relations. an unreflective, unconscious amateur brand
Sociology was a late arrival within British of sociology. In our view, a theoretically-
IR theory and has remained weakly repre- informed, but steadfastly empirical sociology
sented in American IR. In both countries, of work can become one central pillar
there was a suspicion of Human Relations for a new IR paradigm centered on the
as managerial and de-contextualized and of new institutionalism. The real sociological
Marxism as totalitarian and ideological, which opportunity for IR may be to forge theoretical
58 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

common ground with other applied fields, engagement with IR has been fleeting. The
such as Social Policy, which share with IR sub-field of Labor Geography has recently
an empirical, problem-solving approach (see drawn a small but influential group of scholars
Bulmer, 1985). into the ambit of IR (see Herod et al., 2003).
It is easy to forget that History was a Their emphasis on the spatial nature of the
central influence on early IR. The Webbs employment relationship in an era of global-
published their History of Trade Unionism in ization has helped take IR beyond the closed
1893 and since then IR scholars, all over the national systems of the post-war period. Law
world, have contributed to an institutional, was sidelined in IR’s preference for voluntary
trade union history sub-genre within labor collective bargaining. The jurifidication of
and social history; one which has been employment regulation over recent decades
especially strong in Australia. In Britain, the has drawn British academics increasingly
once steady flow of trade union histories has into analysis of legal developments such as
become a trickle. Few pluralist IR academics the national minimum wage, trade union
today write history or are engaged with the recognition and European works councils
mainstream historical community. Radical (Ewing, 2003). Intellectually, this calls for
IR history is more active, but prone to a IR to explore in more depth the nature of
socialist antiquarianism, centered on long law, including differences between ‘hard’ and
catalogues of strikes. More generally, the ‘soft’ law and relationships with the field
preoccupation with trade union history has of socio-legal studies. Psychology is often
long occluded other important historical IR seen as one of the two principal enemies
subjects: employers and management, state of IR (along with neo-classical economics),
employment and social policy, non-union and an alternative root discipline for HRM
employees, women and ethnic minorities, and its understanding of the employment
private service sector workers and so on. relationship. Yet psychologists, such as Guest
It has stood in the way of a more rounded (1998), continue to contribute to the IR field.
social history of the experience of work And while the notion of a psychological
or a more integrated history of IR. The contract does provide an individualistic and
current IR emphasis on varieties of capitalism (possibly) managerial challenge to IR col-
and path dependency, as a foil against neo- lectivism, the renaissance of IR within the
liberal convergence theory, if it is to be more field of management depends upon producing
than rhetoric, calls out for more historical theories that explain the behavior of individual
studies. Jacoby’s (1997) work on American managers and employees.
Welfare Capitalism, Hyman’s (2001) study of Traditional IR was a distinctive synthesis of
European trade unionism or Howells’ (2005) various social science influences, with certain
analysis of the role of the state in the evolution disciplines predominating in different peri-
of the British IR system are all examples of the ods. Thus American IR became locked into
potentially important role history has to play ILE while 1950s and 1960s British IR drew
in linking IR’ old paradigm to its new one. mainly from politics and history. Indian IR
Lyddon (2003) suggests that contemporary remains more influenced by economics than
academic HRM has encouraged a sort of sociology. In the 1970s, industrial sociology
historical amnesia, whereby old IR concepts became the main discipline of British IR, often
and studies have been abandoned in the centered on factory conflict, while since the
pursuit of novelty. This may be one side of the 1980s an empirical, analytical institutional
problem, but the other is that much IR history economics has gained prominence through
is deeply conservative in method and topic the WERS surveys. In our view, the global
area and reluctant to ask new, more topical renaissance of IR calls for an active and
questions about the past. open-minded re-engagement with all these
The remaining disciplines can be dis- surrounding disciplines in the search for
pensed more cursorily mainly because their concepts that can be synthesized into a new
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 59

IR paradigm centered on the contemporary of regulation in his definition of IR, this


employment relationship. was rarely operationalized in IR research
until the 1980s. Phelps Brown (1959:114)
opens his chapter on the ‘Development of
IR AND HRM IN THE BUSINESS Industrial Relations’ with the declaration
SCHOOL CONTEXT that ‘The story of modern British industrial
relations begins with the beginnings of the
Even a single generation ago, the academic IR unions’. For a long time it ended there too;
map of the world of work was badly skewed and for some it still does. As Kaufman
(Ackers, 1994; Redman and Wilkinson, (2004: 610) notes, IR ‘regarded non-union
2006). It neglected substantial areas of the employers and unitarist employment systems
economy where joint regulation was non- with varying degrees of aversion, suspicion
existent or weak and emphasized collective and opprobrium’.
bargaining at the expense of other modes Yet management has always been central to
of regulation, such as joint consultation and the employment relationship. By overlooking
especially legal regulation. With the odd this, traditional academic IR not only left
exception (see Goodman et al., 1977), it a gap in its theory, but in its public policy
highlighted conflict rather than co-operation. mission. It did so by failing to recognize the
But above all, it almost completely ignored the crucial role that employer regulation plays in
most crucial and pervasive form of employ- employees’ lives and the gaps in employment
ment regulation: employer and management regulation left by concentrating exclusively
regulation. Only late in his career did Clegg on voluntary collective bargaining. To take
recognize the extent to which employers the British example, Perkins (1989) notes the
shaped collective bargaining and launch the failure of unions to ‘professionalize’ working
research programme that led to the belated class life through excessive dependence on
re-discovery of Personnel Management as collective bargaining about money wages.
HRM (see Sisson, 1989; Storey, 1989). In this As a result, the state was late in legislating
respect, the field of study of the old academic for universal provisions or in raising the
IR was always a highly partial theorization status of hourly paid work in relation to
of the real world subject of the employment job security, holiday entitlements, pensions
relationship and its regulation. and equal opportunities – areas where Britain
Before HRM, Personnel Management had lagged behind the best continental European
been a marginal field in both Britain and countries. With the death of institutional
the US, partly because it was neglected IR proclaimed over a decade ago (Purcell,
by IR (see Kaufman, 2004). Pioneers like 1993) and the end of joint regulation
Flanders and Clegg (1954) had ignored and (Terry, 2004) more recently, contemporary
dismissed the subject and the former was IR badly needs HRM to fill in much
noted for his ‘frank disdain of personnel of what matters in working life today.
management’ (Brown, 1998: 850). By and By neglecting the central business actor,
large, management activity outside collective academic IR missed out on much of the
bargaining, including non-union companies crucial fine grain of employment regulation.
and consultation, was viewed through the nor- As Bach and Sisson (2000, p. 3) note: ‘It
mative prism of joint regulation and accorded is easy to forget in the current avalanche
marginal status. Despite the protests of some of literature that, as late as 1989, there
veteran IR academics that management had was very little analysis of and information
always been a key concern to them, their of personnel management in practice’. Any
real primary preoccupation had been with applied problem-solving academic field that
collective bargaining, as the key texts testify. ignores such central issues and such crucial
While Clegg and Flanders originally included policy actors is bound to find itself overtaken
non-union forms and non-formal methods by events.
60 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Seen in this light, the emergence of HRM performance and employee well-being, in
as a central topic of IR research is not a addition to its enduring and distinctive
threat to the field – as has so often been emphasis on questions of power and conflict
mooted – but its potential salvation. With in the employment relationship. In this task,
the benefit of hindsight, it is clear that the IR is well positioned as an academic tradition
real threat to IR as a distinctive academic that is now interested in management, but
paradigm came not from the influence of remains sympathetic to employees, concerned
American business school ideology, but from about social justice and the needs of the
fundamental real world changes in the nature wider society and suspicious of authoritarian
of work and the institutional context of management ideologies and pop management
academic life. These widened still further prescriptions. HRM is addressed critically, as
the gap between academic field of study a field of empirical enquiry, not a cure-all set of
and real world subject; while policy makers ready-made prescriptions. HRM-without-IR
and other social scientists began to notice is the real social science problem. Here Bacon
what IR left out. Once the calls for better (2003: 84) identifies an excessive individu-
trained and educated managers were finally alism that overlooks the collective aspects
met by a massive expansion of university of employment and underplays the contested
business schools, changes in the real world terrain in which management choices are
subject and the academic context of its study made. This version of HRM does exaggerate
marched hand-in-hands. Similar instances of the currency of enlightened, high commitment
this twin-track change can be found across the management, and ignores the role of power
globe, in countries as different as India since and conflict in the employment relationship.
market liberalization in 1991 (see Ackers, The business organization appears able to
2006b). In Britain, the combination of 1970s create its own organizational climate unre-
economic crisis and pluralist IR crisis, created strained by institutions and context. For all
the impression that academic IR had little to these reasons, HRM is where the major public
contribute to a successful market economy. policy debate on the future of work takes
Into this intellectual and policy vacuum came place.
HRM, with a more economically relevant To flourish, academic IR must be relevant
agenda, an aspirational vision and a new set to both its real world and academic contexts.
of tools of analysis that are widely seen as The future of the field is far from guaranteed.
more ‘relevant’ to the world of work today, The global IR academic community today
presenting indeed ‘a new orthodoxy’ (Guest, is overwhelmingly concentrated in business
1998). With or without HRM, IR would have schools, though many of these have no
entered a decline. At least the advent of recognizable IR presence. To make sense of
HRM raised the profile of people management this we need to appreciate the wider institu-
within businesses and business schools and tional context within which the IR academic
extended the field of enquiry into areas that IR community resides. Business schools have
had previously neglected and has now begun been a global success story over the last
to grasp. 20 years with a dramatic expansion not only
HRM brings to IR not only a broader in domestic undergraduate students but also of
employment canvass, but also new concepts, mainly overseas, postgraduate MSc and MBA
such as strategy, from management disciplines students. The demand from these students is
that barely existed during the IR golden age. not for traditional IR: the study of a small
As Kaufman (2004: 625) observes, ‘industrial corner of what was once England. All MBA
relations has fallen out of step with the courses have HRM/OB modules, under these
modern workplace because its toolkit of or other labels, but they are taught from
institutional “fixes” is no longer regarded a variety of perspectives: by psychologists,
as very effective’. Today the field needs to post-modernists or by orthodox OB sociolo-
demonstrate its own contribution to business gists. In other words IR has to compete for
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 61

space and its position is not privileged. While not as scientific law, but as temporary
marketing, accounting, finance and HRM/OB ‘walking sticks’ to aid sense making as we
are guaranteed a place at the table – as go along – something akin to Popper’s idea
core business school academic disciplines and of piecemeal social engineering discussed
management functions – IR is not. As the below. Once IR broadens its horizons, beyond
American model of Business School spreads the institutions and solutions of industrial
globally through the influence of AACSB society, there is renewed scope to play a
accreditation, this is especially problematic – part in the ‘rational reconstruction of society’
particularly given the decline of the once (Coleman, 1993). The narrow scientific model
powerful American IR community. often excludes human ethical choices, just
Continued academic centrality demands as causal determinism dehumanizes manage-
a stronger intellectual rationale, perhaps ment practice. Here again, HRM draws IR
linked to notions of human capital and high into the major debates about the future role
performance. Budd (2004: 191) advocates a of business schools (AIM, 2006). Should they
meta-paradigm or organizing map (not theory) follow a social science model or a professional
which defines the parameters of an integrated model akin to medicine? The IR field bridges
IR and HRM field, with efficiency and voice both: it is both a critical, normative approach
and equity as the key objectives. As he to management but also brings a strong
argues, the standard narrow HRM focus on pragmatic orientation with the emphasis on
efficiency must be balanced by IR’s normative useful knowledge and reform. In this new
insistence on employees’ entitlement to fair more ambitious guise, IR could aim to set
treatment and the opportunity to have a the social science agenda for management
meaningful input into decisions. This thematic studies.
approach would define a ‘common vision
of the unique domain of the field’ (Budd,
2004:12) embracing HRM and IR, with the REJOINING THE MAINSTREAM: IR AS
emphasis shifting between different poles INSTITUTIONAL THEORY
of the triad. The normative tradition of
IR has been seen as a scientific weakness Once personnel management is drawn back
(Kaufman, 2004) and an exclusive sympathy into a new combined IR/HRM fold and the
for trade unions no longer serves as an normative assumptions of the old academic
adequate or meaningful social philosophy in IR have been redefined and restated, there
the new economy. By returning to core general remains the question of which bundle of
values, rather than fixing on any specific concepts and approaches can drive academic
institution, Budd positions IR to contribute IR, as an applied social science, with a
to the modern debate about the morality of coherent research programme and a repertoire
business schools. Ghoshal (2005: 76–7) has of new problem-solving policy solutions. The
written a stinging critique of their reliance on answer, at the level of theory, seems to lie
‘ideologically inspired amoral themes which in stripping the old academic IR back to
have actively freed students from any sense its essential core as the institutional analysis
of moral responsibility’, and which view of the employment relationship, and then
the purpose of social theory as ‘solving the looking both for allies and ways of taking this
“negative problem” of restricting the social approach forward.
costs arising from human imperfections’. The Scott’s (2001) Institutions and Organiza-
popularity of critical management studies in tions suggest the potential for a re-engagement
Britain shows the scope for this revived between IR and one central strand of the
normative role. social sciences. His institutional tradition is
According to Roethlisberger (1977), the highly inclusive with space for traditional IR
positivist preference for modeling and ‘sci- as well as Marx, Weber, Durkheim, Parsons,
ence’ has squeezed out the notion of theory, Giddens and even Geertz. Scott provides
62 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

a welcome analytical clarity, distinguishing theory. Two other important boundary issues
three main institutional pillars: regulative stand out.
(coercive rule-making), normative (values); One concerns the important distinction
and cultural-cognitive (symbols, meaning, raised by Scott between variance and process
routines, ways of doing). In these terms, IR approaches to institutions. Process analysis,
has been a center for old institutionalism, once more, is what IR has always done.
which centered on regulative and normative It embraces real-life institutions, like trade
institutions; though ‘custom and practice’ unions, bargaining committees and team
has always played a significant, if rather briefings, and describes and analyzes their
defensive, role in IR analysis. The new operation in real, natural settings. It concerns
institutionalism, by contrast, centers more the relations between events not variables
on cultural-cognitive institutions. This third and in this ‘history matters’ (Gospel, 2005).
dimension could add something new and Variance analysis has stronger pretensions
important to IR analysis, as collective bar- to hard predictive science, like neo-classical
gaining contracts and the search is on for economics and occupational psychology, and
new more fine grain forms of institutional treats institutions as ‘abstract variables’. This
analysis. The cultural-cognitive approach to is the road taken by the new institutionalism,
institutions also contributes something new ‘transaction costs’ economics (see Jacoby,
to IR as a problem solving rather than 1990). Full-scale adoption of variance insti-
science building field. Arguably it suggests tutionalism would destroy everything that
useful new approaches to practical policy the IR research tradition has stood for.
questions, such as how to diffuse HRM ‘best IR institutionalism stands or falls by its
practice’ or achieve regulatory compliance. adherence to critical realist ontology and
In addition to the established coercive and the importance of real, naturalistic context.
normative strategies, new institutionalism Any theory that either argues we cannot
suggests the importance of mimetic influences reach or research institutional context (post-
and organizational isomorphism; and may structuralism/ post-modernism), or that some
illuminate novel forms of voluntary regulation adapted rational choice model is a substitute
as alternatives to blunt state regulation. for doing so (positivist variance theory),
According to Godard (2004: 236), while denies the importance of real social and
there are several types of new institutionalism, historical context. In this light, process theory
they all fall within a ‘broader paradigm is genuine institutionalism, while variant
united by a common focus on the impor- theories with their contrived and synthetic
tance of rules that undergird economic, responses are not.
social and political arrangements forming the In addition, while IR desperately needs a
institutional environment within which the broader sociological view of institutions (see
parties act’. This may be too complacent, Ackers, 2002), we still need to deal with
however. Certain types of new institutional relatively stable ‘bodies’ that are recognizable
turn pose problems for IR institutional theory, as institutions. For IR theory, institutions must
as we normally understand it, demanding be both real and substantial. They do not
that we set our own boundaries. In our need to be formal bodies, but nor can they
view, if new institutionalism is to con- be fleeting social encounters. This is not an
tribute to the rejuvenation of IR, we must argument for returning to the old, descriptive
engage with it critically and selectively ‘brick and mortar’ institutional IR theory.
and not just buy the whole package off That approach lacked sociological sensitivity
the shelf. For instance, one weakness of and often failed to develop either theory or
Scott’s sociological perspective is that none analysis, because it confused the tip of the
of his three pillars really reflect the economic iceberg – hard institutional information –
context of labor and product markets – with the fuller understanding that comes from
a wider weakness of much organizational looking below the surface. Institutions are
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 63

part of social reality, and often a crucial Involvement (EI) in the late 1980s, they
doorway into grasping social reality, but they carried their ontological road map with them
alone cannot give us a rounded picture of (Ackers et al., 2006c; Marchington et al.,
the employment relationship. On the other 1992). Instead of beginning, as a psychologist
hand, institutions have a double social science would, by asking individual employees if they
value, as the place where social problems or ‘felt involved’, they looked for institutions
issues are identified and the practical means and they found them: old ones like trade
whereby these can be solved. Without real- unions and joint consultation committees;
life social institutions society is like sand and new ones such as quality circles,
that slips through our fingers. By combining team briefings and TQM programmes. These
an institutional focus – which may include activities exhibited regularity and had formal
certain types of survey research – with a case- structures with specific managerial roles to
study method that grasps the fine grain of support them. They were never, however, a
socio-economic life, we can do full justice to full picture of the nature of EI. Many small
context. companies explicitly claimed that they had
Blyton and Turnbull (2004) suggest that few structures, but that involvement operated
institutionalism makes IR inherently con- through a dynamic informal culture, an open
servative through the association with a door policy, and management by walking
functionalist antipathy to social change about – all claims that are hard to assess using
Here our response is twofold. Certainly, traditional institutional measures (Wilkinson
institutional theory is better for reformers et al., 2007). For large organizations, however,
than revolutionaries, and mainstream IR has the formal institutions were a useful starting
always stood firmly in the former camp. point: an institutional focus or doorway into
Moreover, the critique of functionalism is the wider social relations. It allowed us to
from another era when, in the 1960s, the ask questions about the gap between rhetoric
New Left challenged the stable institutions and reality and to seek the true meaning of
of industrial society. Today it is the New interview and questionnaire responses, in the
Right that thrives on chaos and free markets context of both what institutions management
(Ackers, 1994). Arguably, new institutional had created, how much money they had spent
theory provides an array of instruments to on them, how often they met and so on.
socially regulate runaway capitalism. This To this could be added other contextual
still leaves the problem of human agency information about the labor and product
and the charge that institutional analysis markets of the firm. In this sense, institutions
reifies what are in effect relations between framed a broader, qualitative research agenda.
people. There is another defensible bor- And it is a short step from assessing the
der that separates institutional theory from regulative and normative impact of New
the methodological individualism of neo- Labour policies and European Works Council
classical economics and managerial psychol- legislation, to exploring the cultural-cognitive
ogy. But it remains important to ask how influence of benchmarks like Investors in
institutional accounts integrate the actions People or the CBI’s Excellence initiative,
of the individuals and groups that consti- or simply the voluntary, mimetic spread
tute them. of TQM.
Many IR academics are already doing A still more recent issue in UK IR research
new institutionalism without knowing it. is Work-Life Balance and Family-Friendly
To illustrate this we take two examples from policies, and once more this displays the
our own research. familiar combination of coercive statutory
When IR researchers of our generation regulation, government normative injunction
found themselves not in the familiar pas- and the cultural-cognitive copying of best
ture of unions, collective bargaining and practice. Here institutions are societal as
strikes, but looking at the new Employee well as organizational and without them,
64 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

researchers can ‘lose’ crucial factors that CONCLUSION: REAL CONTEXT AND
shape thought and behaviour. For example, SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC REFORM
Merlilainen et al. (2004) compare man-
agement careers and work-life balance in For IR scholars institutional theory is both
Finland and Britain using a post-modern very old and very new. They have always
discourse approach. They show convincingly coupled scientific and normative justifica-
that the discourse of the two groups was very tions. In most cases, to gain an adequate
different. The British managers were driven theory of social life, we need to combine
by work and downgraded their children and institutional context with the actors’ social
private lives, working very long hours. By meanings that inhabit this. Without either our
contrast, the Finns sought work-life balance analysis is likely to be incomplete. Beyond
and valued time spent with their children. In this, however, there is a strong reformist,
explanation, the authors refer to a discursive social democratic (in the broadest sense)
or ‘cultural context’ that shapes the way public policy case for institutional social
these management consultants ‘talk about science. You need to be an institutionalist
their work and careers’ (Ibid: 540). We would to improve society, because if we do not
suggest that very often ‘culture’ – the ether start with institutions we do not reach any
of post-modernism – is really no explanation collective agency or public policy position
at all (see Kahn and Ackers, 2004; Kuper, that will structurally change society for the
1999). And Merlilainen et al. later reach for better. We can wish society will collapse, like
‘societal context’ (Ibid: 547), ‘public policy’ a pack of cards, as some radicals do. We
(551), ‘public childcare facilities’ (554) and can train managers and employees on how to
‘institutionalized arrangements’ (558) – all adapt to the status quo, as constructed by the
suggesting the explanatory limitations of institutional power holders we refuse to see,
discourse analysis. as managerial psychology and neo-classical
If the question is: why do managers in economics does. We can urge individuals to
different national states develop different free themselves, at least in their hearts, as
ways of thinking and behaving? the answer, some critical management studies scholars
very probably, is due to institutions. The advocate. But without some institutional
Scandinavian employment and welfare model focus, we can’t reform society in a purposeful
is replete with well-funded regulative, norma- and piecemeal way.
tive and cultural-cognitive institutions, which In the wake of Communism, there has
both make responsible parenthood materially been an understandable reaction against grand
easy and morally desirable. State day-care theories of social change. Tietze et al. (2003),
systems are institutions, but so are strong for instance, argue:
trade unions that help to shape this ‘social
Concomitant with the demise of metanarra-
market’ culture. The corollary is that the tives, we can observe a return of the ‘little’
organizations, institutions and actors that narrative’ (Lyotard, 1979/1986: 61) of the everyday.
operate at that level, and the interaction These little narratives focus on the stories of
with wider societal supports, are crucial to (organizational) lives in terms that emphasize the
understanding the choices individual actors situation and temporal embeddedness of (moral)
choices. The onus of responsibility is on each
make. On the opposite side of the sociological individual/ individual organization – rather than
spectrum, a similar criticism can be made on institutions and bodies. This includes the
of Hakim’s (2000) important positivist work responsibility to make sense of the complexities of
on women’s choices (Hantrais and Ackers, (organizational) circumstance: the ‘big questions’ –
2005). In short, without a grasp of real if answerable at all – are to be addressed
not within universalist and potentially totalitarian
institutional context we fail to understand why ideologies, but within the contingencies and
people behave in a certain way or what could expediences of an increasingly complex world (our
be done to change this behavior. emphasis).
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 65

Within IR and many other applied social Popper was specifically addressing state
sciences, however, the main alternative to power, but the IR parallels are apparent. As
Marxist grand theory has been ‘institutions Flanders (1975:137) argued:
and bodies’. Karl Popper, no less, did not fear
In labour relations, control by the ‘rule of law’ is
the institutional solution, but saw it as the main more than control by legislation. Every instrument
bulwark against totalitarianism. In The Open of regulation that compels management to respect
Society and its Enemies (1945, 1995 edition: rules in making its decisions has to be included: the
354) he posed the question thus: provisions of collective agreements and unwritten
custom and practice as much as the statutory
What have we to say to Marx’s analysis? Are we requirements of protective labour legislation. Even
to believe that politics, or the framework of legal the rules which management makes unilaterally
institutions, are intrinsically impotent to remedy regulate its use of power, though it is not a
such a situation, and that only a complete social matter of indifference to workers whether they
revolution, a complete change of the ‘social system’ have participated in making these rules. Only then
can help? Or are we to believe the defenders of have they any assurance that their interests have
an unrestrained ’capitalist’ system who emphasize been taken into account and can they feel any
(rightly, I think) the tremendous benefit to be gained responsibility for seeing that the rules are observed.
from the mechanism of free markets, and who
conclude from this that a truly free labor market For these reasons, institutional schools like
would be of the greatest benefit to all concerned. IR are potentially unique in their ability to
carry theory into practice. Today, European
In common cause with Anglo-American IR social policy is another illustration of the
pluralists of the same generation, Popper continuing relevance of institutional theory.
chose a third, social democratic option of Law is active in regulating business, but the
‘piecemeal social engineering’ (1995: 364) experience of numerous EU directives shows
and institutional reform through the legal the implementation is at once problematic
framework, starting with labor legislation. In and crude, unless it works with the grain of
his view, ‘the principle of non-intervention, local conditions. Hence policy moves down
of an unrestrained economic system, has from national framework policies, on working
to be given up’, so that we can ‘construct time or equal opportunities, to detailed imple-
social institutions, enforced by the power mentation by institutional actors in localities
of the state, for the protection of the and organizations. In this respect, institutional
economically weak from the economically theory is both a description of how policy
strong’(1995: 355). He contrasts two methods making works and a prescription about how it
of rule, one by ‘institutional’ or ‘indirect’ can be improved. Legal regulation has always
intervention, the other by ‘personal’ or had a normative element, but as we move from
‘direct’ intervention, and judges that ‘from hard to soft regulation, the cultural-cognitive
the point of view of democratic control’ approach to spreading HRM ‘best practice’
the first is clearly preferable (1995: 361–3). becomes ever more critical.
With Weber he regards personal authority In conclusion, Anglo-American IR has
as ‘irrational’ and institutional or rule- never been a closed academic discipline
governed authority as ‘rational’ particularly engaged in pure ‘science building’; but nor
because: has it been an entirely open inter-disciplinary
The legal framework can be known and under- field responding to employment problems in
stood by the individual citizen; and it should be a completely ad hoc way. Rather, as we have
designed to be so understandable. Its functioning argued before, the IR academic community
is predictable. It introduces a factor of certainty and has constructed a hybrid paradigm by selec-
security into social life … As opposed to this, the
tively synthesizing concepts and approaches
method of personal intervention must introduce an
ever-growing element of unpredictability into social from other social sciences in response to
life, and with it will develop the feeling that social contemporary issues (Ackers and Wilkinson,
life is irrational and insecure. 2005). This paradigm has both mirrored and
66 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

shaped the understanding of employment Relations’, Journal of Occupational and Organiza-


problems and their policy solutions in the tional Psychology, 79 (2): 213–16.
real world. In the post-war era of industrial Ackers, P. (2006b), ‘Leaving Labour? Some British
society and the social democratic consensus, Impressions of Indian Academic Employment
the IR public policy tool-kit centered on a Relations’, Economic and Political Weekly (India), XLI:
39: 30.
very narrow range of social institution – trade
Ackers, P. (2007) ‘Collective Bargaining as Industrial
unions and voluntary collective bargaining –
Democracy: Hugh Clegg and the Political Foundations
and tended to ignore both legal regulation and of British Industrial Relations Pluralism’, British
personnel management. As advanced post- Journal of Industrial Relations, 45 (1), March:
industrial societies have changed dramatically 77–101.
in recent decades, joint regulation has become Ackers, P., Marchington, M., Wilkinson, A. and
incapable of playing this central policy Dundon, T. (2006c) ‘Employee participation in
role, which, in turn, has undermined the Britain: From Collective Bargaining and Indus-
hinterland of IR theory that centered on trial Democracy to Employee Involvement and
this specific approach. This exhaustion of Social partnership – Two Decades of Manchester/
the old institutionalism appears to be an Loughborough Research’, Decision (Indian Institute
increasingly global trend. Our argument here of Management, Calcutta), 33 (1), January–June:
75–88.
is that IR can only regain its theory and
Ackers, P. and Wilkinson, A. (2003) (eds) Understanding
policy cutting edge by: first, expanding its
Work and Employment: Industrial Relations In
range to include HRM; second, rethinking Transition. Oxford University Press.
and reviving its traditional normative goals Ackers, P. and Wilkinson, A. (2005) ‘The British
and, third, deepening its analysis of social Industrial Relations Paradigm: a critical outline and
institutions. All three tasks entail an outgoing, prognosis’, Journal of Industrial Relations, 47 (4),
open-minded engagement with the contem- December: 443–56.
porary inter-disciplinary social sciences. The Ackroyd, S. and Fleetwood, S. (2004) Critical Realist
outcome should be better theory, driving more Applications in Organization and Management
compelling research and more relevant public Studies. London: Routledge.
policy. AIM (2006) UK Business Schools: Historical Contexts and
Future Scenarios. London: AIM research.
Bacon, N. (2003) ‘Human Resource Management and
Industrial Relations’, in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson
REFERENCES (eds) Understanding Work and Employment: Indus-
trial Relations In Transition. Oxford: Oxford University
Ackers, P. (1994) ‘Back to Basics: Industrial Relations Press. pp. 71–88.
and the Enterprise Culture’, Employee Relations, Blyton, P. and Turnbull, P. (2004), The Dynamics
16 (8): 32–47. of Employee Relations, 3rd edition, Basingstoke:
Ackers, P. (2002) ‘Reframing employment relations: the Palgrave MacMillan.
case for neo-pluralism’, Industrial Relations Journal, Brown, W. (1998) ‘Clegg, Hugh Armstrong’, in M. Poole
33 (1): 2–19. and M.Warner (eds) IEBM The Handbook of Human
Ackers, P. (2004) ‘Haunted by History: Industrial Resource Management. London: ITP.
Relations Faces the Future’, Organization Studies, Bulmer, M. (1985) ‘The development of sociology and
25 (9): 1623–29. empirical social science in Britain’, in M. Bulmer
Ackers, P. (2005a) ‘Between the Devil and the Deep (ed) Essays on the History of the British Sociological
Blue Sea: Global History, the British Tradition, and Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
the European Renaissance’, Comparative Labor Law Budd, J. (2004) Employment with a Human Face. Ithaca,
and Policy Journal, 27 (1): 93–104. NY: Cornell University Press.
Ackers, P. (2005b) ‘Theorizing the Employment Rela- Coleman, J. S. (1993) ‘The Rational Reconstruction of
tionships: Materialists and Institutionalists’, British Society’, American Sociological Review, 58 (1): 1–15.
Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (3), September: Edwards, P. (ed) (2003) Industrial Relations, 2nd edition,
537–43. Oxford: Blackwell.
Ackers, P. (2006a) ‘Commentary: The History of Edwards, P. (2005) ‘The Promising Future of Industrial
Occupational Psychology: A View from Industrial Relations: Developing the Connections Between
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 67

Theory and Relevance’, Industrial Relations Journal, Hantrais, L. and Ackers, P. (2005) ‘Women’s Choices
36 (4): 264–82. in Europe: Striking the Work-Life Balance’, European
Eldridge, J. (2003) ‘Post-Modernism and IR’, in Journal of Industrial Relations, 11 (2): 197–212.
P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work Hennessy, P. (2006) Having It So Good: Britain in the
and Employment: Industrial Relations In Transition. Fifties. London: Allen Lane.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 325–36. Herod, A., Peck, J. and Wills, J. (2003) Geogra-
Emmott, M. (2005) ‘What is Employee Relations’. phy and Industrial Relations, in P. Ackers and
London: CIPD (Change Agenda). A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work and Employ-
Ewing, K. (2003) ‘Industrial Relations and the Law’, in ment: Industrial Relations In Transition. Oxford:
P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work Oxford University Press. pp. 175–94.
and Employment: Industrial Relations In Transition. Howells, C. (2005) Trade Unions and the State: The
Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 138–60 Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in
Flanders, A. (1975) Management and Unions: The Britain, 1890–2000. New Jersey: Princeton University
Theory and Reform of Industrial Relations. London: Press.
Faber. Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist
Flanders, A. and Clegg, H.A. (1954) (eds) The System of Introduction. Basingstoke: MacMillan.
Industrial Relations in Great Britain: Its History Law Hyman, R. (2001) Understanding European Trade
and Institutions. Oxford: Blackwell. Unionism: Between Market, Class and Society.
Frege, C. (2004) ‘Varieties of Industrial Relations London: Sage.
Research’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Jacoby, S. (1990) ‘The New Institutionalism: What it
43 (2): 179–207. Can Learn from the Old’, Industrial Relations, 29 (2):
Ghoshal, S. (2005) ‘Bad management theories are 316–40.
destroying good management practices’, Academy of Jacoby, S (1997) Modern Manors: Welfare Capitalism
Management Learning and Education, 4 (1): 75–91. since the New Deal. New Jersey: Princeton University
Godard, J. (2004) ‘The New Institutionalism, Capitalist Press. (reviewed by Ackers, P. in Historical Studies in
Diversity and Industrial Relations’, in B. Kaufman, Industrial Relations, 8, Autumn 1999, 188–93).
Theoretical Perspectives on Work and the Employ- Kahn, A.S. and Ackers, P. (2004) ‘Neo-pluralism as
ment Relationship. Champaign, IL: IRRA. pp. 229–64. a theoretical framework for understanding HRM
Godard, J. and Delaney, J. (2000) ‘Reflections on the in sub-Saharan Africa’, International Journal of
high performance paradigm’s implications for IR as a Human Resource Management, 15 (7), November:
field’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 53 (3): 1330–53.
482–503. Kaufman, B. (2003) Theoretical perspectives on work
Goodman, J. F. B., Armstrong, E. G. A., Davis, J. E. and and the employment relationship. Champaign,
Wagner, A. (1977) Rule-making and Industrial Peace. IL: IRRA.
London: Croom Helm. Kaufman, B. (2004) The Global Evolution of Industrial
Gospel, H. (2005) ‘Markets, Firms and Unions: Historical Relations. Geneva: ILO.
and Institutionalist Perspectives in the Future of Korczynski, M. (2003) ‘Consumer Capitalism and Indus-
Unions’, in D. Metcalf and S. Fernie (eds) Unions and trial Relations’ in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds)
Performance. London: Routledge. Understanding Work and Employment: Industrial
Gospel, H. (2006) ‘A British and Historical Perspective Relations In Transition. Oxford: Oxford University
on Workplace Governance: Kaufman and the Press. pp. 265–77.
Global Evolution of Industrial Relations?’, Industrielle Kuper, A. (1999) Culture. Cambridge, MA: Harvard.
Beziehungen, 13 (1): 2006, pp. 57–66. Lyddon, D. (2003) ‘History and Industrial Relations’ in
Guest, D. (1990) ‘Human Resource Management and P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Work
Industrial Relations’, Journal of Management Studies, and Employment: Industrial Relations In Transition.
27 (4): 377–98. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 89–118.
Guest, D. (1998) ‘Beyond HRM’, in P. Sparrow and Marchington, M., Goodman, J., Wilkinson, A. and
M. Marchington (eds) HRM: the New Agenda, Ackers, P. (1992) New Developments in Employee
FT/Pitman. Involvement, Employment Department, UK, Research
Hakim, C. (2000) Work-Lifestyle Choices in the 21st series. London: HMSO.
Century: Preference Theory, Oxford: Oxford University Merilainen, S., Tienari, J., Thomas, R. and Davies, A.
Press. (2004) ‘Management Consultant Talk: A Cross-
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001) Varieties of Capitalism. Cultural Comparison of Normalizing Discourse and
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Resistance’, Organization, 11 (4): 539–64.
68 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Perkins, H. (1989) The Rise of Professional Society. mandate’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41:
London: Routledge. 146–62.
Phelps Brown, H. (1959) The Growth Of British Industrial Storey, J. (1989) New Perspectives on Human Resource
Relations. London: Macmillan. Management. London: Routledge.
Popper, K. (1995) The Open Society and its Enemies. Terry, M. (2004) ‘Can Partnership Reverse the decline
London: Routledge. of British trade unions?’, Work, Employment and
Purcell, J. (1993) ‘The End of Institutional Industrial Society, 17 (3): 450–72.
Relations’, Political Quarterly, 64 (1): 6–23 Tietze, S., Cohen, L. and Musson, G. (2003) Understand-
Redman, T. and Wilkinson, A. (2006) (eds) Con- ing Organizations through Language. London: Sage.
temporary Human Resource Management. London: Webb, B and Webb, S. (1897) Industrial Democracy.
FT/Prentice Hall. London: Longman.
Roethlisberger, F.J. (1977) The Elusive Phenomena. Wilkinson A. (2007) ‘Industrial relations’, in S. Clegg and
Boston: Harvard University Press. J. Bailey, International Encyclopedia of Organization
Scott, R. (2001) Institutions and Organizations, 2nd Studies. London: Sage.
edition, London: Sage. Wilkinson A., Dundon, T. and Grugulis, I. (2007) ‘Infor-
Sisson, K. (1989) Personnel Management in Britain. mation but not consultation: exploring employee
Oxford: Blackwell. involvement in SMES’, International Journal Of
Sisson, K. (2006) ‘Responding to Mike Emmott’ Human Resource Management, 18 (7): 1279–97.
(unpublished). Wood, S. (2000) ‘The BJIR and Industrial Relations in
Stern, R. N. and Barley, S. R. (1996) ‘Organizations the New Millennium’, British Journal of Industrial
and social systems: Organization theory’s neglected Relations, 38 (1): March: 1–5.
4
System and Change in Industrial
Relations Analysis
Edmund Heery

INTRODUCTION invisibility, these models lurk behind much


empirical IR analysis and assumptions about
This chapter is concerned with two types of the nature and rhythms of change shape much
model-building in industrial relations (IR). middle-range IR theory. Key distinctions
The first type comprises what might be that appear within these models concern the
thought of as ‘cross-sectional’ models and is pattern of change and whether it is cyclical
illustrated by the tradition of systems-thinking or directional, gradual or catastrophic, and its
in IR. The distinctive feature of these models origin; whether it is generated endogenously
is that they seek to delineate the object of study within the employment relationship or has
of IR, including the definition of its constituent an exogenous source in the wider economy,
elements, such as actors and institutions, their society or polity.
interrelationship through social processes and
the economic, social, moral and other effects
that are thereby generated. In this tradition the
Systems thinking
constitutive elements of the IR system tend to Discussion of systems thinking must begin
be abstracted from a particular place or time; with Dunlop’s (1993) seminal text, Industrial
this is an approach to theory-building that is Relations Systems, first published in 1958
relatively ahistorical. and arguably the most influential IR book
The second type puts history to the fore ever written (Kaufman, 2004b: 250–251). The
and comprises models of change over time. explicit purpose of Dunlop’s book was to
Models of this kind tend to be less frequently designate the object of study of industrial
articulated in IR theory though on occasion relations and establish the field as an inde-
theorists have tried to identify and evaluate pendent discipline, equivalent to economics
underpinning models of change within IR (Dunlop, 1993: 9–10; 45–46). Whereas the
(Blyton and Turnbull, 2004: 12–18; Erickson subject of the latter was the economic system
and Kuruvilla, 1998). Despite their relative the subject of IR was the ‘industrial relations
70 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

system’, conceived as a distinct and relatively its regulatory function. On the other hand, the
autonomous, but integral, component of the actors were bound by a common ideology,
wider social system. In Dunlop’s (1993: 45) an acceptance of the rules of the IR game
own words, ‘An industrial relations system is that further helped ‘to bind or to integrate the
to be viewed as an analytical subsystem of an system as a whole’ (Dunlop, 1993: 53). A key
industrial society on the same logical plane feature of this ideology for Dunlop was that it
as an economic system, regarded as another conferred legitimacy on all of the actors, such
analytical subsystem’. that each accepted the rightful existence and
The IR system itself comprised a number entitlement to action within the system of the
of elements. At its core were three sets others.
of actors: workers and their institutions,
including trade unions, works councils and
Critique
political parties; a management hierarchy and
the collective organizations of employers; Dunlop’s systems model has cast a long
and specialist institutions of the state, such shadow over IR. Analogous, though less
as the US National Labor Relations Board abstract, definitions of the field have been
(Dunlop, 1993: 47–8). The interaction of these developed by other theorists, from other
actors generated two types of rule, proce- countries (Clegg, 1975; Flanders, 1965).
dural rules that governed their interaction, Scholars have also returned to the original
including procedures for collective bargaining schema and sought to update it for the
and dispute resolution, and substantive rules present (Kaufman, 2004a; Meltz, 1993). More
that specified the terms of the employment generally, Dunlop’s conceptual map of IR
relationship, including pay, hours of work, as a system comprised of context, actors,
work organization and working practices. processes and outcomes has been hard-wired
This web of rules was the vital output of into IR thinking and is followed repeatedly
the IR system in Dunlop’s schema (Dunlop, in course syllabi and textbooks (for example,
1993: 51). Its function was largely integrative, Blyton and Turnbull, 2004).
to allow the regulation of conflict and in doing Dunlop’s system has also been subject
so promote the stability of industrial society. to challenge and there is now an extensive
Influenced by the functionalist sociology critical literature that ranges from revisionist
of Talcott Parsons (Kaufman, 2004b: 254; to fundamental critique. The purpose of what
Hyman, 2004: 265), Dunlop regarded the follows is not to review this critical literature
IR sub-system as discharging a broadly in its totality (see Kaufman, 2004b: 252–5) but
integrative function for society as a whole. rather, themes within it are identified and used
There were two additional elements to to highlight developments in the definition of
Dunlop’s schema, both of which shaped the the field and its constituent elements since
behavior of IR actors. On the one hand, Dunlop was writing. It should also be noted
the IR context influenced IR actors and the that Dunlop’s text was both sophisticated
procedural and substantive rules they created. and often qualified in its arguments but that
Three contexts were regarded as critical: many of the subtleties of his work have been
overlooked by later writers. The focus here,
• the ‘technological characteristics of the work- however, is on his critics’reading of Industrial
place’; Relations Systems rather than an exposition of
• the ‘product and factor markets or budgetary the book itself.
constraints that impinge on the actors’; and
• ‘the locus and distribution of power in the wider System boundaries
society’ (Dunlop, 1993: 48). The cornerstone of Dunlop’s system was the
claim that IR was comprised of a discrete
As these ‘inputs’ to the IR system altered so sub-system of industrial society and one
the web of rules adjusted in order to maintain avenue of critique has been to challenge the
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 71

accuracy of this formulation (Hyman, 2004: engaged in formal processes of rule-making,


267). Critics have wanted to push back the particularly collective bargaining (Hyman,
boundary Dunlop drew around the subject and 1975; Kaufman, 2004b: 254). The critical
in some cases erase it altogether. Recently, response, once more, has been to push back the
two attempts at boundary extension have been boundaries and extend the roster of IR actors.
prominent. On the one hand, there has been One early line of revision was to focus on
an attempt to erase the line between politics workplace actors, particularly informal work
and IR, joining the latter to a broader field groups and union stewards, whose militancy
of political economy. Thus, Howell (2005), posed a ‘challenge from below’ to official IR
in a review of the history of the British institutions in many countries in the 1960s
trade union movement, has argued that union and 1970s (Bain and Clegg, 1974; Hyman,
power, membership and strategies were not 1975: 16–7). More recently, this argument
derived primarily from markets or technology has been restated with a feminist twist. The
or developed within an autonomous system relative exclusion of women’s interests from
of industrial relations. Rather, they were the formal institutions of IR, it has been
powerfully determined by the policies of the suggested, requires a focus on the workplace,
British state and its successive modes of on women’s workgroups and women activists,
intervention in industrial relations. On the if these are to be adequately researched
other hand, there has been an attempt to (Greene, 2003: 309).
connect IR, the sphere of the employment Another response has been to focus on
relationship, to the domestic sphere and the new institutional actors in industrial relations,
analysis of family structure and relationships. whose activities have risen to prominence
This originates largely in a feminist critique since Dunlop was writing or whose signif-
of IR for abstracting the workplace from icance did not register in the intellectual
other areas of social life and assuming it is concerns of his day. One group of actors
populated by gender-neutral subjects (Greene, that have begun to attract the attention of
2003; Wacjman, 2000). In fact, it is asserted, IR scholars is social movement organizations
the substantive rules governing the work of that seek to represent workers’ interests.
men and women are gendered and rest on the As unions – a central actor in Dunlop’s
domestic division of labor, which inter alia schema – have declined in membership and
generates different patterns of labor market power there has been a growth of interest in
participation for the sexes. For those adopting campaigning, advocacy, advisory and service-
this position a fruitful line of research providing institutions that discharge some of
has developed examining the relationship their functions, often for a particular segment
between paid work and domestic and private of the workforce or an identity group (for
life. This has embraced studies of work- example Abbott, 2006; Fine, 2006; Osterman,
life (im)balance, family-friendly practices and 2006). Many of these bodies are rooted in
the links between employment and stages of the new social movements that have emerged
the life-cycle, the latter particularly in the since Dunlop’s time and which have exerted
context of an ageing workforce (for example a powerful influence, particularly over the
Appelbaum et al., 2005; Blyton et al., 2006; system of legal regulation (Piore and Safford,
Duncan et al., 2000).1 2006). Another set of actors that has attracted
some attention are the organizations of end-
System actors users – clients or customers – which may
Dunlop’s roll-call of industrial relations actors shape patterns of service and the work and
was quite extensive. In his own work, employment relations that underpin them (for
however, and in the tradition of IR scholarship example Bellemare, 2000).2 Dunlop oper-
of which he was a part, there tended to be ated within a ‘production-based paradigm’
a narrower focus on collective actors, trade (Korczynski, 2003: 266), which restricted its
unions, employers and state bureaucracies, concern to the relative interests of workers
72 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and employers. Many IR specialists retain and ideology of managers in shaping the
this restricted view but this has become less response of firms to environmental pressures.
tenable in a period when the figure of the The latter ‘do not strictly determine industrial
consumer, and the organizations that give relations outcomes’ (Kochan et al., 1986: 14)
expression to consumer interests, have risen but leave scope for choice, which is exercised
in importance. A final point to note about the in accordance with the ideologically-shaped
interest of IR specialists in new actors is that preferences of managerial decision-makers.
it embraces their relationship with the ‘old’, The logical inference is that patterns of IR will
particularly trade unions. There has been a vary under common technological, market
growth of research on worker-consumer and and institutional conditions as managers inter-
worker-community coalitions and the degree pret the business environment and exercise
to which trade unions can enlist the resources discretion within a framing ideology. While
of new actors as a counter to employers and to this first response emphasizes variation within
promote their own revitalization (for example national economies, the second emphasizes
Foster and Scott, 1998; Frege et al., 2004; variation across countries. Drawing on the
Ogden, 1991; Tattersall, 2005). new institutionalist literature, Godard (2004)
has stressed the enduring differences in
Causation the configuration and outcomes of national
Critics of systems theory have also targeted systems of IR despite common technical
Dunlop’s approach to the explanation of and market pressures. The logical inference
IR phenomena. One target has been the here is that the institutional form of capi-
determinism that many authors detect in talist economies carries greater explanatory
Dunlop’s model with its emphasis on the weight than do the conditioning effects of
adaptation of IR rules particularly to the forces technology and market and, indeed, that
of technical change and market pressures the latter are themselves shaped by the
(Godard, 2004: 230; for a contrary assessment institutional matrix in which they operate.
of this aspect of Dunlop’s work see Fiorito, For institutionalists the capacity to exploit
1990). An associated target has been the new technologies and develop a sustained
celebrated ‘convergence thesis’, developed by presence in particular product markets will
Dunlop in collaboration with Clark Kerr, Fred reflect the institutional form of a particular
Harbison and Charles Myers in another classic ‘variety of capitalism’, including labor market
text of early American IR, Industrialism (IR) institutions which generate particular sets
and Industrial Man (Kerr et al., 1955). of skills and support particular forms of work
This declared that, as countries underwent organization.
technological development and industrialized
so they developed a common form of social Integrative ideology
and economic order, ‘characterized by an Dunlop’s claim that the IR system was knitted
open and mobile society, an educated and together by an integrative ideology has been
technocratic workforce, a pluralistic set of another object of criticism, with critics offer-
organized interest groups, a reduced level of ing alternative understandings of the role of
industrial conflict, and increasing government ideology within IR. One alternative position
regulation of the labor market’ (Kaufman, has been effectively to accept the substantive
2004b: 259). content of Dunlop’s argument but evaluate
Two responses to this perceived combina- the effects of ideology from a competing
tion of determinism and convergence have normative position. Richard Hyman and Ian
been forthcoming, both of which emphasize Brough, in Social Values and Industrial
the diversity of IR at common levels of eco- Relations (1975), argued that the effect of
nomic development. Thomas Kochan, Harry accepted notions of fair payment and occupa-
Katz and Robert McKersie have emphasized tional worth was to shorten worker objectives
the roles of ‘strategic choice’ and the values and contribute to the stabilization of an
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 73

oppressive economic order. Essentially, this the industrial relations system, in this case by
is a variant of what sociologists have labeled undermining the authority of employers.
the ‘dominant ideology thesis’ (Hill, 1990), a
belief that values and interpretative schema System outcomes
play a critical part in social reproduction and A final component of Dunlop’s cross-sectional
reconcile those who are exploited to their model that has attracted criticism is his
condition. conception of IR outcomes as a web of
A second position was developed by substantive and procedural rules that promote
writers, such asAlan Fox and John Goldthorpe social integration. Attack here has followed
(see Gilbert, 1986: 19–49), and stressed the two avenues. On the one hand, it has
anomic character of industrial relations, the been suggested that Dunlop mis-specifies the
absence of normative constraints on distri- outcomes of the IR system. The web of rules
butional conflict within advanced industrial should be conceived, not as defining outcomes
societies. For these writers the decay of themselves but as ‘independent or mediating
the traditional status order through forces variables’ that potentially shape the ‘various
of modernity had unleashed a spiral of outcomes and behaviors’ in which scholars
competition for material resources, which are interested, such as ‘wage rates, strikes,
under the conditions of the 1970s of full work effort and union organizing success’
employment and strong trade unions when (Kaufman, 2004a: 48–9). Since Dunlop wrote,
they were writing, stoked the rate of inflation.3 under the tutelage of labor economics, there
The hallmark of this position, therefore, was has been an explosion of work that seeks to
a de-emphasis of the role of ideology within explain substantive outcomes of this kind and
IR and an associated stress on the instability determine the extent to which they are shaped
of the IR system. by particular institutional configurations (for
A third position differs again and places example Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Metcalf,
ideology back at the center of IR analysis 1989; Rubery et al., 1999). Much of this
but casts it as a corrosive force, attacking the work has focused on business outcomes, such
established IR system, rather than supporting as productivity, financial performance and
it. Thus, Kochan et al. (1986) argued that competitiveness, whether measured at the
American business ideology has been a level of the individual firm or that of the
major force behind the transformation of the national economy (see Nolan and O’Donnell,
Dunlopian industrial relations system in the 2003). But increasingly, IR scholars have
US and noted that a central characteristic of assessed outcomes for workers, such as decent
that ideology has been a failure to accept work or workplace well-being, using the
or accord legitimacy to trade unions (see same basic methodology (for example Brown
also Logan, 2006). A similar development et al., 2006; Green, 2006). There has also
can be seen in the analysis of the trade been a recent growth in attempts to evaluate
union movement. Drawing on the sociology IR outcomes from an explicitly ethical
of social movements, John Kelly (1998) perspective, reflecting the emergence of the
has argued that the ideological framing corporate social responsibility movement and
of grievances by vanguard militants is an the rise of business ethics as a distinct field
essential component of worker mobilization of inquiry (for example Budd and Scoville,
through unions. On this view, ideologies that 2005).
legitimize grievances, attribute their source to On the other hand, scholars have challenged
the actions of employers and present plausible the functionality of the IR system, what
solutions to their resolution play a key part many believe to have been Dunlop’s core
in mobilizing workers in periodic waves of proposition. This attack has come from each
conflict that challenge the existing IR system. of the main normative positions within IR.
A key function of ideology in this formulation, From the radical wing it has been argued
once again, is to delegitimize other actors in that Dunlop over-estimated the capacity of
74 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

the IR system to regulate conflict. The has possibly been the most attacked element
deep fissures of interest running through the of his schema, it has experienced a curious,
employment relationship, on this view, make though little acknowledged revival (see Budd
any accommodation unstable and prone to et al., 2004).
collapse (Hyman, 1975: 12). The pluralist
center has been more accepting of Dunlop’s
position, granting that a functional equiva- RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
lence between the IR system and the economic
and social order is theoretically possible, The tradition of systems thinking epitomized
while spending much effort identifying the by Dunlop continues to exert influence and be
dysfunctions of actually existing systems. developed within IR. Today, it is possible to
A common position adopted by pluralists, identify three broad positions or perspectives
from the British authors of the Donovan on that tradition. The first rejects it utterly and
report (Fox, 1966) to those wishing to holds that the attempt by Dunlop to establish
adapt IR to the flexible, high-performance a general theory of IR that defines its object
economy (Osterman et al., 2001), is to posit of study, constituent elements and function
an ‘institutional lag’, an urgent need to is irredeemably flawed. This argument has
reform IR institutions to match a changed recently been powerfully made by Richard
economy. Hyman who declares, ‘it is neither possible
Perhaps the most severe critique, however, nor desirable to pursue a self contained
has come from a unitary perspective of a neo- theory of industrial relations …’ (2004: 267).
liberal stamp. From the New Right the rules Hyman’s rejection of the systems tradition
of the IR system – whether these be joint rests on a number of grounds, some of which
decision-making with worker representatives, have been identified above. He is critical
collective agreements or minimum wage of its roots in the conservative sociology
laws – have been the sustained target of what of the 1950s, its technical determinism,
Hirschman (1991) identifies as the three main conception of IR as a bounded, largely self-
forms of the ‘rhetoric of reaction’, futility, contained sub-system and assumption that
perversity and jeopardy. Regulation through human agents unreflexively perform the roles
the IR system has been condemned as futile, allocated to them by the system’s functional
a form of ‘mock bureaucracy’ unable to imperative. He also makes two additional
buck market forces or, when its potency is criticisms, however, which are directed at
accepted, said to generate perverse effects that any general theory of IR, even one purged
harm the interests of workers by generating of the unsatisfactory elements in Dunlop’s
unemployment or jeopardize other desirable conception. First, he argues that the historical
conditions, such as competitiveness or liberty origins of IR deny its theoretical coherence.
(see Richardson, 1996). In the face of this The field, he argues, has developed in an
critique, indeed, there has been something of ad hoc fashion in response to the changing
a retreat to Dunlop’s functionalist argument needs of states and employers rather than
amongst the opponents of neo-liberalism. ‘to any underlying intellectual rationale’ and
Pluralists have argued that the rules of for this reason cannot be endowed with
the IR system impose a benign constraint, ‘analytical coherence after the event’ (2004:
shutting off the low road of price competition 266).4 Second, he argues that both the practice
(Streeck, 1992: 29–35), that trade unions and and study of IR vary so greatly across national
collective bargaining generate productivity boundaries as to make the quest for a general
improvements and other benefits (Freeman, specification of the IR system pointless. The
1992; Freeman and Medoff, 1984), and object of study varies, embracing social policy
that deregulation poses a threat to social as well as employment in some European
integration (Clark, 1993). While Dunlop’s countries, as do research traditions, including
belief in the functionality of the IR system different patterns of disciplinary demarcation.
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 75

‘We industrial relations scholars’, Hyman embraces three institutional domains that
notes, ‘cannot assume that we have counter- regulate or govern that relationship. Most
parts in other countries’ (2004: 272). proximate is the institution of the firm with
Hyman is not content to leave IR as its management hierarchy and internal labor
a pragmatic, policy-oriented field and calls market, next are the product and labor
for greater theoretical sophistication (2004: markets in which the firm operates, and
267–9). Specifically, he suggests that IR third are collective institutions, including the
scholars need to have more regard to the representative organs of capital and labor,
theory of theory and, in particular, address the state agencies and civil society organizations.
attributes of effective theorizing. Following Beyond this institutional sphere the employ-
Przeworski and Teune (1970), he argues that ment relationship is shaped by more distant
theories should be judged on the extent to environmental factors, including social forces
which they satisfy four competing (and to (for instance culture, class, ideology, ethics,
a degree contradictory) criteria, generality, history), law and science and technology
parsimony, accuracy and causality, the latter (Kaufman, 2004a: 49–62).
defined in terms of the explanation rather Unlike Dunlop, Kaufman is not prescriptive
than mere observation of ‘a relationship about the explanandum of IR, the dependent
among factors’(Hyman, 1994: 173). Hyman’s variables, empirical regularities or behaviors
position therefore declares a need for theory it seeks to explain. What he does suggest is
in IR, as opposed to the Dunlopian project of that the phenomena to be explained by IR
a theory of IR. Essentially it is a call for IR can be ordered hierarchically and depends
to connect with meta-theory, the concern with on the level of analysis. At the highest
the ontological status of the social world and level, the purpose is to explain the existence
the epistemic status of social theory, which of the employment relationship itself and
is central to other fields of social science but identify the complex of exogenous forces that
typically remote from pragmatic, empiricist formed that relationship and institutionalized
IR (see also Edwards, 2005; Godard, 1993). it within developed societies. At the next level
the ‘institutional structure and configuration
of the employment relationship’ is to be
Employment relations system
explained, at the next the ‘form, operation and
The second position is occupied by those performance of individual institutions’ and
who would purge Dunlop’s legacy of its so on until at the final level the focus is on
undesirable elements and renew the systems ‘all the individual personal and organizational
tradition. For writers in this camp, such outcomes and behaviors that emanate from the
as Meltz (1993) and Kaufman (2004a), the employment relationship’. The latter include
creation of a general theory of IR remains the common foci of research studies published
a viable project. Kaufman’s recent attempt in IR journals, ‘such as job satisfaction, work
to lay the basis of an ‘integrative theory of effort, plant-level productivity, extent of high
industrial relations’ is particularly noteworthy performance work practices, compensation
and deals with three issues: defining the and benefit levels, worker desire for union
object of study of IR, identifying the primary representation and many others besides’
outcomes and behaviors to be explained and (Kaufman, 2004a: 69).
listing the ‘key explanatory components … Neither is Kaufman prescriptive about the
and processes that must be included in the causal factors that should guide IR analysis.
theory’ (2004a: 42). The analytical core of His ERS model clearly implies an interest
IR, in Kaufman’s model, is the employment in the causal links between the broad social
relationship, in which formally free labor is and technical context, the three institutional
hired by an employer to engage in a labor domains (firms, markets and collective insti-
process. From this starting point, he elaborates tutions) and the nature of the employment
an ‘employment relations system’ (ERS) that relationship. But there is no assumption of
76 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

causal priority being allocated to a particular accuracy and has been developed by IR
level and the model leaves ample scope comparativists (for example Marsden, 1999).
for feedback loops and for phenomena at The intention here is not to develop a
different levels to interact and condition each general model of the IR system but to
other. What Kaufman does state, however, identify different national types; to map and
is that IR is a boundary-spanning field that account for variation. It is in this guise
is concerned both with the functioning of that systems-thinking currently exerts most
markets and the workings of hierarchies, influence over IR scholarship, particularly
the domains respectively of economics and through the Varieties of Capitalism (VoC)
organization studies. In seeking to develop school, founded by Peter A. Hall and David
explanations the field should seek to draw on Soskice (1998). The main elements of the
both of these fields and Kaufman believes that latter are dealt with elsewhere in this volume
theoretical work in IR is best derived from (see Chapter 7) but its primary characteristic
the tradition of institutional economics most is the identification of two main forms of
strongly associated with the work of Oliver capitalist economy that solve problems of
Williamson (Kaufman, 2004a: 72). co-ordination (between firms themselves and
Kaufman’s ERS model is developed from between firms and investors and firms and
a critique of Dunlop’s earlier conception of employees) in different ways. In ‘liberal
the IR system and seeks to correct what are market economies’, exemplified by the US,
seen by many as the defects of that concep- co-ordination is primarily through lightly
tion. In Kaufman’s formulation the field is regulated markets, while in ‘co-ordinated
broadened beyond trade unions and collective market economies’, such as Germany, formal
bargaining, there are no assumptions about the encompassing institutions and other non-
functionality of IR and there is a deliberate market mechanisms play a much greater role.
attempt to allow for strategic actors who Both types of economy are characterized by
interact with and shape their institutional and an interlocking and stable set of institutional
wider environment. Like Dunlop the main mechanisms that govern the financing of
concern is to provide a descriptive map of IR, firms, skill formation, wage determination,
to list the component elements of the subject labor processes and inter-firm relations. Each
so that its bounds are clear and differentiated of these institutional combinations possesses
from other fields. To this author, reflective functionality and market and non-market
stock-taking of this kind performs a useful forms of co-ordination are held to confer
service but the strength of Kaufman’s model equivalent though different forms of compar-
is also its weakness. It comprises a much ative advantage on their respective national
fuller listing of the elements of IR (context, economies. In liberal market economies firms
processes and outcomes) than that found in have greater capacity for innovation and have
Dunlop, which better reflects the nature of successfully developed new industries, while
contemporary employment relations. But the in co-ordinated market economies, long-term,
result is a rather anodyne, contentless model, high trust relations between firms, investors
with which it is difficult to find fault but and employees, support incremental change
which provides only a preliminary guide to and competition on the basis of high value
analysis.5 To use Hyman’s terms, generality added in mature manufacturing (Hall and
has been pursued at the expense of parsimony, Soskice, 1998: 14–7).
accuracy and causality. Hall and Soskice’s theory is a contribution
to comparative political economy rather than
IR as such though it has attracted increasing
Varieties of capitalism
attention from IR scholars (for example,
The third contemporary perspective on sys- Godard, 2004). It is a perspective that erodes
tems thinking effectively tries to strike a the boundary between IR and other fields
more even balance between generality and of analysis and seeks to examine IR as an
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 77

integral part of a national business system liberal and co-ordinated economies and that
rather than as a distinct sub-system, sufficient scope for ‘strategic choice’ remains. The
to itself. Thus, drawing on this literature, ‘emphasis on institutional complementari-
Gospel and Pendleton (2003) have examined ties and isomorphic processes’ in Hall and
the implications for IR of ‘insider’ and Soskice’s approach, they say, ‘tends to down-
‘outsider’ forms of business financing and grade the elements of national systems that do
corporate governance, which are representa- not fit the core characteristics of the model’
tive respectively of coordinated and liberal (2003: 571). This argument is reminiscent
market economies. They identify six features of that developed in response to Dunlop’s
of management that vary between these two systems theory by Kochan et al. (1986) in
types, all of which have major implications The Transformation of American Industrial
for the conduct of IR. These are: Relations, which also hinged on an actor-
based account of within-system variation.
1. the responsiveness of enterprise management
Other commentators on Hall and Soskice
to the relative interests of capital and labor; have applied elements of the classic critique
2. the time-frame of managerial decision-making; of systems theory to their work. Perhaps
3. the nature of business strategies; the most noteworthy is Colin Crouch in
4. the importance allocated to financial measures in his book Capitalist Diversity and Change
management decision-making; (2005a; see also Crouch, 2005b). Among
5. the approach to securing employee commitment; other criticisms, Crouch attacks the VoC
and model for its functionalism, determinism and
6. the degree of cooperation with other firms (Gospel conception of firms as ‘institution takers’;
and Pendleton, 2003: 565). actors that repeatedly enact the roles that each
type of business system requires. His central
Simplifying, it is argued that in market out- target, however, is one that has frequently
sider (liberal) economies managers are driven been identified in the critique of systems
by considerations of shareholder value and theory, the inability of the model to allow for
regard employees as a factor of production; or explain change over time. Crouch notes the
time-frames are shorter reducing the scope strong emphasis on path determinacy within
for investment in skills or partnership with the VoC approach and the tendency of its
employees; business strategies are finance adherents to account for social change through
driven and emphasize cost reduction; the exogenous forces that disrupt the established
use of financial ratios to guide management institutional pattern (Crouch, 2005a: 16; see
decision-making discourages the develop- also Streeck and Thelen, 2005).
ment of less tangible assets such as trust In response Crouch makes two points, one
or firm-specific skills; commitment is sought methodological the other substantive. The
through financial incentives; and weak ties methodological point refers to the form of
between firms are reflected in devolved, plant- case analysis that VoC writers employ, which
level bargaining. The reverse pattern, charac- Crouch characterizes as ‘the labeling method’
terized by longer-term decision-making and (2005b: 452). In this approach,
less emphasis on financial controls, is held to
the neo-institutionalist researcher … inspects the
be characteristic of ‘insider’ or ‘coordinated’ characteristics of an empirical case and decides
systems and provides the basis for a less which of a limited number of theoretical models …
adversarial, investment orientation to the it most closely resembles. The case is then
workforce. considered to be ‘an example’ of that model and
Having delineated the place of IR in labeled accordingly, all features of it which do
not fit the model being considered as ‘noise’ and
different types of national business system, disregarded.
Gospel and Pendleton immediately enter a
qualification. They note that the practice of The alternative favored by Crouch is the
labor management varies enormously within ‘analytical method’, in which cases are
78 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

not conflated with theoretical models but models of change that have been elaborated
are assumed to consist of an amalgam of within IR that we now turn.
principles of social organization each capable
of theoretical description in a separate ideal
type.6 The complexity of cases then provides MODELS OF CHANGE
the ground on which change can occur.
Crouch’s substantive argument is that institu- Much IR research in the positivist tradition is
tional change occurs within societies through modeled on the nomothetic natural sciences:
the action of ‘institutional entrepreneurs’ it seeks to establish regularities between
who typically combine previously discrete variables abstracted from time and space.
forms of practice to create new forms. There is an alternative conception of IR as
Change is always recombinant, therefore, a quintessentially historical subject, however,
drawing upon complexity to develop new which, like the historical natural sciences of
institutions. geology and biology, is concerned with the
An example can be seen in the changing evolution of forms (for example, forms of
repertoire of trade unions in the light of labor process, management control systems,
the growing juridification of the employ- trade unionism and modes of state regulation)
ment relationship. In Britain, unions have through time.7 Adherents of this position have
responded to the opportunity afforded by a urged IR scholars repeatedly to be sensitive to
growing volume of law to make greater use the historical origins of the institutions they
of the method of legal regulation and pursue study and have recommended that historical
strategic cases through the courts, particularly subjects and historical methods be included
in the area of discrimination and equality within IR (for example, Lyddon, 2004). In
law. Cases, however, have been integrated what follows this historical imperative is
with the established method of representation accepted but it is also accepted that change
through collective bargaining and a form of can proceed with different rhythms and
pattern bargaining has emerged in which legal under different kinds of propulsive force.
action (or the threat of legal action) has Accordingly, there is an attempt to map the
been used to establish precedents that are models of historical change that are employed
then diffused through collective agreements by IR scholars and which are embedded in
(Heery et al., 2004: 147). Entrepreneurs their empirical work.
within the labor movement, therefore, have This typology is shown in Table 4.1
developed a new, post-voluntarist form of and is comprised of three dichotomous
interest representation that combines previ- elements. In the first place a distinction is
ously distinct institutions. drawn between processes of change that are
Much of Crouch’s response to the VoC cyclical and those that are directional or
school echoes the critical reaction to earlier non-repetitive. In the second, a distinction is
systems models within IR. As systems theory drawn between directional models of change
has re-emerged in this latest form so the that are gradualist or disjunctive; in the
established elements of critique have been former change is steady and cumulative while
articulated; that systems models are deter- in the latter it is catastrophic with sudden
minist, functionalist, allow minimal scope for episodes of change disrupting long periods of
action and choice, are neglectful of variation stability. This disjunctive pattern is frequently
and fail to explain change. This contest is described as ‘punctuated equilibrium’ (see
perennial in social theory. On one side stand Erickson and Kuruvilla, 1998: 9). The third
those who prioritize the explanation of order dichotomy embraces the causes of change and
and on the other are those who seek to explain is based on the familiar distinction between
change, typically by identifying conflict, con- change that is endogenous, originating within
tradiction or complexity as defining elements IR, and change that is exogenous, driven by
of the social world. It is to a fuller account of forces beyond. In combination these variables
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 79

Table 4.1 Models of change underpinning theories of union revitalization


Directional Cyclical
Gradual Disjunctive
Exogenous 1. Stages of development 2. Historical compromise 3. Long waves
Labor-management Social movement unionism a Periodic mobilization of the
partnership a response to response to the neo-liberal turn labor movement generated by
selective pressure exerted by in politics and the collapse of Kondratieff long waves that
technical change (high an earlier accommodation lead both to the accumulation
performance work systems) or between state and labor of grievances and the
the widening scope of product organizational capacity for
markets (globalization) mobilization
Endogenous 6. Social learning 5. Strategic choice 4. Unfolding contradiction
New union strategies are Union revitalization a product Union renewal a function of
diffused by processes of social of strategic choice, reflecting the perennial contest between
learning between and within political competition and the the forces of accommodation
national labor movements; key incursion of new waves of and challenge within the labor
processes include mimetic and activist into positions of power movement
normative isomorphism within unions

generate six types or models of historical this literature partnership is conceived as


change, each of which can be illustrated by an adaptive response to selective pressure
the literature on ‘union revitalization’; one of emanating in some versions from technical
the prime foci of recent IR scholarship that is change, particularly the spread of high
concerned explicitly with explaining changes performance work systems, and in others from
in behavior over time (see Heery et al., 2004: the globalization of product markets.
3–21). The argument from technical change has
been developed by North American writ-
ers influenced by theories of post-Fordism
Exogenous models
or post-industrialism (Appelbaum and Batt,
The first of the six types emphasizes gradual, 1994: 123–45; Bélanger et al., 2002: 45).
cumulative change driven by forces beyond In this formulation the spread of high per-
the employment relationship. Models of this formance work systems requires employers
type have been an enduring feature of IR and to invest in high commitment management
underpinned some of the classic statements to secure the necessary levels of skill,
of its founding fathers. Commons’ analysis commitment and flexibility. This, in turn,
of the growth of national unions and national provides new scope for identifying shared
systems of bargaining in the USA in response interests between employers and employees.
to the growing scale of product markets Accordingly, a new unionism can emerge
provides one example (see Brown, Chapter 6 that centers on advancing employees’interests
of this volume). Another is provided by Kerr in development, involvement and job satis-
et al.’s Industrialism and Industrial Man faction and which makes use of partnership
(1955), in which the creation of a ‘mature’ to embed new forms of production, and
system of industrial relations is presented as their associated management practices, in
a functional adaptation to industrialization. the economy (Frost, 2001). A second, less
Both types of argument continue to be made upbeat account of partnership can be found
today and can be seen in the contemporary in the work of British writers who emphasize
literature on union revitalization, particularly the widening scale of product markets.
that concerned with union use of ‘partnership’ According to Brown and colleagues (Brown
or ‘mutual gains’ strategies to reconstitute et al., 1998: 73; Brown et al., 2000: 616–9;
their relations with employers. In much of Oxenbridge et al., 2003: 324–32), exposure of
80 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

domestic markets to international competition external shock: short bursts of institution-


has led to two broad changes in interest building prompted by crisis, which give way
representation. On the one hand, distributive to long periods of inertia or gradual change.
bargaining by unions to secure a wage The argument in the literature on union
premium has become less tenable. On the revitalization that approximates most closely
other hand, the heightened competitive threat to this model is that which relates experiment
encourages workers and their representatives with ‘social movement unionism’ to the rise
to develop a ‘productivity coalition’ with of neo-liberalism (Robinson, 2002). In this
employers, in which security of employment argument the latter is identified as a political
is exchanged for flexibility. The product of and ideological construct, the carriers of
the first change is a union search for a which have secured control of governments
new modus vivendi while the effect of the often through fortuitous or contingent cir-
second is to channel that search toward either cumstances. They have then proceeded to
formal or informal partnership arrangements attack the institutional and ideological foun-
with employers, based on an exchange of dations of the existing compromise between
cooperative work relations for job stability. state, capital and labor, through a policy of
The second model emphasizes discontinu- ‘labor exclusion’, of denying unions access
ity, episodes of change interspersed by periods to established channels of influence over
of stability; with change itself triggered government and employers (Crouch, 1985;
by the irruption of outside forces into the see also Howell, 2005: 141–58). This militant
employment relationship. Models of this kind strategy of shutting down the institutional
are perhaps less common in IR than those that resources of the labor movement, in time, can
stress the gradual evolution of forms through generate a militant response and the attempt
a sequence of stages but they do have a place. to recreate unions as social movements.
The best example can be seen in the argument The characteristics of the latter include an
that national systems of IR originate in a broad increased emphasis on recruiting and organiz-
political and economic crisis that results in ing, seeking to raise the ‘willingness to act’ of
an ‘historic compromise’, an accommodation workers through mobilization strategies and
between capital and labor enshrined in a set discursive frames that emphasize the pursuit
of IR institutions (for example Sisson, 1987). of social justice, the broadening of union goals
Developments subsequent to this episode beyond quantitative workplace demands and
of institution-building are then channeled a renewed commitment to acting on the terrain
along established paths by the force of of civil society, particularly through union-
path dependency; that is until a new crisis community coalitions (for example Turner
disrupts the system. This may originate in and Hurd, 2001; Wills, 2001). Fundamental
geo-political events that overwhelm existing to this strategy is an attempt to develop
IR institutions, requiring a search for a fresh new power resources by organizing more
accommodation between the stakeholders in workers, deepening their attachment to unions
the employment relationship. An example and capacity for mobilization and forging
can be seen in the impact of Second World alliances with other progressive forces in
War, which generated new institutions to help civil society. At its heart is an attempt
mobilize the working population in the victo- to compensate for the collapse of exter-
rious states and the transplant of institutions nal sources of power, resulting from the
to defeated states. Another is the collapse neo-liberal assault, through a revitalization
of the Soviet Empire, which prompted a strategy focused on building fresh, ‘inter-
search for new IR institutions across the nal’ sources of power. The key point to
previously subject states of Eastern Europe note, however, is that the origins of social
(for example Frege, 1999; Turner, 1998). movement unionism are seen to lie in a
The key features of this model, however, ‘catastrophic’event, the neo-liberal challenge,
remain the same whatever the nature of the which has rendered established patterns of
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 81

union action ineffective and encouraged a new (for example 1968–1974) when states and
departure. employers challenge entrenched union move-
In the catastrophic model there is an ments in order to re-establish profit and
emphasis on historical contingency, with growth levels. They can also be observed,
the evolution of trade unions and other IR in at least some countries, at the end of
institutions jolted onto unanticipated lines downswings when more favorable economic
of development as they encounter crisis. conditions generate power resources for orga-
In the third model, in contrast, there is an nized labor. The relevance of this argument to
assumption that change follows a repeating the debate over union revitalization appears
cycle of decline and renewal as IR institutions to be twofold. First, it suggests that the
adapt to cyclical pressures in their external current period of labor ‘quiescence’ cannot be
environment. The source of these pressures extrapolated into the future; at key transition-
has been variously identified in middle- points militancy may re-emerge. Second, the
range IR theories. From economics the argument is determinist in character and
business cycle has been identified as a key suggests that waves of worker mobilization
factor explaining the rise and fall of union will only emerge under particular conditions
membership and other IR indices (for example when the world economy moves into or out
Bain and Elsheikh, 1976). From politics it of an extended upswing. On this analysis it is
has been suggested that union-government the rise and fall of the world economy that
relations in periods of left government follow fundamentally determines the revitalization
a cyclical pattern; moving from tension to of the labor movement not the strategies or
accommodation as the reciprocal need to re- tactics of its constituent institutions.8
elect a non-hostile government and secure
union election funding becomes apparent
Endogenous models
(Ludlam and Taylor, 2003). And from soci-
ology the periodic organizational crises of Cyclical processes also lie at the core of
American labor, including the recent split the fourth model though in this case they
in the AFL–CIO, have been explained by originate in the employment relationship
reference to waves of mass immigration and itself. Theories of endogenous cyclical change
the tensions these impose on established union are typically rooted in a claim that the
structures (Cornfield, 2006). employment relationship embodies contradic-
Within the union revitalization literature a tory elements; competing impulses that push
notable example of this kind of argument can actors in different directions. For example,
be found in John Kelly’s (1998: 83–107) use of it is often suggested that the employment
Kondratieff cycles or ‘long waves’ to explain relationship is both adversarial, reflecting
recurrent episodes of union militancy. Kelly’s the opposing interests of employer and
starting point is the empirical observation worker, and cooperative, reflecting the mutual
by a variety of scholars that the world dependence of the two parties (Edwards et al.,
economy appears to move through extended 2006). One inference that can be drawn from
cycles of approximately 50 years in duration. this conceptualization is that management
In a sequence that stretches back into the strategies of labor use that assume the
nineteenth century an upswing, distinguished relation has a single, dominant characteristic
by above average growth, is followed after will encounter problems of implementation
about 25 years by a downswing, during as they confront neglected features. Thus,
which growth slackens. Kelly remains non- adversarial strategies of labor control may be
committal on the causal mechanism under- subverted by workers who retain tacit skills
pinning these long waves but notes that the and elements of discretion in even the most
transition points in the cycle are associated tightly regulated labor process, while attempts
with periodic strike waves. The latter are to build worker commitment to management
particularly apparent at the end of upswings goals may be undermined by the periodic
82 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

requirement to control costs or restructure once more.9 Union revitalization on this view,
the employing organization. In Hyman’s therefore, is expressed initially within unions
(1987: 30) famous phrase management strat- and takes the form of a rank-and-file chal-
egy can be regarded as ‘the programmatic lenge to an established and accommodative
choice between alternatives none of which oligarchy.
can prove satisfactory’. A further inference The fifth model emphasizes disjunctive
that can be drawn is that management strategy change that is generated within IR and is
will follow a cyclical or oscillating pattern, perhaps best illustrated by theories of strategic
prioritizing control or cooperation at one point choice. As we have seen these have grown
but switching direction when the limits of each in popularity in recent years and are distin-
approach become apparent. Contradiction, guished by allocating a zone of discretion to
that is, implies cyclical development. strategic actors (states, employers, unions), in
The same line of argument can be seen which they exercise choice within a context
in the analysis of trade unions, particularly of constraint. Episodes of choice therefore
in the influential model of trade union are the key points of disjuncture at which
renewal that has been put forward by Peter new forms emerge; whether these are new
Fairbrother (for example Fairbrother, 1996; management policies, new collective agree-
2000: 3–22). The starting point of this ments, new systems of union government
analysis is the identification of a similarly or new forms of employment law. The field
contradictory impulse within trade unions: of IR is now replete with typologies of
toward accommodation with employers on management and union strategy that seek
the one hand and toward challenge and to specify the menu of choices available
resistance on the other. The latter is gener- to strategic actors (for example Boxall and
ated in the immediate labor process where Haynes, 1997; Purcell and Ahlstrand, 1994).
workers experience exploitative conditions, There has also been a growth of research
while the former stems from the pressure on into the characteristics of actors that lead
representatives to seek institutional security them to exercise choice in a particular way,
from employers and state agencies. It follows to select a particular option from the menu.
that the impulse to accommodation will be In research on management, for instance,
stronger when unions are oligarchic and there has been a focus on the composition
representatives insulated from the potentially of the management team and the relative
militant pressure of the union rank- and-file. power of the different functional groups
Insulation can never be complete, however, represented within it (for example Colling
and the iron law of oligarchy potentially can and Dickens, 1998). The presence of HR
fail. This may be because employers intensify managers and the existence of a strong HR
the rate of exploitation and so generate a function have been identified in a number of
higher level of worker grievance or it may studies as a key factor shaping management
be because the decentralization of bargaining policy and practice, particularly in the area
to workplace level brings union decision- of equality (for example Hoque and Noon,
making closer to workers and more suscep- 2004; Kelly and Dobbin, 1999). In studies of
tible to influence. Both factors are believed union strategy a similar line of development is
to be significant in Fairbrother’s analysis and visible, with researchers variously identifying
have promoted the ‘renewal’ of public service the influence of gender, generational change
unions in Britain in recent years, understood and ideology in shaping strategic choice (see
both as a process of democratization and Heery, 2003: 293–5). On this view, disjunctive
as a growth of militancy. Whatever the change in union behavior is likely to stem from
trigger, however, the key underlying point the replacement of incumbent office holders
is that internal union politics follows a and activists with those of a different stamp.
cyclical pattern, in which accommodation In the literature on union revitalization
is challenged, re-established and challenged a stress on internally-generated disjunctive
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 83

change can be seen in the work of feminist conclusion of this process, of unions changing
IR scholars Fiona Colgan and Sue Ledwith to represent diversity.
(Ledwith and Colgan, 2002). They are The final model of change emphasizes
concerned with explaining the increasing gradual transformation, driven by forces
influence of women and minority groups in internal to IR. In one version there is
unions, a development that is visible across the a stress on IR institutions maturing over
globe and which has led to significant changes time, such that they become more complex
(albeit incomplete and contested) in internal and pursue more differentiated goals. An
union government and in the policies unions example might be the famous ‘iron law of
pursue toward employers and state. Colgan oligarchy’, developed by Robert Michels (see
and Ledwith note that unions have often Crouch, 1982: 163–5) to explain the retreat
pursued policies of exclusion or demarcation from revolutionary politics in trade unions
with regard to women and minority groups. and left political parties. In this argument
Under the former they are denied union the bureaucratization of labor institutions
membership and the benefits it provides, leads inexorably and irreversibly to goal
while under the latter they are accepted as displacement, as incumbent leaders develop
a secondary category of members confirming interests separate from the membership and
their secondary position in the labor market. use their leadership position both to pursue
Both policies have been challenged by these interests and insulate themselves from
the mobilization of women and minorities membership pressure. In a second version
within unions. Colgan and Ledwith note that there is an emphasis on social learning and
‘usurpation’ has often been a key stage in the gradual diffusion of forms across an
this process, defined as ‘where a subordinate institutional field. Key processes here might
group mobilizes through strategies of social include normative and mimetic isomorphism;
change to challenge the dominant group, that is the creation of standards of good IR
and succeeds in changing the structure of practice and their adoption by exemplars that
positions and balance of leadership between provide a model for other organizations.
the groups’ (ibid: 16). They note also that In the literature on union revitalization the
‘usurpation strategies’ are about ‘replacing latter argument is illustrated by studies of the
men with women, white members with black ‘organizing model’ and its international diffu-
and so on’ and consequently have often sion (Cooper, 2000; Heery et al., 2002; Hurd,
been fiercely resisted. The end result of this 1998; 2004; Oxenbridge, 1997). The concept
process can include ‘transformation’, that of an ‘organizing model’ was coined by
is the creation of radical new structures to American trade unionists in the late 1980s and
mainstream equality initiatives within unions, has since influenced policy debate and prac-
and ‘coalition’, understood as the develop- tice in unions across NorthAmerica,Australia,
ment of horizontal linkages between identity New Zealand, Britain and, more latterly, the
groups inside unions and collaboration with countries of continental Europe. It designates
social movement organizations in wider civil a conception of union good practice that com-
society. Much of this model of revitalization prises both core principles and a number of
resembles the union renewal thesis; they specific organizing techniques. The principles
have a shared emphasis on mobilization from include prioritizing organizing, seeking to
below. The key difference is that the change develop collective organization and capacity
described by Colgan and Ledwith is uni- amongst workers and a stress on mobilization
directional not cyclical; they are seeking through a framing discourse that calls for
to map the permanent impact on the ‘old’ ‘dignity, justice and respect’ at work. The
social movement of labor of the new social techniques include selecting strategic orga-
movements grounded in gender and other nizing targets, mounting planned campaigns,
diverse identities. For these writers union mapping workforces to identify members and
revitalization is dependent on the successful activists, using a representative ‘organizing
84 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

committee’ to ensure member involvement, of reference for those reflecting on the nature
and the use of escalating pressure tactics to of the subject (for example Piore and Safford,
foster mobilization and demonstrate union 2006). On the other hand, there has been an
effectiveness. The literature on the diffusion attempt to illuminate the models of historical
of this model has identified a number of factors change that underpin much IR analysis but
that have encouraged its spread both within which are often not articulated. The procedure
and between national labor movements and here has been to develop a typology of models
emphasizes gradual change through processes of change in IR and to illustrate this through
of deliberate learning. Among the factors that the literature on union revitalization.
have been identified has been the role of Critical engagement with Dunlop has itself
national union confederations in sponsoring followed two routes, reflecting the dual
the organizing model and encouraging its purpose of his scheme. Commentators have
diffusion by arranging seminars, conferences asked if it continues to provide a satisfactory
and visits to other countries and by estab- cross-section of IR; a descriptive mapping
lishing training programs for organizers. The of the field’s object study. They have also
latter include the Organizing Institute in the engaged with the causal elements of the
USA, Organizing Works in Australia and model – what Hyman (2004: 269) terms
the Organizing Academy in Britain (Foerster, the genuine ‘theoretical content’; that is, its
2001; Heery et al., 2002). There has also stress on technically-driven change, system
been a focus on the structural features of integration through a binding ideology and
unions that facilitate receptiveness to the assumption of functionality.
organizing model. Thus, Voss and Sherman As we have seen many IR scholars continue
(2000) note that revived union locals in the US to conceive of the field as a system comprising
that have prioritized organizing tend to have actors, processes, outcomes and context. Even
relatively strong links to the union center; amongst those sympathetic to the initial
that is, diffusion follows lines of articulation formulation, however, there is a concern to
between union headquarters and constituent update and extend Dunlop’s list of elements.
branches. The essential point to note in this The empirical substance of the field has
model of union revitalization, however, is that become less coherent but more extensive
change is conceived as diffusion, a gradual since Dunlop first published his book in 1958
process, and that it occurs through a process of and much of the first line of engagement
deliberate knowledge transfer; the latter being has been concerned to identify a greater
conducted through both formal institutional complexity in IR’s object of study. This drive
ties and informal networks within the labor to complexity can be seen in attempts to
movement. lower the boundary walls between Dunlop’s
neatly defined IR system and other, adjacent
fields of inquiry, whether these are political
CONCLUSION economy, the domestic sphere or the system
of corporate governance. It can also be seen
This chapter has reviewed two types of model- in the changing specification of each of the
building within IR through two, separate elements of Dunlop’s study. Thus, there has
processes of examination. On the one hand, been a focus on ‘new actors’ that articulate
it has considered cross-sectional models that interests, such as those of consumers or
seek to designate the object of study of IR, identity groups that were largely disregarded
list the component elements of the IR system at the time when Dunlop was writing. Other
and identify its functional outcomes. The developments include reduced attention to
procedure in this case has been to review collective bargaining as a rule-making process
the subject’s long dialogue with Dunlop’s with a corresponding growth of attention
Industrial Relations Systems (1993), which to management policy and the regulatory
despite its vintage continues to provide a point function of the state, an increased focus on
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 85

the quantifiable outcomes of IR processes of national economies and serving as a


and a change in perceptions of the context corrective to convergence theses, whether
of IR to give greater weight both to the grounded in technical or market determinism.
institutional sources of difference between Nevertheless, they share some of the same
national systems and the strategic choices of weaknesses of Dunlop’s systems theory. The
firms that underpin within-country variation. most persuasive critique is that of Crouch,
Dunlop’s first purpose was to specify clearly who notes the inability of VoC theory to
the object of study of IR, the IR system, allow for significant change. For Crouch,
and identify its constituent elements. The innovation can only be theorized if social
response to his work in the intervening period theory holds a place for contradiction and
points to the frustration of this purpose as complexity. VoC models, with their emphasis
the bounds of the subject have become more on the synergy between institutions, deny
ragged and its empirical subject matter has such a place. Allowing that societies include
grown. Coherence has been sacrificed for a variety of social practices that can be
complexity but to my mind this is a welcome recombined by institutional entrepreneurs
development reflecting real changes in the compromises the elegance of systems mod-
world of work. els but, once again, imports necessary
The substantive argument that many complexity.
believe to be at the heart of Dunlop’s book In Dunlop’s other great book, Industrialism
was that an integrated and institutionally and Industrial Man (1960), there is arguably
distinct IR system was a necessary element a Whiggish conception of history, in which
of industrial society, serving to regulate change advances gradually toward a desirable
economic conflict. This argument has been state.10 The IR system appears as the
repeatedly attacked in the intervening 50 years natural precipitation of a maturing capitalist
though perhaps surprisingly his assumption democracy, called into being by the need for
about the functionality of the IR system a social sub-system to regulate conflict. Many
has found fresh support as pluralist scholars other early IR texts carry this assumption; that
have sought to defend IR from neo-liberal industrial citizenship through trade unions and
attack. It is also the case that systems- collective bargaining, like political citizen-
thinking that is analogous to that of Dunlop ship before it, slowly spreads and civilizes
continues to be developed within IR. The the economy. The substantial erosion of IR
clearest example can be seen in the work institutions in recent decades means that this
of IR comparativists influenced by Hall and optimistic interpretation of the past is no
Soskice’s models of liberal and co-ordinated longer tenable. In its place can be identified
varieties of capitalism. Like Dunlop, there is a series of models of historical change. In
an emphasis in these models on the fixed, the empirical work of IR scholars change is
determined nature of business systems though regarded variously as gradual, disjunctive and
it is path dependency rather than economic cyclical and may be prompted by forces that
development that is the determining force. are internal or external to the employment
There is also a stress on the integrated, relationship. In much work these different
mutually reinforcing character of different models are opposed, as is illustrated by the
system elements, albeit extending beyond the work on union revitalization. For some, the
employment sphere, and on the functionality latter can only occur if unions adapt to secular
of competing business systems. Both liberal trends in work organization or the widening
and co-ordinated market economies can scale of product markets, while for others
prosper in the world economy. This revival of it will be prompted by the periodic crises
systems-thinking has had a positive impact on of capitalism or a challenge to incorporated
IR, boosting comparative work, encouraging union leaders from below. But models of
scholars to examine the links between IR historical change can also be combined,
institutions and other institutional domains such that cyclical processes occur between
86 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

episodes of ‘catastrophic’ reconstruction or a purpose in facilitating public interest disclosure by


secular trend exists beneath short-term cycli- employees is to protect citizens and consumers from
cal fluctuation. Historians have increasingly hazard or unscrupulous action by service providers and
manufacturers.
recognized that change occurs at variable 3 This perspective continues to be articulated
speeds, from Braudel’s classic distinction within IR. Peter Ackers’ call for a ‘neo-pluralism’
between the history of events, conjunctures (2002) is based on a diagnosis of social disintegration,
and the longue durée (Abrams, 1982: 334) to the prescription for which is the rebuilding of the
workplace status order through an ideology of
recent attempts to combine ‘continuitist’ and
stakeholding reinforced by the institutional practices
‘catastrophic’ readings of the past (Wickham, of worker involvement and labor-management part-
2006: 10–4). All of the models of historical nership.
change outlined in this chapter have validity 4 This is perhaps a demanding standard to apply
and can generate empirical and practical and invites a comparison – do other fields of social
inquiry differ both in terms of their responsiveness
insights for IR scholars; they can be combined.
to socially constituted interests and their intellectual
Like historians, IR scholars should recognize coherence? All fields have an external, social history
the complexity of historical processes and the and are shaped by interests and the changing
fact that change occurs in different rhythms definition of social problems, while also possessing
and at variable speeds. an internal, logical history in which practitioners add
knowledge and engage in debate (see Hawthorn,
1976). Whether IR’s social history is such as to dis-
qualify its pretension to the status of an autonomous
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS field is a difficult question to resolve.
5 To provide an example, one of Kaufman’s
conditioning social forces is ‘history’ and the point
I would like to thank Paul Blyton, Paul
is made that national systems of IR exhibit a
Edwards and Jack Fiorito for challenging but path dependency in which traditions and behavioral
helpful comments on an earlier draft of this patterns endure (Kaufman, 2004a: 59). This is clearly
chapter. an important initial observation but leaves more
demanding questions about the origins, nature and
strength of historical traditions to be posed and
resolved.
NOTES 6 Crouch (2005b: 449) notes that the labeling
method in comparative analysis is often defended in
1 These two examples constitute attempts to terms of its parsimony. His response, using Hyman’s
broaden the scope of IR but there has been another terms, is to note the tension between parsimony and
line of criticism, developed by Marxist writers, that accuracy in social theory and to contend that the
seeks to deepen IR analysis. The central claim here accuracy of the analytical approach, in which cases
is that the institutions and processes of the IR system are regarded as ‘amalgams of types’, is an acceptable
are epiphenomenal and that analysis must begin at price to pay for greater complexity.
a deeper level with the generative structures of the 7 The parallels between the historical sciences,
capitalist mode of production. For Hyman (1975: whatever their object of study, is a theme developed
18–19), ‘the crucial fact about the economies of by the great evolutionary biologist, the late Stephen
Western Europe and North America – where most Jay Gould. Gould is perhaps best known to social
studies of industrial relations have had their focus – scientists for his development (with Niles Eldredge)
is their capitalist character (emphasis in original)’ (see of the model of punctuated equilibrium, which has
also Hyman, 1989: 125). The exploitative condition of since diffused across many areas of social and natural
wage labor and the class conflict, which it generates, is inquiry. However, he also developed a useful typology
the source of the uncertain accommodation of capital of models of change in his book on the history of
and labor in the formal system of IR, described by geology, Time’s Arrow, Time’s Cycle (Gould, 1987).
Dunlop. In recognition of this fact, the field should Gould’s typology is the inspiration for much of what
be relabeled ‘the study of processes of control over follows.
work relations’ (Hyman, 1975: 12). 8 Kelly qualifies this determinist argument and
2 To provide one example, the campaigning earlier in the same book stresses the role of union
UK charity, Public Concern at Work, has lobbied leaders and activists in mobilizing workers. This seems
successfully for legislation protecting whistleblowers to express the classic division in Leninist thought
and advises employers and trade unions on public between the laws of motion of the capitalist mode
interest disclosure procedures. Its origins lie in the of production (understood here as a cyclical process
consumer movement, however, and its ultimate rather than a directional movement toward collapse),
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 87

which operate beyond the control of social actors, and Performance Workplace. London and New York:
the space for deliberate and decisive action that is Continuum. pp. 150–80.
reserved for a revolutionary vanguard. Bellemare, G. (2000) ‘End users: actors in the industrial
9 This cyclical process of challenge and accom- relations system?’, British Journal of Industrial
modation is at the heart of many interpretations of
Relations, 38 (3): 383–405.
change in trade unions (for example Turner, 2003).
A particularly graphic example can be seen in the
Beynon, H. (1984) Working for Ford, second edition.
changing interpretation of workplace shop stewards Harmondsworth: Penguin.
by left commentators on British trade unions in the Blyton, P., Blunsdon, B., Reed, K. and Dastmalchian,
1970s and 1980s. While the steward movement A. (eds) (2006) Work-Life Integration: International
of the 1960s was initially regarded as a ‘challenge Perspectives on the Balancing of Multiple Roles.
from below’ driving the renewal of UK unions, Basingtoke: Palgrave MacMillan.
by the end of the 1970s observers were noting Blyton, P. and Turnbull, P. (2004) The Dynamics
the ‘bureaucratization of the rank and file’ as the of Employee Relations, third edition. Basingstoke:
militant impulse flagged (Hyman, 1979). In Beynon’s
Palgrave MacMillan.
(1984: 371) classic study of the Ford Motor Company
in the UK, it is noted that a new rank-and-file
Boxall, P. and Haynes, P. (1997) ‘Strategy and trade
movement then began to emerge in opposition union effectiveness in a neo-liberal environment’,
to the ‘convenor system’ of ‘official’ workplace British Journal of Industrial Relations, 35 (4):
representatives and which labeled itself the ‘workers‘ 567–91.
combine committee’. Brown, A., Charlwood, A., Forde, C. and Spencer, D.
10 Elsewhere in Dunlop’s work, however, alterna- (2006) Changing Job Quality in Great Britain 1998–
tive models of change are deployed and, interestingly, 2004. Employment Relations Research Series No.70.
he was perhaps the earliest IR analyst to develop an London: Department of Trade and Industry.
interest in Kondratieff cycles (Dunlop, 1948).
Brown, W., Deakin, S., Hudson, M., Pratten, C. and
Ryan, P. (1998) The Individualization of Employment
Contracts in Britain. Employment Relations Research
Series No. 4. London: Department of Trade and
REFERENCES Industry.
Brown, W., Deakin, S., Nash, D. and Oxenbridge, S.
Abbott, B. (2006) ‘Determining the significance of the (2000) ‘The employment contract: from collective
Citizens’ Advice Bureau as an industrial relations procedures to individual rights’, British Journal of
actor’, Employee Relations, 28 (5): 435–48. Industrial Relations, 38 (4): 299–316.
Abrams, P. (1982) Historical Sociology. West Compton Budd, J.W., Gomez, R. and Meltz, N.M. (2004)
House near Shepton Mallet: Open Books. ‘Why a balance is best: the pluralist industrial
Ackers, P. (2002) ‘Reframing employment relations: the relations paradigm of balancing competing interests’,
case for neo-pluralism’, Industrial Relations Journal, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical Perspectives on
33 (1): 2–19. Work and the Employment Relationship. Urbana-
Appelbaum, E. and Batt, R. (1994) The New American Champaign IL: Industrial Relations Research Associa-
Workplace. Ithaca and London: ILR Press. tion. pp. 195–227.
Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg, A. Budd, J.W. and Scoville, J.G. (eds) (2005) The Ethics of
(2005) ‘Organizations and the intersection of work Human Resources and Industrial Relations. Urbana-
and family: a comparative perspective’, in S. Ackroyd, Champaign IL: Labor and Employment Relations
R. Batt, P. Thompson and P.S. Tolbert (eds) The Oxford Association.
Handbook of Work and Organization. Oxford: Oxford Clark, J. (1993) ‘Procedures and consistency versus
University Press. pp. 52–73. flexibility and commitment: a comment on Storey’,
Bain, G.S. and Clegg, H.A. (1974) ‘A strategy for Human Resource Management Journal, 4 (1): 79–81.
industrial relations research in Britain’, British Journal Clegg, H.A. (1975) ‘Pluralism in industrial relations’,
of Industrial Relations, 12 (1): 91–113. British Journal of Industrial Relations 13 (3): 309–16.
Bain, G.S. and Elsheikh, F. (1976) Union Growth and Colling, T. and Dickens, L. (1998) ‘Selling the case
the Business Cycle: An Econometric Analysis. Oxford: for gender equality: deregulation and equality
Basil Blackwell. bargaining’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Bélanger, P.R., Lapointe, P.A. and Lévesque, B. (2002) 36 (3): 389–411.
‘Workplace innovation and the role of institutions’, Cooper, R. (2000) ‘Organize, organize, organize. ACTU
in G. Murray, J. Bélanger. A. Giles and P.A. Lapointe conference 2000’, Journal of Industrial Relations,
(eds) Work and Employment Relations in the High 42 (4): 582–94.
88 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Cornfield, D. (2006) ‘Immigration, economic restructur- and Unions: The Theory and Reform of Industrial
ing, and labor ruptures: from the Amalgamated to Relations. London: Faber and Faber. pp. 83–128.
Change to Win’, Working USA, 9 (2): 215–23. Foerster, A. (2001) ‘Confronting the dilemmas of
Crouch, C. (1982) Trade Unions: The Logic of Collective organizing: obstacles and innovations at the AFL-
Action. Glasgow: Fontana. CIO’s Organizing Institute’, in L. Turner, H.C. Katz and
Crouch, C. (1985) ‘Conservative industrial relations R.W. Hurd (eds) Rekindling the Movement: Labor’s
policy: towards labour exclusion’, in O. Jacobi, Quest for Relevance in the 21st Century. Ithaca and
B. Jessop, H. Kastendiek and M. Regini (eds) Economic London: ILR Press. pp. 155–81.
Crisis, Trade Unions and the State. London: Croom Foster, D. and Scott, J. (1998) ‘Conceptualizing union
Helm. pp. 131–53. responses to contracting municipal services, 1979–
Crouch, C. (2005a) Capitalist Diversity and Change: 1997’, Industrial Relations Journal, 29 (2): 137–50.
Recombinant Governance and Institutional Fox, A. (1966) Industrial Sociology and Industrial
Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Relations, Research Paper 3, Royal Commission on
Crouch, C. (2005b) ‘Models of capitalism’, New Political Trade Unions and Employers’ Associations. London:
Economy, 10 (4): 441–56. HMSO.
Duncan, C., Loretto, W. and White, P. (2000) ‘Ageism, Freeman, R. (1992) ‘Is declining unionization of the US
early exit and British trade unions’, Industrial good, bad or irrelevant?’, in L. Mishel and P.B. Voos
Relations Journal, 31 (3): 220–34. (eds) Unions and Economic Competitiveness. Armonk
Dunlop, J.T. (1948) ‘The development of labor NY: M.E. Sharpe. pp. 143–69.
organizations: a theoretical framework’, in R.A. Lester Freeman, R. and Medoff, J.L. (1984) What Do Unions
and J. Shister (eds) Insights into Labor Issues. Do? New York: Basic Books.
New York: MacMillan Co. pp. 163–93. Frege, C.M. (1999) Social Partnership at Work:
Dunlop, J., Harbison, F., Kerr, C., and Myers, C. (1960) Workplace Relations in Post-unification Germany.
Industrialism and Industrial Man, Princeton: Princeton London: Routledge.
University Press. Frege, C.M., Heery, E. and Turner, L. (2004) ‘The
Dunlop, J.T. (1993) Industrial Relations Systems, revised new solidarity? Trade union coalition-building in five
edition. Boston MA: Harvard Business School Press. countries’, in C.M. Frege and J. Kelly (eds) Varieties
Edwards, P. (2005) ‘The challenging but promising of Unionism: Strategies for Union Revitalization in
future of industrial relations: developing theory a Global Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
and method in context-sensitive research’, Industrial pp. 137–58.
Relations Journal, 36 (4): 264–82. Frost, A. (2001) ‘Reconceptualising local union
Edwards, P., Bélanger, J. and Wright, M. (2006) ‘The responses to workplace restructuring in North
bases of compromise in the workplace: a theoretical America’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
framework’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 39 (4): 307–33.
44 (1): 125–45. Gilbert, M. (1986) Inflation and Social Conflict:
Erickson, C.L. and Kuruvilla, S. (1998) ‘Industrial A Sociology of Economic Life in Advanced Societies.
relations system transformation’, Industrial and Labor Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.
Relations Review, 52 (1): 3–21. Godard, J. (1993) ‘Theory and method in industrial
Fairbrother, P. (1996) ‘Workplace trade unionism in the relations: modernist and postmodernist alterna-
state sector’, in P. Ackers, C. Smith and P. Smith (eds) tives’, in R.J. Adams and N.M. Meltz (eds)
The New Workplace and Trade Unionism. London: Industrial Relations Theory: Its Nature, Scope
Routledge. pp. 110–48. and Pedagogy. Metuchen NJ and London: IMLR
Fairbrother, P. (2000) Trade Unions at the Crossroads. Press/Rutgers University and The Scarecrow Press.
London and New York: Continuum. pp. 283–306.
Fine, J. (2006) Worker Centers: Organizing Communities Godard, J. (2004) ‘The new institutionalism, capitalist
at the Edge of the Dream. Ithaca and London: ILR diversity and industrial relations’, in B.E. Kaufman
Press. (ed.) Theoretical Perspectives on Work and
Fiorito, J. (1990) ‘Comments: the wider bounds of IR the Employment Relationship. Champaign
systems’, in J. Chelins and J. Dworkin (eds) Reflections IL: Industrial Relations Research Association.
on the Transformation of Industrial Relations. pp. 229–64.
Metuchen NJ and London: IMLR Press/Rutgers Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (2003) ‘Finance, corporate
University and Scarecrow Press. pp. 96–106. governance and the management of labour: a con-
Flanders, A. (1965) ‘Industrial relations: what is wrong ceptual and comparative analysis’, British Journal of
with the system?’, in A. Flanders, Management Industrial Relations, 41 (3): 557–82.
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 89

Gould, S.J. (1987) Time’s Arrow, Time’s Cycle: Myth Hurd, R.W. (1998) ‘Contesting the dinosaur image: the
and Metaphor in the Discovery of Geological Time. labor movement’s search for a future’, Labor Studies
Harmondsworth: Penguin. Journal, 23 (4): 5–30.
Green, F. (2006) Demanding Work: The Paradox of Hurd, R.W. (2004) ‘The failure of organizing: the
Job Quality in the Affluent Economy. Princeton and New Unity Partnership and the future of the labor
Oxford: Princeton University Press. movement’, Working USA, 8 (1): 5–25.
Greene, A-M. (2003) ‘Women and industrial relations’, Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist
in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Understanding Introduction. London and Basingstoke: MacMillan.
Work and Employment: Industrial Relations in Tran- Hyman, R. (1979) ‘The politics of workplace trade
sition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 305–15. unionism’, Capital and Class, 8: 54–67.
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (1998) ‘An introduction to Hyman, R. (1987) ‘Strategy or structure: capital, labour
varieties of capitalism’, in P.A. Hall and D. Soskice and control’, Work, Employment and Society, 1 (1):
(eds) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional 35–55.
Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Hyman, R. (1989) ‘Theory in industrial relations:
Oxford University Press. pp. 1–70. towards a materialist analysis’, in R. Hyman
Hawthorn, G. (1976) Enlightenment and Despair: (ed.) The Political Economy of Industrial Relations.
A History of Sociology. Cambridge: Cambridge Basingstoke: MacMillan. pp. 120–46.
University Press. Hyman, R. (2004) ‘Theory and industrial relations’,
Heery, E. (2003) ‘Trade unions and industrial relations’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 32 (2):
in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Under- 165–80.
standing Work and Employment: Industrial Rela- Hyman, R. (2004) ‘Is industrial relations theory always
tions in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ethnocentric?’, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical
pp. 278–304. Perspectives on Work and the Employment Rela-
Heery, E., Conley, H., Delbridge, R., Simms, M. and tionship. Champaign IL: Industrial Relations Research
Stewart, P. (2004) ‘Trade union responses to non- Association. pp. 265–92.
standard work’, in G. Healy, E. Heery, P. Taylor and Hyman, R. and Brough, I. (1975) Social Values and
W. Brown (eds) The Future of Worker Representation. Industrial Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Basingstoke: Palgrave. pp. 127–50. Kaufman, B.E. (2004a) ‘Employment relations and
Heery, E., Delbridge, R., Salmon, J., Simms, M. and the employment relations system: a guide to
Simpson, D. (2002) ‘Global labour? The transfer theorizing’, in B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical
of the organizing model to the United Kingdom’, Perspectives on Work and the Employment Rela-
in Y.A. Debrah and I.G. Smith (eds) Globalization, tionship. Champaign IL: Industrial Relations Research
Employment and the Workplace: Diverse Impacts. Association. pp. 41–75.
London: Routledge. pp. 41–68. Kaufman, B.E. (2004b) The Global Evolution of Industrial
Heery, E., Healy, G. and Taylor, P. (2004) ‘Union Relations: Events, Ideas and the IIRA. Geneva:
revitalization: themes and issues’, in G. Healy, International Labor Office.
E. Heery, P. Taylor and W. Brown (eds) The Future Kelly, E. and Dobbin, F. (1999) ‘Civil rights law at work:
of Worker Representation. Basingstoke: Palgrave. sex discrimination and the rise of maternity leave
pp. 1–36. policies’, American Journal of Sociology, 105 (2):
Hill, S. (1990) ‘The dominant ideology thesis after a 455–92.
decade’, in N. Abercrombie, S. Hill and B.S. Turner Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi-
(eds) Dominant Ideologies. London: Unwin Hyman. lization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London:
pp. 1–37. Routledge.
Hirschman, A.O. (1991) The Rhetoric of Reaction: Kerr, C., Dunlop, J.T., Harbison, F. and Myers, C. (1955)
Perversity, Futility, Jeopardy. Cambridge MA: Harvard Industrialism and Industrial Man. Cambridge MA:
University Press. Harvard University Press.
Hoque, K. and Noon, M. (2004) ‘Equal opportunities Kochan, T.A., Katz, H.C. and McKersie, R.B. (1986)
policy and practice in Britain: evaluating the “empty The Transformation of American Industrial Relations.
shell” hypothesis’, Work, Employment and Society, New York: Basic Books.
18 (3): 481–506. Korczynski, M. (2003) ‘Consumer capitalism and indus-
Howell, C. (2005) Trade Unions and the State: trial relations’, in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds)
The Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions Understanding Work and Employment: Industrial
in Britain, 1890–2000. Princeton NJ and Oxford: Relations in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University
Princeton University Press. Press. pp. 265–77.
90 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Ledwith, S. and Colgan, F. (2002) ‘Tackling gender, social mobilization and the challenge to industrial
diversity and trade union democracy: a worldwide relations theory’, Industrial Relations, 45 (3):
project?’, in F. Colgan and S. Ledwith (eds) 299–325.
Gender, Diversity and Trade Unions: International Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1970) The Logic of
Perspectives. London: Routledge. pp. 1–27. Comparative Social Inquiry. New York: Jonathan
Logan, J. (2006) ‘The union avoidance industry in the Wiley.
United States’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Purcell, J. and Ahlstrand, B. (1994) Human Resource
44 (4): 651–76. Management in the Multi-divisional Company.
Ludlam, S. and Taylor, A. (2003) ‘The political Oxford: Oxford University Press.
representation of the labour interest in Britain’, British Richardson, R. (1996) ‘Coercion and trade unions:
Journal of Industrial Relations, 41 (4): 727–49. a reconsideration of Hayek’, British Journal of
Lyddon, D. (2004) ‘History and industrial relations’, Industrial Relations, 34 (2): 219–36.
in P. Ackers and A. Wilkinson (eds) Under- Robinson, I. (2002) ‘Does neo-liberal restructuring pro-
standing Work and Employment: Industrial Rela- mote social movement unionism? US developments
tions in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. in comparative perspective’, in B. Nissen (ed.) Unions
pp. 89–118. in a Globalized Environment: Changing Borders,
Marsden, D. (1999) A Theory of Employment Systems: Organizational Boundaries and Social Roles. Armonk
Micro-foundations of Societal Diversity. Oxford: NY: ME Sharpe. pp. 189–235.
Oxford University Press. Rubery, J., Smith, M. and Fagan, C. (1999) Women’s
Meltz, N.M. (1993) ‘Industrial relations systems as a Employment in Europe: Trends and Prospects.
framework for organizing contributions to industrial London: Routledge.
relations theory’, in R.J. Adams and N.M. Meltz Sisson, K. (1987) The Management of Collective
(eds) Industrial Relations Theory: Its Nature, Scope Bargaining: An International Comparison. Oxford:
and Pedagogy. Metuchen NJ and London: IMLR Basil Blackwell.
Press/Rutgers University and The Scarecrow Press. Streeck, W. (1992) Social Institutions and Eco-
pp. 161–82. nomic Performance: Studies of Industrial Rela-
Metcalf, D. (1989) ‘Water notes dry up: the impact of tions in Advanced Capitalist Economies. London:
the Donovan reform proposals and Thatcherism at Sage.
work on labour productivity in British manufacturing Streeck, W. and Thelen, K. (2005) ‘Introduction:
industry’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, institutional change in advanced political economies’,
27 (1): 1–31. in W. Streeck and K. Thelen (eds) Beyond
Nolan, P. and O’Donnell, K. (2003) ‘Industrial relations, Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Polit-
HRM and performance’, in P. Edwards (ed.) Industrial ical Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Relations: Theory and Practice, second edition. pp. 1–39.
Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. pp. 489–512. Tattersall, A. (2005) ‘There is power in coalition:
Ogden, S. (1991) ‘The trade union campaign against a framework for assessing how and when union-
water privatization’, Industrial Relations Journal, community coalitions are effective and enhance union
22 (1): 20–34. power’, Labor and Industry, 16 (2): 97–112.
Osterman, P. (2006) ‘Community organizing and Turner, L. (1998) Fighting for Partnership: Labor and
employee representation’, British Journal of Industrial Politics in Unified Germany. Ithaca and London: ILR
Relations, 44 (4): 629–49. Press.
Osterman, P., Kochan, T.A., Locke, R.M. and Piore, M.J. Turner, L. (2003) ‘Reviving the labor movement:
(2001) Working in America: A Blueprint for the New a comparative perspective’, in D. Cornfield and
Labor Market. Cambridge MA and London: The MIT H. McCammon (eds) Labor Revitalization: Global
Press. Perspectives and New Initiatives. Research in the
Oxenbridge, S. (1997) ‘Organizing strategies and Sociology of Work Volume 11. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
organizing reform in New Zealand service sector pp. 23–58.
unions’, Labor Studies Journal, 22 (3): 3–27. Turner, L. and Hurd, R.W. (2001) ‘Building social
Oxenbridge, S., Brown, W., Deakin, S. and Pratten, C. movement unionism: the transformation of the
(2003) ‘Initial responses to the Employment Relations American labor movement’, in L. Turner, H.C. Katz
Act 1999’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, and R.W. Hurd (eds) Rekindling the Move-
41 (2): 315–34. ment: Labor’s Quest for Relevance in the
Piore, M.J. and Safford, S. (2006) ‘Changing 21st Century. Ithaca and London: ILR Press.
regimes of workplace governance: shifting axes of pp. 9–26.
SYSTEM AND CHANGE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS ANALYSIS 91

Voss, K. and Sherman, R. (2000) ‘Breaking the iron law Wickham, C. (2006) Framing the Early Middle Ages.
of oligarchy: union revitalization in the American labor Oxford: Oxford University Press.
movement’, American Journal of Sociology, 106 (2): Wills, J. (2001) ‘Community unionism and trade union
303–49. renewal in the UK: moving beyond the fragments
Wacjman, J. (2000) ‘Feminism facing industrial relations at last?’, Transactions of the Institute of British
in Britain’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Geographers, 26 (4): 465–83.
38 (2): 183–202.
5
Values, Ideologies, and Frames
of Reference in Industrial
Relations
John W. Budd and Devasheesh Bhave

Industrial relations – or what some might now According to Kochan and Katz, ‘The
call employment relations, and what others primary thread running through industrial
might call human resources and industrial relations research and policy prescriptions is
relations – is a multidisciplinary field studying that labor is more than a commodity … and
all aspects of work and the employment more than a set of human resources’ and
relationship (Ackers and Wilkinson, 2003; ‘a critical assumption underlying industrial
Budd, 2004; Kaufman, 2004). A multidis- relations research is that there is an inherent
ciplinary approach means that competing conflict of interest between employees and
values and assumptions underlie the analy- employers’ that comes from a ‘clash of
ses, policies, and practices of employment economic interests’ (1988: 6). From this
relations scholars, practitioners, and poli- perspective, labor unions and government
cymakers. Unfortunately, these underlying policies such as minimum wage laws are
beliefs are often implicit rather than explicit, seen as socially beneficial because they
or, with the long-standing focus on how can moderate the unequal bargaining power
industrial relations (IR) processes work, between employees and employers. This
sometimes ignored altogether. But under- passage, therefore, is a good illustration of
standing the industrial relationship, corporate the importance of underlying values and
human resource management practices, labor assumptions in employment relations. At the
union strategies, and work-related public same time, it only describes one perspective
policies and laws requires understanding how (the pluralist perspective). In contrast, labor
values and assumptions form the ideologies unions and government regulations are seen
and frames of reference used by scholars, as detrimental when one assumes that per-
practitioners, and policymakers. fectly competitive labor markets are optimal
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 93

(an egoist perspective), as unnecessary when


Frame of
employers and employees are viewed as Ideology
reference
always having common interests (a unitarist
perspective), and as insufficient when one sees
the employment relationship as an unequal
power relation embedded in greater social and Justification/call Internal guide
political inequalities (a critical perspective). for actions and for action and
outcomes evaluation
These four views of unions and government
regulation – harmful, unnecessary, socially
beneficial, and insufficient – are firmly rooted
in four different theories on the employment Theories of the
relationship that embody different values and employment
assumptions (Budd, 2005). relationship
These four key theories are the egoist,
unitarist, pluralist, and critical models of the
employment relationship.1 They serve as the Behavioral and
central ideologies and frames of reference for Values institutional
scholars, practitioners, and policymakers who assumptions
deal with all aspects of work. These ideologies
and frames of reference are packages of values Figure 5.1 Defining ideology and frame of
reference
and assumptions pertaining to the interests of
Note: This diagram provides schematic definitions,
the parties to the employment relationship – not a causal model.
that is, the needs, wants, and aspirations of
employees, employers, and the state – and the
degree to which these interests are compatible. Each theory is built upon a collection of values
Outlining the important conceptualizations of and assumptions. Values are fundamental
these interests is, therefore, a major part of principles that ought to be true, such as the
this chapter. The section that follows this dis- belief that labor should be treated as more
cussion considers the different assumptions than a commodity. Assumptions are beliefs
about the compatibility of these interests and about human behavior and the nature of
integrates this analysis with a description of various institutions such as markets, laws,
the four key theories. The importance of these corporations, and unions that are presumed
values, assumptions, ideologies, and frames to be true, such as the belief that there is an
of reference is then explored. But first, these inherent conflict of interest in the employment
important concepts need to be defined. relationship. Depending on how each theory
is used, it can serve as an ideology or a frame
of reference.
DEFINING CONCEPTS Thelen and Withall define frame of ref-
erence as a ‘conceptual structure of gen-
Values, ideology, and frame of reference eralizations or contexts, postulates about
are dangerous terms. Everyone has their what is essential, assumptions of what is
own view of what these terms mean and valuable, attitudes about what is possible,
it’s common to use these terms without and ideas about what will work effectively’
defining them. The term ideology is partic- in which each individual ‘perceives and
ularly problematic in being used in many interprets events’ (1949: 159). Fox notes more
different ways (e.g., see Eagleton, 1994). simply that actors ‘perceive and define social
Figure 5.1 summarizes our definitions.2 At the phenomena’ (1974: 271) through frames
center of our discussion are theories of the of reference. More recently, The Norton
employment relationship – coherent models Dictionary of Modern Thought defines frame
of how the employment relationship works. of reference as ‘the context, viewpoint,
94 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

or set of presuppositions or of evaluative the possibility that individuals preach from


criteria within which a person’s perception one ideology while practicing another. In
and thinking seem always to occur, and particular, an important belief in some schools
which constrains selectively the course and of Marxist thought is that ideology serves
outcome of these activities’ (Bullock and as a false consciousness in which the dom-
Trombley, 1999: 334). In other words, a frame inant class uses ideology to disguise their
of reference ‘determines judgment, which control. Managerial statements emphasizing
in turn determines subsequent behavior’ individualism, cooperation, and competition
(Fox, 1966: 2). The themes of perception, are therefore seen as a strategy to legitimize
evaluation, and individual action in these a hierarchical and unequal workplace and to
definitions are central to our definition of promote the continued managerial control of
frame of reference.3 More specifically, we work (Anthony, 1977; Bendix, 1956; Fox,
define frame of reference as a theory used 1966; Kunda, 1992). A definition of ideology
to guide and evaluate behaviors, outcomes, therefore needs to distinguish itself from
and institutions. To distinguish ideology from frame of reference and allow for the possibility
frame of reference, we adopt a definition of that actors say one thing, but do another. At
ideology that emphasizes public exposition the same time, it is important to remember
rather than private evaluation. More specif- that ideologies and frames of reference draw
ically, we define ideology as a theory that upon the same theories of the employment
is used to advocate and justify behaviors, relationship. It is to those theories that we
outcomes, and institutions. This is consistent now turn, starting with a discussion of the
with The Oxford Companion to Philosophy: various assumptions and values about the
‘the most important usage [of ideology] in interests of the parties to the employment
contemporary philosophy and politics’ is as relationship.
‘a collection of beliefs and values held by
an individual or group for other than purely
epistemic reasons’ (Honderich, 2005: 419) EMPLOYEE INTERESTS
and with Fox’s (1966: 5) ‘instrument of
persuasion’ function of ideology.4 Employees are obviously a critical part of
In other words, a frame of reference is the employment relationship. But what do
how one sees the world; an ideology is employees want to get out of work? Intel-
how one wants others to see the world. lectually, how should we model employees
When a decline in union density troubles as actors in the employment relationship
a policymaker because of a concern for (Kaufman, 1999)? Employees have diverse
protecting employees when employers have interests (Ciulla, 2000; Kelloway et al.,
greater bargaining power, the pluralist model 2004; Kelly, 1998). But the four theories
is being used as a frame of reference. of the employment relationship emphasize
When business leaders deploy the egoist some interests over the others. It is therefore
model of the employment relationship to instructive to consider four categories of
call for deregulating labor law and to justify employee interests:
relocating jobs to low wage countries, this
model is being used as an ideology (the • survival and income;
liberal market ideology). Admittedly, one’s • equity and voice;
ideology and frame of reference might involve • fulfillment and social identity; and
the same underlying theory – for example, • power and control.
a radical scholar might evaluate outcomes
and advocate for reforms using a frame of
Survival and income
reference and an ideology both based on
a Marxist conception of the employment Most people need to work to survive. Our
relationship. But our definitions allow for ancient ancestors used basic stone tools to
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 95

butcher animals, cut firewood, and build basic psychologists also believe that fairness is
shelters as many as 2.5 million years ago. In a critical dimension of employment. For
modern societies, wage or salary income is example, Adams’s (1965) equity theory has
the means to purchase the basic necessities of been widely applied to employment issues.
life. In its most primal state, then, a worker’s Most simply, workers are posited to reduce
interest is survival. This survival imperative work effort if they feel that they are working
is reflected in Maslow’s (1943) model of harder than others who are paid the same.
work motivation based on a hierarchy of More generally, organizational justice – that
needs in which individuals are posited to is, employee perceptions of and reactions to
first seek the satisfaction of physiological fairness – has become a key construct in the
needs before pursuing other desires and is human resource management and industrial-
also reflected in Wheeler’s (1985) model organizational psychology literatures (Folger
in which workplace conflict stems from the and Cropanzano, 1998).
deprivation of necessary material resources. For others, the concern with fairness is
Both Adam Smith (1776/2003) and Karl Marx rooted more in human dignity and liberty
(1844/1988) also hypothesized that wages for than in the behavioral sciences. The Inter-
common laborers would fall to levels that national Labour Organization’s (ILO) 1944
just support subsistence so individuals end up Declaration of Philadelphia, for example,
working simply to survive. asserts that, ‘All human beings, irrespective
In a more contemporary vein, one of the of race, creed or sex, have the right to
key foundations of mainstream neoclassi- pursue both their material well-being and
cal economics is modeling individuals as their spiritual development in conditions of
seeking to maximize their personal utility freedom and dignity, of economic security
functions (Varian, 1984). Utility is generally and equal opportunity’. To this end, the ILO
seen as dependent on consumption which promotes labor standards pertaining to equal
means that work is an activity tolerated pay for equal work, reasonable working hours,
by individuals to earn income to buy periodic paid holidays, unemployment and
goods, services, and leisure (Killingsworth, disability insurance, the right to form labor
1983). As a purely income-earning activity, unions, and many other aspects of work.
labor is viewed as any other commod- As human dignity is a critical theological
ity and is exchanged through impersonal concept, the Catholic Church through papal
transactions as determined by supply and encyclicals such as Rerum Novarum and other
demand (Kaufman, 2005). At its core, then, major religions advocate similar standards
neoclassical economics equates employees’ and reinforce fairness as an employee interest
interests to income; while not typically seen in the employment relationship (Budd, 2004;
as mere survival, the implications for the Peccoud, 2004). Ethical theories in the
employment relationship are largely the same Aristotelian and Kantian traditions also sup-
because the focal point of work is the self- port the importance of respecting human dig-
interested acquisition of material or pecuniary nity in the employment relationship (Bowie,
benefits. 1999; Budd, 2004; Solomon, 1992). In fact,
basic labor standards are increasingly argued
to be human rights (Adams, 2001; Gross,
Equity and voice
1998; Wheeler, 1994).
An alternative conceptualization of employee Such standards have traditionally been
interests is that employees not only want grouped together under a broad heading of
income, but also seek fairness. This is perhaps equity (e.g., Barbash, 1987). More recently,
most simply demonstrated by organized Budd (2004) articulates the key employee
labor’s longtime pursuit of ‘a fair day’s pay for interests as equity and voice where equity is
a fair day’s work’. Human resource manage- fair employment standards for both material
ment scholars and industrial-organizational outcomes (such as wages and safety) and
96 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

personal treatment (especially nondiscrim- through their concern with the loss of
ination) and voice is the ability to have human dignity that accompanied the denial
meaningful input into decisions. A similar of human fulfillment in the then-emerging
distinction in the research on justice in the modern employment relationship (Hodson,
behavioral sciences is between distributive 2001). For Marx (1844/1988), the defining
and procedural justice – that is, between feature of being human is freely working to
fairness in outcomes and in procedures create things, but under capitalism, workers
(Folger and Cropanzano, 1998). Whether do not control the means of production and
seen as equity and voice or as distributive are therefore alienated from their labor, and
and procedural justice, the implication for denied their essential dignity as humans.
employee interests is the same – survival Durkheim (1893/1933) sees the division of
and income are too narrow as the basis of labor as eroding social norms and therefore
employee interests; rather, employees seek allowing the exploitation of workers while
fairness not only in work-related outcomes, Weber (1925/1978) sees the bureaucracy of
but also in how these outcomes are pro- modern corporations as undermining dignity
duced. and fulfillment through the depersonalization
of work.
The importance of work for individual
Fulfillment and social identity
fulfillment and dignity is also believed to
Another view of employee interests is based provide the foundation for the importance
on the premise that individuals use work to of work for creating social identities and
provide psychological fulfillment and social spiritual fulfillment. To help define them-
identity. This is clearly reflected in the large selves and where they fit into society,
literature in psychology on work motivation people classify themselves in occupational
that emphasizes intrinsic work rewards over groupings (Ashforth and Mael, 1989; Tajfel,
pay and other extrinsic rewards (Donovan, 1978; Turner, 1987). In other words, work
2001; Latham and Pinder, 2005). Perhaps contributes to employees’ development of
most famously, Maslow (1943) theorized their self-concept by providing them with a
that workers seek love, esteem, and self- social identity and thus another meaning to
actualization after their physiological and their employment beyond that of pay. On
security needs are met. Thus, work provides a spiritual level, as famously articulated by
employees with a basic outlet to channel Weber (1904; 1976), the Protestant work ethic
their intrinsic motivation for achievement of is based on Martin Luther’s concept of work as
desired objectives and personal fulfillment – a ‘calling’ (serving God by doing good work
or more simply, joy in work (De Man, 1929). in whatever occupation you are suited for)
A parallel stream of research in psychology and molded by John Calvin into a belief that
examines the psychological importance of hard work is the path to salvation. In Islam,
paid work. Building on Freud’s claim that Buddhism, and Hinduism, work also serves a
man’s strongest link to reality is work, Jahoda higher motive that allows fulfillment of duty
(1982) argues that employment provides toward God such that individuals’ interests
psychological fulfillment by providing time in work are other than solely economic
structure boundaries, a wider spectrum of (Ali, 1988; Nord et al., 1990; Schumacher,
social activities than those provided by family 1974).
life, and involvement in a broader collective
endeavor.
Power and control
Similar themes are echoed by theo-
rists in other disciplines (Ciulla, 2000; A fourth perspective on employee interests
Leidner, 2006; Muirhead, 2004). In fact, is the belief that workers seek power and
Karl Marx, Emile Durkheim, and Max Weber control in the workplace. Recall from the
all emphasize the importance of fulfillment previous section that for Marx and some
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 97

other theorists, ‘labor in the sense of free EMPLOYER INTERESTS


productive activity is the essence of human
life’ (Singer, 2000: 35). Meaningful work is One of the primary actors in the modern
therefore seen as critical for fulfillment and employment relationship is the employer. It is
dignity, but under capitalism, workers are typical to see the employer’s interests as those
alienated because the product of their labor of shareholders, executives, and managers, or
does not belong to them, they have no control alternatively as those of the organization as an
over what is produced and how it is produced, entity in its own right (which might be peculiar
and work becomes less of a social activity except that US law treats a corporation as a
(Hodson, 2001; Marx, 1844/1988). To achieve person with its own rights and obligations).
dignity, a key worker interest is power: ‘the We generally follow these approaches, but it
ability of an individual or group to control his should be noted that there is some danger
(their) physical and social environment; and, in treating an employer as a monolithic
as part of this process, the ability to influence entity. Executives or managers might have
the decisions which are and are not taken by their own goals independent of those of the
others’ (Hyman, 1975: 26). organization or the shareholders which can
Power and control can be pursued in various lead to principal-agent problems in which the
ways. Around the turn of the twentieth century agent does not always act in the best interests
in the US, craft unions developed work of the principal that hired him or her (Fama,
rules pertaining to apprenticeship standards, 1980; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). When
ownership over specific job duties, exclusion we speak of the employer’s interests, we are
of undesirable or unskilled job duties, work referring to the organization’s interests which
allocation procedures, and other standards will also be assumed to be consistent with
(Perlman, 1928). These work rules were the interests of the shareholders, executives,
often established unilaterally by the unions and managers. To the extent that executives
and enforced by having members refuse to and managers are agents that follow their
work on any other terms and by fining or self-interest rather than the organization’s
expelling members who undermined these interests, the reader is referred back to
standards (Montgomery, 1979). Today, some the previous section on employee interests.
element of power and control are pursued by After all, executives and managers are also
workers through various forms of solidarity employees in the employment relationship –
and resistance (such as reduced work effort, they are hired, fired, and are concerned with
absenteeism, and sabotage) (Edwards, 1986; income, fulfillment, and the like.
Hodson, 2001; Kelly, 1998). Political theories In modeling the employment relation-
in which capitalism is seen as inferior to ship, there are three primary views on the
socialism or syndicalism are at least partly interests of employers. The first is profit
rooted in a perception that workers lack maximization – a firm’s objective is to
sufficient power and control in a capital- structure work so as to generate the highest
ist society. In addition to class struggles profit level possible to the exclusive benefit
between labor and capital, struggles for of the firm’s owners. The second broadens the
workplace power and control can also take objective of profit maximization to include
place along gender and racial lines (Amott consideration of other stakeholders such as
and Matthaei, 1996; Delgado and Stefancic, employees. And the third is the pursuit
2001; Gottfried, 2006; Lustig, 2004). Lastly, of power and control over employees that
industrial relations theories that embrace goes beyond what is necessary to maximize
employees’ interests in power and control are profits in some technical sense. In the first
often derived from a belief that the primary conceptualization, profit maximization is seen
employer interest is power and control over as legitimate. In the second conceptualization,
the workplace; this is discussed in next the pursuit of profits is legitimate when
section. tempered by a respect for the interests of other
98 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

stakeholders. In the third view, a primacy governance. In this system, shareholders


of profits over other concerns is rejected as are residual claimants and everyone else is
illegitimate. seen as receiving fixed payments for their
Before turning to each of these concep- services, such as wages and salaries. Since
tualizations, the reader is reminded to not shareholders single-handedly bear the risk of
confuse employer strategies with employer making a profit or loss, they are seen as
interests. In practice, we observe a mul- the key group and economic performance
titude of employment conditions ranging will be optimized when corporate decisions
from abusive sweatshops to workplaces with maximize shareholder value (Blair, 1995).
generously-rewarded employees that have Maximizing profits and shareholder value
extensive decision-making authority. This therefore go hand in hand.
does not mean that there are a large number Many features of the modern employment
of employer interests; rather, this diversity relationship are linked to the profit motive.
reflects a multitude of strategies for pursuing Frederick Winslow Taylor’s development
the three basic employer interests: profit max- of scientific management in the early-
imization, stakeholder value, or power and twentieth century through carefully studying
control. Moreover, these three interests are work tasks and scientifically determining
not intended to simply capture how employers the one best way of completing a task
express their interests; rather we are also can be seen as driven by the pursuit of
considering different ways of conceptualizing greater efficiency, and therefore profitability
or modeling employer interests. Employers (Kanigel, 1997). As articulated by Weber
likely state that they are pursuing profits in (1919/1946), the rise of the bureaucratic
a legitimate fashion or balancing the needs organizational form was a rational solution
of various stakeholders while radical scholars to decision-making problems in the face of
will see employers as pursuing their interests significant organizational complexity (March
through a more critical lens. The discussion and Simon, 1958). The bureaucratic form
here is intended to capture this wide range of of organization is therefore geared toward
alternatives. the profit motive that is the prime employer
interest. The contemporary movement away
from the narrowly-defined tasks of Taylorism
Profit maximization
and the iron cage of Weber’s bureaucracy
In economic thought, firms are assumed to reflects an attempt to boost profitability by
maximize profits (the difference between creating more flexible employment prac-
revenue and costs) (Varian, 1984). Different tices (Applebaum and Batt, 1994). Layoffs,
types of workers are hired up to the point outsourcing, moving production to low-
at which hiring one more worker costs wage countries, and reducing employee
more than the revenue generated. There are benefits are also all done in the pursuit
differing views on the extent to which labor of enhancing profitability for the benefit of
markets are competitive, to which transaction shareholders.
costs are important, and to which there are
principal-agent problems between workers
Stakeholder value
and firms because of asymmetric infor-
mation (such as the firm not being able Note carefully that the shareholder model
to perfectly observe worker effort), but of corporate governance assumes that labor
these complications do not change the basic markets are perfectly competitive. As such,
foundation that each firm’s objective is to employees face little risk – if managers
maximize profits (Manning, 2003; Wachter, mismanage the business and it goes bankrupt,
2004). The real-world importance of profit the assumption of perfectly competitive labor
maximization is reflected in the Anglo- markets means that workers who lose their
American shareholder model of corporate jobs can always find equivalent jobs elsewhere
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 99

at no cost. Shareholders, however, lose


Power and control
their investment so the shareholder model
holds managers liable for serving shareholder For another set of industrial relations schol-
interests. But what if labor markets are ars, characterizing the interest of employers
not perfectly competitive? Employees invest simply as profit maximization, or even as
their own human capital in a corporation increasing stakeholder value, is too benign.
and therefore, just like shareholders, make Rather, employer interests are modeled as
significant contributions and face risky returns seeking power and control over labor. This
(Blair, 1995). Employees might not be able to dominance serves not only to boost profits,
recoup their investment or find an equivalent but to promote capital accumulation, the
job elsewhere if the business is mismanaged. amassing of wealth, and sociopolitical control
As a result, stakeholder theory asserts that (including, in the extreme, preventing a
all stakeholders – not only shareholders workers’ revolution) by the owners of capital.
and owners, but also employees, customers, For Marx, this dominance is an integral
suppliers, local communities, and others – feature of capitalism. As capitalists control
are sufficiently affected by corporate actions the means of production, they are able to
to deserve the right to be considered in extract labor’s surplus value which further
corporate decision-making. Stakeholder the- empowers the capitalists at the expense of
ory can also be rooted in property rights: workers, not only in the economic arena, but
even in the US with strong restrictions in the sociopolitical realm as well. Rather than
against harming others, property rights are employers benignly seeking profit maximiza-
not unlimited, so, the argument goes, a tion by competing for workers in neutral labor
corporation must take multiple interests into markets, employers are seen as controlling
account (Donaldson and Preston, 1995). In and dominating labor through their superior
other words, a corporation does not exist economic and sociopolitical power (Hyman,
just for the benefit of shareholders, and 1975). In this vein, corporations are seen as
should be operated for the benefit of all using their political clout to promote their own
those who have a stake in it. Supporters of interests by obtaining government subsidies
stakeholder theory believe that shareholders and contracts and by shaping legislation
deserve a fair rate of return, but also that that placates workers enough to avoid a
the ideal of maximizing shareholder value broader working class threat while channeling
without regard for other interests (as in labor conflict into tightly-regulated channels
the shareholder model) rests on questionable preferred by business rather than labor (e.g.,
foundations and should not be used to elevate witness the US restrictions on secondary
the importance of corporations over other boycotts) (Domhoff, 1990).
stakeholders (Ghoshal, 2005). In the workplace, the de-skilling and
In this vein, then, the interest of employ- division of labor that accompany Taylorism
ers in the employment relationship should are not seen as a win-win situation in which
be serving the interests of shareholders, labor works more efficiently, but rather as
employees, and other stakeholders. In the US, managerial strategies to decompose both
32 states have constituency statutes in which skilled craft and clerical occupations into
company directors are explicitly allowed simplified, routine, low-skilled jobs in order to
to consider interests beyond those of the gain control over the workplace (Braverman,
shareholders (Adams and Matheson, 2000). 1974; Montgomery, 1979). Bureaucracy is
In Europe, codetermination policies insti- not seen simply as an efficient structure
tutionalize stakeholder theory by requiring for managing complexity; rather, bureau-
employee representation on corporate boards cracy is seen as a strategy to routinize all
of directors while social norms in Japan also aspects of management and to consolidate
foster a concern for stakeholder value (Jacoby, the power to establish rules and procedures
2001; 2005). in order to control the operations of an
100 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

entire organization (Edwards, 1979). More pressures of workers and employers in a


generally, labor process theory emphasizes pluralistic model or reflect and implement
the importance of control mechanisms in the the political wishes of the dominant class
workplace (Thompson and Newsome, 2004). in a Marxist model. For example, promoting
In addition to issues of control along class freedom and the rule of law might be seen
(labor and capital) lines, control methods as an extension of employer interests, not an
can also occur along gender, racial, and independent interest of the state. However,
ethnic lines, such as with occupational sex some research emphasizes the possibility of
segregation (Greene, 2003). All of these autonomous state action, especially as rooted
are examples where employer interests are in international connections of state officials,
modeled as power and control beyond that the need to maintain domestic stability,
needed to benignly pursue profits. and the ability of government officials to
use resources to pursue their own ends
(Skocpol, 1985). In industrial relations circles,
STATE INTERESTS it is widely believed that the anti-union
policies of the Reagan administration, in
The third major actor in the employment rela- the US, and Thatcher government, in the
tionship is the state. The state has five roles in UK, were more aggressive than would have
the employment relationship (Godard, 2005). been dictated if these administrations were
In the regulative role, laws regulate workers, simply reflecting business lobbying. Either
unions, and companies. In the employer as reflections or as independent interests, we
role, the state is a public sector organization believe the following three categories are
with its own employees. In the facilitative instructive.
role, the state establishes social norms and
provides support services for the employment
relationship. The structural role consists of Freedom and the rule of law
economic policies that shape the economic In the liberal market paradigm, the interest
environment. And in the constitutive role, of the state is in protecting freedom and the
the state determines how the employment rule of law. As applied to the employment
relationship is constituted by the type of relationship, the law’s role is to promote
economic system embraced by the state (such and protect the operation of free markets
as a market-based capitalist economy). But with voluntary exchange between companies,
what are the interests of the state in the investors, consumers, and workers. In the US,
employment relationship that determine how this view manifests itself in an emphasis on
the state acts in these five roles? In other common law principles that support economic
words, what is the state trying to achieve? transactions, especially well-defined property
We present three broad alternatives: a focus rights, liberty of contract, and the law of torts
on freedom and the rule of law, an interest to protect against property damage (Posner,
in promoting equitable outcomes, and an 1986). As captured by a report from the Bush
objective to support the domination of the administration:
elite. As with the discussion of employer
interests, these three interests are intended By providing a legal foundation for transactions,
the government makes the market system reliable:
to capture different ways of conceptualizing it gives people certainty about what they can
or modeling state interests; they do not trade and keep, and it allows people to establish
simply describe how the state expresses its terms of trade that will be honored by both sellers
interests. and buyers. The absence of any one of these
In all three conceptualizations of the state’s elements—competition, enforceable property
rights, or an ability to form mutually advantageous
interests, it’s possible that the state does contracts—can result in inefficiency and lower
not have independent interests; rather, its living standards (Council of Economic Advisors,
policies might simply mediate the political 2004: 149).
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 101

Equitable outcomes to be acting autonomously and neutrally,


given its role of protection of ownership it is
In pluralist political thought, the state
in effect intertwined with particular economic
responds to the power of competing interest
interests (Hyman, 1975; King, 1986). To
groups and, in the variant most relevant
wit, Kelly (1998) discusses how government
here, enforces existing rules while also ensur-
repression of strikers, and the protection of
ing fair outcomes (Dunleavy and O’Leary,
strike replacements, reduces the effectiveness
1987; Faulks, 1999). An alternative vision
of collective action and thereby favors capital
of the state’s interest in the employment
over labor.
relationship is therefore the promotion of
equitable outcomes. As articulated by Sidney
and Beatrice Webb, two of the founders of
industrial relations, the state must balance
THE (IN)COMPATABILITY
various interests: OF INTERESTS

[I]ndustrial administration is, in the democratic The framework developed in this chapter
state, a more complicated matter than is naively asserts that the ideologies and frames of
imagined by the old-fashioned capitalist, demand-
ing the ‘right to manage his own business in his
reference of industrial relations are rooted
own way.’…In the interests of the community in two key dimensions: the interests of the
as a whole, no one of the interminable series parties to the employment relationship and
of decisions can be allowed to run counter to the degree of compatibility of these interests.
the consensus of expert opinion representing the The compatibility or incompatibility of inter-
consumers on the one hand, the producers on the
other, and the nation that is paramount over both
ests, in turn, depends on how markets and the
(1897: 821–3). employment relationship work. Now that the
interests have been described, consider four
In contrast to liberal market proponents then, different views on the compatibility of these
in this paradigm there is greater support for interests and the nature of the employment
government intervention to reduce market relationship.
imperfections (such as unemployment), to
equalize bargaining power between employ- 1. Employers and employees freely pursue their
ers and employees through unionization and own self-interest in competitive labor markets;
social safety nets, and to provide workers with when these interests align, they consummate an
greater voice through works councils. At an economic transaction, when they do not align, they
international level, there is support for the keep searching for mutually-beneficial exchanges.
International Labour Organization (ILO) and 2. Although labor markets might not be perfect,
its promotion of labor standards. For those that employers and employees share a unity of
see labor rights as human rights, the state has interests, especially in that treating employees
the responsibility to guarantee these rights. well improves the company’s bottom line and vice
versa.
3. Employers and employees interact as unequals
Dominance of the elite with some shared and some conflicting interests,
but these conflicts are economic in nature and
A third view on the interests of the state limited to the employment relationship.
in the employment relationship is that the 4. Employers and employees interact as unequals
capitalist state perpetuates the dominance of with significant power differentials that are
the ruling class. This view is most clearly pervasive through all social relations.
articulated in Marxist thought in which social
change is driven by capitalism rather than These differing views on the compatibility or
the behavior of the state so that the state is incompatibility of the interests of employers
viewed as an instrument of the capitalists who and employees, as possibly shaped, mediated,
are then society’s ruling class (Faulks, 1999; or reflected by the interests of the state, define
Pierson, 1996). Even though the state appears the four theories that underlie the essential
102 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 5.1 Four theories of the employment relationship


Theory Employer interests Employee interests State interests Key beliefs
Egoist Profit-maximization Utility-maximization Freedom and rule of law Freedom and individual
(survival and self-interest yield optimal
income) outcomes through free
market transactions.
Unitarist Profit-maximization Fulfillment Freedom and rule of law Corporate policies can align the
interests of employers and
employees.
Pluralist Profit-maximization or Equity and voice Equitable outcomes Optimal outcomes are achieved
stakeholder value when there is a balance
between employer and
employee interests.
Critical
Political Power and control Power and control Dominance of the elite Capital dominates labor in the
economy employment relationship
and in broader societal
institutions.
Feminist Power and control Power and control Dominance of the elite Male concerns dominate
female concerns in the
employment relationship
and in broader societal
institutions.
Race Power and control Power and control Dominance of the elite Concerns of one ethnic group
dominate other groups’
concerns in the employment
relationship and in broader
societal institutions.

ideologies and frames of reference for most reflect each worker’s productive contribu-
industrial relations scholars, policymakers, tions. If workers and employers are equal
and practitioners – the egoist, unitarist, plu- in terms of economic power, legal expertise
ralist, and critical employment relationships and protections, and political influence, then
(see Table 5.1). neoclassical economic theory shows that
abuses and exploitation are prevented by
perfect competition in the labor market.
The egoist employment relationship
Employment-at-will – that is, the right to
The egoist employment relationship is rooted hire and fire, or take a job and quit, at anytime
in the pursuit of individual self-interest by for any reason – is a key feature of the
rational agents in economic markets. Labor is egoist employment relationship. Employers
conceptualized as a commodity like any other and employees should be able to enter into any
productive resource. Employees are seen explicit or implicit agreement involving any
as interested in income while firms pursue mutually-agreeable terms and conditions of
profit maximization. The state promotes employment, including compensation, hours,
economic transactions through protecting duration of employment, job duties, and
property rights and enforcing contracts. As the like. In the interests of both economic
such, there isn’t a conflict between employers optimization and individual freedom, employ-
and employees; rather, they simply engage ers and employees should likewise be able
in voluntary, mutually-beneficial transactions to end these arrangements when conditions
to buy and sell units of productive labor or preferences change, or if a better deal
based on what the market will bear. Wages comes along (Epstein, 1984). Labor unions
are never too low or too high, they simply and government-mandated labor standards are
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 103

seen as interfering with the invisible hand of model ranging from hierarchical, paternalistic
the free market and distort employment and approaches to high-commitment approaches
output levels throughout the economic system to strategic approaches (Appelbaum and
(Reynolds, 1984). Unions are also seen as Batt, 1994; Katz and Darbishire, 2000). The
interfering with the discipline of the market underlying common denominator, however,
by protecting lazy workers. Note carefully that is the attempt to devise human resources
the egoist employment relationship critically policies that are seen as aligning the interests
depends on embracing a value system in of employees and employers. Some com-
which efficiency is the primary objective of mon examples include valid and reliable
the employment relationship and whatever the selection measures to hire and promote
market bears is best. employees; training and development oppor-
The three remaining theories place less tunities; respectful methods of supervision;
emphasis on market determinism; markets are compensation that provides more than a living
seen as useful for allocating scarce resources wage while also rewarding performance;
to productive uses, but as also imperfect benefits that foster personal growth, security,
because of information problems, mobility and work-life balance; and informal or
and transactions costs, unequal access to formal dispute resolution procedures.5 As
financial and legal resources, the importance reflected by the emphasis on employees’
of behavioral concerns such as fairness or interest in fulfillment, psychology is arguably
social pressure in individual decision-making, the dominant disciplinary influence in the
and other real-world complications (Manning, unitarist camp.
2003). The three remaining theories are The unitarist emphasis is generally on
also rooted in a different set of values individual rather than collective identities,
(based on embracing different employee behaviors, and practices. In fact, in the uni-
interests), especially in that workers are seen tarist employment relationship, labor unions
as human beings with psychological and and government-mandated labor standards are
physical needs and aspirations, and in the unnecessary. If companies are following the
last two theories, with moral worth and human resource management school’s ideas
democratic rights, too. of effective management, then workers will
be satisfied and will not support a union
or need mandated labor standards. Such
The unitarist employment
institutions are also largely seen as unnec-
relationship
essary because the unitarist view emphasizes
The second theory embraces a unitarist view fulfillment and intrinsic rewards. The role of
of the employment relationship – the right the state is limited – while some scholars
employment policies and practices will align advocate government policies to promote high
the interests of employers and employees performance work practices (e.g., Levine,
(Bacon, 2003; Fox, 1974; Lewin, 2001). In 1995), human resources professionals are
other words, labor and management have a more likely to lobby against rather than for
unity of interests; any conflict in practice additional regulation; instead, the state’s role
stems from poor employment practices. This is seen as promoting the rule of law and
frame of reference underlies contemporary economic transactions because this serves
human resource management which focuses organizational performance. As with the other
on creating policies that simultaneously theories, this perspective is rooted in specific
benefit employers (through their interest in values and assumptions pertaining to the
profit maximization) and employees (through interests of the employment relationship and
their interest in fulfillment) (Pfeffer, 1998; the nature of conflict within this relationship,
Ulrich and Brockbank, 2005). and is often used as an important ideology
In practice, there are a number of vari- and frame of reference by industrial relations
ants of the human resource management actors.
104 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

productive counterweight to corporate power;


The pluralist employment
social insurance and mandated minimum
relationship
standards also help protect all workers against
The pluralist employment relationship con- the vagaries of the business cycle and
sists of workers and employers bargaining corporate power.
in imperfect labor markets in the presence
of pluralist conflict – that is, in an employ-
The critical employment relationship
ment relationship consisting of multiple,
sometimes-conflicting interests (employers The critical employment relationship is rooted
might want lower labor costs, flexibility, in the power and control interests of employ-
and an intense pace of work while employ- ers and employees and therefore sees the
ees might want higher wages, employment employment relationship as a struggle for
security, and a safe work environment) as power and control (Gall, 2003; Hyman,
well as shared interests (such as quality 1975; 2006). The schools of thought sub-
products, productive workers, and profitable scribing to this frame of reference can be
companies) (Clegg, 1975; Fox, 1974). grouped together under the umbrella of critical
The pluralist view of conflict is inti- industrial relations and encompass Marxist,
mately related to a belief that labor mar- feminist, and other sociological theories
kets are not perfectly competitive. Sidney based on the division and control of labor.
and Beatrice Webb, John R. Commons, While sharing the view that labor is more
and other early institutionalists attributed than just a commodity, unlike the pluralist
the exploitive Anglo-American employment view in which employer-employee conflict
conditions of the early twentieth century to is confined to the employment relationship,
the superior power of large corporations over the critical perspective is that employment
individual employees (Kaufman, 1997). This relations conflict is part of a broader societal
power advantage was believed to be rooted clash between competing groups (Kelly,
in market imperfections such as isolated 1998). A Marxist perspective assumes that
company towns, mobility costs, lack of employer-employee conflict is one element
family savings or other resources, segmented of unequal power relations between the
markets, and excess labor supply. Moreover, capitalist and working classes throughout
a core pluralist value is the rejection that society. A feminist perspective focuses on
labor is simply a commodity (Kaufman, 2005) unequal power relations between men and
and therefore that labor is entitled to equity women; a critical race perspective emphasizes
and voice in the employment relationship segregation and control along racial lines
(Budd, 2004). As such, the role of the state (Amott and Matthaei, 1996; Delgado and
is to promote equitable outcomes. Because Stefancic, 2001; Gottfried, 2006; Greene,
inequitable outcomes are seen as stemming 2003; Lustig, 2004).
from imperfect labor markets and unequal In the critical employment relationship, the
bargaining power, unions and mandated labor labor market is not seen as a neutral forum
standards are viewed as mechanisms for for matching self-interested workers with self-
leveling the playing field between employers interested firms (as in the egoist employment
and employees thereby promoting the optimal relationship); rather it is seen as a socially-
operation of markets rather than interfering based instrument of power and control
with it (as predicted by theories rooted in (Hyman, 1975). The employment relationship
competitive markets). Also, because of the is therefore not a voluntary exchange but
belief that there are at least some conflicts rather is a contested exchange (Bowles and
of interests, the pluralist industrial relations Gintis, 1990). Because of the socially-rooted,
school rejects the unitarist reliance on cor- ongoing conflict between labor and capital,
porate self-interest and goodwill to protect human resource management practices are
workers. Rather, labor unions are seen as a not seen as methods for aligning worker and
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 105

employer interests, but rather as disguised that ideology as hollow rhetoric to support
rhetoric that quietly undermines labor power a special interest. We believe, however, that
and perpetuates the dominance of capital it is more instructive to see these ideologies
(Legge, 1995). Strong, militant labor unions (and frames of reference) as rooted in the
are seen as important advocates for workers’ four theories of the employment relationship.
interests in the workplace and in the political Depending on the application, all four theories
arena. But ultimately, relying on collective can serve as an ideology and as a frame
bargaining to advance workers’ interests is of reference. Many of the examples used
inadequate because of the structural inequal- here follow the rest of the literature and
ities that pervade the workplace and the focus on managerial ideologies and frames of
greater sociopolitical context. That conflict reference, but it again bears emphasizing that
between competing groups is not limited to the all industrial relations actors have ideologies
employment relationship also means that the and frames of reference. This is implicit in
state is largely concerned with perpetuating Dunlop’s (1958) assertion that an industrial
the dominance of the powerful group, whether relations system is stable only if the actors
it be capitalists, men, or a dominant ethnic share a common ideology.
group. As with the other theories, the key Management discourse currently empha-
to understanding the critical employment sizes market ideals (Kunda and Ailon-
relationship is through an analysis of the Souday, 2005). The ideal corporation is
interests of the employment relations actors portrayed as a nimble network of empowered
paired with an understanding of how the entrepreneurial work groups that focus on
parties interact and the extent to which the core competencies; excess layers of man-
various interests are compatible. agement are supposed to be downsized; low
value added activities are supposed to be
outsourced. This ideology is grounded in the
FROM THEORY TO IDEOLOGY AND egoist employment relationship model and
FRAME OF REFERENCE its laissez-faire ideals. Scholars that believe
the values and assumptions that underlie
Ideologies and frames of reference related to the egoist model and use it as their frame
work and industrial relations are pervasive, of reference see the calls for more flexible
from portrayals of labor in the paintings business organizations as legitimate and wise.
of Victorian England to the coverage of The power of the four models is in illumi-
contemporary events in the mainstream media nating alternative perspectives. Scholars that
(Barringer, 2005; Martin, 2004). Under Mao, analyze the employment relationship through
the authoritarian communist regime in China a critical frame of reference see this market-
until the late 1970s emphasized unitarist based ideology as a mechanism of control
employment themes because communism is that causes workers to buy into a system that
supposed to resolve the conflicts of interest doesn’t serve their interests because employer
believed to be inherent in capitalism (Taylor and employee interests are fundamentally
et al., 2003). In the Western workplace, opposed.
business executives and managers use ide- Similarly, unitarist corporate ideologies
ology to legitimatize employment practices are seen as valid frames of reference by
(Anthony, 1977; Bendix, 1956; Kunda and unitarist actors, but are seen as disguised
Ailon-Souday, 2005); unions and workers use coercion and union busting by actors who
ideology to justify their own behaviors and look at human resources policies through
actions. The various actors use their frames the lenses of pluralist and critical frames of
of reference to evaluate the ideologies and reference. Differing views on labor unions –
actions of others. When another’s ideology is from harmful to unnecessary to benefi-
unconvincing (because it is rejected by your cial to inadequate – are clearly rooted
frame of reference), it is tempting to dismiss in the four frames of reference presented
106 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

here (Budd, 2005). Contrasting perspectives Kochan et al. (1986) ascribe the rise of
on ownership and control rights also flow the nonunion employment relationship in the
from these frames of reference. In the United States largely to managerial frames of
egoist model, property rights are paramount reference. Poole et al. (2005) find that the
so a firm’s owners should have complete attitudes of British managers are linked to
control rights. In the pluralist model, stake- broader political and economic trends while
holders merit full consideration, and in Barley and Kunda (1992) present qualitative
the critical model, even stakeholder rights evidence that US managerial ideologies
are insufficient to overcome the structural differ between economic expansions and
inequalities of capitalism. In advocating contractions. There are likely many other
such positions, the underlying theories are complex factors that determine what ideology
being used as ideologies; in evaluating is dominant, how ideology shapes frames
ownership and control rights, the underlying of reference and values, and many other
theories are being employed as frames of important questions. There is therefore a
reference. need for more research on the dynamics
The importance of ideologies and frames of ideologies and frames of reference. For
of reference is also apparent in the legal industrial relations, the starting point is the
arena. In the US, for example, the Lochner-era four theories presented here.
Supreme Court in the early 1900s is well-
known for striking down labor and employ-
ment laws on the basis that they interfered CONCLUSION: VALUES AT WORK
with the liberty of contract. In the critical
frame of reference, the liberty of contract The chapter presents four theories as a
might be viewed as a rhetorical justification starting point for understanding the major
for rulings that favored capital, but there is perspectives within the study and practice of
some evidence that judges truly believed that industrial relations. When these theories are
liberty of contract benefited capital and labor used to analyze employment relations and to
as in the egoist frame of reference (Forbath, determine one’s actions, they become the four
1985). As a second example, Dannin (2006) key frames of reference in industrial relations.
shows how contemporary US judges decide When these theories are employed to advocate
labor law cases using common law principles a certain viewpoint, they become the central
pertaining to property rights as the basis for ideologies in the field. Distinguishing
their legal analyses. This is consistent with between ideologies and frames of reference
their legal training so it is not surprising that allows us to readily analyze situations in
it forms the basis of their egoist frame of which some actors express one view but other
reference. actors see those actions differently. Union
Empirical work on ideologies and frames leaders may express an ideology of employee
of reference is rare, but a few studies voice and balancing interests; employers may
support the approach outlined here. In surveys see this in their frame of reference as rhetoric
of US and Canadian employment relations covering up the union’s selfish pursuit of
scholars, Godard (1992, 1995) finds that better wages for union members at the
significant fractions of scholars use each of expense of others. Rooting these ideologies
our four theories as a frame of reference. and frames of reference in four theories of the
Moreover the evaluations of different employ- employment relationship allows us to readily
ment relations issues are consistent within appreciate where these differing ideologies
a frame which supports the coherence of and frames of reference are coming from.
these models. Godard (1997) further finds that Continuing with the previous example, the
managerial ideologies/frames of reference union leader’s ideology might be rooted in a
are an important determinant of managerial pluralist model whereas the employer’s frame
actions pertaining to industrial relations. of reference is an egoist or unitarist model.
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 107

The postmodern emphasis on discourse the workplace. Contrary to the characteriza-


underscores the importance of explicitly tion of even some industrial relations scholars
recognizing the power of language in the (e.g., Kochan, 1998), values do not comprise
world of work (Burrell, 2006; Hearn and just the normative foundations of the field;
Michelson, 2006). By rooting the analysis rather, values and assumptions underlie views
of industrial relations ideologies and frames on how the employment relationship works
of reference in the four theories of the analytically as much as how it should work
employment relationship, it becomes apparent normatively (Budd et al., 2004).
that clashes in discourse and practice between On both a normative and positive level, as
different ideologies or frames of reference the support for various values and assump-
stem from divergent underlying values and tions wax and wane, the four ideologies
assumptions, especially as they pertain to and frames of reference exhibit an uneven
the interests of the parties in the modern trajectory during the development of the
employment relationship. One of the key field and practice of Anglo-American indus-
values of industrial relations outside the egoist trial relations (Ackers and Wilkinson, 2005;
model is that labor is more than just a Kaufman, 1993; 2004). The egoist employ-
commodity (Kaufman, 2005). In contrast, ment relationship was firmly cemented by
in the egoist model one of the key values the end of the nineteenth century in the US
is that laissez-faire market outcomes have with the development of the employment-at-
particular worth because they are produced will doctrine and the rejection of mandated
by voluntary free exchange. These differing labor standards on the grounds that it
values go a long way toward explaining interfered with free contracting. Cycles of
divergent ideologies and frames of reference economic depressions and widespread sweat-
in employment relations and approaching shop working conditions, however, sparked
industrial relations in this way reveals these the development of Marx’s views on work
underlying differences. and capitalism in the mid-1800s, and the
Values and ideologies are defined here later development of the pluralist model
(and elsewhere) with a large normative around the turn of the twentieth century, and
component – they represent principles and the creation of the unitarist model shortly
systems that ought to be true. Adherents to thereafter. The pluralist model was embraced
the egoist model lobby for the deregulation on an international scale with the creation
of the employment relationship. Believers of the ILO at the end of First World War.
in the unitarist model argue that companies During the 1920s, the four models competed
should use certain human resources practices. for dominance, but the Great Depression
Subscribers to the pluralist theory support discredited the egoist and unitarist models in
public policy reforms that make it easier for the US. During the 1930s, then, the New Deal
workers to unionize. Adherents to the critical policies of the Roosevelt administration were
school seek more fundamental changes in rooted in the pluralist model. In Great Britain,
ownership and control rights. But at the same the centrality of the pluralist model was
time, it is essential to recognize the theoretical reflected in the Donovan Royal Commission
or analytical aspects that are rooted in the on Trade Unions and Employers’Associations
values and assumptions of industrial relations. in the 1960s. Fast forward to the twenty-first
The egoist model predicts that market-based century and we see that with the rise of the
relationships maximize welfare. The unitarist liberal market paradigm, the egoist model has
model implies that providing opportunities for made a comeback; its ideology is certainly
individual fulfillment boosts employee pro- spoken with the loudest voice in popular
ductivity. The pluralist model hypothesizes discourse. In spite of ideas for revitalizing
that unions can improve productivity. The pluralist (Ackers, 2002; Budd, 2004) and
critical model predicts that managers will critical (Kelly, 1998) industrial relations, the
pursue strategies that increase their control in field is in flux as the pluralist and critical
108 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

models face significant challenges from the 2 It should be emphasized that Figure 5.1 is
egoist and unitarist perspectives (Ackers and intended to capture our definitions; it is not presented
Wilkinson, 2003, 2005; Kaufman, 2004). as a theoretical model of the determinants of any
of the components of the figure. The popularity of
With respect to evaluating corporate poli- an ideology, for example, might shape values and
cies or shaping public policy, competition assumptions. While it’s important to understand the
among these ideologies and frames of refer- determinants of dominant ideologies, such theoretical
ence are to be expected since, as illustrated issues are beyond the scope of what Figure 5.1 is
here, the models embrace different visions of intended to portray.
3 These themes are also consistent with the
the interests of the employment relationship construct of framing in psychology (Tversky and
and of their compatibility or incompatibility. Kahneman, 1986) and collective action frames in
But as an intellectual endeavor, the diversity sociology (Benford and Snow, 2000).
of industrial relations is both a strength 4 Definitions of ideology that emphasize assess-
and a weakness. It is a weakness when ment and understanding (e.g. Godard, 1995) are
frames of reference under our definitions.
adherents of different views are isolated and 5 So-called low road strategies rooted in low wages
talk past each other. It is a strength when and managerial control are better captured by the
diverse perspectives can help us understand egoist theory of the employment relationship in that
the complex issues inherent across the entire they are rooted in a narrow conception of employee
spectrum of the world of work. To foster interests and in an emphasis on what the labor market
will bear.
this strength, competing and shared values,
ideologies, and frames of reference must be
given explicit recognition in our scholarship REFERENCES
and discourse. For those new to the field,
a true understanding of industrial relations Ackers, Peter (2002) ‘Reframing Employment Relations:
requires an appreciation for the diverse values, The Case for Neo-Pluralism,’ Industrial Relations
ideologies, and frames of reference in the Journal, 33 (1): 2–19.
world of work. Ackers, Peter and Wilkinson, Adrian (eds.) (2003)
Understanding Work and Employment: Industrial
Relations in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Ackers, Peter and Wilkinson, Adrian (2005) ‘British
Industrial Relations Paradigm: A Critical Outline
We gratefully acknowledge the helpful com- History and Prognosis,’ Journal of Industrial Relations,
ments of Nicolas Bacon and Jack Fiorito. 47 (4): 443–56.
Adams, Edward S. and Matheson, John H. (2000)
‘A Statutory Model for Corporate Constituency
Concerns,’ Emory Law Journal, 49 (4): 1085–135.
NOTES
Adams, Stacy J. (1965) ‘Inequity in Social Exchange,’ in
Leonard Berkowitz (ed.), Advances in Experimental
1 The broad scope and concise length of this review
precludes a detailed examination of significant varia- Social Psychology, Volume 2. New York: Academic
tions and details within the theories and perspectives Press. pp. 267–99.
outlined here. For example, Godard (1992: 244; 2005) Adams, Roy J. (2001) ‘Choice or Voice? Rethinking
includes a fifth model based on a pluralist economic American Labor Policy in Light of the International
and political system which is ‘far more egalitarian Human Rights Consensus,’ Employee Rights and
in opportunities and outcomes and which provides Employment Policy Journal, 5 (2): 521–48.
workers with far greater rights’ than in what he terms Ali, Abbas (1988) ‘Scaling an Islamic Work Ethic,’ The
the orthodox pluralist perspective. While these two Journal of Social Psychology, 128 (5): 575–83.
views perhaps envision different reforms and ideal
Amott, Teresa and Matthaei, Julie (eds.) (1996) Race,
institutions, they are rooted in similar assumptions
Gender, and Work: A Multicultural Economic History
and values so we consider them as one model. The
interested reader is referred to the references cited of Women in the United States. Revised edn. Boston:
herein and to the other chapters of this Handbook South End Press.
for more nuanced discussions of various theories and Anthony, P.D. (1977) The Ideology of Work. London:
perspectives. Tavistock.
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 109

Appelbaum, Eileen and Batt, Rosemary (1994) The New Burrell, Gibson (2006) ‘Foucauldian and Postmodern
American Workplace: Transforming Work Systems in Thought and the Analysis of Work,’ in Marek
the United States. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. Korczynski, Randy Hodson, and Paul Edwards (eds.),
Ashforth, Blake E. and Mael, Fred (1989) ‘Social Social Theory at Work. Oxford: Oxford University
Identity Theory and the Organization,’ Academy of Press. pp. 155–81.
Management Review, 14 (1): 20–39. Ciulla, Joanne B. (2000) The Working Life: The Promise
Bacon, Nicolas (2003) ‘Human Resource Management and Betrayal of Modern Work. New York: Three Rivers
and Industrial Relations,’ in Peter Ackers and Press.
Adrian Wilkinson, (eds.), Understanding Work and Clegg, H.A. (1975) ‘Pluralism in Industrial Relations,’
Employment: Industrial Relations in Transition. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 13 (3): 309–16.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 71–88. Council of Economic Advisors (2004) Economic Report
Barbash, Jack (1987) ‘Like Nature, Industrial Relations of the President. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Abhors a Vacuum: The Case of the Union-Free Printing Office.
Strategy,’ Industrial Relations/Relations Industrielles, Dannin, Ellen. (2006) Taking Back the Workers’ Law:
42 (1): 168–79. How to Fight the Assault on Labor Rights. Ithaca, NY:
Barley, Stephen and Kunda, Gideon (1992) ‘Design Cornell University Press.
and Devotion: Surges of Rational and Normative Delgado, Richard and Stefancic, Jean (2001) Critical
Ideologies of Control in Managerial Discourse,’ Race Theory: An Introduction. New York: New York
Administrative Science Quarterly, 37 (3): 363–99. University Press.
Barringer, Tim (2005) Men at Work: Art and Labour in De Man, Hendrik (1929) Joy in Work. Tr. Eden and Cedar
Victorian Britain. New Haven: Yale University Press. Paul. New York: Henry Holt.
Bendix, Reinhard (1956) Work and Authority in Industry. Domhoff, William G. (1990) The Power Elite and the
New York: Harper & Row. State: How Policy is Made in America. New York:
Benford, Robert D. and Snow, David A. (2000) ‘Framing Aldine De Gruyter.
Processes and Social Movements: An Overview Donaldson, Thomas and Preston, Lee E. (1995) ‘The
and Assessment,’ Annual Review of Sociology, Stakeholder Theory of the Corporation: Concepts,
26: 611–39. Evidence, and Implications,’ Academy of Manage-
Blair, Margaret M. (1995) Ownership and Control: ment Review, 20 (1): 65–91.
Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty- Donovan, John J. (2001) ‘Work Motivation,’ in Neil
First Century. Washington, D.C.: Brookings. Anderson, et al. (eds.), Handbook of Industrial, Work,
Bowie, Norman E. (1999) Business Ethics: A Kantian and Organizational Psychology, Volume 2. London:
Perspective. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers. Sage. pp. 53–76.
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert (1990) ‘Contested Dunleavy, Patrick and O’Leary, Brendan (1987) Theories
Exchange: New Microfoundations for the Political of the State: The Politics of Liberal Democracy.
Economy of Capitalism,’ Politics and Society, 18 (2): London: Macmillian Education.
165–222. Dunlop, John T. (1958) Industrial Relations Systems.
Braverman, Harry (1974) Labor and Monopoly Capital: New York: Henry Holt.
The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century. Durkheim, Emile (1893/1933) The Division of Labor in
New York: Monthly Review Press. Society. Tr. George Simpson. New York: Macmillan.
Budd, John W. (2004) Employment with a Human Face: Eagleton, Terry (1994) Ideology. New York: Longman.
Balancing Efficiency, Equity, and Voice. Ithaca, NY: Edwards, P.K. (1986) Conflict at Work: A Materialist
Cornell University Press. Analysis of Workplace Relations. Oxford: Basil
Budd, John W. (2005) Labor Relations: Striking a Blackwell.
Balance. Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Edwards, Richard (1979) Contested Terrain. New York:
Budd, John W., Gomez, Rafael and Meltz, Noah M. Basic Books.
(2004) ‘Why a Balance is Best: The Pluralist Indus- Epstein, Richard A. (1984) ‘In Defense of the Contract
trial Relations Paradigm of Balancing Competing at Will,’ University of Chicago Law Review, 51 (4):
Interests,’ in Bruce E. Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical 947–82.
Perspectives on Work and the Employment Relation- Fama, Eugene (1980) ‘Agency Problems and the Theory
ship. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research of the Firm,’ Journal of Political Economy, 88 (2):
Association. pp. 195–227. 288–307.
Bullock, Alan and Trombley, Stephen (eds.) (1999) The Faulks, Keith (1999) Political Sociology: A Criti-
Norton Dictionary of Modern Thought. 2nd Revised cal Introduction. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University
edn. New York : W.W. Norton & Company. Press.
110 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Folger, Robert and Cropanzano, Russell (1998) Organi- Hyman, Richard (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist
zational Justice and Human Resource Management. Introduction. London: Macmillan.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Hyman, Richard (2006) ‘Marxist Thought and the
Forbath William E. (1985) ‘The Ambiguities of Free Analysis of Work,’ in Marek Korczynski, Randy
Labor: Labor and the Law in the Gilded Age,’ Hodson, and Paul Edwards (eds.), Social Theory at
Wisconsin Law Review, 1985 (4): 767–817. Work. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 26–55.
Fox, Alan (1966) ‘Industrial Sociology and Industrial Jacoby, Sanford M. (2001) ‘Employee Representation
Relations,’ Royal Commission on Trade Unions and and Corporate Governance: A Missing Link,’ Univer-
Employers’ Associations Research Papers 3. London: sity of Pennsylvania Journal of Labor and Employment
HMSO. Law, 3 (3): 449–89.
Fox, Alan (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power and Jacoby, Sanford M. (2005) The Embedded Corporation:
Trust Relations. London: Farber and Farber. Corporate Governance and Employment Relations in
Gall, Gregor (2003) ‘Marxism and Industrial Relations,’ Japan and the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
in Peter Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson (eds.), University Press.
Understanding Work and Employment: Industrial Jahoda, Marie (1982) Employment and Unemployment:
Relations in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University A Social-Psychological Analysis. Cambridge, MA:
Press. pp. 316–24. Cambridge University Press.
Ghoshal, Sumantra (2005) ‘Bad Management Theo- Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, William H. (1976)
ries are Destroying Good Management Practices,’ ‘Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency
Academy of Management Learning and Education, Costs, and Ownership Structure,’ Journal of Financial
4 (1): 75–91. Economics, 3 (4): 305–60.
Godard, John (1992) ‘Contemporary Industrial Relations Kanigel, Robert (1997) The One Best Way: Frederick
Ideologies: A Study of Canadian Academics,’ Winslow Taylor and the Enigma of Efficiency.
Relations Industrielles, 47 (2): 239–66. New York: Penguin.
Godard, John (1995) ‘The Ideologies of U.S. and Katz, Harry C. and Darbishire, Owen (2000). Converging
Canadian IR Scholars: A Comparative Analysis and Divergences: Worldwide Changes in Employment
Construct Validation,’ Journal of Labor Research, Systems. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
16 (2): 127–47. Kaufman, Bruce E. (1993) The Origins and Evolution of
Godard, John (1997) ‘Whither Strategic Choice: the Field of Industrial Relations in the United States.
Do Managerial IR Ideologies Matter?,’ Industrial Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Relations, 36 (2): 206–28. Kaufman, Bruce E. (1997) ‘Labor Markets and
Godard, John (2005) Industrial Relations, the Economy, Employment Regulation: The View of the “Old”
and Society. 3rd edn. Concord, Ontario: Captus Press. Institutionalists,’ in Bruce E. Kaufman (ed.), Govern-
Gottfried, Heidi (2006) ‘Feminist Theories of Work,’ ment Regulation of the Employment Relationship.
in Marek Korczynski, Randy Hodson, and Paul Madison, WI: Industrial Relations Research Associ-
Edwards (eds.), Social Theory at Work. Oxford: Oxford ation. pp. 11–55.
University Press. pp. 121–54. Kaufman, Bruce E. (1999) ‘Expanding the Behavioral
Greene, Anne-Marie (2003) ‘Women and Industrial Foundations of Labor Economics,’ Industrial and
Relations,’ in Peter Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson, Labor Relations Review, 52 (3): 361–92.
(eds.), Understanding Work and Employment: Indus- Kaufman, Bruce E. (2004) The Global Evolution of
trial Relations in Transition. Oxford: Oxford University Industrial Relations: Events, Ideas, and the IIRA.
Press. pp. 305–15. Geneva: International Labour Office.
Gross, James A. (1998) ‘The Broken Promises of the Kaufman, Bruce E. (2005) ‘The Social Welfare Objectives
National Labor Relations Act and the Occupational and Ethical Principles of Industrial Relations,’ in
Safety and Health Act: Conflicting Values and John W. Budd and James G. Scoville (eds.), The
Conceptions of Rights and Justice,’ Chicago-Kent Law Ethics of Human Resources and Industrial Relations.
Review, 73 (1): 351–87. Champaign, IL: Labor and Employment Relations
Hearn, Mark and Michelson, Grant (eds.) (2006) Association. pp. 23–59.
Rethinking Work: Time, Space, and Discourse. Kelloway, Kevin E., Gallagher, Daniel G., and
Melbourne: Cambridge University Press. Barling, Julian (2004) ‘Work, Employment, and the
Hodson, Randy (2001) Dignity at Work. Cambridge: Individual,’ in Bruce E. Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical
Cambridge University Press. Perspectives on Work and the Employment Relation-
Honderich, Ted (ed.) (2005) The Oxford Companion to ship. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research
Philosophy. 2nd edn. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Association. pp. 105–31.
VALUES, IDEOLOGIES, AND FRAMES OF REFERENCE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 111

Kelly, John (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A. (1958)
Mobilization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London: Organizations. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Routledge. Martin, Christopher R. (2004) Framed! Labor and the
Killingsworth, Mark R. (1983) Labor Supply. Cambridge: Corporate Media. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Cambridge University Press. Marx, Karl (1844/1988) Economic and Philosophic
King, Roger (1986). The State in Modern Society: Manuscripts of 1844. Tr. Martin Milligan Amherst,
New Directions in Political Sociology. Chatham, NJ: NY: Prometheus Books.
Chatham House Publishers. Maslow, Abraham H. (1943) ‘A Theory of Human
Kochan, Thomas A. (1998) ‘What is Distinctive About Motivation,’ Psychological Review, 50 (4): 370–96.
Industrial Relations Research?,’ in George Strauss Montgomery, David (1979) Workers’ Control in America:
and Keith Whitfield (eds.), Researching the World of Studies in the History of Work, Technology, and Labor
Work: Strategies and Methods in Studying Industrial Struggles. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Relations. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. pp. 31–45. Muirhead, Russell (2004) Just Work. Cambridge:
Kochan, Thomas A. and. Katz, Harry C. (1988) Collective Harvard University Press.
Bargaining and Industrial Relations: From Theory to Nord, Walter R., Brief, Arthur P., Atieh, Jennifer M.,
Policy and Practice. 2nd edn. Homewood, IL: Irwin. and Doherty, Elizabeth M. (1990) ‘Studying Meanings
Kochan, Thomas A., Katz, Harry C., and McKersie, of Work: The Case of Work Values,’ in Arthur
Robert B. (1986) The Transformation of American P. Brief and Walter R. Nord (eds.), Meanings of
Industrial Relations. New York: Basic Books. Occupational Work. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Kunda, Gideon (1992) Engineering Culture: Control pp. 21–64.
and Commitment in a High-Tech Corporation. Peccoud, Dominique (ed.) (2004) Philosophical and
Philadelphia: Temple University Press. Spiritual Perspectives on Decent Work. Geneva:
Kunda, Gideon and Ailon-Souday, Galit (2005), ‘New International Labour Office.
Designs: Design and Devotion Revisited,’ in Stephen Perlman, Selig (1928) A Theory of the Labor Movement.
Ackroyd, Rosemary Batt, Paul Thompson, and Pamela New York: Macmillan.
S. Tolbert (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Work Pfeffer, Jeffrey (1998) The Human Equation: Building
and Organization. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Profits by Putting People First. Boston: Harvard
pp. 200–19. Business School Press.
Latham, Gary P. and Pinder, Craig C. (2005) ‘Work Pierson, C. (1996) The Modern State. New York:
Motivation Theory and Research at the Dawn of the Routledge.
Twenty-First Century,’ Annual Review of Psychology, Poole, Michael, Mansfield, Roger, Gould-Williams,
56: 485–516. Julian, and Mendes, Priya (2005) ‘British Managers’
Legge, Karen (1995) Human Resource Management: Attitudes and Behavior in Industrial Relations:
Rhetorics and Realities. Basingstoke: Macmillan A Twenty-Year Study,’ British Journal of Industrial
Press. Relations, 43 (1): 117–34.
Leidner, Robin (2006) ‘Identity and Work,’ in Marek Posner, Richard A. (1986) Economic Analysis of Law. 3rd
Korczynski, Randy Hodson, and Paul Edwards (eds.), edn. Boston: Little, Brown.
Social Theory at Work. Oxford: Oxford University Reynolds, Morgan O. (1984) Power and Privilege: Labor
Press. pp. 424–63. Unions in America. New York: Universe Books.
Levine, David I. (1995) Reinventing the Workplace: How Schumacher, E. F. (1974) ‘Economics from the Buddhist
Business and Employees Can Both Win. Washington, Point of View,’ Management Review, 63 (5): 39–42.
D.C.: Brookings Institution. Singer, Peter (2000) Marx: A Very Short Introduction.
Lewin, David (2001) ‘IR and HR Perspectives on Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Workplace Conflict: What Can Each Learn from Skocpol, Theda. (1985) ‘Bringing the State Back in:
the Other?,’ Human Resource Management Review, Strategies of Analysis in Current Research,’ in Peter
11 (4): 453–85. B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol
Lustig, Jeffrey R. (2004) ‘The Tangled Knot of Race and (eds.), Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge:
Class in America,’ in Michael Zweig (ed.), What’s Cambridge University Press. pp. 3–37.
Class Got To Do With It? American Society in the Smith, Adam (1776/2003) An Inquiry Into the Nature
Twenty-First Century. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York:
pp. 45–60. Bantam Books.
Manning, Alan (2003) Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Solomon, Robert C. (1992) Ethics and Excellence:
Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ: Cooperation and Integrity in Business. New York:
Princeton University Press. Oxford University Press.
112 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Tajfel, Henri (1978) ‘Social Categorization, Social Wachter, Michael L. (2004) ‘Theories of the Employ-
Identity, and Social Comparison,’ in Henri Tajfel (ed.), ment Relationship: Choosing Between Norms and
Differentiation Between Social Groups. New York: Contracts,’ in Bruce E. Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical
Academic Press. pp. 61–76. Perspectives on Work and the Employment Relation-
Taylor, Bill, Kai, Chang, and Qi, Li (2003) Indus- ship. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research
trial Relations in China. Cheltenham: Edward Association. pp. 163–93.
Elgar. Webb, Sidney, and Webb, Beatrice (1897) Industrial
Thelen, Herbert and Withall, John (1949) ‘Three Frames Democracy. London: Longmans, Green, and Co.
of Reference: The Description of Climate,’ Human Weber, Max (1919/1946) From Max Weber: Essays
Relations, 2 (2):159–76. in Sociology. Tr. H.H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills.
Thompson, Paul and Newsome, Kirsty (2004) ‘Labor New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Process Theory, Work, and the Employment Relation,’ Weber, Max (1904/1976) Protestant Work Ethic and the
in Bruce E. Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical Perspec- Spirit of Capitalism. Tr. Talcott Parsons. London: Allen
tives on Work and the Employment Relation- and Unwin.
ship. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research Weber, Max (1925/1978) Economy and Society: An
Association. pp. 133–62. Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Tr. E. Fischoff.
Turner, John.C. (1987) Rediscovering the Social Group: Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich (eds.), Berkeley:
A Self-Categorization Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. University of California Press.
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1986) ‘The Wheeler, Hoyt N. (1985) Industrial Conflict: An
Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice,’ Integrative Theory. Columbia: University of South
Science, 211 (4481): 453–58. Carolina Press.
Ulrich, Dave and Brockbank, Wayne (2005) The HR Wheeler, Hoyt N. (1994) ‘Employee Rights as Human
Value Proposition. Boston: Harvard Business School Rights,’ in Jacques Rojot and Hoyt Wheeler (eds.),
Press. Employee Rights and Industrial Justice, special
Varian, Hal. R (1984) Microeconomic Analysis. 2nd edn. issue of Bulletin of Comparative Labour Relations,
New York: W.W. Norton and Company. 28: 9–18.
6
The Influence of Product
Markets on Industrial
Relations
William Brown

Industrial relations are profoundly affected of bargaining structures, designed in large


by the nature of the markets in which firms part to manage these competitive pressures.
compete. The relationships between employ- It explores how this has influenced trade
ers and workers cannot avoid being influenced unions because, as the labor economist
by the competitive pressures bearing down on Nickell has observed, ‘what unions do
the employers, whether those pressures are depends upon what they can do, and this
light and permissive, or tight and unforgiving. depends on the extent of product market com-
How employers respond to these pressures is petition’ (Boeri et al., 2001: 296). Attention
another matter. There may be many different is also given to public sector employment
ways of managing labor that allow firms to that, despite its insulation from normal price
keep afloat in a given competitive situation. mechanisms, is now heavily influenced by
There will be consequent differences in their comparable constraints. The chapter next
industrial relations (IR). But whatever style of considers survey-based economic evidence
labor management is adopted, an important of the link between industrial relations and
and unavoidable constraint on that style is product markets. It then focuses in to look
whether, and with what urgency, the firm’s at ethnographic case study evidence. This
business is under competitive threat. sheds light on how competitive pressures
This chapter is concerned with the rela- are translated into the varied patterns of
tionship between IR and the intensity of managerial control or complacency under
competition for a firm’s goods and services – which great diversity of industrial relations
that is to say, the competitiveness of what has developed in different industries and
is known generically as its ‘product market’. at different times. Finally, it considers the
The chapter first considers the development impact of the geographical widening of
114 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

product market competition in an increasingly its geographical extent. He described how


international economy, and the implications of what he called the ‘competitive menace’ is
this for contemporary IR institutions, which the marginal producer ‘… with the lowest
were rarely intended to reach beyond national standards of living and cost and quality of
frontiers. work, he is the producer whose competition
tends to drag down the level of others toward
his own’ (Commons, 1964: 251).
COMPETITIVE INFLUENCES ON ‘Throughout the course of industrial evo-
BARGAINING STRUCTURE lution the part played by the merchant
stands out as the determining factor. The
Product markets have, in a world of more key to the situation is at all times the price-
or less imperfect competition, always had bargain’, Commons argues. ‘It is the merchant
a huge influence on bargaining structures. who controls both capital and labor. If the
The reasons lie in the nature of trade union merchant has a market, he can secure capital.
activity. Unions attract and retain members by The ‘conflict of capital and labor’ is a
negotiating and protecting improvements in conflict of market and labor, of merchant
their pay and conditions of work. They have and wage-earner, of prices and wages’
traditionally done this either directly by using (Ibid: 261). Associations of manufacturers are
the threat of strike action, or by controlling primarily price-regarding. An extension of
the supply of labor. The consequence is that, the product market, to include lower-paying
if they are successful, and unless there are marginal producers, is likely to provoke
off-setting productivity improvements, they conflict, because established wage-earners
increase unit wage costs for the firms that may try to protect their wages through
employ their members. But this in turn implies trade union action, When this happens, ‘…
that they reduce those firms’ capacity to the manufacturer turns, for the time, from
compete successfully in their product markets. the market and faces the workman. His
So the organizational challenge facing unions “employers’ association” is wholly different
is how to reduce the jeopardy in which in method, object and social significance, and
members’ jobs are placed as a result of usually in personnel from his “manufacturers’
increasing the cost of their labor. association”’ (Ibid: 262).
The argument that this would be best met by Power in industrial relations thus follows
unions’ organizing the whole product market the contours of the markets for the goods and
was explored by the institutional economist services produced, and not just the contours
John Commons. In 1909, in a study of of the market for labor. It is not that the labor
the development of the shoe industry in market is irrelevant. Indeed, the state of the
the US, he drew attention to the historical labor market is of great importance to the
emergence of a gap separating the wage relative power of employers and unions. Other
bargain (between the employer and workers) things being equal, unions generally become
from the price bargain (between the retailer stronger if the labor they organize becomes
and the consumer). Relationships between scarcer. But what they and employers have
journeymen, masters, and customers that, in to fight over is decided by the employers’
a restricted local economy, had regulated not profits. They consequently do battle on a
only wages, but also prices and quality, gave field delineated by the employers’ product
way to increasing domination by merchant market.
retailers who fixed prices by reference to the The implications for unions are sum-
cheapest labor market from which they could marized by Kochan. He describes how
obtain substitute goods, wherever that might Commons:
be. The employment standards of the local
labor market become threatened by those of showed that as transportation systems improved
the relevant product market, however great and it became feasible for employers to
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 115

manufacture products in low labor cost cities organizational interests. But in practice it
and transport them to sell in high labor cost cities, compounds into a broader collusion by both
it became necessary for unions to organize all
sides against the consumer of the product in
competing employers in these various cities. The
basic principle involved here is that unless unions question. Providing that all the employers in
organize all the substitutes for union labor, any the product market are united, collectively
increases in wage costs in the unionized portion of they maintain a monopoly position which
the market will result in a loss of employment to the permits them to charge the consumer higher
non-union sector. Similarly, a strike by employees
prices than would otherwise be the case. The
in the unionized sector will lead consumers to shift
their demand to the non-union sector (Kochan, resulting monopoly profits (referred to by
1980: 50). economists as ‘rents’) may then, in effect, be
shared with the union members by means of
Irrespective of whether labor is organized in a collective agreement that establishes pay
trade unions, the management of it has been levels that are higher than would otherwise
shaped by the predisposition of employers to have been the case. This is where the state
see labor market issues as secondary to the of the labor market and the organizational
price-driven pressures of the product market. strength of the union become important;
Clegg notes that from very early on, many they influence what share of rents the union
trade associations can win.
… interfered with the laws of supply and demand By combining against the consumer across
on their own, even undertaking to regulate wages the full extent of their product market, both
without any pressure from unions. This was true of sides benefit. The unions gain employer
both coal and iron. In coalmining the regulation of recognition and also relatively favorable, and
prices and wages on a county basis by the coal-
stable, terms of employment for their mem-
owners was the general practice long before stable
unions were established (Clegg, 1970: 122). bers. Individual employers have the tricky
problem of managing pay and conditions
In the present, as in the past, employers looked after by their employers’ association.
constantly monitor their local labor markets They are then free to concentrate on compet-
to ensure their own firm’s pay levels are ing with each other by other means. Nor need
sufficiently competitive to attract and retain such collusion be to the detriment of the
workers. But they have a quite different consumer. By reinforcing training and other
concern with the cost implications of what institutions at the industrial level, it can uphold
their commercial competitors are paying, a quality standards for goods and services. It is
concern which predisposes them, if possible, likely to prevent a degrading ‘race to the
to ‘take wages out of competition’ by bottom’ in employment conditions.
colluding with those competitors. It wasAdam In Europe and some other countries,
Smith who observed, over 200 years ago, the result, in due course, was a remark-
that ‘Masters are always and everywhere in ably stable organizational arrangement: the
a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform industrial agreement. Sometimes called a
combination, not to raise wages of labor over ‘multi-employer’ or ‘sectoral’ agreement,
their actual rate’ (Smith, 1776: 59). this became the foundation of collective
Thus, while it is in the interest of unions bargaining in European industrialized coun-
to organize all the workers in a given product tries for much of the twentieth century.
market, the employers whom they confront Such arrangements often started on a local
are predisposed to collude with each other basis. Clegg notes that in Britain ‘until the
as product market competitors. They do this last quarter of the nineteenth century, most
in order to bring stability to employment, employers’ associations were limited to a
which is always a sensitive and potentially single town or region’ (Clegg, 1970: 121).
volatile aspect of any firm’s operations. It But they generally developed, in response
might seem surprising that there should be to wider industrial conflict, and depending
this congruence in employer and trade union on the ease of transport of the product,
116 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

to regional or national level. In his study of the regulation of working conditions in this country
the cotton industry, Turner notes that such (Ministry of Labour, 1961: 18).
development tended to be more unstable
In effect, European governments accepted
when the employers had a strong cartel or
the implied inefficiencies arising from this
monopoly element, ‘but once it is clear that
officially blessed, industry-wide collusion
the unions are established, the employing
against the consumer, in return for the public
body may move to a quite opposite attitude,
benefits in terms of industrial peace, effective
of accommodation to collective organization
training management, and a raft of individual
among its workers’ (Turner, 1962: 378).
employment rights. In Britain there were
And once such bargaining structures were
adverse inflationary implications that first
established as the main means of fixing pay
emerged in the late 1950s, exacerbated by
rates, working hours, holiday entitlements,
declining productivity growth, but it was
and so on, they would typically become
not until the late 1980s that government
powerfully reinforced with their own distinct
ministers were publicly to criticize industrial
apprenticeship arrangements, dispute proce-
agreements as a source of inefficiency and
dures and, in most European countries, legal
uncompetitiveness. As a senior government
support.
minister, Kenneth Clarke, put it, in urging the
Despite the fact that these industrial agree-
abandonment of pay rises linked to industrial
ments were technically in constraint of trade,
agreements:
they commanded considerable governmental
support. In effect, government tolerated If we move to a system where pay increases are
the restraint they placed on competition based primarily on performance, merit, company
because of the benefits they offered in terms profitability, and demand and supply in the local
of industrial peace and good employment labor market, we will dethrone once and for all the
annual pay round and the belief that pay increases
standards. From the late-nineteenth century
do not have to be earned (Financial Times, 12th
onward, industry-based collective bargaining February 1987).
was officially encouraged by British
governments, typically as arrangements The benefits of collusion in the product market
that were generally called National Joint as a basis for managing labor relations were
Industrial Councils. In industries where the substantial. Trade unions whose organiza-
unions were too weak for these, then the tional logic was tied to a particular skill or
Wages Boards (later Wages Councils) were occupation, rather than product market, (such
established, on the bases of the distinct as those based on craft) would accommodate
product markets where labor exploitation to industrial collective bargaining by becom-
was seen to be a problem – Coffin Furniture; ing, for these purposes alone, members of
Cotton Waste Reclamation; Keg and Drum union federations, such as the Confederation
manufacture; Lace Finishing, or whatever. of Shipbuilding and Engineering Unions.
As recently as 1961, the Ministry of Labor’s In industries characterized by considerable
official Industrial Relations Handbook heterogeneity of product market – such
could say: as engineering – employers would exercise
substantial discretion at workplace level but,
When the agreement is made by a number of on the key issues of basic wage rates and hours
different employers or, as is often the case, by
an employers’ association acting on behalf of
of work, they would follow the industrial
the whole or the greater part of the firms in a agreement (Marsh, 1965: 176).
given industry within a wide area, all the workers The grip of the industry agreement was
employed by the employers concerned are secured usually tighter in industries characterized
equality of treatment, while each employer is by homogeneity of production technique
protected against unfair competition by reason of
lower wages costs in so far as his competitors are
and product, such as the manufacture
parties to the agreement. For many years collective of hosiery, or ceramics, or carpets, or
agreements have played a most important part in newspapers. Some employers’ associations
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 117

imposed considerable discipline, including notable exception of the US), was to confront
the enforcement of lock-outs. In cotton, for the unions with employers’ associations and
instance, they fined mill owners who contin- to negotiate product market based, and hence
ued to run their mills when their association industry based, collective agreements.
was in dispute with unions; they refused This was a satisfactory compromise so long
help to member firms who paid above or as two conditions prevailed. The first was
below agreed wage-rates; and as late as 1950, that the rival firms were sufficiently evenly
they expelled firms which paid unauthorized matched within their product market, and
bonuses on wages (Turner, 1962: 377). Even gaining sufficiently from their collusion, for
today some continue to exercise discipline there to be inadequate net benefit to induce
over their members, such as the association one or more larger firms to break away and
that organizes electrical contractors for the deal with trade unions on their own (Ulman,
construction industry, where licensing and 1974). The second condition was that trade
safety issues are dominant. unions were able to organize all relevant
Because labor can itself be so contentious workers across the whole of the appropriate
and troublesome to manage, competing product market, in order to ensure that the
employers have a strong incentive to take firms they dealt with would not be undercut
it out of contention as an issue between by competitors, able to gain advantage from
themselves. Despite this, there have always employing cheaper labor.
been some employers who have pursued their The first condition prevailed in Europe,
own independent, enlightened employment but it was not sustainable in Japan and
practices as a distinctive means of product the US. European governments of the first part
market competition. A number of Quaker- of the twentieth century generally provided
owned British firms come to mind that substantial legislative support for industry-
invested heavily in long-term relationships based collective bargaining and also often for
with employees and in their broader social the associated training arrangements, welfare
welfare. Thereby they undoubtedly gained and employment rights. In large part this was
competitive advantage. But for most of the because these countries had political parties
nineteenth and twentieth centuries this sort backed by trade unions, whose periods in
of benign, employee-oriented independence government sustained this legal support. Thus
remained very much more the exception than both trade union security and employer soli-
the rule (Donkin, 2001). darity received statutory support, and strong
industrial agreements were a consequence.
Japan and the US, by contrast, not only
THE BREAK UP OF PRODUCT MARKET lacked union-backed political parties with a
BASED BARGAINING STRUCTURE commitment to collective bargaining, but had
major industries that were, from early on,
The starting point of this account of the characterized by a relatively small number
underlying market dynamics of industrial of dominant firms for which there were no
relations was the predisposition of firms net benefits from industry-based collective
to concentrate, whether in competition or bargaining (Sisson, 1987).
collusion, on the market in which their goods In Europe, it was in Britain that industry-
and services are traded. Wages are secondary based bargaining first started to crumble.
to prices. If employees organize themselves Initially this was because Britain’s very
into trade unions, sooner or later they have laissez-faire legal structure provided little
to come to terms with the employers’ primary reinforcement to industrial bargaining and
concern with the product market, and organize training institutions. These came under par-
accordingly. As a consequence, firms’ normal ticular pressure when labor markets were tight
response, for most of the twentieth century, in the 1950s and 1960s, creating exceptional
and for most developed economies (with the strains between employers seeking to attract
118 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and retain scarce labor. One after another, are currently associated with the International
industrial agreements began to break up, Trade Union Confederation. They cover broad
usually when dominant employers felt that separate industrial areas such as transport,
they would gain more by controlling their own journalism, metalworking, and chemicals,
industrial relations strategy, most commonly energy and mining (Levinson, 1972). But
by improving the motivational power of their whatever they contribute in terms of commu-
internal pay structure and by paying higher nication, lobbying, and the spread of good
rates. Early examples were Cadbury leaving practice, there is no evidence that they have
the confectionary makers, Dunlop leaving the made a major contribution to the exercise
rubber manufacturers, and Esso leaving the of power in collective bargaining (Borgers,
petroleum refiners (Brown and Terry, 1978: 2000; Cooke, 2005). Of the many obstacles
130). Here we have cases of mainly labor that confront attempts to build international
market pressures causing the break up of trade union solidarity, the greatest challenge is
employer solidarity and hence of industrially probably simply that of getting workers in one
based bargaining units. But this was hap- country to make sacrifices and worsen their
pening firmly within the bounds of a secure own job prospects in defense of workers in
national product market. By contrast, the another country whose jobs are under threat.
second precondition is challenged by threats Even in domestic disputes, collective action
to the integrity of national product markets makes tough demands on worker altruism;
themselves. the evidence is that such demands become
The second precondition for industry-based unsustainable when extended across frontiers.
collective bargaining is a trade union orga- International trade union co-operation can,
nization that is sufficiently comprehensive through political action and consumer bans,
to encompass the whole product market. play a part in inhibiting the irresponsible
As has been noted, the early expansion use of exploited labor in other countries.
of product markets as transport improved There has recently been some development
within countries brought no insurmountable of cross-frontier union co-operation within
problems. Unions and employer associations the European Union (EU) (Marginson and
connived to out-flank and match each other in Sisson, 2004). But experience suggests that
expanding the geographic scope of collective the international use of direct coercion
agreements. But once agreements reached by collective sanctions is not an available
national frontiers this process of joint reg- option.
ulation stopped. Extending further was no The challenge facing trade unions is grow-
problem for what Commons described as ing massively. Product markets have, in recent
the ‘merchant retailers’. They simply bought decades, become substantially more exposed
wherever abroad price and transport costs to international competitive pressures. This
provided the cheapest package. Nor did is because the world economy has become
expanding overseas necessarily impede the steadily more open to trade. The annual
established national producers who, as the growth of international trade since World
twentieth century drew to a close, increasingly War Two has been consistently higher than
outsourced abroad or became multi-national the annual growth in world output, and over
and established their own production facilities the past 20 or so years has been twice as
in cheap labor countries. great. Quite apart from this relative growth
For trade unions, however, the challenge of trade between nations, the number of
of incoming, cheaper product substitutes major trading nations and the size of the
from beyond national frontiers has been world’s competitive base have increased. The
severe and often insuperable. There is over emergence of China, India, and the old Soviet
a 100 years of history of attempts at nations as serious competitors since about
international trade union co-operation. Ten 1990 has roughly doubled the worldwide
industry-specific ‘global union federations’ reservoir of employees competing for jobs.
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 119

These ‘new’ trading countries threaten excep- fewer sectors tenable for effective industrial
tionally tough competition not only in terms collective agreements.
of low wage rates but also, and of greater long- In Britain this has been partly reflected
term significance, in terms of relatively high in the steady contraction in the coverage of
standards of education. industrial (multi-employer) collective agree-
The internationalization of product markets ments as the main basis of pay fixing in the pri-
has also been increased by the internation- vate sector. They had covered the majority of
alization of company ownership. Foreign the private sector workforce in 1960. By 2004,
direct investment has over the past 20 years however, industrial agreements covered only
increased at twice the annual rate of world 4 per cent of private sector workers (in work-
trade, facilitated by technological develop- places with ten or more employees). Another
ments that have improved long-distance trans- 17 per cent of the workers in such workplaces
port, communication, and control systems were covered by enterprise-based (single-
(Acocella, 2005; Singh and Zammit, 2004). employer) agreements. But the remaining
The movement of jobs between countries, four-fifths of the private sector workforce had
even while still within individual enterprises, lost the support of any collective bargaining
becomes ever easier. Companies can easily whatsoever (Kersley et al., 2006: 186).
move to sources of labor beyond the reach Product market circumstances have also
of both trade unions and legal employment influenced the manner of this radical restruc-
protections. turing of collective bargaining. A survey of
From the trade union point of view, the UK multi-plant enterprises was conducted in
prospects of gaining any effective bargaining 1985, at a time when industrial agreements
leverage on ever more sprawling product mar- were already in retreatment, and when the
kets are bleak. There have, of course, always single-employer bargaining, at that time to
been some unionized industrial sectors that some extent replacing them, was close to its
have been exposed to foreign competition. peak (Marginson et al., 1988). This confirmed
A feature of the trade unions most affected that their adjustment was influenced by their
is that they have often shown considerable exposure to international competition: ‘…
sensitivity to this source of vulnerability. it is employers whose companies compete
Thus, for example, in the 1960s and 1970s, the primarily within the UK who appear to
export-oriented metal-working unions took be most interested in taking wages ‘out of
the lead in promoting counter-inflationary competition’ either on an intra-enterprise or
domestic economic policies in Germany, an intra-industry basis’. (Marginson et al.,
Switzerland and Australia (Crouch, 1993: 1988: 150).
268; Kitay and Lansbury, 1997: 225). But Firms’ internal arrangements are strongly
in the twentieth century the challenge was influenced by their product markets. The
often from unionized labor elsewhere, and survey by Marginson et al. showed that, as
in a relatively limited number of sectors employers withdrew from industrial agree-
of manufactures. More recently, international ments (whether or not they continued to recog-
competition has intruded into an increasing nize trade unions), they tended to restructure
range of both manufactures and services, and their internal pay-fixing arrangements along
it has been much less constrained by trade product market lines so that pay could be
unions, not least because their coverage has linked more directly to the performance of
been diminishing in most countries. There specific business units, whether profit centers,
are still some sheltered sectors. Unions are divisions, or individual establishments. As
responding to the fact that many personal a result, for any particular establishment in
services are, by their nature, not amenable one of these multi-plant companies, what
to overseas substitution, and thus offer sub- tended to matter in terms of pay levels
stantial organizational potential (Milkman, depended not on where the establishment
2004). But elsewhere they are finding ever was in the country geographically – that
120 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

is on its local labor market – but where sold to the private sector. In Britain, this
it was situated in the business i.e on its has included railways, bus transport, road
product market. Thus, even when divorced haulage, telecommunications, docks, vehicle,
from collusion with their competitors, and aircraft and ship manufacture, steel, gas,
when free to manage their own employment water, electricity, coal, munitions, airlines,
policies, employers remain focused primarily research laboratories, recruitment services,
upon the demands of the market for their waste disposal, airports, publishing, and much
product, rather than the demands of the market else. For most of these, the transition, since
for their labor. the 1980s, to the demands of a more-or-less
competitive product market was traumatic
and often strike-ridden. In Australia, as
THE USE OF PROXY PRODUCT in Britain, trade union membership has
MARKETS IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR usually fallen substantially, and established
patterns of job control and work organiza-
When we turn to the public sector, the influ- tion have been changed beyond recognition
ence of product markets on industrial relations (Brown et al., 1998; Kitay and Lansbury,
was traditionally notable for its absence. This 1997).
was simply because, operating in non-traded The chastening effect of the introduction
goods and services, these large and, in most of product market pressures on both trade
countries, highly unionized industries were union and managerial behavior has had a
unconstrained by normal market forces. Their substantial influence over British government
labor markets are distinctive because the policy toward those public services that
employer is usually the dominant provider have remained in state ownership. Since
and purchaser of specialist skills – whether the 1980s, governments have introduced a
soldiering, teaching, nursing, fire-fighting, or number of devices to mimic or partially create
whatever. Their product markets are even similar stimuli. Those that introduced direct
more aberrant because, quite apart from competition include: compulsory outsourcing
the absence of any price-fixing mechanism, of, and compulsory tendering for, non-core
questions of quality and distribution are by activities, such as catering and cleaning in
their nature politically determined. This tends hospitals and schools; building and highways
to place trade unions in a strong bargaining maintenance for local government; pilot
position, although they have traditionally training for the armed forces; and prisoner
been reluctant (and in some countries legally transport for goals. One of the clearest
unable) to use it. Pay is usually fixed by examples where partial exposure to markets
reference to external comparison with the has had a fundamental impact on industrial
private sector. ‘Rent’ is reflected in levels of relations was the creation, since the 1990s, of
job security, manning levels, and job control. some privately owned and managed prisons.
If public sector employment were preserved Covering about 10 per cent of the British
in this isolation from the traded sector, its prison population at time of writing, the
industrial relations would remain a very large existence of these, and the threat of more, has
‘special case’ on the margins of the present permitted the relatively peaceful introduction
discussion. of a number of procedural constraints on the
Product market change has, however, use of collective action by previously often
become a crucial issue for the public sectors militant prison officers.
of most western industrialized countries Much quasi-market intervention in Britain
in recent years. In large part this has has been less direct. Throughout the health
been because there has been widespread and education sectors, a proliferation of
privatization. For political, fiscal, strategic, league tables and associated performance
and economic reasons, a variety of usu- measures has been used to try to channel
ally highly unionized industries have been funds and users in ways that might stimulate
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 121

efficient labor management. The civil service THE ECONOMIC EVIDENCE OF


has seen its once monolithic pay structure PRODUCT MARKET EFFECTS
broken up – mimicking private sector multi-
divisional enterprises – into mock product In a perfectly competitive product market, the
market fragments reflecting the domains of role of trade unions is highly constrained.
different departments and agencies. The net They may engage in co-operative behavior
effects of these changes across public services, aimed at improving a firm’s productivity.
in terms of efficiency and service delivery, Sometimes called ‘partnership’ in Britain
remain highly controversial. Industrial rela- and ‘mutual gains’ in the US, this has
tions have certainly become more overtly become more evident in the past decade
conflictual by comparison with the private in response to tighter competition. But any
sector. While public services accounted for more confrontational action that succeeded in
a small minority of strike action until the raising wages or improving work conditions
1990s, during the years 2000–2005 they without compensating productivity improve-
consistently accounted for at least a half of ments may threaten the survival of the firm and
all strikes and three-quarters of all working its jobs by rendering it uncompetitive. Most
days lost through strikes in the UK (ONS, product markets are, however, to varying
2006: 186). Some trade union opposition to extents, imperfectly competitive. The firms
quasi-market innovations has been successful. that operate successfully within them receive
An example was the teachers’ success in the resulting rents as monopoly profits.
blunting the impact of performance-related Whether trade unions are able to obtain a
pay in 1999. But generally the introduction share of those rents, and thereby benefit their
of proxies for product markets has had members, depends upon the organizational
the government’s desired effect of dimin- issues discussed earlier.
ishing the influence of public sector trade Even if unions cannot organize the whole
unions. product market, the degree of its imperfection
It was noted earlier that the condition of has considerable bearing on their strategy.
the labor market is of great importance to the An imperfect product market implies that the
relative power of employers and unions, but individual firms operating in it have some
that they do battle on a field delineated by monopoly power. This may arise, among
the employers’ product market. It was also other things, from a distinctive product, a
noted that the labor market for the public good reputation for service, or a familiar
sector, which in Britain now largely means brand name. If unions can organize firms that
the public services, was highly constrained, have monopoly power, they should be able
with the state being the main provider and to extract some of the rent as benefits for
the main purchaser of the specialist skills their members. Even if the firm is in such a
required. This places the state, as employer, competitive situation that there is no rent, or
in a relatively weak position with regard to its if there is rent but the union cannot mobilize
employees, not least because of the political the strength to bargain a share of it, the
costs arising from the disruption of public union may still maintain employer recognition
services. The radical changes in public sector and employee members through co-operative
industrial relations of the past 20 or so years strategies that, for example, facilitate superior
can be seen as a response to this. There has quality of service.
been a restructuring of incentives by the state Similarly, in a perfect labor market,
in an effort to ensure, to use the previous employees of like skills and other attributes
metaphor, that power follows the contours of would be paid the same, irrespective of
the market for the services delivered, not those the profitability of their employers. But in
of the market for labor delivering them, and practice, labor markets are also imperfect.
thereby to rebuild the authority of the state as As we have seen, one reason for this
an employer. is the active role that employers play in
122 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

‘taking wages out of competition’ in order In Britain’s private sector during the post-
to bring stability to labor management. But war years of relatively high trade union
the ending of the collusive fixing of wages strength, employees’ pay did generally reflect
with industrial collective agreements does not their firm’s profitability (Carruth and Oswald,
end the manipulation of wages by employers. 1989: 166). But while this is consistent with
Employers when bereft of employers’ asso- a link between product market circumstances
ciations do not necessarily become passive and industrial relations outcomes, it is far
‘price takers’. For all but the smallest firms, from sufficient evidence, because firms have
or those dealing in transitory and relatively many reasons for success other than the
unskilled labor, employers remain, within product market in which they are placed. One
fairly broad labor market constraints, active study that explored this further exploited the
‘price makers’. But they do so with the peculiar characteristics of Australia’s wage-
objective of maximizing the productivity of fixing system that made it possible to identify,
their labor. Internal pay structures are delicate by occupation and establishment, informal
motivational devices, whether or not they establishment-negotiated pay increases over
include performance-related pay and other and above the quasi-judicially established
explicit incentives. Notions of ‘fair pay’ industrial rates (Brown et al., 1984). The
are essentially concerned with relative pay, survey was conducted in 1974 of nearly
and the pay comparisons most intensely felt 20,000 employees in 44 occupations in 198
by workers arise within the enterprise. The establishments across nine industries in the
demotivating consequences of internal pay urban labor market of Adelaide. The analysis
mismanagement can rapidly corrode labor suggested, as had the Coventry time-series
productivity. Internal pay structures require study cited above, that pay settlements at
constant management attention. establishment level owed more to the circum-
Once away from an industrial agreement, stances of the employer than to the occupation
employers thus place great emphasis on the of the employee. More important, the analysis
integrity of their firms’ internal pay structures, also suggested that the variance in the size
adapting them to the particular needs of their of these establishment settlements correlated
businesses, while keeping a weather eye on with the concentration ratio of the industry
their local labor market pay levels in order to they were in. The less competitive was the
keep broadly in line with other employers. The industry, the less were the establishment-
effects of this were clearly demonstrated by a specific determinants of pay. It was concluded
study of employees in seven occupations in that wages paid by individual employers in
25 firms in the Coventry engineering industry excess of the industrial rates could only partly
over the decade of the 1970s, a watershed be explained in terms of meeting the needs
period in which these firms were breaking of the local labor market. They also appeared
away from industrial collective bargaining to reflect ‘… employers’ efforts, within the
into managing their own pay (Nolan and bounds of their product market power, to
Brown, 1983). The study showed clearly construct internal pay structures that will
how, as the decade progressed, the size of placate their employees, and motivate them
the annual pay rise an individual received to work productively’ (Ibid: 175).
owed less and less to their occupation, and The influence of product markets is also
more and more to the firm they were in. reflected in the changing impact of collec-
For the increasingly independent employers, tive bargaining. In a review of the micro-
in toughly competitive product markets, the economic effects of trade unions, Metcalf
labor market was a loose constraint. The notes that several studies in the 1980s had
important determinant of pay was ‘… the way reported a negative association between union
in which employers manage work and pay so presence and financial performance. But by
as to maximize their control over unit costs 1990 there were distinctive product market
and output’ (Ibid: 284). effects. Research suggested that ‘over the
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 123

course of the 1980s this negative impact The longer-term implications for trade
weakened such that by 1990 the overall union unions are serious. Noting Blanchard’s obser-
effect was halved as compared to 1984 and vation that across OECD countries ‘rents are
unionized establishments had lower financial getting smaller, leading to less room for rent
performance only where the union was strong extraction … this decrease in attractiveness
and the establishment had some market [of unions to members] is reflected, in nearly
power’ (Wilkinson, 2000: 3). ‘This tempering all countries, by decreased membership and
of the impact of unions was confirmed by support’ (Boeri et al., 2001: 295), Metcalf
Machin and Stewart (1996) who concluded concludes that ‘more intense product market
that by 1990 unions only impacted adversely competition implies a corrosion of the impact
on profitability where there was a closed of union recognition in the workplace which
shop and/or weak competition in the product suggests that in the longer term unions may
market’ (Metcalf, 2003: 146). need to find a different role if they are
‘The intensity of competition has a pro- to prosper’ (Metcalf, 2003: 157). It is a
found effect on what unions can do … It is well conclusion arrived at by the very different
known that non-competitive product markets route of economic modeling of recent labor
permit unions to raise wages. But unions can market performance in the US and Europe
capture product market rents in forms other by Ebell et al. (2004: 11) which concludes
than wages’, observes Metcalf, citing their that the decline in unionization in the US and
propensity to protect members by introducing UK might have been a direct consequence of
rigidities in work organization, rigidities product market reforms of the 1980s.
which may incidentally discourage innovation The picture that emerges from these quan-
and thus productivity growth (Ibid: 155). His titative studies is consistent with the earlier
own analysis of the 1998 British WERS (using more descriptive account. As product mar-
over 1100 workplaces in the trading sector) kets become more internationally exposed,
permitted him to investigate this in unusual employers find it increasingly difficult to man-
detail (controlling for a substantial num- age labor through employers’ associations.
ber of workplace and workforce variables) If they cannot exercise control over wages
because the survey contained comparative by collusion with each other, they have the
measures of labor productivity and of financial option of going alone, and making more active
performance. When there is relatively low use of their payment systems as motivational
competition, with the firm reporting five or devices. If employers’ associations do break
fewer competitors, ‘the probability of above up, the ending of the industrial collective
average labor productivity is 14 per cent agreements associated with them has severe
lower for a unionized workplace than its non- implications for trade union recognition.
union counterpart. But when there are six Bargaining may continue with employers
or more competitors the corresponding figure on an individual basis, but its success is
is 0.6 per cent (not statistically significant). dependent upon the extent of those employers’
And when there is little product market monopoly power, as well as the union’s orga-
competition the likelihood of above average nizational strength. Recent years have seen a
financial performance is 12.4 per cent lower reduction in trade unions’ capacity to bargain
for a union than non-union workplace, yet the a share of rents, both because those rents
corresponding figure is 7.4 per cent higher may have diminished and because unions
with a more competitive product market’ are less able to mobilize effective bargaining
(Ibid: 157). This is powerful evidence that power over geographically extended product
product market competition plays a crucial markets. In the public services, the largely
role in determining union influence over monopolistic and exclusively national nature
both working practices and pay levels: the of the product market ensures that the role of
tighter the competition, the less the union public employees’ unions is relatively secure.
influence. But the scope for private sector trade unions
124 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in sectors exposed to foreign competition is machines broke down, and the restrictions
becoming increasingly curtailed. placed on the managerial staff who set the
prices.
What determined the leniency, from the
pieceworker’s point of view, of these ‘custom
THE TRANSMISSION OF PRODUCT and practice’rules? Two influences were iden-
MARKET CIRCUMSTANCES INTO tified. One was the slackness of management
WORKPLACE RELATIONS controls over work: over such matters as
the recording of working time, the foreman’s
Thus, so far this discussion has been con- freedom to compensate for lost piece-working
cerned with the broad structures of industrial time, and departmental cost controls. The
relations and how they are shaped by product other was the authority and coherence of
market circumstances. But product markets the factories’ shop stewards’ committees,
also impact upon day-to-day industrial rela- which had a potential role in controlling
tions in a much more immediate way. By unruly bargaining that might jeopardize union
what means do product markets actually solidarity. Both influences, the slackness of
change behavior and thereby shape the ways controls and the lack of authority of the shop
employers treat workers? steward organization, were then shown to
A study conducted in the heavy bargain- correlate with a composite measure of the
ing environment of the British engineering constraints exercised by product market and
industry of the 1960s permitted a close technological factors.
examination of this question (Brown, 1973). The relevant conclusions drawn were,
The subject of inquiry was the individual first, that the rules governing the bargaining
piecework payment systems that were then process are ‘… heavily influenced by the
prevalent in the industry. They were widely control systems that managements see fit to
perceived to be a major cause of wage inflation install in their factories’. Second, that ‘the
through ‘wage drift’ processes that involved principal pressures influencing management
no formal negotiation. What were the origins control systems are those of the product
of piecework pay rises, and why did their market, and different product markets can
pace differ substantially between factories? vary considerably in both the degree and the
Case studies of ten factories provided detailed character of their competitiveness’ (Brown,
individual wage data over several years, as 1973: 175). Third, that ‘… the organiza-
well as opportunities for extensive interviews tional and bargaining characteristics of the
and observation. A close relationship was workforce are not the root causes of poor
identified between the pace of informally management controls; a weakly integrated
derived piecework pay rises, on the one hand, workforce may exacerbate the weaknesses of
and, on the other, the widely understood a control system further but it will have been
but unwritten, local workshop ‘rules’ that the initial inadequacy of the controls which
in effect regulated the informal bargaining made the integration of the shop steward
over piecework ‘prices’. These rules were body difficult in the first place’ (Ibid: 171).
not formally negotiated but developed as And, finally, that ‘… under relatively full
‘custom and practice’. This was primarily employment and trade union organization,
as a result of low-level managerial errors it is the product market rather than the
that, once accepted as desirable by workers, labor market which has the major economic
tended to become taken as binding precedents impact upon piecework wage determination’
by their shop stewards and defended by (Ibid: 175).
threats of strike action. The relevant rules The chain of influence described here
concerned questions such as the criteria for is fairly straight-forward. An uncompetitive
re-evaluating piecework prices, the appro- product market does not directly cause
priate level of compensation payment when poor management, but it does increase the
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 125

probability of it because it provides an the employer has little financial incentive


environment in which management has little to respond positively to the needs and
incentive to devote resources to building capabilities of employees.
and maintaining effective controls over labor The more recent history of British industrial
and production. Sloppy controls give rise relations has been dominated by varied
to inconsistency of payment and treatment responses to tightening product markets. For
of workers that generates discontents and some industries the shock has been so great,
encourages worker constraints on the organi- and the response so inadequate, that they have
zation of work. Loss of control is manifest in contracted almost to the point of vanishing
many ways, and the firm unwittingly concedes in the face of overseas competition – coal-
to its workers much of the rent accruing mining, ceramics, ship-building, footwear,
from its partial monopoly position. For the textiles and clothing are examples. Some
workers, the rent they thereby gain takes companies have responded by derecognizing
various largely haphazard forms: inequitably unions, sometimes also out-sourcing work to
distributed ‘windfall’ pay rises, substantial non-union organizations – television, facili-
control over the pace and conduct of work, ties management, newspapers, and banking
discretion over job mobility, control over provide examples. A common response has
overtime, and so on. A loss of focus on been to maintain formal union recognition
competition in the product market leads to a but implicitly to reduce it substantially by
loss of control over the management of the reducing both the range of issues subject
labor market. to negotiation and the influence that unions
The post-war British engineering industry can have over them (Brown et al., 1998;
was far from unique in this response to weak Brown et al., 2000). Increasingly this has
product market competition. Other major been combined with explicit co-operative
industries have seen similar development bargaining arrangements (Oxenbridge and
of haphazard workplace rent sharing arising Brown, 2002). In all cases the primary driver
from weak managerial controls. This was for change has been heightened product
perhaps most notable in the decade or market competition, and an accompanying
so of slack competition that followed the feature has been a much-weakened trade
devastation of potential overseas competitors union, less capable of accessing rents for
during Second World War. Thus the docks its members other than through co-operative
industry saw its workforce develop diverse strategies.
localized controls over manning, piecework,
and work allocation (Mellish, 1972). National
newspapers allowed their union chapels to CONCLUSION
exercise almost complete control over work
patterns, overtime and manning levels, a This chapter has argued that product markets
level of restriction that must have provided form the foundation upon which industrial
a barrier to new entrants from which the own- relations institutions are built. Trade union
ers probably benefited (Sisson, 1975). The strength with respect to employers is, of
petroleum refining and distribution industry course, much affected by the tightness of
allowed middle managers repeatedly to con- the labor market, whether that arises from
cede aspects of the management of overtime an economic boom, or from effective union
to local union branches (Ahlstrand, 1990; controls over labor supply, or whatever
Flanders, 1964). One could go on. A lack else. But it is pre-existing imperfections in
of financial restraint on employers is often the product market that permit collective
associated with poor labor management – the bargaining to deliver benefits to workers.
stable lads employed by race-horse trainers The greater the imperfections, the greater the
and the household staff of the British royalty scope for union members to benefit, provided
provide well-documented examples – because their union can exercise effective leverage
126 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

over all suppliers to the product market, states of Eastern Europe since 2004 will slow
or over individual employers who occupy a this down.
sufficiently monopolistic position within it. A third strategy, aimed at tackling the
It has been argued here that the configu- huge difficulties raised by the globalization
ration of product markets has been moving of product markets, is that of consumer cam-
in ways that are increasingly adverse for paigns, whereby adverse publicity is given to
collective bargaining. This is of less signif- those brand names which use suppliers with
icance in the public sector. Although even poor labor standards. During the past decade
there the state has been eroding the bargaining such campaigns have prompted a substantial
position of public sector trade unions by increase in the use of publicly reported ‘ethical
mimicking product market incentives in order trading audits’ by both major consumer
to weaken the employers’ focus on labor. But good brand names and major supermarket
the changing nature of product markets is chains. The challenge such campaigns face
of deep significance for the private sector, is formidable. Because trading enterprises
where so much employment is now exposed steer by the commercial imperatives of their
to competition from parts of the world product markets then, to the extent that their
where neither trade unions nor statutory markets are global, the standards of employ-
minimum labor standards offer significant ment for increasing numbers of workers will
constraints. tend to be dragged down by the depth of
Denied effective coercive bargaining inequality of labor across the world economy.
power because of tighter product market The campaigners have to counter this by
competition, trade unions in many sectors are appealing to the consciences of consumers,
obliged to focus increasingly on strategies and thereby threatening the reputation of the
which in the past have tended to brand names and supermarkets. It is a vivid
augment, rather than replace, confrontational vindication of John Commons’ emphasis, a
bargaining. One of these is co-operative 100 years ago, on the pivotal role of the
working with employers through the arrange- ‘merchant retailer’.
ments sometimes referred to as ‘partnership’ This chapter has been concerned with
and ‘mutual gains’ . The success of this the interaction of markets and institutions.
depends very much upon the willingness A major role of trade unions has always been
of the employer to make it effective and to to build institutions to provide the agreements
encourage trade union membership as a means and other protections that might insulate their
of upholding good employment practice. members from the harsh vagaries of the mar-
Another strategy that is well-established in ket for their labor. Such vagaries have, in turn,
Europe is that of lobbying the government depended heavily upon the markets for the
to improve statutory support for employment goods and services that their labor produced.
standards. Legal enforcement of improved Ensuring that the geographic reach of union
terms and conditions is directly as important organization equaled that of their members’
to union members as to any other employees. labor markets was relatively straight-forward.
It also establishes a floor on which collective Doing the same for their employers’ product
bargaining can be build without fear of markets was more difficult. But it suited the
being seriously under-cut. The improvement employers’own desire to remove employment
of statutory rights such as minimum wages as an issue of competitive contention and,
and maximum working hours is of particular with state support, provided the basis for
importance to unions seeking to organize nationally based employment regulation for
those large numbers of workers in the private many countries for most of the twentieth
services, where international competition century.
does not pose a threat. A major stimulus Collective bargaining, and national statu-
since the 1970s has come from the European tory labor standards, tamed labor mar-
Union, but the addition of poorer new member kets so long as product markets were
THE INFLUENCE OF PRODUCT MARKETS ON INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 127

predominantly nation-based. It has been Carruth, A. A. and Oswald, A. J. (1989) Pay


the increasingly international nature of the Determination and Industrial Prosperity. Oxford:
world economy that has thrown these sys- Clarendon Press.
tems into disarray. Product markets that Clegg, H. A. (1970) The System of Industrial Relations
extend beyond the reach of either union in Great Britain. Oxford: Blackwell.
Commons, J. R. (1964) ‘American Shoemakers, 1648–
movements or national governments now
1895: A Sketch of Industrial Evolution’ Labor and
threaten the security and well-being of
Administration. A. M. Kelley: New York, reprinted
workers world-wide. The challenge for the from Quarterly Journal of Economics, November,
twenty-first century is to develop new inter- 1909.
national institutions, capable of protecting Cooke, W. N. (2005) ‘Exercising power in a prisoner’s
decent labor standards and of diminish- dilemma: transnational collective bargaining in an
ing the inequalities that will otherwise era of corporate globalisation?’, Industrial Relations
destroy them. Journal, 36 (4): 283–302.
Crouch, C. (1993) Industrial Relations and European
State Traditions. Oxford: Clarendon.
Donkin, R. (2001) Blood, Sweat and Tears: the Evolution
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS of Work. New York: Texere.
Ebell, M., Doppelhofer, G., and Haefke, C. (2004)
The author is grateful for helpful comments Product market regulation in the presence of unions:
from David Metcalf, Peter Nolan, Jon Trevor, quantitative implications. Discussion paper.
and the editors. Financial Times, 12th February 1987.
Flanders, A. (1964) The Fawley Productivity Agreements.
London: Faber and Faber.
Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H.,
REFERENCES Dix, G., and Oxenbridge, S. (2006) Inside the
Workplace: Findings from the 2004 Workplace
Acocella, N. (2005) Economic Policy in the Age of Employment Relations Survey. London: Routledge.
Globalization. Cambridge: CUP. Kitay, J. and Lansbury, R. (1997) Changing Employment
Ahlstrand, B. (1990) The Quest for Productivity. Relations in Australia. Oxford: OUP.
Cambridge: CUP. Kochan, T. (1980) Collective Bargaining and Industrial
Boeri, T., Brugiavivi, A., and Clamfors, L. (eds), (2001) Relations. R. D. Homewood: Irwin.
The Role of Unions in the Twenty-First Century. Levinson, C. (1972) International Trade Unionism.
Oxford: OUP. London: Allen and Unwin.
Borgers, F. (2000) ‘Global unionism: organizational Machin, S. and Stewart, M. (1996) Trade unions and
challenges’, in Hanami, T. (ed.), Universal Wisdom financial performance’, Oxford Economic Papers,
through Globalisation. Tokyo: Japan Institute of 48 (2): 213–41.
Labor. Marginson, P., Edwards, P. K., Martin, R., Purcell, J.,
Brown, W. (1973) Piecework Bargaining. London: and Sisson, K. (1988) Beyond the Workplace: Man-
Heinemann. aging Industrial Relations in the Multi-Establishment
Brown, W. and Terry, M. (1978) ‘The changing nature Enterprise. Oxford: Blackwell.
of national wage agreements’, Scottish Journal of Marginson, P. and Sisson, K. (2004) European
Political Economy, 25 (2): 119–34. Integration and Industrial Relations. Basingstoke:
Brown, W., Hayles, J., Hughes, B., and Rowe, L. Palgrave.
(1984) ‘Product and labor markets in wage Marsh, A. (1965) Industrial Relations in Engineering.
determination: some Australian evidence’, British Oxford: Pergamon.
Journal of Industrial Relations, XXII (2): 169–76. Mellish, M. (1972) The Docks after Devlin. London:
Brown, W., Deakin, S., Hudson, M., Pratten, C. and Heinemann.
Ryan, P. (1998) The Individualisation of Employment Metcalf, D. (2003) ‘Unions and productivity, financial
Contracts in Britain. London: DTI. performance and investment: international evidence’,
Brown, W., Deakin, S., Nash, D., and Oxenbridge, S. in Addison, J. T. and Schnabel, C. (eds), International
(2000) ‘The employment contract: from collective Handbook of Trade Unions. Cheltenham: Elgar.
procedures to individual rights’, British Journal of Milkman, R. (2004) Organizing Immigrants in California.
Industrial Relations, 38 (4): 611–30. Cornell: ILR Press.
128 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Ministry of Labour (1961) Industrial Relations Hand- tic perspectives’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
book. London: HMSO. 20 (1): 85–104.
Nolan, P. and Brown, W. (1983) ‘Competition Sisson, K. (1975) Industrial Relations in Fleet Street.
and workplace wage determination’, Oxford Oxford: Blackwell.
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 45 (3): Sisson, K. (1987) The Management of Collective
269–88. Bargaining. Oxford: Blackwell.
Office for National Statistics (2006) ‘Labor dis- Smith, A. (1776) The Wealth of Nations. London: Strahan
putes in 2005’, Labor Market Trends, 114 (6): and Cadell.
174–90. Turner, H. A. (1962) Trade Union Growth, Structure and
Oxenbridge, S. and Brown, W. (2002) ‘The two faces Policy. London: Allen & Unwin.
of partnership? An assessment of partnership and Ulman, L. (1974) ‘Connective bargaining and competi-
co-operative employer/trade union relationships’, tive bargaining’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy,
Employee Relations, 24 (3): 262–76. 21 (2): 97–109.
Singh, A. and Zammit, A. (2004) ‘Labor standards and Wilkinson, D. (2000) ‘Collective bargaining and
the “race to the bottom”: rethinking globalization workplace financial performance in Britain’, mimeo,
and workers’ rights from developmental and solidaris- Policy Studies Institute, April.
7
Varieties of Capitalism and
Industrial Relations
Kerstin Hamann and John Kelly

INTRODUCTION between industrial relations and varieties of


capitalism. The fifth section evaluates the
Industrial relations systems have long been correspondence between national patterns of
classified into different groups, such as the industrial relations and varieties of capital-
Anglo-Saxon, the Scandinavian, or the con- ism empirically. The chapter concludes by
tinental European model. Similarly, welfare suggesting directions for further research.
states have also been sorted into several
categories, such as Christian-democratic,
liberal, or social-democratic. The Varieties NATIONAL DIFFERENCES IN THE
of Capitalism (VoC) approach has grouped INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS LITERATURE
capitalist systems – especially those of
the OECD – into several categories, such Much of the research into national patterns
as Liberal Market Economies (LMEs) and of industrial relations has engaged with the
Coordinated Market Economies (CMEs). long-standing debate over the degree of
Given the parallel existence of these clas- convergence or divergence between advanced
sifications of capitalist political economies, capitalist economies. The seminal statement
this chapter discusses to what extent the of the convergence hypothesis by Kerr et al.
VoC approach is congruent with or differ- (Industrialism and Industrial Man, 1960) was
ent from industrial relations classifications. a critique of the Marxist argument that the
It also analyzes whether and how the VoC development of technology would generate
approach contributes to the study of industrial increasing strains and conflicts in the relations
relations. The next section reviews the between labor and capital and facilitate the
literature on national models of industrial transition to a socialist society. Kerr et al.
relations and; the third section outlines the argued that technological development in a
main variants of the VoC approach. The context of competitive product markets would
chapter then assesses the theoretical links produce convergent ‘pluralistic industrialism’
130 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

instead of socialism. The defining attributes Analyzing production at the national level,
of this society were increased affluence and however, some commentators found that
social mobility, class dealignment in voting the economic superiority of US capitalism
behavior and party politics, and an industrial could force the economies and industrial
relations system based around group, not relations systems of Europe and Japan to
class, interests and regulated primarily by converge on the US model (Dore et al.,
collective bargaining. 1999). This revival of interest in converging
The world strike wave of 1968–1974 production systems was short-lived because
and the associated problems of stagflation, comparative industrial relations scholars
declining profitability and industrial and were increasingly taking a broader approach
political disorder called into question both the and describing and analyzing differences
predictions and the underlying assumptions between national systems of employment
of the original convergence hypothesis (see regulation. For example, Visser (1992) drew
Armstrong et al., 1991: 169–220; Kelly, 1998: attention to the stability of union density
83–107). Even more troubling for conver- in Scandinavia and Belgium compared to
gence theorists was the variety of government the rest of the advanced capitalist world, a
responses to the economic and industrial fact he explained by reference to the role
relations problems of the 1970s. In a number of unions in the provision of unemployment
of countries leftist governments initiated what benefit (see also Western, 1997). Hyman’s
Pizzorno (1978) described as a process of (2001) framework for analyzing trade union
‘political exchange’ in which they offered behavior and strategy develops three ideal
increased legal rights to unions in return types of union movement. Unions can
for union commitment to wage moderation. function as labor market actors (as in the
One of the major themes in the analysis of UK), as class actors (for example Italy),
political exchange (increasingly described as or as social actors (for example Germany)
corporatist policymaking) was the classifica- although in practice unions display varying
tion of differences between countries. Italy degrees of each of these tendencies. The
and Sweden, for example, had well developed distinction between coordinated economies
corporatist arrangements compared to the and liberal market economies (see below)
‘pluralistic fragmentation’ of the UK and the has informed a number of IR studies, such
US, where corporatism was weak or non- as Gospel and Pendleton (2003) on trends
existent (Goldthorpe, 1984; Regini, 1984). in corporate governance or Turnbull et al.’s
The increased globalization of production, (2004) analysis of British, Irish, and German
trade, and investment through the 1980s airlines.
revived the convergence hypothesis. Piore and Perhaps the most systematic typology of
Sabel (1984) charted the evolution of produc- national systems of industrial relations was
tion systems throughout the twentieth century developed by Crouch (1993), who categorized
from Fordism to post-Fordism (or ‘flexible industrial relations along two dimensions,
specialization’), a superior form of economic power of organized labor (high-low) and
organization to its mass production prede- degree of centralization of labor and capital
cessor. Womack et al. (1990) built on this (high-low), resulting in a 2 x 2 matrix. He
work to argue that Japanese ‘lean production’ labeled these neo-corporatism (strong labor),
and shop floor participation had demonstrated for example Scandinavia; neo-corporatism
its economic superiority to other forms of (weak labor), for example Germany,
work organization and workplace industrial Netherlands; contestational bargaining
relations. In their view competition would (strong labor), for example the UK, Italy;
force other firms to adopt the ‘Japanese model’ and pluralistic bargaining (weak labor), for
or go under (see also Oliver and Wilkinson, example France, Spain (Crouch, 1993: 43,
1992 but cf.; Bélanger et al., 1994; Kochan 289–90; see also Regini, 1984). While the
et al., 1997). analysis focuses on the roles of unions, the
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 131

country cases are broadly comparable to VoC working-class mobilization and cross-class
categories, as discussed below. coalitions (Esping-Andersen, 1990: 31). The
This brief review reveals a striking parallel social-democratic type emphasizes universal-
between the analyses of industrial relations ism and decommodification of social rights
scholars and those of political economists. to the working and the middle classes and is
The distinction between a ‘liberal’ model found primarily in Scandinavia. The liberal
of industrial relations and some form of model emphasizes welfare measures that
European model is commonplace and co- are means-tested and provides only modest
exists with more elaborate typologies. The universal transfers and social insurance plans;
next section shows how political economists this regime is predominant in the US, Canada,
have attempted to construct national patterns and Australia. The conservative regime is
and clusters. present in highly corporatist countries, such
as Austria, Germany, or France, and while in
this welfare regime the state rather than the
APPROACHES TO THE VARIETIES OF market provides most of the welfare, it also
CAPITALISM SINCE THE 1990s emphasizes status differences and thus offers
few redistributive policies (Esping-Andersen,
A series of events and developments in the 1990: 26–8).
1990s led to renewed interest in understanding Other authors have developed slightly
the systematic differences and similarities different categories. Hicks and Kenworthy
across the economies of Western democracies: (2003), for instance, identify two welfare
the decline of neo-corporatism and varied state dimensions, ‘progressive liberalism’ and
national responses to external pressures, ‘traditional conservatism’. The difference in
including European economic unification classification matters when the relationship
and globalization, demographic changes in between the types of welfare state is related to
advanced industrialized economies, and the economic performance in three areas, income
replacement of the Keynesian consensus by redistribution, jobs, and gender equality.
neo-liberal ideas and policies. The politi- Based on an empirical analysis of OECD
cal economy literature broadly distinguishes countries, the authors conclude that thinking
between two approaches: one addresses of welfare states in terms of dimensions
primarily types and origins of welfare states, rather than categories is a more useful
while the second one looks at economic approach because it allows for ‘more elegant
systems more generally by taking the complex and fine-grained analyses of cross-regime
interaction between sets of institutions and differences in parameters explaining welfare
actors as its starting point for analysis state phenomena’ (Hicks and Kenworthy,
(see Ebbinghaus and Manow, 2001). 2003: 31).
The development and crisis of welfare
states form the central focus of Huber and
Welfare-state centered approaches
Stephens (2001a, b), who understand the
Welfare state regimes are of great impor- welfare state to be closely linked to the
tance to industrial relations because they balance of power between different groups
link to issues germane to unions, such as and political institutions. They differ from
(un)employment protection. Some of the Esping-Andersen (1990) in that they re-label
foremost studies analyzing types of welfare the conservative welfare state as ‘Christian
systems are Esping-Andersen’s works, espe- democratic’ to denote the pivotal role of
cially his seminal book The Three Worlds partisan politics. They also separate Australia
of Welfare Capitalism (1990). He identifies and New Zealand into a fourth type, the ‘wage
three distinct types of welfare state, social- earner welfare state’ (Huber and Stephens,
democratic, liberal, and conservative and 2001a: 87). Huber and Stephens identify
reasons these regime types are the result of political parties as the motor of welfare
132 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

state development. The ideology, or ‘political welfare states lack coordination and broadly
coloring’, of the parties was instrumental correspond to the category of liberal market
in shaping the welfare state; which parties economies (see below). In this approach,
were holding elected office, in turn, reflected industrial relations play a central part as the
social cleavages and the distribution of power, strength, organization, and representation of
especially the strength of organized labor the working class forms a core component
and religious cleavages (Huber and Stephens, of the explanation for the emergence of the
2001a: 1). The country’s position in the welfare and industrial relations institutions.
international economy and its production Going beyond types of welfare states,
regime were also pivotal factors in developing some authors have combined the analysis of
welfare systems. Furthermore, welfare state types of capitalist systems and adjustment
development and retrenchment are intrinsi- to new economic pressures with the insights
cally political processes and are facilitated from the literatures on welfare states and on
or constrained by political institutions that political institutions and processes. Swank
distribute power within the political system. (2002) examines how these different aspects
For example, where multiple veto points are related and finds that it is not just economic
exist, such as in Switzerland or Germany, institutions and actors that determine how
welfare retrenchment was very limited, while capitalist states respond to globalization,
those constitutions that have few built- but also political institutions and processes.
in veto points allow for more rapid and The three different types of welfare state –
dramatic retrenchment (Huber and Stephens, social democratic, corporatist-conservative
2001a: 1–5). and liberal – changed in different ways
Huber and Stephens (2001a) also find because of the differing forms of interest
that some labor market parameters cor- representation and the varying strengths of left
respond broadly to welfare state types: and right political parties in these countries
for example, social-democratic countries (Swank, 2002: 280–2).
(Scandinavia) generally feature high union
density; Christian-democratic countries (for
Actor- and institution-centered
example Germany, Netherlands, Belgium)
approaches
have lower union density, but high bargain-
ing coverage. Corporatism and bargaining The second approach to understanding dif-
centralization similarly differ across types of ferences and similarities across advanced
welfare states – the social democratic and industrialized economies looks at a variety of
Christian democratic welfare states have rela- economic institutions and actors emphasizing
tively high scores on the corporatism index, the way in which coordination is organized.
while corporatism is less prevalent in the Several of these studies thus include industrial
liberal welfare states, despite some variation relations and production systems as well
within the categories. Liberal welfare states as welfare protection systems (for example
(for example Ireland, the UK, and US) have Rhodes, 2005; Schmidt, 2002: 113; Swank,
lower skill levels while social democratic 2002: 41–4). Many of these studies use
systems have the highest skill levels; wage these frameworks to understand how national
dispersion is highest in the liberal welfare economies have responded to the challenges
states and much less so in the other two of demographic changes, European economic
types, and social democratic welfare states integration, and globalization. They find that
show considerably higher levels of active the organization of the national economy
labor market policies than the other welfare has much to contribute to our understanding
state types (Huber and Stephens, 2001a: of national responses. This approach links
85–99). Similarly, types of welfare regimes together distinct spheres of the political
and varieties of capitalism overlap: liberal economy – and sometimes the political
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 133

system – and understands these parts to be which are not systematically discussed. LMEs
connected as ‘complementarities’, (see Hall are characterized by the fact that ‘firms coordi-
and Soskice, 2001a; Höpner, 2005). Authors nate their activities primarily via hierarchies
differ in the emphasis they place on various and competitive market arrangements’ (Hall
actors and institutions, the range of countries and Soskice, 2001a: 8), and the market mech-
they use as their empirical base, and the types anism based on supply and demand is, by and
of classifications they develop. large, driven by factors identified in the liberal
Maybe the most prominent analysis of or neoclassical economic model. The US and
varieties of capitalism is the edited volume the UK serve as standard ideal-type cases of
with the same title by Peter Hall and David this type of economy. In CMEs, by contrast,
Soskice (2001b). In particular the editors’ firms’ coordination depends more heavily on
Introduction (Hall and Soskice, 2001a) pro- non-market relationships (Hall and Soskice,
vides a comprehensive framework outlining 2001a: 8). Thus, compared to LMEs, CMEs
the differences between two main types display higher levels of cooperation among
of capitalist economies – liberal market actors, which takes time to develop (Hall and
economies (LMEs) and co-ordinated market Soskice, 2001a: 13). Hall and Soskice do
economies (CMEs) – while also briefly not provide any normative evaluation about
mentioning a third variant, the Mediterranean which system is better or preferable. Instead,
economies (MEs). The authors emphasize they conclude that each of these ideal types
that their interpretation of political economies has comparative advantages that are used by
relies on an actor-centered approach that specific industries. For example, high-skill,
focuses on how these institutions affect actors’ high-wage industries find that CMEs with
strategic interactions (Hall and Soskice, their patient capital, generous welfare systems
2001a: 5). and publicly-supported training regimes pro-
In a context of economic globalization vide a better economic environment, while
and restructuring, firms act as ‘key agents low-wage, low-skill industries that respond
of adjustment’ and therefore constitute the quickly to changing market demands find
centerpiece of the analysis (2001a: 5). Hall LMEs more advantageous (2001a: 40–1).
and Soskice adopt a ‘relational’ conception of Hall and Soskice’s approach grounds
firms according to which firms engage in coor- comparative analysis in a clear theoretical
dination processes in five spheres: industrial framework and directs attention to a wide
relations, vocational training and education, range of economic institutions (pace Albert,
corporate governance, inter-firm relations, 1993). However, the approach has been
and employees. The different institutions in criticized from various perspectives. For
these spheres are not isolated, but instead example, one of the criticisms of VoC has been
are interconnected, producing what Hall and the fact that industrial relations play only a
Soskice label ‘institutional complementari- minor part in firms’ coordination strategies,
ties’, where different institutions reinforce and that power relationships between unions
and complement each other. Institutions, in and employers as well as class conflict are
this view, are important because they provide underemphasized (Crouch, 2005: 80; Howell,
support for firms as they attempt to resolve 2003; 2005). While Hall and Soskice (2001a)
coordination problems (Hall and Soskice, have little to say about class conflict in LMEs,
2001a: 9). the assumption of the congruency of class
Together, the interlocking, mutually rein- interests is particularly evident in the volume’s
forcing institutions and the way firms interact discussion of CMEs: organized production
with other actors in these five spheres co- systems and their complementary welfare
vary systematically to produce two ideal types protection systems benefit not just labor, but
of capitalist political economy, LMEs and also employers, who see comparative advan-
CMEs, and the Mediterranean economies, tages in such arrangements. This emphasis
134 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

on a minimum of cross-class consensus in classification against a large number of indi-


coordinated economies is mirrored in research cators. Based on a combination of five institu-
focused on the role of employers in the tional spheres – ‘product-market competition;
creation of these systems including their the wage-labor nexus and labor-market insti-
welfare states (for example Mares, 2001; tutions; the financial intermediation sector and
Swenson, 2002).1 corporate governance; social protection and
Asecond main criticism of Hall and Soskice the welfare state; and the education sector’
is that in assigning a central role to the firm (Amable, 2003: 14) – he establishes a set of
they downplay the role of the state. Howell linkages and institutional complementarities
(2005) argues that the British state played a between these spheres. The resulting clusters
key role in the reconstruction of industrial are identified as the market-based model,
relations throughout the twentieth century. the continental European model, the Social-
More generally, Weiss (2003) contends that Democratic model, the Mediterranean model,
states continue to play a key role in the and the Asian model (cf. Kitschelt et al.,
regulation of economic policy, constructing 1999: 430–4 for a similar, fourfold typology
the fiscal and other environments within but without the Mediterranean model). Coates
which firms make decisions. Finally, while (2000: 9–11) contends that different ‘models
Hall and Soskice’s approach is able to explain of capitalism’ can be distinguished according
institutional stability through the notion of to the actors that control decisions about
complementarities, it is perhaps less well production and investment: in market-led
equipped to account for the type of radical capitalisms it is the firm that predominates;
institutional change witnessed in the UK after in state-led capitalisms, economic decision
1979 or in Ireland after the first social pact making is shared between firms and the state,
in 1987 (for these and additional critiques, as in Japan or South Korea; and finally
see Crouch, 2005: 80–2; Hamann and Kelly, in ‘negotiated or consensual capitalism’,
2007; Howell, 2005; Pontusson, 2005). economic decisions involve the three social
Other authors have responded to these partners, firms, trade unions and the state, as
weaknesses by constructing their own typolo- in Germany or Scandinavia.
gies. Schmidt (2002) identifies three types These and other classifications and typolo-
of capitalist economies: market capitalism, gies (see for example Boyer, 2005; Whitley,
embodied by the US and the UK; managed 1999) agree on a distinct variety of capitalism,
capitalism, practiced by central and northern variously called liberal market or market-
European countries (for example Germany, led capitalism and typified by the US
Netherlands, Sweden); and state capitalism, and UK. Where there is disagreement is
prevalent in France and Italy. These types are over how to classify the remaining advanced
distinct along three dimensions: business rela- capitalist countries, particularly those in
tions, including inter-firm relations, industry- Western Europe. Do these countries con-
finance relations, and investment patterns; stitute two groups, the co-ordinated market
the role of the government in the economy economies and the Mediterranean economies,
and the characteristics of the state; and the or should the Scandinavian economies be
structure of the wage bargaining system and grouped as an additional type? Similar
the role of the government in labor regulation disagreement concerns the theoretical basis
(Schmidt, 2002: 113). She thus adds an in- for classification. Some analyses start from a
depth analysis of cases outside of the LME– theoretical framework, such as the transaction
CME classification, and by looking at case costs model of coordination, and proceed to
studies over time rather than cross-sectional construct a logical typology based on modes
‘slices’, also incorporates dynamics of change of coordination (Hall and Soskice, 2001a).
(Schmidt, 2002: 111). Others proceed inductively, examining a large
Amable (2003) develops five models of body of evidence on institutions and outcomes
capitalism and tests the robustness of his and attempting to fit a typology to the data
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 135

(Amable, 2003). Of particular interest here is focusing on high-skill, high-quality export


the way industrial relations are woven into the manufacturing goods’ (King and Wood, 1999:
analyses of capitalism, and the extent to which 387). Looking at industrial relations in more
the VoC approach furthers our understanding detail, we find that the VoC classifications can
of industrial relations. assist research on industrial relations in six
ways.
First, because of variations in the role of
markets across countries we would expect
LINKS BETWEEN VARIETIES OF corresponding variations in the forms and
CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL degree of organization of the industrial rela-
RELATIONS INSTITUTIONS tions actors and their relationships. Amable
(2003) in particular posits we would expect
How, then, are the types of capitalism linked significant differences in bargaining coordi-
to industrial relations? What is the use of nation, union density, and industrial conflict
establishing typologies of capitalism in the between the five varieties of capitalism he
context of industrial relations? Although Hall identifies. Hall and Soskice (2001a: 24–25), in
and Soskice claim there are no sustained contrast, find that CMEs display higher levels
and dramatic macro-economic performance of bargaining coordination and coverage, as
differences between CMEs and LMEs, they well as lower levels of industrial conflict,
also point to significant labor market differ- but will not necessarily show higher union
ences. Specifically, LMEs are likely to show density compared to LMEs (see also Thelen,
higher rates of employment and of income 2001). Furthermore, CMEs rely on ‘industrial
inequality than CMEs (Hall and Soskice, relations systems in which unions play an
2001a: 21–2). Soskice (1999) presents a more important part and which allow cooperative
dynamic approach and examines whether industrial relations within the company and
different varieties of capitalism have affected coordinated wage bargaining across compa-
how labor relations have changed since the nies’ (Soskice, 1999: 106–7, emphasis in the
1980s. He finds that organized labor has original).
remained ‘incorporated’, in some fashion, Second, differences in welfare state
in the non-market coordination processes regimes across VoCs are associated with
present in CMEs, whereas organized labor differences in labor supply and labor force
has been progressively excluded in the LMEs, composition. Liberal welfare states typically
which rely on market coordination between have a larger low-wage sector compared to
employers while the state remains at ‘arm’s Christian democratic welfares states. As the
length’ (Soskice, 1999: 103). According to low-wage sector tends to employ relatively
Hall and Soskice (2001a), the types of capi- large numbers of women, female participation
talism have distinctive industrial relations. For rates are often higher in the liberal welfares
instance, LMEs tend to feature less regulated states (Huber and Stephens, 2001b: 117–8).
and more flexible labor markets with weaker In other words, social policy is instrumental
unions, less centralized bargaining and less in shaping labor supply (Esping-Andersen,
employment protection. The lack of employer 1990: 150).
coordination means that it is difficult for the Third, varieties of capitalism differ system-
state to negotiate with business collectively atically in the skill composition of their labor
(Soskice, 1999: 110). Union strength is forces, which in turn are linked to the business
critical because in LMEs, strong unions are strategies of firms. For instance, the generous
considered to weaken competitiveness by unemployment benefits found in the CMEs
driving up production costs (King and Wood, provide incentives for individuals to go
1999: 387). By contrast in CMEs, employers through industry-specific training at low
have an interest in strong unions because they wages, which in turn makes it possible and
‘form an essential part of productive strategies profitable for employers to invest in high-skill
136 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

industries (Estevez-Abe et al., 2001). LMEs, expected to yield less wage inequality than
in contrast, operate with lower skill levels under more decentralized arrangements. Also,
and flexible labor markets and less generous pay trends might be affected, directly or
unemployment benefits (Mares, 2001). Thus, indirectly, by the higher unemployment often
industrial relations factors (wage protection) found in the LMEs.
interact with welfare systems (employment And finally, Höpner (2005: 334) points out
and unemployment protection) in the area that the understanding of industrial relations
of skill formation and are associated with as part of a larger web of institutions can have
different types of production regimes. important policy ramifications. Proponents
Fourth, differences in the training and wel- of particular reforms thus need to exercise
fare regimes of national capitalism are linked caution when attempting to import success
to wage bargaining institutions: coordinated strategies from other countries. What ‘works’
wage bargaining systems would be expected in one particular institutional setting might
where industry-specific skills are important, not necessarily have the same effect in a
while weakly coordinated systems would be different set of economic institutions; func-
found where general skills matter most. This tional equivalents might need to be carefully
is because wage determination systems are defined and sought. Moreover, changing one
related to wage protection, which ‘reinforces part of the set of ‘complementary’ institutions
the effects of employment and unemployment might have ramifications for some or all
protection by reducing the risk that the wage of those institutions as well. To illustrate,
levels for specific skills might drop radically Heery and Adler (2004) have shown that
in the future’ (Estevez-Abe et al., 2001:153; where bargaining coverage is high and
emphasis in the original). Within CMEs, uncoupled from union density, unions have
production strategies centered around highly relatively weak incentives to invest resources
skilled workers face the problem that those in recruiting and organizing new members.
workers can be ‘poached’ by other firms In contrast, where coverage is closely tied to
(Hall and Soskice, 2001a: 24). Industrial density, as in the LMEs, unions have far more
relations institutions need to address this powerful incentives to engage in organizing.
problem through wage bargaining institutions
and extension mechanisms that assure com-
parable wages for specific skill levels across
an industry. Coordinated bargaining should DO VARIETIES OF INDUSTRIAL
therefore enhance worker job tenure at firms RELATIONS CORRESPOND TO
and preempt inflationary trends (Hall and VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM?
Soskice, 2001a: 24–5). Empirical evidence
from 18 OECD countries broadly supports While Hall and Soskice (2001a) suggest
these theoretically developed linkages. that IR should systematically vary across
Fifth, varieties of capitalism may be useful types of capitalism as they form part of
in understanding labor market outcomes such an interconnected set of complementary
as wage inequality (see Huber and Stephens, institutions, some of the contributions in
2001b; Rueda and Pontusson, 2000). Since their edited volume hint that IR do not
trade unions promote pay equality the more always fit neatly into the different varieties
rapid demise of union density in the LMEs of capitalism. Italy is a case in point: while
might result in greater pay inequality com- labeled an ‘ambiguous’case that is classed as a
pared to the CMEs. However, it could also ‘Mediterranean’ economy in the introductory
be the case that bargaining coverage, either chapter (Hall and Soskice, 2001a: 21), Thelen
as well as or instead of union density, has in her chapter on labor politics in the same
the greater impact on pay inequality. Insofar volume characterizes Italy as a CME. She
as centralized bargaining takes wages out reasons that Italy’s industrial relations system
of competition between firms it would be resembles that of CMEs rather than that of
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 137

LMEs, in particular with respect to bargaining Broadly, countries fall into three clusters
patterns (Thelen, 2001: 88–9). Thus, while with respect to union density: the LMEs, the
industrial relations are part of a set of four Scandinavian countries – three of which
complementary institutions, sometimes they operate the Ghent system of unemployment
apparently take on a character of their own insurance (Western, 1997: 193) – and a much
that does not necessarily mesh well with the more heterogeneous CME group. Table 7.1
other institutions. This might be particularly suggests that density decline has indeed been
the case for the understudied ‘Mediterranean’ steeper in the six LMEs for the 1980–2000
cases that are sometimes characterized by a time period compared to the remaining 14
lack of institutional complementarities (see non-LMEs (median percentage point declines
Crouch, 2005: 71–2). We observed earlier were 20 and 9 respectively). However,
that several authors (Amable, 2003; Hyman, also striking are the differences within the
2004) argue that the Northern and Southern ‘non-LME’ group. The four Scandinavian
European economies should be distinguished economies stand out here because density
from the prototypical coordinated economies, rose in one of them and fell only slightly
such as Germany, and from the LMEs. To in the other three. Equally striking is the
see whether this fourfold typology rather variation within pairs of countries that are
than a threefold classification scheme makes otherwise very similar. For example, since
sense for industrial relations, we have exam- the late 1980s density has risen in Spain but
ined 20 OECD countries along a series of fallen in Portugal. If we look at changes over
indicators commonly used in the industrial time, Table 7.1 shows that the gap between
relations literature (Perraton and Clift, 2004): the Scandinavian economies and the other
union density and union structure, bargaining countries has actually widened: there is no
structure and bargaining coverage, employ- evidence of convergence.
ment protection, income inequality, industrial Union structure displays even more sys-
conflict, and unemployment rates. We address tematic variation across countries and again
three questions: are there continuing and the evidence suggests that countries can be
significant differences in patterns of industrial meaningfully grouped into several categories.
relations between varieties of capitalism? Is Unitary confederations are largely confined
there evidence of convergence? And how to the LMEs but are also found in Austria
can we account for significant changes over and Greece. Occupational divisions are found
time? We rely on comparisons of means and both in the four Scandinavian countries
medians because the small number of cases and in a number of CMEs. Political and
in each group precludes meaningful statistical religious cleavages are more prevalent in the
testing (cf also Huber and Stephens, 2001a: Mediterranean economies and in some of
Tables 4.2– 4.4). Overall the data have pro- the CMEs (Belgium and the Netherlands for
duced a broad clustering of four groups as pre- example) (Ebbinghaus and Visser, 2000).
sented in the following tables and discussion. Bargaining structure is increasingly dif-
According to Golden et al. (1999) the type ficult to measure because bargaining is
of capitalist system had little systematic effect often conducted at multiple levels within
on changes in union density between 1950 national economies and because of significant
and 1989. Union density decline was most variation in the coordinating capacity of
pronounced in Austria (CME), the US (LME), the social partners. Nonetheless Visser and
France and Italy (ME), and Japan (considered colleagues (cited in Calmfors et al., 2001)
by Hall and Soskice as a particular type of have attempted to produce a composite
CME, 2001a: 34). However, these data cover measure that takes into account the degree
only 12 countries and do not go beyond 1989. of centralization of bargaining as well as
If we include additional cases and take the the degree of coordination exercised by the
time series up to 2000, the evidence fits better unions at each level (Table 7.2).2 The data
with the VoC approach (see Table 7.1). show that a significant degree of bargaining
138 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 7.1 Union density (%) and density change in 20 OECD countries 1980–2000
Country 1980 1990 2000 Absolute change Relative change
1980–2000, % 1980–2000, %
points
Denmark 79 75 74 −5 −6
Finland 69 72 76 +7 +10
Norway 58 59 54 −4 −7
Sweden 80 80 79 −1 −1
Mean N. Europe 71.5 71.5 71 −0.5
France 18 10 10 −8 −44
Greece 39 32 27 −12 −31
Italy 50 39 35 −15 −30
Portugal 61 32 24 −37 −61
Spain 7 11 15 +8 +114
Mean MEs 35 25 22 −12.8
Austria 57 47 37 −20 −35
Belgium 54 54 56 +2 +4
Germany 35 31 25 −10 −29
Netherlands 35 25 23 −12 −34
Switzerland 31 24 18 −13 −42
Mean C. Europe 42 36 32 −10.6
Australia 48 40 25 −23 −48
Canada 35 33 28 −7 −20
Ireland 57 51 38 −19 −33
New Zealand 69 51 23 −46 −67
UK 51 39 31 −20 −39
USA 22 15 13 −9 −41
Mean LMEs 47 38 26 −20.7
Source: OECD 2004a, Table 3.3.

Table 7.2 Bargaining coordination index decentralization has occurred and that the
and rankings in 15 OECD countries 1973–77
differences between types of capitalism have
and 1993–97
shrunk. On the other hand the rank ordering of
Country 1973–77 1993–97
countries and types of countries has remained
Denmark 0.639 (4) 0.341 (9) remarkably stable over a 25-year period
Finland 0.642 (3) 0.465 (3)
Norway 0.419 (6) 0.419 (5)
(with the exception of one or two countries
Sweden 0.745 (2) 0.389 (7) such as Ireland and the Netherlands) so
Mean N. Europe 0.616 (3.75) 0.404 (6.0) that the Scandinavian and the Mediterranean
France 0.104 (15) 0.079 (15) economies clearly stand out from the rest and
Italy 0.382 (8) 0.324 (10) from each other.
Spain 0.395 (7) 0.343 (8) Bargaining coverage rates are somewhat
Portugal 0.223 (13) 0.284 (11) more clear-cut in that they remained quite
Mean MEs 0.276 (10.75) 0.258 (11.0)
stable and high during the 1980s and 1990s
Austria 0.823 (1) 0.648 (2) in most non-LMEs compared to the LMEs.
Belgium 0.521 (5) 0.442 (4) Within the latter group, they fell significantly
Germany 0.346 (11) 0.243 (12)
Netherlands 0.340 (12) 0.393 (6)
in the UK and New Zealand and to a lesser
Switzerland 0.209 (14) 0.194 (13) degree in the US (Table 7.3). It is also
Mean C. Europe 0.448 (8.6) 0.384 (7.4) evident that levels of bargaining coverage are
Ireland 0.365 (10) 0.759 (1) diverging, not converging, across the varieties
UK 0.370 (9) 0.141 (14) of capitalism. Over the past 20 years, coverage
Mean LMEs 0.368 (9.5) 0.450 (7.5) has risen slightly in the Scandinavian and
Source: Calmfors et al., 2001: Table 4.2. 0 =Low, 1 =High. Mediterranean economies, remained stable
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 139

Table 7.3 Collective bargaining coverage (%) in 20 OECD


countries 1980–2000
Country 1980 1990 2000 Change
1980–2000
Denmark 70+ 70+ 80+ +10
Finland 90+ 90+ 90+ 0
Norway 70+ 70+ 70+ 0
Sweden 80+ 80+ 90+ +10
Mean N. Europe 78 78 83 +5
France 80+ 90+ 90+ +10
Greece N/a N/a N/a N/a
Italy 80+ 80+ 80+ 0
Portugal 70+ 70+ 80+ +10
Spain 60+ 70+ 80+ +20
Mean MEs 73 78 83 +10
Austria 95+ 95+ 95+ 0
Belgium 90+ 90+ 90+ 0
Germany 80+ 80+ 68 −12
Netherlands 70+ 70+ 80+ +10
Switzerland 50+ 50+ 40+ −10
Mean C. Europe 77 77 75 −2
Australia 80+ 80+ 80+ 0
Canada 37 38 32 −5
Ireland N/a N/a N/a N/a
New Zealand 60+ 60+ 25+ −35
UK 70+ 40+ 30+ −40
USA 26 18 14 −12
Mean LMEs 55 47 36 −19
Source: OECD 2004a, Table 3.3.

in the central European CMEs but declined a combination of union density and bargaining
sharply in the LMEs. structure (not bargaining coverage) appears
We turn now to the degree of protection for to best predict earnings inequality (OECD,
employees in the labor market embodied in the 2004a: 160–161). Table 7.5 shows that the
legal regulation of dismissal and redundancy. most distinctive profiles and the clearest
As Table 7.4 shows two groups of countries trends are to be found in the Scandinavian
stand out: the Mediterranean economies still countries and in the LMEs while develop-
provide a relatively high degree of protection ments in the CMEs and the Mediterranean
for employees while the LMEs, on the other economies are less clear. In the Scandinavian
hand, provide far fewer rights. Looking at countries pay inequality was relatively low in
trends we find a degree of convergence, the early 1980s and has more or less remained
with some relaxation of legislation in the stable through the late 1990s. In the LMEs,
Mediterranean economies and a mild increase by contrast, pay inequality was already high
in the level of employment protection in in the early 1980s and has increased still
the LMEs. further in the intervening years. If we return
Another labor market outcome that has been to Table 7.1 it is clear that these inequality
extensively investigated by IR researchers is profiles are strongly associated with trends in
the degree of income inequality both at a point union density. Where density has remained
in time across countries and over time. Hall high – as in Scandinavia – inequality has
and Soskice (2001a) posit that pay inequality remained low; where union density has fallen
would be one of the main areas in which most sharply, as in the LMEs, inequality
varieties of capitalism would show systematic has dramatically increased. As with density
differences. According to recent OECD data, we observe a degree of divergence, not
Table 7.4 Employment protection legislation in 19 OECD countries, late 1980s–2003
Country Late 1980s Late 1990s 2003 Change late
1980s–2003
Denmark 1.5 1.5 1.5 0
Finland 2.8 2.3 2.2 −0.5
Norway 2.3 2.3 2.3 0
Sweden 2.9 2.9 2.9 0
Mean N. Europe 2.4 2.3 2.2 −0.2
France 2.3 2.3 2.5 +0.2
Greece 2.5 2.3 2.4 −0.1
Italy 1.8 1.8 1.8 0
Portugal 4.8 4.3 4.2 −0.6
Spain 3.9 2.6 2.6 −1.3
Mean MEs 3.1 2.7 2.7 −0.4
Austria 2.9 2.9 2.4 −0.5
Belgium 1.7 1.7 1.7 0
Germany 2.6 2.7 2.7 +0.1
Netherlands 3.1 3.1 3.1 0
Switzerland 1.2 1.2 1.2 0
Mean C. Europe 2.3 2.3 2.2 −0.1
Australia 1.0 1.5 1.5 +0.5
Canada 1.3 1.3 1.3 0
Ireland 1.6 1.6 1.6 0
New Zealand N/a 1.4 1.7 +0.3
UK 0.9 0.9 1.1 +0.2
USA 0.2 0.2 0.2 0
Mean LMEs 1.0 1.2 1.2 +0.2
Source: OECD 2004b, Table 2.A2.1. Scale from 0 (Low) to 6 (High).

Table 7.5 Gross earnings inequality (90:10 ratios) for full time employees
in 19 OECD countries 1980–1984 to 1995–1999
Country 1980–1984 1990–1994 1995–1999 Change, 1st
to last period
Denmark 2.17 2.16 N/a −0.1
Finland 2.49 2.39 2.36 −0.13
Norway N/a N/a 1.96 N/a
Sweden 2.01 2.11 2.23 +0.22
Mean N. Europe 2.22 2.22 2.18 −0.04
France 3.18 3.21 3.07 −0.11
Greece N/a N/a N/a N/a
Italy 2.29* 2.35 2.40 +0.11
Portugal 3.56* 3.76 N/a +0.20
Spain N/a N/a N/a N/a
Mean MEs 3.01 3.11 N/a +0.10
Austria 3.45 3.56 N/a +0.11
Belgium 2.40* 2.28 N/a −0.12
Germany 2.88 2.79 2.87 −0.01
Netherlands 2.47 2.60 2.85 +0.38
Switzerland N/a 2.71 2.69 −0.02
Mean C. Europe 2.80 2.79 2.80 0
Australia 2.88 2.82 2.94 +0.06
Canada N/a N/a 3.65 N/a
Ireland N/a 4.06 3.97 −0.09
New Zealand 2.89 3.06 3.28 +0.39
UK 3.09 3.39 3.45 +0.36
USA 3.91 4.39 4.59 +0.68
Mean LMEs 3.19 3.54 3.65 +0.46
*1985–1989
Source: OECD 2004a, Table 3.2.
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 141

Table 7.6 Industrial conflict in selected OECD countries 1985–2003 (days lost per
1000 workers)
Country 1985–1989 1994–1998 1999–2003 Change (%, 1985–1989
to 1999–2003)
Denmark 240 309 43 −82.1
Finland 340 183 49 −85.6
Norway 140 103 63 −55.0
Sweden 120 43 38 −68.3
Median N. Europe 190 143 46 −75.2
France 60 97 N/a N/a
Greece 1480 N/a N/a N/a
Italy 300 113 126 −58.0
Portugal 90 24 17 −81.1
Spain 650 256 203 −68.8
Median MEs 300 61 126 −68.8
Austria 0 1 81 N/a
Belgium N/a 29 N/a N/a
Germany 0 4 4 N/a
Netherlands 10 26 11 N/a
Switzerland 0 3 3 N/a
Median C. Europe 0 4 8 N/a
Australia 230 87 57 −75.2
Canada 280 209 163 −41.8
Ireland 290 73 70 −75.9
New Zealand 500 30 19 −96.2
UK 180 22 24 −86.7
USA 90 43 45 −50.0
Median LMEs 255 58 51 −75.6
Sources: Bird 1991, Table 1; Monger 2005, Table 1.

convergence, among the advanced capitalist in days lost through strikes over the past
countries. 20 years.
Does the level of industrial conflict vary Finally we examine levels and trends in
across the varieties of capitalism (Amable, unemployment, one of the most widely-
2003; Hall and Soskice, 2001a: 24–25)? used indicators of labor market functioning
Table 7.6 suggests that the picture is again (Table 7.7). The data indicate that the Mediter-
complex. Measured by days lost per 1000 ranean economies have operated at relatively
workers in recent years (1999–2003), the level high rates of unemployment for many years,
of industrial conflict in 6 LMEs – 51 days while the Scandinavian economies have
lost per 1000 workers – was only a little generally displayed the lowest levels of unem-
higher than in 11 non-LMEs (43 days lost per ployment (Portugal and Finland excepted in
1000). However, if the non-LME countries are each category). In general, unemployment
divided into three groups a different pattern was lower in most countries in recent years
emerges. The central European CMEs are (1999–2003) compared to the early 1990s.
less conflict-prone than the LMEs but the
highest levels of conflict are found in several
Interpreting the evidence
Scandinavian (Denmark and Finland) and
Mediterranean economies (Spain and Italy) as What does this evidence suggest about the
well as in the LMEs. Looking at changes over utility of the VoC approach as a way
time it is clear that while strike activity has of understanding cross-national variations
generally declined in most countries, trends in in industrial relations? For some indica-
the central European economies have moved tors the distinction between LMEs and
in the opposite direction, with a modest rise ‘other’ types of capitalism does make sense.
142 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 7.7 Standardized unemployment economies. Which indicators are most impor-
rates (%) in selected OECD countries tant in assigning countries to categories?
1985–2003 Third, the data point to convergence
Country 1985– 1994– 1999– on some dimensions of industrial relations
1989 1998 2003
but divergence on others. In four areas
Denmark 6.3 6.2 4.8 the evidence clearly indicates convergence
Finland 5.0 14.1 9.4
Norway 3.0 4.7 3.7
in recent years: bargaining structures have
Sweden 2.2 9.2 5.5 become more decentralized almost every-
Mean N. Europe 4.1 8.6 5.9 where; employment protection laws have
France 10.0 11.7 9.3 been relaxed in the strictest regimes but
Greece N/a 9.7 10.8 tightened in the weakest regimes, producing
Italy 9.3 11.5 9.8
Portugal 7.3 6.6 4.8
convergence toward a moderate level of
Spain 20.0 17.8 11.5 protection; strike rates have fallen in most,
Median MEs 11.7 11.4 9.3 though not all, countries; and the dispersion
Austria N/a 4.2 4.0 in unemployment rates is now far lower than
Belgium 9.4 9.5 7.5 in the 1980s or 1990s. On the other hand
Germany 6.4 8.7 8.4
Netherlands 7.8 5.6 3.0
union density rates, bargaining coverage, and
Switzerland N/a 3.8 3.1 earnings inequality have all diverged and
Median C. Europe 7.9 6.4 5.2 the gaps between the different varieties of
Australia 7.4 8.4 6.5 capitalism have increased. But given that
Canada 8.9 9.4 7.4 capitalist economies change over time, how
Ireland 16.2 11.1 4.6
New Zealand 5.0 6.9 5.6
can we judge whether the changes produce
UK 9.9 7.8 5.3 more coherent and cohesive categories or blur
USA 5.8 5.3 4.9 the distinctions between categories? Again,
Mean LMEs 8.9 8.2 5.7 the answer will most likely depend on the
Sources: OECD 2004a Statistical Annex Table A; OECD indicators that are chosen as most significant.
2001 Statistical Annex Table 22. Thus, the convergence-divergence debate is
unlikely to be resolved by empirical evidence
alone.
Fourth, how are we to account for sig-
Bargaining coverage shows a clear divide nificant changes over time? In line with
between LMEs and non-LME countries some of the evidence on divergence, Thelen
whereas industrial conflict shows an equally (2001) argues that the changes in indus-
clear divide between the central European trial relations that can be observed across
CMEs and the rest. Beyond these comparisons advanced economies are different in LMEs
the binary divide is of little value because the compared to CMEs. In LMEs, the logic of
advanced capitalist countries more commonly production and competition means that firms
fall into four groups rather than two. In are interested in weakening ‘overarching
addition to the LMEs and central European institutions for the collective representation of
economies, the Mediterranean economies and labor’ since plant-level bargaining flexibility
the Scandinavian economies show distinct without strong sectoral or national unions
patterns of unionism and industrial relations and bargaining structures better meshes with
structures and outcomes. internal labor markets (Thelen, 2001: 72).
Second, the data raise questions about the Firms in CMEs, on the other hand, continue
logic of using specific indicators as a basis for to rely on highly skilled workers for ‘their
classification. This includes concerns about competitive strategies around high-quality,
between-group and within-group variation. high value-added production that depends on
For instance, profound differences are visible a high degree of stability and cooperation
between Ireland and the UK, although both with labor’ (Thelen, 2001: 73). Therefore,
are commonly classed as liberal market employers, much like workers, are supportive
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 143

of collective representation of labor above the from ongoing contestation among a number
firm level (Thelen, 2001: 73). While deregu- of actors with competing interests (Hall
lation is an appropriate term to describe the and Thelen, 2005). In other cases, how-
developments in IR in LMEs and reflects the ever, it may result from government action.
low coordination capacity among employers, Governments have the power not just to
CMEs are much more aptly described by a pass economic policies that may indirectly
process of ‘controlled decentralization’ or ‘re- result in institutional change, but can more
regulation’, where coordination continues, directly modify the institutional makeup of
albeit often at lower levels, and matches the economy, as well as the structure and
non-market coordination among employers outcomes of industrial relations, such as
(Thelen, 2001: 78–80). wage inequality. One additional variable to
The most dramatic declines in union density account for variation in such outcomes is party
and bargaining coverage have occurred in composition of the government. Rueda and
LMEs, which might reflect the increased Pontusson (2000: 380), for example, find that
role of market regulation and the power whether the government is dominated by the
of employers. But bargaining coverage has left or the right matters for wage inequality,
not declined in all of the LMEs and union particularly in LMEs. This is because in CMEs
membership decline varies considerably. (roughly equivalent to SMEs in Rueda and
In addition most LMEs have been operating Pontusson, 2000) wage bargaining is more
at historically low levels of unemployment, widely institutionalized and less dominated by
which ought to have facilitated some recovery governmental policies such as minimum wage
of union membership, but generally this has legislation than in LMEs. In other words,
not happened. due to the scope of collective bargaining,
governments in CMEs have less opportunity
to influence wages directly, and consequently,
partisanship matters less. Where bargaining
DIRECTIONS FOR FURTHER is less encompassing, as in LMEs, on the
RESEARCH: A DYNAMIC PERSPECTIVE other hand, parties in government have more
ON POLITICS, VoC, AND INDUSTRIAL of an influence on legislating wages, which
RELATIONS makes partisanship more meaningful. Iversen
and Cusack (2000: 346), in contrast, find that
Overall, the VoC literature has been criticized governments have expanded welfare states
for taking on a relatively static view of through transfer payments and social services
economic institutions, and for being poorly provision regardless of party ideology, but
equipped to account for change (Streeck and ‘partisanship continues to be important in
Thelen, 2005: 5; and see above). It has the redistributive aspect of the welfare
also been criticized for downplaying the role state’. Together with labor market institutions,
of politics and political actors. These two partisanship of the government helps explain
issues, however, are linked because a focus on the responses of governments to the pressures
political parties and the state makes it possible of deindustrialization (Iversen and Cusack,
to account better for significant change in 2000: 316).
industrial relations systems. To explain welfare expenditures, Swank
The VoC approach centers on institu- (2002) finds that it is not just economic
tional equilibria of interconnected institutions institutions and actors that determine how
and does not systematically incorporate an capitalist states respond to globalization, but
account of change. This does not mean, how- also political institutions and processes. He
ever, that the framework could not encompass distinguishes between Nordic social democ-
mechanisms of institutional change. For racies, corporatist conservative welfare states,
example, institutional change may be the and liberal welfare states, similar to the mod-
outcome of incremental change resulting els established by Esping-Andersen (1990).
144 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Swank (2002: 5) contends that welfare state spheres of corporate governance and inter-
retrenchment can be expected to be most firm relations (Howell, 2005; Kelly, 2006).
pronounced in the small liberal welfare states Only when Margaret Thatcher, elected as
since their ‘political institutions and pro- Prime Minister in 1979, legislated a series
grammatic structures’ facilitate retrenchment of sweeping reforms in the political economy
policies, while those of the larger West did Britain metamorphose into a paradigmatic
European welfare states are more likely to example of an LME. These reforms were
blunt pressures for retrenchment produced not the result of some inherent movement
by global capital flows (see also Iversen, of economic institutions into a system where
2005). the parts fit together more coherently than
A focus on partisanship and party com- before, or some internal movement toward
position of governments can also provide an equilibrium state. Instead, they were the
important insights into the question of how result of governmental action and legislation
change in economic institutions and types of (see Walsh and Crawford, 2003 for details
capitalism comes about, or why institutions of the equally far-reaching legislative assault
are stable (cf also Golden et al., 1999: on unions in New Zealand; and see Hamann,
223; Huber and Stephens, 2001a). This is 2005 for an explanation of institutional
not to deny that economic actors sometimes stability in Spain focused on politics).
have vested interests in modifying existing Ireland presents an interesting contrasting
institutions, or that much change results case, where an economy that is generally
from the actions of economic actors. Rather, described as a classic LME has adopted
we want to point to the linkages between some coordination strategies rather typical of
economic and political actors and institutional CMEs. The 1987 Programme for National
change (or stability) that are sometimes Recovery (PNR) was the first in a series
neglected in the IR literature. For instance, of social pacts that would not have been
union membership decline in the LMEs was expected in a liberal market economy. It was
not simply the result of changing labor and the government that pushed for a social
product markets because these changes were pact in response to economic problems
themselves influenced by governments’ eco- and electoral pressures (Hamann and Kelly,
nomic and labor relations policies paralleling 2007). While the overall organization of the
Huber and Stephens’ observations on the Irish economy might still, by and large,
importance of party leanings for welfare reflect LME characteristics, wage restraint
state policies. Golden et al. (1999: 223), for is now coordinated centrally by political
instance, suspect that ‘government policy and and economic actors, which questions the
politics played at least as important a role classification of Ireland as an ideal-type LME.
as the market in promoting such catastrophic The Irish case again demonstrates that shifts
collapse’ of union membership in the UK and in economic institutions can be initiated by
the US (cf also King and Wood, 1999). governments, and that the electoral interests
Prior to the 1980s, the political-economic of governing parties can play an active role in
institutions and processes present in the UK changing economic institutions.
can be loosely described as a ‘mixed form’ Austria is another striking illustration of the
in Hall and Soskice’s (2001a) ideal-type con- importance of government partisanship and
figuration of LMEs and CMEs. This ‘hybrid’ interests in modifying economic institutions
constellation combined CME characteristics (see Hamann and Kelly, 2007). Austria has
of industry-wide bargaining and coverage been one of the most corporatist coun-
rates of around 70 per cent; training was tries in Western Europe in the post-war
similarly coordinated at the industry level; period, and the social partners were heavily
and internal labor markets within many large involved and integrated in political economy
firms helped retain employees. These features institutions and decision-making until the
were coupled with LME characteristics in the populist-right Freedom Party (FPÖ) joined
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 145

the conservative People’s Party (ÖVP) in a to move beyond what is becoming a rather
coalition government in 2000. Soon after, sterile debate.
the government for the first time passed For future research we propose to focus
policies unilaterally that previously would on the role of the state and political parties
have been negotiated through the corporatist in order to understand the reproduction and
structures, such as a major pension reform, transformation of IR systems. Despite existing
sparking an unprecedented wave of strikes and claims that globalization will reduce and
mobilizations. In addition, the government heavily constrain the role of national political
attacked some of the institutional foundations actors, a growing body of evidence indicates
of corporatism in an attempt to diminish the that such actors retain considerable power
power of the unions (and also employers) and must therefore comprise a key part of
in the policy-making process. Again, govern- the explanation for both the persistence and
mental ideology and policy was instrumental change in IR systems.
in altering the institutions and processes of
Austria’s political economy.
NOTES

CONCLUSION 1 We concentrate here on criticisms of the VoC


approach that are closely linked to industrial relations.
Many other criticisms have been leveled against the
The VoC literature continues to generate approach, and in particular against Hall and Soskice
both debate and criticism. In our view, it (2001b) and work based on that volume; see, for
facilitates a rigorous and systematic com- example, Allen (2004); Blyth (2003); Coates (2005);
parative study of both national capitalisms Goodin (2003); Höpner (2005); and Watson (2003).
and national systems of industrial relations. 2 The Visser scale incorporates union density and
so hence the very low score for France despite the high
It does so by grounding comparative analysis degree of centralized bargaining. Siaroff (1999) uses
in a theoretical framework, although Hall an even wider array of measures including strike days
and Soskice’s version privileges the firm lost, union policy and economic performance. But the
at the expense of other actors. The VoC sheer breadth and inclusiveness of his corporatism
literature is also valuable for IR researchers measure makes it very difficult to correlate it with
other variables.
because of its insistence on looking at the
interconnections between institutions, such as
welfare systems, wage bargaining systems,
REFERENCES
and skill levels.
Even though the evidence reinforces the
Albert, Michel (1993) Capitalism Against Capitalism.
value of grouping national IR systems into London: Whurr Publishers.
clusters, it calls into question the utility of the Allen, Matthew (2004) ‘The varieties of capitalism
widely-used CME vs. LME dichotomy. The paradigm: not enough variety?’, Socio-Economic
empirical data indicate that it is meaningful Review, 2 (1): 87–108.
to distinguish the Northern, Central and Amable, Bruno (2003) The Diversity of Modern
Southern European economies in addition to Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
the LMEs. Are these different types of IR Armstrong, Philip, Glyn, Andrew and Harrison, John
systems converging or diverging? Industrial (1991) Capitalism Since 1945. Oxford: Blackwell.
relations are actually more complex and Bélanger, Jacques, Edwards, P.K. and Haiven, Larry (eds)
(1994) Workplace Industrial Relations and the Global
cannot be reduced to a simple trend in one
Challenge. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
direction or the other. On some dimensions,
Bird, Derek (1991) ‘International comparisons of
IR systems appear to be converging while industrial disputes in 1989 and 1990’, Employment
on others, they are diverging. Consequently, Gazette, 99 (12): 653–58.
we need to start asking more precise and Blyth, Mark (2003) ‘Same as it never was: Tempo-
better theorized questions about IR, linked to rality and typology in the varieties of capitalism’,
other spheres of national political economies, Comparative European Politics, 1 (2): 215–25.
146 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Boyer, Robert (2005) ‘How and why capitalisms differ’, Goodin, Robert E. (2003) ‘Choose your capitalism?’,
Economy and Society, 34 (4): 509–57. Comparative European Politics, 1 (2): 202–13.
Calmfors, Lars, Booth, Alison, Burda, Michael, Checchi, Gospel, Howard and Pendleton, Andrew (2003)
Daniele, Naylor, Robin and Visser, Jelle (2001) ‘The ‘Finance, corporate governance and the management
future of collective bargaining in Europe’, in Tito Boeri, of labour: A conceptual and comparative analysis’,
Agar Brugiavini and Lars Calmfors (eds), The Role of British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41 (3): 557–82.
Unions in the Twenty-First Century. Oxford: Oxford Hall, Peter and Soskice, David (2001a) ‘An introduction
University Press. pp. 1–155. to varieties of capitalism’, in Peter Hall and David
Coates, David (2000) Models of Capitalism: Growth Soskice (eds), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional
and Stagnation in the Modern Era. Cambridge: Polity Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford:
Press. Oxford University Press. pp. 1–68.
Coates, David (ed.) (2005) Varieties of Capitalism, Hall, Peter and Soskice, David (eds) (2001b) Varieties
Varieties of Approaches. Houndmills: Palgrave of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of
Macmillan. Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University
Crouch, Colin (1993) Industrial Relations and European Press.
State Traditions. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Hall, Peter and Thelen, Kathleen (2005) ‘Institutional
Crouch, Colin (2005) Capitalist Diversity and change in varieties of capitalism’, paper presented at
Change: Recombinant Governance and Institutional the American Political Science Association Meeting,
Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Washington, D.C., September.
Dore, Ronald, Lazonick, William and O’Sullivan, Mary Hamann, Kerstin (2005) ‘Third-Way Conservatism?
(1999) ‘Varieties of capitalism in the twentieth The Popular Party and labour relations in Spain’,
century’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15 (4): International Journal of Iberian Studies, 18 (2):
102–20. 67–82.
Ebbinghaus, Bernhard and Philip Manow (2001) ‘Intro- Hamann, Kerstin and Kelly, John (2007) ‘Party politics
duction: studying varieties of welfare capitalism’, and the re-emergence of social pacts in Western
in Bernhard Ebbinghaus and Philip Manow (eds), Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 40 (8):
Comparing Welfare Capitalism. London: Routledge. 971–94.
pp. 1–24. Heery, Edmund and Adler, Lee (2004) ‘Organizing
Ebbinghaus, Bernhard and Visser, Jelle (2000) Trade the unorganized’, in Carola Frege and John Kelly
Unions in Western Europe Since 1945. London: (eds), Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Union
Macmillan Reference. Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy. Oxford:
Esping-Andersen, Gøsta (1990) The Three Worlds of Oxford University Press. pp. 45–69.
Welfare Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Hicks, Alexander and Kenworthy, Lane (2003) ‘Varieties
Press. of welfare capitalism’, Socio-Economic Review, 1 (1):
Estevez-Abe, Margarita, Iversen, Torben and Soskice, 27–61.
David (2001) ‘Social protection and the formation Höpner, Martin (2005) ‘What connects industrial
of skills: a re-interpretation of the welfare state’, relations and corporate governance? Explaining insti-
in Peter Hall and David Soskice (eds), Varieties tutional complementarity’, Socio-Economic Review,
of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of 3 (2): 331–58.
Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Howell, Chris (2003) ‘Review article: varieties of
Press. pp. 145–83. capitalism: and then there was one?’, Comparative
Golden, Miriam, Wallerstein, Michael and Lange, Politics, 36 (1): 103–24.
Peter (1999) ‘Postwar trade-union organization Howell, Chris (2005) Trade Unions and the State: The
and industrial relations in twelve countries’, in Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in
Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks and Britain, 1890–2000. Princeton: Princeton University
John D. Stephens (eds), Continuity and Change Press.
in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Cambridge Huber, Evelyne and Stephens, John D. (2001a)
University Press. pp. 194–230. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State. Chicago:
Goldthorpe, John H. (1984) ‘The end of convergence: University of Chicago Press.
corporatist and dualist tendencies in modern Western Huber, Evelyne and Stephens, John D. (2001b)
societies’, in John H. Goldthorpe (ed.), Order and ‘Welfare state and production regimes in the era of
Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism: Studies in the retrenchment’, in Paul Pierson (ed.), The New Politics
Political Economy of Western European Nations. of the Welfare State. New York: Oxford University
Oxford: Clarendon Press. pp. 315–43. Press. pp. 107–45.
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 147

Hyman, Richard (2001) Understanding European Trade OECD (2004b) ‘Employment protection regulation and
Unionism. London: Sage. labour market performance’, in OECD Employment
Hyman, Richard (2004) ‘Varieties of capitalism, Outlook 2004. Paris: OECD. pp. 61–125.
national industrial relations systems and transna- Oliver, Nick and Wilkinson, Barry (1992) The Japanisa-
tional challenges’, in Anne-Wit Harzing and Joris tion of British Industry, 2nd edition. Oxford: Blackwell.
van Ruysseveldt (eds), International Human Resource Perraton, Jonathan and Clift, Ben (2004) ‘So where are
Management: Managing People Across Borders. national capitalisms now?’, in Jonathan Perraton and
London: Sage. pp. 411–32. Ben Clift (eds), Where Are National Capitalisms Now?
Iversen, Torben (2005) Capitalism, Democracy, and London: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 195–261.
Welfare. New York: Cambridge University Press. Piore, Michael F. and Sabel, Charles F. (1984) The
Iversen, Torben and Cusack, Thomas R. (2000) ‘The Second Industrial Divide. New York: Basic Books.
causes of welfare state expansion: deindustrializa- Pizzorno, Alessandro (1978) ‘Political exchange and col-
tion or globalization?’, World Politics, 52 (April): lective identity in industrial conflict’, in Colin Crouch
313–49. and Alessandro Pizzorno (eds), The Resurgence of
Kelly, John (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Class Conflict in Western Europe Vol 1. London:
Mobilization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London: Macmillan. pp. 277–98.
Routledge. Pontusson, Jonas (2005) ‘“Varieties and commonali-
Kelly, John (2006) ‘Bringing the state back in’, Labor ties” of capitalism’, in David Coates (ed.), Varieties
History, 47 (2): 252–58. of Capitalism, Varieties of Approaches. London:
Kerr, Clark, Dunlop, John T., Harbison, Frederick and Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 163–88.
Myers, Charles A. (1960) Industrialism and Industrial Regini, Marino (1984) ‘The conditions for political
Man, 2nd edition 1973. Harmondsworth: Penguin. exchange: How concertation emerged and collapsed
King, Desmond and Wood, Stewart (1999) ‘The political in Italy and Great Britain’, in John H. Goldthorpe
economy of neoliberalism: Britain and the United (ed.), Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism:
States in the 1980s’, in Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Studies in the Political Economy of Western European
Gary Marks and John D. Stephens (eds), Continuity Nations. Oxford: Clarendon Press. pp. 124–42.
and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Rhodes, Martin (2005) ‘“Varieties of capitalism” and the
Cambridge University Press. pp. 371–97. political economy of European welfare states’, New
Kitschelt, Herbert, Lange, Peter, Marks, Gary and Political Economy, 10 (3): 363–70.
Stephens, John D. (1999) ‘Convergence and Rueda, David and Pontusson, Jonas (2000) ‘Wage
divergence in advanced capitalist democracies’, in inequality and varieties of capitalism’, World Politics,
Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks and 52 (April): 350–83.
John D. Stephens (eds), Continuity and Change Schmidt, Vivien (2002) The Futures of European
in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Cambridge Capitalism. New York: Oxford University Press.
University Press. pp. 427–60. Siaroff, Alan (1999) ‘Corporatism in 24 industrial
Kochan, Thomas A., Lansbury, Russell D. and MacDuffie, democracies: meaning and measurement’, European
John Paul (eds) (1997) After Lean Production: Journal of Political Research, 36 (2): 175–205.
Evolving Employment Practices in the World Auto Soskice, David (1999) ‘Divergent production regimes:
Industry. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. coordinated and uncoordinated market economies in
Mares, Isabela (2001) ‘Firms and the welfare state: the 1980s and 1990s’, in Herbert Kitschelt, Peter
when, why, and how does social policy matter to Lange, Gary Marks and John D. Stephens (eds),
employers?’, in Peter Hall and David Soskice (eds), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism.
Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations New York: Cambridge University Press. pp. 101–34.
of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen (2005) ‘Intro-
Press. pp. 184–212. duction: institutional change in advanced political
Monger, Joanne (2005) ‘International comparisons of economies’, in Wolfgang Streeck and Kathleen
labour disputes in 2003’, Labour Market Trends, 113 Thelen (eds), Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change
(4): 159–204. in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford: Oxford
OECD (2001) OECD Employment Outlook 2001. University Press. pp. 1–39.
Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Swank, Duane (2002) Global Capital, Political Institu-
Development. tions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States.
OECD (2004a) ‘Wage-setting institutions and economic Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
performance’, in OECD Employment Outlook 2004. Swenson, Peter (2002) Capitalists Against Markets: The
Paris: OECD. pp. 127–81. Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in
148 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

the United States and Sweden. New York: Oxford in Peter Fairbrother and Charlotte A. B. Yates (eds),
University Press. Trade Unions in Renewal: A Comparative Study.
Thelen, Kathleen (2001) ‘Varieties of labor politics London: Continuum. pp. 117–34.
in the developed democracies’, in Peter Hall and Watson, Matthew (2003) ‘Ricardian political econ-
David Soskice (eds), Varieties of Capitalism: The omy and the “varieties of capitalism” approach’,
Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Comparative European Politics, 1 (2): 227–40.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 71–103. Weiss, Linda (2003) ‘Introduction: bringing domestic
Turnbull, Peter, Blyton, Paul and Harvey, Geraint institutions back in’ in Linda Weiss (ed.), States in
(2004) ‘Cleared for take-off? Management-labour the Global Economy: Bringing Domestic Institutions
partnership in the European civil aviation industry’, Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
European Journal of Industrial Relations, 10 (3): pp. 1–33.
287–307. Western, Bruce (1997) Between Class and Market:
Visser, Jelle (1992) ‘The strength of labour movements Postwar Unionization in the Capitalist Democracies.
in advanced capitalist democracies: Social and Princeton: Princeton University Press.
organizational variations’, in Marino Regini (ed.), Whitley, Richard (1999) Divergent Capitalisms: The
The Future of Labour Movements. London: Sage. Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems.
pp. 17–52. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Walsh, Pat and Crawford, Aaron (2003) ‘From Womack, James P., Jones, Daniel T. and Roos, Daniel
organizational breadth to depth? New Zealand’s (1990) The Machine That Changed the World.
trade unions under the Employment Contracts Act’, New York: Rawson Associates.
8
New Forms of Work and the
High Performance Paradigm
Stephen Procter

INTRODUCTION investigated are likely to involve the


following:
We can date the emergence of the high
performance model to a series of studies • an extension of employee involvement or
published in the US in the mid-1990s participation in decision-making, often in the
(Appelbaum and Batt, 1994; Delery and form of the establishment of semi-autonomous
Doty, 1996; Huselid, 1995; Ichniowski et al., teams;
1997; MacDuffie, 1995; Osterman, 1994; • a division of labour such that employees are
required to perform a range or a wider range of
Pfeffer, 1994). Their basic concern was to see
tasks.
whether new ways of organizing work and
managing people were having an effect on
A full account of the high performance
the performance of organizations. For some,
model would also take into considera-
this represents a new research paradigm, in
tion the following broader organizational
which more traditional institutional concerns
aspects:
are played down or neglected completely
(Godard and Delaney, 2000). Others see it
• a conception of organizational performance that
as a more natural reflection of the shift in
does not consist of nor largely rely upon the
the balance of power in the employment minimisation or reduction of the costs associated
relationship in favor of management and with employees;
employers. • a recognition – or, at least, the hope or intention –
Although reaching a precise definition that the management of work and people has
would be difficult and probably counter- a direct and significant effect on organizational
productive, the new forms of work being performance;
150 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

• an acknowledgment that issues of work orga- et al., 2000). In the mid-1990s, however,
nization cannot be separated from considera- when these ideas were coming to prominence,
tions more usually associated with production a wide range of expressions was in use.
management. Osterman (1994), for example, both refers
to and makes use of the ‘variety of labels’
To examine the idea of ‘high performance’ (173), with ‘flexible work practices’ perhaps
this chapter divides into five main parts. being the most common expression in his own
Following this brief introductory section, paper. Ichniowski et al. (1996), on the other
the second part looks at what we mean hand, are among those who use ‘workplace
by ‘high performance’, examining issues of innovations’ or ‘innovative work practices’.
terminology and definition and attempting to The situation is made more complicated by
put the idea in its broader context. The third the tendency of European-based academics to
part looks at the ‘high performance model’ avoid the term ‘high performance’ altogether,
itself, highlighting the major works in this and instead see things in terms of Human
area and showing how they stand in relation Resource Management (HRM) and its link
to each other. The fourth section looks at a with performance (see, for example, Guest,
series of issues raised by the model. This 1997; Paauwe, 2004).
covers the overall conclusion to be drawn Some of the explanation for, and impli-
from the volume of research, the diffusion cations of, these differences in terminology
and importance of the model, the role played will emerge at various points in this chapter.
by the institutional context, the implications of Despite the differences, there is enough
the model for employees and, finally, some of commonality in the substance of what is being
the more basic theoretical and methodological considered to let us examine all of these things
issues it faces. under the same heading. In the course of the
The fifth part brings all these considerations present chapter we shall rely largely on the
together and offers some judgment on the different terms used by the different authors;
model and its implications. Our argument here where an over-arching term is required for
is that an understanding of many of the issues the sake of clarity of exposition, we shall
identified in the fourth section would benefit use the terms ‘high performance model’ or
from contributions made from an industrial ‘high performance management’ or, as a more
relations (IR) perspective. Rather than dis- general expression, ‘HR management’.
missing the high performance model and
taking some delight in the difficulties in which
it finds itself, the current situation offers those High performance management
working in an industrial relations tradition This is not to say, of course, that these and
the opportunity to shape the development of other expressions are simply different ways
research and practice in this area. of describing exactly the same thing. This
becomes clear if we move from terminology
to definition. A key issue here is whether we
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE MODEL: are talking about high performance practices
or high performance systems. If the former,
DEFINITION AND CONTEXT
then this suggests that a number of different
practices can be identified as such, and that
Terminology
each will have an independent effect on
A first set of problems facing anyone performance. For those who emphasise the
approaching these issues for the first time idea of systems, however, it is the combined
are those of terminology and definition. A lot effect of a particular set of practices that is
of the work in this area has coalesced important. The problem then is to identify
around the term ‘high performance work sys- the component parts of such a system and,
tem’ (HPWS) (see, for example Appelbaum on top of that, to establish whether there is a
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 151

single high performance system or a number of a high performance model, a definition of


of systems, each appropriate to a different HRM is unlikely to include them. How far
situation. We will approach these issues more a high performance model might extend into
systematically in the third section of this more recognisably HRM territory – to include,
chapter. say, training and appraisal – would then seem
Whether they are better seen as individual to be something that could be looked at
practices or system components, there is still only on a case-by-case basis. The danger of
the question of what should be included taking this too far is that ‘high performance’
under the ‘high performance’ heading. The becomes conflated with traditional ‘good’
issue is perhaps best illustrated by Becker HRM practice (Godard and Delaney, 2000)
and Gerhart’s (1996: 785) review of just and thus loses any distinctiveness it might
5 papers in this area. There were a total of 27 have. One way out of this is for the high
‘high performance work practices’ considered performance model to focus on issues of
across the 5 papers. Of these 27, none was work organization and for HRM policies to be
common to all the studies; just 2 were common treated as important or essential supports. This
to as many as 4 papers; and 20 of the practices is the approach taken by Osterman (1994),
were included in just 1 of the 5 papers. for example, but it is certainly far from
As we noted in the introduction, central universally applied.
to the idea of high performance work Similar issues arise when we look at
is the extension of employee autonomy, the relationship between high performance
often in the form of semi-autonomous team work practices or systems and production
working. Osterman’s (1994) influential study management policies such as lean pro-
was based on four work organization prac- duction and Total Quality Management.
tices: self-directed work teams, job rotation, Wood’s (1999) review of the ‘HRM and
problem-solving groups and Total Quality performance’ literature is perhaps the most
Management. Although not able to discern direct attempt to address this question. He
patterns in the distribution of these practices, introduces the notions of high commitment
he was able to identify the first of them as management (HCM), which, following the
an ‘anchoring practice’ (1994: 177), in that work of Walton (1985), works exclusively
more than 70 per cent of establishments with through commitment; and high involvement
at least 1 of the 4 practices had self-directed management (HIM), a less restrictive version
teams. For Appelbaum et al. (2000: 102), of HCM where high commitment policies
‘[the] opportunity to participate in substantive are augmented by those aimed at skill acqui-
decisions is an essential element of an HPWS’. sition and knowledge. High performance
Just as for Osterman, this had four main management (HPM) can then simply mean
parts: worker autonomy, communication, self- either HCM/HIM or the combination of
directed work teams and problem-solving HIM and production management policies
groups. Again, it was the team working such as TQM or lean production. We shall
element provided by the latter two of these return to this relationship when we look at
that was central, providing the conditions in ‘universal super-bundles’ in the third part of
which the former two could be made to work this chapter.
most effectively.
There is then the issue of where high
Performance
performance management stands in relation
to HRM. What makes things difficult here, The picture is no more straightforward when
of course, is that HRM itself has no settled we turn to the other side of the equation. Here
definition. In broad terms, however, we we ask the question: on the basis of what idea
can agree with Boxall and Purcell (2003) of performance should the effectiveness of the
and say that while considerations of work high performance model be judged? At first
organization would be central to a definition sight there seems to be a number of advantages
152 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in using financial measures. At least for see the goals of the firm as, first, survival
large, private sector organizations they are and, then, sustained competitive advantage,
easily obtainable and directly comparable they argue that there are, in addition, the
across organizations. Ichniowski et al. (1996) objectives of organizational flexibility and
argue that financial performance is important social legitimacy.
because this is what organizations themselves
are focused on. On the other hand, financial
Historical context
measures might be thought of as quite remote
from high performance management when Although itself dating only from the mid-
such practices might be applied only to those 1990s, the high performance model needs
employees directly involved in production to be considered in the context of other
(Ichniowski et al., 1996). attempts to understand the restructuring of
Some of the difficulties become apparent work and employment relations. Two sets
when we look at specific financial measures. of debates are particularly important here:
Profit is perhaps the most obvious but its use in the ‘what do unions do?’ debate of the
this context is far from straightforward. Quite 1980s and 1990s; and the more prolonged
apart from the issue of its availability, using debates around the concept of flexibility. The
current levels of profit might underestimate high performance model is closely related
the performance of those organizations that to the first of these. Based on Freeman
are in pursuit of more long-term, growth- and Medoff’s (1984) examination of the
oriented objectives (Becker and Gerhart, nature and effects of trade unionism in the
1996). Perhaps the most important objection, US, the possibility was advanced that union
however, is that the level of profit might power would enhance rather than detract from
be a measure not so much of organizational economic performance. Rather than appear-
success as of the ability of management ing simply as a residual, the link between
to prevail in a distributional struggle with union strength and economic performance
employees. became the subject of a more explicit and
A number of studies use measures that systematic analysis. Despite Freeman and
are more closely related to the changes Medoff’s (1984) findings in the US, empirical
being applied, and these are often of an work in the UK failed to provide support
industry-specific nature. In Appelbaum et al.’s for this hypothesis (Fernie and Metcalf,
(2000) three-industry study in the US, for 1995).
example, each industry emphasized a different The emergence of the high performance
performance measure: ‘uptime’ of capital in model in the mid-1990s needs to be seen in this
the steel industry, for example, and throughput context, since both it and the work inspired by
time in apparel. This in some ways provides Freeman and Medoff are centrally concerned
a truer test of effectiveness, since these with the relationship between employment
are the kind of measures that the managers relations and economic performance. In both,
themselves are directing their efforts toward. we see an emphasis on the employment
The disadvantage is that it makes it difficult to relations side of the equation. The change
compare results and to make generalizations. that occurs is that what happens on this side
These difficulties are compounded if we of the equation is seen as being determined
allow for organizations with multiple goals. by management rather than labor. At the
Paauwe (2004) calls for a multi-dimensional same time, we see a shift away from concern
approach to performance, arguing that it for national-level measures of productivity
should be concerned not just with economic or and what they might imply for government
strategic rationality but should also take into policy, and their replacement by a concern
account wider societal demands such as fair- for profit and what this implies for corporate-
ness and legitimacy. Boxall and Purcell (2003) level strategies. As we shall see, the high
argue along similar lines. Although they performance model in fact makes very
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 153

little reference to the ‘what do unions do?’ skeptical or actively hostile (Vallas, 1999;
debate. Williams et al., 1987). Although flexible
A whole range of other attempts to specialization is portrayed as the revival of
understand workplace and organizational craft production, Piore and Sabel did not
restructuring have centered on the concept explore in any real depth its implications for
of flexibility (see Kalleberg, 2001; Vallas, the nature of work. The assumption was that
1999). In some cases, the idea of flexibility the use of more flexible capital equipment
is operationalized in a quite specific way. would be associated with the development of a
In the UK context, for example, debate in highly flexible, multi-skilled workforce. As a
the 1980s and early 1990s centered on the way of understanding what was happening to
notion of the ‘flexible firm’, which claimed management and work inside organizations,
that employers were achieving flexibility it provided little more than unsubstantiated
by dividing their labor force into core and generalizations.
peripheral groups and managing each group
in a different way (Atkinson, 1984). This idea
provoked a long and lively debate (see Pollert, THE HIGH PERFORMANCE MODEL:
1991; Procter et al., 1994) but, despite DIFFERENT APPROACHES
its immediate plausibility, the flexible firm
suffered ultimately from a lack of supporting
Classifying different approaches
empirical evidence (Cully et al., 1999; see
also Cappelli, 1995, for the US). In the UK, Within the broad field we can identify a
at least, it seemed that any restructuring of number of different approaches to the link
employment was taking place on the basis between practice and performance. Two main
of broader corporate strategies with regard to classificatory devices have been developed.
products and customers (Ackroyd and Procter, The first of these is provided by Delery and
1998; Batt, 2000). Doty (1996), whose concern was to show
More ambitious approaches to the concept that the field of Strategic Human Resource
of flexibility were based on the idea that Management (SHRM) was not an ‘atheo-
its pursuit marked an epochal change in the retical wasteland’ (1996: 828). They distin-
development of capitalism (Vallas, 1999). guished between three broad approaches.
This was often characterized as a transition
from Fordism to post-Fordism. This took • The universalistic approach, in which certain
a variety of forms but perhaps the most strategic HR practices can be identified that,
important of these attempts to conceptualize in all circumstances will result in enhanced
and explain the restructuring of work and pro- organizational performance.
duction was Piore and Sabel’s (1984) ‘flexible • The contingency approach, in which HR policies
specialization’ thesis. They argued that the are effective to the extent they are consistent with
other aspects of the organization – in particular,
capitalist world faced a fundamental choice
its competitive or business strategy.
between persisting with an economy based on • The configurational approach, in which the
mass production and returning to one based important thing is not individual HR practices
on craft production in its new guise of flexible but their configuration in particular patterns or
specialization. Under flexible specialization, ‘clusters’. What is required is both the ‘horizontal
production was based on flexible networks of fit’ between the different practices and the
technologically sophisticated manufacturing ‘vertical fit’ between the cluster of practices and
firms. other organizational characteristics.
Partly as a result of its appeal from a
policy point of view, flexible specialization A second classification makes a twofold
did attract a number of adherents (Hirst distinction between ‘best practice’ and ‘best
and Zeitlin, 1989). A substantial part of the fit’ approaches (see e.g. Purcell, 1999).
reaction it generated, however, was either The former equates roughly to Delery and
154 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Doty’s (1996) universalistic approach; while axis we represent the relationship between
the latter stresses the ‘fit’ aspects of their the different practices in their proposed effect
configurational approach, encompassing both on performance. Using the same terminology
the horizontal and the vertical aspects. as MacDuffie (1995) we can distinguish
In fact, neither of these classification between additive and multiplicative effects.
devices is entirely satisfactory. An exami- The former suggests that the effect of each
nation of Delery and Doty’s classification practice is independent of the presence of
reveals that their three approaches cannot be other practices: to arrive at the overall effect
regarded as mutually exclusive. In particu- on performance we simply add them up.
lar, the ‘vertical fit’ in the configurational A multiplicative effect implies that the impact
approach is difficult to distinguish from of each individual practice depends on what
the contingency approach; and there also other practices it is combined with. In the
seems to be no logical reason why an extreme case, the absence of one practice (that
approach cannot be both universalistic and is, it has a value of zero) would mean that
configurational. The best practice/best fit all the other practices would have zero effect.
distinction, on the other hand, makes no This is one way of expressing what Delery and
explicit reference to the idea of configurations Doty (1996) describe as the configurational
or clusters of practices, although in usage this (or cluster or bundle or system) approach;
configurational aspect tends to be associated the additive effect, on the other hand, we can
with best fit, leaving best practice to be describe as non-configurational.
equated with the universalistic approach. On the horizontal axis on Table 8.1 we have
The best practice/best fit debate also what we call the ‘scope of application’. Are
tends to get confused with the issue of any effects (configurational or not) posited to
bundles or systems. The issue here is the apply universally or are they contingent upon
relationship between different practices. As certain conditions?
Ichniowski et al. (1996) point out, different Reconsidering Delery and Doty’s (1996)
pairs of practices might be substitutes or classification in these terms allows us to
complements. If the former (say, self-directed see that the configurational approach can be
work teams and problem-solving groups) then combined with either the universalistic or the
one will have no effect if the other is present, contingent. It also allows us to see some of
and there might even be a negative impact. the limitations of the best practice/best fit
If two practices are complements (say, self- classification. If best practice is equated with
directed work teams and team-based pay), universalism, and best fit with configurational,
then the opposite applies: the effect of one then the two overlap in cell 3 in Table 8.1; if,
depends upon the presence of the other. however, best practice is restricted to cell 1
The difficulties with the classification sys- (that is, universal and additive) and best fit to
tems seem to arise from their attempt to force cell 2 (contingent and configurational), then
what is essentially a two-dimensional picture cell 3 is effectively ignored. Using Table 8.1
into one dimension. These two dimensions to provide the structure, we will now look at
are represented in Table 8.1. On the vertical some of the most notable attempts to examine

Table 8.1 Classification device for studies linking HR practice


and organizational performance
Scope of application
Universal Contingent
Relationships Non-configurational 1 4
between practices (additive)
practices Configurational bundles 3 2
and/or systems (multiplicative)
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 155

the relationship between HR practice and external. Internal or ‘horizontal’ fit refers
organizational performance. to individual practices fitting together into
some kind of coherent system or ‘bundle’:
Universal practices the effect depends on the combination rather
We start in cell 1 of Table 8.1 with the idea than the practices individually. External or
that innovative work and HR practices are ‘vertical’ fit, on the other hand, refers to the fit
universal in application and additive in effect. between the practices and other aspects of the
This kind of approach is often associated with organization. Logically, this is independent
the work of Pfeffer (1994), who provided a list of internal fit (this would be cell 4 in
of 16 HR practices that he saw as common to Table 8.1), but the two are more often
successful US organizations. The list of items considered together: can different bundles of
was subsequently reduced to seven (Pfeffer, practices be identified and can their existence
1998). More rigorous support for the idea of be explained by an external factor?
universally applicable practices was provided Something of the idea of internal fit is
by Huselid (1995), whose study of a large captured by Appelbaum and Batt (1994), who
sample of US corporations across a number identify two high performance work systems
of industries concluded that firms can obtain in the US: American Lean Production, a
substantial financial benefits from investment version of lean production that omits the HRM
in high performance work practices. Having and industrial relations institutions present
constructed an index of high performance in the original Japanese model (Womack
work practices, he estimated that an increase et al., 1990); and American Team Production,
of one standard deviation implied US$ 27,044 which combines self-directed teams on the
more in sales/employee, US$ 18,641 more sociotechnical or Swedish model (Berggren,
in market value and US$ 3,814 more in 1993) with an emphasis on quality engi-
profits. neering. Similarly, Appelbaum et al.’s (2000)
Osterman’s (1994) study was concerned four ‘essential dimensions’ could exist in
with the extent to which ‘flexible work isolation, but, it was argued, ‘combining them
practices’ (work teams, job rotation, quality increases the chance that they will have
circles and Total Quality Management) were an effect’ (p.104). Appelbaum et al. found
being adopted in the US. The performance of evidence for a high performance work system
organizations is implicit rather than explicit having significant impact on ‘uptime’ in the
in this study, but Osterman’s analysis of how steel industry; for ‘team sewing’ to reduce
the practices were combined in individual throughput time and costs in the apparel
establishments led him to the conclusion that industry; and for ‘cell production’ to improve
there were no natural clusters: it was practices plant performance in medical imaging. Their
rather than systems that were important. study is unusual in being conducted across a
In a UK context, West et al. (2002) took small number of industries, but it does suggest
mortality rates as a measure of hospitals’ a certain degree of industry-based specificity
performance. Their survey examined three in the system-performance link.
areas of management: training, team working In looking at the notion of external fit,
and appraisal. An increase of one standard perhaps the greatest attention has been paid
deviation in their measure of appraisal, for to what Wood (1999) calls ‘strategic fit’. The
example, was estimated to result in 1090 basic question here is whether the success
fewer deaths after hip fracture (per 100,000 of a high performance system is contingent
admissions). upon the broader business strategy of an orga-
nization. Schuler and Jackson’s (1987) work
Contingent bundles represents an early and influential attempt to
Turning to cell 2 focuses our attention on look at the link between HRM practices and
the notion of ‘fit’. As already noted, we can competitive strategies. Taking Porter’s (1980,
identify two basic forms of fit: internal and 1985) distinction between three strategies
156 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of innovation, quality enhancement and cost to provide ‘consistent support for the con-
reduction, they looked at the employees’ clusions that groups or clusters of human
necessary ‘role behaviors’ for each and, in resource management practices have large
turn, the implications for HR management effects on productivity, while changes in
in such areas as job design, appraisal and individual work practices have little or no
compensation. Drawing on qualitative US effect on productivity’ (p.291). Looking at
case study data, their conclusion was that one part of the steel production process, they
‘effectiveness can be increased by systemati- identified four different HRM systems. These
cally melding human resource practices with ranged from the most traditional (system 4),
the selected competitive strategy’ (Schuler where work was closely supervised and pay
and Jackson,1987: 217). was based on the quantity of production, to
The idea of strategic fit is also given the most innovative (system 1), where there
some support by Youndt et al.’s (1996) study were high levels of employee involvement and
of what they call ‘human-capital-enhancing problem-solving teams. Taking production
HR systems’, but here the main effect line ‘uptime’ as their measure of produc-
on performance came through a link with tivity, they found system 1 to be the most
manufacturing strategy rather than corporate productive.
strategy per se. More broadly, although this In the UK context the WIRS/WERS
approach has some intuitive appeal, it does (Workplace Industrial/Employee Relations
raise a dilemma. On the one hand, the idea of Survey) series has been used to follow a
‘strategic fit’ might be taken to highlight the similar line. This quasi-official series of sur-
part work organization and HR management veys, begun in 1980, provides comprehensive
can play in organizational strategy; on the and reliable data on a variety of aspects of
other, it does tend to cast them in very much workplace-level employee relations and HR
a secondary role (Wood, 1999). We shall management. This has allowed researchers
return to this issue in the fourth part of this to develop classifications for workplaces
chapter. on the basis of their employee relations
characteristics, which can then be used with
Universal bundles survey’s measures of workplace performance
We turn now to cell 3 of Table 8.1. Again (in terms of productivity, quality and finance)
we have systems or bundles but the claim or to see if there is any connection between the
the implication is that these are of universal two. Fernie and Metcalf (1995) used the data
application. Arthur’s (1994) study of manu- from the third survey in the series (WIRS3),
facturing performance in US steel minimills conducted in 1990, to look at the performance
can be looked at in this light. He identifies and implications of different forms of what they
distinguishes between two human resource called workplace governance. In terms of
systems: one based on employee commitment, both productivity and productivity growth,
the other on control. His main aim is to test they found that the ‘collective bargaining’
empirically the hypothesis that the steel plants workplace was outperformed by its ‘employee
with a ‘commitment’ system will outperform involvement’ counterpart. In Fernie et al.
those with ‘control’. Data from 30 US plants (1994) the data are used to address the impact
showed that those with the commitment of HRM. Their own findings show that the
system performed better than those with ‘strong union’ workplace is out-performed by
control in terms of labor inputs, scrap rates the ‘strong HRM’ workplace.
and labor turnover. As one of the early studies The idea of the HPWS was the explicit
in this area, Arthur provided backing to the focus of attention for Ramsay et al. (2000) in
more general arguments of Walton (1985) and their analysis of the 1998 WERS4 data. In an
others. attempt to address the question of whether
Ichniowski et al.’s (1997) study of steel practices worked together in bundles, they
finishing lines in the US likewise claims subjected a set of 24 likely HRM practices
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 157

to factor analysis. On this basis they were that had been developed in Toyota, lean
able to identify three groups of practices, one production was essentially the application of
of which proved to have some association a just-in-time (JIT) system, in which stock or
with measures of workplace performance. inventory is reduced to the minimum possible
Although this offers some support for the idea level. A comparison between a Toyota plant
of a ‘universal bundle’, the support would in Japan and a US automotive producer
be stronger if, rather than simply emerging showed the former to have twice the level
from the data, the three sets of practices of productivity or to require ‘half the human
were more deeply rooted in more conceptual effort’ to make a car.
considerations. Although significant doubt has been cast
on the validity of these figures (Williams
Universal super-bundles et al., 1992), two aspects of the claims made
We can take this argument a stage further by the advocates of lean production are of
by saying that what might be important particular interest to us here. A lean plant,
is not so much an HR system or bundle it was claimed (Womack et al., 1990: 99),
itself, but how the system fits with other ‘transfers the maximum number of tasks
organizational systems. Extending the idea of and responsibilities to those workers actually
internal fit in this way is what Wood (1999) adding value to the car on the line’. Thus,
calls ‘organizational fit’. Here we give it the ‘in the end, it is the dynamic work team
name ‘universal super-bundle’. The fit now that emerges as the heart of the lean factory’
covers a wider area but is still horizontal or (1990: 99). In other words, what might appear
configurational in nature; and the application to be a system based on the management of
is still claimed to be universal rather than operations (in particular, the flow of materials)
contingent. In terms of Table 8.1 we again find is, in fact, a system that relies heavily on the
ourselves in cell 3. management of people.
It is in this light that we can consider But what kind of work team would
Wood’s (1999) main conclusion that, while operate under lean production? The idea of
the evidence does seem to support some team working is usually associated with a
version of the universalistic hypothesis, it group’s ability to act with some degree of
is just as strong for the hypothesis that autonomy, but any control over the pace of
the key to performance is the link between production would be severely circumscribed
‘high involvement’ work practices and such by the removal of buffer stocks which lean
techniques or philosophies as TQM and lean production implies (Klein, 1989). Delbridge
production. His main support for this is drawn et al.’s (2000) examination of teams in
from the two US studies of Lawler et al. ‘lean’ plants in the automotive components
(1995, 1998) – although he does stress that sector found that the role of production
the evidence is certainly not overwhelming. workers was quite limited to the areas of
In Wood’s view it is this combination of maintenance and production management.
HR management and the management of More generally, Benders and Van Hootegem
production that explains the positive impact (2000) identify the key characteristics of the
on performance that tends to be attributed ‘lean’ team as: the focal position of foreman;
to the universal effect of HR management the minute description and rigorous regu-
alone. lation of work through Standard Operating
We can see something of this if we look at Procedures (SOPs); and the use of continuous
the idea of lean production. The term arose out improvement (kaizen) techniques to effect
of the US-based International Motor Vehicle marginal improvement in these SOPs.
Program, a US$ 5 million, 14-country project A second aspect of lean production is
which resulted in the publication of The the claim that its principles are of universal
Machine that Changed the World (Womack application. Despite their argument that it
et al., 1990). Based on the production system emerged in response to specific conditions
158 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

faced by the Japanese economy, Womack between practice and performance has in fact
et al. (1990: 88) maintain that ‘lean pro- been established? In the previous section
duction can be introduced anywhere in the of this chapter we have looked at some of
world’. MacDuffie (1995) provides some the most important attempts to address the
development of what we have called here question of the practice-performance link and,
the universal super-bundle. Although drawing notwithstanding their differences in method
on data from the International Motor Vehicle and approach, all seem to at least point in the
Program (IMVP), he argues that Womack same direction.
et al. (1990) did not explain in sufficient For Godard (2004), however, this entire
depth how the HR practices they identified ‘high performance paradigm’should be called
achieved the necessary degree of integration into question. He points to a number of studies
with production. In MacDuffie’s view, what which offer the paradigm little support.
he calls the ‘flexible’ (rather than lean) These include his own longitudinal study
production system in automotive assembly of Canadian enterprises, which revealed few
has an ‘organizational logic’ that provides this positive associations and even some negative
integration. Using multiplicative relationships ones (Godard, 1998). There has been a
between individual work practices, and also tendency, he argues, ‘to emphasize results
between the resultant work systems and HR that appear to support the high performance
and production systems, MacDuffie found paradigm while skating over those that do not’
strong support for the effects of these (Godard, 2004: 354; see also Wood, 1999).
processes of bundling and integration: the Overall, he claims, ‘we should treat broad-
flexible production systems formed in this brush claims about the performance effect
way outperformed mass production in terms of HPPs [high performance practices], and
of both productivity and quality. This is to about research findings claiming to observe
be taken together with other findings from them, with a healthy degree of scepticism’
the same project (MacDuffie and Pil, 1997) (Godard, 2004: 355). Thus while not going so
that gave qualified support to the idea that far as to dismiss the high performance model
firms in the automotive sector across a range completely, he does suggest that the issues we
of countries were converging on the lean examine in this part of the chapter should not
production model. be regarded merely as minor issues capable of
being quickly and easily resolved. We can see
this quite clearly when we turn to the issue of
HIGH PERFORMANCE MANAGEMENT: the model’s diffusion.
THE ISSUES
Diffusion of the model
The advocates of the high performance model
thus find themselves in something of a For Pil and MacDuffie (1996: 423) there is
quandary. On the one hand, the previous a ‘striking paradox’ to be explained: despite
section of this chapter shows that in a rela- the strong links that research has been able to
tively short period of time a strong, positive establish between practice and performance,
link seems to have been established between the so-called ‘high performance’practices had
certain HR practices or systems and the not been diffused widely and quickly. This
performance of organizations. On the other was a particular concern of Osterman (1994),
hand, a number of important issues remain to whose 1992 survey of US establishments
be resolved, and it is these we consider now. examined the extent to which each of his
four practices (self-directed work teams,
job rotation, problem-solving groups and
Overall assessment
Total Quality Management) was present in
The first of these issues is perhaps the an establishment’s ‘core’ workforce. Taking
most basic: can we say that the relationship as his criterion the presence of at least
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 159

two of the practices across at least 50 per 1989–1993/94, their strongest finding is that
cent of the core workforce, he found that adoption of a set of innovative work practices
37 per cent of workplaces could be considered is linked to the existence of a complementary
‘transformed’. Repeating this survey in 1998, set of practices in HR management. They are
Osterman (2000) found that his headline to some degree supported by the study of steel
figure for diffusion had risen to 71 per cent. finishing lines carried out by Ichniowski et al.
As Lawler et al. (1995) and others (Ichniowski (1997), who found that in older lines there has
et al., 1996) had earlier pointed out, this been investment in other systems of skill and
and other figures refer more to individual work relationships.
work practices (or their aggregation) than For Godard (2004) the issue is not so
to the existence of high performance work much lack of diffusion across organizations
systems. as lack of diffusion within them. Interpreting
So how can the slow rate of diffusion be Osterman’s (2000) study as showing that
explained? Osterman (1994) himself looked relatively few organizations fully adopt the
at a range of possibilities for trying to identify high-performance model, he argues that this
which establishments were likely to become suggests that for most employers the overall
‘transformed’. Some of these proved sta- benefits of adoption begin to level-off after a
tistically significant (especially ‘managerial certain point is reached. Part of the problem
values’) and some did not (including the here is that many studies look only at the
presence of a trade union). Other authors have benefit derived from new practices, ignoring
taken a more negative approach, and instead any consideration of their cost. One exception
tried to identify barriers to diffusion. Among to this is Cappelli and Neurmark (2001),
those tentatively suggested by Ichniowski whose US study showed that while there
et al. (1996) were: the limited performance was weak evidence of high performance
gain for some businesses; the need to make practices raising productivity, the evidence
radical change if ‘bundles’are required; labor- on increased labour costs was much stronger.
management distrust; and the constraints Guthrie’s (2001) study of the effects of high
imposed by institutional and public policy. involvement work practices in New Zealand
Appelbaum and Batt (1994) provide a similar companies also cautioned against simply
list, considering the barriers under three advocating their more extensive use. As
headings: the dilemmas facing firms and employees became more valuable and more
managers; union and worker ambivalence; important in the organization’s performance,
and institutional barriers. Neither Ichniowski he concluded, ‘greater use of these practices is
et al. (1996) nor Appelbaum and Batt (1994) associated with significant productivity losses
undertake any systematic investigation of in the face of mounting employee turnover’
these possibilities. (Guthrie, 2001: 188).
Pil and MacDuffie (1996) try to understand
the lack of diffusion in terms of ideas drawn
Importance of high performance
from evolutionary economics and innovation
management
theory. They suggest that pre-existing orga-
nizational ‘routines’ can make it difficult to Some light on our second issue – the limited
effect radical changes. Their ‘competence- rate of diffusion – might also be cast by
destroying’ nature means that performance consideration of our third: how important are
might actually worsen when such changes are the management of HR and work in overall
made, making new working practices difficult organizational performance?
to persist with or unlikely to be introduced Becker and Gerhart (1996) argue that
in the first place. Pil and MacDuffie’s (1996) we should be concerned not just with the
own study of the worldwide automotive existence of a positive relationship – which
assembly industry provides some support for many studies had been able to establish –
this idea. Looking at take-up over the period but with the magnitude of any positive effect.
160 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

A number of other commentators have pointed


Institutional/cultural context
to this as an important issue (Godard and
Delaney, 2000; Guest, 1997; Ichniowski et al., Cutting across all the issues we have consid-
1996). ered so far in this section is the question of
From studies that have looked at this institutional or cultural context. We observed
in a more or less direct way, a range of in the introduction to this chapter that the idea
answers has emerged. Amongst these is the of the high performance workplace was one
Arthur Andersen ‘Worldwide Manufacturing that was developed out of the experience of
Competitiveness Survey’, which looked at US companies in the 1980s and 1990s. We
the use of the principles of lean production have also seen that the greater part of research
by companies in the automotive components on this subject continues to be US-based. To
industry (Lowe et al., 1997; Oliver et al., the extent that we can identify the impact of
1996). Taking three areas – seats, exhausts the high performance model, therefore, we
and brakes – they explored what they defined must ask to what degree this is confined to
as ‘world-class performance’ in terms of both a particular setting.
productivity and quality. The key factor in Research on the link between practice
explaining performance, it was argued, was and performance has been carried out in a
whether a company was located in a supply wide variety of national and regional settings.
chain that was operated in a disciplined Amongst European countries, Rodriguez and
manner. The study found no convincing Ventura (2003) found internal human resource
evidence of the universal applicability and systems to have a positive impact on the finan-
superiority of any particular system of work cial performance of manufacturing companies
organization and human resource manage- in Spain, with more support offered to a uni-
ment: it was location and ownership that were versalistic interpretation than to a contingent
the important explanatory factors. one; d’Arcimoles (1997) also found some
As we have seen, Ramsay et al.’s (2000) relationship between performance and certain
analysis of the 1998 UK WERS data provided HR indicators amongst large French compa-
some support for the idea of a universal nies in the 1980s; Lahteenmaki et al. (1998),
bundle. Their regression equation as a whole, however, found barely any such relationship
however, was able to explain less than in a study of Finnish organizations, their chief
4 per cent of the total extent to which argument being that many studies failed to
productivity differed between workplaces. take into account the stage of the economic
Likewise, Huselid’s (1995) results for the US cycle at which research was undertaken.
explained only 1–3 per cent of the variation in Research in emerging economies also
financial performance. reveals a variety of findings. Bae and
On the other hand, Delery and Doty Lawler’s (2000) research in Korean firms
(1996) found HR factors to account for quite gave support to their main hypothesis, that
large differences in financial performance in high involvement HRM strategies improved
the US banking sector. Three HR practices economic performance, with their results
were found to be significant in terms of favoring a best practice rather than a best
performance, and the average level of each fit approach. Bae et al. (2003) extended this
of these across the sector was calculated. work in a comparative study of Korea, Taiwan,
Compared to banks with the average level of Singapore and Thailand. Their results were
adoption, banks whose level was one standard broadly supportive of the effectiveness of
deviation above this enjoyed a 30 per cent HPWSs’ right across this range of settings.
better performance. As proportions of the total A particular feature of the work was the
variation in performance, moreover, 11, 10 difference they identified between locally
and 6 per cent were claimed respectively by owned companies and MNC subsidiaries:
the universalistic, contingency and configura- perhaps surprisingly, the new work system
tional approaches. has slightly more effect in the former.
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 161

Huang’s (1997) findings in Taiwan alone (Osterman, 1994). The presence of high
were rather more mixed than this; while Fey performance practices was associated with a
et al.’s (2000) study of foreign firms operating higher probability of lay-offs and no gains in
in Russia focused on HR outcomes, giving real wages. ‘The bottom line,’ he concluded,
support to the idea that they could be used as ‘is that there is very little evidence that
mediating variables between HRM practices HPWOs [High Performance Work Organi-
and firm performance. zations] have delivered on the promise of
There have been few attempts, however, to “mutual gains”’ (Osterman, 2000: 191).
make a systematic analysis of this growing Others have found that mutual gains can
volume of international data. We can observe be identified. Godard’s (2001) survey of
differences in findings across countries, but Canadian employees found that team-based
we don’t know to what degree these simply work had positive associations with belong-
reflect the same differences in approach that ingness, task involvement, job satisfaction,
result in different findings within countries. empowerment, commitment and citizenship
Looked at from the other direction, we might behavior. Appelbaum et al.’s (2000) three-
ask what particular differences in cultural sector US study found that HPWSs increase
or institutional context might explain the workers’ trust in their managers and enhance
differences in the findings. Godard’s (2004) their intrinsic rewards from work; also that
proposed ‘political economy’ approach, for the opportunity to participate in decision-
example, suggests that we concentrate on the making was associated with an improvement
nature of economic institutions. He argues in wages. For Appelbaum et al. (2000: 115)
that, without reform of the institutional condi- there were ‘win-win outcomes for plants and
tions, it would be misguided to advocate the workers’.
widespread adoption of the high performance Another way of looking at this issue is
‘paradigm’ in liberal market economies such to address the claim that, to the extent
as the US and the UK. they are effective, high performance practices
operate through work intensification and
employee stress rather than involvement and
Mutual gains
commitment. Barker (1993), for example,
We turn now to the question of the distri- sees self-managed teams as being effective
bution of gains from the adoption of high through the notion of concertive control;
performance management. In particular, to and lean production has been accused of
what degree do employees benefit from the constituting management-by-stress (Parker
performance gains available? As Osterman and Slaughter, 1988).
(2000) points out, there are strong reasons to Direct evidence on this issue is mixed.
expect that employees will gain, since to some Appelbaum et al. (2000) found no evidence
degree the whole high performance model that HPWS practices amount to a ‘speed-up’
is posited on an enhancement of employee that negatively affects workers’ stress. Their
discretion and skill. Godard and Delaney findings suggested that the opportunity for
(2000) argue that the high performance substantive participation is related to lower,
paradigm considers these things only insofar not higher, levels of job stressors. Godard
as they are the means through which the (2001), by contrast, found that alternative
performance outcomes are achieved. We shall work practices were associated with more
look at these ‘transmission mechanisms’ in stressful work. This finding is supported by
more detail in the next section. Here we Ramsay et al. (2000) who also found high
consider work that has looked explicitly at the performance work practices to be positively
question of mutual gain. related to job strain. This, they argued, raised
Osterman’s (2000) 1997 survey looked questions about the widely held assumption
at how employees had fared in those US that positive performance outcomes from
workplaces designated ‘transformed’ in 1992 HPWS flow via positive employee outcomes.
162 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

There is also the question of what the works through changing employees’ attitudes
high performance model implies for organized and behaviors. Guest (1997), for example, has
labor. Perhaps as a reflection of the model’s attempted to construct a framework that links
US roots, trade unions hardly feature at HRM strategy and practice, on the one hand,
all in a large number of studies. As we with performance and financial outcomes,
have seen in the section on the diffusion of on the other, through the intermediation of,
the high performance model, they tend to first, the HRM outcomes of commitment,
appear on the periphery of analysis, either quality and flexibility, and then the behavior
as one possible characteristic of a high outcomes of effort, co-operation, involvement
performance organization or as a barrier to the and citizenship.
model’s diffusion. The central and potentially Interesting questions are raised, therefore,
performance-enhancing role that trade unions when practice and performance appear to
enjoyed in the debates surrounding Freeman have an association in the absence of these
and Medoff’s (1984) What do Unions Do? intermediating variables. Although Ramsay
seems largely to have disappeared. et al. (2000) could use the 1998 UK WERS
As Godard (2004) demonstrates, however, data to establish an association between a
there is a still a body of work that addresses high performance work system and certain
more systematically the relationship between measures of performance, this could not
trade unions and the high performance be explained by ‘employee outcomes’ such
model. His own study of Canadian ‘high as commitment and job discretion. These
performance’ organizations (Godard, 1998) findings in some ways echo what Fernie et al.
showed that union avoidance was not a (1994) found from WERS3: that although
major motivation in the adoption of such a HRM workplaces outperformed their more
model. Whether the high performance model unionised counterparts, they did so despite
provides the vehicle for trade unions to take having worse industrial relations.
part in and derive benefit from a strategy This might suggest that other transmission
of ‘partnership’ with employers is less clear. mechanisms are at work. This possibility
In line with broader considerations of this is allowed for by Ichniowski et al. (1996),
strategy, Godard (2004) suggests that only who identify three basic explanations of the
where unions have the opportunity and also practice-performance link. As well as the
the strength to be involved in something more possibilities that individual workers work
than a superficial partnership, can this be to harder (as a result of heightened levels of
their advantage. motivation) and work smarter (as greater
involvement means they are able to make their
jobs more efficient), Ichniowski et al. also
Transmission mechanisms
allow for improvements in performance to be
As the preceding section makes clear, the the result of more structural changes which
issue of mutual gains can also be seen in can accompany changes in work.
the context of – or as part of – the issue A greater emphasis on this possibility
concerning the ‘transmission mechanisms’ of would certainly be in line with the universal
the high performance model. While research super-bundle approach we identified earlier,
seems to have been successful in establishing and a number of researchers seem to be
the existence of a positive association between moving in this direction. Purcell (1999)
HR practice and organizational performance, suggests that operational strategies can be a
it has been less so in explaining how that rela- key intervening variable, and amongst types
tionship comes about. According to Boselie of economic gain from high performance
et al.’s (2005: 77) comprehensive survey workplace practices identified by Appelbaum
of journal articles in this area, the linking et al. (2000) are a reduction in the total number
mechanisms are ‘largely disregarded’. The of employees and a reduction in interruptions
general assumption is that any relationship to production.
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 163

and develop the internal resources that might


Underpinning theory
generate a sustained competitive advantage.
Consideration of transmission mechanisms The theory requires that this resource has a
inevitably brings with it questions concerning number of qualities, prime amongst which
the theory underpinning the link between HR is inimitability. What is required, in other
practice and performance. Some of these we words, is something that other organizations
have already touched on in our attempt to are unable to copy.
classify the different ways of approaching this Boxall and Purcell (2003) argue that neither
issue. Both Boxall (1992) and Purcell (1999) the human resources themselves nor the
have criticized the idea of ‘best fit’ between HR policies or practices can provide the
HR and corporate strategy. Purcell (1999) means necessary to generate a sustained
points to the difficulties involved in opera- competitive advantage. The human resources
tionalizing the concept, while both authors are or the people themselves can be moved from
concerned with its theoretical shortcomings, one organization to another; likewise, the
especially its reliance on the concepts of policies or practices by which to manage them
strategy developed by Porter. They also argue can also easily be adopted. The real source of
that the best practice/best fit debate has its inimitability and differentiation, it is argued,
limitations as a means of providing the basic exists at a higher level, with the idea of ‘social
structure to the debate. Boxall and Purcell architecture’. HRM is to be seen as the creator
(2003) argue for combining the two, with best of an organization’s distinctiveness rather
practice providing a ‘base-line’set of practices than the distinctiveness itself. A universally
and best fit the means by which organizations applicable set of principles might thus result in
can differentiate themselves beyond that. a number of different sets of practices (Becker
In general, the development or application and Gerhart, 1996).
of theory has often taken second place to Boxall and Steeneveld (1999) use this
the methodological sophistication required to approach in their study of New Zealand engi-
manipulate large, complex data-sets. Boselie neering consultancies. Following a detailed
et al.’s (2005: 71) survey article tried to longitudinal study, they are able to establish
identify which theoretical framework was how the more successful companies differ
being used in each case, but found that ‘this from the less successful in term of ‘human
proved far from obvious in many of the capital’ or people, but they claim that it was
articles’. Other authors have used specific much more difficult to discern the ‘social
theoretical concepts for specific purposes. architecture’ or ‘human process advantage’
In addressing the issue of the complementarity required for sustained competitive success.
of practices, for example, Ichniowski et al. While this might illustrate the long-term,
(1997) argue this could be done on the basis of strategic importance of high performance
economic ideas of incentive contract theories, management, the inability to draw definite
which stress the importance of interactive conclusions even at the end of an in-depth,
effects. Likewise, Pil and MacDuffie (1996) long-term project would seem to limit the
try to understand the issue of diffusion in terms predictive or prescriptive capacity of this
of ideas about organizational ‘routines’ drawn approach.
from evolutionary economics and innovation Despite the apparent status it gives to
theory. HRM or high performance management, the
More recently we have seen attempts to implications of the RBV need to be exam-
redress the rather atheoretical nature of the ined carefully. The fact that the necessary
practice-performance debate by looking at in contribution made by management in this
terms of the resource-based view (RBV) of area is, by definition, unique is something
the firm (see Boxall and Purcell, 2003; Purcell, of a double-edged sword. While it seems to
1999; Wright et al., 1994). Under the RBV, the emphasize the importance to an organization
chief concern of an organization is to identify of how its employees are managed, it makes
164 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

it more difficult to see exactly what form that surveys rely on questions that can be answered
management should take. It would seem to easily within a structured framework. ‘Box-
undermine any claim that HPM or HRM might ticking’ questions of this nature, however,
have to provide something that is of universal will tend to focus attention on observable
application (Wood, 1999). structures at the expense of organizational
The danger also, especially from an indus- processes (Purcell, 1999). Other issues in
trial relations point of view, is that the focus the generation of the data include a reliance
is very much internal to the firm. Quite apart on subjective judgments on such things as
from its management focus, the danger is innovative work practices and organizational
of neglecting the institutional context within performance, and the fact that data from
which organizations are operating. Paauwe a large organization or establishment might
(2004) tries to get this round by combining come from a single respondent (Ichniowski
the RBV with institutionalist theory in et al., 1996). Osterman (1994) argues that
his context-based human resource theory senior HR managers, the likely recipients of
(CBHRT) (see also Paauwe and Boselie, questionnaire surveys in this area, are very
2005). While this might be welcomed as an often ignorant of how employees’ work is
attempt to temper the RBV and its impact, organized.
it is less easy to see how these two different Just as serious are the issues involved in
approaches can be brought together either in the interpretation of the data (see Godard,
theory or in its application. 2004; Boselie et al., 2005). The most basic of
these is that cross-sectional work can identify
an association between variables but cannot
Methodological issues
establish whether that association is based on
As well as the theoretical issues, the high a particular causal relationship (Godard and
performance model continues to face a Delaney, 2000). It is conventional in cross-
number of methodological ones. Many of sectional research to acknowledge this (see,
these stem from the fact that a large part of for example, Arthur, 1994; Delery and Doty,
the work devoted to identifying the existence 2000) but, implicitly or explicitly, causal
and nature of a practice-performance link has relationships are attributed to the findings.
been in the form of large-scale, cross-sectional In looking at the practice-performance link
questionnaire surveys. Ichniowski et al. it is assumed that practice causes perfor-
(1996) describe what an ideal research design mance. It could plausibly be argued that
would be in these circumstances, involving, the direction of causality runs the other
for example, the random assignment of way: that better-performing companies are
innovative work practices and a sample which in a position to make investments in certain
closely resembles the population. They also working practices. Schneider et al. (2003)
show why such an ideal is unlikely to be take this one stage further, by showing
attained. how the ‘reverse causality’ might operate
A number of issues arise in the generation through employee attitudes. They studied
of data. The first of these is response the relationship between employee attitudes
bias. With response to most questionnaire and firm performance across a number of
surveys being of a voluntary nature, it US companies over a number of years, and
might be the case that the more successful concluded that it could not simply be assumed
firms are more likely to respond. More that attitudes lead to performance: ‘some do
than this, bias would arise as a result of and some do not, and some employee attitudes
high performance practices being more likely apparently are the result [emphasis added] of
to be retained in firms where the benefits financial and market performance’ (Schneider
exceed the costs (Godard and Delaney, 2000). et al., 2003).
There is also the issue of the nature of Another possibility is that there is a third
the questions. By their nature, questionnaire variable involved, one that explains both
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 165

practice and performance. As Ichniowski et al. CONCLUSIONS


(1996) point out, an ideal situation would be
one in which the extent of high performance What can we conclude from our review of
management was uncorrelated with other the high performance model? We can see
characteristics that affect performance. But first of all that, although they can be a
could it be the case, for example, that source of confusion, issues of terminology and
organizations that are good at managing definition are not anything like insuperable
human resources will be good at other aspects difficulties. There exists enough common
of management? In order to guard against ground and common focus for a range of
the ‘omitted variable’ problem, longitudinal terms and definitions to co-exist. It would
studies might be preferred to cross sectional serve little purpose to try and impose too rigid
ones (Ichniowski et al., 1996). a distinction between what is and what isn’t
An attempt to engage with these issues ‘high performance’.
of causality has been made by Guest et al. Where some change might be made is
(2003) (see also Wright et al., 2003). Using how the different approaches to the issue
data on HR practice in the UK in 1999, might be classified. There appears in any case
they found that while an association could to be a move away from the best-practice/
be established between HR practices and best-fit distinction that had achieved some
performance, the same could not be said currency. As the analysis presented in this
for HR practices and subsequent changes in chapter suggests, explicit account needs to be
performance. Rather than practice causing taken of both of the dimensions (the scope
performance, there was, argued Guest et al. of the application of HPM practices and
(2003), stronger support for the idea of reverse the relationship between them) along which
causality. On this basis they could not support studies might be classified.
the view that ‘greater application of HRM More fundamentally than this, it seems to
is likely to result in improved corporate be generally recognized that there is a range
performance’ (311). of issues that still need to be addressed. These
In Wood’s (1999) view, part of the we have identified as follows:
confusion arises as a result of having too
many studies that adopt too simplistic a view • overall assessment of the model;
of what hypotheses to test. The implication • its rate of diffusion;
of this is that there should be a more • its importance in an organization’s performance;
synergistic relationship between, on the one • the institutional/cultural context;
hand, hypothesis-testing, quantitative surveys • the issue of mutual gains;
and, on the other, hypothesis-generating, • the model’s ‘transmission mechanisms’;
qualitative case studies. There are, however, • underpinning theory;
very few case studies that address in a direct • methodological issues.
way the relationship between HR practice and
performance (Boselie et al., 2005). From the Our argument here is that an industrial
ones that do, moreover, it is difficult to get relations perspective is in a good position to
any feel for potential conceptual development. generate understanding of these issues and
As we have already seen, it might be argued thus to shape the future development of the
that Boxall and Steeneveld’s (1999) account debate around the high performance model. If
of New Zealand engineering consultancies we look at the issue of diffusion, for example,
reveals more of the weaknesses than the then, here as elsewhere, attempts to isolate
strengths of the resource-based view of the particular factors as ‘barriers’ have not proved
firm; while Truss’ (2001) study of Hewlett- particularly fruitful. Understanding diffusion
Packard, though interesting in itself, does in terms of the labor-management relation-
not carry with it any important theoretical ships within particular workplaces appears to
implications. offer much more promise. Similarly, existing
166 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

research has been weak on identifying and for a more synergistic relationship between,
explaining the importance of the national or on the one hand, hypothesis-testing, quanti-
regional context. It might be argued that much tative surveys and, on the other, hypothesis-
of the literature in the broad HRM area is generating, qualitative case studies.
of this nature, amounting to little more than The methodological and the theoretical
bemusement at why other settings are not the issues might indeed be addressed simul-
same as the US. Again, an understanding of taneously. What a more qualitative, case-
the most important features of institutional study approach would do is not simply
context is something that emerges naturally establish that the direction of causality ran
from an industrial relations perspective. one way or the other; it would reveal
The contribution industrial relations might much more of the dynamics of the situation.
make is perhaps most obvious in the area What would be important then is not so
of mutual gains. This is not just a question much management action but the relationship
of establishing the proportions in which any between management and employees. It might
performance gains are divided. Irrespective of only be when organizational performance is
the extent to which they gain either financially considered in the context of the employment
or through having greater discretion at work, relationship that it can fully be understood.
employees at the moment enter into this
picture as passive recipients. A more explicit
focus on employees’ attitudes and strategies
might not just allow us to see how any REFERENCES
gains are generated and divided; it might also
Ackroyd, S. and Procter, S. (1998) ‘British Manufacturing
allow us to say more about the diffusion
Organization and Workplace Industrial Relations:
and impact of the high performance model. Some Attributes of the New Flexible Firm’, British
Overlapping with this is a need to look Journal of Industrial Relations, 36 (2): 163–83.
more deeply at the ‘transmission mechanism’ Appelbaum, E. and Batt, R. (1994) The New American
between practice and performance. This is Workplace: Transforming Work Systems in the United
a rather crude way of approaching what is States. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
essentially a system of social relations. A bet- Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg, A.
ter understanding of management-employee (2000) Manufacturing Advantage: Why High-
relations might generate a less mechanistic Performance Work Systems Pay Off. Ithaca, NY:
understanding of how management actions Cornell University Press.
d’Arcimoles, C. (1997) ‘Human Resource Policies and
have ‘effects’.
Company Performance: a Quantitative Approach
All of this points to a more fundamental
Using Longitudinal Data’, Organization Studies,
reconsideration of theoretical and method- 18 (5): 857–74.
ological issues. The whole debate might Arthur, J. (1994) ‘Effects of Human Resource Systems on
be accused of being rather atheoretical in Manufacturing Performance and Turnover’, Academy
nature. Recent attempts have been made of Management Journal, 37 (3): 670–87.
to remedy this, by promoting the RBV Atkinson, J. (1984) ‘Manpower Strategies for Flexible
as the means by which the relationship Organizations’, Personnel Management, Aug: 28–31.
between HR management and performance Bae, J. and Lawler, J. (2000) ‘Organizational and HRM
is best understood. Not only might this Strategies in Korea: Impact on Firm Performance in
make generalization difficult, but it also an Emerging Economy’, Academy of Management
Journal, 43 (3): 502–17.
downplays any role that the employment
Bae, J., Chen, S., Wan, T., Lawler, J. and Walumbwa, F.
relationship might play in the analysis. The
(2003) ‘Human Resource Strategy and Firm Perfor-
main methodological issues stem from the mance in Pacific Rim Countries’, International Journal
widespread reliance on the cross-sectional of Human Resource Management, 14 (8): 1308–22.
survey as the means of identifying the Barker, J. (1993) ‘Tightening the Iron Cage: Concertive
practice-performance relationship, and we Control in Self-Managing Teams’, Administrative
can echo those such as Wood (1999) who call Science Quarterly, 38 (3): 408–37.
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 167

Batt, R. (2000) ‘Strategic Segmentation in Front- Workplace?’ Employment Policy Institute Economic
line Services: Matching Customers, Employees Report, 8 (3).
and Human Resource Systems’, International Fey C., Bjorkman, I. and Pavlovskaya, A. (2000) ‘The
Journal of Human Resource Management, Effect of Human Resource Management Practices
11 (3): 540–61. on Firm Performance in Russia’, International
Becker, B. and Gerhart, B. (1996) ‘The Impact of Journal of Human Resource Management, 11 (1):
Human Resource Management on Organizational 1–18.
Performance: Progress and Prospects’, Academy of Freeman, R. and Medoff, J. (1984) What Do Unions Do?
Management Journal, 39 (4): 779–801. New York: Basic Books.
Benders, J. and Van Hootegem, G. (2000) ‘How the Godard, J. (1998) ‘Workplace Reforms, Managerial
Japanese Got Teams’, in Procter, S. and Mueller, F. Objectives, and Managerial Outcomes’, International
(eds) Teamworking. London: Macmillan. pp. 43–59. Journal of Human Resource Management, 9 (1):
Berggren, C. (1993) The Volvo Experience: Alternatives 18–40.
to Lean Production in the Swedish Auto Industry. Godard, J. (2001) ‘High Performance and the Trans-
London: Macmillan. formation of Work? The Implications of Alternative
Boselie, P., Dietz, G. and Boon, C. (2005) ‘Common- Work Practices for the Experience and Outcomes of
alities and Contradictions in HRM and Performance Work’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54 (4):
Research’, Human Resource Management Journal, 776–805.
15 (3): 67–94. Godard, J. (2004) ‘A Critical Assessment of the High-
Boxall, P. (1992) ‘Strategic Human Resource Manage- Performance Paradigm’, British Journal of Industrial
ment: Beginnings of a New Theoretical Sophistica- Relations, 42 (2): 349–78.
tion?’, Human Resource Management Journal, 2 (3): Godard, J. and J. Delaney (2000) ‘Reflections on
60–78. the “High Performance” Paradigm’s Implications for
Boxall, P. and Steeneveld, M. (1999) ‘Human Resource Industrial Relations as a Field’, Industrial and Labor
Strategy and Competitive Advantage: a Longitudinal Relations Review, 53 (3): 482–502.
Study of Engineering Consultancies’, Journal of Guest, D. (1997) ‘Human Resource Management and
Management Studies, 36 (4): 443–63. Performance: a Review and Research Agenda’, Inter-
Boxall, P. and Purcell, J. (2003) Strategy and Human national Journal of Human Resource Management, 8
Resource Management. Basingstoke: Palgrave. (3): 263–76.
Cappelli, P. (1995) ‘Rethinking Employment’, British Guest, D., Michie, J., Conway, N. and Sheehan, M.
Journal of Industrial Relations, 33 (4): 563–602. (2003) ‘Human Resource Management and Cor-
Cappelli, P. and Neurmark, D. (2001) ‘Do “High porate Performance in the UK’, British Journal of
Performance” Work Practices Improve Establishment- Industrial Relations, 41 (2): 291–314.
level Outcomes?’, Industrial and Labor Relations Guthrie, J. (2001) ‘High Involvement Work Prac-
Review, 54 (4): 737–75. tices, Turnover and Productivity: Evidence from
Cully, M., Woodland, S., O’Reilly, A. and Dix, G. (1999) New Zealand’, Academy of Management Review,
Britain at Work: As Depicted by the 1998 Workplace 44 (1): 180–90.
Employee Relations Survey. London: Routledge. Hirst, P. and Zeitlin, J. (1989) ‘Flexible Specialization
Delbridge, R., Lowe, J. and Oliver, N. (2000) ‘Worker and the Competitive Failure of UK Manufacturing’,
Autonomy in Lean Teams: Evidence from the World Political Quarterly, 60 (2): 164–78.
Automotive Components Industry’, in Procter, S. and Huang, T. (1997) ‘The Effect of Participative Manage-
Mueller, F. (eds) Teamworking. London: Macmillan. ment on Organizational Performance: the Case of
pp. 125–42. Taiwan’, International Journal of Human Resource
Delery, J. and Doty, H. (1996) ‘Modes of Theorizing Management, 8 (5): 677–89.
in Strategic Human Resource Management: Tests Huselid, M. (1995) ‘The Impact of Human Resource
of Universalistic, Contingency and Configurational Management Practices on Turnover, Productivity, and
Performance Predictions’, Academy of Management Corporate Performance’, Academy of Management
Journal, 39 (4): 802–35. Journal, 38 (3): 635–72.
Fernie, S. and Metcalf, D. (1995) ‘Participation, Ichniowski, C., Kochan, T., Levine, D., Olson, C. and
Contingent Pay, Representation and Workplace Strauss, G. (1996) ‘What Works at Work: Overview
Performance: Evidence from Great Britain’, British and Assessment’, Industrial Relations, 35 (3):
Journal of Industrial Relations, 33 (3): 379–415. 299–333.
Fernie, S., Metcalf, D. and Woodland, S. (1994) ‘What Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G. (1997)
has Human Resource Management Achieved in the ‘The Effects of Human Resource Management
168 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Practices on Productivity: a Study of Steel Fin- Parker, M. and Slaughter, J. (1988) Choosing Sides:
ishing Lines’, American Economic Review, 87 (3): Unions and the Team Concept. Boston: South End
291–313. Press.
Kalleberg, A. (2001) ‘Organizing Flexibility: the Flexible Pfeffer, J. (1994) Competitive Advantage through
Firm in the New Century’, British Journal of Industrial People. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
Relations, 39 (4): 479–504. Press.
Klein, J. (1989) ‘The Human Costs of Manufactur- Pfeffer, J. (1998) The Human Equation: Building Profits
ing Reform’, Harvard Business Review, Mar–Apr: by Putting People First. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
60–6. School Press.
Lahteenmaki, S., Storey, J. and Vanhala, S. (1998) ‘HRM Pil, F. and MacDuffie, J. (1996) ‘The Adoption of High-
and Company Performance: the Use of Measurement Involvement Work Practices’, Industrial Relations,
and the Influence of Economic Cycles’, Human 35 (3): 423–55.
Resource Management Journal, 8 (2): 51–65. Piore, M. and Sabel, C. (1984) The Second Industrial
Lawler, E., Mohrman, S. and Ledford, G. (1995) Creating Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic
High Performance Organizations. San Francisco: Books.
Jossey Bass. Pollert, A. (ed.) (1991) Farewell to Flexibility? Oxford:
Lawler, E., Mohrman, S. and Ledford, G. (1998) Blackwell.
Strategies for High Performance Organizations. San Porter, M. (1980) Competitive Strategy. New York: Free
Francisco: Jossey Bass. Press.
Lowe, J., Delbridge, R. and Oliver, N. (1997) ‘High- Porter, M. (1985) Competitive Advantage. New York:
performance Manufacturing: Evidence from the Free Press.
Automotive Components Industry’, Organization Procter, S., Rowlinson, M., McArdle, L., Hassard, J.
Studies, 18 (5): 783–98. and Forrester, P. (1994) ‘Flexibility, Politics and
MacDuffie, J. (1995) ‘Human Resource Bundles and Strategy: in Defence of the Model of the Flexible
Manufacturing Performance: Organizational Logic Firm’, Work, Employment and Society, 8 (2):
and Flexible Production Systems in the World Auto 221–42.
Industry’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Purcell, J. (1999) ‘Best Practice and Best Fit: Chimera or
48 (2): 197–221. Cul-de-sac?’, Human Resource Management Journal,
MacDuffie, J. and Pil, F. (1997) ‘Changes in Auto Industry 9 (3): 26–41.
Employment Practices: an International Overview’, in Ramsay, H., Scholarios, D. and Harley, B.
T. Kochan, R. Lansbury, and J. MacDuffie, (eds) After (2000) ‘Employees and High Performance
Lean Production. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Work Systems: Testing Inside the Black Box’,
Press. pp. 9–42. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 38 (4):
Oliver, N., Delbridge, R. and Lowe, J. (1996) ‘Lean 501–31.
Production Practices: International Comparisons in Rodriguez, J. and Ventura, J. (2003) ‘Human Resource
the Auto Components Industry’, British Journal of Management Systems and Organizational Perfor-
Management, 7, special issue, 29–44. mance: an Analysis of the Spanish Manufacturing
Osterman, P. (1994) ‘How Common is Workplace Industry’, International Journal of Human Resource
Transformation and Who Adopts It?’, Industrial and Management, 14 (7): 1206–26.
Labor Relations Review, 47 (2): 173–88. Schneider, B., Hanges, P., Smith, D. and Salvaggio, A.
Osterman, P. (2000) ‘Work Reorganization in an Era (2003) ‘Which Comes First: Employee Attitudes
of Restructuring: Trends in Diffusion and Effects on or Organizational Financial and Market Perfor-
Employee Welfare’, Industrial and Labor Relations mance?’, Journal of Applied Psychology, 88 (5):
Review, 53 (2): 179–86. 836–51.
Paauwe, J. (2004) HRM and Performance: Achieving Schuler, R. and Jackson, S. (1987) ‘Linking Competitive
Long Term Viability. Oxford: Oxford University Strategies with Human Resource Management
Press. Practices’, Academy of Management Executive, 1 (3):
Paauwe, J. and Boselie, P. (2003) ‘Challenging “Strate- 207–19.
gic HRM” and the Relevance of the Institutional Set- Truss, C. (2001) ‘Complexities and Controversies in
ting’, Human Resource Management Journal, 13 (5): Linking HRM with Organizational Outcomes’, Journal
56–70. of Management Studies, 38 (8): 1121–49.
Paauwe, J. and Boselie, P. (2005) ‘HRM and Perfor- Vallas, S. (1999) ‘Rethinking Post-Fordism: the Meaning
mance: What Next?’, Human Resource Management of Workplace Flexibility’, Sociological Theory, 17 (1):
Journal, 15 (4): 68–83. 68–101.
NEW FORMS OF WORK AND THE HIGH PERFORMANCE PARADIGM 169

Walton, R. (1985) ‘From Control to Commitment in Wood, S. (1999) ‘Human Resource Management and
the Workplace’, Harvard Business Review, Mar–Apr: Performance’, International Journal of Management
76–84. Reviews, 1 (4): 367–413.
West, M. A., Borrill, C., Dawson, J., Scully, J., Carter, M., Wright, P., Gardner, T. and Moynihan, L. (2003) ‘The
Anelay, S., Patterson, M. and Waring, J. (2002) ‘The Impact of HR Practices on the Performance of Business
Link Between the Management of Employees and Units’, Human Resource Management Journal, 13 (3):
Patient Mortality in Acute Hospitals’, International 21–36.
Journal of Human Resource Management, 13 (8): Wright, P., McMahan, G. and McWilliams, A. (1994)
1299–310. ‘Human Resources and Sustained Competitive Advan-
Williams, K., Cutler, T., Williams, J. and Haslam, C. tage: a Resource-based Perspective’, International
(1987) ‘The End of Mass Production?’, Economy and Journal of Human Resource Management, 5 (2):
Society, 16 (3): 405–39. 301–26.
Williams, K., Haslam, C., Williams, J. and Cutler, T. Youndt, M. A., Snell, S. A., Dean, J. W. and
(1992) ‘Against Lean Production’, Economy and Lepak, D. P. (1996) ‘Human Resource Manage-
Society, 21 (3): 321–54. ment, Manufacturing Strategy and Firm Perfor-
Womack, J., Jones, D. and Roos, D. (1990) The mance’, Academy of Management Journal, 39 (4):
Machine that Changed the World. New York: Rawson 836–66.
Associates.
9
Changing Traditions in
Industrial Relations Research
George Strauss and Keith Whitfield

INTRODUCTION whether our perceptions were mirrored in the


main journals, albeit only those which are
In Researching the World of Work: Strategies more empirically tractable. It was followed
and Methods in Studying Industrial Relations by a not dissimilar paper by Carola M. Frege
Research (Whitfield and Strauss, 1998), we (2005), which examined similar themes and
made a number of points about the way in addressed some new issues.
which Industrial Relations (IR) research is We also listened closely to the views of
undertaken, and how it might respond to the those who reviewed the book, to see if there
challenges it currently faces. In particular, we were any profound disagreements with our
stated that the views. Most readers seemed to accept our
caricature of the past, present, and future of
… tide engulfing industrial relations is strong… but the field. Less encouragingly, however, few of
we feel that allied to changes in conceptual tools, those reacting to our rather pessimistic views
a broadening of scope, and possibly a modification
of the future offered suggestions as to how it
of the field’s title, the development of a distinctive
and powerful approach to research design can might be made brighter.
contribute to a renaissance in the field … (Whitfield This chapter has three main objectives. The
and Strauss, 1998: 294). first is to outline the arguments we made in
our 1998 book. Our treatment is deliberately
Since then, we have undertaken a content concise; those wanting more depth can consult
analysis of the field’s main academic journals the original. The second objective is to
covering almost half a century (Whitfield and examine our assertions in the light of the two
Strauss, 2000), oriented around the themes journal content analyses, ours and Frege’s.
developed in the book. The analysis was quite Third, we address the question of where IR
narrowly focused, but allowed us to check goes from here.
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 171

A FIELD IN FLUX identified with IR (for example, Clawson,


2003; Voss and Sherman, 2000). Inevitably,
The academic field of IR faces some difficult there has developed a questioning of the
dilemmas, and its future depends on how it efficacy of differing approaches to examining
responds. These dilemmas originate from a the employment relationship.
number of key shifts in the topics that the Just as the problems which academic IR
field seeks to understand, in the structure of deals with have changed, so have the research
academia, and in the opportunities open to techniques used to study them. The advent
researchers. of the computer has made the quick and
It is something of a cliché to say that cheap analysis of massive data-sets possible.
research in IR is in a state of flux. There This has caused major changes in research
are, however, probably stronger grounds mehtodology throughout most of the social
for saying this now than ever before. The sciences. As a consequence, academic dis-
field’s subject matter is changing ever more course has become increasingly quantitative.
markedly, its conceptual framework is under
increasing scrutiny, boundaries between it and
Changing problems
related fields of study are becoming ever
more blurred, and new research techniques One of the distinctive characteristics of
are continuously being developed. These IR has been its focus on socially defined
changes are broadly linked to a series problems. For example, before 1940, IR
of transformations in how work and the research in the US concentrated on the
employment relationship are perceived. There legitimization of unions and the case for social
is a much wider recognition of the importance insurance (Millis and Montgomery, 1938–45).
of what some call ‘labor’ (and others ‘human During the immediate postwar period, there
resources’ or ‘human capital’) to the prosper- was much industrial unrest and the focus
ity of modern economies and the development turned to strikes and inflation (Strauss and
of a ‘good society’. Organizations are much Feuille, 1978). During the 1960s, it was
more likely to recognize that the utilization training and race relations. More recently,
of human resources is pivotal in attaining the dominant themes have been the decline
competitive advantage in ever-more-complex of unions, the attempts to reinvigorate them
product markets. (Voss and Sherman, 2000), and the impact
Seventy years ago, academic IR covered of participation schemes (Ichniowski et al.,
broadly both what Kaufman (2004) called 2000).
‘Institutional Labor Economics’ and British IR research focused on unions
‘Personnel Management’. Gradually, as and union-management relations during the
Kaufman documents, it narrowed its scope to 1960s, on shop-floor labour-management
primarily union-management relations. But relations during the 1970s, and, more recently,
more recently there is some evidence that on the role of management and work orga-
its scope is once again broadening. Issues nization. The heightened interest in human
such as ‘high-performance’ work practices, resource management (HRM)has contributed
occupational health and safety, employment to the recent burst of British scholarship in
discrimination, employee satisfaction, job that area. The decentralization of bargaining
security, and comparative international in contemporary Australia has been accom-
industrial relations have come to play an panied by a greater research emphasis on
important role in the research agenda. This workplace issues.
broadening of scope has been associated with The perceived nature of problems also
a greater interchange between IR researchers affects the funding that is available, and
and scholars from other fields. Topics such this greatly influences the kind of research
as the decline in union density are covered done. In the early1970s, there was liberal
increasingly by scholars who are not normally government financing of poverty and training
172 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

studies in the US. More recently, Sloan It was perhaps best known for its extensive use
Foundation funding has paved the way for of the case method. In the US, the pioneering
extensive research on ‘high-commitment’ study of this type was John R. Commons’
workplaces. Perceived social problems led to single case study of shoemakers (Commons,
the establishment of the Donovan Commis- 1909). In Britain, a similar impact resulted
sion in Britain (Royal Commission on Unions from the work of Sidney and Beatrice Webb.
and Employers’ Associations, 1968), the Theories were relatively unimportant, but to
Hancock Committee in Australia (Hancock, the extent they developed, they emerged from
1985), and the Dunlop Commission in the the facts, not as logical deductions from other
US (Commission on the Future of Worker- theories.
Management Relations, 1994). Each spon- Now dominant in the US, and increasingly
sored important research, and also inspired important in other English speaking countries,
a host of related funding opportunities and is a more deductive approach that is far
research studies. less grounded in specific research contexts.
The deductive approach seeks general laws
that apply in every situation to some extent,
From policy to theory even though they may explain only part of
Compared with related fields and disciplines, any given situation. The search for such
IR research has traditionally been strongly laws starts from hypotheses (for this reason
focused on the major policy issues of the it is sometimes called the ‘hypothetico-
time. As a consequence, relative to more deductive’ approach). In IR, these hypotheses
theoretically-inclined fields, it has tended to: were traditionally drawn from economics, but
increasingly they have come from psychology
1) be more multidisciplinary; or one of the other social sciences. Hypotheses
2) be more focused on a number of different developed logically from such assumptions
organizational levels; are tested against empirical facts as rigorously
3) be more based on representative samples; as possible. In short, facts are used to test
4) more often involve respondents who are role theories, not to develop them. This type of
holders rather than private individuals; and research tends to be quantitative rather than
5) be more likely to examine complex causal qualitative, and to make use of large data-
processes. sets and often complex multivariate statistical
analysis. Many of these data are economic
In recent years, however, IR research has in orientation, though there is increasing
shown an increasing tendency to become use of more employment-focused data-sets,
more oriented toward issues that are of particularly a range of workplace surveys in a
more interest to fellow academicians than growing number of countries.
policy-makers, potentially weakening the link In some areas, the two traditions have
between research and policy. developed in unison, with secondary analysis
of large-scale survey data being deployed
alongside complementary case studies
Less inductive, more deductive
(Edwards, 2005). As Marginson (1998)
The highly inductive tradition of context- points out, in Britain, large scale surveys
specific research, once dominant in IR have been widely used in the inductive mode
research in English-speaking countries, is to raise questions. Thus it would be incorrect
clearly under siege (Cappelli, 1985). The to see the more abstract, newer style of
earlier approach was predominantly based research as simply crowding out the more
on intensive studies of individual situations, traditional type. Nonetheless, there does seem
typically with the purpose of coming to to have been a distinct shift toward more
focused policy recommendations, and pos- deductive, less context-specific, and more
sibly a contribution to middle-range theory. theory-oriented inquiry.
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 173

Construct validity is particularly important


Forms of validity for researchers in psychology, but less so for
One of the key differences among the various economists. It is more significant for policy-
research strategies is the attention given to the oriented than for theoretical researchers. Inter-
validation of constructs, models, and findings. nal validity has been a particularly important
Distinctions are often made among three concept for economists, and it is notable
major forms of validity: construct, internal, that much econometric research is concerned
and external (Schwab, 2005). with ensuring that a statistical model has
internal consistency. External validity is
• Construct validity concerns the degree to which important for policy-based researchers, given
the variables considered accurately reflect the that their work is intended to influence policies
factors composing the underlying conceptual affecting general populations. By contrast,
model (or hypothesis), for example, the degree to much theoretical research explicitly focuses
which IQ scores are good measures of cognitive on extreme or atypical cases to test whether
ability. theoretical ideas are widely applicable. If they
• Internal validity relates to the causal model (the apply in extreme cases, presumably they will
hypothesized relationship) itself and concerns the also apply in cases which are less extreme.
degree to which the empirical model estimated
is consistent on its own terms, for example,
whether the relationship between union presence Research methods: qualitative
and pay is solely due to the impact of the and/or quantitative
former on the latter and can therefore be
estimated in (determined by) a single statistical Most inductive research is qualitative and
equation. most deductive research is quantitative, but
• External validity concerns the degree to which the this isn’t always the case. Sometimes quantita-
results can be generalized beyond the particular tive researchers will analyze a set of available
situation studied. data with no hypotheses in mind, hoping
that an interesting pattern will emerge –
Attaining high levels of all three forms of ‘magic computer on the wall, what’s the
validity in a single project is rare. Typically, meaning of this all?’ Only then is an attempt
they are traded off against each other, and made to explain this pattern logically. Though
against more practical considerations such sometimes sneeringly called the ‘kitchen sink’
as cost and time. The nature of the trade- approach, quantitative inductive research
off reflects the resources available to the occasionally yields unexpected results, just as
researcher, the rationale for the study, and random testing of drugs sometimes provides
the research tradition within which the work unexpected cures. In contrast, qualitative
is done. methods may be employed in a deductive
IR research has traditionally been strong in fashion when, having completed one case
terms of construct validity, but rather weak study, the researcher undertakes another with
in terms of external validity. The advent the intent of determining whether the same
of workplace IR surveys has introduced a relationships hold in both cases. Often they
stronger element of external validity into the do not, and this may lead the researcher
field, albeit at the (for some unacceptable) to look for explanations of the difference.
expense of construct validity. A key problem This is a common approach in comparative
for the field, however, lies in the area of international studies.
internal validity, especially the ability of Among the advantages of the quantitative
researchers to distinguish between cause and approach is transparency: how the research
effect, for example, to determine whether is conducted is generally clear, others may
the often-found positive association between replicate the study, and typically the data
HR practices and performance runs from the on which the conclusions are based are
former to the latter, or vice versa. made publicly available. By contrast, the
174 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

reported results of qualitative research may Even within quantitative research there are
be affected by the researcher’s biases and differences among fields. Economists gener-
expectations. Surveys are less likely to be seen ally favor regressions, while psychologists are
as biased. Another advantage of the quan- more likely to use techniques that identify
titative approach is its ability to generalize. patterns, such as factor analysis. Psycholo-
Conclusions based on qualitative research in gists emphasize the need to validate proxy
a small number of situations may have limited measures, that is, to ensure high construct
external validity. While qualitative research validity; economists typically do not see this
may suggest hypotheses, quantitative research as a problem. Many younger IR scholars, who
assists in determining how widely these hold have been broadly trained in both economics
and the general strength of the relationship. and organizational behavior, feel comfortable
Compared with the quantitative approach, with both econometric and psychometric
qualitative research typically considers a techniques. Consequently, linear regression
broader range of variables and issues, many analysis, which was for a while the almost
of which are difficult to quantify. This helps standard technique used in economic research,
the researcher understand the dynamics of a is being increasingly supplemented by factor,
relationship – how it actually operates (what path, cluster, maximum likelihood, and meta-
some call ‘getting into the little black box’). analysis.
Although quantitative research may indicate There are national differences. American
that factors A and B are correlated, unless sociologists make greater use of quantitative
the data are longitudinal it may be hard to techniques than do those elsewhere, while
determine the direction of causation, thereby many continental European sociologists shun
yielding low internal validity. Qualitative them altogether, arguing that these techniques
research can often tell us something about merely deal with superficial aspects of under-
causation. Further, it typically yields a richer lying problems. Indeed, some IR researchers
picture of actual behavior than quantitative reject quantitative analysis as suggesting
research, and so may be more useful in policy spurious and misleading exactitude. In other
making. words, they argue that statistical relations
lack external validity and do not accurately
reflect the real world’s complexity. A related
Disciplinary, theoretical, and
approach argues that valid research should
national backgrounds
involve ‘subjects’who participate in gathering
Industrial Relations, broadly defined, involves and evaluating the data, such as in ‘action
contributions from a variety of cognate research’.
disciplines and fields. Not only do researchers This diversity complicates scholarly com-
from different disciplinary backgrounds look munication. The problem is no longer one
at different questions, but they use different of national languages, but of differences in
methods. Their methods influence the nature frames of reference and theoretical paradigms.
of their findings. Though seemingly translated into English,
Methods change over time. The big change much German sociology is virtually unintelli-
in IR in recent years has been the increasing gible to US readers, even to US sociologists.
use of quantitative methods. Psychologists Furthermore, many of the technical terms
were among the first to quantify, then that constitute the common discourse of post-
economists, and, more recently, institutional modernists are meaningless to quantitative
IR researchers and labor historians. Early labor economists. Take for example Keenoy’s
industrial sociologists specialized in ethnog- (1999: 1) view of ‘HRM as a Hologram’ or his
raphy and case studies; now they often ‘attempt to analyze the problem of HRM ... in
use quantitative methods. Today, scholars in terms of the intrinsic conceptual-theoretical,
most areas studying employment engage in empirical, representative, and institutional
calculations. ambiguities which characterize the discourse
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 175

and practices of HRM [which, he argues] without numerical data get published. Editors
stem from the epistemological limitations of also want to publish ‘new’ research; mere
modernistic methodologies’. Few economists replication of previous studies rarely gets into
think in terms like this (and for some print. Consequently, favored articles are based
this language is almost undecipherable). The on small ‘advances’on previous studies which
reverse is also true: most post-modernists are are heavily supported by statistics. The net
mathematically illiterate (and proud of it). Yet effect is to discourage inductive research.
both deal with the world of work. They might On the other hand, in the US, the Journal
learn from each other. of Labor Research and the Labor Studies
Journal both publish significant numbers of
qualitative articles, while the same is true of
Values and personal interests
the Industrial Relations Journal in the UK
IR is a normative, value-oriented field. and the Journal of Industrial Relations in
Many IR scholars identify with unions. Australia.
Consequently, until recently, unions received
more attention than management. By contrast,
Technology
those who receive part of their income
as management consultants are likely to Computers have revolutionized the social
deal with managerial problems and from a sciences. They have made it possible to store
managerial perspective. And even those who and analyze large amounts of data cheaply,
try to be neutral are often charged with being as long as these data can be reduced to
pro-union (Brown, 1998). symbolic (largely numerical) form. In recent
One of the personal advantages of more years, there has been not only a phenom-
traditional forms of face-to-face research, enal growth in the capacity of computer
such as ethnography and interviewing, was hardware, but also an increase in supporting
that it provided the researcher with a sense software – particularly in statistical programs
of psychological involvement that may be that allow a wider range of data to be
largely lacking in the computerized study of analyzed. Calculations that previously might
data-sets. The passion and excitement that have taken hundreds of hours can now
once characterized IR may be lost, and those be done almost instantaneously. Given the
who crave personal involvement or desire to availability of computers and the growing
change the world may pick other fields of number of databases, quantitative research
study. can be converted into article form without
researchers ever leaving their offices. On the
other hand, it discourages qualitative research,
Journal preferences
and it may lead to attempts to categorize
In academia, it is increasingly the case, squishy data into hard numbers, for example,
particularly for younger researchers, that they by coding interviews into rigid categories.
publish or perish. The preferences of journal Despite its presumed objectivity, the coding
editors carry great weight. Recent changes process is very open to being influenced by
in British research funding arrangements, research biases.
for instance, have increased the kudos for
publishing in a small set of ‘front-rank’
Availability of data
journals. This editorial system generally
encourages safe, narrow articles that can Data availability has a strong impact on
pass the scrutiny of often-hostile reviewers. the nature of IR research and on the
Most journals today seem to prefer highly methods used. National workplace surveys
empirical studies, heavily buttressed with in Australia and the UK, as well as a
statistics, to think-pieces with unorthodox series of somewhat similar but consider-
new ideas. Particularly in the US, few articles ably less comprehensive US studies, have
176 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

created a bonanza for scholars. These data unions and companies, as aggregates, and the
have facilitated a growing interest in both state.
workplace studies and the use of quantitative The different disciplines related to IR focus
techniques which permit hypothesis testing. on different levels: economics and psychol-
The ready availability of statistics showing ogy on individuals, sociology on groups
votes in National Labor Relations Board and larger aggregations, and political science
(NLRB) elections contributed to a plethora on countries. It should not be surprising,
of US research on voting behavior. Later, therefore, that the recent spurt in interest
the decision to stop collecting data on all in comparative international relations has
but large US strikes has inhibited studies of contributed to the fact that some of the most
strike incidence. Similarly, the availability innovative IR work is being done by scholars
of surveys of the population generally (such who have backgrounds in political science (for
as the Panel Study of Income Dynamics example, Thelan, 2004).
in the US and the Socio Economic Panel Different techniques are more appropriate
in Germany) has encouraged studies that for research at each level. Further, different
can utilize these data and has discouraged insights emerge depending on the level
other kinds of research. In other words, studied. Thus, if one is concerned with
the availability of potential answers has strikes at the individual level, one looks at
encouraged questions. phenomena such as workers’ needs, attitudes,
A lamentable tendency among some and frustrations. At the workplace level, the
researchers when good quantitative data are behavior of specific members of management,
not available is to test a hypothesis by select- the social structure of the group, and perhaps
ing the best alternative (technically ‘proxy’) the nature of technology may be most ger-
around. Sometimes, this best alternative is mane. To study these issues, ethnography may
bad, in other words, construct validity is low. be appropriate. At the plant level, fine-grained
This is like the drunk looking for lost keys ethnographic studies may be too difficult;
under the street lamp because this is where hence, plant-level research may involve case
the light is. studies. At higher levels, quantitative analyses
An unfortunate consequence of the greater of economic data (profits, changes in the
availability of survey data (as well as of com- cost of living, and the like) may be more
puters to analyze them) is that IR researchers relevant. And still other variables must be
are now less likely to go out into the field to considered in comparing strike rates among
talk to real workers and real managers. One countries, such as their histories, economies,
danger, particularly for a problem-oriented and governmental institutions.
field, is that important insights are lost
and overly simplistic conclusions accepted.
Interdisciplinary research
A second danger is that the IR literature will
lose the colorful descriptions that were once IR claims to be interdisciplinary. There
common. are obvious advantages to utilizing several
disciplines, in that each discipline can provide
its own insights and so reduce the likelihood
Level of analysis
of narrow, single-dimensional perspectives on
Studies differ in the organizational levels complex, multidimensional problems. Unfor-
they examine: the individual worker; the tunately, these advantages are rarely garnered
workplace; the enterprise, firm, industry, or in practice. Indeed, there are many examples
country; or the entire world? Traditionally, of failure, despite highly laudable attempts to
the primary focus of IR has been on unions, break down disciplinary barriers.
management, and especially their collective There are two main types of interdisci-
bargaining relationships. A second stream of plinary research. The first involves a single
research dealt with the relationships between researcher (or a research team from a common
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 177

discipline) drawing on a variety of disciplines. same phenomena, but fail to communicate


The second involves several researchers, each with each other because they use differ-
from a different discipline. To date, neither ent languages and read different journals.
type has been common in IR research, though Psychologists and economists, for example,
this may be changing, especially as the train- study labor turnover, sometimes using equiv-
ing of IR students gets broader. Generally, the alent data, yet they rarely cite each other.
first type has been more fruitful. Researchers ‘Organizational justice,’ especially ‘procedu-
from different backgrounds may have trouble ral justice,’ is one of the most popular subjects
communicating, and could therefore produce in micro-organizational behavior (Greenberg,
what some have called ‘the cross-sterilization 1990). Much of the research in that field has
of the social sciences’. involved IR issues, such as compensation,
Among the few examples of research that promotion, and discipline. Yet, despite its
extends beyond discipline-specific bound- obvious relevance, little research in the
aries is Getman et al. (1976). In this study, procedural justice tradition has appeared in IR
two lawyers and a psychologist employed publications or has been cited by those who
an attitude survey to test legal propositions call their field IR.
regarding the impact of management behavior One of the major factors inhibiting inter-
on workers’ voting patterns. Similarly, some disciplinary research is that it takes research
economists, such as Freeman and Medoff from the comfort of the shared assumptions
(1984) and Farber and Krueger (1993), have and ways of seeing and doing that exists within
introduced attitudinal variables into their disciplinary boundaries. In particular, the cri-
equations. teria used to judge a ‘good’ piece of research
In some cases, IR scholars have borrowed differ between disciplines, and few studies
from other fields. For example, the concept of satisfy all of them. For example, Getman
‘union commitment’, is derived from an anal- et al.’s highly policy-relevant study was
ogous concept, ‘organizational commitment’, criticized by economists on methodological
widely employed in organizational behavior grounds (Dickens, 1983), and by researchers
(see, for example, Gordon et al., 1980). outside of economics for lacking in realism
Somewhat similarly, Walton and McKersie (Siegel, 1998). Psychologists would no doubt
(1965) drew on game theory and psychology, regard the attitudinal variables in Freeman and
but applied its conceptual apparatus directly to Medoff’s and Farber and Krueger’s work as
collective bargaining. Kelly (1998) builds his rather primitive.
analysis of union behavior partly on sociologi- The advent of workplace IR surveys was
cal theories of collective action. On the whole, expected to encourage interdisciplinary anal-
however, IR researchers have been rather ysis. Representative sample surveys, it was
parochial. Some are uncomfortable with any hoped, would interact complementarily with
conceptualization that treats IR as only one non-generalizable case studies. Yet the British
form of a broader socio-economic category. experience is that little inter-disciplinarity has
An example is the reluctance of researchers occurred. Much of the analysis of the early
to follow up on Walton and McKersie’s survey data has been conducted by economists
somewhat theoretical analysis of bargaining using a narrow range of quantitative methods,
behavior, thus permitting the new academic and very little has been undertaken by
field of negotiations and conflict resolution to IR specialists themselves (Millward, 1993).
develop with little IR participation (and few Indeed, some of the latter have been critical
jobs for IR academicians). Similarly, IR has of survey data, arguing that it fails to capture
made little use so far of the highly relevant the true complexity and dynamic character of
concepts of transaction cost economics or British IR (McCarthy, 1994); in other words,
sociological theories of collective action. that it lacks construct validity.
A common problem is that researchers But there is some room for hope. There
from different disciplines may deal with the is, for example, a largely new approach to
178 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

compensation and careers that links psy- as revealed by surveys or on deviant ones
chology, sociology, and economics, making (Lipset et al., 1956). Another approach is
use of such concepts as procedural justice; to administer surveys of workplace practices
agency, tournament, expectancy, and equity to key union and management leaders in a
theories; organizational ecology; and com- large sample of organizations and then survey
mitment. Few of the scholars contributing to the attitudes toward these policies of all the
this development identify their field as IR, workers in a small sample of firms taken from
however. the larger sample. In this way, the larger study
can determine the extent of a practice, while
the smaller ones look at its impacts.
Multi-method research
A growing number of IR studies make use of
Data sources
more than one method. This has numerous
advantages. First, through ‘triangulation’, IR scholars gather their data from a variety
it helps validate findings. If two methods of sources. Those who are interested in
lead to the same conclusion, the findings bargaining behavior may set up laboratory
are more robust than if one method alone experiments or perhaps observe real union-
is used. If they disagree, more research management bargaining sessions (in the
may be necessary. The findings of the ethnographic tradition). Those whose research
International Motor Vehicle Project were focuses on workers’ attitudes favor attitude
based largely on managers’ responses to surveys. Institutional researchers examin-
detailed questionnaires (McDuffie and Pil, ing union-management behavior traditionally
1995). But to ensure that the questions engage in case studies (but more recently may
were understood and answered accurately, also use workplace surveys). In doing research
the researchers personally visited most of the of this type, researchers typically gather their
plants around the world. Second, if several own data. Economists, by contrast, typically
methods are employed, each may provide base their research on data collected by others,
different nuances or insights. Consequently, usually a government agency. However, a
the ultimate findings are richer. And if the few economists have conducted carefully
results differ, totally new questions may be controlled field experiments designed to mea-
raised. Third, one method can be used to sure the impact of various forms of training
improve another. Focus groups, for example, and income supplements on the employment
can be used to help design survey questions. history of disadvantaged workers. And there
Case studies can help improve causal models is a growing field of experimental economics
used in quantitative studies. Experimental that utilizes laboratory experiments to study
methods can be used to evaluate different economic behavior, such as risk taking.
econometric models. A hallmark of traditional IR research was
Fourth, one method can lead to another that scholars tended to collect their own
when the techniques are used in sequence, data. A major advantage of gathering one’s
one after another, rather than simultaneously. own data is that the nature of the data
Thus, one study may be ‘nested’ within collected and the data-collecting technique
another. Case studies may be used at first can be tailored to fit the questions being asked
to suggest relationships, and, afterward, (in other words, there may be high construct
surveys or other quantitative measures can be and internal validity). On the other hand, it
employed to determine the extent to which is generally cheaper to use data collected
they can be ‘generalized’. Alternatively, if a by others. Further, there is the advantage
survey finds that X is correlated with Y, case of transparency: if generally available data
studies can be used to get into ‘the black box’ are used, other researchers can repeat and
and analyze the dynamics of this relationship. check on the original researcher’s findings.
Case studies may be run on typical examples, Researchers who collect their own data may
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 179

bias the questions they ask so as to get the from 17 per cent in 1967 to 57 per cent in 1997.
answers they want. What ethnographers and According to both studies, articles which
case study collectors ‘see’ may be heavily are purely descriptive or purely theoretical
influenced by their own expectations and (without data) have become increasingly rare
values. This is a serious limitation. in Anglo–Saxon journals but, according to
Frege, still common in IB.
Looking back to 1967, Whitfield and
SOME EVIDENCE OF CHANGE Strauss found a trend away from policy
oriented research and toward discipline-
Evidence as to how the nature of research is building in both countries, the proportion of
changing is provided by two studies, both of articles of the former type in the four main
which looked at articles appearing in major journals increasing from 34 per cent in 1967
academic IR journals. The first (Whitfield and to 65 per cent in 1997. Further, the proportion
Strauss, 2000) examined articles appearing at of papers using data which contained mul-
15 year intervals (1952, 1967, 1982, and 1997) tivariate analysis grew quite rapidly so that,
in two British journals, the British Journal of by 1997 they constituted the vast majority
Industrial Relations (BJIR) and the Industrial of papers published in US journals. Taking
Relations Journal (IRJ), two American ones, the four longest-running journals as a whole,
the Industrial and Labor Relations Review the proportion of papers involving data that
(ILRR) and Industrial Relations (IR) as utilized multivariate analysis increased from
well as one each from Canada, Relations 6 per cent to 47 per cent. This shift was more
Industrielles (RI) and Australia, the Journal of pronounced in the US-based journals, but less
Industrial Relations (JIR). The second study, so in JIR.
(Frege, 2005) looked at the same British and The overall proportion of articles on what
US journals, but instead of Canadian and Whitfield and Strauss call ‘union management
Australian journals, to provide an illustration relations’ and Frege calls ‘industrial relations
of continental European developments, it topics’has remained roughly constant over the
looked at Industrielle Beziehungen (IB). This years. Whitfield and Strauss noted, however,
study compared the entire set of articles a marked contrast between journals in this
appearing in the 1970s with those appearing respect. ILRR witnessed a substantial decline
in the 1990s. Both studies coded the articles in the proportion of articles on union-
under a number of headings, most of which are management relations from 58 per cent in
listed in the attached tables. Tables 9.1 and 9.2 1967 to 20 per cent in 1997, whereas the
are based on the Whitfield and Strauss paper other three journals all saw a corresponding
(but only the four oldest of these journals increase. In short, IR resembled BJIR and JIR
(BJIR, ILRR, IR, and JIR). Table 9.3 is based rather than ILRR in this area.
on Frege’s paper. Frege classifies articles by ‘analytic level’,
The findings of the two studies are broadly with one category being ‘micro’. US jour-
comparable. Some of the differences can be nals had more micro articles during both
ascribed to differences in the years covered, of her chosen periods, and the proportion
though we suspect that important parts are due of these increased from the 1970s to the
to differences in coding rules. Both studies 1990s. Meanwhile, the proportion in Britain
found a marked trend away from inductive declined. The closest Whitfield and Strauss
to deductive research, with the US journals equivalent to Frege’s ‘micro’ is ‘individ-
moving further than those based in Australia, ual/household’. The proportion of papers in
Britain, and Germany. Whitfield and Strauss this category has gone up in both countries;
found this trend to be somewhat stronger however, only in the ILRR did they constitute
than did Frege; the proportion of articles a majority of data-based articles.
published in the former’s four longest running Whitfield and Strauss discovered that only a
journals classified as deductive increased small proportion (16 per cent) of studies used
Table 9.1 Nature of papers published in main IR journals
1967 1982 1997
BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total
Articles coded 22 19 19 16 76 24 27 19 23 93 21 30 22 17 90
Basic
approach
Deductive 3 (14%) 4 (21%) 4 (21%) 2 (13%) 13 (17%) 8 (33%) 21 (78%) 16 (84%) 4 (17%) 41 (44.0%) 10 (48%) 26 (87%) 15 (68%) 0 (0%) 51 (57%)
Inductive 18 (82%) 14 (82%) 7 (37%) 10 (62%) 49 (65%) 13 (54%) 6 (22%) 2 (11%) 19 (83%) 50 (54%) 11 (52%) 4 (13%) 7 (32%) 17 (100%) 39 (43%)
Unclassified 1 (4%) 1 (5%) 8 (42%) 4 (25%) 14 (18%) 3 (13%) 0 (0%) 1 (5%) 0 (0%) 4 (4%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%)
Primary
Orientation
Discipline 10 (46%) 9 (47%) 5 (26%) 2 (13%) 26 (34%) 15 (63%) 18 (67%) 16 (84%) 9 (39%) 58(62%) 9 (43%) 28 (93%) 17 (77%) 4 (23%) 58 (65%)
orientation
Policy orientation 11 (50%) 10 (53%) 6 (32%) 9 (56%) 36 (47%) 5 (21%) 7 (26%) 3 (16%) 13 (57%) 28 (30%) 9 (43%) 1 (3%) 4 (18%) 13 (77%) 27 (30%)
Unclassified 1 (44%) 0 (0%) 8 (42%) 5 (31%) 14 (18%) 4 (16%) 2 (7%) 0 (0%) 1 (4%) 7 (8%) 3 (14%) 1 (3%) 1 (5%) 0 (0%) 5 (5%)
Data
Yes 12 (55%) 18 (95%) 11 (58%) 16 (100%) 57 (75%) 21 (87%) 27 (100%) 17 (90%) 21 (91%) 86 (92%) 20 (95%) 30 (100%) 20 (91%) 17(100%) 87 (97%)
No 10 (45%) 1 (5%) 8 (42%) 0 (0%) 19 (25%) 3 (13%) 0 (0%) 2 (10%) 2 (9%) 7 (8%) 1 (5%) 0 (0%) 2 (9%) 0 (0%) 3 (3%)
Subject area
Union- 12 (55%) 11 (58%) 3 (16%) 6 (38%) 32 (42%) 15 (63%) 9 (33%) 7 (37%) 8 (35%) 39 (42%) 16 (76%) 6 (20%) 8 (36%) 11 (65%) 41 (46%)
management
relations
Source: Whitfield and Strauss (2000).
Table 9.2 Type of data and methods of analysis used
1967 1982 1997
BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total BJIR ILRR IR JIR Total
Articles with data 12 18 11 16 57 21 27 17 21 86 20 30 20 17 87
Type of data
Quantitative 6 (50%) 10 (56%) 8 (73%) 2 (13%) 26 (46%) 16 (76%) 23 (85%) 14 (82%) 12 (57%) 68 (79%) 13 (65%) 29(97%) 17 (57%) 3 (18%) 62 (71%)
Non-quantitative 6 (50%) 10 (56%) 8 (73%) 2 (13%) 26 (46%) 5 (24%) 4 (15%) 3 (18%) 9 (43%) 32 (37%) 7 (35%) 1 (3%) 3 (15%) 14 (82%) 38 (35%)
Multivariate analysis 0 (0%) 2 (11%) 1 (9%) 1 (6%) 4 (7%) 4 (19%) 20 (74%) 13 (76%) 4 (19%) 41 (48%) 6 (30%) 25(83%) 17 (85%) 2 (12%) 41 (47%)
Data collected by:
Author 3 (25%) 3 (17%) 3 (27%) 11 (69%) 20 (35%) 10 (48%) 6 (22%) 7 (41%) 7 (33%) 41 (48%) 14 (70%) 6 (20%) 6 (30%) 7 (41%) 49 (56%)
Other 2 (17%) 8 (44%) 6 (55%) 5 (31%) 21 (37%) 7 (33%) 16 (59%) 10 (59%) 8 (38%) 38 (44%) 6 (30%) 24(80%) 15 (75%) 1 (6%) 39 (45%)
Case study 2 (17%) 4 (22%) 3 (27%) 5 (31%) 14 (25%) 7 (33%) 5 (19%) 4 (24%) 3 (14%) 24 (28%) 6 (30%) 1 (3%) 2 (10%) 6 (35%) 20 (23%)
Multi-method 0 (0%) 2 (11%) 3 (27%) 0 (0%) 5 (9%) 3 (14%) 2 (7%) 4 (24%) 4 (19%) 14 (16%) 5 (25%) 2 (7%) 4 (20%) 3 (18%) 18 (20%)
Source: Whitfield and Strauss (2000).
Table 9.3 Industrial Relations research methods
1970 1990
BJIR IRJ ILRR IR Total BJIR IRJ ILRR IR IB Total
Broad research topics
IR topics 42 (43%) 42 (62%) 57 (52%) 43 (36%) 184 (47%) 123 (63%) 143 (73%) 77 (32%) 71 (36%) 84 (92%) 498 (54%)
HR topics 27 (29%) 16 (24%) 19 (17%) 42 (36%) 104 (27%) 44 (23%) 36 (19%) 62 (26%) 54 (28%) 1 (1%) 197 (21%)
Labor market topics 25 (27%) 10 (15%) 33 (30%) 34 (29%) 102 (26%) 28 (14%) 16 (8%) 104 (43%) 70 (36%) 6 (6%) 224 (24%)
Total 94 (100%) 68 (100%) 109 (100%) 119(100%) 390 (100%) 195 (100%) 195 (100%) 243 (100%) 195 (100%) 91 (100%) 919 (100%)
Nature of Article
Empirical descriptive 20 (21%) 18 (26%) 20 (18%) 25 (21 %) 83 (21%) 56 (29%) 86 (44%) 10 (4%) 17 (9%) 12 (13%) 181 (20%)
Empirical inductive 30 (32%) 12 (17%) 33 (30%) 41 (35%) 116 (30%) 56 (29%) 37 (19%) 146 (60%) 94 (48%) 20 (22%) 353 (38%)
Empirical deductive 9 (9%) 11 (16%) 29 (27%) 15 (13%) 64 (16%) 38 (19%) 21 (11%) 71 (29%) 59 (30%) 5 (6%) 194 (21%)
Thinkpiece/essay 20 (21%) 19 (28%) 18 (17%) 25 (21%) 82 (21%) 40 (21%) 48 (25%) 12 (5%) 17 (9%) 39 (43%) 156 (17%)
Theory 15 (16%) 8 (12%) 9 (8%) 13 (11%) 45 (12%) 5 (3%) 3 (2%) 4 (2 %) 8 (4%) 15 (17%) 35 (4 %)
Total 94 (100%) 68 (100%) 119 (100%) 119 (100%) 390 (100%) 195 (100%) 195 (100%) 243 (100%) 195 (100%) 91 (100%) 919 (100%)
Methodology
Qualitative 19 (32%) 20 (49%) 16 (20%) 19 (24%) 74 (28%) 58 (39%) 96 (67%) 11 (5%) 20 (12%) 24 (59%) 209 (28.6%)
Quantitative 40 (68%) 21 (51%) 66 (80%) 62 (76%) 189 (72%) 92 (61%) 48 (33%) 216 (95%) 150 (88%) 17 (41%) 523 (71.4%)
Total 59 (100%) 41 (100%) 82 (100%) 81 (100%) 263 (100%) 150 (100%) 144 (100%) 227 (100%) 170 (100%) 41 (100%) 732 (100%)
Dataset size
Small 36 (61%) 36 (88%) 50 (61%) 49 (60%) 171 (65%) 89 (59%) 122 (85%) 51 (22%) 64 (38%) 30 (81%) 356 (49%)
Large 23 (39%) 5 (12%) 32 (39%) 32 (40%) 92 (35%) 61 (41%) 22 (15%) 176 (78%) 106 (62%) 7 (19%) 372 (51%)
Total 59 (100%) 41 (100%) 82 (100%) 81 (100%) 263 (100%) 150 (100%) 144 (100%) 227 (100%) 170 (100%) 37 (100%) 728 (100%)
Analytical level
Macro 22 (37%) 9 (22%) 17 (21%) 18 (22%) 66 (25%) 27 (18%) 49 (34%) 20 (9%) 24 (14%) 6 (13%) 126 (17%)
Sector 11 (19%) 10 (24%) 21 (26%) 24 (30%) 66 (25%) 34 (23%) 31 (22%) 26 (11%) 30 (18%) 6 (13%) 127 (17%)
Firm 14 (24%) 16 (39%) 11 (13%) 17 (21%) 58 (22%) 73 (48 %) 51 (35%) 65 (29%) 60 (35%) 28 (62%) 277 (38%)
Micro 12 (20%) 6 (15%) 33 (40%) 22 (27%) 73 (28%) 16 (11%) 13 (9%) 116 (51%) 56 (33%) 5 (11%) 206 (28%)
Total 59 (100%) 41 (100%) 82 (100%) 81 (100%) 263 (100%) 150 (100%) 144 (100%) 227 (100%) 170 (100%) 45 (100%) 736 (100%)
Source: Frege (2005).
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 183

more than one method in 1997, and even fewer that might have grown out of the field’s more
did in earlier years. They also found that, traditional approach (but which that approach
in 1997, data for the overwhelming majority did not itself encompass). Whatever the net
of articles appearing in the two US journals effect of these changes, it is clear that IR
was collected by ‘others’. Outside the US, it scholars have still not settled on a way of
was more typically collected by the authors undertaking research that is both distinctive
themselves. and widely-accepted. The search for the Holy
These two studies largely support our Grail goes on.
book’s original observations. We see no
reason to change them. Specifically, they
indicate that our field is extremely hetero- THE FUTURE
geneous, which is possibly both its main
strength and its main weakness. There are In 1998, we argued that the future advance-
substantial cross-national differences in the ment of IR as a field of study required that
way in which research is undertaken. The US more attention should be paid to four main
has clearly seen the greatest move toward the areas:
more deductive, discipline-oriented approach,
though ILRR seems to have reflected this 1) concepts;
more than IR. Of the non-US journals, 2) scope;
both the Australian JIR and the German IB 3) title;
have remained more committed to publishing 4) research design.
papers in the older Industrial Relations
tradition than is the British BJIR.
Yet taking the field as a whole, there have
Conceptual developments
been moves over time away from inductive,
policy-oriented, macro-focused research and In our view, conceptual development in the
toward that which is deductive, discipline- IR area has stalled. If anything, scholars from
oriented, and micro-focused in all countries other fields have increasingly studied topics
studied. The use of multi-method approaches which traditionally were considered to be in
is still the exception rather than the rule, but IR’s balliwick, but now using these other
does show signs of becoming more prominent. fields’ analytic tools. Further, as Jarley et al.
Secondary analysis of data-sets is becoming (2001) document, a high percentage of the
more common, reflecting the many changes articles appearing in the main US IR journals
in the nature of the subject and the broader are written by scholars whose identification
environment. is not with IR (at least they don’t belong to
There has therefore clearly been consider- the field’s primary professional organization,
able change in the nature of IR research in then called the Industrial Relations Research
recent years, but whether this is a good or Association). This causes the authors ‘to
bad thing is debatable. Clearly, the field has question whether IR can sustain a unique
adapted to the availability of powerful data- scholarly community…[and whether] … IR
sets, and has made considerable use of the journals will continue to provide a venue for
range of new analytical techniques that have sustaining a coherent, cumulative literature
emerged in the economic and social sciences. that will distinguish the field from other areas’
But, to some extent, this has been at the cost (p. 343). But as Kaufman (2004) suggests, the
of losing its close connections both with the IR field in the UK may be more cohesive than
people and institutions studied and with the that in the US, and so less likely to change.
policy implications of the research findings. A key contribution to the discussion of
And there is a prima facie case that it has conceptual tools is Paul Edwards’ recent
resulted in a failure to develop a broader, (2005) paper, which built on our original spec-
multi-method, approach to empirical research ulations. The key theme of this paper is that
184 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

one of IR’s main strengths is its sensitivity to


IR’s scope
context. In short, this means that how Factor A
influences Factor B depends on other Factors, In 1998, we suggested that IR should return
C, D, and E (psychologists call them mod- to its earlier emphasis on policy. To our
erators). Greater context-sensitivity, Edwards mind, there has been little positive change
argues, will facilitate further methodological in this respect, if anything the reverse. In
progress, build stronger links with the other terms of subject-matter, we have definitely
social sciences, and possibly result in greater seen a major expansion in the range of
policy relevance. subjects examined in recent years, and IR
Context-specificity, however, comes at research now covers far more than just union-
quite a cost. It inevitably fragments the management relations. However, much of
subject-area. Studies undertaken in given this new research is done at arm’s length
settings help us to understand the complexity from the concerns of key policy-makers.
of relationships within that particular set- Indeed, the current political situation, at least
ting, but may provide few insights as to in the US, makes it unlikely that academic
what is happening elsewhere. Often single- policy recommendations would be reflected
situation research is justified as contributing in practice. This reduces scholars’ incentives
to the development of middle-range theory, to make them. In short, it would seem that IR
but typically the theoretical contribution of research has broadened its scope, while not
such highly-focused studies is minimal. IR noticeably increasing its involvement with the
still lacks an overall theory. This may be real world that it seeks to understand.
strength, but on balance it may be even
more a weakness. Consequently, IR people
The end of IR as a distinct field?
typically only have fragments of theory with
which to work, and they lack the more all- The trend toward abandoning the term ‘Indus-
embracing theoretical frameworks that those trial Relations’ has continued, especially in
in related fields and disciplines have at their the US. Where it is not being displaced by
disposal. Human Resource Management, it is being
Context-specificity also gives an air to the replaced by Work Studies or, more commonly,
field that suggests that it is a second-order Employment Relations. Among the organi-
subject-area that uncovers uncomfortable zations changing their name are the former
facts that others explain and develop. For Industrial Relations Research Association in
example, many of the key features of the the US (now the Labor and Employment
so-called new institutional labor economics Relations Association) and the former British
are based around stylized/simplified facts Workplace Industrial Relations Surveys (now
that have been developed from the work of Workplace Employment Relations Surveys).
IR researchers, such as those related to the How long before the other leading institutions
internal labor market concept. While some in the field follow suit? The new names imply
IR scholars have attempted to develop alter- that IR covers more than labor-relations. But
native, more realistic, theoretical approaches does it all imply that IR is no longer a distinct
around such context-specific research (most field?
notably, for example, Michael Piore), these
efforts have been overwhelmed by the work
Research design
of those attempting to integrate their existing
and less realistic theoretical frameworks with In 1998, we argued that IR should place
what is typically a narrow conception of greater emphasis on research design; for
the facts outlined by the context-focused example, multi-method studies which permit
researchers. The advent of Personnel Eco- triangulation should be encouraged. Some
nomics is a prime example of this in action progress has definitely been made in this area.
(Lazear, 2000). Younger scholars, in particular, are thinking
CHANGING TRADITIONS IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS RESEARCH 185

more broadly about research design, and are Edwards, P. (2005) ‘The Challenging but Promising
crossing the qualitative/quantitative divide Future of Industrial Relations: Developing Theory
more often. This may reflect broader and and Method in Context-Sensitive Research’, Industrial
more systematic research training, or merely a Relations Journal, 36 (4): 264–82.
change in the background of those researching Farber, H. S. and Krueger, A. B. (1993) ‘Union
Membership in the United States: The Decline
in the subject-area, away from those who
Continues’, in Bruce Kaufman and Morris Kleiner,
enter from the practitioner domain. Purely
(eds) Employee Representation: Alternatives and
descriptive work is being replaced by that Future Directions. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations
which is avowedly analytical. In our view, Research Association.
this is the area in which greatest and positive Freeman, R.B and Medoff, J.L (1984) What do unions
change is occurring and which offers the most do? New York : Basic Books.
scope for the future advancement of a field that Frege, C. (2005) ‘Varieties of Industrial Relations
has made and continues to make major and Research: Take-over, Convergence or Divergence?’
distinctive contributions to our understanding British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (2):
of the world of work. 179–207.
Getman, J.G., Goldberg, S.B., and Herman, J.B. (1976)
Union Representation Elections: Law and Reality.
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Gordon, M.E., Philpot, J.W., Burt, R.E., Thompson, C.A.,
and Spiller, W.E. (1980) ‘Commitment to the Union –
The authors would like to thank all of the Development of a Measure and an Examination
authors of Researching the World of Work: of its Correlates’, Journal of Applied Psychology,
Strategies and Methods in Studying Industrial 65: 479–99.
Relations (1998) for stimulating a lot of the Greenberg, J. (1990) ‘Organisational Justice: Yesterday,
ideas that have gone into this paper and Paul Today and Tomorrow’, Journal of Management,
Blyton, Dan Cornfield, and Jack Fiorito for 16 (2): 399–432.
Hancock, K.J. (1985) Australian Industrial Relations Law
extremely perceptive comments on an earlier
and Systems: Report of the Committee of Review.
draft.
Canberra: AGPS.
Ichniowski, Casey, Levine, Davis, Olson, Craig,
and Strauss, George (eds) (2000) The American
REFERENCES Workplace: Skills, Compensation, and Employee
Involvement. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Brown, William. (1998) ‘Funders and Research: The Jarley, Paul, Chandler, Timothy, and Faulk, Larry
Vulnerability of the Subject’, in Keith Whitfield and (2001) ‘Maintaining a Scholarly Community: Casual
George Strauss (eds) Researching the World of Authorship and the State of IR Research’, Industrial
Work: Strategies and Methods in Studying Industrial Relations, 40 (2): 338–43.
Relations. Ithaca: ILR Press. pp. 267–86. Kaufman, Bruce. (2004) The Global Evolution of
Cappelli, Peter. (1985) ‘Theory Construction in IR and Industrial Relations. Geneva: International Labor
Some Implications for Research’, Industrial Relations, Office.
24 (1): 90–112. Keenoy, Tom (1999) ‘HRM as Hologram: A Polemic’,
Clawson, Dan. (2003) The Next Union Upsurge: Labor Journal of Management Studies, 36 (1): 1–23.
and the New Social Movements. Ithaca: ILR Press. Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi-
Commission on the Future of Worker-Management lization, Collectivism and Long Waves. Routledge:
Relations. (1994). Final Report. US Department of London.
Labor and US Department of Commerce. Lazear, E. P. (2000) ‘The Future of Personnel Economics’,
Commons, John, R. (1909) ‘American Shoemakers, Economic Journal, 110: 611–39.
1648–1895’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 24 Lipset, S.M., Trow, M.A., and Coleman, J.S. (1956) Union
(November): 39–98. democracy: the internal politics of the International
Dickens, W.T (1983) ‘The Effect of Company Campaigns Typographical Union. New York: Free Press.
on Certification Elections: Law and Reality Once Marginson, P. (1998) ‘The Survey Tradition in British
Again’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 36 (4): Industrial Relations Research’, British Journal of
560–75. Industrial Relations, 36 (3): 361–88.
186 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

McCarthy, W. (1994) ‘Of Hats and Cattle: or the and George Strauss (eds) Researching the World of
Limits of Macro-survey Research in Industrial Rela- Work: Strategies and Methods in Studying Industrial
tions’, Industrial Relations Journal, 25(4): 315–22, Relations. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
December. Strauss, George and Peter Feuille (1978) ‘Industrial
McDuffie, J. P. and Pill, F. (1995) The international Relations Research: A Critical Appraisal’, Industrial
assembly plant study: update on round two findings. Relations, 17 (3): 259–77.
Briefing paper, MIT International Motor Vehicle Thelan, Kathleen. (2004) How Institutions Evolve: The
Program, Cambridge, MA. Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Great Britain,
Millis, Harry and Royal Montgomery. The Economics of the United States and Japan. Cambridge: Cambridge
Labor. Vol. 1. Labor’s Progress and Some Basic Labor Universitry Press.
Problems ( 1938); Vol. II, Labor’s Risks and Social Voss, Kim and Sherman, Rachel. (2000) ‘Breaking the
Insurance (1938); Vol. III Organized Labor (1945). Iron Law of Oligarchy: Union Revitalization in the
New York: McGraw-Hill. American Labor Movement’, American Journal of
Millward, N. (1993) ‘Uses of the Workplace Industrial Sociology, 106 (2): 303–49.
Relations Surveys by British Labor Economists’. Walton R. E. and McKersie R. B. (1965) A Behavioral
CEP Discussion Papers 0145, Centre for Economic Theory of Labor Negotiation. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Performance, LSE. Whitfield, K. and Strauss, G. (eds) (1998) Researching
Royal Commission on Trade Unions and Employers’ the World of Work: Strategies and Methods in
Associations 1968). Report (London: HMSO). Studying Industrial Relations. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Schwab, D. P. (2005) Research Methods for Organiza- Whitfield, Keith and Strauss, George (2000) ‘Methods
tional Studies. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum. Matter: Changes in Industrial Relations Research
Siegel, Jay. (1998) ‘Industrial Relations Research and the and their Implications’, British Journal of Industrial
American Policy-Making Process’, In Keith Whitfield Relations, 38 (1): 141–52.
PART TWO

The Actors in Industrial Relations


10
Trade Union Morphology
Jack Fiorito and Paul Jarley

Morphology (dfn): Any scientific study of form and recent suggestions that unions may be con-
structure. From Webster’s New World Dictionary, ceptualized as networks that produce social
Second College Edition, 1984.
capital.
morphology [mawr-fol-uh-jee] – noun; the study We focus on national and local unions in
of the form or structure of anything [Origin: English speaking Anglo-Saxon nations, par-
1820–30; MORPHO- + -LOGY; first formed in
ticularly Britain and the US, with occasional
G. Dictionary.com Unabridged (v 1.01) Based on the
Random House Unabridged Dictionary, © Random references elsewhere. Unions are largely
House, Inc. 2006. embedded within and shaped by national
cultures, institutions, and legal systems
(Ebbinghaus and Visser, 1999), such that
attempts at broader comparisons tend to be
SCOPE limited to summary statistics, such as mem-
bership levels, that are most easily compared
Union structure traditionally connotes exter- (for example, Visser, 1989, 2006). There are a
nal (or horizontal) and internal (or vertical) few notable exceptions to this generalization,
dimensions (Fiorito et al., 1991). External of course, studies that expressly address union
structure refers to the scope of membership, structures across nations (for example, Visser
boundaries in terms of membership crite- and Waddington [1996] comparing Sweden,
ria and patterns distinguishing one union The Netherlands, and Britain). There are
from another, etc. Internal structure refers also collections of more in-depth analyses
to two sub-dimensions, governance (or repre- within specific nations, or that emphasize
sentation) and administration. In addition to particular union effects across nations on such
external and internal structure, this chapter topics as productivity or employer innovation
considers the nature or ‘soul’ (Budd, 2004: (for example, Addison and Schnabel, 2003).
137–57) of union representation, encompass- Other studies focus on federations of unions
ing the ‘servicing model’ vs. ‘organizing (for example, Ebbinghaus, 2003) or other
model’ debate, and in doing so, addresses structural units.
190 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

UNION GOALS AND STRATEGIC noting various anomalies of union structure,


CHOICE Strauss concedes that ‘it is the regularities that
should prove of greatest interest’ (1993: 2).
Structural functionalism suggests that any dis- In this modest but important sense, choices
cussion of structure should start with function matter. Ship captains and airline pilots have
or purpose. Unions dedicated primarily to little control over currents, winds, and others’
protecting and improving the well-being of choices, yet their choices on courses, speed,
their members or workers generally within and other variables are decisive, albeit not
an existing socio-economic order will likely entirely deterministic. Union leaders and the
choose different strategies and structures members who ultimately choose and direct
than those dedicated primarily to creating them may not enjoy the degree of control that
a new socio-economic order. The choice of ship captains and pilots do, but their choices
who to serve (for example, members vs. are still decisive. Although the case of any
workers generally) is also important. A union given union at a particular moment may be
emphasizing its members’ interests might best understood in terms of its idiosyncratic
have relatively less interest in works councils milieu, a more general understanding of union
or protective legislation than one emphasizing morphology requires appreciation for the role
broader interests. The choice of strategy itself of choice.
may affect structure as well. For example,
a strategy emphasizing collective bargaining
might favor narrower craft unions while EXTERNAL STRUCTURE
a strategy emphasizing political action or
mutual aid might favor more general unions. A primary distinction here is between craft vs.
This basic framework has been laid out industrial unions, with craft unions emphasiz-
previously (Fiorito et al., 1991). ing representation of particular skill groups
Given that union strategy is addressed in regardless of product or service produced, and
another chapter, we only wish to point out that industrial unions emphasizing representation
our discussion of morphology is embedded in for workers producing a particular product or
a broader framework – it does not assume that service without regard to worker skills. Other
a discussion of unions logically begins with representation bases including enterprise, reli-
structure. gion, ideology, geography, or ethnicity/tribe
As a further preliminary, we note that are important in some nations. Some of these
our emphasis on choice is deliberate. Others bases have been or still are important in some
(for example, Strauss, 1993) challenge that nations or within some niches in advanced
emphasis, noting that union structures are Anglo-Saxon nations at times (for example,
in many instances most easily understood Scottish teachers) and at different levels
as historical accidents, highly idiosyncratic, within labor movements (for example, the
affected by leader personalities and vari- peak federation or local level). Further, there
ous other nearly random influences, or as are occasional calls to reconsider establishing,
reactions to environmental factors such as or efforts to establish, unions on alternate
legislation affecting recognition, workforce bases (for example, Cobble (2001) on craft
feminization, and institutions such as mecha- unions and other forms), recent efforts to
nisms for union roles in providing government unite US Wal-Mart workers (for example,
funded benefits (Ebbinghaus and Visser, Associated Press, 2005), community-based
1999). All true! Strategic choices are not alliances or transformations for the British
made in a vacuum or a laboratory free from steel workers’ union (now ‘Community’ but
‘contaminants.’Nonetheless choices are made still mainly iron and steel workers (Trades
and actions and consequences follow from Union Congress, 2005)); also see, for exam-
those choices that differ from the actions ple, Jacoby and Verma (1992), ro ‘company
and consequences of other choices. Although unions’ in the US. The community-based
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 191

union form may have particular appeal for diversified their membership bases, often in
industry-based unions in declining industries response to employment declines within tra-
that traditionally dominated particular areas. ditional jurisdictions (for example, autos and
Historically, craft unions emerged by the steel) coupled with opportunistic organizing
early twentieth century as the dominant form or mergers (for example, Chaison, 2001).
in the nations of main interest, possibly due to Although the assertion that many national
an ‘organic solidarity’ arising from common unions today (in the US) are ‘general’ unions
training and skills and the ability of craft (Budd, 2005: 196) may be an overstatement,
unions to wage successful strikes due to dif- there is some merit in this as a description
ficulty in replacing skilled workers. As indus- of tendencies. In Australia, the statutorily
trialization proceeded, however, Taylorist encouraged consolidation of unions via min-
and Fordist reorganizations of work in imum size requirements for legal registration
many industries undermined traditional craft clearly pushed unions toward general forms.
distinctions, lending support to calls from Many of the more general unions have
Marxists and others for industry-based unions internalized formerly external structures, in
that were in socialist views better suited to effect preserving occupational or industrial
a broader sense of class consciousness rather identities within their union through divisions
than craft consciousness (Strauss, 1993). and similar sub-structures, making them a
In the US, the craft vs. industrial debate bit like mini-federations. In the past, unions
exploded in the 1930s with pro-industrial have used similar internalization of external
unionism forces (what became the Congress structure to address enterprise-specific issues
of Industrial Organizations or CIO) seceding (for example, GM and Ford ‘departments’
from the dominant labor federation, the within the US’ United Auto Workers). With
American Federation of Labor (AFL), orga- bargaining increasingly decentralized from
nizing millions of workers on an industrial industry levels to enterprise levels (see
basis and creating many well-known unions Chapter 21), enterprise dimensions within
such as the United Auto Workers (UAW). At union structures should grow in importance,
the same time, craft unions such as the Inter- and increasing roles for European works coun-
national Brotherhood of Electrical Workers cils will likely add momentum to this trend.
(IBEW) were in many instances compelled to Britain presents an interesting case in
accept a new reality and relax their opposition evolving union structures. Several national
to industrial unionism in practice if not in unions have made conscious efforts to
principle. The AFL–CIO merger of 1955 ‘re-brand’ themselves in response to mem-
reflected various influences but of greatest bership composition changes and perceived
immediate significance was its meaning in opportunities for survival and growth. One
terms of acceptance of industrial unionism. In of the first and better-known instances is
fact, industrial unions and industrial unionism Unison, the mainly public sector giant, but
(even within some nominal craft unions) more recent examples include Community,
tended to dominate organized labor for much Connect (mainly telecommunications), and
of the twentieth century. Amicus (mainly manufacturing, printing,
The continued dominance of either form and finance). These are recently formed or
is in serious doubt. In theory, market forces re-branded unions that can still be linked in a
in either product or labor markets remain a ‘union genealogy’ sense to specific industries,
strong impetus for craft or industrial forms by occupations or firms, but their intent seems to
influencing bargaining structures needed ‘to be to evolve away from their roots. The GMB
take wages out of competition’ (Commons, (‘Britain’s General Union’) is also an inter-
1909), but the legal and perhaps sociological esting case in asserting that its three-initial
concept of ‘community of interest’ seems a ‘name’doesn’t stand for anything in particular
less significant driver of union structure today in terms of craft or industry, although it once
than in past times. Many unions have clearly did (General, Municipal, and Boilermakers).
192 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

A further interesting British case for a ver.di (United Services Union) in Germany
slightly different reason is the construction illustrates that these trends extend beyond the
union, UCATT. While its acronym is more focal nations (Keller, 2005; also see Streeck
traditional in not spelling anything that would and Visser, 1997). In Britain, the number of
be mistaken for a word, and reflecting ‘major’ national unions (say with 10, 000 or
words (for example, ‘c’ for construction) more members) is just over 30 (Trades Union
that reveal its base, it is notable as the Congress, 2006). Even within these respective
modern descendant of various genuine trade numbers of unions, relatively small numbers
unions in an industry (along with railroads) account for a very substantial majority of
and nation famous for its narrow craft-based union membership. These ‘dominant players’
unions. In fact, some US writers still note have sometimes questioned whether ‘one
that Britain’s unique Industrial Relations (IR) union, one vote’-type executive committee
characteristics include numerous narrow craft structures are appropriate, particularly in
unions, but one could argue that British the US. To some extent the CWF secession
(or Australian) union consolidation toward reflected this tension (among other factors),
general unions is considerably more advanced with nearly all of the seceding unions coming
than that in the US. from the ranks of the AFL-CIO’s largest
Some American unions have taken smaller affiliates. The implications for worker choice
and sometimes faltering steps in this re- of representative may be interesting. On one
branding direction, notably in the cases of hand, consolidation suggests fewer choices
PACE and UNITE-HERE. In these cases, the and greater centralization of decision-making,
letters used to form the new ‘name’ still link but on the other, the CWF secession partly
the union to its roots, but the union seems to enabled by that consolidation may ultimately
have consciously chosen a name that can have lead to more competition for membership and
more general appeal as an acronym. Some more responsive union leadership.
might argue that names are unimportant, but Is industrial unionism doomed? Around
in these instances they seem to carry at 1950, it appeared that industrial unionism had
least symbolic importance, reflecting trends arrived to stay. Some may even have pointed
toward union generality in external structure. to Marxian predictions of its inevitability
PACE, however, was relatively short-lived and appropriateness. Now its future seems
as a national union, subsequently merging in doubt. The theoretical underpinnings in
into the United Steel Workers of America. terms of market structure are still relevant
Thus the generality trend continued, but the (see Commons, 1909), but in many industries
re-branding trend was abandoned in this globalization has undermined the viability of
instance. national industrial unions. Cornfield (2006)
Intertwined with this trend toward general recently argued that the CWF’s formation
unionism is a distinct consolidation trend. In represents resurgent ‘universalistic’ industrial
terms of membership, and more so in terms unionism, but the CWF unions tend to rep-
of organizing activity (Fiorito, 2003; Fiorito resent workers in local and regional product
and Jarley, 2003), union membership is being and service markets and have generally not
concentrated in smaller numbers of national faced the full force of globalization. It is
unions. (This despite the notable failure of still conceivable that industrial unionism will
the proposed merger between the UAW, resurge at a transnational level or through
IAM, and USWA that would have created more closely co-ordinated national units
a new ‘superunion’ roughly comparable to (if that is truly different than transnational
the German I.G. Metall.) The AFL-CIO had unionism). European economic integration
over 100 affiliates as recently as about 1980, and similar movements elsewhere will tend
but today claims about 60 affiliates (prior to to push in that direction. The obvious anchor
the Change to Win Federation [CWF] seces- on these trends is limited ‘like-consciousness’
sion). The recent creation through merger of across national borders, limiting workers’
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 193

sense of community of interest. This too these professional unions are fairly small
may change as information technology and and sometimes uncomfortable about being
globalization become more pervasive (for labeled ‘unions’ (preferring terms such as
example, as underscored by the ubiquitous ‘professional association’). In contrast to
Wal-Mart, McDonald’s, and Starbucks). It the devastating impact of globalization on
may be apt to note that the Industrial Workers many industrial unions, however, these unions
of the World have recently organized a few have generally benefited from restructuring
Starbucks shops in New York, although this of economies toward more professional work
may be of no real significance and merely (Wilson, 2006).
an instance of ‘boutique unionism’ under a Research in these areas is limited by
universalistic name (albeit a name with con- ignorance regarding union membership com-
siderable historical significance in the US). position. None of the focal nations can
An interesting question is whether indus- claim sufficient data to track changes in
trial unionism can resurge at a transnational this over time. In the US case, the last
level if its national counterparts evolve away time a government-sponsored survey solicited
from industrial forms. Some sort of ‘matrix’ information on the industrial composition
structure that would allow functional linkages of membership was 1979 (US Bureau of
along industrial lines between sections of Labor Statistics, 1980). Case studies both
general unions would seem appropriate, within nations (for example, Chaison, 2001;
perhaps something similar to the Building and Keller, 2005) and across nations (for example,
Construction Trades Department within the Chaison, 1996) have examined particular
AFL-CIO that links historically craft-based unions and small samples of cases that
unions based on their common industrial inter- provide observable events through mergers.
ests. With international conglomerate giants, Frequently these studies suggest that while
attention also is needed to linkages across theory and norms emphasize synergies and
industrial interests within firms. At least to resource rationales (for example, that larger
some extent the International Confederation unions can function more effectively and effi-
of Free Trade Unions’(ICFTU) ‘Global Union ciently), opportunism and idiosyncrasies such
Federations’ (formerly ‘Trade Secretariats’) as union internal politics and personalities
serve this role. play a large role. There have been very limited
Amidst this discussion emphasizing indus- efforts to link external structure to outcomes,
trial unionism and general unionism, it should with limited success (for example, Fiorito
be noted that ‘craft’unionism (broadly defined et al., 1995; Heery et al., 2003b; Maranto and
to include occupation-based unions beyond Fiorito, 1987).
traditional crafts) survives and thrives in
certain quarters. Indeed, many of the public
employee unions that have grown despite INTERNAL STRUCTURE
general union decline have a distinctly craft
orientation (for example, nurses, teachers). As noted earlier, internal structure consists
Increasingly, craft-oriented unions are in of two main dimensions, representation or
fact professional worker unions. In part governance (two sides of the same coin)
this reflects technological changes that have and administration. The first focuses on the
undermined some traditional crafts (for exam- extent that union members control their union
ple, factory prefabrication of components for- directly or through representative govern-
merly built on-site or technological advances ment, for instance, indirectly through their
such as paint spray-guns that have deskilled power to choose and change leaders. The
jobs in construction), while broader shifts second focuses on how efficient and effective
in advanced industrial economies toward the union is in achieving its goals.
professional services have favored growth The contours of representative and admin-
in professional worker ranks. In many cases istrative structures may be the result of
194 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

different contingencies (Jarley et al., 1997), A more extreme form of this debate
but the everyday tension between these two contrasts spontaneous worker actions with
features has long been noted (for example, organizationally sanctioned activity. Batstone
Child et al., 1973) in expressions such as (1988: 86) summarizes this debate within the
‘a union must at the same time be an army context of British workplace reforms and shop
and a town meeting’ (Muste, 1928). More steward roles in the 1970s:
recently, Heckscher (1988) alluded to unions
as associations trying to act like organizations. The bureaucratization thesis is part of a larger ethos
At least in the focal nations, unions have a of ‘workerism’ or ‘rank-and-filism’ which assumes
that the spontaneous actions of workers are to
strong democratic tradition, often reinforced be applauded while those of formal worker orga-
in statutes motivated by deviant cases or nizations are to be condemned; pre-reform shop
perceived abuses. stewards were an expression of spontaneity. Or,
A long-standing union democracy debate to put the matter another way, the thesis accepts
revolves around the allegedly inherent ten- that there exists a tension between the ‘movement’
and ‘organization’ features of trade unions and
dency of organizations, including unions, believes that the former is the more valid. While
toward oligarchy and conservatism, or accepting the high premium (apparently) placed on
Michels’ ‘Iron Law’ (Voss and Sherman, democracy in this approach, I would wish to argue
2000). Such tendencies have unquestionably that the extent to which worker interests can be
been observed in some unions (for example, promoted without formal organization is limited
and the extent to which stewards could ever be
Moody, 1988). Their inevitability, however, seen as simply part of the ‘rank-and-file’ is open
has been repeatedly challenged by scholars to question.
studying union democracy and related mat-
ters. Notable recent contributions in this vein As Batstone’s comments suggest, there is a
include works by Heery (2006), Kelly and tendency in some quarters to see only the
Heery (1994), Knoke (1990), Moody (1988), coercive, disempowering face of bureaucracy.
and Voss and Sherman (2000). This myopia neglects the enabling or empow-
Much of the literature presumes or con- ering face (Adler and Borys, 1996).
cludes that union democratic traditions are Democracy or governance studies typi-
frequently at odds with organizational effec- cally examine behavioral indicators such as
tiveness as suggested by the juxtaposition of member participation, election closeness, and
oppositional concepts (for example, army vs. leader turnover, attitudinal indicators such as
town meeting, organization vs. association, members’ perceived influence, and structural
or bureaucracy vs. democracy). Alternatively, indicators from union constitutions including
some argue that this tension may exist in provisions on election and convention fre-
the short term, but that long run suppression quency, concentration of authority, potential
or neglect of democracy reduces member power bases for leadership challenges, and
commitment and consequently the union’s member ability to recall incumbents (Strauss,
capacity for mobilization and effectiveness 1991). No single indicator stands out. Rather,
in the long term (Kochan, 1980). Also, some researchers seem to agree that there are many
would argue that democracy is itself a union possible ways to measure democracy and none
goal, and thus a union cannot be effective or that is clearly superior despite some efforts
efficient if it is not democratic as a matter to identify the key indicator (for example,
of definition, aside from any adverse goal Gamm, 1979). There has been some effort
achievement effects from autocracy (Strauss, to move away from a simple democracy
1991). The other side of the argument stresses vs. autocracy perspective toward a broader
that even autocratic unions can have a focus on governance structures (Jarley et al.,
democratizing influence at the workplace, and 2000). Consistent with the multiple indicators
that members are far more concerned with that view but with a configurational emphasis,
influence than participating in the democracy evidence suggests that certain combinations
of their union (Bok and Dunlop, 1970). of structural variables recur such that one
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 195

can identify distinctive union governance are used in other organizations. Warner
types, at least among US national unions (1975) noted this parallel for unions and
(Jarley et al., 2000). other organizations, and further that several
New issues continue to be added to bureaucracy dimensions tended to correlate
the union democracy and governance mix. positively with each other and size in both
A growing issue is the role of ‘identity groups’ settings but that centralization stood apart and
such as women, ethnic groups, gays and decreased with size.
lesbians, and disabled workers. Nominally A notable qualifier arises for centralization,
‘color-blind’ (and similar) policies have often however, as centralization of decisions often
been judged insufficient to give effective means control by elected leaders relative
voice to large segments of workers who to non-elected staff, and in this sense is
have traditionally been minorities in many confounded with democracy (Warner, 1975).
unions. Based on data from as recently as In theory, a union could be highly centralized
2002, Heery called the absence of ethnic and highly democratic (in at least some
minorities in UK union officer ranks ‘truly regards), but in practice the two may be
striking’ (Heery, 2006: 464). ‘Reserved seats’ closely related and difficult to distinguish.
and similar devices have been offered as A further complication arises because of the
partial solutions, but there are differing views distinctions between staff, elected officials,
on the desirability and efficacy of these and and members within unions. In most organi-
alternatives (Colgan and Ledwith, 2003; also zations, virtually all members are employees.
see Chapter 30). There is no staff vs. elected officer distinction,
Varied conceptions of democracy, its and ‘members’(employees) do not have rights
intertwining with centralization, and mixed to elect organizational leaders. Although the
results make it difficult to summarize findings staff vs. officer division in unions has some
on the long-standing debate on democracy parallels in staff vs. line division within other
and effectiveness. That said the evidence organizations, the latter division does not
appears to favor those arguing for democ- entail such clear bureaucracy vs. democracy
racy as a prerequisite for effectiveness (for overtones unless one adopts the somewhat
example, Charlwood, 2004; Fiorito et al., strained assumption that shareholders are
1995; Maranto and Fiorito, 1987). It may analogous to union members and exercise
be premature to summarize evidence on their democratic control (at least in so far
governance structure links to outcomes, but as a share is comparable to a citizen)
at least some of the findings suggest promise via top line employees, for instance, top
in this approach (see Jarley et al., 2000). executives.
Studies focused on union effectiveness In sum, the parallels between unions and
per se and those that examine unions as orga- most other organizational forms exist at a
nizations tend to draw their inspiration from fairly broad level. They begin to break down
earlier work based in other organizational upon closer examination. While something
settings, notably businesses. Researchers have may be learned by transplanting concepts and
established that many bureaucracy concepts measures, there are clearly limitations. Some
are somewhat transplantable. That is, one progress has been made in understanding
can speak of centralization of decisions, union effectiveness and its antecedents, in
and a cluster of ‘rationalization’ measures some cases paralleling findings from other
(US sense; Barbash, 1969) or ‘structuring of settings, but at the same time there have been
activities’ (Warner, 1975) including special- notable discrepancies and poor performance
ization of functions, hierarchy of authority, for some measures (for example, Charlwood,
formalization of procedures, and standard- 2004; Delaney et al., 1996; Fiorito et al., 1995;
ization of tasks within unions, or at least 2001; 2002; Heery et al., 2003b; Jarley et
in larger unions including most nationals, al., 1997). Failings may partly reflect such
in much the same way that these concepts limitations, incomplete models (for example,
196 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

inadequate environmental influence concep- Unions themselves joined (often friendly and
tualizations or indicators), or both. constructively-minded) critical observers in
Qualifiers aside, it appears that the ‘logic recognizing a crisis; of course, prescriptions
of organizations’ more generally applies vary, but there are some common themes in
somewhat to unions. Decentralization and much of this work. Central among these is the
innovation were linked with positive union familiar debate on the ‘organizing model’ vs.
outcomes such as organizing or overall ‘servicing model’ of unionism.
effectiveness in various studies (for example,
Fiorito et al., 1995; 2002; Maranto and Fiorito,
The organizing (mobilizing) model
1987) but results were sometimes mixed (for
and the servicing model
example, Charlwood, 2004). Rationalization
was positively linked to innovation (Delaney In caricatures, the traditional servicing model
et al., 1996; Jarley et al., 2002; Fiorito union, the union type that came to dominate
et al., 2000a), but its linkage to downstream unionism in the focal countries by the
effectiveness outcomes has been more elusive latter half of the twentieth century, is a
and perhaps even contrarian in some instances vending machine, roadside auto service, or an
(for example, Charlwood, 2004; Fiorito et al., insurance policy. Members pay their dues in
1995; 2002). Some concepts closely linked exchange for union representation services,
to rationalization have demonstrated expected for when they have a need, breakdown,
positive impacts on union outcomes such as or claim, respectively. The servicing union
organizing (for example, Heery et al., 2003b; employs staff to provide these services more
Voss and Sherman, 2000). Clark and Gray effectively and efficiently, in theory, than
(2005) and Heery (2006) recently offered members can provide services to themselves.
some of the first published evidence regarding Notice that in the servicing model, the focus
longitudinal changes in administrative prac- of union morphology research at least in terms
tices within unions, and suggests that unions of internal structure, is on staff. Staff members
are improving their practices (rationalizing). are employees of the union and in examining
As yet little published work has linked how unions structured their activities it was
these changes to those in outcomes such as natural for union morphology research to
organizing effectiveness (but see Fiorito et al., borrow heavily from the literature on busi-
2007). nesses. Efforts to understand rationalization,
innovation, and even the conflict between
bureaucracy and democracy within unions
UNION CRISIS AND THE CONFUSED and their links to union effectiveness can all be
SEARCH FOR UNION RENEWAL viewed as a product of the dominance of the
service model of unionism and recognition of
Several studies of ‘union renewal’ and related the key role of staff in carrying out the day-to-
assessments or suggestions of new directions day activities of servicing model unions. (See
for unions emerged in the late 1990s and Kelly and Heery’s book Working for the Union
early 2000s with important implications for (1994) on union staff and officer roles.)
union morphology research (for example, Citing the growing evidence of union
Fairbrother, 2000; Heery, 2003; Heery et al., decline, concessionary bargaining, increasing
2003a; Kelly, 1998; Masters, 1997; Nissen, management ability to work the ‘system’ to
2003a; Rose and Chaison, 2001; Turner et al., its advantage, and general union malaise,
2001). Many of these reflected a sense of organizing model proponents attacked the
crisis, a sense that unions are at a critical servicing model as not merely broken, but
juncture. It is a mildly interesting coincidence fundamentally flawed. In seminal pieces
that writers in both the UK (Fairbrother, outlining the debate, Banks and Metzgar (for
2000) and US (Masters, 1997) authored example, Metzgar, 1991) and Muehlenkamp
books entitled ‘Unions at the Crossroads.’ (1991) argued that unions need to return to
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 197

their self-help roots. Kelly’s (1998) recent industrial nations, with fewer than 8 per cent in
effort to advance mobilization theory and Canada and the UK and fewer than 5 per cent
highlight the importance of workers’ injustice in Australia and the US (Kuruvilla and Fiorito,
perceptions in motivating collective action is 1994: 550). Gallagher and Strauss (1991:
in many ways another effort to underscore the 166) acknowledged limited evidence, but
importance of activating members in pursuit suggested that a potential consequence of
of union goals. The importance of member steady union decline of recent decades is
activism has long been recognized: ‘The diminished activism, not simply in terms of a
strength of a union depends, in part, upon shrinking activist base, but because activism
its ability to mobilize its members not only is motivated in part by perceived effectiveness
in strikes, but also in policing the collective or union instrumentality. Some recent studies
agreement, filing grievances, and serving in present an admittedly haphazard sampling,
the capacity of union stewards or committee but suggest still lower activist cadres, fewer
members’ (Gallagher and Strauss, 1991: 139, than 2 per cent among US manual worker
emphasis added). members in two large and diverse locals
Union members generally cannot, or at least (Nissen, 1998: 136–138), and fewer than
will not, pay a dues ‘price’ that provides 3 per cent among UK union members in a back
the expected services adequately (see also office check processing operation (Hartley,
Fiorito et al., 1993), perhaps due to reasons 1996: 339). Reviewing her activism findings,
involving Wachter’s (2003) assertion that (ser- Hartley concluded that among her subjects,
vicing model) union workplace governance is ‘union membership is more like an insurance
much more expensive than non-union human policy rather than membership of a social
resource management governance (but see group’ (1996: 340). Nissen observed that the
Turnbull, 2003: 513). What workers are often activist numbers are ‘way too small, even in
willing to do, however, and can do very the best cases’ (1998: 149) and that ‘... locals
efficiently in many instances, is supplement are not getting even the mildly motivated
their dues payments with their own services members to volunteer. Instead, the volunteers
that collectively can provide very substan- are the most devoted members’ (1998:
tial benefit to the individual member. For 140). Both Hartley and Nissen stressed the
example, a group acting in concert may be importance of individuals’ feelings of union
able to achieve a grievance settlement much commitment as the key influence on activism.
more quickly and on more satisfactory terms To some degree such feelings are based
than can their contract’s formal procedure. on ideologies that are relatively immutable
In some ways, the organizing model is a among adults. Kuruvilla and Fiorito (1994)
call to resume the ‘fractional bargaining’ also noted activism-enhancing roles for social
(Kuhn, 1961) that institutionalized, mature IR referents (for example, co-workers) and job
sometimes likened to anarchy on the shop dissatisfaction, however, respectively under-
floor. scoring the importance of: (1) one-on-one
Just how often and to what extent members efforts and social networks (see below);
are willing to mobilize as activists is unclear, and, (2) Kelly’s (1998) stress on injustice
however. Insufficient activism has long been perceptions as a cause of mobilization. Nissen
a concern: ‘In early research, participation also offered some hope for union influence in
was found to be low, wherever it was describing success from conscious efforts by
studied’ (Gallagher and Strauss, 1991:154). unions to bolster activism, and in finding a key
This presents a major challenge to, or question role for democracy and transparency within
for, the organizing model. Data from the the union as key influences on commitment.
World Values Survey in the early 1980s Our focus on union morphology requires
showed that fewer than 10 per cent of union that we leave this interesting topic aside
members were willing to volunteer for unpaid for now. Still, the potential importance of
union work in the vast majority of advanced union structural considerations for individual
198 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

union commitment and activism, and their suggests, a greater prevalence of rank-and-file
importance in turn for the ‘very fabric or delegate committees in the workplace.
of unions’ (Gordon et al., 1980: 480), or More fundamentally, the more complex
unionism’s ‘soul’ (more on this later) are union structures associated with the organiz-
apparent. ing model suggests a difference in the fabric of
More generally, the move from the servic- workplace interactions among union members
ing to the organizing model of unionism can and between union members and management
be viewed as a form of decentralization and on the shop floor. Here, union morphology
shift in responsibility away from paid staff research would benefit greatly from concepts
and toward workplace rank-and-file activists. and analytic tools developed in the burgeoning
In a recent rephrasing, Banks and Metzgar, literature on social networks and social capital
(2005: 27) argued: ‘The focus needs to be in the workplace. (See Putnam (2000) for
on building rank and file committees for more on social networks and an analysis
everything a union does.’ From this very basic that places US union decline in a broader
idea considerable confusion and controversy context of social network decline.) Without
have followed both in understanding the basic getting into an extended discussion of social
logic and limits of this new (or should we network terminology, whereas the servicing
say old?) approach to unions as well as in model suggests flat, sparse network structures
fashioning research to guide union policy composed of weak ties among members
makers interested in using organizational and between members and their union, the
transformation as a primary vehicle for their organizing model suggests dense networks
union’s renewal. of strong ties among members and between
Understanding the organizing model of members and the union (Jarley, 2005).
unionism requires new concepts and ana- Research on social networks and social cap-
lytic tools. Very little research, especially ital suggests that dense interpersonal networks
quantitative research in English speaking involving many frequently used ties generates
countries, has focused on variations in union the shared values, resilient trust and mutual
structure at the workplace level (but see understanding that make group cooperation
Batstone, 1988, especially Chapter 3, for a and coordination possible (for a review see
thorough analysis of UK developments during Adler and Kwon, 2002). Frequent interactions
the 1960s and 1970s). Yet, the servicing permit people to know and trust one another,
vs. organizing model distinction suggests share information and develop common goals,
very different contours and roles for union values, and points of view (Tsai and Ghoshal,
structures in the workplace. For one, the shift 1998). Collective goal congruence reduces the
from a servicing to organizing model changes possibility for opportunistic behavior (Ouchi,
the role of stewards (for instance delegates) 1980) and increases the likelihood that people
in the workplace. Their roles become less will share knowledge and resources (Tsai and
about bureaucratic grievance processing and Ghosal, 1998). Dense networks contain many
more about education, relationship build- redundant contacts who can observe each
ing, and mobilization. In essence stewards others’ behavior, thereby lowering transaction
become internal organizers. More generally, costs by making it more difficult for people to
the shift from the servicing to organizing engage in undetected social loafing (Lazega,
model increases the need for co-ordination 1999). Dense networks also facilitate the free
mechanisms to mobilize workers and as a circulation of resources throughout the system
result, we should observe more complex promoting the creation of resilient trust based
structures at the workplace in unions that have on generalized reciprocity norms – the will-
made the transformation. One might expect ingness to do something for someone today
more stewards (or delegates), more frequent knowing that someone else will return the
meetings among stewards in the workplace, favor at a later date. Generalized reciprocity
and as Banks and Metzger’s (2005) reference norms improve the durability of social capital,
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 199

making it less vulnerable to erosion through patterns are themselves important features of
exit of any single individual. union structure and differences in them may
To put all of this in more familiar language very well be linked to differences in union
to students of the labor movement, dense member satisfaction, commitment, participa-
networks facilitate the formation of a sense tion, and mobilization, the very outcomes
of a community of interests (or class con- often associated with union effectiveness and
sciousness). More frequent interaction breeds renewal.
solidarity and redundancy in network ties, Banks and Metzgar (2005) acknowledge,
and reduces free-riding. The result is that as many have suggested, that the contrast
members are more willing to mobilize in between servicing and organizing has been
support of one another because an injury overplayed. Members value services, and
to one is seen as an injury to all. Very unions often ‘organize around services’,
preliminary work by Johnson and Jarley that is by touting the service that union
(2005) suggests that among a sample of representation will provide when members
young union members of the United Food and have a need, breakdown, or claim, as well
Commercial Workers, those members with as representation’s value on an ongoing non-
denser workplace networks knew more about crisis basis. Further, Banks and Metzgar
their union and developed greater trust and were really speaking of organizing in the
reciprocity norms toward it than workers with sense of mobilization rather than in the
sparse workplace networks. sense of recruiting new members or winning
Jarley (2005) has gone so far as to argue that representation rights. These latter ends can
by themselves, the conflict escalation methods of course be served through mobilization
associated with the traditional organizing or activism, as can grievance settlements,
model are unlikely to sustain a dense network bargaining gains, or legislative influence,
among union members in the workplace. He and in that sense the phrase ‘organizing
argues that unions should engage in a variety for everything we do’ (Butler, 1991) has
of social capital building activities that will clear meaning. From the standpoint of union
maintain and enhance network density as morphology research, this recognition of the
well as solidarity between the union and its parallel importance for unions of servicing
members in times of labor peace so that they and mobilizing members makes it clear that
can be more effectively tapped to mobilize a full understanding of union effectiveness
workers in times of need. Jarley’s discussion is requires an examination of staff, activist,
highly speculative, but the key point is that an and member structures in the workplace and
examination of union social structure in the beyond.
workplace offers a promising new approach Much work needs to be done here,
to union morphology research and union chief among it is assessing the degree to
renewal. Peetz et al.’s (2002) examination of which unions have systematically adopted
Australian workplace delegate activism also the key elements of the organizing model
supports the importance of social network and how they have attempted to reconcile
concepts within unions. the need to mobilize members with the
Different ‘models’ of unionism (be they need to service them. We have several
service, organizing, value added or social interesting case studies, but little systematic
capital) may be associated with different evidence (but see Heery et al., 2000a; 2000b).
patterns of interaction among union members More fine-grained analysis is also needed to
and between union members and their union understand the relationship between various
(as well as management). We have stressed elements of national union bureaucracy (for
network density here, but other features of example, professionalization, centralization,
these networks may be important as well, for coordination, and communication), member
example, the degree of centrality of union networks in the workplace and activism.
representatives in the network. These different Carter (2000) noted the contradictions and
200 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

consequent difficulty in a top-down approach union tradition of promoting active workplace


to implementing the organizing model in trade unionism’ (Heery, et al., 2003a: 81; also
Britain’s MSF. Lévesque and Murray (2002) see Batstone, 1988 regarding government-
and Voss and Sherman (2000) offered some backed efforts to ‘domesticate’ the shop
interesting insights in these regards as well. stewards’ movement). Thus the face validity
Exploring the relationship between workplace of a call for greater mobilization and less
activism, innovation and democracy in unions reliance on staff servicing might have been
is another important area for future work. All less compelling than in the US. Coupled
of this will require new data sets that allow with severe membership declines (although
us to match national union structures and less dramatic than in the US) and rising
practices with data from individual locals and employer opposition (Gall, 2003), British
workplaces, a daunting but necessary task. unions and union scholars might more readily
interpret calls for an ‘organizing model’ as
calls for greater organizing commitment or
Organizing-driven unions
for a specific set of organizing tactics relating
To add confusion to the debate about the to mobilization in varying degrees (see Heery
evolving nature of unionism, the emer- et al., 2000a).
gence of the organizing model coincided As Fletcher and Hurd (1998; 2001) noted,
with increased recognition of the need for however, there is no inevitable link between
recruiting and organizing non-union workers activating workers in an organizing model
and the two have been understandably con- sense and external organizing. Mobilized
founded. Note that Bronfenbrenner’s work workers may, despite their activism, see little
on rank-and-file-intensive organizing tactics gain in spending their efforts and dues on
(for example, 1997) appeared at this time. organizing non-union workers. Fletcher and
Given its emphasis on member activism to Hurd coined the term ‘organizing-driven’
organize non-union workers (for example, unions to distinguish those unions that placed
one-on-one organizing; large rank-and-file a high priority on organizing non-union
organizing committees) it is understandable workers from the organizing model and its
that organizing and the organizing model are emphasis on member mobilization; the term
often conflated despite the fact that Banks ‘recruiting union’ is used similarly in the UK.
and Metzgar were focusing on mobilization They argued that external organizing, rather
rather than external organizing per se. There than membership mobilization per se, is the
is also evidence that some unions con- more pressing matter for unions.
sciously made the link by believing that the As with the organizing model, there is
increases in member activism brought about little systematic evidence on the extent to
by the organizing model would substitute which unions have adopted an organizing-
for paid administrative staff in contract driven approach and what this means for
administration, freeing staff resources for union structure. With respect to external
greater external organizing (Fletcher and structure there is a temptation to equate an
Hurd, 1998). (Information technology was organizing-driven approach with the afore-
also seen as offering significant potential to mentioned trend toward general unionism and
redirect resources toward organizing (Fiorito re-branding of the resulting unions with names
et al., 2000b.) that emphasize the collective nature of unions
In Britain, the confusion may be multiplied (for example, Unison, Connect, and even
by historically lower reliance on the servicing UNITE-HERE) without reference to industry
model, consistent with lower dues and staffing or occupation. Although merger activity may
levels, and lower employer opposition, as play a larger role in union re-branding than
compared to the US. The shop stewards’ adoption of an organizing-driven approach,
movement of the 1960s illustrates a stronger the more generic names also suggest a
British tradition of self-help, ‘an indigenous broader sense of union jurisdiction and
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 201

a more opportunistic approach to organizing. ‘recover’before receiving another assignment


If such a broadening is associated with an (Early, 1996; 1998). (One might speculate that
organizing-driven approach, it brings with it increasing emphasis on specialist organizers
obvious questions about the potential need to is a manifestation of a broader specialization
form divisional structures to accommodate a trend in union staff roles that extends to
variety of potential sectional interests within equality or diversity issues, among others. See
the union based on industry, occupation, geog- Heery (2006)).
raphy, or identity. Even the ‘One Big Union- Foerster (2003) noted that backgrounds
ism’ philosophy of the Industrial Workers may be a source of tension between Orga-
of the World was modified to incorporate nizing Institute-type graduates and organizers
industrial divisions as problems of neglecting who rise up through the ranks. There are
these distinctive interests became apparent. other potential tension sources in terms of
With respect to internal structure, the most goal conflict, with functionally dedicated
visible innovations consistent with movement organizers’ performance linked closely to
toward organizing-driven unions have been at membership and organizing gains rather than
the federation level with the creation of the satisfying current members or being re-
Organizing Institute in the US (see Foerster, elected. That may be a necessary tension,
2001), its counterpart Organising Academy in as current members will always prevail
the UK, and Organizing Works in Australia. in commanding leaders’ attention (Strauss,
The development of these federation-level 1993: 24). Similarly, Heery et al. (2003a:
entities suggests a recognition among peak 82) allude to ‘organizing initiatives being
union leaders that many affiliates are unable derailed through the demand for servicing of
to make the transition to organizing-driven existing members’. There is another element
unions on their own and need a new source of of tension in terms of what has been called
trained professional organizers who not only the ‘high octane atmosphere’ of an organizing
bring the newest organizing techniques to the campaign versus the routine of day-to-day
national unions that employ them, but serve as union activism. Echoing Early’s (1998) point
agitators for change within their employing on burnout but in a slightly different way, it is
unions by pushing union staff and officers unlikely that a workgroup can sustain for long
attuned to servicing members to adopt a more the sort of energy level that can accompany
organizing-driven approach (Foerster, 2003). short-term campaigns.
The reliance on paid professional organizers, In some ways the debate about the relative
many of whom are young college graduates wisdom and efficacy of using professional (for
or drawn from the ranks of political or instance, highly formally trained staff spe-
community activists by the peak federation cialist) organizers vs. volunteer (for instance,
bodies that have trained them, has drawn trained rank-and-file generalists) activists is a
criticism from some commentators who argue variant of the servicing vs. organizing debate
that organizing new members is best left recast around external organizing rather than
to volunteer rank-and-file activists. Volunteer servicing issues. It involves both debates
organizers, they argue, are likely to be more about centralization (national vs. local control
effective because they have more in common over the organizing function) and member vs.
with the workers they are attempting to orga- staff ownership of the day-to-day organizing
nize. They may also be less susceptible to the function. There is some evidence to suggest
burnout that often accompanies professional that decentralization is associated with greater
organizers because they remain attached to a organizing success (Fiorito et al., 1995). From
local union where they have more manageable an internal structure standpoint, however,
geographic jurisdiction that allows them to the debate about the proper approach to
spend time with their families as well as the organizing function might be as illusory
the opportunity to rotate back onto the a distinction as in the servicing context.
shop floor after each organizing campaign to A renewed emphasis on external organizing
202 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

may lead to both an increase in the number heart of Fairbrother’s call for union renewal,
of professional organizers (and rationalization the union renewal term has taken on broader
of the organizing function; see Heery et al., and varied meanings, including not only
2000b; 2003a) as well as the development activism or mobilization, but also organizing
of an extensive network of local volunteer commitment and partnerships with employers
activists to support the organizing function. among others (Heery, 2003).
In short the task may require both greater In a sense, Heery (2003) encourages
professionalization (and rationalization) and appreciation for the view that there are
more membership activation. different problems and opportunities facing
What seems clear is that any push to various unions. Bringing unions back to life
a more organizing-driven approach should in the sense of asserting renewed or greater
result in an increase in the proportion of influence on behalf of workers therefore
union resources, financial and human, devoted involves various paths, what the business
to organizing and a corresponding increase strategy and organizational theory literatures
in organizing activity. At least in the US, refer to as ‘equafinality.’A relatively universal
despite considerable rhetoric advocating more problem is activating members, but passive
resources for organizing there is as yet little servicing model unionism is not the only
evidence that these calls have been heeded in problem and thus the organizing model does
practice, at least in the aggregate (see Farber not constitute a sufficient solution (Fiorito,
and Western, 2002), and even for many unions 2004, Fletcher and Hurd, 2001).
often cited as among those truly committed to Budd (2004: 137–157) proffered the ‘soul’
organizing (Fiorito, 2003; Fiorito and Jarley, terminology in suggesting that union strategy
2003). Masters (1997) pointed out that the is a combination of union soul (servicing vs.
financial commitment required may exceed organizing model orientation) and scope of
realistic union capacity, and Rose and Chaison representation (business unionism focused on
(2001) raised similar questions regarding both the workplace vs. social unionism focused
Canadian and US unions. In Britain, an on broader social issues). We are hesitant
apparent increase in organizing commitment to accept Budd’s implicit definition of union
may have waned as political exclusion eased strategy. First, another chapter will address
with the return of a Labour Government union strategy in more depth. Second, a
(Heery et al., 2003a). If the resources have simple but useful distinction is that goals are
not been allocated and organizing activity has about ‘what’ and strategy is about ‘how.’ The
not increased, significant changes in internal soul issue (organizing model versus servicing
union structure to support organizing are model) is fairly clearly about how, but the
doubtful. More definite conclusions require scope of representation issue (workplace
better data. versus broader) is arguably about what.
That said, Budd’s juxtaposition of soul
and scope does suggest some meaningful
Union ‘soul’ and union renewal:
union types. Combining an organizing soul
configurational approaches
with a broad scope yields ‘social movement
The term ‘union renewal’ is sometimes unionism,’ while an organizing soul with a
attributed to Fairbrother (2000) in his call narrow scope yields ‘employee empowerment
for revitalization and renewed rank-and-file unionism.’ A servicing soul combines with a
activism among moribund UK public sector broad scope to suggest European-style ‘social
unions. Many of these unions could be said to partnerships,’ while a narrow scope and
have been put on their back foot and doubly servicing soul produce ‘business unionism’
damned in over a decade of Conservative (job control). Budd introduces additional
government hostility to both unions and public factors to draw finer distinctions, for example,
sector workers. Although one could argue between efficiency-enhancing unionism (see
that organizing model concepts were at the Masters, 1997 on value-added unionism and
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 203

Fiorito et al., 1991 for related discussion), McKay, 1999: 610). VAU was portrayed
solidarity unionism, and other subtypes. as a logical successor to business unionism
As in some other areas (for example, that has lost its ability to deliver the goods
Jarley et al., 2000 on union governance), via more oppositional approaches in the
this approach emphasizes that configurations face of increased management resistance.
of multiple factors rather than the level There is a strong ‘top down’ element to
of a particular factor may be critical. In this approach, with relatively little need for
effect this is a configurational rather than mobilization and relatively much need for
contingency approach. It has been popular in servicing by officers and staff. Nissen (2003b)
the business strategy literature for many years, asserted a much greater potential for SMU,
and has a long tradition in industrial relations with such unions forming the workplace-
as well, arguably dating to Hoxie’s (1917) centered wing of broader social movements.
time if not earlier. Configurational approaches But here too, he acknowledged limitations,
are often useful pedagogical devices, but seeing SMU as particularly suited to low
frequently disappoint as quantitative research wage workers, notably women and immigrant
tools. Here as in other applications the types workers, where calls for social justice are most
may resonate with prior knowledge and credibly linked to union efforts to improve
provide a readily understandable way to view their members’ well-being.
union differences, for instance, a way to This seems to leave much unclaimed ‘turf,’
approach union morphology. They may also unless we assume that globalization will
serve prescriptive purposes, ideal types that inevitably greatly expand the ranks of low-
highlight an underlying logic toward union wage workers (as often seems to be the case.)
renewal that should guide efforts to align Some of Budd’s other types may help to fill
strategy with external and internal structure in some of that turf, but is the rest left to
and union practice. Yet, from a research allegedly more efficient (Wachter, 2003) non-
perspective if the types truly add value, they union human resource management, or worse,
must explain variance in some important ‘black holes’ (Guest and Conway, 1999)?
outcome, above and beyond that explained by This conundrum of matching union types to
reference to the underlying dimensions that workplace settings is one of the problems
form the types. If not, a contingency approach raised by approaches stressing union con-
is suggested even though the configurational figurations. It is not insurmountable, but it
approach may remain useful in some regards. does call into question, with previously noted
Nissen (2003b) recently illustrated the use concerns about the value added by types, the
of the configurational approach in assessing utility of a configurational approach relative
two contrasting future strategic directions for to more general contingency approaches,
the US labor movement, value-added union- or perhaps the need to consider both. We
ism (VAU) and social movement unionism remain somewhat agnostic about configura-
(SMU). Here too, goals and strategy are tional approaches from a quantitative research
entwined, with VAU corresponding closely to perspective, finding them useful in some
Budd’s efficiency-enhancing type and SMU regards but possibly too limiting.
matching closely to Budd’s like-named type.
Nissen acknowledged that each type may fit
a particular niche. For example, where unions CONCLUDING COMMENTS
are strongly rooted in companies, they may
be able to leverage their strength into genuine With the crisis in union membership, con-
partnerships where their contributions to solidation and concentration of union mem-
firm performance are effectively traded for bership in fewer and fewer unions, and
acceptance of unionism, much like some the debate about the proper path to union
recognition deals in the UK based on ‘the renewal, understanding union morphology,
“business case” for unionism’ (Gall and especially the link between union structure,
204 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

practices and effectiveness, is of paramount Studying these phenomena requires new


importance to both the study and practice of concepts and approaches and ultimately
unionism. This chapter has argued that on there is a need for a ‘unified theory’ that
balance the empirical evidence amassed to links structures and activities on the shop
date suggests that structure matters. Some floor with national union morphology and
important findings relating to union renewal, union outcomes. Such a theory may or may
on union outcomes such as organizing and not require a configurational, rather than
effectiveness, appear fairly robust to setting, contingency approach to unions. But at a
for instance, they emerge in broad cross- minimum, the configurational approaches that
sections of unions. Notable in this vein are are implicit in many prescriptive writings on
findings on decentralization and innovation the future of unions give us insights into the
(Fiorito et al., 1995; 2002; 2007) and to underlying logic of ideal union forms that
some extent on rationalization in terms of highlight important linkages between union
its effects on innovation, an intermediate strategy, structure, and practice at multiple
outcome (Delaney et al., 1996; Fiorito et al., levels of the union movement.
2000). Other research corroborates some of Several of today’s most pressing ‘big
these findings, at least in part (Charlwood, questions’ with respect to union morphology
2004; Fiorito 2004; Heery et al., 2003b; remain largely unanswered. For example,
Voss and Sherman, 2000). Much of this what workplace structures produce the great-
was noted earlier in conjunction with our est mobilization capacity? Have organizing
discussion on internal (or vertical) and model unions, those that have developed
external (or horizontal) structure, because the workplace mobilization structures and suc-
contingencies thus far examined have been cessfully activated members, fared better
internal or external structure measures or an in organizing, bargaining, or politics than
outcome (for example, innovation) linked to servicing model unions? What does it really
structure measures. mean to be an organizing-driven or recruiting
Yet, the issue is far from settled. One union, and have those that have made this
persistent problem has involved a lack of transition fared better than those that have not?
systematic cross-sectional and time series data The year 2005 witnessed a major fracturing
on union member characteristics, structures, of the US labor movement over this last
and practices. This has left gaps in our issue (and others). It may be too soon to say
knowledge and made it difficult to distinguish whether the rebel unions of the Change to
correlation from causality. Another, more Win Federation are generating results such
subtle concern is that implicit in most of as organizing gains and increased influence
the quantitative research conducted to date for their members that will vindicate or
has been adherence to a ‘servicing model’ legitimize their rebellion, or whether as the
of unionism. Recognizing the key role staff ‘loyalists’ argue, their secession has simply
has played in carrying out the day-to-day weakened the collective voice of labor. Of
activities of the union, union morphology course, assessments will need to consider the
research has borrowed heavily from the environment and other organizational factors
literature on businesses to construct measures to provide persuasive evidence unless the
of national union internal structures (for simple (bivariate) evidence is overwhelming.
example, bureaucracy, centralization, and As with union renewal itself, much work on
innovation) that are then linked to differences union morphology remains to be done.
in national union outcomes. Yet, the recent
decentralization of industrial relations in all
English-speaking countries and the greater ACKNOWLEDGMENT
emphasis on member mobilization it has
spawned suggests increased importance for We thank Paul Blyton and Edmund Heery for
formal and informal workplace structures. helpful comments on an earlier draft.
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 205

REFERENCES Clark, Paul F. and Gray, Lois S. (2005) ‘Chang-


ing Administrative Practices in American Unions:
Addison, John T. and Schnabel, Claus, (eds) A Research Note.’ Industrial Relations, 44 (4):
(2003). International Handbook of Trade Unions. 654–58.
Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Cobble, Dorothy Sue (2001) ‘Lost Ways of Unionism:
Elgar. Historical Perspectives on Reinventing the Labor
Adler, Paul S. and Bryan, Borys (1996) ‘Two Types of Movement.’ In Lowell Turner, Harry C. Katz, and
Bureaucracy: Enabling and Coercive.’ Administrative Richard W. Hurd (eds), Rekindling the Movement.
Science Quarterly, 41 (1): 61–90. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. pp. 82–96.
Adler, Paul S. and Kwon, Seok-Woo (2002) ‘Social Colgan, Fiona and Ledwith, Sue (eds) (2003) Gender,
capital: Prospects for a new concept.’ Academy of Diversity and Trade Unions: International Perspec-
Management Review, 27 (1): 17–40. tives. London: Routledge.
Associated Press (2005) ‘Alliance Aims to Commons, John R. (1909) ‘American Shoemakers,
Organize Wal-Mart Workers.’ On-line article at 1648–1895: A Sketch of Industrial Evolution.’
http://www.nytimes.com, August 23, 2005. American Economic Review, 24 (1): 39–84.
Banks, Andy, and Metzgar, Jack (2005) ‘Response to Cornfield, Dan (2006) ‘Immigration, Economic Restruc-
‘Unions as Social Capital.’ Labor Studies Journal, turing, and Labor Ruptures: From the Amalgamated
29 (4): 27–35. to Change to Win.’ Working USA, 9 (2) (June):
Barbash, Jack (1969) ‘Rationalization in the American 215–223.
Union.’ In Gerald G. Somers (ed.), Essays in Industrial Delaney, John T., Jarley, Paul, and Fiorito, Jack. (1996)
Relations Theory. Ames, IA: Iowa State University ‘Planning for Change: Determinants of Innovation in
Press. pp. 147–62. US National Unions.’ Industrial and Labor Relations
Batstone, Eric (1988) The Reform of Workplace Industrial Review, 49 (4) (July): 597–614.
Relations: Theory, Myth and Evidence. Oxford, UK: Early, Steve (1996) ‘New organizing should be
Clarendon Press. membership-based.’ Labor Notes, 205, April 12.
Bok, Derek and Dunlop, John T. (1970) Labor and Early, Steve (1998) ‘Membership-based organizing.’ In
the American Community. New York: Simon and G. Mantsios (ed.), A New Labor Movement for the
Schuster. New Century. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Bronfenbrenner, Kate B. (1997) ‘The Role of Union Ebbinghaus, Bernhard (2003) ‘Ever Larger Unions:
Strategies in NLRB Certification Elections.’ Industrial Restructuring and Its Impact on Union Confedera-
and Labor Relations Review, 50 (2): 196–212. tions.’ Industrial Relations Journal, 34 (5) (December):
Budd, John W. (2004) Employment with a human face. 446–60.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Ebbinghaus, Bernhard and Visser, Jelle (1999) ‘When
Budd, John W. (2005) Labor Relations: Striking a Institutions Matter: Union Growth and Decline in
Balance. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin. Western Europe, 1950–1995.’ European Sociological
Butler, Margaret (1991) ‘Organizing for Everything We Review, 15 (2) (June): 135–58.
Do.’ Labor Research Review, 17 (special issue on ‘An Fairbrother, Peter (2000) Unions at the Crossroads.
Organizing Model of Unionism’): 7–17. London: Mansell Publishing.
Carter, Bob (2000) ‘Adoption of the Organising Farber, Henry S. and Western, Bruce. (2002) ‘Ronald
Model in British Trade Unions: Some Evidence from Reagan and the Politics of Declining Union Organi-
Manufacturing Science, and Finance (MSF).’ Work, zation.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations, 40 (3):
Employment, and Society, 14 (1): 117–36. 385–401.
Chaison, Gary N. (1996) Union Mergers in Hard Times. Fiorito, Jack (2003) ‘Union Organizing in the United
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. States.’ In Gregor Gall (ed.), Union Organizing:
Chaison, Gary N. (2001) ‘Union Mergers and Union Campaigning for Trade Union Recognition. London:
Revival.’ In Lowell Turner, Harry C. Katz, and Richard Routledge. pp. 191–210.
W. Hurd (eds), Rekindling the Movement. Ithaca, NY: Fiorito, Jack (2004) ‘Union Renewal and the Organizing
ILR Press. pp. 238–55. Model in the United Kingdom.’ Labor Studies Journal,
Charlwood, Andy (2004) ‘Influences on Trade Union 29 (2): 21–53.
Organizing Effectiveness in Britain.’ British Journal of Fiorito, Jack, Gramm, Cynthia L., and Hendricks, Wallace
Industrial Relations, 42 (1): 69–93. E. (1991) ‘Union Structural Choices’. In George
Child, John., Loveridge, Ray, and Warner, Malcolm Strauss, Daniel G. Gallagher, and Jack Fiorito, (eds),
(1973) ‘Toward an Organizational Study of Trade The State of the Unions. Madison, WI: Industrial
Unions.’ Sociology 7 (1): 71–91. Relations Research Association. pp. 103–37.
206 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Fiorito, Jack and Jarley, Paul (2003) ‘Union Organizing Gamm, Sarah (1979) ‘The Election Base of National
Commitment: Rhetoric and Reality.’ Proceedings Union Executive Boards.’ Industrial and Labor
of the Fifty-fifth Annual Meeting of the Industrial Relations Review, 32 (3): 295–311.
Relations Research Association. Champaign, IL: IRRA, Gall, Gregor (2003) ‘Employer Opposition to Union
pp. 283–93. Recognition.’ In Gregor Gall (ed.), Union Organizing:
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul and Delaney, John T. (2000a) Campaigning for Trade Union Recognition. London:
‘The Adoption of Information Technology by US Routledge. pp. 79–96.
National Unions.’ Relations Industrielles/Industrial Gall, Gregor and McKay, Sonia (1999) ‘Developments
Relations, 55 (3): 451–76. in Union Recognition and Derecognition in Britain,
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul, and Delaney, John T. (2007) 1994-98.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations,
‘Change to Win: Can Structural Reform Revitalize the 37 (4): 601–4.
American Labor Movement?’ Advances in Industrial Gallagher, Daniel G. and Strauss, George (1991) ‘Union
and Labor Relations, 15: 359–91. Membership Attitudes and Participation.’ In George
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul and Delaney, John T. (2002) Strauss, Daniel G. Gallagher, and Jack Fiorito, (eds)
‘Information Technology, Union Organizing, and The State of the Unions. Madison, WI: Industrial
Union Effectiveness.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations Research Association. pp. 139–74.
Relations, 40 (4): 627–58. Gordon, Michael E., Philpot, John W., Burt, Robert E.,
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul, and Delaney, John T. (1993) Thompson, Cynthia A. and Spiller, William E. (1980)
‘National Union Effectiveness.’ Research in the ‘Commitment to the Union: Development of a
Sociology of Organizations, 12: 111–37. Measure and an Examination of Its Correlates.’
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul, and Delaney, John T. Journal of Applied Psychology, 65 (4): 479–99.
(1995) ‘National Union Effectiveness in Organizing: Guest, David, and Conway, Neil (1999) ‘Peering into the
Measures and Influences.’ Industrial and Labor Black Hole: The Downside of the New Employment
Relations Review, 48 (4): 613–35. Relations in the UK.’ British Journal of Industrial
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul, and Delaney, John T. (2001) Relations, 37 (3): 367–89.
‘National Unions as Organizations.’ In Gerald R. Ferris Hartley, Jean (1996) ‘The ‘New’ Service Sector:
(ed.), Research in Personnel and Human Resources Employment Status, Ideology and Trade Union
Management, 20: 231–68. Participation in the UK.’ In Patrick P. Pasture, Johan
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul, Delaney, John T., and J Verbeckmoes, and Hans H. de Witte (eds), The
Kolodinsky, Bob (2000b) ‘Unions and Information Lost Perspective? Trade Unions Between Ideology
Technology: From Luddites to Cyberunions?’ Labor and Social Action in the New Europe. Avebury Press:
Studies Journal, 24 (1): 3–34. Aldershot, England and Brookfield, VT. pp. 326–352.
Fletcher, Bill, Jr. and Hurd, Richard W. (1998) ‘Beyond Heckscher, Charles C. (1988) The New Unionism.
the Organizing Model: The Transformation Process New York: Basic Books.
in Local Unions.’ In Kate Bronfenbrenner, Sheldon Heery, Edmund (2003) ‘Evolution, Renewal, Agency:
Friedman, Richard W. Hurd, Rudy A. Oswald, and Developments in the Theory of Trade Unions.’ In Peter
Ronald Seeber (eds) Organizing to Win. Ithaca, NY: Ackers and Adrian Wilkinson (eds), Understanding
ILR Press. pp 37–53. Work and Employment. Oxford: Oxford University
Fletcher, Bill, Jr. and Hurd, Richard W. (2001) ‘Over- Press. pp. 278–304.
coming Obstacles to Transformation: Challenges Heery, Edmund (2006) ‘Union Workers, Union Work:
on the Way to a New Unionism.’ In Lowell A Profile of Paid Union Officers in the United King-
Turner, Harry C. Katz, and Richard W. Hurd (eds), dom.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations, 44 (3):
Rekindling the Movement. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. 445–71.
pp. 182–208. Heery, Edmund, Kelly, John and Waddington, Jeremy
Foerster, Amy (2001) ‘Confronting the Dilemmas (2003a) ‘Union Revitalization in Britain.’ European
of Organizing: Obstacles and Innovations at the Journal of Industrial Relation, 9 (1): 79–97.
AFL-CIO Organizing Institute.’ In Lowell Turner, Heery, Edmund, Simms, Melanie, Delbridge, Rick,
Harry C. Katz, and Richard W. Hurd (eds) Salmon, John and Simpson, Dave (2003b) ‘Trade
Rekindling the Movement. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. Union Recruitment Policy in Britain: Forms and
pp. 155–81. Effects.’ In Gregor Gall (ed.), Union Organizing:
Foerster, Amy (2003) ‘Labor’s Youth Brigade: What Can Campaigning for Trade Union Recognition. London:
the Organizing Institute and Its Graduates Tell Us Routledge. pp. 56–78.
About the Future of Organized Labor?’ Labor Studies Heery, Edmund, Simms, Melanie, Delbridge, Rick,
Journal, 28 (3): 1–31. Salmon, John, and Simpson, Dave (2000a)
TRADE UNION MORPHOLOGY 207

‘Union Organizing in Britain: A Survey of Policy and A.J Leenders and Shaul M. Gabbay (eds) Corporate
Practice.’ International Journal of Human Resource Social Capital and Liability . Norwell MA: Kluwer
Management, 11 (5): 986–1007. Academic Publishers.
Heery, Edmund, Simms, Melanie, Simpson, Dave, Lévesque, Christian, and Murray, Gregor (2002) ‘Local
Delbridge, Rick and Salmon, John (2000b) ‘Organiz- Versus Global: Activating Local Union Power in the
ing Unionism Comes to the UK.’ Employee Relations, Global Economy.’ Labor Studies Journal, 27 (3):
22 (1): 38–57. 39–65.
Hoxie, Robert F. (1917) Trade Unionism in the United Maranto, Cheryl L. and Fiorito, Jack (1987) ‘The Effect of
States. New York: D. Appleton. Union Characteristics on NLRB Certification Election
Jacoby, Sanford M., and Verma, Anil (1992) ‘Enterprise Outcomes.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 40
Unions in the United States.’ Industrial Relations, (2): 225–40.
31 (1): 137–58. Masters, Marick F. (1997) Unions at the Crossroads.
Jarley, Paul (2005) ‘Unions as Social Capital: Renewal Westport, CT: Quorum Books.
through a Return to the Logic of Mutual Aid?’ Labor Metzgar, Jack (1991) ‘Introduction’ Labor Research
Studies Journal, 29 (4): 1–26. Review, 17 (special issue on ‘An Organizing Model
Jarley, Paul, Fiorito, Jack and Delaney, John Thomas of Unionism’): vi–viii.
(1997) ‘A Structural Contingency Approach to Moody, Kim (1988) An Injury to All: The Decline of
Bureaucracy and Democracy in US National American Unionism. London and New York: Verso.
Unions.’ Academy of Management Journal, 40 (4): Muehlenkamp, Robert (1991) ‘Organizing Never Stops.’
pp. 831–61. Labor Research Review, 17 (special issue on ‘An
Jarley, Paul, Fiorito, Jack and Delaney, John T. Organizing Model of Unionism’): 1–5.
(2000) ‘Union Governance: An Empirically-grounded Muste, A.J. (1928) ‘Factional Fights in Trade Unions,’ In
Systems Approach.’ Journal of Labor Research, 21 (2): J.B.S. Hardman (ed), American Labor Dynamics. New
227–46. York: Harcourt and Brace. pp. 332–33.
Jarley, Paul, Harley, Bill and Hall, Richard (2002) Nissen, Bruce (2003a) ‘Alternative Strategic Directions
‘Innovation in Australian Trade Unions.’ Industrial for the US Labor Movement: Recent Scholarship.’
Relations, 41 (2): 228–48. Labor Studies Journal, 28 (1): 133–55.
Johnson, Nancy B. and Jarley, Paul (2005) ‘Unions Nissen, Bruce (2003b) ‘The Recent Past and Near Future
as Social Capital: The Impact of Trade Union of Private Sector Unionism in the US: An Appraisal.’
Youth Programmes on Young Workers’ Political and Journal of Labor Research, 24 (2): 323–38.
Community Engagement.’ Transfer, 11 (4): 605–16. Nissen, Bruce (1998) ‘Utilizing the Membership to
Keller, Berndt (2005) ‘Union Formation Through Merger: Organize the Unorganized.’ In Kate Bronfenbrenner,
The Case of Ver.di in Germany.’ British Journal of Sheldon Friedman, Richard W. Hurd, Rudolph A.
Industrial Relations, 43 (2): 209–32. Oswald, and Ronald L. Seeber (eds), Organizing
Kelly, John (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi- to Win. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
lization, Collectivism, and Long Waves. Routledge: pp. 135–49.
London. Ouchi, Walter, G. (1980) ‘Markets, Bureaucracies,
Kelly, John, and Heery, Edmund (1994) Working for and Clans’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 25 (1):
the Union: British Trade Union Officers. Cambridge: 129–41.
University Press. Peetz, David, Webb, C. and Jones, M. (2002) ‘Activism
Knoke, David (1990) Organizing for Collective Action. Amongst Workplace Union Delegates’. International
New York: de Gruyter. Journal of Employment Studies, 10 (2), October 2002,
Kochan, Thomas A. (1980) Collective Bargaining and 83–108.
Industrial Relations: From Theory to Policy to Practice. Putnam, Robert D. (2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse
Homewood, IL: Irwin. and Revival of American Community. New York:
Kuhn, James W. (1961) Bargaining in Grievance Simon and Shuster.
Settlements: The Power of Industrial Work Groups. Rose, Joseph B., and Chaison, Gary N. (2001)
New York: Columbia University Press. ‘Unionism in Canada and the United States in
Kuruvilla, Sarosh C. and Fiorito, Jack. (1994) ‘Who Will the 21st Century: Prospects for Revival.’ Relations
Help? Willingness to Work for the Union.’ Relations Industrielles/Industrial Relations, 56 (1): 34–65.
Industrielles/Industrial Relations, 49 (3): 548–75. Strauss, George (1993) ‘Issues in Union Structure.’
Lazega, E. 1999. ‘Generalized Exchange and Economic In Samuel B. Bacharach, Ronald Seeber, and
Performance: Social Embeddedness of Labor Con- David Walsh (eds), Research in the Sociology of
tracts in a Corporate Law Partnership.’ In Roger Th. Organizations, 12: 1–49. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
208 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Strauss, George (1991) ‘Union Democracy.’ In George Visser, Jelle (1989) European Trade Unions in Figures,
Strauss, Daniel G. Gallagher and Jack Fiorito (eds), Deventer, The Netherlands: Kluwer.
The State of the Unions Madison, WI: Industrial Visser, Jelle (2006) ‘Union Membership Statistics in
Relations Research Association. pp. 201–36. 24 Countries.’ Monthly Labor Review, 129 (1)
Streeck, Wolfgang and Visser, Jelle (1997) ‘The Rise (January): 38–49.
of the Conglomerate Union.’ European Journal of Visser, Jelle and Waddington, Jeremy (1996) ‘Indus-
Industrial Relations, 3 (3): 305–332. trialization and Politics: A Century of Union
Tsai, W. and S. Ghoshal (1998) ‘Social Capital and Value Structural Development in Three European Countries.’
Creation: The Role of Intrafirm Networks.’ Academy European Journal of Industrial Relations, 2 (1):
of Management Journal, 41 (4): 464–477. 21–53.
Trades Union Congress (2005) ‘Britain’s Unions.’ Voss, Kim and Sherman, Rachel (2000) ‘Breaking the
On-line directory at http://www.tuc.org.uk/tuc/ Iron Law of Oligarchy: Union Revitalization in the
unions_main.cfm#C American Labor Movement.’ American Journal of
Trades Union Congress (2006) TUC Directory 2006. Sociology, 106 (2): 303–349.
London: TUC. Wachter, Michael L. (2003) ‘Judging Unions’ Future
Turnbull, Peter (2003) ‘What Do Unions Do Now?’ Using a Historical Perspective: The Public Policy
Journal of Labor Research, 24 (3): 491–527. Choice between Competition and Unionization.’
Turner, Lowell, Katz, Harry C. and Hurd, Richard W. (eds) Journal of Labor Research, 24 (2): 339–57.
(2001) Rekindling the Movement: Labor’s Quest for Warner, Malcolm (1975) ‘Unions as Complex Organi-
Relevance in the 21st Century. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. zations.’ Relations Industrielles/Industrial Relations,
US Bureau of Labor Statistics (1980) Directory of US 30 (1): 43–59.
National Unions and Employee Associations, 1979. Wilson, Tom, TUC Director of Organisation and Services
Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office. (2006). Interviews with first author, June and July.
11
Trade Union Strategy
Peter Boxall

INTRODUCTION Strategic choice in trade unions


‘Strategy can be viewed as the set of consistent
Over the last ten years, against a backdrop behaviors by which the organization estab-
of a long period of union decline, discussion lishes for a time its place in its environment’
of union strategy has become increasingly (Mintzberg, 1978: 941).
common in the English-language industrial When we say that trade unions have
relations (IR) literature. The goal of this strategies, we are saying that they have
chapter is to offer a framework for con- ‘characteristic ways’ of interacting with their
ceptualizing and analyzing union strategy, environments (Boxall and Purcell, 2003: 28).
situating it within its wider contexts. The Strategy is the pattern of critical choices about
chapter adopts a strategic choice perspective ends and means that we see unfolding in an
and uses the notion of ‘organizational life organization’s behavior. As we observe trade
cycles’ to make sense of existing studies of unions over time, we can come to discern their
union strategy. One of the advantages of the typical intentions or goals and the resources
life cycle model is that it helps us to critically they typically build or mobilize to try to reach
review the present arguments surrounding these goals.
the strategic challenges that unions face in Two misconceptions about the notion of
the Anglo-American world. Some degree of strategy must be dealt with straight away.
caution must be exercised, however, when First, as with business organizations, none
borrowing concepts from management theory. of this implies that unions will use formal
There are important parallels with business methods of strategic planning. Strategies exist
firms, but trade unions as organizations also irrespective of whether formal planning takes
have distinctive features which need to be place (Mintzberg, 1978, 1990). Like other
carefully incorporated into the analysis. We organizations, unions use a range of admin-
begin with a discussion of what we mean by istrative structures and political processes
‘strategy’ in trade unions. to evolve strategy – standing committees,
210 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

annual conferences, informal ‘deals’ among and Haynes, 1997; Heery, 2005; Lange
power-brokers, management directives, direct et al., 1982) but what varies is the extent
action by those in the front-line, and so of their strategic choice. In environments
on (Boxall and Haynes, 1997). Rituals of where workers readily act in collective ways
formal planning, where they exist, may be and where employers can, and will, reach
useful in helping to theorize strategic issues accommodations, unions enjoy an extensive
and develop creative recommendations for realm of strategic choice (Boxall and Haynes,
change. On the other hand, they might amount 1997). On the other hand, unions restricted
to little more than a ‘talkfest’ and make very to organizing workers in the secondary
little impact on a union’s characteristic modes labor market among hostile employers face
of behavior. a much less favorable environment. They
Second, nothing in the notion of strategy retain a degree of strategic choice but some
assumes that unions will be particularly effec- aspirations, such as organizing low-skilled,
tive in dealing with the strategic problems vulnerable groups of workers on small sites,
they face. Like other organizations, unions may simply be unattainable in the absence
exhibit strengths and weaknesses in relation of explicit state support (Boxall and Haynes,
to their environment. In the worst case, 1997: 569–70).
the weaknesses of existing structures and Even though many, if not most, unions
processes expose unions to the risk that are currently facing difficult environments,
their strategies – their characteristic ways of it would be unhelpful to adopt a hyper-
behaving – will drift further and further away deterministic stance which casts them as a
from the challenges actually presented by hopelessly reactive and powerless class of
their environments: a syndrome known in the organizations. Ann C. Frost’s (2001) work on
business management literature as ‘strategic the different responses of three union ‘locals’
drift’ (Johnson and Scholes, 2002: 76). In to restructuring in the North American steel
time, this will undermine, and may fatally industry usefully illustrates this point. Faced
compromise, a union’s economic viability and with very similar and serious threats to the
its social legitimacy. competitive viability of their plants (and thus
Meaningful discussion of strategy does, to their memberships), union leaders adopted
however, imply a ‘strategic choice’ perspec- a much more engaging, multi-level interaction
tive (Child, 1972, 1997). Both words are with management in two plants than in the
important: ‘strategic’ means that some actions third. In the former cases, union members
are critical or consequential for the survival were fully involved in developing proposals
of organizations and, if they survive, their for change while, in the latter, the local
relative degree of performance (Boxall and union president centralized decision-making
Purcell, 2003: 30–2). The word ‘choice’ in the union. Because of the need to use
underlines the fact that deciding to do one the deep technical knowledge of workers
thing usually implies deciding not to do to bring about productivity gains, it is not
another: strategies involve heading down surprising that restructuring was much more
one path, with all that this implies about successful in the cases where union members
opportunities for learning, both good and bad, were deeply involved. In fact, in the case
while denying ourselves the option of heading where only the union president engaged with
down another. management, restructuring proposals were
The notion of ‘choice’ also reminds us that unworkable: neither the branch president nor
organizations are rarely totally ‘determined’ management had sufficient knowledge of
by their environments: there is always some what was workable. The point here is that how
element of discretion in the hands of leaders a union engages with its own members is one
and other actors in the organization (Child, of the principal dimensions of strategic choice
1972, 1997). In this sense, it is fair to (Boxall and Haynes, 1997). In this respect,
describe unions as ‘strategic actors’ (Boxall the union locals in Frost’s (2001) study were
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 211

not simply determined by their environment: mediating organizations between employers


even in such difficult circumstances, there and workers while being embedded in this
were strategic options available to union wider context.1 Most of their strategic behav-
leaders and the different strategic choices ior is oriented to organizing workers and
they took around activating and expressing negotiating with employers. In playing this
membership participation led to markedly mediating role in industries, occupations and
different outcomes. workplaces, however, unions are engaged
with wider economic and socio-political
forces. They typically operate not only at the
The contexts of union strategy level of employer-employee interactions but
Reviews of trade union structures and strate- ‘at the level of the society’ where they seek
gies regularly note that unions are located ‘to defend workers both as workers and as
within a network of actors and the strategies citizens’ (Levesque and Murray, 2002: 47).
they form are influenced by a range of critical Powerful union movements play an important
factors expressed through the behavior of role in the political economy. Individual
the actors in this network and through wider unions often affiliate with a national union
economic and socio-political influences (for federation which plays some role in evolving
example, Charlwood, 2004; Fiorito et al., strategies designed to influence the national
2001; Fiorito, 2004; Heery, 2005; Hyman, (and international) political economy, includ-
1994; Masters and Atkin, 1999). Figure 11.1 ing the framework for regulating interest
depicts the way in which unions act as conflicts in the workplace. Links with political

Economic context:
trends in real income; levels
of unemployment; product
market conditions;
technological change;change
in occupational structure

Worker and labor Employer context:


movement context: industry and
orientations of The trade union’s corporate
relevant workers, strategic choices: structure;
unionised and non- shaped in the management
unionised; levels of context of its ideologies and
workplace structure, traditions strategies;
dissatisfaction; and internal politics company
inter-union politics performance

Socio-political context:
systems of labor regulation
(national and international);
capital market institutions;
other organizations in local
communities; power
dynamics in wider society,
including state support of
unions or opposition to them

Figure 11.1 The context of trade union strategy


212 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

parties – and the various ways this influence In the US context, for example, ‘business
can be exerted – are very important to many, unionism’ connotes a pattern in which unions
if not most, trade unions (for example, James, came to focus on ‘instrumental goals’ at
2004). On a more local basis, unions may also the workplace and had little truck with
develop strategies to engage with community- class politics or revolutionary ideals (Fiorito
based organizations (for example, in the et al., 2001). Business unionism represented a
pursuit of ‘living wage’ campaigns (for pattern of union strategic choices that fitted the
example, Nissen, 2000). economic, ideological and political context of
The box in Figure 11.1 symbolizing union US industrial relations, particularly from the
strategic choices notes the way that these 1950s through to the late 1970s, but which
choices are inevitably shaped by the union’s many now argue has become part of an ill-
structure, its traditions (or ‘culture’) and fitting and failing pattern of behavior (see, for
its internal politics (for example, Fiorito example, Voss and Sherman, 2000).
et al., 2001; Heery, 2005; Hyman, 2001; In parallel with the literature on ‘vari-
Voss and Sherman, 2000). It is unhelpful eties of capitalism’ (Gospel and Pendleton,
to see a union’s structure as something 2003; Hall and Soskice, 2001), which notes
devolving straightforwardly from its strategy. that the labor strategies of firms tend to
This would be an overly simplistic reading of be heavily shaped by the surrounding set
Alfred Chandler’s (1962) famous dictum that of economic and political institutions, the
‘structure follows strategy’. As Mintzberg’s literature on union strategies is now locating
(for example, 1978) work argues, it is more unions in a similar way (see this Handbook,
helpful to understand strategy and structure Chapter 7). Unions develop ‘histories of
as interactive: new strategies can give rise to action’within ‘particular national institutional
new structures (as, for example, when a union environments’ (Frege and Kelly, 2004: 38).
decides to represent another occupational In Hyman’s (2001) terms, ‘market-oriented’
group and does so by merger with another unionism, typical in the Anglo-American
union). On the other hand, existing struc- world, needs to be distinguished from ‘class
tures tend to condition what is strategically unionism’, prevalent in Italy and Spain,
possible, making some goals ‘thinkable’ and and from the social dialogue model found
others virtually impossible. Thus, in ‘large, in Germany. Union strategy in neo-liberal
merged “super unions”’, existing structures environments (Boxall and Haynes, 1997) –
and established roles seriously affect the where unions must rely on industrial strategy
possibilities for implementing certain kinds unsupported by corporatism or political spon-
of espoused strategy (Charlwood, 2004: 383). sorship – is significantly different from union
For example, Carter’s (2000) analysis of strategy in societies where unions have social-
attempted strategic change in the Manufac- partner status. As Heery and Adler (2004:
turing, Science and Finance Union (UK) 63–4) put it,
shows how regional officials and branch
representatives are often in a position to where states accord the status of social partner
resist the dictates of national officials on the to unions and allocate resources to support their
functions there is less incentive to organize but
grounds of strongly-held beliefs that some
where states pursue a policy of union exclusion
ideas will simply not work and certainly the need to cultivate internal resources of power
not without their willing cooperation (see, through organizing is correspondingly stronger.
especially, pp. 128–9).
Saying that union strategy is influenced by a Dominant institutional features in societies
range of actors and contextual factors are not, mean that unions tend to focus in different
however, saying very much. Analysis takes a ways, creating significant variation in the
step forward when studies or frameworks help extent to which workplace organizing is a
us to identify patterns of strategic behavior as key strategic thrust (Heery and Adler, 2004).
unions interact with these contextual factors. Besides key differences around the integration
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 213

Maturity: Renewal crisis:


Establishment
stable growth successful
crisis:
but variations in reconfiguration
viable strategic
performance and to cope with
configuration
readiness for threatening
or failure
change change or failure

Figure 11.2 Phases of industry evolution


Source: Boxall and Purcell, 2003: 189.

of unions into the political economy, compe- the premise that organizations are typically
tition between union federations is a major located in industries and industries are subject
difference across different national contexts, to evolutionary forces (Carroll and Hannan,
something which occurs in Italy and Spain but 1995).
which has been relatively rare in the English- Industries emerge at particular points in
speaking world (Behrens, Hamann, and Hurd, time and evolve through a ‘life cycle’:
2004), at least until the recent split-up of periods of establishment, maturity,
the AFL-CIO in the United States (see this and renewal/decline (as summarized in
Handbook, Chapter 10). Figure 11.2). The organic or establishment
This brief review of the wider context phase involves high levels of start-ups
means that we must recognize significant with founding leaders of organizations
diversity in union strategy across different experimenting with a range of business
societies. While influencing the direction of models (what set of product features or
labor legislation and political settlements is services to offer, which technologies to adopt,
important to all union movements, some are how to organize work and employment
much more focused on strategies at national systems, how to fund the organization, how
political levels than are others. As Turner to gain official sanction, etc.). This process
(2004: 6–7) notes, there is currently an impor- of experimentation and jostling for influence
tant distinction between ‘labor movements eventually leads to the creation of one or
that (are) focus(ing) revitalization efforts on more ‘dominant designs’ for organizations
mobilization, and those … focus(ing) on insti- in the industry (Boxall and Purcell, 2003;
tutional position and/or reform’ (emphasis Suarez and Utterback, 1995). Dominant
in original). Preferences and the balance of designs are systems of choices which are
energy can, of course, change over time economically and socially sustainable.
within a single labor movement as one Individual organizations, while inevitably
avenue becomes problematic or faces a crisis. building their own idiosyncrasies, either
Having said this, this chapter must make mould their strategies around one of these
some strategic choices of its own. While dominant designs or fail. Organizations that
recognizing the importance of both workplace successfully perceive and adopt a dominant
and wider political strategies, and their design enjoy the growth opportunities,
interconnectedness, the chapter will direct its and room for elements of variation, that
analysis to studies within the Anglo-American come with the mature phase. However,
‘market-oriented’ tradition of trade unionism. nothing lasts forever and the mature phase
is eventually challenged by serious change
(economic, technological, social or political)
Strategy and the life cycle of trade
in the environment. At this point, dominant
unions: organic and mature phases
designs are either reformed in functional
Organizational ecology is a school within ways or organizations fail. As this suggests,
organizational studies which starts from strategic choices are typically laid down by
214 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

founding leaders and solidify in periods of crusading rhetoric and with notions of righting
growth but then become subject to challenge injustice.
by subsequent coalitions of actors when
the dominant design is underperforming or The mature phase
shown to be failing. Success in the organic phase meant that unions
Despite variations in rates of change, matured into organizations which could no
the three-phase model of industry evolution longer rely on grassroots’ spontaneity but
is well supported by research in industrial required some kind of permanent structure
economics (Mueller, 1997). It provides a of officials and management committees (for
useful structure to analyze all sorts of orga- example, Hyman, 1989; Lester, 1958). The
nizations, including trade unions (Hannan, dominant design of unions became heavily
1995; Kearney, 2003; Lester, 1958). laced with bureaucratic features. It is in the
mature phase that we need to apply a more
The organic phase sophisticated understanding of unions as orga-
Unions began as ‘social movement organiza- nizations if we are to interpret union strategy.
tions’ (Hannan, 1995: 121). The great surge In organizational terms, maturity meant that
of union formation in the US took place in the unions came to exhibit a conflict between
nineteenth century while the largest growth the ‘administrative rationality’ needed in an
of membership took place in ‘great spurts’ at efficient bureaucracy and the ‘representative
the end of the First World War, throughout the rationality’ of an organization of volunteers
Great Depression of the 1930s, and during the (Child et al., 1973: 77). The hiring of
Second World War (Hannan, 1995; Kaufman, permanent administrators or paid officials
2004). Here, and elsewhere in the English- inevitably created a tension between hierar-
speaking world, trade unions sprang from chical control by the managerial elite and
serious interest conflicts between workers and democratic decision-making by the members.
employers: conflicts over safety, pay levels, It opened up the possibility for ‘agency
employment security, working hours and the issues’ (Fiorito et al., 2001: 242): for the
pace of work: over the whole relationship goals of leaders to diverge from those of
between what is given and what is asked for members (Lester, 1958: 56–8). While there
in the wage-work bargain. are similar tensions in business organizations,
At the outset, then, trade unionism was a the ambiguity around leadership in unions as
grassroots-driven, collective worker response voluntary organizations – the members pay to
to objectively poor conditions. Its funda- belong and are not employees of the union –
mental goal was to significantly improve is a distinctive characteristic.
the experience of work and the returns to The ways in which this tension is worked
labor and to ensure that organized labor out vary across different unions and across
could play an ongoing role in the regulation the same union at different times (Boxall and
of working conditions. Union organizations Haynes, 1997). Some mature unions appear
were more ‘militant and turbulent, with to behave as official-led organizations in
internal factionalism and vigorous external which members consume a standard diet of
opposition’ (Lester, 1958: 21). Membership services in exchange for their subscriptions:
participation was high. Working-class com- the ‘servicing’ model. Others seek to embrace
munities – in which people lived nearby the ‘organizing’ model or ‘empower’ the
and frequently traveled to and from work members.2 Such a strategic choice appears
together – created dense networks of ‘social as a decision taken by the managerial elite,
capital’ (Jarley, 2005). In the context of a much as might be expected in a corporation.
surging social movement, we must understand However, it is entirely possible that the
trade union ‘strategy’ as something organic members themselves are seeking to shift the
rather than manufactured: something driven implicit model of union behavior, that they
by evident needs for change, heavy with lead their officials into a more grassroots, shop
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 215

floor–driven style of unionism. As Turnbull not rest on a simple dichotomy between


(1988: 113) puts it, ‘trade union structure adversarialism and cooperation but rests on
and behavior involves a two-way process blends of the two. Any form of sustainable
of internal control’ (emphasis in original). engagement with an employer involves some
At various times, paid and/or lay officials level of co-operation and carries the risk of
may be pulling in one direction while strong incorporation (see, for example, Craft, 1991;
groups of members pull in another, albeit Hyman, 1989). Some unions go little further
within a context of long-term interdependence than they must to secure the best contract
(Crouch, 1982: 187–9; Heery, 2005). In all they can, assiduously avoiding identification
mature unions, then, there is a ‘politics of with the sort of employer decisions that
leadership’which requires sensitive analysis if could subsequently prove unpopular with
strategic decision-making is to be understood members. Other unions adopt an approach
(Boxall and Haynes, 1997: 571). which involves classical bargaining while
In terms of workplace strategies, mature simultaneously exploring the possibilities
unions can exhibit a range of styles. In Boxall of ‘concertation’ (Crouch, 1982: 109–17)
and Haynes’ (1997) typology, union strategy or closer integration with the employer’s
is understood as a conjunction of choices business. One strategy involves union officials
in relation to workers and employers. The in a kind of ‘attitudinal structuring’ (Walton
worker face of union strategy is concerned and McKersie, 1965: 184–280) where they
with the extent to which the union blends offer their ideological support on the shop
servicing and organizing models. Boxall and floor. Again, this can back-fire if officials
Haynes (1997) argue that servicing and misinterpret the mood of members on key
organizing are wrongly portrayed as dichoto- issues. More robustly participative options
mous choices,3 that all unions provide some involve the pursuit of joint working parties
services to members, which are particularly in which activists, rather than paid officials,
important when members seek protection are engaged (as, for example, in two of
against management actions directed at them Frost’s (2001) case studies). The most exten-
as individuals (Masters and Atkin, 1999; sive option involves seeking to raise the
Terry, 1994). Given this reality, the strategic level of participation to that of the firm’s
question in terms of the worker dimension ‘strategic activities’ (Kochan et al., 1986:
of union strategy is the extent to which 15–8), such as business portfolio choices and
unions build organizing capabilities which plant location decisions, a strategy which
complement their servicing activities. The carries heightened risks of incorporation
logical starting place is the creation of net- (Terry, 1994).
works of activists, while another is associated Combining the employer and worker
with incorporating or fostering strong cells of dimensions leads to four patterns of union
workers. More powerful forms of organizing strategic choice (see Figure 11.3) (Boxall
presuppose the presence of activists and/or and Haynes, 1997). ‘Classic unionism’, the
cells but add the propensity to mobilize style most associated with the historical
the total membership around key issues, rise of workforce struggle for improved
generating episodes of mass organization conditions, depends on a conjunction of
or ‘surges of participation’ when important classical choices. On the worker side, classic
worker interests are threatened (Fosh, 1993: unions are not simply organizations of
580). To the extent that unions naturally consumers but pose a threat to employers
encompass or complement their servicing through activism and mobilization. On the
roles with these more powerful forms of employer side, the approach is vigorously
worker participation, they are a threat to oppositional: the engagement does not extend
employer control in the workplace. beyond the explicit wage-work bargain,
Similarly, Boxall and Haynes (1997) argue although an intensive amount of job reg-
that the employer face of union strategy does ulation may occur. ‘Paper-tiger unionism’
216 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Classic unionism Partnership unionism

Worker relations: servicing plus solid Worker relations: servicing plus solid

organizing organizing

Employer relations: robust adversarialism, Employer relations: credible

no incorporation adversarialism with extensive cooperative

practices

Paper-tiger unionism Consultancy unionism

Worker relations: servicing only Worker relations: mostly servicing,

Employer relations: formalistic limited organizing

adversarialism Employer relations: routine adversarialism

with some cooperative practices

Figure 11.3 Four patterns of trade union strategic choice in neo-liberal environments
Source: Boxall and Haynes, 1997: 576.

entails a stance of ‘formalistic adversari- complexity resulting from amalgamations of


alism’ toward employers without building diverse worker groups into ‘general unions’,
a base of worker activism. Without strong or because of size and the resulting diversity
state support compelling employers to deal of employers encountered, or because of
with them, paper tiger unions wither away. significant ideological differences between
‘Consultancy unionism’ is distinguished from officials and members (Boxall and Haynes,
‘paper tigerism’ through an ability to carry 1997). It is thus important to distinguish
out routine collective bargaining (at enterprise between specific unions and patterns of
and/or establishment levels) and some basic unionism. A large union may exhibit more
attempts to stimulate organization, typically than one pattern of unionism.
through a selective network of activists. This Large unions are, in certain ways, analo-
enables limited expressions of co-operation gous to conglomerate firms (Willman, 2001):
with employers. ‘Partnership unionism’ is ‘head office’ officials preside over clusters
a style now widely discussed in which or portfolios of bargaining units, in which
unions seek a more constructive engagement the economics of organizing differ and across
in the strategic management of firms and which variegation in strategy is inevitable.
industries. Boxall and Haynes (1997) contrast Willman (2001: 98) defines a ‘viable bargain-
this from consultancy unionism, arguing ing unit … as one that is capable of sustaining
that partnership unionism is best launched collective bargaining with an employer with-
from a position of workplace strength in out long-term support from elsewhere in the
which the union presents both a threat and union’. His framework identifies four broad
an opportunity to the employer’s business. types of bargaining unit (Figure 11.4). In the
Management is far more inclined to respect most desirable condition (A), the employer
partners with power (see also Belanger et al., is co-operative and members are active,
2002: 66–7). reducing union costs per member and enabling
While fieldwork shows that some unions other units to be subsidized. In condition B,
fall into one of the main categories in members are willing to pay dues but not
Figure 11.3, other unions exhibit greater so willing to participate in union activities
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 217

Employer
Cooperative Recalcitrant

Membership A C

Lay representation Low facilities


Facilities agreements High official
Active Check-off involvement
Exporter of funds High potential for
Politically powerful conflict
within union Importer of funds

B D

Full facilities De-recognition potential


Low lay representation Politically low profile
Passive
High official involvement Importer of funds
Exporter of funds

Figure 11.4 Willman’s ‘Union Portfolio’


Source: Willman, 2001: 103.

(perhaps because of time demands). Like A, inviable sites are not always popular with
however, this condition enables some cross- existing members.
subsidization. The problematic categories are The Boxall and Haynes (1997) framework
C and D: in the former, members are prepared indicates the way in which unions tend
to take action but conflict is costly because the to adapt their workplace strategies to the
employer is oppositional while, in the latter, context they face. As mentioned, paper-tiger
the combination of a recalcitrant employer unionism is a failing strategy outside a state-
and a passive membership is likely to lead to enforced system of union recognition and
de-recognition. contract negotiation. Consultancy unionism
The implication of Willman’s (2001: 114) poses little threat and thus depends on an
framework is that it is important to analyze employer seeing the efficiency and legitimacy
unions as ‘portfolios of viable and inviable value in negotiating a collective contract.
bargaining units’. This casts quite a different Where not pressed by strong activism, the
light on the dynamics of union growth and majority of employers now prefer a regime
decline. It is possible for a union to grow in of individual contracts and direct forms of
membership numbers but if this is heavily worker voice (Boxall and Purcell, 2003),
loaded toward risky bargaining units (types albeit with strong elements of standardization
C and D); the union’s financial viability is which help to demonstrate equity of treatment.
undermined. On the other hand, a union In Anglo-American societies, classic union-
could experience membership decline but ism has become a common pattern in public
consolidate around a cluster of highly viable sector services, such as public health and
sites (types A and B) and, thus, become education. Health and education professionals
stronger. This perspective ‘helps to explain have increasingly responded with force to
the size distribution of unions in the UK, a context in which rising community needs
with the persistence of viable small unions and new technologies have escalated work
during a long period of increasing union demands while governments have struggled
concentration’ (Willman, 2001: 105). Larger to improve funding or have deliberately
scale is not always beneficial. We might also constrained it for broader reasons of economic
note that official-driven expansion strategies or political management (Boxall and Haynes,
that involve acquiring and cross-subsidizing 1997; Charlwood, 2004). Classic unionism is
218 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

also common in those parts of the private also wants to exercise what Walton et al.
sector where it first emerged but which now (1994) call ‘escape’: shifts of production
represent a much lower share of national sites to lower cost and less troublesome
employment: mining, large-scale manufactur- locations (nowadays, the seemingly ubiqui-
ing and the transport infrastructure. Workers tous ‘outsourcing’ and ‘offshoring’). In these
in these sectors may be quiescent during contextual conditions, partnership unionism is
periods of high unemployment but still gen- inherently fragile: ‘even where management
erally show a capacity to mobilize when they is ideologically supportive, unions cannot
consider important interests are threatened. easily alter the wider politics of restructuring
It goes without saying that unions cannot and rationalization in large organizations’
initiate the partnership pattern without a (Boxall and Haynes, 1997: 587). A recent
willing management. Management can be study of an aerospace firm in the UK
interested in situations where significant by Danford et al. (2004) confirms this
change is required to stay or become assessment: union-management partnerships
competitive (Boxall and Purcell, 2003), as are unlikely to survive in product market
shown in the British partnership arrangements contexts characterized by intense margin com-
studied by Haynes and Allen (2000) and petition where managers are unable to make
Tailby and Winchester (2000). Firms with any meaningful commitment to job security
highly unionized workforces whose managers because of corporate requirements to secure
wish to restructure work to build ‘high- cost reductions. In these situations, played out
performance work systems’ have an obvious frequently in Anglo-American capital market
incentive to work co-operatively with their regimes, management is instinctively resistant
unions when union leaders and activists can to growth in union power, an attitude which
help to legitimate and facilitate change. For inevitably becomes apparent over time. It
their part, union leaders in these situations seems likely that only in rare situations will
often have an incentive to do so because contemporary Anglo-American management
there are ‘positive aspects of the new be willing and able to sustain a joint
model, which workers themselves naturally philosophy respecting the union’s institutional
espouse (expression of tacit skills, teamwork security and protecting existing union jobs.
and reduced supervision)’ (Belanger et al., Lesser forms of partnership can, of course,
2002: 41). However, the tension for unions be pursued where management does not
lies in the fact that the new work systems directly undermine the union but declines to
simultaneously involve a degree of challenge promise strong forms of job security and this
to worker interests: obviously to employment may appeal to union leaders who feel they
security and, some would argue, to employee can sustain their internal legitimacy in these
stress levels through work intensification (see, conditions.
for example, Godard, 2004; Ramsay et al.,
2000). This latter point is currently a matter
Strategy and the life cycle of trade
of some debate: other evidence on the impacts
unions: the renewal crisis
of new work systems finds that it is possible
to create a pathway to higher performance This last comment brings us naturally to the
which works through involvement without current debate over union strategy. Unions in
intensification (see, for example, Appelbaum the Anglo-American world have moved past
et al., 2000; Mackie et al., 2001). their prime into an era of crisis, characterized
Where the degree of change needed is by serious decline in union density, loss of
severe, however, management will typically workplace relevance and political marginal-
pursue a blend of what Walton et al. ization. There is an outpouring of writing
(1994) call ‘forcing’ (imposed change) and on how unions might renew themselves,
‘fostering’ (facilitated, cooperative changes including important edited collections by
in working styles). Increasingly, management Bronfrenbrenner et al. (1998), Fairbrother and
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 219

Yates (2003), Harcourt and Wood (2004), effect change (Belanger et al., 2002: 67).
Healy et al. (2004), Milkman and Voss (2004), Where it has been successful, it has often
Verma and Kochan (2004), and Frege and entailed a blend of old and new tactics
Kelly (2004), among others. The ‘dominant including
designs’ of trade unions are currently the
subject of extensive critique. focusing on issues such as dignity and fairness
As we have just seen, one avenue for in addition to material concerns; using ‘corpo-
rate campaigns’, which involve interfering in the
renewal lies through the pursuit of partnership
employer’s relations with lenders, clients, share-
unionism but union leaders adopting this holders, and subsidiaries; strategically targeting
strategy must make a very careful assessment industries and workplaces to be organized; staging
of their context and the direction in which frequent direct actions; pressuring public officials to
it is evolving. Helping management renew influence local employers; allying with community
and religious groups; using the media to dis-
companies is not the same as renewing
seminate the union’s message; and circumventing
trade unions. For example, when labor- the NLRB election process to demand ‘card-check
substituting technological changes become recognition’ (Voss and Sherman, 2000: 311–2).
irreversible in an industry, as has been
happening in Canadian metal-mining, unions Voss and Sherman’s (2000: 309) study of a
might secure a high skill-high pay contract for group of 14 Californian union locals identifies
the workforce remnant but cannot protect the three important conditions for unions to break
‘vast majority’ of their membership who are out of bureaucratic business unionism into a
‘simply displaced’ (Chaykowski, 2002: 600). ‘revitalized’ mode: first, ‘an internal political
In these conditions, ‘reinventing’ the union crisis that fosters the entry of new leadership’;
is a reality for only a small proportion of second, these new leaders having ‘activist
members. The logical strategy for the vast experience in other social movements’; and,
bulk of members is to ‘milk till dry’ the third, the new leaders having the political and
wages and benefits available under traditional resource backing of the national leadership
contracts and the redundancy compensation in the relevant union. Such transitions are
offered to buy out their jobs as these contracts not victim-less because some ‘resistant staff
are restructured. What workers do after they in some of the fully revitalized locals have
are paid out – whether they retrain or whether been let go or encouraged to quit’4 (Voss and
they ever work again – is up to them. Sherman, 2000: 324).
Studies of union revitalization thus need This study helps to make the point that
to consider not only the employer face we should avoid creating the picture that a
of strategy but simultaneously examine the simple return to organic unionism is generally
impacts on workers. Since unions are volun- occurring or is generally feasible. While
tary organizations of workers, the question of organic unionism can, and does, re-emerge
the prospects for union renewal turns very in some situations of objective exploitation,
critically on the analysis of worker needs the challenge for unions is generally one of
and how these have evolved. One prominent rebalancing the roles of officials, activists
line of analysis has been that associated with and members, finding new ways to integrate
the renewal of unions as ‘social movements’ centralized decision-making and servicing
(for example, Johnston, 1994; Juravich and with grassroots’ democracy and involvement.
Hilgert, 1999; Nissen, 2003) or through redis- Unless they willingly dissolve themselves into
covery of the organizing model (for example, cells of workers, unions will remain bureau-
Bronfrenbrenner and Juravich, 1998; Hurd, cracies in which the management of staff
1998). Social movement unionism has re- and their role-relations with members remain
emerged in situations of low wages, poor critical. Union renewal involves some kind of
conditions and social exclusion, where unions reform of union bureaucracy, not a repudiation
have ‘constructed broader coalitions of work- of it. In this regard, the model emerging in
ers and identity-based community groups’ to the UK is more accurately called ‘managed
220 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

activism’ in which ‘management skills and Rogers, 1999), a pattern mirrored elsewhere
processes are directed at promoting activism in the Anglo-American world (Boxall et al.,
while activists themselves are encouraged to 2007). The representation gap is highest
“manage” their own activity’ (Heery et al., among young workers, those on low incomes,
2000: 1004). In the US, Lustig (2002: 8) has and those whose workplaces have lots of labor
described the ‘successor to services-unionism problems.
that provides for increased activism and If most of this frustrated demand could
recruitment but retains centralized control’ as be effectively organized (and many workers
a ‘mobilizing model’, one which ‘embraces who experience it are in small, hard-to-reach
grassroots activity but still directs it from workplaces), union movements would be
above’. Nissen’s (2000: 47) study of the stronger and more politically powerful in
living wage campaign in Miami, for example, all Anglo-American societies. However,
underlines the importance of building a social they would still be irrelevant to most
movement organization, one in which a workers in the private sector who no longer
small staff of highly-skilled, paid organizers identify with trade unionism. For example,
coordinates and maintains the agenda: studies of worker identities show how some
workers are opposed to what they perceive
… the living wage issue is not really the product
of a genuine, more spontaneous ‘organic’ social
as the leveling strategies of trade unions.
movement. Low wage workers play a very small Milton (2003: 41) explains how the North
role (or no role) in most living wage coalitions … American high-tech workers he studied
Building the coalition is a long, hard organizing regard ‘unions as anti-creative and opposed
process. Given that, there is seldom a substitute for to the meritocracy system that anchors
competent, paid staff to organize the work and get
‘grassroots leaders’ involved.
excellence in technology-based industries’.
Strategies of organizing around discontent at
There is growing recognition that current a particular workplace are relevant to some
union renewal strategies might help to worker groups but alienate others who want
make unions more externally focused on non-conflictual forms of voice (Freeman and
recruitment and more internally concerned Rogers, 1999) and ‘express strong interest
with membership involvement but will hardly in having a job environment that supports
usher in an era of mass worker mobilization continued learning and development’ (Verma
(see, for example, Hurd, 2004). As Kaufman and Kochan, 2004: 7). For Verma and Kochan
(2004: 52) points out, the ‘growth prospect of (2004: 14), the implication is that unions
unions is directly tied to the breadth and depth should ‘adopt strategies and organizational
of labor problems affecting wage earners’: structures that allow them to retain members
absent such conditions, great spurts do not as they move across jobs and through different
occur in union density (see also Charlwood, stages of their life cycle’. Similarly, Bryson
2004). Similarly, de Turberville (2004: 785) (2004: 22), in his analysis of the British
comments that it is ‘questionable whether, in Worker Representation and Participation
periods of economic expansion, with increas- Survey, argues that unions need to grow the
ing job opportunities, the organizing model ‘aspirational agenda’ while simultaneously
could generate a sustainable membership and having enough power to be credible on the
stewards system let alone a wider social adversarial agenda, when that is needed.
movement’. In sum, research on the prospects for
There are, as noted, significant pockets of union renewal increasingly cautions against
worker discontent where a traditional union any kind of ‘one-size-fits-all’ prescription
strategy is wanted and needed. This is demon- for union revitalization and has moved on
strated by studies of union representation from simplistic appeals to the organizing
gaps: around a third of US workers in non- model. Studies suggest that while unions still
unionized firms in the private sector have have a traditional or classical role to play
frustrated demand for unionism (Freeman and where workers are exploited, are vulnerable
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 221

to restructuring or are experiencing serious strategic question in terms of the worker


imbalance in the wage-work bargain, their dimension of union strategy is the extent to
chances of generating broader social appeal which unions build organizing capabilities
depend on whether they can find a non- which complement their servicing activities.
traditional role that engages with the develop- Similarly, the employer face of union strategy
mental aspirations that now characterize many does not rest on a simple dichotomy between
workers (Rose, 2000). What is not clear is adversarialism and cooperation but rests
the basis on which workers who are pursuing on blends of the two. A certain level of
self-development in and across workplaces cooperation is necessary in any union bar-
might want support from trade unions, would gaining engagement if a workable collective
be prepared to pay for it and would be agreement is going to result. Union choices
prepared to participate in sustaining it. While along worker and employer dimensions,
unions need a ‘proactive’, ‘autonomous’ evolved in particular contexts, create various
agenda (Levesque and Murray, 2002: 50), patterns of unionism, each carrying different
they need processes capable of keeping pace risks and advantages. It is important to
with the way worker interests, and attitudes distinguish unions from patterns of unionism
to representation, have been evolving. If they and it helps to analyze union growth and
cannot develop such processes, the ‘dominant decline not simply in terms of membership
designs’ of trade unions will continue to numbers. Trade unions are usefully analyzed
exhibit ‘strategic drift’. as portfolios of viable and inviable bargaining
units, particularly if we bring into such
analysis the politics of portfolio decisions.
CONCLUSIONS Understanding the particular tensions that
unions face as mature bureaucracies is
Unions are voluntary organizations mediating important to understanding their strategic
the different but overlapping interests of behavior. Anglo-American unions have now
workers and employers and expressing a moved from maturity into a renewal crisis
broader voice for workers in society. Their brought about by a long period of decline.
strategic choices, influenced by their own They are confronted with major evolution in
structures, traditions and internal politics, are employer strategies, elements of which appeal
shaped within the context of workplace inter- to workers while other parts pose threats.
actions and within a much larger economic Questions of union revitalization turn not only
and socio-political context. In comparative on the employer face of strategy but also –
terms, there are major differences between and very critically – on the analysis of worker
unions within labor movements which enjoy needs and how these are evolving. Research
‘social partner’ status and those that must indicates that while some worker groups need
survive with minimal state support. While and want traditional union representation, oth-
recognizing these and other key variations, ers have moved on to a more developmental
this chapter has focused on trade union strat- orientation to work based on self-help and
egy within the Anglo-American tradition of personal growth. Whether union movements
trade unionism and analyzed patterns of union can renew themselves through simultaneously
strategy across establishment, maturity and responding to these two sets of needs is
renewal/decline phases of the organizational currently a very open question.
life cycle.
At the workplace level, union strategy can
be understood as a conjunction of postures ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
toward workers and employers. Servicing and
organizing models are helpful for understand- I am very grateful to Jack Fiorito and Ed Heery
ing the worker face of union strategy but for their comments on an earlier draft. The
do not constitute a simple dichotomy: the usual disclaimer applies.
222 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

NOTES Bronfrenbrenner, K., Oswald, R., Friedman, S., Seeber, R.


and Hurd, R. (1998) (eds) Organizing to Win: New
1 To save space, representative sources for each Research on Union Strategies, Ithaca: ILR Press.
of these influences are not included in the chapter. Bryson, A. (2004) A Perfect Union? What Workers Want
Suffice to say, the factors identified are not From Unions, London: TUC.
controversial. Carroll, G.R. and Hannan, M. T. (eds) (1995)
2 Hurd (1998) notes that the contrast between Organizations in Industry: Strategy, Structure and
‘servicing’ and ‘organizing’ models was first used in
Selection, New York & Oxford: Oxford University
an AFL-CIO teleconference in 1988 and published in
the resulting manual, ‘Numbers That Count’.
Press.
3 A view very much reinforced by the respondents Carter, B. (2000) ‘Adoption of the organizing model
to Fiorito’s (2004) survey of British trade union officials in British trade unions: some evidence from
(see, especially, pp. 37–40). Manufacturing, Science and Finance (MSF)’. Work,
4 One might note that vigilant unions grieve Employment and Society, 14 (1): 117–36.
against such ‘constructive dismissals’ when companies Charlwood, A. (2004) ‘Annual review article 2003: the
instigate them. new generation of trade union leaders and prospects
for union revitalization’. British Journal of Industrial
Relations, 42 (2): 379–97.
Chaykowski, R. (2002) ‘Reinventing production systems
REFERENCES and industrial relations: technology-driven trans-
formation in the Canadian metal-mining industry’.
Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg, A. Journal of Labor Research, 23 (4): 591–613.
(2000) Manufacturing Advantage: Why High- Chandler, A. (1962) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in
Performance Work Systems Pay Off, Ithaca: ILR the History of Industrial Enterprise, Cambridge, Mass.:
Press. MIT Press.
Behrens, M., Hamann, K. and Hurd, R. (2004) ‘Con- Child, J. (1972) ‘Organizational structure, environment
ceptualizing labor union revitalization’. In Frege, C. and performance: the role of strategic choice’.
and Kelly, J. (eds) Varieties of Unionism: Strategies Sociology, 6 (3): 1–22.
for Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy, Oxford: Child, J. (1997) ‘Strategic choice in the analysis of action,
Oxford University Press. structure, organizations and environment: retrospect
Belanger, J., Giles, A. and Murray, G. (2002) ‘Towards and prospect’. Organization Studies, 18 (1): 43–76.
a new production model: potentialities, tensions and Child, J., Loveridge, R. and Warner, M. (1973) ‘Towards
contradictions’. In Murray, G., Belanger, J., Giles, A. an organizational study of trade unions’. Sociology,
and Lapointe, P. (eds) Work and Employment Rela- 7 (1): 71–91.
tions in the High-Performance Workplace. London Craft, J. (1991) ‘Unions, bureaucracy, and change: old
and New York: Continuum. dogs learn new tricks very slowly’. Journal of Labor
Boxall, P. and Haynes, P. (1997) ‘Strategy and trade Research, 12 (4): 393–405.
union effectiveness in a neo-liberal environment’. Crouch, C. (1982) Trade Unions: the Logic of Collective
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 35 (4): Action, Glasgow: Fontana.
567–91. Danford, A., Richardson, M., Tailby, S. and Upchurch, M.
Boxall, P. and Purcell, J. (2003) Strategy and Human (2004) ‘Partnership, mutuality and the high-
Resource Management, Basingstoke and New York: performance workplace: a case study of union strat-
Palgrave Macmillan. egy and worker experience in the aircraft industry’.
Boxall, P., Haynes, P. and Freeman, R. (2007) In Healy, G., Heery, E., Taylor, P. and Brown, W.
‘Conclusions: what workers say in the Anglo- (eds) The Future of Worker Representation, Bas-
American world’. In Freeman, R., Boxall, P. and ingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Haynes, P. (eds) What Workers Say: Employee Voice De Turberville, S. (2004) ‘Does the “organizing model”
in the Anglo-American Workplace, Ithaca: Cornell represent a credible union renewal strategy?’ Work,
University Press. Employment and Society, 18 (4): 775–94.
Bronfrenbrenner, K. and Juravich, T. (1998) ‘It Fairbrother, P. and Yates, C. (2003) Trade Unions
takes more than house calls: organizing to win in Renewal: A Comparative Study, London and
with a comprehensive union-building strategy’. In New York: Routledge.
Bronfrenbrenner, K., Oswald, R., Friedman, S., Fiorito, J. (2004) ‘Union renewal and the organizing
Seeber, R. and Hurd, R. (eds) Organizing to Win: New model in the United Kingdom’. Labor Studies Journal,
Research on Union Strategies, Ithaca: ILR Press. 29 (2): 21–53.
TRADE UNION STRATEGY 223

Fiorito, J., Jarley, P. and Delaney, J. (2001) ‘National a survey of policy and practice’. International Journal
unions as organizations’. Research in Personnel and of Human Resource Management, 11 (5): 986–1007.
Human Resources Management, 20: 231–68. Hurd, R. (1998) ‘Contesting the dinosaur image: the
Fosh, P. (1993) ‘Membership participation in work- labor movement’s search for a future’. Labor Studies
place unionism: the possibility of union renewal’. Journal, 22 (1): 5–30.
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 31 (4): Hurd, R. (2004) ‘The rise and fall of the organizing model
577–92. in the US’. In Harcourt, M. and Wood, G. (eds) Trade
Freeman, R. B. and Rogers, J. (1999). What Workers Unions and Democracy, Manchester and New York:
Want, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Manchester University Press.
Frege, C. and Kelly, J. (2004) ‘Union strategies in Hyman, R. (1989) The Political Economy of Industrial
comparative context’. In Frege, C. and Kelly, J. (eds) Relations, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Revitalization in a Hyman, R. (1994) ‘Changing trade union identities and
Globalizing Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press. strategies’. In Hyman, R. and Ferner, A. (eds) New
Frege, C. and Kelly, J. (2004) (eds) Varieties of Unionism: Frontiers in European Industrial Relations, Oxford:
Strategies for Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy, Blackwell.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hyman, R. (2001) Understanding European Trade
Frost, A. (2001) ‘Reconceptualizing local union Unionism, London: Sage.
responses to workplace restructuring in North James, P. (2004) ‘Trade unions and political parties’. In
America’. British Journal of Industrial Relations, Harcourt, M. and Wood, G. (eds) Trade Unions and
39 (4): 539–64. Democracy, Manchester and New York: Manchester
Godard, J. (2004) ‘A critical assessment of the high- University Press.
performance paradigm’. British Journal of Industrial Jarley, P. (2005) ‘Unions as social capital: renewal
Relations, 42 (2): 349–78. through a return to the logic of mutual aid?’ Labor
Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (2003) ‘Finance, Studies Journal, 29 (4): 1–26.
corporate governance and the management of labor: Johnson, G. and Scholes, K. (2002) Exploring Cor-
a conceptual and comparative analysis’. British porate Strategy: Text and Cases, Harlow: Pearson
Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (3): 557–82. Education.
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001) ‘An introduction to Johnston, P. (1994) Success While Others Fail: Social
varieties of capitalism’. In Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (eds) Movement Unionism in the Public Workplace, Cornell:
Varieties of Capitalism: the Institutional Foundations ILR Press. Juravich, T. and Hilgert, J. (1999)
of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University ‘UNITE’s victory at Richmark: community-based union
Press. organizing in communities of color’. Labor Studies
Hannan, M. (1995) ‘Labor unions’. In Carroll, G. R. and Journal, 24 (1): 27–41.
Hannan, M. T. (eds) (1995) Organizations in Industry: Juravich, T. and Hilgert, J. (1999) ‘UNITE’s victory
Strategy, Structure and Selection, New York & Oxford: at Richmark: community-based union organizing in
Oxford University Press. communities of color’. Labor Studies Journal, 24 (1):
Harcourt, M. and Wood, G. (eds) Trade Unions and 27–41.
Democracy, Manchester and New York: Manchester Kaufman, B. (2004) ‘Prospects for union growth in the
University Press. United States in the early 21st Century’. In Verma,
Haynes, P. and Allen, M. (2000) ‘Partnership as A. and Kochan, T. (eds) Unions in the 21st Century,
union strategy: a preliminary evaluation’. Employee New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Relations, 23 (2): 164–87. Kearney, R. (2003) ‘Patterns of union decline and
Healy, G., Heery, E., Taylor, P. and Brown, W. growth: an organizational ecology perspective’.
(2004) (eds) The Future of Worker Representation, Journal of Labor Research, 24 (4): 561–78.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Kochan, T.A., Katz, H.C. and McKersie, R.B. (1986)
Heery, E. (2005) ‘Sources of change in trade unions’. The Transformation of American Industrial Relations,
Work, Employment and Society, 19 (1): 91–106. New York: Basic Books.
Heery, E. and Adler, L. (2004) ‘Organizing the Lange, P., Ross, G and Vannicelli, M. (1982) Unions,
unorganized’. In Frege, C. and Kelly, J. (eds) Change and Crisis: French & Italian Union Strategy
Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Revitalization and the Political Economy 1945–1980, London: Allen
in a Globalizing Economy, Oxford: Oxford University and Unwin.
Press. Lester, R. (1958) As Unions Mature: An Analysis of the
Heery, E., Simms, M., Delbridge, R., Salmon, J. and Evolution of American Unionism, Princeton: Princeton
Simpson, D. (2000) ‘Union organizing in Britain: University Press.
224 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Levesque, C. and Murray, G. (2002) ‘Local versus global: Suarez, F. and Utterback, J. (1995) ‘Dominant designs
activating local union power in the global economy’. and the survival of firms’. Strategic Management
Labor Studies Journal, 27 (3): 39–65. Journal, 16 (6): 415–30.
Lustig, J. (2002) ‘New leadership and its discontents’. Tailby, S. and Winchester, D. (2000) ‘Management
Social Policy, 33 (1): 4–10. and trade unions: towards social partnership?’ In
Mackie, K.S., Holahan, C.K. and Gottlieb, N.H. (2001) S. Bach and K. Sisson (eds) Personnel Management:
‘Employee involvement management practices, work A Comprehensive Guide to Theory and Practice,
stress, and depression in employees of a human Oxford: Blackwell.
services residential care facility’. Human Relations, Terry, M. (1994) ‘Workplace unionism: redefining
54 (8): 1065–92. structures and objectives’. In Hyman, R. and Ferner, A.
Masters, M. and Atkin, R. (1999) Union strategies (eds), New Frontiers in European Industrial Relations,
for revival: a conceptual framework and literature Oxford: Blackwell.
review. Research in Personnel and Human Resources Turnbull, P. (1988) ‘An economic theory of trade union
Management, 17: 283–314. behavior: a critique’. British Journal of Industrial
Milkman, R. and Voss, K. (eds) (2004) Rebuilding Relations, 26 (1): 85–118.
Labor: Organizing and Organizers in the New Union Turner, L. (2004) ‘Why revitalize? Labor’s urgent mission
Movement, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. in a contested global economy’. In Frege, C. and
Milton, L. (2003) ‘An identity perspective on the Kelly, J. (eds) Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for
propensity of high-tech talent to unionize’. Journal Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy, Oxford:
of Labor Research, 24 (1): 31–53. Oxford University Press.
Mintzberg, H. (1978) ‘Patterns in strategy formation’. Verma, A. and Kochan, T. (2004) ‘Unions in the 21st
Management Science, 24 (9): 934–48. century: prospects for renewal’. In Verma, A. and
Mintzberg, H. (1990) ‘The design school: reconsidering Kochan, T. (2004) (eds) Unions in the 21st Century,
the basic premises of strategic management’. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Strategic Management Journal, 11 (3): 171–95. Verma, A. and Kochan, T. (2004) (eds) Unions in the 21
Mueller, D. (1997) ‘First-mover advantages and path st Century, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
dependence’. International Journal of Industrial Voss, K. and Sherman, R. (2000) ‘Breaking the iron law
Organization, 15 (6): 827–50. of oligarchy: union revitalization in the American labor
Nissen, B. (2000) ‘Living wage campaigns from a movement’. American Journal of Sociology, 106 (2):
‘social movement’ perspective: the Miami case’. Labor 303–49.
Studies Journal, 25 (3): 29–50. Walton, R. and McKersie, R. (1965) A Behav-
Nissen, B. (2003) ‘Alternative strategic directions for ioral Theory of Labor Negotiations, New York:
the US labor movement: recent scholarship’. Labor McGraw-Hill.
Studies Journal, 28 (1): 133–55. Walton, R., Cutcher-Gershenfeld, McKersie, R. (1994)
Ramsay, H., Scholarios, D. and Harley, B. (2000) Strategic Negotiations: A Theory of Change in Labor-
‘Employees and high-performance work systems: Management Relations, Boston: Harvard Business
testing inside the black box’. British Journal of School Press.
Industrial Relations, 38 (4): 501–31. Willman, P. (2001) ‘The viability of trade union
Rose, M. (2000) ‘Work attitudes in the expanding organization: a bargaining unit analysis’.
occupations’. In Purcell, K. (ed.) Changing Boundaries British Journal of Industrial Relations, 39 (1):
in Employment, Bristol: Bristol Academic Press. 97–117.
12
Employer Organizations
Franz Traxler

As with any other kind of interest association, (Traxler, 1995). Employers will generally
employer organizations are burdened with the prefer bilaterally individual exchange rela-
problem of collective action (Olson, 1965). tions with labor, since they can deploy their
The primary goal of interest associations is strategic advantages in the labor market most
to provide collective goods the benefits of effectively in these circumstances. In contrast
which nobody interested in these goods can to this, initiatives for collective exchange
be excluded from. Hence, there is a strong relations come from the employees, since it is
incentive for rational, self-interested actors to only a collective approach which can enable
take a free ride (not to contribute), with the them to improve their strategic capacities.
consequence that associational action may be The historical sequence of the formation
suboptimal in terms of effectiveness or may of trade unions and employer organizations
even fail. This line of reasoning presupposes clearly reflects this configuration of power and
that the members of the interest group share a interests. Unions were usually formed first.
basic interest in the common good, although The employers responded by embarking on
they may vary in the degree of their interest. collective action only after the unions had
This assumption does not fully match the proved their capacity to exert pressures upon
situation of employers, since their interest in them.1
associational action as such is dubious. This However, even when unions have been
follows from the structural power asymmetry formed, employers may refrain from col-
in the labor market (Offe, 1985). Their control lective action. If there is no notable union
over the means of production equips the presence in their company, employers will see
employers with a much broader range of no need to set up or join an employer asso-
options for advancing their labor market ciation. Generally, union density increases
interests compared to the options at the with firm size (Visser, 1991). As a result,
disposal of employees. This power asymmetry smaller companies are not pressurized by
explains why employers and employees union presence to join employer organi-
differ in their preference between individual zations. Large companies may also regard
and collective forms of industrial relations joining employers’ organizations as pointless
226 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

if they have sufficient resources to adopt In contrast to the US, the UK and Canada,
a systematic strategy of union avoidance. employer confederations of these countries
Alternatively, they may recognize a union participate in national tripartite boards which
for single-employer bargaining instead of deal also with labor market issues. However,
resorting to multi-employer bargaining which their policy inputs are symbolic rather than
involves employer organizations. If employer providing governance because of the volatility
organization membership is actually seen of the party system and the absence of
as a reasonable option, then the standard organized business in the collective bar-
problem of free riding in collective action gaining process. More than any other labor
becomes relevant. There is good reason relations arrangement, the existence and tasks
to believe that employers rationally follow of employer organizations are thus subject
their self-interest more consistently than any to a strategic choice, as made by their
other interest group. This is because inter- constituency.
firm competition continuously forces them to Adopting a cross nationally comparative
weigh the costs of their decisions against their perspective, the structure of this chapter is
benefits. Large companies, in particular, can as follows. It begins with an overview of the
rely on considerable in-house expertise, so activities of employer organizations and then
as to be able to carefully examine the cost– analyzes multi-employer bargaining as a key
benefit ratio of associational membership. The determinant of membership strength. The next
upshot of these considerations appears as a section turns to the structures of employer
paradox. The special dilemma of employer organizations. The chapter concludes with
organizations is that they have to organize the implications exogenous changes such as
the most powerful interest group in society. internationalization have for the future of
This power superiority diminishes the need employer organizations.
of employers to rely on associational action.
Multinational enterprises for example, have
more resources than employer organizations ACTIVITIES OF EMPLOYER
and also surpass them in terms of their
ASSOCIATIONS
territorial scope of action. This means that
employer organizations are condemned to
Interest representation
cope with a double problem of collective
action. On the one hand, the benefit of Businesses have interests not only in relation
their activities is far more uncertain than in to labor but also vis-à-vis other businesses
the case of other interest associations. On with which they have exchange relations:
the other hand, their potential membership customers and the suppliers of power, raw
is more able to pursue its rational self- materials, intermediate goods, finance and
interest, such that there is a higher risk manifold services. Any of these interests
of free riding, as compared to most other may be taken up by associations which may
interest groups. At worst, these problems advance them either directly vis-à-vis the
may be so overwhelming that employer market counterparts of their members or
organizations fail to establish themselves as indirectly vis-à-vis the state. The state is an
noticeable actors in industrial relations. Most important target of interest politics, since any
importantly, this holds true for the US and kind of markets are framed by state regulation,
Canada.2 Likewise, the role of employer such that interest groups will seek to lobby
organizations as bargainers is negligible in for regulations of benefit to them. Hence,
the UK. In the transformed economies of employer associations in the narrow sense
Central and Eastern Europe, the newly formed relate only to a certain segment of business
associations usually lack a bargaining man- interests that originates in the labor market.
date, single-employer bargaining prevails and However, this does not rule out the possibility
collective bargaining coverage is very low.3 that they also organize other interests which
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 227

will be captured here as ‘product market market interests and product market interests
interests’. We thus differentiate between three (Traxler et al., 2001; Traxler, 2004a). This
basic types of business interest associations trend gathered momentum during the 1980s,
(Schmitter and Streeck, 1981): pure employer with mergers between lower-level (sectoral)
organizations process only labor market associations and spilled over to the peak level
interests; ‘mixed’ associations combine the afterwards. Peak organizations are understood
representation of labor and product market as being not a subordinate member of
interests; and pure trade associations are another national employer organization. They
specialized in product market interests. In the were involved in mergers in the following
following, pure employer organizations and countries: Norway (in 1989), Finland, Ireland
mixed associations are subsumed under the (both in 1993), Sweden (in 2001) and Japan
category of employer organization. (in 2002) all saw amalgamations of their
In the vast majority of countries pure principal pure employer peak with trade
employer associations co-exist with mixed peak associations. The Portuguese employer
associations. From a historical perspective, confederation, CIP, extended its activities
however, employer organizations usually from labor to product market interests during
emerged as pure associations for two main the 1980s. In 1992 the principal employer
reasons. First, trade associations were set up confederation of Denmark, DA, incorporated
earlier. Second, the logic of representing prod- product market interests through the merger
uct market interests differs from that dealing of its largest association for industry with its
with labor market interests. The labor market trade association counterpart. Likewise, the
interests of business are far less divisive NZ Employers Federation (renamed Business
than its product market interests. The product New Zealand in 2001) has changed its
market interests of a certain business group profile from a pure to a mixed employer
usually need to be advanced in relation to other confederation as a result of mergers at lower
business groups, whereas the counterpart in levels and the enlargement of its confederal
matters of labor market interests is labor. activities to product market interests. As a
Therefore the conflicts of interest originating consequence of these developments at peak
in product markets are endogenous to business level, Germany and Switzerland remain the
as a class, while such conflicts ensuing only countries in Table 12.1, where the
from the labor market are exogenous to principal employer peak organization is still
business. This results in distinct requirements a pure form.
for domain demarcation. When it comes The tendency to replace pure with mixed
to representing labor market interests, it is employer organizations can be traced to
reasonable to establish rather encompassing three main factors. First, labor relations have
associations, since controlling a broader labor increasingly lost their status as a relatively iso-
market segment than one’s counterpart means lated policy area. Growing interdependence
a strategic advantage. This contrasts with the of policy fields thus more and more cross-
strategic imperatives of representing product cuts the traditional boundaries of employer
market interests which imply delimiting the organizations and trade associations. Second,
membership domain so narrow that all kinds bargaining tasks have been curtailed due to
of product market interests conflicting with bargaining decentralization. Hence, the shift
those of the association’s constituency can be of pure employer organizations to product
externalized. Comparative empirical studies market interests aims to reinforce their status
show that pure trade associations significantly as a voice of business. Third, mergers between
outnumber pure employer organizations and employer organizations and trade associations
cover far narrower domains (Traxler, 1993). are devised to economize on resources. This
Regardless of these distinct logics of associa- follows from intensified market competition
tional action, there has been a long-term trend which has induced the companies to curb
toward merging the representation of labor costs. The driving force behind mergers has
228 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 12.1 The largest employer peak organization: Basic data (1994–96)
Country Name Density∗ Bargaining role∗∗ Predominant level of Extension
collective bargaining practices∗∗∗
A WKÖ 100 3 MEB 2
AUS CAI (1994–95), ACCI 75c 3 MEB 3
B VBO/FEB 72 3 MEB 3
CDN — 0 — SEB 0
CH ZSAO, SAVa 37 2 MEB 1
D BDA 72d 1 MEB 1
DK DA 39 3–2 MEB 0
E CEOE 72 2 MEB 3
F CNPFb 74 2 MEB 3
FIN TT 44 3 MEB 3
I C 39 2 MEB 0
IRL IBEC 39 3 MEB 0
JP Nikkeiren 40g 2 SEB 0
N NHO 31 3 MEB 0
NL VNO (1994), VNO-NCW 79 2 MEB 3
NZ NZEF 90 0 SEB 0
P CIP 34 2 MEB 3
PL KPP 20–25e 0 SEB 0
S SAF 55 1 MEB 0
SI GZS 100 3 MEB 3
UK CBI 54 0 SEB 0
USA — 0 1 SEB 0
Notes:
∗ In terms of employees covered, period means or most recent data
∗∗ Recurrent involvement in wage bargaining: 0 = no substantial role; 1 = indirectly only, via member associations;

2 = co-ordination of member associations; 3 = direct involvement as a bargainer


∗∗∗ Compulsory membership included; 0 = non-existing/irrelevant; 1 = limited; 2 = pervasive

MEB = multi-employer bargaining; SEB = single-employer bargaining


a ZSAO renamed in SAV in 1996, b CNPF renamed in MEDEF in 1998,c 1997, d West Germany,
e 2002

For abbreviations, see Appendix.


Source: Traxler et al. (2001), Franz Traxler data set.

thus been the companies themselves, so as to at higher levels set the framework for the
overcome multiple membership and multiple negotiations at lower levels (Traxler et al.,
payment of dues. 2001). Hence, the tasks of the peaks have
Employer organizations differ in their invo- tended to shift from negotiation to cross-
lvement in collective bargaining. Table 12.1 sectoral co-ordination of the bargaining activ-
documents the role of the principal cross- ities of their member associations which then
sectoral national peak organizations in wage formally conclude the collective agreements.
bargaining on a regular basis. Excluding This pattern applies to the majority of the
the US and Canada from consideration, one 20 peaks listed in Table 12.1. This contrasts
finds that they are directly engaged in wage with the situation in Germany and Sweden,
bargaining in approximately one third of the where the peaks lack a direct role in wage
countries. In comparison to previous periods, bargaining and are only indirectly involved in
the peaks negotiate collective agreements less the bargaining process via collective bargain-
frequently, since bargaining has become more ing conducted by their member associations. It
decentralized since the late 1970s. In most should be noted that the bargaining role of the
countries, however, this process has assumed peaks somewhat varies with issues and over
the form of ‘organized decentralization’ in time. In Sweden, for instance, the peak still
the course of which the bargaining parties negotiates with the union confederations over
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 229

non-wage issues. The German BDA is autho- governments is absent, if wage bargaining
rized to co-ordinate its affiliates in matters of is so unco-ordinated, that none of the wage
principle so as to prevent precedents to the agreements has a noticeable impact on the
disadvantage of the employers. In countries, economy. It is worth emphasizing that this
such as Italy, Portugal and Spain, the employer correlation between co-ordination activities
confederations have occasionally negotiated and associational participation in public
central-level pacts on incomes policy. On a policy holds regardless of how effective the
regular basis, however, the main responsibil- co-ordination activities are. In the case of
ities for bargaining remain with the sectoral peak-level co-ordination, their effectiveness
associations in most of the 20 countries. is uncertain because it is impossible for the
In all cases, representing the labor market peaks to make their affiliates comply by fiat.
interests of their members vis-à-vis the state In addition to the unions and the state as
forms an essential part of the activities of the classic interlocutors of employer organi-
the peaks. In the UK and New Zealand their zations, their peaks have increasingly targeted
representational tasks have been limited to the public by means of political lobbying,
these activities, after single-employer bar- opinion formation and campaigning.4 On the
gaining supplanted multi-employer bargain- one hand, this reflects the above changes in
ing in the 1980s and early 1990s, respectively. tasks, namely the shift to mixed associations
The same profile characterizes the employer and the curtailed role in bargaining. On
organizations in the USA and Canada, where the other hand, this trend follows from the
neither cross-sectoral peaks exist nor multi- fact that organized business is the vanguard
employer bargaining figures prominently. In of what may broadly be captured as the
the case of the US, for example the sectoral neoliberal agenda: deregulation, privatization
employer organizations are involved in lob- and welfare state retrenchment. Against this
bying for labor law issues and sometimes deal background, political campaigning becomes
with law suits. Cross-national comparison a key activity. It can serve as a means of
shows that the bargaining system significantly downplaying the considerable conflicts of
determines the extent to which the state interests within more complex, mixed associ-
incorporates the peaks into public policy- ations; and it also aims to generate legitimacy
making (Traxler, 2004b). The scope of partic- needed for the far-reaching restructuring
ipation of the peaks in public policy diverges of society.
along the divide between co-ordinated and
uncoordinated wage policies. In this respect
Service activities
co-ordinated bargaining is understood in
the broad sense, insofar as cross-sectoral Aside from interest representation, the range
co-ordination may rely on peak-level bargain- of activities performed by employer organi-
ing, peak-level co-ordination or co-ordination zations also includes service activities. The
by a lower-level pattern setter under the difference between interest representation and
umbrella of the peak. services is that the former is a collective
In countries with co-ordinated wage poli- good, whereas the latter are private goods.
cies, the peaks enjoy significantly more Since private goods are excludable, they
participation rights than their counterparts can be traded. Interest associations like
in countries where wage bargaining is employer organizations use private goods
uncoordinated. This is because attempts at as selective incentives, for instance they
cross-sectoral wage co-ordination matter in trade their provision against membership, so
macro-economic terms and thus set a strong as to overcome the problem of collective
incentive for governments to seek the action. This implies that the members get
co-operation with the bargaining parties the associational services free of charge or at
also in policy areas other than incomes relatively cheap rates. Moreover, associations
policy. Conversely, such an incentive for may sell their services also to non-members on
230 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

a commercial basis. The pattern most common companies themselves vary more markedly,
to employer organizations is that they con- since the need for services clearly decreases as
centrate on providing non-payable services firm size increases. Associational services are
for members. One can, however, observe of special importance to small companies due
a growing tendency of commercialization to their limited resources. Large companies
(selling products and services on the market). can easily buy or make themselves all the
New Zealand’s employer organizations, for services offered by associations, with the
instance, have taken this route in response to exception of the protection against strikes, as
the dismantling of multi-employer bargaining provided by a dispute fund run by employer
by the 1991 labor law reform (Carrol and organizations. This means that services work
Tremewan, 1993). In the Netherlands many as a selective incentive for membership
employer organizations have set up special, primarily in the case of the smaller companies.
commercial subunits to offer services to In addition to the existence of a dispute fund,
members and also non-members. it is the opportunity to participate in the
Services are generally seen as becoming association’s decision-making process, which
more important as a way of attracting sets the strongest selective incentive for the
employers (Visser and Wilts, 2006). Services large companies to associate. This is because
may include such activities as dissemination they are more vulnerable to strike actions due
of information, advice on legal questions and to their higher levels of unionization; and
management problems, consultancy, training they have more power to exert influence on
and further training. What kind of services an their employer organization as a result of their
association provides depends mainly on its superior resources.
representational profile. Hence, the services
of pure employer organizations are geared to
industrial relations, while they address also
product market interests in the case of mixed MULTI-EMPLOYER BARGAINING
associations. Services specific to employer AND MEMBERSHIP
organizations are assistance of members
in matters of single-employer bargaining, As outlined above, there is hardly a reason
representation of members in labor court for employers to associate, as long as unions
proceedings and financial support in case do not enter the labor relations scene. There-
of a labor conflict. These three services are fore the basic incentive to form employer
borderline cases of the distinction between association is unionization on the side of
private goods and collective goods, as the labor. Unionization, however, is not a suffi-
members for which they are provided are cient precondition for gathering in employer
the direct beneficiaries; at the same time, organizations. Alternatively, employers may
however, these services contribute to process- either try to do away with union presence
ing collective employer interests. In the case in their company, if this presence is rather
of mixed associations, advice and support weak; or they may embark on single-
regarding public programmes to aid business employer bargaining, if unions are strong.
constitute a very important incentive for As an implication, the appeal of employer
membership in the European countries, since organizations directly hinges on the power
organized business generally participates in of multi-employer bargaining.5 Power means
their implementation there. two things. On the one hand, this refers
Although the relative importance devoted to positive incentives, for instance special
to representational activities and services benefits multi-employer bargaining offers in
varies with the associations, interest represen- comparison to single-employer bargaining.
tation usually prevails in that most of their On the other hand, multi-employer bargaining
resources are allocated to this type of activity. may create negative incentives which more or
In comparison to this, the priorities of the less force the employers to join.
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 231

Positive membership incentives Negative membership incentives


from multi-employer bargaining from multi-employer bargaining

In the literature one finds four main kinds Negative incentives may be set either by
of positive incentives (Clegg, 1976; Sisson, the unions or the state. Unions can exert
1987; Traxler et al., 2001). First, multi- strong pressures on employers to accept
employer bargaining reduces transactions multi-employer bargaining, if they pursue
costs of the employment relationship. In this ‘whipsawing’ tactics aimed at confronting
respect, the difference to single-employer the employers individually. A related reason
bargaining is gradual, since any kind of to associate is that employer organizations
collective agreement helps economize on can work as ‘strike insurance’, in particular
transaction costs. However, this effect is when they run a dispute fund. Membership
larger in the case of multi-employer bar- in the employer organization thus diminishes
gaining, as certain areas of employment the risk of becoming a target of strikes.
regulation can be externalized to the signatory If, nevertheless, a labor conflict occurs, the
employer organization and its union coun- companies can rely on financial support from
terpart. Second, multi-employer bargaining their employer organization. This protective
may perform a cartelizing function. Above function of multi-employer bargaining may
all, this means taking wages out of inter-firm be backed by statutory provisions, imposing
competition. This cartelizing effect becomes a peace obligation on the parties to collec-
even more powerful if the standardization tive bargaining as long as their collective
of wages helps employers reduce inter- agreement is in force.
firm competition in their product markets. This brings us to the impact of state reg-
Under these circumstances, the standard ulation on the strategic choice of employers.
rate works as a means of passing wage This choice is strongly conditioned by the way
increases on to consumers and forcing in which labor law regulates the legal effects
low-cost ‘sweat shops’ out of the market. of multi-employer agreements. In principle,
Third, multi-employer bargaining may enable a collective agreement applies only to those
employers to neutralize the workplace from companies which are members of the signa-
trade union activity. This is because multi- tory employer organization. Labor law, how-
employer agreements are forced to set out ever, may provide for an extension scheme
provisions which are applicable to any (Traxler, 1994). The first variant of such
company covered. As a consequence, these extension schemes makes a multi-employer
provisions are rather general in content and agreement generally binding within the mem-
often set merely minimum standards, thus bership domain of the signatory employer
restricting management prerogatives less than organization, thus covering also companies
single-employer settlements. Fourth, access not affiliated to the respective employer orga-
to benefits in areas other than labor relations nization. A less widespread form of extension
may be tied to membership in an employer is devised to bind employers and employees in
organization. When employer organizations certain sectoral or geographical areas outside
are mixed, businesses may join for the the domain of the multi-employer agreement,
reason of product market interests, and if these areas resemble those covered orig-
may then become roped into the organi- inally by the agreement, and if there are
zations’ representational activities in labor no parties conducting collective bargaining.
relations. Conversely, business associations The standard extension procedure is that the
may engage in multi-employer bargaining responsible authority declares a collective
even when this is not their primary concern. agreement as generally binding at the request
This is because the role of a bargainer is the of either or both of the bargaining parties.
key to participation in public policy, as noted Both extension mechanisms set a strong
above.6 incentive for employers to associate provided
232 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

there is a notable practice of application. in Austria, since labor law – with the
As regards the first mechanism, employers exception of a few explicitly listed busi-
have good reason to expect that a collective nesses – forbids single-employer bargaining
agreement will bind them even if they and authorizes only associations (employer
remain outside of the employer organization. organizations and unions at multi-employer
Hence, it is rational especially for the larger level) to conclude collective agreements.
companies to join in order to be entitled The case polar opposite to these manifold
to participate in the bargaining process, regulations conducive to employer organi-
the outcome of which may bind them in zations is represented by US and Canadian
any case (Gladstone, 1984). The smaller labor law. Its provisions rather discourage
companies (which have lesser capacities to from entering multi-employer bargaining and,
influence the bargaining process) will become concomitantly, the formation of employer
members of the employer organization, since organizations, since they focus on the single
they need its services for implementing the employer when it comes to determining the
collective agreements. Likewise, the second scope of a bargaining unit and to certifying
extension mechanism fosters the formation of a union as the unit’s bargaining agent for the
employer organizations, since employers will employees. The US National Labor Relations
prefer regulating the employment relationship Board (NLRB), for instance, defines a bar-
themselves over regulation by third parties. gaining unit as a group of employees sharing a
In some countries (Belgium, France and ‘community of interest’ that is usually seen as
the Netherlands) the unions and employer the result of performing similar types of work,
organizations use the extension mechanism and being employed by the same company.
as a vehicle for performing public func-
tions (health and safety, vocational training,
The determinants of employer
unemployment schemes) and raising financial
density
resources. In this case the agreement imposes
a levy on the employers which is designed As these statutory provisions for bargaining
to finance the public task as well as the and employer organizations markedly vary
signatory parties as such, since they keep across countries, so does the relevance of the
a certain share for their own organization. other incentives for multi-employer bargain-
Unaffiliated companies are also charged via ing outlined above. In line with this, cross-
the application of the extension provision national comparison shows a high degree of
(Traxler et al., 2001). This establishes a variation in employer density, measured as the
practice of compulsory dues payment which ratio of the number of employees working in
comes close to compulsory membership. In the member firms under the umbrella of the
Austria and Slovenia, one finds formalized largest employer peak to the total number of
compulsory membership in employer orga- employees of the firms covered by the peak’s
nizations in that all firms belonging to the domain (Table 12.1).8 This variation ranges
domain of the chambers of business are legally from zero to 100 per cent. Employer density
required to be their members. While chambers is zero in the case of the US and Canada,
based on compulsory membership act as trade as there is no country-wide cross-sectoral
associations in many European countries, the employer peak.Austria’s and Slovenia’s peaks
situation of Austria and Slovenia is special, record 100 per cent, because of compul-
since their chambers of business perform sory membership. Even though employer
the tasks of both a trade association and an organizations remain invisible in two cases,
employer organization.7 In fact, they prevail density averaged over the 20 countries where
over their voluntary counterparts and operate membership is voluntary is rather high, with
as the principal employer organizations. In an unweighted mean of 48.4 per cent. Where
addition, employer organizations and multi- does this high capacity to attract membership
employer bargaining enjoy special protection come from? As comparative quantitative
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 233

analysis shows (Traxler et al., 2001; Traxler, the cornerstone of their structures, since this
2004a), the incidence of extension practices not only defines the businesses eligible for
most strongly affects employer density and membership but also pre-determines the range
even dominates the effect of the level of of interests incorporated by the organizations.
unionization. Accordingly, union density has Branch or sectoral affiliation is most fre-
a significant impact on employer density quently used for demarcating the membership
only when there is no practice of extending domain. Other relevant criteria are firm
collective agreements. This is because the size, the production system and ownership/
enactment as well as the application of business orientation. In this respect, one finds
extension provisions is fairly independent of associations specialized in organizing small
union strength. and medium-sized firms; small-scale craft
Extension practices are pervasive in coun- production; co-operatives and not-for-profit
tries with comparatively high union density organizations. Public ownership of companies
(Belgium and Finland) and in countries with has widely lost its relevance for domain
very low unionization (France and Spain). specification in Western Europe, in the wake
Aside from this, comparative analysis also of extensive privatization and deregulation.9
suggests that the high employer density If the public-sector employees have the
in terms of employees emanates from a right of collective bargaining, the state has
generally stronger propensity of the large formed separate employer organizations in
firms to associate, as compared to their smaller countries like Sweden and Norway, whereas
counterparts (Traxler, 1995). This implies the authorities themselves negotiate in other
that extension practices provide a weaker cases. It should be noted that the employer
incentive for the small companies to join groups complementary to these characteristics
their employer organization. As comparative (large firms, privately-owned companies,
analysis shows (Traxler et al., 2007), labor profit-oriented businesses) rarely form special
regulation constitutes the divide between organizations. This is because they represent
‘large’ and ‘small’ companies by exempting the mainstream of business interests that
what is legally defined as a small firm normally dominates the politics of employer
from the purview of certain employee rights. organizations.10
Furthermore, available data on unionization In countries, where employer organizations
and collective bargaining coverage by firm have a notable role in industrial relations,
size (Visser, 1991; Traxler, 1994) indicate that a multiplicity of them exists. For instance,
large and small companies differ far more around 1000 employer organizations are
in their associability, if extension practices under the umbrella of the German BDA. This
are absent. While the large firms therefore is not outstanding, as the smaller countries
represent the membership stronghold of the of Western Europe appear to count no
employer organizations in terms of firm fewer organizations in relation to the size of
size, manufacturing in particular the metal- their labor force, as available data suggest.
working industry does so in sectoral respects According to the respective national statistical
(Traxler et al., 2007). offices the Portuguese employer organizations
totaled 436 in 1996, and there were around
100 employer organizations in Sweden in the
THE STRUCTURE OF EMPLOYER early 2000s. This multiplicity of associations
ORGANIZATIONS emanates from the specific power relationship
between employer organizations and their
member firms. Since the large companies tend
Membership domains and
to be more powerful than their associations,
hierarchical differentiation
the latter are forced to suit their domains to
The way in which employer organizations the special interests of the former. This results
demarcate their potential membership lays in rather narrow demarcations. This tendency
234 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

is especially pronounced in the case of mixed distinct parameters of domain demarcation, as


associations which have to accommodate to outlined above, one finds that the hierarchical
the high diversity of product market interests structures are more able to unify the various
across the distinct business groups. sector and branch interests than the other
The large number of organizations goes categories of interest differentiations. There
hand in hand with an elaborate hierarchical are only three countries, where the unification
differentiation that ranges from the primary of employer interests along sectoral lines
associations (which organize the businesses remains incomplete. In Australia, industry
themselves) up to the peaks. In some coun- entertains a special organization, whereas
tries like Germany this complex pyramid the service sector does so in Norway and
of associations covers no less than four Portugal. Other characteristics of domain
hierarchical levels. This pyramid is designed specialization more often feed through to
to unify powerful special interests in a step- distinctive peaks. In particular, separate
wise process, so as to equip the employer organization applies to small and medium-
organizations with strategic capacity when sized firms and craft production. The fact
it comes to interacting with the state or the that craft production correlates with small
unions at higher levels of interest aggregation. size indicates that the interest cleavages
Table 12.2 lists all national employer peaks along firm size are most difficult to recon-
of the 22 countries in Table 12.1, as far cile. Interests distinct from the predominant
as they exceed a certain threshold of cross- interests of the large companies, prompt
sectoral encompassment, covering at least two their smaller counterparts to form separate
complete one-digit ISIC sectors. Recalling the associations.

Table 12.2 The system of employer organization (1991–98)∗


Country Total number Number of peak organizations by main parameter of demarcation
General Firm size, Ownership/business Sector
(business sector) production system orientation
A 1 1 0 0 0
AUS 2–3 1 1 0 0–1
B 1 1 0 0 0
CDN 0 0 0 0 0
CH 2 1 1 0 0
D 1 1 0 0 0
DK 1 1 0 0 0
E 2 1 1 0 0
F 3 1 2 0 0
FIN 2 1 0 0 1
I 11–10 1 5 5–4 0
IRL 1 1 0 0 0
JP 1 1 0 0 0
N 2 1 0 0 1
NL 4–2 2–1 2–1 0 0
NZ [1] [1] 0 0 0
P 1–2–3 1 0–1 0 0–1
PL [3] [2] [1] 0 0
S 3 1 0 2 0
SI 4 2 2 0 0
UK [1] [1] 0 0 0
USA 0 0 0 0 0
Note:
∗ National employer peak organizations covering at least two complete one-digit ISIC sectors. Peak organizations lacking a

notable role in collective bargaining are put in parentheses.


Source: Traxler et al. (2001), Franz Traxler data set.
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 235

Most frequently, one general employer threatening to secede otherwise, enforced


organization co-exists with one or more the withdrawal of SAF from centralized
special peaks for small and medium-sized bargaining as well as internal reforms that
companies, crafts, etc. This pluralism is dismantled the bargaining capabilities of
most accentuated in Italy. However, a large SAF (Swenson and Pontusson, 2000). Such
number of countries register only one single predominance rests on marked asymmetry in
peak. It should be noted, however, that resource distribution, as anecdotal evidence
Table 12.2 somewhat downplays the degree of shows. An extreme case is Denmark where
associational fragmentation, since it records the largest affiliate, representing the industry,
only those peaks which play a notable role has accounted for around 50 per cent of the
in bargaining matters either directly (through total wage sum covered by DA (Jørgensen
bargaining themselves or co-ordination activ- and Traxler, 2007). In the early 2000s the
ities) or indirectly via extensive involvement staff of the Dutch VNO-NCW consisted of
of their affiliates in bargaining).11 In addition 160 employees (Kenis and Traxler, 2007),
to the listed associations, further cross- as compared to 225 employees of its most
sectoral national employer peaks exist in important affiliate, organizing the metal-
several countries (Austria, Ireland, Portugal, working industry (Visser and Wilts, 2006).
Denmark, Sweden and Finland) which confine
their activities to lobbying the authorities
The unit of membership and its
(Traxler et al., 2007). In all cases but
legal effects
Austria, they are specialized in organizing
crafts or small and medium-sized enterprises. Finally, the structures of the employer associ-
In Ireland and Finland, their restriction to ations are shaped by how their statutes define
lobbying is not voluntary, as their efforts the unit of membership and its legal effects.As
to join the tripartite peak-level negotiations far as the primary associations are concerned,
taking place recurrently in these countries the standard definition of the membership unit
have been vetoed by the associations of is the company, as compared to the individual
business and labor which participate in person as the owner of the respective business.
this process. If more than one peak has a At higher hierarchical levels, one can differen-
bargaining role, the general peak is always tiate between associations which have solely
the principal actor. The role of the peaks in lower-level associations as members and
the bargaining process is relatively weak, as associations which organize associations as
compared to their member associations. The well as the companies themselves. This even
peaks can build their co-ordination activities includes the peak level, although direct firm
merely upon non-binding recommendations membership is not standard at this level. Eight
and their negotiations are overshadowed by of the 20 principal confederations listed in
the formal or informal power of their affiliates Table 12.1 accept this kind of membership.12
to either veto peak-level agreements or opt In all these cases direct firm membership is
out. Analogous problems emerge when peaks designed to attract very large firms. Obtaining
are expected to formulate joint positions the privileged status of a direct affiliate to
vis-à-vis the state. In this case they often the confederation, these firms play a key role
limit themselves to taking up only those issues in associational affairs and also significantly
and interests which are not controversial contribute to the confederation’s budget
among their members. Alternatively, their (Traxler et al., 2007). The most important legal
position may echo the interests of their effect of membership relates to the bargaining
largest affiliates. Sweden provides a striking role of the employer organizations. In this
example of the predominance of one single respect, the distinction is between conforming
member over its peak. Despite resistance and non-conforming members. In contrast
from other employer groups, the powerful to non-conforming members, conforming
association of the engineering industry, by members are regularly bound by the collective
236 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

agreement concluded by their organization. In associations is covered by the collective


the vast majority of countries, membership agreements to which the association is a party.
always implies the conforming status. This In Germany even pure employer organizations
may be traced to widespread extension have adopted the principle of non-conforming
practices in most countries where multi- membership, and have usually done so against
employer bargaining prevails. Under these the warnings by their sectoral umbrella asso-
circumstances non-conforming membership ciations. This includes the largest affiliate of
does not make sense. This, however, does not BDA, Gesamtmetall, which in 2005 counted
necessarily rule out the possibility that either 2000 companies with 200,000 employees
large member companies may be entitled to obtaining non-conforming membership under
conclude their own collective agreements, as its umbrella, as compared to around 4,800
is the case of some Dutch companies (Kenis conforming members employing 1.9 million
and Traxler, 2007), or the employer organi- employees. The German development cor-
zation signs a single-employer agreement on roborates the limited control the higher-level
behalf of one of its members, if wished by associations have over their member associa-
the respective member.13 In comparison to tions. Likewise, the option of non-conforming
this, non-conforming membership is formally membership underscores the weakness of
established as a special type of membership, employer organizations in governing their
such that a company can choose to be members, unless they are backed by such
either a conforming or a non-conforming exogenous, legally-based mechanism as the
member. This duality of membership status extension provision.
was important in some sectors in the UK,
such as the chemical industry (Armstrong,
1984), as long as multi-employer bargaining CONCLUSIONS
was practiced. Since the mid-1990s, a growing
number of primary employer associations in If it is true that the raison d’etre of employer
Germany have introduced the status of a non- organizations is bargaining, then almost all
conforming member in response to the decline of the incentives for employers to join them
in membership (Grote et al., 2007). As in have markedly declined. Economic interna-
the British case, non-conforming members tionalization has eroded the cartelizing effect
have full access to the services provided by of multi-employer agreements. In Europe
the associations. It is primarily the smaller the extension of the statutory rights of the
companies which become a non-conforming employee workplace representatives which
member, while the larger companies still started with national legislation in the 1970s
prefer conforming membership that includes and continued with the Directive on the
protection against strikes. In Denmark a European Works Councils in the 1990s has
special kind of non-conforming membership undermined the possibility of using multi-
has developed as the result of some mergers employer settlements as a means of exclud-
between trade associations and employer ing the union from workplace influence,
organizations, when the formerly independent since these representatives are formally or
associations continued to exist as distinctive informally linked to the union organization
subunits with separate membership under (Traxler et al., 2001). As unionization has
the new common umbrella. In this case, strongly dwindled in most countries since
the companies which are solely members of the late 1970s, so the risks of being targeted
the trade subunit are not bound by the collec- by whipsawing have declined. The pressures
tive agreements concluded by the association which the employers have put upon the unions
(Jørgensen and Traxler, 2007). This arrange- and the employer associations to decentralize
ment, however, differs from the British and bargaining since the 1980s, so as to hand over
German pattern in that any member of the bargaining tasks to the companies themselves,
employer subgroup of the mixed Danish reflects this development. Furthermore, the
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 237

structure of the economy has changed in a The problem with these reforms is that
way detrimental to the recruitment capacities they threaten to replace old difficulties
of employer organizations. Manufacturing as with new ones. The formation of mixed
their traditional membership stronghold has associations magnifies the centrifugal forces
been shrinking, as compared to the service by incorporating divisive product market
sector. Likewise, the small companies which interests whose lines of conflict may spill
are harder to organize than larger units have over to the area of labor relations. Organized
expanded in terms of both their number and decentralization may turn into disorganization
employment. when reaching a scale that makes the parties to
Since time series data on membership multi-employer bargaining lose their control
in employer associations are sparse, it is over the process. Cuts in dues and the
difficult to assess the scale of effects these shift from free to payable services create
adverse changes in exogenous conditions new internal inequalities, since the members
have had. Available comparative studies differ in their dues burden and their demand
suggest that employer density (in terms for services.15 Commercialization is also
of employees) has remained rather stable conflict-provoking, since this means that
since the early 1980s (Traxler et al., 2001; the employer organizations compete with
Traxler, 2004a; Traxler, 2005).14 As it seems, service companies which may form part of
employer organizations have been able to their own domain or the domain of their
accommodate to the new circumstances in umbrella organization. Most of these conflicts
most countries, by undergoing functional and crystallize in the divide between large and
structural adjustments. Functionally, there has small companies. The latter are often the
been the gradual re-orientation from labor to suppliers of the former in product markets,
product market interests. In cooperation with are generally less interested in organized
their union counterpart and backed by labor decentralization, pay less dues, need more
law, the employer organizations have usually services and they may also produce some
managed to retain an organized approach of those services (consultancy) the employer
to bargaining decentralization, which enables organizations are going on to sell.
them to set a framework for bargaining within Due to the tendency of these reforms
the companies by their higher-level agree- to ever exacerbate internal cleavages, there
ments, and to retain a co-ordinating role in the is every reason to believe that employer
overall bargaining process. Furthermore, they organizations can continue to integrate their
have commercialized their services in some constituency primarily by means of state
cases. These functional adjustments fit well support. As noted above, statutory extension
into the structural changes aimed mainly at schemes are paramount. The rather high
economizing on resources. Aside from merg- stability of employer organizations thus
ers (including those between associations of ensues from the fact that they can rely
the same type) and commercialization of on pervasive extension practices in most
services, staff reductions have helped lower countries (Table 12.1). Conversely, employer
costs. In several countries, namely Austria, density strongly declined in each of the three
Denmark, Finland and Sweden, restructuring countries where extension was rescinded.
of this kind has resulted in substantial cuts In Great Britain and New Zealand this
in dues. The fact that these reforms were happened in tandem with the collapse of
enforced by the member companies indicates multi-employer bargaining. Britain’s lower-
that they resort to ‘voice’ rather than ‘exit’ level employer associations lost around half of
when they feel uncomfortable with their their density in terms of establishments over
association. This is because they have enough the 1980s (Millward et al., 1992). Density of
power to enforce real change, something the NZEF (in terms of employees) fell from
which the individual employees cannot expect 90 per cent to 67 per cent during the 1990s
to bring about in relation to their union. (Traxler, 2004a). In Germany the practice
238 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of extending multi-employer agreements has PL Poland


dwindled, in accordance with BDA efforts, S Sweden
since the early 1990s, while diversity in SI Slovenia
business interests has enormously grown as UK United Kingdom
a result of unification. This has encouraged USA United States of America
employers, especially those in East Germany,
to escape from bargaining coverage by not Associations and Parties
joining or leaving their association.According ACCI Australian Chamber of
to surveys by the Deutsche Institut für Commerce and Industry
Wirtschaftsforschung density of firms in the BDA Bundesvereinigung der
East German manufacturing sector dropped Deutschen
from 36 per cent in 1993–4 to 10 per cent in Arbeitgeberverbände
2005, and density in terms of employees did C Confindustria
so from 74 per cent to 30 per cent over the CAI Confederation of Australian
same period. Lack of extension practices has Industry
not caused a decline of employer organization CBI Confederation of British
only in the case of the Scandinavian countries, Industry
where unionization levels are very high. CEOE Confederación Española de
As noted above, employer associations are Organizaciones
reactive undertakings insofar as they were Empresariales
set up in response to the rise of the union CNPF Conseil National du Patronat
movement. Hence, the continued decline of Français
the unions tends to qualify the interest of DA Dansk Arbejdsgiverforening
business in employer associations. This means GZS Gospodarska zbornica
that they have become increasingly reactive to Slovenije
the state, as their viability ever more depends IBEC Irish Business and
on supportive national regulations. Employers’ Confederation
KPP Konfederacja Pracodawcow
Polskich
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS NHO Næringslivets
Hovedorganisasjon
Nikkeiren Japan Federation of
Country Codes
Employers’ Associations
A Austria NZEF New Zealand Employers’
AUS Australia Federation
B Belgium SAF Svenska
CDN Canada Arbetsgivareföreningen
CH Switzerland SAV Schweizerischer
D Germany Arbeitgeberverband
DK Denmark TT Teollisuus ja Työnantajat
E Spain VBO/FEB Verband van Belgische
FIN Finland Ondernemingen –
F France Fédération des Entreprises
I Italy Belgique
IRL Ireland VNO Verbond van Nederlandse
JP Japan Ondernemingen
NL Netherlands VNO-NCW Vereniging van Nederlandse
N Norway Ondernemers – Nederlands
NZ New Zealand Christelijke
P Portugal Werksgeversverbond
EMPLOYER ORGANIZATIONS 239

WKÖ Wirtschaftskammer 9 In Italy, the employer organizations of the very


Österreich large nationalised industry sector played a pioneering
role in industrial relations, until they were dissolved as
ZSAO Zentralverband
independent associations in the 1990s (Regalia and
Schweizerischer Regini, 1998).
Arbeitgeber- 10 A notable exception to this rule is the Business
Organisationen Council of Australia which was set up in 1983 by a
group of larger employers because of their perception
that CAI gave undue emphasis to their interests
(Lansbury and Wailes, 2004). There are also special
NOTES organizations for private companies in Eastern Europe
against the background of a historically strong state-
1 This sequence applies only to labor relations. The owned sector.
rise of trade associations designed to process business 11 This does not hold true for the peaks in the UK,
interests other than labor market interests (see below) Poland and New Zealand. While put in parentheses for
preceded the unions. this reason, they are nevertheless listed, because they
2 In Canada multi-employer bargaining by are the only cross-sectoral peaks of their countries.
employer associations generally prevails only in two 12 KPP and the successor of Nikkeiren introduced
provinces (Quebec and British Columbia) and a few direct firm membership in 2002.
sectors (trucking and construction) (Thompson and 13 For example, this is exceptional practice in
Taras, 2004). Austria.
3 It is only Slovenia and Slovakia which deviate from 14 For instance, the expansion of the service sector
this pattern, with multi-employer agreements as the does not negatively affect employer density, in stark
prevalent mode of bargaining (Marginson and Traxler, contrast to union density.
2005). 15 Generally, the imperative to cut costs and
4 For an instructive case study of Sweden, see dues restrains the possibility of the associations to
Pestoff (1995). substitute their declining role in bargaining for such
5 When multi-employer bargaining attracts services as the provision of specialist expertise, unless
employers, their cooperation may be limited to these services are made payable.
joint negotiations instead of setting up a formal
organization. This informality is rather unusual. In
Hungary, however, this practice has spread among
the larger companies (Marginson and Traxler, 2005).
6 For instance, in Spain only employer associations
REFERENCES
meeting the criterion of representativeness are vested
with rights of consultation, in contrast to pure trade Armstrong, E.G.A. (1984) ‘Employers Associations in
associations. The Portuguese employer organizations Great Britain’, in J.P. Windmuller and A. Glad-
also enjoy legally-based preferential treatment. stone (eds), Employers Associations and Industrial
7 In Slovenia voluntary associations may take over Relations. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
the bargaining tasks in the foreseeable future. Carrol, P. and Tremewan, P. (1993) ‘Organizing
8 In principle, employer density can be measured Employers: The Effect of the Act on Employers and the
in two ways, referring to either the firms themselves Auckland Employer Association’, in R. Harbridge (ed.),
or the firms’ employees. Measuring density of firms
Employment Contracts: New Zealand Experiences.
is difficult as we lack comparable statistics on the
number of firms and their breakdown by the number
Wellington: Victory University Press.
of employees for many countries. Such statistics, Clegg, H. A. (1976) Trade Unionism under Collective
however, are needed to disentangle employers Bargaining. Oxford: Blackwell.
from companies without employees. At any rate, Gladstone, A. (1984) ‘Employers Associations in
density in terms of employees covered is the more Comparative Perspective: Functions and Activities’,
appropriate indicator, when it comes to measuring in J. P. Windmuller and A. Gladstone (eds),
associational power in the labor market. The figures Employers Associations and Industrial Relations.
presented in Table 12.1 are limited to density of Oxford: Clarendon Press.
a country’s principal employer peak in terms of Grote, J., Lang, A. and Traxler, F. (2007) ‘Germany’, in
employees covered, because many narrower employer
F. Traxler and G. Huemer, (eds), Handbook of Business
organizations usually exist outside the umbrella of the
principal peak. It is hard to collect reliable data on the
Interest Associations, Firm Size and Governance: A
actual and/or potential membership of these narrower Comparative Analytical Approach. London and New
associations, because their domains rarely coincide York: Routledge.
with conventional statistical classifications of business Jørgensen, C. and Traxler, F. (2007) ‘Denmark’, in
activities. F. Traxler and G. Huemer, (eds), Handbook of Business
240 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Interest Associations, Firm Size and Governance: Thompson, M. and Taras, D.G. (2004) ‘Employment
A Comparative Analytical Approach. London and New Relations in Canada’, in G.J., Bamber, R. D, Lansbury
York: Routledge. and N. Wailes, (eds), International and Comparative
Kenis, P. and Traxler, F. (2007) ‘The Netherlands’, in Employment Relations. London: Sage.
F. Traxler and G. Huemer, (eds), Handbook of Business Traxler, F. (1993) ‘Business Associations and Labor
Interest Associations, Firm Size and Governance: Unions in Comparison: Theoretical Perspectives and
A Comparative Analytical Approach. London and Empirical Findings on Social Class, Collective Action
New York: Routledge. and Associational Organizability’, British Journal of
Lansbury, R.D. and Wailes, N. (2004) ‘Employ- Sociology, 44 (4): 673–91.
ment Relations in Australia’, in G.J., Bamber, R. Traxler, F. (1994) ‘Collective Bargaining: Levels and
D, Lansbury and N. Wailes, (eds) International Coverage’, in OECD Employment Outlook. Paris:
and Comparative Employment Relations. London: OECD.
Sage. Traxler, F. (1995) ‘Two Logics of Collective Action in
Marginson, P. and Traxler, F. (2005) ‘After Enlarge- Industrial Relations?’, in C. Crouch and F. Traxler
ment: Preconditions and Prospects for Bargaining (eds), Organized Industrial Relations in Europe: What
Coordination’, Transfer, 3 (3): 423–38. Future? Aldershot: Avebury.
Millward, N., Stevens, M., Smart, D. and Hawes, W. R. Traxler, F. (2004a) ‘Employer Associations, Institutions
(1992) Workplace Industrial Relations in Transition. and Economic Change: A Crossnational Comparison’,
Aldershot: Dartmouth. Industrielle Beziehungen, 11 (1–2): 42–60.
Offe, C. (1985) Disorganized Capitalism: Contemporary Traxler, F. (2004b) ‘The Metamorphoses of Corpo-
Transformations of Work and Politics. Oxford: ratism’, European Journal of Political Research,
Polity. 43 (4): 571–98.
Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Traxler F., Blaschke S. and Kittel B. (2001) National
Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, London: Labor Relations in Internationalized Markets. Oxford:
Harvard University Press. Oxford University Press.
Pestoff, V. A. (1995) ‘Towards a New Swedish Model Traxler, F., Brandl, B. and Pernicka, S. (2007)
of Collective Bargaining and Politics’, in C. Crouch ‘Business Associability, Activities and Governance:
and F. Traxler (eds), Organized Industrial Relations in Crossnational Findings’, in F. Traxler, and G. Huemer,
Europe: What Future? Aldershot: Avebury. (eds), Handbook of Business Associations, Firm
Regalia, I. and Regini, M. (1998) ’Italy: The Dual Size and Governance: A Comparative Analytical
Character of Industrial Relations’, in A. Ferner and Approach. London and New York: Routledge.
R. Hyman (eds), Changing Industrial Relations in Traxler, F. and Huemer, G. (eds) (2007) The Handbook
Europe. Oxford: Blackwell. of Business Associations, Firm Size and Governance:
Schmitter, P.C. and Streeck, W. (1981) ‘The Organization A Comparative Analytical Approach. London and
of Business Interests’, Discussion Paper IIM/LPM New York: Routledge.
81–13. Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin. Visser, J. (1991) ‘Trends in Trade Union Membership’, in
Sisson, K. (1987) The Management of Collective OECD Employment Outlook 1991. Paris: OECD.
Bargaining. Oxford: Blackwell. Visser, J. and Wilts, A. (2006) ‘Reaching Out and
Swenson, P. and Pontusson, J. (2000) ‘The Swedish Fitting in: Dutch Business Associations at Home (and)
Employer Offensive against Centralized Bargaining’, in Europe’, in W. Streeck, J. Grote, V. Schneider
in T. Iversen, J. Pontusson and D. Soskice (eds), and J. Visser (eds), Governing Interests: Business
Unions, Employers and Central Banks. Cambridge: Associations Facing Internationalization. London and
Cambridge University Press. New York: Routledge.
13
Management Strategy and
Industrial Relations
Nicolas Bacon

INTRODUCTION broadening the range of HRM practices now


studied.
Since the 1980s managers rather than trade
unions or the state have been responsible for
the most important developments in industrial MANAGEMENT INDUSTRIAL
relations (IR). Industrial relations in many RELATIONS STRATEGIES
firms and countries have changed significantly
as a result, as managers have become more The term ‘strategy’ is frequently used in an
reluctant to recognize, consult or negotiate ‘illusive and imprecise’ manner when applied
with trade unions, and have made the to IR (Hyman, 1987: 27). Lewin (1987: 8)
contentious claim to be adopting a strategic similarly observed that IR researchers often
approach to human resource management fail to ‘offer a consistent, clear or distinctive
(HRM). Research on management strategy in definition of strategy’ and as a result ‘strategy
industrial relations duly increased in order to as applied to industrial relations is consis-
track and understand the implications of these tent with virtually any management action’
potentially important changes. Important (Lewin, 1987: 36). A careful definition is
questions included the extent to which man- therefore required before we can begin to
agers were behaving strategically, the nature assess whether and when managers have a
of the new strategies adopted and the reasons strategic approach toward industrial relations.
for changes in management approach? This According to Thurley and Wood (1983:
chapter reviews the literature that emerged 198) ‘Industrial relations strategies refer
on management strategies within and beyond to long-term policies which are developed
industrial relations to understand these critical by the management of an organization in
issues. The insights generated from this order to preserve or change the procedures,
research have gradually transformed the study practices or results of industrial relations
of IR, according managers a central role and activities over time’.1 Reflecting subsequent
242 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

research conducted since the early 1980s, little more than opportunistic responses to
this chapter defines management industrial economic and political liberalization (Legge,
relations strategies as requiring formal plans 1995; see also Purcell, 2001).
that integrate employment practices; contain Emphasizing formal plans and consistent
an underlying set of management values; practices in labor management strategies also
involve significant managerial choice; inte- implies that managers should make long-
grate activities at different organizational term plans. Gospel (1992: 10–11 and 181)
levels; support the firm’s operations; deliver usefully distinguishes between intended and
effective outcomes and endure over the long- enacted strategies, rejecting the suggestion
term. 2 As this exacting list of requirements that most British employers had long-term
implies, it is necessary to consider the separate and coherent strategies, but detecting a
elements of strategy in detail to illustrate why ‘clear pattern of behavior over time’. As
labor management strategies have proved so this implies, it may be difficult to assess
elusive. whether managers have a long-term plan
First, it is reasonable to assume that because management intentions may not be
industrial relations strategy requires a formal immediately obvious.
management plan.At the outset, it is important Further, not all observers agree that limited
to note that many firms simply do not have consistency between employment practices
a formal plan of any kind. The British and a reliance on short-term adjustments indi-
Workplace Employment Relations Survey, cate a lack of strategy. According to Edwards
for example, asks managers whether their (1995: 14) ‘strategy is not a neat package
workplace is ‘covered by a formal strategic producing clear outcomes but necessarily
plan which sets out objectives and how they contains several competing elements and has
will be achieved’, followed by show cards to be constantly reinterpreted as new results
prompting them to indicate whether the plan emerge and as the world changes’. Similarly,
includes any of seven issues (taking in three Streeck (1987: 285) argues that strategy does
employment components) (Kersley et al., not imply a ‘common and clear sighted
2006: 62). In 2004, 30 per cent of British vision’, and matching IR to business needs
workplaces did not have a strategic plan and requires experimentation. However, firms
a further 10 per cent had a plan with no experimenting with apparently inconsistent
employment components (ibid.: 62). practices, that reflect immediate circum-
In addition to a formal plan, industrial rela- stances, are involved in a process of searching
tions strategy also implies that employment for a strategy that they may or may not find,
practices are part of a consistent management rather than necessarily engaging in strategy-
approach. However, it is evident that man- formulation.
agers rarely maintain consistent practices over Strategy also appears to require an under-
time. At least in the short term, employment lying set of management values guiding con-
practices often seem ad hoc and opportunistic sistent choices over employment practices.
reactions to market changes (Sisson, 1994). Employment practices without these values
For example, in the late 1980s managers in place are unlikely to result in consistent
introduced flexible staffing and changed the choices and a meaningful strategy. However,
nature of contracts in response to labor it is doubtful whether such underlying values
market opportunities rather than developing exist and management values that support
far-sighted strategies or staffing plans (Hunter high commitment management practices may
et al., 1993). Since the 1980s, firms often claim be especially rare. For example, Kochan
to have attached greater importance to labor and Dyer (1993) argue that managers did
management and to have adopted a strategic not make a strategic commitment to high
human resource management approach. This commitment management practices in the late
claim appears to lack real substance not 1980s because they did not value investing
least because new initiatives are frequently in employees. In the second section of
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 243

this chapter I will consider management often difficult to achieve because it involves
style and values as potential explanations managers from the corporate board down
of differences in employment practices to the shop-floor, and it also involves a
between firms and changes in approach over range of managerial functions from industrial
time. relations to finance and operations managers
Labor management strategies also require (Hyman, 1987). Corporate structure and
significant scope for management choice. corporate strategies therefore affect integra-
The strategic choice theory of IR developed tion between industrial relations strategies
in the 1980s recognized managers as the decided at different organizational levels.
critical actors initiating major workplace Section four considers the effects of corporate
changes and exercising strategic choices in structure and corporate-level decisions on
deciding on their approach (Kochan et al., industrial relations as reasons why firms
1986). In contrast to these claims however, do not adopt a strategic approach to labor
many managers appear to lack the necessary problems (Marginson et al., 1988; Purcell,
freedom to make significant choices – in 1993). The fifth section further considers the
most circumstances employment practices links between labor management and business
are determined by markets that limit man- strategy.
agement options. The term ‘strategy’ has An alternative approach is to deduce a
little substantive purchase if employment strategic approach post hoc if managers adopt
practices are severely restricted by labor and best practices. Adopting high commitment
product markets. According to Thompson management practices to take full advantage
(2003) for example, shareholder pressure and of employee effort and commitment (see the
global product markets increasingly restrict chapters by Delaney, Frost and Procter in
the options available to managers and prevent this volume(Chapters 33, 22 and 8 respec-
the provision of job security and high wages. tively)) may require strategic action and a
This is an important point because managers paradigm shift in managers’approach. Section
themselves often claim they have little choice six explores whether the adoption of high
and competitive global markets force them commitment management practices indicates
to relocate overseas or reduce terms and a strategic approach to industrial relations. As
conditions of employment (Lewin, 1987: 36; we shall see, relatively few firms adopt these
see also Brown, Chapter 6 in this volume). The best practices.
degree of management choice is unfortunately The chapter will therefore discuss indus-
difficult to establish not least because the trial relations strategies from these different
choice of research method may influence standpoints – as reflecting an underlying
the findings. Industrial or firm context often management style, the exercise of managerial
explain employment practices in surveys choice, shaped by corporate structure and
where it is possible to control these effects strategy, linking employment practices to
(Marginson, 1998). In contrast, case studies business strategy, and implementing high
suitable for tracking decision-making often commitment management practices. Each
attribute too much choice and intention to research stream contributes important insights
managers rather than explaining employment to understanding labor management strategy
practices by market pressures (Morris and and, in addition to evaluating this work the
Wood, 1991; Muller-Jentsch, 2004). The third chapter includes constructive ways forward
section of the chapter looks at the extent to develop future research. The conclusion
to which managers deciding on employment reflects on models and strategy types devel-
practices have a degree of freedom to exercise oped and tested in the research literature,
strategic choice. the applicability of the strategy concept to
Labor strategies also require integration the analysis of industrial relations and the
between management plans and activities at degree to which strategies are empirically
different organizational levels. Integration is verifiable.
244 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

MANAGEMENT STYLE AND discrete bundles of employment practices,


TYPOLOGIES however, limited the usefulness of Fox’s
initial typologies (Edwards, 1995: 602).
A common approach to understanding labor Clegg (1979: 163) identified three main
management strategy is to describe it as problems with the simple unitarism-pluralism
a broad management style. Management contrast: these frames of reference do not
style is ‘the existence of a distinctive set distinguish between firms with significant
of guiding principles, written or otherwise, numbers of employees if most recognize
which set parameters to and signposts for trade unions;3 neither type exists ‘in pure
management action in the way employees form’; and on different issues managers shift
are treated and particular events handled’ between frames of reference. Fox (1974)
(Purcell, 1987: 79). A management style may also developed six typologies of labor man-
guide industrial relations strategy, providing agement styles (traditional, classical conflict,
an ‘underlying rationale’ for discretionary continuous challenge, sophisticated modern,
managerial choices in employment policies standard modern and sophisticated paternal-
(Purcell, 1987: 533; see also Kochan and ism), subsequently refined and reclassified
Dyer, 1993: 573). Table 13.1 outlines alter- into five types of management style as
native typologies of different management listed in Table 3.1 (Purcell and Sisson,
styles developed to help distinguish between 1983). Typologies of labor management
industrial relations in different firms. style are valuable for classifying a firm’s
Fox (1966) who distinguished between general approach. The ensuing failure to
unitary (anti-union) and pluralist (accepting find distinct approaches or styles in prac-
unions) management frames of reference tice, however, suggested that rather than
underlying general approaches to industrial adopting strategic approaches to industrial
relations (outlined in detail in Chapter 5 relations, managers were mainly pragmatic
in this volume) made the first significant and opportunistic (Deaton, 1985; Sisson and
contribution. The assumption that firms adopt Sullivan, 1987: 429). After all, a consistent

Table 13.1 Management style industrial relations typologies


Authors Areas covered Key dimensions Ideal Types
Fox (1966, 1974) Trade unions and industrial Unitarism 6 (traditional, classical
relations (anti-union)/pluralism conflict, continuous
(accepts unions) challenge, sophisticated
modern, standard
modern, sophisticated
paternalism)
Purcell and Sisson (1983) Trade unions and industrial Unitarism/pluralism 5 (traditional, sophisticated
relations paternalists,
constitutionalists,
consulters, standard
modern)
Purcell (1987) Purcell and Industrial relations and Individualism (labour control, 7 (traditional, paternalists,
Ahlstrand (1994) human resource paternalism or employee sophisticated human
management development)/collectivism relations, bargained
(unitary, adversarial or constitutional,
cooperative relationship sophisticated
with employee consultative, modern
representatives) paternalist, co-option)
Storey and Bacon (1993) Industrial relations (4 Individualism/collectivism 8 according to the mixture
aspects), work (defined differently across each employment
organization (3 aspects) according to each area
and human resource employment area)
management (3 aspects)
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 245

management style is unlikely to exist if the extent to which the firm invests in
we cannot identify distinctive approaches. and develops employees (p. 536) usefully
Recognition that management style is rather relabeled by others as ‘investment orientation’
more fluid than initially suggested – changing (Marchington and Parker, 1990) and ‘human
in response to economic and political devel- resource management priority’ (Guest, 2001).
opments – subsequently led to further work Whether managers recognize employee rights
on management style to produce alternative to have a say in decision-making was labeled
models. collectivism (Purcell, 1987: 538) indicating
It is helpful at this point to depart ‘management attitudes and behaviour toward
from a description of types in order to trade unions in the workplace’ (Marching-
explain the early 1980s context, where UK ton and Parker, 1990) and later ‘industrial
and North American managers reassessed relations priority’ (Guest, 2001). These two
industrial relations strategies and in many dimensions capture the varied ways in which
cases withdrew support for trade unions and firms combine approaches to industrial rela-
collective bargaining in response to product tions and human resource management as part
market competition. New management style of an overall management style. Storey and
models developed to describe changes in Bacon (1993) further classified management
approaches and models expanded to account style as approaches emphasizing individu-
for greater interest in human resource manage- alism or collectivism across three areas of
ment practices (Purcell and Ahlstrand, 1994). industrial relations, work organization and
Influenced by non-union human relations human resources (see also Gospel, 1992).
firms, Japanese management practices and This framework covers a broad range of
work redesign experiments in unionized firms, issues and captures multifaceted recipes of
managers not only sought to delimit union employment practices. However, including
influence but to engage individual employees a complex range of employment practices
in continuous performance improvements produces many different combinations of
through a broader array of human resource practices that we cannot easily reduce to a
management practices. Walton (1985) con- small and parsimonious number of indicative
trasted the ‘control’ approach of Taylorist job management styles. As Table 13.1 indicates,
design with the ‘commitment’ approach to over time the number of ideal types identified
labor management in quality of work life and has steadily increased.
employee involvement experiments in the US The enduring presence of simple typologies
during the 1970s. The labor process debate indicates management styles – unitarism
from the mid-1970s also studied management and pluralism, direct control and relative
styles and strategies. In rejecting Braverman’s autonomy, control and commitment, individu-
(1974) argument that managers adopted alism and collectivism – remain useful refer-
a uniform Taylorist scientific management ence points to describe different approaches
strategy, Friedman (1977) identified two to labor management. All such typologies
broad labor management approaches – direct inevitably simplify a complex reality: they
control (Taylorism) and encouraging respon- collapse a range of approaches into a limited
sible autonomy via employee involvement in number of types; firms appear to use tech-
the work process. Labor management style niques associated with both typologies; and
models gradually incorporated these insights the typologies imply a coherent managerial
from parallel fields. attachment to one approach rather than a
Returning to a description of types of series of ad hoc practices. Nevertheless,
management style reflecting these changes, the job of analysts is to simplify and this
Purcell (1987) identified a more subtle strand of theory is a commendable attempt
range of management styles measured on to do this. Edwards (1995: 14) appropriately
the two dimensions of individualism and regards typologies ‘as elements which can be
collectivism. Individualism was defined as combined in various ways’, for example, with
246 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

one employment practice developing control medium-sized enterprises are two areas where
and reducing costs, and another maximizing more work is still required. Management
commitment and potential (see Marchington style models have already developed to some
and Harrison, 1991). Finding one practice extent to allow for different approaches
used to exercise control and another to in non-union firms. Models have moved
develop commitment clearly does not prevent beyond Fox’s (1974: 287) classic account that
classifying an overall management style managers with a unitarist ideology enforce
(Edwards, 1995: 603). management prerogative by ‘coercive power’
Assessing practices across the three areas and demand ‘unquestioning obedience’ from
of industrial relations, work organization and employees. Managerial attitudes toward trade
human resource management practice is a unions are insufficient for studying non-union
useful way forward (Gospel, 1992; Storey companies because strategies to remain non-
and Bacon, 1993) because managers often union also involve different human resource
seek to reduce costs in one area but invest management approaches from site to site
in another. Broadly speaking, managers make (Roy, 1980). Purcell and Ahlstrand (1994)
basic industrial relations choices between identified three non-union management styles
unitarism restricting employee voice, or or typologies on the basis of ‘individualism’
pluralism encouraging employee input into or use of human resource practices: ‘sophis-
decision-making (often but not necessarily ticated human relations’ companies invest
through trade unions). Work organization in employees; managers in the ‘paternalist’
choices require the selection of practices firm care for employee welfare in return
to concentrate on mainly the direct control for loyalty; and in the ‘traditional’ approach
of employees conducting specified tasks managers minimize labor costs (see also
or responsible autonomy encouraging a Dundon and Rollinson, 2004). This clarifies
broader task contribution. The approach to human resource approaches in non-union
human resources/personnel practices empha- firms but assumes a standard approach to the
sizes either minimum cost or high investment issue of employee representation. However,
(Table 13.2). This set of employment relations non-union employee representation takes a
choices thus combines some of the parsimony variety of forms (Gollan, 2006; Taras and
of earlier models with the necessary breadth Kaufman, 2006) and future work may usefully
to capture some of the complexity of con- combine these forms with approaches to
temporary labor management. The intention human resource management to develop
is not to suggest labor management strategies typologies of non-union firms.
must involve practices emphasizing only Management style in employment rela-
individualism or collectivism across each of tions usually describes larger firms, but
the three policy areas, it allows for different appears especially useful to categorize small
recipes in reality. and medium-sized firms (SMEs) and more
The models discussed so far provide a work should be encouraged in this area.
framework to classify all firms. An alternative Labor management strategy is difficult to
is to concentrate on a more sophisticated describe and classify in SMEs as few have
understanding of approaches in specific types formalized employment practices. In such
of firms. Non-union firms and small and firms, management style is a very useful

Table 13.2 Employment relations choices


Management Approach
Individualism Collectivism
Policy Areas Industrial Relations Unitarist Pluralist
Work Organization Direct Control Responsible Autonomy
Human Resources/ Personnel Minimum Cost High Investment
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 247

concept because we can trace a direct link hole’ (no unions and no sophisticated HRM
from management attitudes to management practices). Cross-national studies of specific
behaviors and employee experiences. It has industries also generate management style
therefore proved particularly insightful to typologies such as low wage, HRM, Japanese-
identify such styles as ‘fraternalism’ in orientated and joint-participatory approaches
SMEs to manage highly skilled workers with (Katz and Darbishire, 2000). This remains
significant levels of discretion and trust in a useful and parsimonious way of imposing
the labor process. Among firms where we order on complex changes.
would expect to find fraternalism, Baron To develop the concept of management
and Hannan (2002) found a wider range of style, more work is required to establish the
labor management styles in small knowl- links between managerial values and specific
edge intensive firms and explained this by employment practices. It would be helpful
the entrepreneurs’ organizational blueprints to develop reliable measurement instruments
including ‘the premises that guided their in order to do this. In one of the few
thinking about how to organize employment attempts to do this so far, Osterman (1994:
relations and manage personnel’ (p. 10). 179) assessed managerial values with a
Organizational blueprints are very similar to single survey question – ‘In general, what is
the concept of management style. In contrast, your establishment’s philosophy about how
many SMEs adopt a ‘sweating’ strategy to appropriate it is to help increase the well-being
manage unskilled employees (Goss, 1991). of employees with respect to their personal
Rainnie (1989) argues that large dominant or family situations’. He found managerial
firms force many small supplier firms to values measured in this way correlated with
adopt a ‘sweating’ strategy of authoritarian flexible work practices. The same variable
management, tight supervision and low wage relabeled ‘humanistic values’ was associ-
levels. Management style in family-owned ated with more establishment-level training
and run SMEs appears to be different (Osterman, 1995). Other research provides
again with ‘negotiated paternalism’ used and less support for the management style con-
informal family loyalties generating a sense of cept. Godard (1997: 212) measured manage-
mutual obligation (Ram and Holliday, 1993). rial ideology by three questions addressing
Studies of SMEs are an important area for ‘values and beliefs about unions, employee
future research and returns attention to the involvement programs, and the participatory
importance of the enterprise founder’s role rights of workers in general’. Although
in establishing labor management style (see managerial ideology thus measured correlated
Purcell and Sisson, 1983). with employment practices, other context
An alternative to developing increasingly variables (for example, firm size, technology
sophisticated and differentiated types of man- and market conditions) were more important.
agement style is to use typologies as devices to Reliable survey questions to capture a general
identify the main trends and impose a frame- labor management style connected to specific
work on complex changes in management employment practices are yet to be developed.
practices. For example, McKersie (1987) An alternative approach worth developing
identified three main strategies adopted by in parallel in the future is to link managerial
US managers in the 1980s – the traditional attitudes on individual issues to specific
or New Deal system of collective bargain- practices. The association between attitudes
ing, the non-union system and transitional and practices is likely to be stronger if
industrial relations (McKersie, 1987). In the the attitude measured relates directly to
UK, Guest (2001: 97) identified four broad specific employment practices.4 For example,
patterns: traditional pluralism (similar to the managers’ attitudes toward work-life balance
New Deal system); individualism (non-union issues correlate with providing family-
sophisticated HRM employers); partnership friendly practices (Kersley et al., 2006:
with unions; and the ‘bleak house’ or ‘black 272; Woodland et al., 2003) and managers’
248 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

attitudes toward unions are strongly related establishing managers, rather than unions,
to workplace-level union density (Kersley as the central industrial relations actor in
et al., 2006: 114). Guest and Peccei (2001) the US (Strauss, 1984). Strategic choice
reported a link between partnership princi- theory makes several important assumptions.
ples and practices in UK companies with First, managers ‘have discretion over their
co-operative management-union relations, decisions; that is, where environmental con-
measuring 15 items on a five point scale of straints do not severely curtail the parties’
whether and how strongly the organization ‘is choice of alternatives’ (Kochan et al., 1984:
believed to support or oppose each principle’ 21). From the mid-1980s, the theory claims
(p. 218). Bacon and Blyton (2000) show managers exercised an increasing degree of
that different management rationales correlate strategic choice in redesigning employment
with quite different types of team working and practices. As Kaufman (2003: 199) notes,
that these types of teams produced contrasting in essence “‘strategy” implies choice over
outcomes for firms and employees. alternative people management approaches’,
One way forward may be to identify and strategic choice theory requires a (high)
the required managerial attitudes and values degree of managerial autonomy. Second, the
for a range of different employment issues theory assumes managers make important
and then explore the relationship between and significant decisions affecting the rela-
these attitudes to build a more effective tionship between employers and employees,
measure of management style. It is of rather than routine decisions. Third, industrial
course possible that management values on relations decisions link across different levels
specific issues are unrelated and an underlying from strategic business policy, to the collec-
managerial ideology does not exist. If it tive bargaining and workplace levels of the
does exist then developing tools to assess firm. Section four will discuss the linking of
these values could have several important industrial relations decisions across different
practical implications. For example, it may organizational levels.
help firms select managers based on their Managers have undoubtedly reshaped
orientation to labor management to support employment relations over the past 25 years
the effective implementation of practices. but it is less clear that this is the result
In addition, such tools could track the of greater strategic choice. Managers have
development of management values over time limited latitude for strategic choice if eco-
during a transition period when seeking to nomic conditions structurally determine many
change employment practices. industrial relations decisions (Hyman, 1987).
Management style helps to conceptualize Lewin (1987: 8) for example argued that
approaches to employment relations and increased market competition in the 1980s
highlights the importance of values and reduced rather than increasing the scope
attitudes that explain managerial behavior as for choice in labor management. Market
a sustained stream of relatively consistent competition may explain many develop-
decisions. The assumption that pressures from ments including changes to working practices
shareholders or from the firm’s external envi- (Osterman, 1994, 2000), greater managerial
ronment do not easily deflect the underlying control on the shop-floor (Edwards and
managerial philosophy will be questioned Scullion, 1982) and wage restraint (Brown et
toward the end of the next section. al., 2003). Even arguments in much of the
Total Quality Management/High Performance
Work Practice literature that customers have
MANAGERIAL STRATEGIC CHOICE become more demanding with the emergence
of niche markets may offer managers little
Management values are also an important fea- choice but to introduce flexible, high-quality
ture of the strategic choice theory of industrial work systems to meet changing customer
relations. This theory marked a paradigm shift requirements. Managerial choices may thus
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 249

merely involve passive adaptation to short- workers of management choices made since
term market pressures or long-term funda- the 1980s. The theory, for example, allows for
mental transitions in capitalism (Piore and a low cost or an investment approach to labor
Sabel, 1984; Thompson, 2003). management and does not clarify the factors
Although important, this argument has shaping various choices and identifying the
two problems. First, it leaves no room for most likely outcomes.
managerial discretion in deciding between Hyman (1987: 30) reinserts the politics
alternative employment practices to meet into strategic choice in offering an alternative
strategic aims. For example, should managers Marxist explanation whereby strategic choice
reduce labor costs by increasing work pace or exists because the contradictions inherent
reorganizing working methods? Second, it is in managing labor in capitalism make all
not clear that market pressures have brought employment practices ‘different routes to
about an overall reduction in strategic labor partial failure’. Managers devise strategies
management choice. The effects of market and select appropriate courses of action, but
pressures on strategic choice are complex. the underlying requirement to both control
Cost pressures do force managers to act to employee behavior and develop their commit-
reduce labor costs although as stated such ment creates a tension and class-based conflict
pressures do not direct managers in exactly that managers cannot resolve. Managers use
how to act. At the same time cost pressures diverse and varied practices for tactical
also increase management choice by reducing reasons to manage this tension and bundles
the abilities of employees to resist changes to of employment practices as a result rarely
working practices, protect jobs and negotiate conform to management style typologies
pay increases (Osterman, 2000). (ibid.: 49). This is a useful insight but the term
If we take into account factors other than ‘partial failure’ is unhelpful. Acknowledging
the product market, it is even less clear that that managers are often unsuccessful at
the degree of managerial strategic choice managing potential conflict and securing high
has declined. Labor market deregulation levels of employee commitment does not
has offered managers greater labor flexi- necessarily imply managers always fail in
bility including relocation, subcontracting, this endeavor. It is important to identify the
outsourcing and off-shoring work. We should reasons why labor management choices are
not dismiss strategic choice simply because more or less successful. Both Hyman and
one factor may be forcing managers to Edwards tend to stress the unmanageability
make certain decisions. Rather than market of capitalist firms when in many cases these
liberalization restricting strategic options in firms seem to be very effective at surviving
labor management over the past 25 years, and generating streams of profit.
it has changed the nature of incentives The emphasis on strategic choice did
surrounding different management choices. initially exaggerate the degree of manage-
Many managers feel employment decisions rial discretion to act without regard to
have been liberated from trade union influence structural constraints (Kochan and Dyer,
rather than more constrained by market 1993: 571). Intensified competition between
pressures. firms due to globalization reduces the scope
This leads on to a further criticism of for managerial discretion in many respects
strategic choice theory in industrial relations given the imperative of reducing costs and
in that it provides only ‘a framework that increasing returns to shareholders. It is
does not say what sorts of choice will be incorrect, however, to claim strategic choice is
made’ (Edwards, 1995: 599). As a result, therefore necessarily reducing per se because
Edwards (1995: 20) suggests that strategic globalization recreates new opportunities for
choice theory is ‘industrial relations with strategic choices in other respects.
much of the politics removed’ in that it does Strategic choice is a commendable attempt
not stress the mainly negative implications for to simplify trends in labor management but it
250 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

collapses a complex range of choices into two unit strategies (Purcell and Ahlstrand, 1994).
options: choice or determinism. Most authors This does not imply that corporate directors
conclude that strategies are a matter of con- never consider labor management issues.
textualized choice, suggesting managers have The UK Company Level Industrial Relations
‘considerable scope’ (Sisson and Marginson, Survey (Marginson et al., 1988) reported that
2003: 182) or ‘some degree’ (Kessler and company level directors often consider indus-
Purcell, 2003: 314) of choice. Should we trial relations issues in strategic decisions
therefore regard labor management as the with employment implications. However, the
result of constrained choices? Unfortunately, personnel function is more likely to be
this does little to specify the precise degree of involved at the implementation stage of key
choice in different contexts. decisions rather than at the decision-making
stage (Purcell, 1995: 77).
A number of factors increase the chance
CORPORATE STRATEGY AND that managers consider employment issues
STRUCTURE in corporate strategy. Firms with a personnel
director on the main board of directors are
As mentioned in the previous section, Kochan much more likely to consider labor man-
et al. (1984) argued that strategic choice agement issues when deciding on business
in industrial relations requires managers to strategy. In addition, those firms are also
link decisions across different levels of the more likely to have company-wide personnel
firm, from corporate to workplace levels. This policies and personnel policy committees
requires the existence of industrial relations (Sisson, 1995; 2001: 80). Workplace level
plans at both corporate and workplace levels findings are similar: workplaces in firms
for managers to link. Section one described with a personnel director on the board are
the lack of a formal plan with employment also more likely to include employment
components in many workplaces. Many firms components in strategic workplace plans and
also lack an overall industrial relations policy involve managers responsible for employ-
at corporate level. For example, Marginson ment relations matters in preparing these
et al. (1988) asked UK corporate personnel plans (Kersley et al., 2006: 62–64). However,
managers whether they had an overall human at least in the UK, personnel functional
resource management policy. Although 80 representation has not increased at board
per cent claimed they had an overall policy, level (Millward et al., 2000); there is no
few could describe it when asked, indicating evidence that general workplace business
such policies were informal aims rather than strategies are currently more likely to include
coherent plans. Even these descriptions of employment components than in the past;
informal aims were not associated with the and the involvement of managers responsible
actual company practices used. for employment matters in preparing strategic
The failure to find corporate industrial plans has actually declined (Kersley et al.,
relations policies suggests that industrial 2006: 67). The low status and marginal role of
relations issues are unlikely to feature personnel managers clearly demonstrate that
in many corporate strategies. Employment few firms adopt a strategic approach to labor
components or industrial relations strategies management. As a result, corporate decisions
are indeed rarely principal ingredients of restrict the range of strategic choices over
corporate strategy at boardroom level and employment practice available to managers.
are at best marginal rather than integral Most research therefore points to severe
to corporate strategies (Purcell, 1983: 4). restraints from ‘beyond the workplace’
Labor management is therefore appropriately imposed by corporate strategies and corporate
described as a ‘third order’ strategy involving structures on strategic industrial relations
decisions made after firms have developed and choices (Purcell, 1983). In addition, the
started to implement corporate and business growth of large diversified multi-divisional
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 251

companies appears to deter managers from an important mechanism to restructure organiza-


investment or high road approach toward staff tions through a radical change in ownership.
in a number of further ways. It decentralizes Buy-outs appear to reverse the process of
industrial relations strategies to business unit corporate diversification and financial con-
level (Purcell, 1989); industrial relations trol that previously prevented investments
decisions are distant from corporate strategy- in human resource management (Bacon
making (Purcell, 1995); and the financial et al., 2004; Bruining et al., 2005). Buy-
control of business units in such companies out managers report an increase in high
appears to prevent long-term investments commitment management practices after buy-
in high commitment management practices outs especially where existing managers and
(Purcell, 1989). employees are involved in ownership, where
Corporate and divisional managers fre- buy-outs enter joint ventures, employment
quently constrain and instruct workplace- issues appear in strategic plans, and the
level managers on a wide range of industrial buy-out prioritizes customer service. The
relations decisions, restricting the autonomy extent to which buy-outs facilitate strategic
of workplace industrial relations managers labor management choices is still to be fully
to make strategic decisions (Marginson et understood and requires further research.
al., 1988; see also Kochan, 1980). Despite As the structure of large diversified corpo-
the formal decentralization of collective rations makes strategic choices in industrial
bargaining, few managers in workplaces relations difficult, we might expect to find
belonging to large multi-establishment firms greater choice exercised in small and medium-
or in the public sector are able to make sized enterprises (SMEs). Managers in SMEs
autonomous industrial relations decisions on certainly have strong views on employment
such issues as union recognition and pay issues, resist outside interference and advice,
(Kirkpatrick and Hoque, 2005; Sisson, 2001). and few recognize trade unions. However,
Corporate structure therefore continues to employment practices vary in a predictable
exert an important downward and restrictive manner within the SME sector suggesting
influence on employment practices. Research that employment practices reflect the SME’s
highlights the importance of corporate trends context rather than managerial choice. Anal-
toward diversification and divisionalization as ysis of the 1998 British Workplace Employ-
especially pervasive pressures restricting the ment Relations Survey, for example, reveals
adoption of progressive employment practices that SMEs adopt more sophisticated formal
(Sisson and Marginson, 2003). Briefly stated, employment practices if they employ and need
it is less appropriate for diversified firms to retain highly skilled employees (Bacon and
operating in a range of different product Hoque, 2005). The position of small firms
markets to make central employment relations in the supply chain also appears to explain
decisions as the needs of different business labor management strategies. Rainnie (1989)
units will most likely vary. Highly division- argues that large customers tend to dominate
alised companies are also likely to exercise small supplier firms, with ‘dependent’ SMEs
financial control from the center that restricts forced to adopt authoritarian management,
discretionary expenditure on employment tight supervision and low wage levels. This
matters at divisional level, notwithstanding implies that networks around small firms
the appearance of devolved decision-making. coerce managers to adopt specific practices
It is clearly difficult for industrial relations and restrict strategic choices. However, small
managers to influence corporate decisions firms also proactively develop networks
although recent corporate structure and of contacts with other firms and business
ownership changes suggest possible ways advisory organizations in order to learn how
in which corporate strategy and employ- to develop more sophisticated employment
ment issues may be integrated. Management practices (Bacon and Hoque, 2005; Erickson
buy-outs, for example, have become an and Jacoby, 2003). The degree of strategic
252 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

choice in labor management for SMEs appears practices to business strategies, not least
to reflect whether they are proactive in devel- because business strategies are only rarely
oping networks to learn about employment straightforward or clear-cut (Legge, 1995;
practices, or whether larger dominant firms Whipp, 1992). Many firms seek to compete on
coerce them into certain activities. Research several bases simultaneously pursuing more
is still developing into the labor management than one strategy at a time seeking, for
implications of networks on SMEs. example to improve quality and reduce costs
Understanding the impact of corporate (Wood, 1999: 374). In such cases, managers
strategy and structure on the organization are likely to use a complex blend of some
of management of industrial relations has employment practices to reduce costs and
explained the disconnection between corpo- others to increase employee commitment to
rate strategy and labor management. Recent producing quality products or services. This
work on buy-outs and SMEs is only starting to presents a series of difficult management
clarify the circumstances in which corporate choices.
strategy and labor management are connected.

HIGH COMMITMENT EMPLOYMENT


BUSINESS STRATEGY AND LABOR PRACTICES
MANAGEMENT
An alternative approach is to assume a
Rather than assuming corporate directors strategic approach to labor management may
should take labor management strategy into exist if managers implement the best or most
account when designing broader corpo- effective employment practices. Accumulated
rate strategies, managers may of course research from the mid-1990s shows a positive
be exercising limited choice but acting link between adopting a supporting bundle
strategically if they develop employment of high commitment management practices
practices that support business strategies and firm performance (Wall and Wood,
that are already decided (Jackson et al., 2005). Chapters 33 (Delaney), 22 (Frost) and
1989; Guest, 1987; Miller, 1987; Purcell, 8 (Procter) in this volume describe these
2001; Schuler and Jackson, 1987). Managers practices and evaluate the evidence in detail.
selecting appropriate employment practices to To the extent that the aim of management
match business strategies may therefore be strategy is to maximize firm performance,
acting strategically (see Cappelli, 1999). For and high commitment management prac-
example, the following employment practices tices maximize firm performance, then firms
all appear appropriate: airlines providing adopting these practices have effective labor
innovative services pay higher wages (John- management strategies.
son et al., 1989); workers in automobile Unfortunately, the limited adoption of high
assembly plants receiving less training in commitment management practices indicates
cost-driven mass production work systems an overall lack of labor management strategy
(MacDuffie and Kochan, 1995); mini-mills according to the high commitment manage-
producing differentiated steels investing in ment paradigm. Between 1998 and 2004,
practices to develop employee commitment for example, the number of UK workplaces
(Arthur, 1992); and hotels competing on reporting the bundle of high commitment
service quality deploying high commitment management practices increased from only 13
employment practices (Hoque, 1999). to 16 per cent (Kersley et al., 2005: 40) and in
Matching employment practices to busi- the US only 10 per cent of workplaces reported
ness strategy appears to imply at first glance three or more ‘alternative work organization
limited scope for strategic labor manage- practices’ (Gittleman et al., 1998). A similar
ment choices. It is, however, more difficult picture emerges from single industry studies.
in practice to match specific employment Relatively few firms adopt the employment
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 253

practices of their most successful competitors explicit links between the issues shaping
in the same industry. For example, Ichniowski management strategy are essential to generate
and Shaw (1995) found only 11 per cent of more precise and interesting hypotheses and
steel processing lines had high commitment assess the likely direction of employment
management practices and in MacDuffie’s relations.
(1995) study of the auto industry only 25 per The increased study of management in
cent of workplaces reported the employment industrial relations remains controversial for
practices of the most productive sites. Most some researchers because it may make
firms do not have a strategic approach to industrial relations research less scientific
labor management if adopting high commit- (Godard and Delaney, 2000; Sisson and
ment management practices is a reasonable Sullivan, 1987: 431). It may also result in work
measure. If managers deploy opportunistic that is regarded as managerialist whereby
ad hoc collections of employment practices ‘labor management is made subservient to
then it is ultimately more useful to analyze the needs of the firm’ (Purcell, 1993: 523),
each practice individually rather than as part incorporating the study of industrial relations
of a broader strategy. into a management-driven agenda focused
solely on firm productivity. This could occur
because studying management may eclipse
CONCLUSION: THE STRATEGY the traditional focus on trade unions, and
CONCEPT AND IR ANALYSIS displace labor movement values such as
equality of treatment and wealth redistribution
This chapter has discussed several different as legitimate aims of inquiry (Godard and
ways of understanding labor management Delaney, 2000).
strategy. Labor strategies result from man- Although it is always helpful to reflect on
agement choices with regard to some if the values underpinning industrial relations
not all of the following considerations: a research, Kochan (2000) is surely correct
strategic planning process; coherence; values; to argue that industrial relations researchers
an assessment of the scope of choice; corpo- since the 1980s had little realistic choice other
rate structure and strategy; business strategy; than to study management in greater detail
and a practical assessment of employment in order to remain of practical relevance.
practices that work. The applicability of the To neglect the study of management in
strategy concept to the analysis of industrial industrial relations over the past 20 years
relations and the degree to which strategies would have impoverished the subject because
are empirically verifiable depends on incre- managers not trade unions were initiating
mentally improving the conceptualization and major industrial relations changes (Kochan,
measurement of labor management strategies 2000). Rather than diminishing the study of
with helpful suggestions provided in this industrial relations, research on management
chapter. has helped to ensure the continuing practical
The most interesting work often emerges relevance of academic inquiry and enriched
from exploring the connections between these our understanding of the factors affecting
issues. For example, managers may only adopt employment (for example, see Gospel, 1992;
high commitment management practices if and Sisson and Marginson, 2003). Fur-
labor laws compel action and allow no thermore, focusing on management should
strategic choice. Another example is the lead to increased rather than less criticism
suggestion that high commitment manage- of managers. In many workplaces where
ment practices require business strategies managers deny trade unions influence, then it
emphasizing quality, management values that is managers who are solely responsible if labor
support investing in employees and gain- problems such as low productivity persist.
sharing, or an influential role for the HR Labor problems are thus now clearly the
function (Kochan and Dyer, 2001). Making result of mismanagement, requiring criticism
254 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of managers and consideration of ways networks’. International Journal of Human Resource


to improve management practice including Management, 16 (11): 1976–99.
employment legislation. Bacon, N., Wright, M. and Demina, N. (2004) ‘Man-
Purcell’s (1983: 6) argument that the agement buyouts and human resource management’.
inevitable broadening of the boundaries of British Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (2):
325–47.
industrial relations to encompass managers
Baron, J.N., and Hannan, M.T. (2002) ‘Organizational
involved ‘no more than a further twist to blueprints for success in high-tech start-ups: Lessons
the multi-disciplinary nature of the subject’ from the Stanford project on emerging companies’.
now predominates. Unless trade unions or California Management Review, 44 (3): 8–36.
governments start to initiate major changes in Braverman, H. (1974). Labor and Monopoly Capital.
industrial relations, research studying the role New York: Monthly Review Press.
of managers, developments in human resource Brown, W., Marginson, P. and Walsh, J. (2003) ‘The
management practices and the broader corpo- management of pay as the influence of collective
rate context that shapes employment strate- bargaining diminishes’. In P. Edwards (ed.) Industrial
gies, will continue to increase over the coming Relations: Theory and Practice, Second Edition,
years. Oxford: Blackwell. pp. 189–213.
Bruining, H., Boselie, P., Wright, M. and Bacon,
N. (2005) ‘HRM in Buyouts in the UK and
the Netherlands’. International Journal of Human
NOTES Resource Management, 16 (3): 345–65.
Cappelli, P. (ed) (1999) Employment Practices and
1 The detailed contents of industrial relations Business Strategy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
strategies, for example the decision whether to Clegg, H.A. (1979) The Changing System of Industrial
recognize unions, mechanisms for handling conflict Relations in Great Britain. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
and the level and scope of bargaining, will not be Deaton, D. (1985) ‘Management style and large scale
covered in detail here and are covered in other
survey evidence’. Industrial Relations Journal, 16 (2):
chapters in this book.
67–71.
2 Other definitions stress that strategy also requires
intention by decision-makers, proactive management, Drago, R. (1996) ‘Workplace transformation and the
embedding in the firm’s direction and history, disposable workplace: Employee involvement in
espousal in plans and delivery in practice and variation Australia’. Industrial Relations, 35 (4): 526–43.
in subject matter (see Marchington and Parker, Dundon, T. and Rollinson, D. (2004) Employment
1990: 59). Relations in Non-Union Firms. London: Routledge.
3 Updating this point, the contrast is of limited help Edwards, P. (1995) ‘Assessment: Markets and man-
to classify firms in countries where a majority of firms agerialism’. In P. Edwards (ed.) Industrial Relations:
do not recognize unions. Theory and Practice in Britain. Oxford: Blackwell. pp.
4 Dastmalchian in this volume makes a similar
599–613.
point that developing climate measures associated
Edwards, P. and Scullion, H. (1982) The Social
with specific practices is a useful way to increase the
predictive capacity of industrial relations climate. Organization of Workplace Conflict. Oxford, Basil
Blackwell.
Erickson, C.L., and Jacoby, S.M. (2003) ‘The effect
of employer networks on workplace innovation and
REFERENCES training’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
56 (2): 203–24.
Arthur, J.B. (1992) ‘The link between business strategy Fox, A. (1966) Industrial Sociology and Industrial
and industrial relations systems in American steel Relations. Research Paper 3, Royal Commission on
minimills’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Trade Unions and Employers’ Associations. London:
45 (3): 488–506. HMSO.
Bacon, N., and Blyton, P. (2000) ‘High road and low road Fox, A. (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power and Trust
teamworking: Perceptions of management rationales Relations. London: Faber and Faber.
and organizational and human resource outcomes’. Friedman, A. (1977). Industry and Labor. London:
Human Relations, 53 (11): 1425–58. Macmillan.
Bacon, N. and Hoque, K. (2005) ‘HRM in the Gittleman, M., Horrigan, M. and Joyce, M. (1998)
SME sector: valuable employees and coercive ‘Flexible workplace practices: evidence from a
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 255

nationally representative survey’. Industrial and Labor Systems. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University
Relations Review, 52 (1): 99–115. Press.
Godard, J. (1997) ‘Whither strategic choice: Do Kaufman, B.E. (2003) ‘John, R. Commons and the
managerial ideologies matter?’ Industrial Relations, Wisconsin school on industrial relations strategy and
36 (2): 206–29. policy’. Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 57 (1):
Godard, J. and Delaney, J.T. (2000) ‘Reflections on 3–30.
the ‘High Performance’ paradigm’s implications for Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H.,
industrial relations as a field’. Industrial and Labor Dix, G. and Oxenbridge, S. (2005), Inside the
Relations Review, 53 (3): 482–502. Workplace: First Findings from the 2004 Workplace
Gollan, P.J. (2006) ‘Editorial: consultation and non- Employment Relations Survey, Department of Trade
union employee representation’. Industrial Relations and Industry. London.
Journal, 37 (5): 428–38. Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H.,
Gospel, H. (1992) Markets, Firms and the Management Dix, G. and Oxenbridge, S. (2006) Inside the
of Labor. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Workplace: Findings from the 2004 Workplace
Goss, D. (1991). ‘In search of small firm industrial Employment Relations Survey. London: Routledge.
relations’. In R. Burrows (ed.) Deciphering the Enter- Kessler, I. and Purcell, J. (2003) ‘Individualism and
prise Culture: Entrepreneurship, Petty Capitalism and collectivism in industrial relations’. In P. Edwards
the Restructuring of Britain. London: Routledge. (ed.) Industrial Relations. Oxford: Blackwell.
pp. 152–75. pp. 313–37.
Guest, D. (1987) ‘Human resource management and Kirkpatrick, I. and Hoque, K. (2005) ‘The decentralization
industrial relations’. Journal of Management Studies, of employment relations in the British public sector’.
24 (5): 503–21. Industrial Relations Journal, 36 (2): 100–20.
Guest, D. (2001) ‘Industrial relations and human Kochan, T.A. (1980) Collective Bargaining and Industrial
resource management’. In J. Storey (ed.) Human Relations. Homewood, Illinois: Richard Irwin.
Resource Management: A Critical Text. London: Kochan, T.A. (2000) ‘On the paradigm guiding industrial
Thomson Learning. pp. 96–113. relations theory and research: comment on John
Guest, D.E. and Peccei, R. (2001) ‘Partnership at Godard and John, T. Delaney, “reflections on the ‘high
work: Mutuality and the balance of advantage’. performance’ paradigm’s implications for industrial
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 39 (2): relations as a field”’. Industrial and Labor Relations
207–36. Review, 53 (4): 704–11.
Hoque, K. (1999) ‘Human resource management and Kochan, T.A. and Dyer, L. (1993) ‘Managing trans-
performance in the UK hotel industry’. British Journal formational change: the role of human resource
of Industrial Relations, 37 (3): 419–43. professionals’. International Journal of Human
Hunter, L., McGregor, A., MacInnes, J. and Sproull, A. Resource Management, 4 (3): 569–88.
(1993) ‘The “flexible firm”: Strategy and segmenta- Kochan, T. and Dyer, L. (2001) ‘HRM: an American
tion’. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 31 (3): view’. In J. Storey (ed.) Human Resource Manage-
383–407. ment: A Critical Text. London: Thomson Learning.
Hyman, R. (1987) ‘Strategy of structure? Capital, labour pp. 272–87.
and control’. Work, Employment and Society, 1 (1): Kochan, T.A., McKersie, R.B. and Cappelli, P. (1984)
25–55. ‘Strategic choice and industrial relations theory’.
Ichniowski, C. and Shaw, K. (1995) ‘Old dogs Industrial Relations, 23 (1): 16–39.
and new tricks: Determinants of the adoption of Kochan, T.A., Katz, H.C. and McKersie, R.B. (1986)
productivity-enhancing work practices’. Brookings The Transformation of American Industrial Relations.
Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue Microe- New York: Basic Books.
conomics. pp. 1–65. Legge, K. (1995) ‘HRM: Rhetoric, reality and hidden
Jackson, S.E., Schuler, R.S. and Rivero, J.C. (1989) ‘Orga- agendas’. In J. Storey (ed.) Human Resource
nizational characteristics as predictors of personnel Management: A Critical Text. London: Thomson
practices’. Personnel Psychology, 42 (4): 727–86. Learning. pp. 33–59.
Johnson, N.B., Sambharya, R.B. and P. Bobko (1989) Lewin, D. (1987) ‘Industrial relations as a strate-
‘Deregulation, business strategy, and wages in gic variable’. In M.M. Kleiner, R.N. Block,
the airline industry’. Industrial Relations, 28 (3): M. Roomkin and S.W. Salsburg (eds) Human
419–30. Resources and the Performance of the Firm. Madi-
Katz, H.C. and Darbishire, O. (2000) Converging son, WI: Industrial Relations Research Association.
Divergences: Worldwide Changes in Employment pp. 1–41.
256 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

MacDuffie, J.P. (1995) ‘Human resource bundles and Purcell, J. (1983) ‘The management of industrial
manufacturing performance: Organizational logic relations in the modern corporation: Agenda for
and flexible production systems in the world auto research’. British Journal of Industrial Relations,
industry’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 21 (1): 1–16.
48 (2): 197–221. Purcell, J. (1987) ‘Mapping management styles in
MacDuffie, J.P. and Kochan, T.A. (1995) ‘Do U.S firms employee relations’. Journal of Management Studies,
invest less in human resources? Training in the 24 (5): 533–48.
world auto industry’. Industrial Relations, 34 (2): Purcell, J. (1989) ‘The impact of corporate strategy
147–68. on human resource management’. In J. Storey (ed.)
Marchington, M. and Harrison, E. (1991) ‘Customers, New Perspectives on Human Resource Management.
competitors and choice: employee relations in London: Routledge. pp. 67–91.
food retailing’. Industrial Relations Journal, 22 (4): Purcell, J. (1993) ‘The challenge of human resource
286–99. management for industrial relations research and
Marchington, M. and Parker, P. (1990) Changing practice’. International Journal of Human Resource
Patterns of Employee Relations. Hemel Hempstead: Management, 4 (3): 511–27.
Harvester Wheatsheaf. Purcell, J. (1995) ‘Corporate strategy and its link with
Marginson, P. (1998) ‘The survey tradition in British human resource management strategy’. In J. Storey
industrial relations research: an assessment of the (ed.) Human Resource Management: A Critical Text.
contribution of large-scale workplace and enterprise London: Routledge. pp. 63–86.
surveys’. British Journal of Industrial Relations, Purcell, J. (2001) ‘The meaning of strategy in human
36 (3): 361–88. resource management’. In J. Storey (ed.) Human
Marginson, P., Edwards, P., Martin, R., Purcell, J. and Resource Management: A Critical Text. London:
Sisson, K. (1988) Beyond the Workplace. Oxford: Basil Thomson Learning. pp. 59–77.
Blackwell. Purcell, J. and Sisson, K. (1983) ‘Strategies and practice
McKersie, R.B. (1987) ‘The transformation of American in the management of industrial relations’. In G. Bain
industrial relations: The abridged story’. Journal of (ed.) Industrial Relations in Britain. Oxford: Blackwell.
Management Studies, 24 (5): 433–40. pp. 95–120.
Miller, P. (1987) ‘Strategic industrial relations and Purcell, J. and Ahlstrand, B. (1994) Human Resource
human resource management: distinction, definition Management in the Multi-divisional Company.
and recognition’. Journal of Management Studies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
24 (4): 347–61. Rainnie, A. (1989). Industrial Relations in Small Firms.
Millward, N., Bryson, A. and Forth J. (2000) All Change London: Routledge.
at Work? London: Routledge. Ram, M., and Holliday, R. (1993) ‘Relative merits: family
Morris, T. and Wood, S. (1991) ‘Testing the survey culture and kinship in small firms’. Sociology, 27 (4):
method: Continuity and change in British industrial 629–48.
relations’. Work, Employment and Society, 5 (2): Roy, D. (1980) ‘Fear stuff, sweet stuff and evil stuff:
259–82. Management’s defences against unionization in the
Muller-Jentsch, W. (2004) ‘Theoretical approaches to South’. In T. Nichols (ed.) Capital and Labor: A Marxist
industrial relations’. In B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theo- Primer. Glasgow: Fontana. pp. 395–415.
retical Perspectives on Work and the Employment Schuler, R.S. and Jackson, S.E. (1987) ‘Linking com-
Relationship. Illinois: IRRA. pp. 1–40. petitive strategies with human resource management
Osterman, P. (1994) ‘How common is workplace practices’. Academy of Management Executive, 1 (3):
transformation and who adopts it?’ Industrial and 207–19.
Labor Relations Review, 47 (2): 173–88. Sisson, K. (1994) ‘Personnel management: paradigms,
Osterman, P. (1995) ‘Skill, training, and work organiza- practice and prospects’. In K. Sisson (ed.) Personnel
tion in American establishments’. Industrial Relations, Management. Oxford: Blackwell. pp. 3–50.
34 (2): 125–46. Sisson, K. (1995) ‘Human resource management and the
Osterman, P. (2000) ‘Work reorganization in an era personnel function’. In J. Storey (ed.) Human Resource
of restructuring: Trends in diffusion and effects on Management: A Critical Text. London: Routledge.
employee welfare’. Industrial and Labor Relations pp. 87–109.
Review, 53 (2): 179–96. Sisson, K. (2001) ‘Human resource management and
Piore, M. and Sabel, C.J. (1984) The Second Industrial the personnel function – a case of partial impact?’. In
Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic J. Storey (ed.) Human Resource Management: A Crit-
Books. ical Text. London: Thomson Learning. pp. 78–95.
MANAGEMENT STRATEGY AND INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 257

Sisson, K. and Marginson, P. (2003) ‘Management: Thurley, K. and Wood, S. (1983) Industrial Relations
Systems, structures and strategy’, in P. Edwards and Management Strategy. Cambridge: Cambridge
(ed.) Industrial Relations, Second Edition, Oxford: University Press.
Blackwell. pp. 157–88. Wall, T. and Wood, S. (2005) ‘The romance of human
Sisson, K. and Sullivan, T. (1987) ‘Editorial: Manage- resource management and business performance,
ment strategy and industrial relations’. Journal of and the case for big science’. Human Relations, 58 (4):
Management Studies, 24 (5): 427–32. 429–62.
Streeck, W. (1987) ‘The uncertainties of management Walton, R. (1985) ‘From control to commitment in the
in the management of uncertainty: Employers, labor workplace’. Harvard Business Review, March–April:
relations and industrial adjustment in the 1980s’. 77–84.
Work, Employment and Society, 1 (3): 281–308. Whipp, R. (1992) ‘Human resource management,
Storey, J. and Bacon, N. (1993) ‘Individualism and competition and strategy: Some productive tensions’.
collectivism: into the 1990s’. International Journal of In P. Blyton and P. Turnbull (eds) Reassessing
Human Resource Management, 4 (3): 665–684. Human Resource Management. London: Sage.
Strauss, G. (1984) ‘Industrial relations: Time of change’. pp. 33–55.
Industrial Relations, 23 (1): 1–15. Wood, S. (1999) ‘Human resource management and
Taras, D.G. and Kaufman, B.E. (2006) ‘Non-union performance’. International Journal of Management
employee representation in North America: diversity, Reviews, 1 (4): 367–413.
controversy and uncertain future’. Industrial Relations Woodland, S., Simmonds, N., Thornby, M., Fitzgerald, R.
Journal, 37 (5): 513–42. and McGee, A. (2003) The Second Work-Life Balance
Thompson, P. (2003) ‘Disconnected capitalism: Or why Study: Results from the Employer Survey Main Report.
employers can’t keep their side of the bargain’. Work, Employment Relations Research Series No. 22. DTI
Employment and Society, 17 (2): 359–78. HMSO, London.
14
The State in
Industrial Relations
Richard Hyman

In his pioneering attempt to develop a general (mediating the uniform impact of technology)
theory of industrial relations (IR), Dunlop was central.
(1958) defined its essence in terms of three In part, this perspective reflected the
‘actors’ (employers and managers, workers specific realities of the North American
and their representatives and governmental institutional framework in the early postwar
agencies) and three ‘contexts’ (technology, decades, together with an assumption that
market constraints and the distribution of these would become the model elsewhere. The
power in society). One might assume from this comparative study Industrialism and Indus-
that the role of government and the impact of trial Man (Kerr et al., 1960), of which Dunlop
politics (the dynamics of power) would have was a co-author, established the dominant
figured prominently in his analysis, and that of approach in Anglo-Saxon industrial relations
subsequent writers who embraced his systems analysis for much of the subsequent period.
model. However, this was not the case. In Diversity in national industrial relations
practice the main focus of Dunlop, and most systems was the product of the distinctive
subsequent writers in the English-speaking composition and priorities of the ‘industrial-
world, was on the rules negotiated between izing elites’ who had driven the process of
employers and unions. Dunlop placed key economic modernization; but common tech-
explanatory emphasis on the economic and (in nologies and cross-national markets would
particular) technological factors which influ- create convergence toward a common model
enced employment regulation: he devoted two of regulation, which would match the contem-
central chapters of his book to a comparison porary Anglo-American pattern of ‘pluralistic
of work rules in coal-mining and construc- industrialism’. This was defined as a system
tion, arguing that cross-national similarities in which employers and unions developed
reflected common technical requirements. increasingly effective and non-conflictual bar-
Politics, and government, were in effect gaining relationships, making detailed state
treated as peripheral; collective bargaining regulation unnecessary. Hence in this view,
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 259

‘mature’ industrial relations systems became More specifically I insist, following Polanyi
detached from the political process. In Britain, (1944) that markets including labor markets
similarly, Kahn-Freund argued that are politically constructed. My proposed
analytical model points to a tension between
there exists something like an inverse correlation
between the practical significance of legal sanctions
three state functions relevant to industrial
and the degree to which industrial relations have relations: accumulation, pacification and
reached a state of maturity. The legal aspect of legitimation. This I explore by examining
those obligations on which labour-management a variety of employment-relevant state
relations rest is, from a practical point of view, least functions in a wide range of national and
important where industrial relations are developed
most satisfactorily (1954: 43–4).
historical contexts. I end by asking whether
there can be a general theory of the role of
This treatment long persisted in Anglo- the state in industrial relations.
American industrial relations writing: for
example, in his influential textbook Kochan
(1980: 1) defined industrial relations as ‘an
interdisciplinary field that encompasses the WHAT IS THE STATE?
study of all aspects of people at work’;
but his focus was almost exclusively on What do we mean when we speak of
management-union relations, while the state the state? It is essential to pose this
was peripheral. question, even if it is impossible to give
English-language writing in our subject has a definitive answer in the space available
typically assumed, in effect, that ‘politics’ (indeed arguably, a definitive answer is in
and ‘industrial relations’ are institutionally principle unattainable). As Held has argued
separate spheres (Giles, 1988). While the state (1983: 1), ‘there is nothing more central to
may ‘intervene’in employment relations, such political and social theory than the nature
intervention is (or should be) bounded and of the state, and nothing more contested’.
issue-specific. Similarly, the labor market and Part of the reason is that in English – unlike
the welfare state are regarded as unrelated most continental European languages – to
socio-economic subsystems: industrial rela- use the term ‘state’ implies a distinctive,
tions scholars focus on the former, leaving ‘theoretical’ approach to the role of political
the latter to social policy departments. This institutions in socio-economic relations.
perspective contrasts markedly with the One common response is to reduce the
conceptions of employment regulation which concept to a set of empirical descriptors:
prevail in many countries, and in literatures the government, the parliament, the courts
and languages other than English. and so on. Some years ago the index of
I will argue in this chapter that the notion a well-known textbook on British industrial
of ‘pluralistic’ detachment between the state relations contained the entry: ‘State, see
and industrial relations reflects a distinctive government’. Yet if the term ‘state’ merely
historical conjuncture in a limited number of denotes a set of identifiable institutions,
countries; and that it stems from an empiricist there is no obvious reason (except perhaps
tradition which reduces social relations to for brevity) to employ it at all. This is
institutional interconnections. I also suggest indeed the argument of Wilensky, who opens
that it is necessary to distinguish sharply his impressive comparative study of ‘rich
between the concept of the state and the democracies’ with the statement (2002: xxv)
specific institutions of government; and that that ‘throughout I avoid vague discussion of
it is therefore misleading to speak in terms of “the state” or “society”; instead I examine
‘state intervention’, for the state is an integral the components of these grand abstractions ...
element in any productive system and it is The entire book is an attempt to specify the
impossible to establish a clear separation institutions – executive, legislative, judicial,
between the ‘economic’ and the ‘political’. military – that comprise the state ...’
260 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Yet in any sphere of intellectual endeavor, and essentially an arena, a place, and yet
abstraction serves a necessary purpose. Some this is the very source of its autonomy’. And
abstractions (like capitalism, or indeed soci- Stråth (1996: 218) characterizes the state as ‘a
ety, or an industrial relations system) may network structure with no permanent content.
be ‘grand’; others, like management, or The state is constantly being recreated, in new
productivity, or unemployment, may be more forms, by the groups and structures active in
mundane and taken-for-granted. Even what society’.
we mean by an institution is complex and Common to most approaches which tran-
multi-faceted. Abstraction is the necessary scend the institutional and descriptive is a
link between simple description on the one rejection, as Crouch (1993: viii) puts it,
hand and analysis and explanation on the of the ‘view that sees a clear distinction
other. When Hollingsworth and Boyer, for between state and civil society’. Taken to the
example, write (1997: 2) that ‘markets and extreme, as for example in the writings of
other coordinating mechanisms are shaped Poulantzas (1968), the state is so pervasive
by and are shapers of social systems of pro- as to be omnipresent. Though his approach
duction’, they are employing three separate is very different, Mann (1986: 113) argues
abstractions to assert the existence of a set of that there has been a transformation of state
two-way causal interdependences. To move power from primarily ‘despotic’ to primarily
closer to our own theme, when Streeck refers ‘infrastructural’ forms, which he defines as
(1997: 52) to ‘state capacity’ he is positing ‘the capacity of the state actually to penetrate
an interrelationship or articulation among civil society, and to implement logistically
institutions through which the whole may political decisions throughout the realm’. The
represent more than the sum of its parts. corollary is that while governments may
Definitions of the state can embody many be regarded as ‘actors’ which ‘intervene’
different emphases. For Weber, famously, in industrial relations, it is inappropriate to
it was ‘that human community which suc- refer to the state in similar terms. Yet even
cessfully claims the monopoly of legitimate if the state is not in any simple sense an
physical violence within a given territory’. ‘actor’, state power certainly shapes and
As Skocpol has suggested (1979: 25), this conditions industrial relations. It does so,
conception underlies two more recent but moreover, in ways which transcend the typical
opposing theoretical traditions, one highlight- focus of academic industrial relations on the
ing legitimacy and consent, the other coercion employment relationship narrowly defined:
and domination. Weber’s reference to ‘com- for crucially, the role of the state in creating
munity’(Gemeinschaft) is also significant: the (either actively, or by abstention) a regime of
state comprises diffuse relationships which welfare provision, and a broader conception of
cannot be reduced to a set of formal institu- citizenship, shapes in turn the basis on which
tions. As Jessop (1982: 221) insists, though workers enter the labor market.
from a very different theoretical background,
‘state power is a complex social relation’,
subsequently adding (1990: 316) that ‘the
state does not exist as a fully constituted, orga- STATE AND MARKET: THE
nizationally pure, and operationally closed FRAMEWORK FOR EMPLOYMENT
system but is an emergent, contradictory, REGULATION
hybrid and relatively open system’. Skocpol
(1985: 28), though approaching from yet Sidney and Beatrice Webb, the British pio-
another perspective, writes that ‘states may neers of the study of industrial relations
be viewed ... as configurations of organization (though not of the term itself), wrote in the
and action that influence the meanings and preface to their History of Trade Unionism
methods of politics for all groups and (1894: vii–ix) that what they initially con-
classes in society’. For Mann (1986: 112), ceived as an investigation of economic issues
somewhat paradoxically, ‘the state is merely turned out to encompass ‘the political history
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 261

of England’. More recent writers, as indicated thus a distinctively artificial creation (and in
above, have tended to reaffirm a division some respects a contradictory idea), and its
between politics and industrial relations: too character reflects ‘structures, conventions and
great an overlap was evidence of ‘imma- practices’ which vary with time and place
turity’. More broadly, it has been normal (Peck, 1996: 266). State policy in turn does
to treat politics and economics as largely much to explain this variation: if ‘the creation
separate social worlds. Academic demarca- of the conditions under which labour power
tions have run in parallel with ideological is sold has historically been one of the basic
presuppositions. During the cold war, a close and unchanging functions of the capitalist
interconnection between state and economic state’ (Coates, 2000: 225), how this function
life was seen as the hallmark of ‘command is performed is far from uniform or constant.
economies’, regarded as inefficient and def- Polanyi wrote of a ‘double movement’ in
initely undesirable (Friedman, 1962; Hayek, capitalist economies: the first involving the
1960). Since the end of the Soviet empire, imposition of ‘free’markets, the second (in the
the ‘Washington consensus’ has insisted that twentieth century) a countervailing process
those western (and even more so, Third World) to impose some constraint on the disruptive
governments which in the postwar decades social consequences of market liberalism.
had sought systematically to regulate the The creation of a regulatory web governing
economy should abandon such attempts in employment (whether through statute or
order to ‘free’ the market. Such ‘deregulation’ collective agreement) – a process which
should extend, in particular, to the labor Esping-Andersen (1990) terms ‘decommodi-
market and the employment relationship. fication’ – can evidently be interpreted within
Yet such arguments are misconceived: this framework. And we can describe more
states and markets are not opposites but recent trends as a third movement: the
interdependent (Iversen, 2005). As Lindblom deliberate unraveling of this regulatory web –
has insisted (1977: 8), ‘in all political systems what Streeck (1987) has described as the
of the world, much of politics is economics, re-imposition of ‘contract’ in place of ‘status’.
and most of economics is also politics’. This process is commonly termed ‘deregula-
Hence Crouch (1993: 299–300) contests the tion’, but this is misleading: not only because
view that market processes are somehow markets are themselves regulatory institutions
‘natural’, and that state involvement is an (Standing, 1997), but also because diverse
unnatural and problematic distortion of their experiences (Chile, Thatcher’s Britain, much
functioning. ‘To view the subject historically of Eastern Europe since the collapse of
is to see it the other way round; states and the Soviet empire and many countries of
organizations are enmeshed in the economy the Third World) suggest that, paradoxically,
from the outset; it is how they were often market intensification requires a strong state
driven out that needs explanation’. This was (Gamble, 1988) which suppresses resistance.
indeed the classic thesis of Polanyi (1944): This contrasts with the common assump-
the creation of ‘free’ markets in Britain in tion that market liberalization and political
the early nineteenth century involved the democracy go hand-in-hand.
massive deployment of state power to displace Abstracting analytically from a diversity of
pre-existing economic relationships. ‘Markets national and historical experience, one may
are themselves institutions’, as Hall puts it identify three broad and often contradictory
(1986: 282–3) and hence ‘ultimately artifacts (Offe, 1984) functions of state activity with a
of political action’. bearing on employment relations.
This applies a fortiori to the arena of
industrial relations. For Polanyi, labor was • Accumulation: encouraging economic perfor-
a ‘fictitious commodity’: since work was mance, productivity and competitiveness. Obvi-
inseparable from the worker, it could never ously there are crucial debates whether this
be bought and sold in the same way as requires active state intervention and encour-
say wool or potatoes. A labor market is agement, or on the contrary the ‘freeing’ of
262 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

markets. As suggested above, ‘non-intervention’ the Treasury and the Department of Industry
(or ‘deregulation’) must itself be viewed as a form had no qualms at risking conflict in the inter-
of intervention (or regulation). ests of accumulation. A stark parallel can be
• Pacification: preserving the integrity of national seen in Germany under the Kohl government
territory, maintaining social order, defusing or sup- between 1982 and 1998, when the labor
pressing conflict. Historically, in most countries,
ministry was headed by a leader of the trade
the boundaries between industrial conflict and
social and political disorder have been uncertain,
union wing within Kohl’s own party, whereas
and in many countries this remains the case. the economics ministry was controlled by his
Repression is a persistent feature of the evolution business-oriented junior coalition partner. In
of industrial relations, though most academic both countries, the subsequent abolition of a
literature is blind to this (Fusfeld, 1979; Kelly, separate employment ministry can be seen as
1998: 14, 56–7). a deliberate effort to reduce the influence of
• Legitimation: maintaining popular consent by labor within the state machinery.
pursuing social equity (which typically requires It is common to argue that the functionaries
‘market-correcting’ interventions) and fostering who occupy the state apparatus have their
citizenship and voice at work. Involving the ‘social own distinctive interests and world-view, and
partners’ in economic and social policy-making,
often favor policies which enlarge their own
as discussed below, may be a means of enhancing
government legitimacy.
influence and competence (Zeitlin, 1985:
26–7). As will be indicated below, historical
experience in some countries certainly
To speak of ‘state functions’ (a term also used encourages such a thesis. Where does this
by Mann, 1986), it should be emphasized, is leave the idea of a pluralist separation between
not to imply that governments will necessarily politics and industrial relations? Miguélez
pursue all three objectives consistently or will and Prieto (1991: xvii) assert that an industrial
do so effectively. One reason is that there is relations system ‘is a model based on the
almost inevitably a tension, or more strongly a autonomy of the parties’. This is plausible, if
contradiction, between these different policy we recognize that such autonomy is relative.
goals, and this results in complex, and at If we assume two polar (and empirically
times unstable, forms of interlinkage between scarcely conceivable) situations of absolute
government and industrial relations. For regulation of employment by market forces
example, across Europe (and in many other on the one hand, or by state prescription on the
parts of the world), the combination of an other, industrial relations as conventionally
ageing population and a perceived need to understood cannot exist. But because the
curb public expenditure to sustain national ‘autonomy of the parties’ is always bounded,
competitiveness has resulted in efforts to industrial relations involves an uneasy tension
cut back state pension systems; but such between state and market, voluntarism and
attempts risk provoking public disorder and prescription. Such a tension may even be
undermining government legitimacy. And a regarded as a defining characteristic of
second, interconnected reason is the role of industrial relations. One consequence is that
political contingency. Governments – and the articulation between state and market
indeed states – do deploy ‘autonomous varies across countries and may change
power’. Their policies are the outcomes of over time.
conflicts within and between political parties,
and between ministers and state functionaries
who may themselves be internally divided. CROSS-NATIONAL DIVERSITY
For example, when the UK possessed a
separate Ministry of Labour its officials were The literature on European industrial relations
strongly committed to the maintenance of commonly proposes a triple classification of
industrial peace through accommodation with national systems according to the extent and
the trade unions, whereas their counterparts in character of state engagement with employers
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 263

and (particularly) trade unions, and such applicable’. By contrast, Crouch suggests that
analysis is applicable on a broader, global his more recent classification ‘emerged from
scale. Regini (1986: 61–2) distinguished the literature of the 1970s and 1980s’.
between ‘the concertation model’, in which As seen above, Anglo-Saxon writing on
‘unions were closely involved in the for- industrial relations has traditionally taken
mulation and implementation of economic ‘pluralistic industrialism’ as the norm. But
policies’ and regulation more generally was pluralism was and is not typical; in most
highly centralized; ‘political isolation’, where countries, political power is an overt feature
governments excluded labor from the pol- of industrial relations though in ways which
icy process; and ‘pluralistic fragmentation’, are contextually variable. ‘In large parts of the
where ‘politics’ and ‘industrial relations’ world, the entire industrial relations system
were institutionally demarcated and unions is dominated, directly or indirectly, by the
depended solely on their labor market power. government’ (Sturmthal, 1973: 8).
Somewhat earlier, Hibbs (1978) had made First, there is continued national diversity
a similar three-way distinction in classify- of politico-economic regimes or ‘varieties of
ing national patterns of industrial conflict capitalism’(Hall and Soskice, 2001), in which
according to whether governments tended to the state often performs important functions as
intervene to redistribute national income (in economic actor and regulator or co-ordinator;
part through welfare provision) toward labor, and this diversity is often reflected in different
or conversely reinforced the share of profits, or forms of employment regulation. Hence
remained relatively aloof from distributional convergence has not occurred (though note, as
conflicts. More recently, Crouch (1993: 4) discussed below, that there are today frequent
applied ‘a threefold division between con- arguments that ‘globalization’ is a new, and
testation, pluralism and corporatism’; while more powerful driver of convergence).
van Waarden (1995: 110–1) writes of ‘three Second, as a corollary, highly ‘politicized’
general kinds of state action, liberal plu- industrial relations systems which Anglo-
ralism: a passive state which upholds the Saxon writers have long considered an
principle of non-intervention, corporatism: anachronism have tended to persist. This is the
active state interference, but usually in case in most of Africa, Asia, Latin America
consultation with the social partners, [and] and even in many countries of Western
statism: active and direct state interference Europe, for example France and Italy.
with terms of employment and working Third, new connections have arisen
conditions’. between industrial relations and political
These different classifications overlap, but agendas even in countries where there
are far from identical. They differ, for exam- was for a time considerable detachment.
ple, in whether they focus on institutional One argument would be that ‘pluralist
interconnections and the policy process, or industrialism’was the outcome of a temporary
(as with Hibbs) on material outcomes; and and contingent interaction of social, political
whether the focus is on relations between and economic forces. Typically this involved
the state and the labor movement (as with a ‘post-war compromise’ between unions
Regini and to a large extent Crouch), or and (nationally embedded) employers,
more broadly (as with van Waarden) on which established a stable institutionalized
the role of the ‘social partners’ in public relationship where mutual gains could be
policy. There are also differences in how far generated by rapid economic growth. Rising
such classifications are taken as empirical national income also funded expanding
descriptors or ideal types. For example, Regini welfare states. In the very different economic
cautioned against the mechanical application conditions of the late twentieth and early
of his typology to specific national cases, twenty-first centuries, these compromises
and argued (1986: 62) that ‘during the unraveled – or were sustained only by
1970s, the three models seemed even less increasingly overt state action.
264 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

The next section discusses in more detail its role in industrial relations, both across
the ways in which the state can be seen as countries and over time.
omnipresent in the dynamics of industrial This section suggests (though such classi-
relations. Thereafter I suggest a simple fications are inevitably somewhat arbitrary)
typology of three models of interconnection seven key respects in which the state shapes
between states and industrial relations. the national industrial relations regime:

• as an employer in its own right;


• through defining and delimiting the procedural
THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT IN status of the other ‘actors’ and prescribing the
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS: ARENAS ‘rules of the game’;
OF REGULATION • by legislating individual employment rights;
• by shaping the labor market through macroeco-
nomic management;
The ‘varieties of capitalism’ literature which
• through ‘supply-side’ labor market policies which
has become so influential in recent years shape the capacities brought by employees;
(see Chapter 7 in this volume) insists that • crucially, as a ‘welfare state’ limiting workers’
while all market economies may share certain dependence for survival on the employment rela-
core dynamics, their distinctive institutional tionship, and hence enhancing their bargaining
configurations result in very different social power; and finally;
and economic outcomes. Much of this lit- • as the matrix of ideas of citizenship which may
erature assumes some form of functional (though not necessarily) shape the relationship
interdependence between different elements between employers and employees.
of each nation’s institutional architecture.
For example, Dore (2000: 45–7) refers to All these arenas of state action operate to
‘institutional interlock’ as typical of national some degree in every country, but to very
economies and of the relationship between different degrees, and with stark contrasts
economy and broader society; Aoki (2001) in their relative importance. In consequence,
writes of ‘institutional complementarity’; there are multiple configurations in the role
Marsden (1999) argues that the institutions of government as an industrial relations actor
which constitute the ‘employment system’ (Amable, 2003).
within any country tend to ‘cluster’ over
time, according to an underlying structural
The state as employer
logic. As Hollingsworth and Boyer (1997:
2–3) put it, the industrial relations system All states are employers. Though the role
and other institutional arrangements tend of the state in LMEs is in theory more
to be ‘tightly coupled with each other’ limited than in CMEs, and though in much
and thus ‘coalesce into a complex social of the world the last two decades have seen a
configuration’. The consequence, but also process of privatization of public enterprises
the reinforcing dynamic, is that ‘firms will and contracting out of public services, almost
gravitate toward the mode of coordination for universally the majority of those working
which there is institutional support’ (Hall and in the military, law enforcement and public
Soskice, 2001: 9). While the last-cited authors administration, and at least a substantial
find it useful to present a dichotomy between proportion in health, education and social
liberal and co-ordinated market economies services, are state employees (and those who
(LMEs and CMEs), many other writers find are not are nevertheless typically subject to
this too broad-brush to make sense of the indirect state control of their employment con-
sheer diversity of institutional arrangements. ditions). This makes the state, broadly defined,
And the state itself is central to any national the largest single employer in most countries.
institutional architecture: there are radical As a result, we may add, the simple notion of
variations in the form, extent and depth of ‘three actors’in industrial relations – workers,
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 265

employers and government – is inadequate, of ‘modern’ employment relations. In most


since the state so to speak occupies two seats countries there were growing problems in
at the table. public-sector industrial relations in the 1980s
As Chapter 16 in this volume indicates, state and 1990s. Growing budgetary deficits often
employment typically involves distinctive led to efforts to cut public spending; in
industrial relations regimes. In some respects, Europe, these pressures were reinforced by the
the rules are more restrictive than in the private constraints on public expenditure laid down
sector. In very few countries are the armed by the EU in the 1991 Maastricht Treaty.
forces allowed to unionize, and in many the In many countries, incomes policies were
exclusions are far wider. The right to col- more rigorously enforced in the public than
lective bargaining may be constrained, either the private sector; the unequal impact led
because some categories of public employee to feelings of inequity and a breakdown of
enjoy a distinctive status (such as the German the ‘psychological contract’ between the state
Beamte), or because of the doctrine that and public employees. In addition, inter- and
this would infringe the sovereignty of the intra-union conflicts associated with public-
legislature in defining the terms of public sector collective bargaining became common.
employment. Often there are also prohibitions The growing weight of public sector unions
or tight limitations on strikes in ‘essential within national confederations (notably in
services’. Conversely, however, there is Sweden) shifted the balance of power, with
widespread formal encouragement of col- challenges to established bargaining policy.
lective representation for public employees. In some countries (notably Italy) greater
In Britain, this dates back to the Whitley assertiveness by groups with key skills, who
Reports at the end of the 1914–18 war. In lost out from egalitarian wage policy, caused
the US it stems from the Kennedy Executive major tensions. Such factors have led in some
Order 10988 of 1962, which authorized countries to a rise in militancy, often at the
unionization and collective bargaining for same time as dispute numbers were falling
federal employees, and was widely matched sharply in the private sector.
at state and local level. Partly because of
the at least latent political leverage of public
employees, in almost all countries their rate
Procedural regulation: defining the
of unionization is today higher, and often far
‘actors’ and the ‘rules of the game’
higher, than in the private sector. Job security
in the public sector has often been high Even in ‘voluntarist’ systems (where the state
(which in many countries has made public supposedly ‘abstains’ from involvement in
employment a basis for political patronage). industrial relations) it has an unavoidable
Secure employment has often been linked role in procedural regulation. This typically
to ideologies of ‘public service’ and of the involves defining the status, rights and
government as a ‘good employer’. For these obligations of the ‘actors’, and prescribing
reasons, in many countries (though by no and enforcing the ‘rules of the game’. Such
means all), public employment traditionally regulation can shape the major contours of
displayed peaceful industrial relations. the whole national system: for example,
The dynamics of public-sector industrial Howell (2005: 190) develops a powerful
relations are complex: does the state act as an argument that at key moments of social and
imitator or innovator? In Britain, governments economic crisis, ‘the British state ... played
have tended to follow ‘good practice’ in a central role in the construction, embedding
the private sector (which in recent years and legitimization of new industrial relations
has meant the importation of management institutions’.
styles and structures which critics consider One fundamental issue in any country is
inappropriate); in France and Italy, by con- the legal status of collective agreements. Typ-
trast, the public sector has been the dynamo ically they are binding on the signatories and
266 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

those they represent (‘collective contracts’) – In many others, employers’ associations have
though Britain is one of the most notable limited membership and non-members are not
exceptions. Where this is the case (and in some affected by their agreements. But elsewhere,
countries where it is not) the law specifies notably in many Western European countries
who may negotiate such agreements, often with strong traditions of ‘employer soli-
linking this to the registration or certification darity’, there exist ‘extension mechanisms’
of trade unions and employers’ associations. (sometimes known as erga omnes rules)
Particularly in developing countries, such whereby multi-employer agreements apply,
procedures can be used to privilege those either automatically or in the case of explicit
organizations which the government favors government determination to this effect, to
politically. One fascinating European instance non-member firms (Traxler and Behrens,
of selective certification is in France, where 2002). Not surprisingly, such provisions can
for historical reasons the law defines five trade constitute quite an incentive to firms to join
union confederations as ‘most representative’, the relevant employers’ association, so they
which gives them privileged access to peak- can influence the outcome of agreements to
level dialogue, and to company-level recogni- which they will be subject.
tion even where they have only one member. In many countries, the state prescribes
Much more generally, different approaches to obligatory mechanisms (at least in firms
the regulation of the ‘actors’ can encourage, over a certain size) for collective employee
or inhibit, collective organization in trade representation at company or workplace level,
unions in particular, but also in employers’ imposing an obligation on management to
associations (Adams, 1993). Except for a brief inform and consult the representatives over
period around WWII, US law and policy have key business and personnel policies. In some
offered little encouragement, in contrast to cases, as in Germany, this gives the workforce
most of Western Europe. Shifts in policy from a virtual veto over major decisions which
pro- to anti-collectivism can have dramatic threaten employment security.
effects, as in Britain under Thatcher and A fourth, and very important, procedural
even more notably in New Zealand with the role of the state is in handling (or avoiding)
Employment Contracts Act 1991. Note that in breakdowns in collective bargaining. Where
most of Western Europe, even conservative there are disagreements over the interpre-
parties (and governments) have tended to tation of legally enforceable agreements
favor collective regulation of employment. (‘disputes of right’, in the American parlance),
Another important issue is whether col- there typically exists dedicated machinery
lective agreements apply only to firms (and of adjudication such as labor courts. Most
indeed workers) who are members of the national systems also contain either voluntary
signatory organizations, or more generally. or compulsory mechanisms of conciliation,
It is widely the case that employers are mediation and arbitration applicable to ‘dis-
not permitted to discriminate between union putes of interest’ (where strikes and lock-outs
members and non-members, and that the latter are in principle permissible). There may also
are therefore entitled to the terms and con- be powers enabling governments to delay,
ditions contained in collective agreements. or even prohibit totally, stoppages in certain
In the US, more broadly, the ‘duty of fair cases.
representation’ requires unions to represent
the interests even of non-members where
Substantive employment rights
recognition exists. But what of firms which are
not members of their appropriate employers’ How far are the terms of the contract
association and/or do not recognize trade of employment a private matter between
unions? In countries like Britain or the employer and employee? The ideological
US, multi-employer bargaining is a marginal debate noted in an earlier section can also be
phenomenon and the issue scarcely arises. regarded as a conflict of organizing principles
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 267

between LMEs and CMEs, reflected in the (and the ‘social partners’ may strongly resist
contrast between ‘Anglo-Saxon’ – or as legislation).
Crouch (2005: 29–30) suggests is a preferable As described above, there has been a
term, Anglophone – and (Western) continen- recent trend in many countries toward what
tal European models of industrial relations is misleadingly termed ‘deregulation’ but in
(Hyman, 2004). In the former, the individual fact entails a shift in regulatory mechanisms
contract of employment is the primary point toward ‘market forces’ and the power asym-
of reference; restrictions on the contractual metries which these embody. ‘Flexibility’ has
liberty of employer and employee require become the watchword (Ramaux, 2006), but
special justification (or in extreme versions there has been substantial variation in the
of liberal ideology, cannot be justified at fervor with which this has been pursued,
all). In the latter, it is considered absurd the extent of the ‘rigidities’ addressed (in
to imagine that an individual employee can Europe, many changes have been limited to
bargain on equal terms with an employer the liberalization of temporary contracts and
who may well be a giant corporation; the of working time regimes), and in the extent to
state therefore has the right and indeed duty which governments have acted independently
to define standards which must be observed of the other industrial relations ‘actors’.
in all employment contracts, in order to In some countries, indeed – as discussed
prevent unequal bargaining power resulting below – modifications to existing legislative
in unreasonable conditions. (One interesting prescriptions have been negotiated with the
reflection of this clash of perspectives can ‘social partners’ and have been replaced,
be seen in the implementation of the EU not by individualization but by collective
Directive on working time. The UK was the bargaining.
only country to allow any individual employee
to ‘opt out’ of the 48-hour limit on weekly
Macroeconomic management:
working time. Elsewhere in Europe it was
structuring the labor market
recognized that the idea of a ‘voluntary’
agreement to unlimited hours of work was For much of the postwar period, at least in
fanciful.) Western Europe, a widely accepted function
In practice, all states define some individual of the state was in exercising macroeconomic
employment rights which limit the parameters management: in particular, using fiscal and
of individual contracts, but there is great monetary policy to raise aggregate demand in
variation in the scope of such regulation and – periods of recession and reduce it in periods
an issue less commonly researched – the rigor of ‘overheating’. This was consistent with
of its enforcement. In most countries, employ- the analysis of Keynes (1936), that the labor
ment law defines basic standards governing market was not a naturally self-equilibrating
all contracts: minimum wages, maximum and mechanism: in periods of demand deficiency,
‘abnormal’ hours, annual leave; individual there would be high unemployment, and
and collective dismissals; health and safety; reducing wages (as orthodox economic theory
equal opportunities; vocational and educa- recommended) would make matters worse.
tional leave; parental leave. As indicated The resulting policy prescriptions were that
above, in LMEs the impact of such regulation governments should be prepared to run budget
tends to be relatively limited (though note that deficits when unemployment was high, and
the US has some of the strongest legislation do the opposite when the economy was
on equal employment opportunities in the booming. This would be consistent with
world). Note also that there is considerable balanced budgets over the full economic
variation also within CMEs: whereas in some cycle. Such macroeconomic management
countries the law prescribes a wide range should be regarded as an ‘industrial relations’
of contractual terms, in others most such issue, in that ‘full’ employment (on a strict
issues are regulated by collective bargaining definition, probably impossible to achieve)
268 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and economic growth affect the balance of there have been efforts to construct a ‘neo-
power within the labor market, and also the Keynesianism’ which combines elements of
margins for negotiation within ‘free collective Keynes’ theories with those of classical
bargaining’. In addition, historical evidence economics which he attacked. Despite con-
shows that in most (though not all) coun- tinued pressure by many national trade union
tries, trade union membership tends to vary movements for the continuation or revival of
inversely with the level of unemployment. policies of demand management, government
Keynes wrote in an era of mass unem- willingness to make full employment the
ployment. In the postwar years when unem- primary target of macroeconomic policy
ployment was lower and there was a scarcity has largely evaporated; the new orthodoxy
of key skills, a dilemma emerged: economic involves a return to neoclassical assumptions
expansion, generally seen as desirable in that the labor market can and should regulate
itself, created inflationary pressures which itself; or else, more pessimistically, that there
in turn threatened the stability of national is nothing that governments can do to shape
currencies. In Britain, notoriously, this led to the overall health of the labor market.
‘stop-go’ economic policies: when inflation
increased, governments applied restrictive
From demand to supply: the pursuit
measures which created a rise in unem-
of ‘employability’
ployment and a brake on economic growth.
An alternative which proved effective in Demand management may be a necessary
some European countries with centralized but insufficient means to ‘full’ employment.
bargaining regimes was the adoption of Unless the supply and demand of different
formalized incomes policies, whereby unions types of competence are in balance, there
accepted the need for wage restraint in return are likely to be shortages of certain types
for government commitment to maintain of labor (or in specific parts of a country)
expansionary macroeconomic measures. while unemployment remains relatively high
In this context it is important to note among some occupational groups or regions.
the role of central banks: in an increasing Typically, ‘supply-side’intervention is seen as
number of countries, independent of national necessary to correct such imbalances.
governments but surely part of the state. These Management of supply and demand
are rarely recognized by industrial relations can reasonably be seen as complementary.
analysts as relevant ‘actors’ but can exert a A good example in practice can be seen
crucial role, as is increasingly argued (Iversen, in Sweden. The social-democratic finance
1999; Iversen et al., 2000). To take one minister Wigforss introduced ‘Keynesian’
notable instance, in Germany the Bundesbank policies in the 1930s (some say he invented
has traditionally oriented its interest rate Keynesianism before Keynes), but these were
policies to the level of wage settlements; and subsequently supplemented by ‘active labor
unions have known that if they pursued, and market policy’, targeted at the retraining
won, over-ambitious increases they would and relocation of those who were unem-
be punished by restrictive policies which ployed, in addition to specific job creation
would result in unemployment. Since the schemes. Much more generally, vocational
introduction of the euro, many regard the and educational training in many countries
European Central Bank as performing a is provided on a free or subsidized basis by
similar role. the state; alternatively or in addition, many
Since the 1970s, Keynesianism has been governments provide incentives to employers
widely discredited as the basis for public pol- to undertake in-house training. Such measures
icy, following the growing evidence that high obviously enhance a country’s skills base.
inflation and economic stagnation (‘stagfla- With the shift away from Keynesian
tion’) could coexist in a manner unpredicted policies, the principle of ‘activation’ has
by Keynes and his contemporaries – though grown in importance, but typically as a
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 269

substitute for demand management rather than considered an important part of industrial
a supplement. A clear example can be seen in relations. By contrast (as indicated in the
the European Employment Strategy launched introduction), mirroring the predominant ten-
by the EU a decade ago, where ‘employability’ dency in Anglo-Saxon industrial relations to
is a key policy theme. On the one hand this see politics as a separate sphere, so the welfare
can be seen as an attempt to capitalize on regime is typically disregarded, its study left
the opportunities of a ‘knowledge economy’ to specialists in social policy. This is in
by fostering the diffusion of new, up-market sharp contrast to most countries of continental
skills and qualifications. On the other, much Western Europe, where ‘the equivalent term
of the focus is on providing basic literacy, for “social policy” refers to both the welfare
numeracy and work discipline for those at state and industrial relations’ (Crouch, 1999:
risk of social exclusion. In this case, the 437), and both are the responsibility of
notion of ‘employability’ can easily be seen a single ministry and are studied by the
as shifting responsibility for their situation to same researchers. Here it is interesting to
the unemployed themselves (Hyman, 2005). note the French term rapport salarial, the
meaning of which cannot be captured by the
banal English ‘wage relationship’: typically
Industrial relations and
the concept encompasses skill formation,
the welfare state
wage determination, collective bargaining,
The ‘decommodification’ of labor which employment protection and labor market
was mentioned earlier – the institutional policies, and not least state welfare provision
protection of the labor force from total (Amable, 2003; Boyer, 1986).
dependence for survival on the discretion The welfare regime takes very different
of the employer – has two distinct dimen- forms in different countries, not only in
sions. One is constituted by the complex of terms of the balance between public and
employment legislation, already discussed. private provision (Arts and Gelissen, 2002;
Directly, laws which specify minimum wages Esping-Andersen, 1990), but also in the
or the length and organization of the working nature and extent of integration between
week and limit the circumstances in which a its governance and the industrial relations
worker can be dismissed, if actually enforced, ‘actors’. Outside Europe (and even in some
substantially limit the market dimension of European countries), state provision is often
the employment relationship. So, indirectly, extremely limited. In Japan, major firms
do laws which give trade unions or works often provide extensive welfare benefits. The
councils rights of joint regulation. The second US is also notable for the existence of
dimension involves institutional support for relatively generous provision by individual
workers who are sick or injured, unemployed, employers, often the outcome of collective
or past retirement age. Financial benefits in bargaining (Jacoby, 1998); but such benefits,
such circumstances, and services such as being company-based, have always been
health care, again provide a buffer against unevenly distributed, have recently been
the commodity status of labor. Those who are under widespread attack, and their coverage
aged or incapacitated may be able to withdraw has declined in parallel with trade union
from the labor market without major loss of membership. In much of the world, welfare
income; those who lose their job may not feel depends on individual resources or (more
obliged to take the first available alternative, commonly) on support from the extended
however unsuitable. family.
Some such protections may be derived Any significant system of ‘decommodifi-
from private insurance, or from collective cation’ strengthens the position of workers
agreements with employers, but universally both individually and collectively, facili-
they are provided to some degree by the tating the emergence and stability of col-
state. The ‘welfare state’ should therefore be lectivized industrial relations (Korpi and
270 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Esping-Andersen, 1984). For this very rea- achievement of the past two centuries as the
son, in some countries early trade unions rise, at national level, of universal citizenship.
(particularly of skilled workers) provided This process, he argued, occurred in three
their own ‘friendly benefits’ in order to stages. The first, largely accomplished in
shield members against the contingencies of the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries,
their working lives. In general this function involved the institutionalization of the civil
was displaced by the rise of the welfare basis of citizenship: ‘the rights necessary for
state, but as part of this process the trade individual freedom – liberty of the person,
unions in some countries (sometimes together freedom of speech, thought and faith, the
with employers) obtained a key role in the right to own property and to conclude valid
administration of public welfare (Ebbinghaus, contracts, and the right to justice’. The second,
2002; Streeck and Hassel, 2003). Where this is roughly 100 years later, saw the extension of
the case, their institutional position in society political citizenship through electoral reform:
is buttressed, and they may acquire a range of ‘the right to participate in the exercise of
subsidies from the state which enable them to political power’. The third, a project of the
maintain their activities even in the absence of twentieth century, was the creation of ‘social
significant membership – as is most strikingly citizenship’: the right to at least minimum
the case in France. In a small number of standards of ‘economic welfare and security’
European countries, the historical decision and hence to enjoy ‘the life of a civilized
to delegate to trade unions the running of being’ (1950: 10–11).
publicly subsidized unemployment insurance Though Marshall’s central theme was the
funds (the so-called ‘Ghent system’) has a gradual ‘civilization’ of capitalism, he largely
remarkably powerful effect in sustaining high neglected the role of the citizen as worker.
union density (Western, 1998). He noted that the success of trade unions in
In many countries, in recent years estab- establishing their right to exist, to bargain,
lished welfare systems have been under and if necessary to take industrial action,
challenge, as a result of demographic changes, transformed the geography of social relations,
constrained public finances and an ideological creating ‘a secondary system of industrial
shift toward liberalization and ‘activation’ citizenship, parallel with and supplementary
(Esping-Andersen, 2002). Where welfare has to the system of political citizenship’ (1950:
been an accepted part of the industrial 42–4). This was, however, not for Marshall,
relations agenda, this has imposed serious a central component of the rise of ‘social cit-
challenges to the stability of the whole izenship’, which he identified rather with the
industrial relations system. The implications rise of public education and the welfare state
are considered in more detail below. more generally; hence industrial relations
does not figure prominently in his discussion.
Yet does citizenship end at the workplace
The construction of ‘industrial
gates? Does the contract of employment
citizenship’
give the employer an unbounded right to
The most fundamental influence of the state is command, or does ‘industrial citizenship’
in defining the status of labor in the polity, the entail a right to employee voice, or, more
economy and society as a whole. Crucially, grandly, ‘industrial democracy’?
is democracy a principle which applies only Here, the distinction between LMEs and
in a narrowly bounded political sphere, or CMEs can be mapped against the familiar
is it of more general import? Over half a contrast between shareholder and stakeholder
century ago, in his lectures on Citizenship and capitalism (Albert, 1993; Dore, 2000; Hutton,
Social Class, Marshall (1950) explored the 1996). In the former, company law requires
evolution of institutions linking rights, status managers to give (virtually) exclusive priority
and responsibilities in modern (and more to the interests of shareholders; in the
specifically, British) society. He saw the key latter, management is required (or at least
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 271

permitted) to consider the interests of other Underlying this model is a ‘civil law’
‘stakeholders’, notably employees. Manda- tradition’ which privileges individual con-
tory systems of employee voice express tracts (van Waarden, 1995: 132), allied to a
the same stakeholder conception: the ‘social prevalent doctrine in the formative period of
order’ of the enterprise embodies the principle capitalist industrialization that the state should
of employee as citizen (Kotthoff, 1994). To not ‘interfere’ in economic life. (Laissez faire
present the contrast starkly, in certain legal means, literally, let people – and specifically,
regimes the influence of labor through the property-owners – do as they wish.) In fact
industrial relations system is a conditionally the notion of state non-intervention is absurd.
tolerated anomaly, a qualification to the Every state defines what counts as property
principle described in the US as ‘employment and what rights and responsibilities attach
at will’; whereas in others it is a natural to it; establishes what may and may not
expression of the status of the employee as be bought and sold; creates and underwrites
a member of the employing organization. In the currency; and adjudicates complaints
codifying one or other of these conflicting of breach of contract. In practice, laissez-
understandings of the employment relation- faire means the creation of a distinct set
ship, the state exerts its most profound and of biases: bestowing specific privileges on
pervasive influence in industrial relations. capital (notably the invention of the principle
of ‘limited liability’, freeing companies from
the risks and responsibilities applying to
STATE, ECONOMY AND INDUSTRIAL ordinary citizens) and then permitting an
RELATIONS: SOME STYLIZED MODELS imbalance of market power to operate with
little or no hindrance: this might be described
In the light of the preceding discussion, it is as ‘non-intervention in favor of capital’.
clear that there are almost infinitely possible This legal-ideological context has shaped
permutations of the ways in which the state, employment regulation along the lines
directly and indirectly, shapes the industrial which Kahn-Freund (1954) termed ‘col-
relations regime. In the earlier section on lective laissez-faire’. When trade unionism
cross-national diversity I noted that it is and collective bargaining received (partial)
common to seek to simplify complex reality protection from the common-law presumption
by applying three-part classifications of such of illegality,
regimes. In this section I undertake a similar
the easiest way to sanction the workers’ right to
exercise, in this case suggesting a somewhat collective action ... was to treat it as an extension of
different three-part typology. It should be property rights and a corollary of the free market.
stressed that these are ‘ideal types’ rather The workers were entitled to sell their labor, or
than empirical descriptors; actually existing not to sell it, to the highest bidder as they wished.
states involve some mix of the different And if they were entitled to act in this manner as
individuals, why not as a group, like other groups
elements. of property owners?’ (Rimlinger, 1977: 224).

Such a foundation for industrial relations


The laissez-faire state: embedding
regulation is in practice ‘internally contradic-
market individualism
tory’ (Klare, 1981: 454). The model of the
The notion of the laissez-faire state, as I use commercial contract implies that employment
it here, overlaps closely with the concept is a one-off transaction rather than a continu-
of LME and partially with the ‘English- ing relationship, implicitly underwriting man-
speaking’ world (only partially, because of agerial authority once a contract is reached
the very different trajectories of Australia and (Collins, 1986). The circumstances under
New Zealand, which until recently have had which employees can obtain the capacity
much in common with aspects of the other two to act collectively, and the boundaries of
models I discuss). legitimate collective action, remain uncertain
272 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and thus open to determination by far from laissez-faire state, the processes of industrial
neutral courts. And ‘collective laissez-faire’ relations will be unfavorable to labor.
offers no protection to those outside the
collective regulatory web. In reality, even in
LMEs the property rights approach has been The social state: the
supplemented by other forms of procedural
decommodification of labor
and substantive regulation, to an extent which
relations
makes the whole idea of ‘non-intervention’
fanciful (Howell, 2005). This approach also The idea of a free market is an oxymoron, a
makes protections obtained by labor vulnera- fortiori in the case of the ‘fictitious commod-
ble to shifts in the economic balance of power, ity’ (Polanyi, 1944) of labor. The employment
to judicial creativity or to relatively technical relationship is a social and political invention,
legislative changes: this is very apparent from and the rights and obligations of each party
experience in Britain, where in consequence, are necessarily defined by the state. As was
‘as the basis for a settlement between labour seen in the previous section, the state has
and capital, collective laissez-faire proved some role everywhere in the procedural and
to be precarious’ (Deakin and Wilkinson, substantive regulation of the employment
2004: 42). relationship, in structuring the labor market,
Since administrative action by government in modifying the dependence of employees
can radically alter the effective rules of on the employer, and hence in negotiating the
industrial relations (as, for example, through ambiguous interrelationship between the roles
changes in the membership and operational of citizen and of worker.
procedures of the US National Labor Nevertheless, it is in continental Western
Relations Board), unions may be able to Europe that these functions are typically
defend a pre-existing industrial relations ‘set- regarded as most developed. For this reason
tlement’ only through political mobilization. it is common to speak of a ‘European social
Here, though, an important obstacle is the model’. This notion is misleading but contains
phenomenon of ‘state capture’ – a concept an important element of truth. Western Europe
developed with reference to post-communist comprises some 20 separate countries, 15 of
Eastern Europe (Hellman et al., 2000) but which constituted the European Union (EU)
particularly apposite in the case of the US, before its 2004 enlargement, with distinctive
where only the ultra-rich can today expect to national traditions and institutional arrange-
attain top political office, where successful ments. Nevertheless certain features are com-
electoral campaigns depend on massive mon to most of these. In important respects,
corporate subsidies, and where trade unions’ it is accepted that ‘labor is not a commodity’.
‘political action funds’ are increasingly Both socialist and catholic traditions, which
dwarfed by those of companies (Masters and inform the dominant political parties, reject
Delaney, 2005), while the political agenda is the idea of work as primarily or exclusively
shaped by media moguls with little affection a market transaction. Collective agreements
for labor. ‘State power in the United States have priority over individual employment
is ... everywhere permeated by organized contracts, while centralized bargaining and in
societal interests’ (Skocpol, 1985: 12). To some countries legal extension mechanisms
an important degree, a similar tendency can result in high levels of coverage (even
be seen in Britain. (When Marx and Engels when union density is low). In most cases
wrote that ‘the authority of the modern state there is a standardized system of workplace
is just a committee which administers the representation at least partially independent
common affairs of the whole bourgeois class’, of management (underwritten by law or peak-
perhaps they were showing some prescience!) level agreement, or both). Most countries
The growing political power of employers possess an extensive, publicly funded welfare
virtually guarantees that in the contemporary system, and the ‘social partners’ often have a
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 273

key role in its administration. One may add with industrial capitalism; in most nations
that government frequently rests on coalition of Western Europe and North America their
politics, creating a bias toward compromise contours were set in the early twentieth
and an obstacle to radical institutional change. century or before, and consolidated half a
Yet despite overarching commonalities, century ago within the framework of ‘postwar
national distinctiveness – involving idiosyn- settlements’ when the political and economic
cratic ‘state traditions’ (Crouch, 1993) – influence of labor movements was often at
results in an evident ‘variable geometry’ its peak. But in countries which developed
(Ebbinghaus, 1999). It is common to distin- ‘modern’ economic systems more recently,
guish at least three groupings: the Nordic the evolution of industrial relations has
countries with an ‘inclusive strategy of followed different lines.
equality’ (Palme, 2001) and particularly The notion of the ‘developmental state’,
high levels of unionization; Mediterranean originally coined by Johnson (1982) with
countries with detailed state regulation of sub- reference to Japan, has since been applied
stantive employment conditions but relatively more generally to the ‘newly industrializing’
undeveloped welfare systems; and a ‘central’ countries of East Asia and beyond (Haggard,
or ‘Germanic’ group with extensive but less 1986; Öniş, 1991; Weiss, 2004). The logic of
egalitarian welfare systems and primarily pro- the concept is that while state and economy
cedural state regulation of industrial relations. are everywhere intertwined, ‘late’ indus-
A central question for much of the recent trialization within a world system already
literature is whether the ‘European social dominated by rich and hegemonic nations
model(s)’ can survive the challenges of a requires particularly overt and systematic
more integrated global economy, or whether state direction. The developmental state has
they will succumb to a kind of ‘Gresham’s typically involved an elite state bureaucracy
law’ (Crouch and Streeck, 1997) whereby with control over the financial system and
‘bad’ institutional arrangements drive out a symbiotic relationship with private capital,
‘good’. Many argue that while EU policy able to give priority to the accumulation func-
is supposedly informed by the values of the tion and to determine the strategic priorities
social model, and is intended to consolidate for growth. (One may note similarities with
it, in practice the liberal bias of economic postwar industrial development in southern
integration embodies many of the priorities European countries.)
of LMEs (Chapon and Euzéby, 2002; Hodge What are the implications for the evolution
and Howe, 1999; Hyman, 2001; Scharpf, of industrial relations? While Kerr et al.
2002; Wickham, 2002). EU enlargement in (1960) placed considerable emphasis on the
2004, encompassing countries from Central composition and ideology of national ‘indus-
and Eastern Europe with inferior employ- trializing elites’ in shaping the character of
ment conditions and without the institutional the labor force and the pattern of relationships
foundations for wide-ranging collective regu- with employers, analysis of the developmental
lation, is also seen as a threat of a downward state has tended to focus on political context
spiral of ‘deregulation’ (Dauderstädt, 2003; and antecedents, and different modes of
Vaughan-Whitehead, 2003). Such concerns industrialization. In many post-colonial states,
connect with the broader issue of the impact organized labor had played an important
of ‘globalization’ and will be addressed in the role in the struggle for independence and
last substantive section. could not easily be excluded from influence
in the polity and the workplace. In many
dictatorships and other authoritarian regimes,
The developmental state: the ideal
labor exclusion could form an inherent part
national capitalist?
of the suppression of potential opposition.
Industrial relations systems, in the conven- Another important political influence was the
tional sense of the term, evolved in parallel cold war: first in Japan, then in the later
274 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

East Asian industrializers, anti-communism (though one with continuing state direction),
helped legitimize an ethos of national unity ending the former security of employment (the
and opposition to militant trade unionism, ‘iron rice bowl’), accentuated the disruptive
contributing strongly to what Öniş (1991: force of economic transformation. China is
124) terms the developmental state’s ‘key also notable for the existence of a party-
role in the promotion of cooperative labor- controlled ‘transmission belt’ trade union,
management relations’. of a kind previously common to the whole
The literature on economic development soviet bloc. A major uncertainty is whether
makes a fundamental distinction between this may evolve in the direction of greater
‘import substitution’ and ‘export-oriented’ independence, leading to the emergence
industrialization (ISI and EOI). Kuruvilla of industrial relations at workplace level
(1995) explores some of the industrial rela- with affinities to experience elsewhere; for
tions implications. In ISI, high tariff walls example, Howell (2006) suggests that moves
enabled the domestic production of basic toward more democratic electoral processes
industrial goods. Notably in Latin America, at grassroots level have resulted in an uneven
this enabled authoritarian regimes to develop process of invigoration of some local union
domestic industry. In some cases (Argentina branches.
under Perón was the most obvious example), If the developmental state has been a
this was accompanied by a collaboration suitable framework for ‘late development’,
between the state and ‘corporatist’ trade what of the countries attempting to achieve
unions (Cook, 1998). EOI occurred in part ‘late late development’? In much of the
under external pressure for the reduction ‘Third World’ (most notably Africa) there
or removal of tariffs, and could occur in are problems of state-building, a weakness
two phases. The first, price-competitive, of civil society, extreme subjection to impe-
involved exploiting the comparative advan- rialist forms of external domination (today
tage of a low-wage regime, the suppression typically through the agency of multinational
of autonomous (or at least, militant) trade capital, though supported by the hegemonic
unionism, and in many cases the creation nation-states), tensions between ‘modern’ and
of ‘export processing’ or ‘free enterprise ‘traditional’ economic sectors. Is ‘industrial
zones’ with even fewer worker protections relations’ in any strong sense more than a
than the rest of the economy. A second stage, marginal phenomenon?
visible in only a few (notably East Asian) In any event, the scope for the relative
countries involved value-added EOI. This economic autarchy of the developmental
strategy has offered scope for the company- state is today constrained by the liberal-
level incorporation of labor, either through ization of the world economic system. The
company unionism on the Japanese model ‘Washington consensus’, initially helping
(joint commitment to productivity) or (more drive the shift from ISI to EOI strategies,
likely) non-union HRM (Frenkel and Peetz, has subsequently sought to eliminate the
1998). institutional arrangements which contributed
A distinctive model of developmental state to the success of EOI (Fernández Jilberto
can be seen in China. While many, perhaps and Riethof, 2002). The structural adjustment
most newly industrializing countries have program imposed by the World Bank have
authoritarian regimes, China is exceptional had disastrous effects in terms of worker
in its disregard for the niceties of political insecurity and impoverishment. Such trends
democracy, and for the ruthlessness with have however produced a reaction, notably
which accumulation has been pursued (the in Latin America but also for example in
concept of ‘oriental despotism’ which Marx Korea, with popular discontent provoking
used to characterize the ‘Asiatic mode of radical industrial and political protest. The
production’ is perhaps apposite). The rapid implications for industrial relations are as yet
shift from a command to a market economy unpredictable.
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 275

THE TRAJECTORIES OF ‘MODERN strength of labor enabled unions to move from


CAPITALISM’: THE RISE, DECLINE – the (conflictual) defense of workers’ interests
AND REVIVAL? – OF ‘CORPORATISM’ in the industrial arena to the (non-conflictual)
pursuit of their interests in the political arena.
Writing 40 years ago, Shonfield sought to This could facilitate high investment, hence
account for the superior economic perfor- economic growth, hence subsequent increases
mance of the ‘modern capitalism’ of many in both wages and social expenditure: a
continental European countries compared to virtuous circle. Such a trade-off was institu-
Britain or the USA. His explanation (1969: tionalized immediately after the war inAustria
66–7) centered on ‘the vastly increased and the Netherlands, but imitated elsewhere
influence of the public authorities on the in the 1960s and 1970s. A corollary of such
management of the economic system’. A com- schemes was that unions and employers’
bination of long-range planning and publicly associations achieved a privileged position
funded national welfare meant that ‘the in macro-policy formulation, which enhanced
violence of the market has been tamed’. their own organizational status and in turn
He also commented on the, at first sight, made it easier for them to enforce decisions
surprising fact ‘that full employment and on their constituents (particularly important
the enhanced bargaining power of wage- where unions agreed to wage restraint). As
earners have not resulted in the diversion Katzenstein (1985) noted, institutionalized
of resources away from investment’, and solutions to the ‘trilemma’ were particularly
attributed this to ‘the corporatist formula for necessary in the small, export-oriented states
managing the economy. The major interest which comprised much of Western Europe –
groups are brought together and encouraged and also easier to achieve because of the den-
to conclude a series of bargains about their sity of networks between state functionaries
future behaviour’ (1965: 5, 231). and representatives of labor and capital (for
The idea of corporatism became a popular the Swedish case see Svensson and Öberg,
theme of industrial relations analysis in the 2005).
following decade. In many European coun- Many academic analysts, following
tries, the ‘post-war settlement’ had resulted Shonfield, described such a relationship as
in a seeming contradiction (or as some ‘corporatist’. This was slightly awkward,
writers have called it, a ‘trilemma’) between since the term was previously used as a label
full employment, stable exchange rates and for Mussolini’s fascist regime in Italy; and as
price stability. If full employment created described in the previous section, the concept
the basis for strong trade unions, what was was also associated with authoritarian
to prevent them using this strength to shift regimes in Latin America. Hence some
the distribution of income between labor and writers preferred the terms ‘neo-corporatism’
capital and also to press the government to or ‘concertation’, others referred to ‘political
increase the proportion of national income exchange’ (Baglioni, 1987; Pizzorno, 1978;
devoted to social welfare? If successful, Regini, 1984). There were other problems
such pressure could result in inflation and/or with the theory of corporatism. For example,
devaluation, and perhaps capital flight. peak-level concertation on a rather similar
Yet as Shonfield intimated, this was not agenda was consolidated in Sweden in
the universal experience. In particular, in the the early 1950s and was widely seen as
countries of Western Europe where unions the basis for a long period of economic
were strongest there was commonly a trade- success; but the state was involved only
off in which they restrained their wage in the background, since both unions and
demands in return for government commit- employers were anxious to preserve their
ment to pursue an expansionary economic own autonomous decision-making role. Or
policy and to develop the welfare state. For to take what was for several decades another
Korpi and Shalev (1979), the organizational success story, (West) Germany: here too
276 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

the state was detached from the bargaining fiscal and monetary policy. Now unions were
process (a detachment strongly valued far weaker, capital was more cosmopolitan
as an expression of Tarifautonomie – and mobile, while financial liberalization
roughly equivalent to ‘free collective constrained governments’ economic policy
bargaining’); but in addition, the trade-off discretion (formally so, within the eurozone) –
between wage moderation and economic issues which are considered further in the
growth was achieved not through central section which follows. The new ‘pacts for
co-ordination but because the main trade employment and competitiveness’ (PECs)
unions were ‘encompassing’ (Olson, 1982) have been primarily designed to reduce, or
and could anticipate the macroeconomic at least stabilize, unit labor costs and to
consequences of their own bargaining reduce both corporate taxation and budget
activity. A further factor, as noted above, deficits (Fajertag and Pochet, 2000; Rhodes,
was that the Bundesbank pursued a rigorous 2001; Sisson et al., 1999). In the process,
anti-inflationary policy and unions were unions have been invited to maintain wage
aware that high wage settlements would moderation but at the same time to accept
lead to deflationary monetary policy and cutbacks in the welfare state and often also
unemployment. It could also be argued that some weakening of labor market regulation.
‘corporatist’ relationships between state The main rationale for such pacts has been
and economic actors were not necessarily that the outcome will be greater national eco-
the outcome of trade union strength, and nomic competitiveness and more attraction
could arise without union involvement; to capital to invest in the country, thereby
for example, the postwar Japanese model reducing unemployment. Governments, in
was sometimes described as ‘corporatism many cases lacking the electoral base to push
without labor’, and the same might be said of through unpopular policies unilaterally, have
‘developmental states’ more generally. been keen to ‘construct support coalitions’
By the 1980s, corporatist arrangements (Gourevitch, 1986: 239) as a means of blame
had come under increasing pressure and avoidance.
often unraveled. Corporatism had emerged In contrast to the positive-sum trade-offs
as a mechanism for encouraging economic of previous decades, if unions agree (and in
growth with positive-sum outcomes; now the some cases, notably in France and Germany,
economic situation was far less favorable, they have not) this has often been as a
with inflation and unemployment both least-worst option and without specific com-
rising in many countries. In some countries, pensation (except perhaps in bolstering their
trade unions were weakened by recession organizational status as ‘social partners’).
and no longer needed to be ‘bought off’ Hancké and Rhodes (2005) also suggest that
by government; in others, their capacity while unions possessed significant bargaining
to guarantee wage restraint had been power in the run-up to European monetary
undermined by rank-and-file revolts. In the union, since they might have mobilized
main, corporatism – both as practice and as nationally against the project, once the new
theory – fell out of fashion. monetary regime was a reality the scope to
Yet in the 1990s, peak-level concertation affect government policy largely disappeared.
again became widely practiced in Western However, national variations are important. In
Europe, though in a form very different particular, unions in many countries have been
from that of previous decades (Berger and able to ensure that ‘deregulation’ maintains a
Compston, 2002; Regini, 1997). The previous collective alternative to simple marketization.
agreements had been reached, as has been In Italy, for example, most relaxations of
seen, when unions appeared strong; in addi- former statutory regulation has followed
tion, employers were largely rooted in the peak-level agreements between unions and
national economy, and national governments employers, bolstering collective authority; in
had considerable autonomy in determining Belgium, ‘derogation’ from legislated rules
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 277

is possible only by collective agreement; The ‘strong globalization’ argument can


in the Netherlands, areas of public welfare be simply summarized. Recent decades have
have been delegated to sectoral collective seen, first, the liberalization of cross-national
bargaining (which, in contrast to the US trade through the reduction or removal of
model), ensures comprehensive coverage tariff barriers; second, the cross-national
(Trampusch, 2006). integration of production within multinational
Some parallels can be seen in the countries companies (MNCs); third, the removal, some-
of Central and Eastern Europe, in particular times forcible, of obstacles to cross-national
those which joined the EU in 2004. Here, investment and the more general liberalization
even more starkly than in the west, there of financial flows across borders, which in
have been painful processes of restructuring combination with advances in information
in the transition to a market economy, in technology and telecommunications render
many countries involving the collapse of transactions in shares and currencies contin-
employment security and a lack of adequate uous and instantaneous. The corollary, it is
welfare provision to cushion the blow. often argued, is that individual companies are
Transition has been widely associated with increasingly free – and given the pressures
attempts to introduce tripartite concertation, of competitiveness, are obliged – to escape
with strong encouragement from the EU. the regulatory force of national industrial
However, trade unions in most cases are weak relations systems and establish employment
and divided, organization among employers is regimes which suit their distinctive mar-
rudimentary, and governments often cling to ket strengths and weaknesses (Katz and
the authoritarian reflexes of the old regime, Darbishire, 2000; Kochan et al., 1997).
and tripartism has generally achieved very Concurrently, the increasingly autonomous
limited success. Ost (2000) has referred dynamic of financial flows destabilizes mate-
to ‘illusory corporatism’, a hollow facade rial economies and allows capital-holders to
designed to sideline protest. Other assess- ‘punish’ national regimes and governments
ments have however been somewhat less the policies of which fail to match the
dismissive; for example, Avdagic (2005: 47) criteria of rectitude embraced in financial
stresses nationally distinct paths: in Hungary, markets. Taken together, the cross-national
‘unstable bargaining with a rather low level of extension of production chains, product mar-
concessions for organized labor’; in Poland, kets, corporate structures and financial flows
‘labor cooptation with minimal concessions makes national boundaries and the nation-
to the unions’; but in the Czech Republic, state largely irrelevant. The only option for
‘pragmatic institutionalized bargaining’ of a the latter is to accommodate to the new
kind familiar in the west. international regime: fostering competitive-
ness by pursuing labor market flexibility;
reducing tax burdens by shifting from welfare
‘GLOBALIZATION’ AND STATE to ‘workfare’ (Handler, 2004; Jessop, 1999)
CAPACITY or ‘competitive solidarity’ (Streeck, 2001);
stimulating, or at least permitting, increased
My discussion until now has assumed the income inequality (Iversen and Wren, 1998);
(relative) autonomy of nation state. Is this and more generally reducing the role of
reasonable in an era of ‘globalization’, seen the state from ‘steering’ the economy to
by some as leading inevitably to ‘the retreat the piecemeal correction of discrete ‘market
of the state’ (Strange, 1996)? I have reviewed failures’ (Majone, 1994).
elsewhere the debate on the eclipse of the The thesis of the irresistible imperatives
nation state (Hyman, 1999, 2006), and this is of globalization is sometimes dismissed
a question which will be considered in greater as little more than ideology (Hirst and
detail in Chapter 34 of this volume. But it is Thompson, 1996). Other counter-arguments
necessary to address some of the issues here. stress unevenness (Carter, 2005; Mann, 1997),
278 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

contradiction and/or contingency, including of state capacity to shape industrial relations


political contingency (Hamann and Kelly, in nationally distinctive ways has occurred
2003; Kitschelt et al., 1999; Streeck, 1998). (Boyer, 1996; Boyer and Drache, 1996; Wade,
The corollary is that ‘deregulation’ is as much 1996).
a matter of political choice as of economic The very intensity of the ‘globalization’
necessity; even if ‘competitiveness’ is an debate suggests that what is occurring is
increasingly coercive objective, how it can multi-faceted and contradictory. Levy (2006)
be achieved is far from self-evident. The argues, indeed, that challenges to the tradi-
‘social’ or ‘developmental’ state may remain tional roles of the state offer new options
as successful as the ‘laissez faire’ alternative; for shaping the economy – and may indeed
if Gresham’s law really applied, there would require them.
be no point in international treaties mandating
liberalization. Although economic, technological, social, and ideo-
logical changes may produce demands for reduced
The elusive nature of the challenge of
state intervention, such forces also create opportu-
‘globalization’ helps explain the diversity of nities for new kinds of state intervention. There is a
national responses, which contradict the thesis Janus-faced or dual-edged quality to these forces;
of universal ‘Anglo-Saxonization’ of indus- they can push state intervention up as well as down.
trial relations. For example, Kwon (2004: 92), In other words, state activism can be renewed and
replenished, rather than simply eroded.
while identifying some common themes in
the reorganization of motor manufacturing Similarly, Weiss (1998: 5, 11) challenges the
in Germany and the US, found that the view that laissez faire is the only option: ‘state
trends ‘did not confirm the rejuvenation of capability has today become an important
market liberalism’; market relations remained advantage in international competition .... The
socially structured in nationally distinctive ability of nation-states to adapt to interna-
ways. In respect of the reconfiguration of tionalization (so-called ‘globalization’) will
‘social models’, Iversen and Pontusson (2000) continue to heighten rather than diminish
argue that if continental European systems are national differences in state capacity, as
converging, it is toward a ‘Germanic’ rather well as the advantages of national economic
than an American model. Crouch (1995) coordination’.
has insisted that while the forms of decom- A caveat is necessary however. First, some
modification may need to alter, it remains political choices may be virtually irreversible.
possible to preserve the principle: a thesis Some domestic restructuring – ‘freeing’ the
supported by Falkner and Tálos (1994) and central bank from government control, large-
Hemerijk and Schludi (2001). Along similar scale privatization of public enterprise – can
lines, Lane (1995: 195) points out that ‘despite only be undone with immense difficulty if at
much deregulationist activity in labour and all. Signing up to supranational treaties which
capital markets, re-regulation or alternative prohibit controls over investment or require
forms of state regulation have often occurred’, the marketization of public services irrevo-
adding that ‘new modes of response remain cably constrains the capacity for economic
strongly determined by pre-existing forms of steering (unless, like the US, one is large and
state organization’. Much of the analysis of powerful enough to disregard such rules with
Germany and Japan in Streeck and Yamamura impunity). As Ruggie (2003: 106, 116) puts it,
(2001) and Yamamura and Streeck (2003)
develops an analogous interpretation. This is the rights enjoyed by transnational corporations
consistent with Jacoby’s thesis (2004: 19) of have increased manyfold over the past two decades,
‘weak-path-dependence’, whereby countries as a result of multilateral trade agreements, bilateral
investment pacts and domestic liberalization ...
‘adapt to common environmental changes in
Globalization was a one-way bet for the business
a similar way’ but ‘fashion those adaptations community: governments were needed to create
to preexisting institutions’. It seems plausible the space within which business could expand and
to conclude that no systematic elimination integrate, but they were not otherwise welcome.
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 279

Second, the bias of global market forces and REFERENCES


the sheer power of the new agglomerations
of international capital entail some choices Adams, R (1993) ‘Regulating Unions and Collective Bar-
possible only through an uphill struggle, gaining: A Global, Historical Analysis of Determinants
and almost certainly require the very strong and Consequences’, Comparative Labor Law Journal
counter-force of broad public and labor 14 (3): 272–301.
movement mobilization. Albert, M. (1993) Capitalism against Capitalism.
London: Whurr.
Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism.
CONCLUSION Oxford: OUP.
Aoki, M. (2001) Information, Corporate Governance,
and Institutional Diversity: Competitiveness in Japan,
Can we have a general theory of the state the USA, and the Transitional Economies. Oxford:
in industrial relations? Probably not, if only, OUP.
because there does not exist a general theory Arts, W. and Gelissen, J. (2002) ‘Three Worlds of Welfare
of the state or of industrial relations. The Capitalism or More?’, Journal of European Social
best we can expect to do is to provide Policy 12 (2): 137–158.
accurate maps of diversity, seek explanations Avdagic, S. (2005) ‘State-Labour Relations in East
for recurrent patterns and present plausible Central Europe’, Socio-Economic Review 3 (1):
accounts of causal dynamics. 25–53.
Three broad points can, however, be Baglioni, G. (1987) ‘Constants and Variants in Political
asserted. First, in the words of Bordogna and Exchange’, Labour 1 (3): 57–91.
Berger, S. and Compston, H. (eds) (2002) Policy
Cella (1999: 28), ‘all models of industrial
Concertation and Social Partnership in Europe.
relations, and not just the more “statist” ones, New York: Berghahn.
have been characterized throughout their Bordogna, L. and Cella, G.P. (1999) ‘Admission,
history by complex and sometimes difficult Exclusion, Correction: The Changing Role of the
relationships with the state’. State in Industrial Relations’, Transfer 5 (1–2):
Second, modern states are all embedded, 14–33.
nationally and internationally, within the Boyer, R. (1986) La théorie de la régulation: une analyse
economic dynamics of capitalism (Jessop, critique. Paris: la Découverte.
2002; Kelly, 1998). This does not mean Boyer, R. (1996) ‘The Convergence Hypothesis Revisited:
that all governmental action is economically Globalization but Still the Century of Nations?’,
determined (not least because the electoral in S. Berger and R. Dore (eds), National Diver-
sity and Global Capitalism, Ithaca: Cornell UP.
cycle is shorter than the business cycle),
pp. 29–59.
but the overarching influence of a capitalist Boyer, R. and Drache, D. (1996) ‘Introduction’, in
logic cannot be ignored. ‘Industrial battles R. Boyer and D. Drache (eds), States Against Markets:
are fought on the bourse floor as well as The Limits of Globalization, London: Routledge.
the foundry floor: industrial relations as pp. 1–27.
an academic study is trivialized if such Carter, B. (2005) ‘The Restructuring of National States in
connections are not emphasized’ (Guille, the Global Economy’ in P. Fairbrother and A. Rainnie
1984: 492). This is even truer in an era when (eds), Globalization, State and Labour, London:
the bourse is global and electronic (though Routledge. pp. 136–150.
when foundries have almost disappeared, at Chapon, S. and Euzéby, C. (2002) ‘Towards a Con-
least in the old industrial economies). vergence of European Social Models?’, International
Social Security Review 55 (2): 37–56.
Third, universally there are continuing
Coates, D. (2000) Models of Capitalism: Growth and
tensions which underlie the priorities of Stagnation in the Modern Era. Cambridge: Polity.
state action: there is always a trade-off Collins, H. (1986) ‘Market Power, Bureaucratic Power
between accumulation, pacification and legit- and the Contract of Employment’, Industrial Law
imation (or to use a different vocabulary, Journal 15 (1): 1–13.
efficiency, equity and stability) and never Cook, M.L. (1998) ‘Toward a Flexible Industrial
‘one best way’. Relations? Neo-Liberalism, Democracy and Labor
280 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Reform in Latin America’, Industrial Relations 37 (3): Neo-liberal Reforms’ in A.E. Fernández Jilberto and
311–36. M. Riethof (eds), Labour Relations in Development,
Crouch, C. (1993) Industrial Relations and European London: Routledge. pp. 1–25.
State Traditions. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Frenkel, S. and Peetz, D. (1998) ‘Globalization and
Crouch, C. (1995) ‘Exit or Voice: Two Paradigms for Industrial Relations in East Asia’, Industrial Relations
European Industrial Relations after the Keynesian 37 (3): 282–310.
Welfare State’, European Journal of Industrial Friedman, M. (1962) Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago:
Relations 1 (1): 63–81. Chicago UP.
Crouch, C. (1999) ‘Employment, Industrial Relations and Fusfeld, D. (1979) The Rise and Repression of Radical
Social Policy: New Life in an Old Connection’, Social Labor, 1877–1918. Chicago: Kerr.
Policy and Administration 33 (4): 437–57. Gamble, A. (1988) The Free Economy and the Strong
Crouch, C. (2005) Capitalist Diversity and Change: State. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Recombinant Governance and Institutional Giles, A. (1988) ‘Industrial Relations Theory, the State
Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford UP. and Politics’ in J. Barbash and K. Barbash (eds),
Crouch, C. and Streeck, W. (1997) ‘Introduction: The Theories and Concepts in Comparative Industrial
Future of Capitalist Diversity’, in C. Crouch and Relations, Columbia: University of South Carolina
W. Streeck (eds), The Political Economy of Modern Press. pp. 123–53.
Capitalism: Mapping Convergence and Diversity, Gourevitch, P. (1986) Politics in Hard Times. Ithaca:
London: Sage. pp. 1–18. Cornell UP.
Dauderstädt, M. (2003) ‘EU Eastern Enlargement: Guille, H. (1984) ‘Industrial Relations Theory: Painting
Extension or End of the European Social Model?’ in By Numbers?’, Journal of Industrial Relations 26 (4):
R. Hoffmann, O. Jacobi, B. Keller and M. Weiss (eds), 484–95.
European Integration ans a Social Experiemnt in a Haggard, S. (1986) ‘The Newly Industrializing Countries
Globalized World, Düsseldorf: Hans-Böckler-Stiftung. in the International System’, World Politics 38 (2):
pp. 69–95. 343–70.
Deakin, S. and Wilkinson, F. (2004) ‘The Evolution Hall, P.A. (1986) Governing the Economy. Oxford:
of Collective Laissez-Faire’, Historical Studies in Oxford UP.
Industrial Relations 17: 1–43. Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (eds) (2001) Varieties
Dore, R. (2000) Stock-Market Capitalism, Welfare of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of
Capitalism: Japan and Germany Versus the Anglo- Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford UP.
Saxons. Oxford: Oxford UP. Hamann, K. and Kelly, J. (2003) ‘The Domestic Sources of
Dunlop, J.T (1958) Industrial Relations Systems. Differences in Labour Market Policies’, British Journal
New York: Holt. of Industrial Relations 41 (4): 639–63.
Ebbinghaus B. (1999) ‘Does a European Social Model Hancké, R. and Rhodes, M. (2005) ‘EMU and Labor
Exist and Can It Survive?’ in G. Huemer, M. Mesch Market Institutions in Europe’, Work and Occupations
and F. Traxler (eds), The Role of Employer Associations 32 (2): 196–228.
and Labour Unions in the EMU, Aldershot: Ashgate. Handler, J.F (2004) Social Citizenship and Workfare in
pp. 1–26. the United States and Western Europe: The Paradox
Ebbinghaus B. (2002) Varieties of Social Governance: of Inclusion. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.
Comparing the Social Partners’ Involvement in Pen- Hayek, F.A. (1960) The Constitution of Liberty.
sion and Employment Policies. Max-Planck-Institut Chicago UP.
Working Paper. http://www.mpi-fg-koeln.mpg.de/ Held, D. (1983) ‘Introduction: Central Perspectives on
people/es/papers/Ebbinghaus_SocGov_2002.pdf the Modern State’ in D. Held (ed.), States and
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Societies, Oxford: Blackwell. pp. 1–55
Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. Hellman, J. Jones, G., Kaufmann, D. and Schankerman,
Esping-Andersen, G. (2002) Why We Need a New M. (2000) Measuring Governance, Corruption, and
Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford UP. State Capture: How Firms and Bureaucrats Shape the
Fajertag, G. and Pochet, P. (eds) (2000) Social Pacts in Business Environment in Transition Economies. World
Europe: New Dynamics. Brussels: OSE/ETUI. Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2312, April.
Falkner, G. and Tálos, E. (1994) ‘The Role of the State Hemerijck, A. and Schludi, M. (2001) ‘Welfare
within Social Policy’, West European Politics 17 (3): Adjustment in Europe: The Transformation of the
52–76. European Social Model?’, in L. Magnusson and
Fernández Jilberto, A.E. and Riethof, M. (2002) J. Ottosson (eds), Europe: One Labour Market?,
‘Labour Relations in the Era of Globalization and Brussels: PIE - Peter Lang. pp. 21–105.
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 281

Hibbs, D.A. (1978) ‘On the Political Economy of Long- Market Economies, Cambridge: Cambridge UP. pp.
Run Trends in Strike Activity’, British Journal of 1–37.
Political Science 8 (2): 153–75. Iversen, T. and Wren, A. (1998) ‘Equality, Employment
Hirst, P. and Thompson, G. (1996) Globalization and Budgetary Restraint: The Trilemma of the Service
in Question: The International Economy and the Economy’, World Politics, 50 (4): 507–546.
Possibilities of Governance. Cambridge: Polity. Jacoby, S.M. (1998) Modern Manors: Welfare Capitalism
Hodge, S. and Howe, J. (1999) ‘Can the European since the New Deal. Princeton: Princeton UP.
Social Model Survive?’, European Urban and Regional Jacoby, S.M. (2004) The Embedded Corporation:
Studies 6 (2): 178–84. Corporate Governance and Employment Relations in
Hollingsworth, J. R. and Boyer, R. (1997) ‘Coordination Japan and the United States. Princeton: Princeton UP.
of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production’, Jessop, B. (1982) The Capitalist State. Oxford: Martin
in J. R. Hollingsworth and R. Boyer (eds), Contempo- Robertson.
rary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions, Jessop, B. (1990) State Theory. Cambridge: Polity.
Cambridge: Cambridge UP. pp. 1–47. Jessop, B. (1999) ‘The Changing Governance of
Howell, C. (2005) Trade Unions and the State: The Welfare’, Social Policy and Administration 33 (4):
Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in 348–59.
Britain, 1890–2000. Princeton: Princeton UP. Jessop, B. (2002) The Future of the Capitalist State.
Howell, J. (2006) New Democratic Trends in China: Cambridge: Polity.
Reforming the All-China Federation of Trade Unions. Johnson, C. (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle:
IDS Working Paper 263. Brighton: IDS. The Growth of Industry Policy 1925–1975. Stanford:
Hutton, W. (1996) The State We’re in: Why Britain Stanford UP.
Is in Crisis and How to Overcome It. London: Kahn-Freund, O. (1954) ‘Legal Framework’ in A. Flan-
Vintage. ders and H.A. Clegg (eds), The System of Industrial
Hyman, R. (1999) ‘National Industrial Relations Systems Relations in Great Britain, Oxford: Blackwell.
and Transnational Challenges’, European Journal of pp. 42–127.
Industrial Relations 5 (1): 89–110. Katz, H. and Darbishire, O. (2000) Converging
Hyman, R. (2001) ‘The Europeanisation – or the Divergences: Worldwide Changes in Employment
Erosion – of Industrial Relations?’, Industrial Relations Systems. Ithaca: ILR Press.
Journal 32 (4): 280–94. Katzenstein, P.J. (1985) Small States in World Markets.
Hyman, R. (2004) ‘Is Industrial Relations Theory Always Ithaca: Cornell UP.
Ethnocentric?’ in B.E Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical Per- Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi-
spectives on Work and the Employment Relationship, lization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London:
Madison: IRRA. pp. 265–92. Routledge.
Hyman, R. (2005) ’Trade Unions and the Politics Kerr, C., Dunlop, J.T., Harbison, F.H. and Myers, C.
of European Integration’, Economic and Industrial (1960) Industrialism and Industrial Man. Cambridge:
Democracy 26 (1): 9–40. Harvard UP.
Hyman, R. (2006) ‘Structuring the Transnational Space: Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment,
Can Europe Resist Multinational Capital?’ in A. Ferner Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.
and J. Quintanilla, (eds), Multinationals, Institutions Kitschelt, H., Lange, P., Marks, G. and Stephens, J. D.
and the Construction of Transnational Practices, (eds) (1999) Continuity and Change in Contemporary
London: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 239–54. Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Iversen, T. (1999) Contested Economic Institutions. Klare, K. E. (1981) ‘Labor Law as Ideology: Toward a
Cambridge: Cambridge UP. New Historiography of Collective Bargaining Law’,
Iversen, T. (2005) Capitalism, Democracy and Welfare. Industrial Relations Law Journal 4 (3): 450–82.
Cambridge: Cambridge UP. Kochan, T. (1980) Collective Bargaining and Industrial
Iversen, T., Pontusson, J. and Soskice, D. (eds) Relations. Homewood: Irwin-Dorsey.
(2000) Unions, Employers and Central Banks: Wage Kochan, T. A., Lansbury, R. D. and MacDuffie, J. P. (eds)
Bargaining and Macroeconomic Regimes in an (1997) After Lean Production: Evolving Employment
Integrating Europe. Cambridge: CUP. Practices in the World Auto Industry. Ithaca:
Iversen, T. and Pontusson, J. (2000) ‘Comparative Cornell UP.
Political Economy: A Northern European Perspective’, Korpi, W. and Esping-Andersen, G. (1984) ‘Social Policy
in T. Iversen, J. Pontusson and D. Soskice (eds), as Class Politics in Post-War Capitalism’ in J.H.
Unions, Employers, and Central Banks: Macroeco- Goldthorpe (ed.) Order and Conflict in Contemporary
nomic Coordination and Institutional Change in Social Capitalism, Oxford: Clarendon. pp. 179–208.
282 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Korpi, W. and Shalev, M. (1979) ‘Strikes, Industrial Peck, J. (1996) Work -Place: The Social Regulation of
Relations, and Class Conflict in Industrial Societies’, Labor Markets. New York: Guilford.
British Journal of Sociology 30 (2): 164–87. Pizzorno, A, (1978) ‘Political Exchange and Collective
Kotthoff, H. (1994), Betriebsräte und Bürgerstatus: Wan- Identity’ in C. Crouch and A. Pizzorno (eds), The
del und Kontinuität betrieblicher Mitbestimmung. Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western Europe Since
Munich and Mering: Rainer Hampp. 1968. London: Macmillan.
Kuruvilla, S. (1995) ‘Economic Development Strategies, Polanyi, K. (1944) The Great Transformation: The
Industrial Relations Policies and Workplace IR/HR Political and Economic Origins of our Times.
Practices in Southeast Asia’ in K. Wever and L. Turner New York: Farrar and Rinehart.
(eds), The Comparative Political Economy of Industrial Poulantzas, N. (1968) Political Power and Social Classes.
Relations, Madison: IRRA. pp. 115–50. London: NLB.
Kwon, H.-K. (2004) ‘Markets, Institutions and Politics Ramaux, C. (2006) Emploi, éloge de la stabilité: L’État
under Globalization’, Comparative Political Studies social contre la flexicurité. Paris: Mille et une nuits.
37 (1): 88–113. Regini, M. (1984) ‘The Conditions for Political
Lane, C. (1995) Industry and Society in Europe: Exchange’ in J.H. Goldthorpe (ed.), Order and Conflict
Stability and Change in Britain, Germany and France. in Contemporary Capitalism, Oxford: Clarendon.
Aldershot: Edward Elgar. pp. 124–42.
Levy, J.D. (2006) ‘Introduction: The State also Rises’ Regini, M. (1986) ‘Political Bargaining in Western
in J.D. Levy (ed.), The State after Statism: New Europe during the Economic Crisis of the 1980s’ in O.
State Activities among the Affluent Democracies. Jacobi, B. Jessop, H. Kastendiek and M. Regini (eds),
Cambridge: Harvard UP. Economic Crisis, Trade Unions and the State, London:
Lindblom, C.E. (1977) Politics and Markets. New York: Croom Helm. pp. 61–76.
Basic Books. Regini, M. (1997) ‘Still Engaging in Corporatism? Recent
Majone, G. (1994) ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State in Italian Experience in Comparative Perspective’,
Europe’, West European Politics 17 (3): 77–101. European Journal of Industrial Relations 3 (3):
Mann, M. (1986) ‘The Autonomous Power of the State’ 259–78.
in J.A. Hall (ed.), States in History, Oxford: Blackwell. Rhodes, M. (2001) ‘The Political Economy of Social
pp. 109–36. Pacts: “Competitive Corporatism” and European
Mann, M. (1997) ‘Has Globalization Ended the Rise and Welfare Reform’ in P. Pierson (ed.), The New Politics
Rise of the Nation-State?’, Review of International of the Welfare State, Oxford: OUP. pp. 165–94.
Political Economy 4 (3): 472–96. Rimlinger, G.V. (1977) ‘Labor and the Government:
Marsden D. W. (1999), A Theory of Employment A Comparative Historical Perspective’, Journal of
Systems: Micro-foundations of Societal Diversity. Economic History 37 (1): 210–25.
Oxford: Oxford UP. Ruggie, J.G. (1982) ‘International Regimes, Transac-
Marshall, T. H. (1950) Citizenship and Social Class. tions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the
Cambridge: Cambridge UP. Postwar Economic Order’, International Organization
Masters, M.F. and Delaney, J.T. (2005) ‘Organized 36 (2): 379–415.
Labor’s Political Scorecard’, Journal of Labor Research Ruggie, J. G. (2003) ‘Taking Embedded Liberalism
26 (3): 365–92. Global: The Corporate Connection’, in D. Held
Miguélez, F. and Prieto, C. (eds), (1991) Las relaciones and M. Koenig-Archibugi (eds), Taming Globaliza-
laborales en España, Madrid: Siglo XXI. tion: Frontiers of Governance. Cambridge: Polity.
Offe, C. (1984) Contradictions of the Welfare State. pp. 93–129.
London: Hutchinson. Scharpf, F.W. (2002) ‘The European Social Model:
Olson, M. (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Coping with the Challenges of Diversity’, Journal of
Haven: Yale UP. Common Market Studies 40 (4): 645–70.
Öniş, Z. (1991) ‘The Logic of the Developmental State’, Shonfield, A. (1965) Modern Capitalism: The Changing.
Comparative Politics 24 (1): 109–26. Balance of Public and Private Power. Oxford:
Ost, D. (2000) ‘Illusory Corporatism in Eastern Europe: OUP.
Neoliberal Tripartism and. Postcommunist Class Sisson, K., Freyssinet, J., Krieger, H., O’Kelly, K., Schn-
Identities’, Politics and Society 28 (4): 503–30. abel, C. and Seifert, H. (1999) Pacts for Employment
Palme, J. (2001) ‘Will Social Europe Work?’ in and Competitiveness http://www.eurofound.eu.int/
M. Kohli and M. Novak (eds), Will Europe Work? publications/files/EF9960EN.pdf
Integration, Employment and the Social Order, Skocpol, T. (1979) States and Social Revolutions.
London: Routledge. pp. 35–51. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.
THE STATE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 283

Skocpol, T. (1985) ‘Bringing the State Back in: the Transition of the Swedish Model, Stockholm:
Current Research’ in P.B. Evans, D. Rueschmeyer Arbetslivsinstitutet. pp. 127–59.
and T. Skocpol (eds) Bringing the State Back in, Trampusch, C. (2006) ‘Industrial Relations and Welfare
Cambridge: Cambridge UP. pp. 3–37. States: The Different Dynamics of Retrenchment in
Standing, G. (1997) ‘Globalization, Labour Flexibility and the Netherlands and Germany’, Journal of European
Insecurity’, European Journal of Industrial Relations Social Policy 16 (2): 121–33.
3 (1): 7–37. Traxler, F. and Behrens, M. (2002) Collective
Strange, S. (1996) The Retreat of the State: The Bargaining Coverage and Extension Procedures,
Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge: http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2002/12/study/
Cambridge UP. tn0212102s.html
Stråth, B. (1996) The Organization of Labour Markets. van Waarden, F. (1995) ‘Government Intervention
London: Routledge. in Industrial Relations’ in J. Van Ruysseveldt,
Streeck, W. (1987) ‘The Uncertainties of Management in R. Huiskamp and J. van Hoof (eds), Comparative
the Management of Uncertainty’, Work, Employment Industrial and Employment Relations, London: Sage.
and Society 1 (3): 281–308. pp. 109–33.
Streeck, W. (1997) ‘German Capitalism: Does it Exist? Wade, R. (1996) ‘Globalization and Its Limits: Reports
Can it Survive?’ in C. Crouch and W. Streeck (eds), The of the Death of the National Economy Are Greatly
Political Economy of Modern Capitalism: Mapping Exaggerated’, in S. Berger and R. Dore (eds), National
Convergence and Diversity, London: Sage. pp. 33–54. Diversity and Global Capitalism, Ithaca: Cornell UP.
Streeck, W. (1998) ‘Public Power Beyond the Nation- pp. 60–88.
State’, in R. Boyer and D. Drache (eds), States Vaughan-Whitehead, D. (2003) EU Enlargement Versus
Against Markets: The Limits of Globalization, London: Social Europe?: The Uncertain Future of the European
Routledge. pp. 299–315. Social Model. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Streeck, W. (2001) ‘International Competition, Suprana- Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1894) History of Trade
tional Integration, National Solidarity: The Emerging Unionism. London: Longmans.
Constitution of “Social Europe”’ in M. Kohli Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1897) Industrial Democracy.
and M. Novak (eds), Will Europe Work? Integra- London: Longmans.
tion, Employment and the Social Order, London: Weiss, L. (1998) The Myth of the Powerless State. Ithaca:
Routledge. pp. 21–34. Cornell UP.
Streeck, W. and Hassel, A. (2003) ‘Trade Unions as Western, B. (1998) Between Class and Market: Postwar
Political Actors’ in J.T. Addison and C. Schnabel Unionization in the Capitalist Democracies. Princeton:
(eds), International Handbook of Trade Unions, Princeton UP.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 335–65. Wickham, J. (2002) The End of the European Social
Streeck, W. and Yamamura, K., (eds) (2001) The Origins Model: Before it Began? Dublin: ICTU.
of Nonliberal Capitalism: Germany and Japan in Wilensky, H.L. (2002) Rich Democracies: Political
Comparison. Ithaca: Cornell UP. Economy, Public Policy and Performance. Berkeley:
Sturmthal, A. (1973) ‘Industrial Relations Strategies’ in University of California Press.
A. Sturmthal and J. Scoville (eds), The International Yamamura, K. and Streeck, W. (eds) (2003) The End
Labor Movement in Transition, Urbana: University of of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese
Illinois Press. pp. 1–33. Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell UP.
Svensson, T. and Öberg, P.O. (2005) ‘Power and Trust: Zeitlin, J. (1985) ‘Shop Floor Bargaining and the State:
The Mechanisms of Cooperation’ in P.O. Öberg and A Contradictory Relationship’ in S. Tolliday and
T. Svensson (eds), Power and Institutions in Industrial J. Zeitlin (eds) Shop Floor Bargaining and the State,
Relation Regimes: Political Science Perspectives on Cambridge: CUP. p. 145.
15
The Legal Framework of
Employment Relations
Simon Deakin and Wanjiru Njoya

INTRODUCTION scientists are, in turn, devoting increased


resources to exploring the impact of legal
The field of labor law grew up alongside and related regulatory changes on the issues
that of industrial relations and they have which concern them, which include organi-
generally been closely aligned. Industrial or zational performance, labor market outcomes
‘employment relations’ research has had a in terms of indicators such as unemployment,
major, perhaps even predominant influence, poverty and inequality, national economic
in shaping labor law scholarship. In the first competitiveness, and cross-national diversity.
half of the twentieth century, legal scholars To speak of alignment or engagement
and practicing lawyers in Europe and North between labor law and the social sciences
America looked to industrial sociology to is not to assume that the process is without
provide them with concepts and data which difficulties. In the immediate post-war years,
could be used to challenge the pre-existing ‘industrial pluralism’ provided a theoretical
legal order, which they saw as restrictive and framework that united the various aspects
outdated. This is the approach associated, of what became known in the Anglophone
most notably, with ‘legal realism’ in the world as ‘industrial relations’. Labor law was
US and the work of the ‘social jurists’ in part of that field, its place acknowledged,
Weimar Germany. Labor law continues to for example, by Kahn-Freund’s chapter in
reflect these origins and, as a legal sub- the first (1954) edition of The System of
discipline, is uniquely open to the influence Industrial Relations in Britain, which was
of the social sciences. Today labor lawyers entitled ‘Legal Framework’. This contained
are taking on the task of engaging not the influential observation that ‘there is, per-
just with the broad sociological tradition haps, no major country in the world in which
as it relates to employment relations, but the law has played a less significant role in
with political science, gender theory, social the shaping of [collective labor relations] than
psychology, and, above all, economics. Social in Great Britain’ (Kahn-Freund, 1954: 47).
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 285

Kahn-Freund’s belief in the peripheral role of regulatory techniques, has to accommodate a


law was not, however, confined to his analysis greater range of objectives, at the same time
of the British case; in his 1972 Hamlyn that its use as an instrument of social and eco-
lectures, Labour and the Law, in the context of nomic policy is contradicting the ‘pluralist’
a broad comparative synthesis, he continued methodological precepts around which many
to insist that law was a ‘secondary force of those techniques were initially developed.
in human affairs, and especially in labour Under these circumstances it is no surprise
relations’ (Kahn-Freund, 1977: 2). This can that labor lawyers regularly talk about the
be read, at one level, as a methodological ‘crisis’ of their discipline and seek to develop
point: a reminder that there are limits to how new conceptual frameworks for use in legal
far the law can be used in an instrumental discourse. One option, increasingly gaining
way to shape social and economic outcomes. ground, is to widen the scope of the subject
But it was also, implicitly, a reaffirmation of so that it in effect becomes ‘the law of
a particular version of the pluralist position, the labor market’, encompassing the variety
namely the idea that industrial relations of mechanisms currently being used, in a
systems rested on an autonomous or ‘extra- legal context, to regulate labor supply and
legal’ arrangement of social forces. The law, demand. At one level this involves greater
and the state more generally, could support attention being paid to the links between
that arrangement of forces in various ways, labor law and other fields of regulation
as it did when it intervened to maintain such as social security law, company law,
or extend collective bargaining (‘auxiliary’ taxation and active labor market policy.
legislation), or to set wages and terms of More fundamentally, those who take this
employment in areas of the economy where view argue that ‘a broader focus on “labour
collective agreements were weak or non- market regulation” has a stronger chance of
existent (‘regulatory’ legislation), but it could holding the subject together than the existing
not fundamentally alter it. framework’ (Mitchell and Arup, 2006: 16).
That view, as we now know, did not long This is not just about redrawing boundaries,
survive the ending of the policy consensus but moving away from
around support for collective bargaining
a traditional labor law subject [which] is still largely
which occurred in most systems, in varying organized around legal categories (the contract of
forms, in the course of the 1980s and 1990s. employment, the law pertaining to bargaining and
Yet labor law has ‘fragmented’ as a field not conciliation and arbitration, the law on trade unions
simply because the state no longer supports and industrial action, health and safety law and so
collective bargaining as the principal or pre- on), and applies mainly to legal reasoning and to
generally legal materials,
ferred mechanism for regulating employment
to the same degree that it did, but also to one in which ‘our inquiry will inevitably
because many additional interests to those be directed to key issues in regulatory
of ‘subordinated’ or dependent labor are scholarship – the constitutive role of regu-
taken into account in the framing of labor lation, types of regulatory norms, regulatory
legislation (Collins, 1997). The expansion of techniques, regulatory institutions, and their
anti-discrimination legislation and the related effectiveness, responsiveness and coherence’.
orientation of labor law toward human rights This necessitates a greater recognition of
discourses offer one illustration (Fredman, ‘the importance of interdisciplinary studies
1997); another is provided by attempts in understanding the need for particular
to use law as a mechanism for ensuring legal modifications in labor markets, and
economic ‘competitiveness’ (Collins, 2001, understanding the evolution of labor law’
2002, 2003), raising employment levels (Arup and Mitchell, 2006: 17–18).
(Ashiagbor, 2005) and bringing about a ‘more In one sense this simply takes us back to
flexible labor market’ (Davies and Freedland, the origins of labor law which was, after all,
2007). Labor law, understood as a set of founded in a similar spirit of interdisciplinary
286 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

openness (Finkin, 2006). However, opening to social scientists. We will not attempt to
up legal discourse and analysis to outside review the vast empirical literature, mostly
influence was only part of the process which consisting of work by social scientists, which
took place in the first decades of the twentieth examines aspects of the operation of legal
century; the refashioning of legal concepts in rules in practice. This is, indeed a huge
the light of what were then seen as new social field. The study of the way legal rules work
policy goals was also important, and this, in practice has a very long tradition in
paradoxically perhaps, focused attention back industrial relations scholarship, which, if we
on to those very doctrinal structures which just consider the British context, can be traced
formed the core of ‘formalist’ legal analysis. right back to the pioneering work of the
Kahn-Freund famously enjoined labor Webbs and their contemporaries on the poor
lawyers to follow the example of Sinzheimer law (Webb and Webb, 1910; 1927a; 1927b),
in going ‘through’ not ‘round’ the law, by factory legislation (Hutchins and Harrison,
which he meant that legal studies should not 1911), and the first minimum wage laws
seek to abandon conceptual exposition as one (Tawney, 1914; 1915). After a mid-century
of its core tasks (Kahn-Freund: 1981: 77). It lull during the period of collective laissez-
is indeed difficult to see how labor law could faire, increasing statutory intervention in the
survive as a discrete field if this were not one labor market in the 1970s led to seminal
of its central objectives; and it is therefore analyses of the operation of the Industrial
appropriate that the conceptual reformulation Relations Act 1971 (Weekes et al., 1975) and
of labor law’s basic categories, including the unfair dismissal legislation of the 1970s
the employment contract or relationship, is (Dickens et al., 1985), as well as a series
currently the focus of a considerable body of of studies carried out under the auspices of
work (Freedland, 2003; Collins et al., 2007). the (then) Social Science Research Council’s
For sociologists, economists, and others who program on ‘monitoring labour legislation’
are concerned with the social operation or (see Hepple and Brown, 1981). In the course
functioning of legal rules and institutions, the of the 1990s and 2000s this type of work,
internal structure of labor law might seem in many cases sponsored by the Department
to be less of a pressing issue. Yet, a unified of Employment and the Department of Trade
approach to the subject would recognize that and Industry, became both more quantitative
labor law is not simply a cipher for wider and more explicitly policy-orientated, and
social or economic forces, but an autonomous it is now normal practice for Parliamentary
institutional phenomenon, which influences legislation to be accompanied by regulatory
the way in which policy is translated into impact assessments of considerable detail
formal legislation, and the way in which rules and sophistication. A survey of empirical
operate in practice. To that extent, many of the work concerning the operation of labor laws
internal workings of the labor law system – not since 1997, carried out in 2005, provided an
simply the institutional processes by which overview of the findings of a large number
disputes are resolved, but the forms of legisla- of academic papers on subjects ranging
tion and the conceptual categories which are from working time regulation, the national
used by lawyers to frame their own discourse – minimum wage, trade union recognition,
are, in principle, of importance to social scien- European works councils, non-standard work,
tists seeking to understand the implications of and work-life balance legislation. But this
legal regulation for their own areas of inquiry. study also found that ‘there is a relatively
In the context of a collection of papers limited amount of interdisciplinary/multi-
designed to provide an overview of research disciplinary research bringing together aca-
in the employment relations field, our aim, demic lawyers and those trained in social
as labor lawyers, is to reassess the place of science’. This was because, on the one hand,
labor law in that wider area of study and ‘labor law research and writing has been
to argue the case for labor law’s importance constrained by traditional methods’, while, on
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 287

the other, industrial relations scholars ‘still the proposition that labor law is principally
investigate labour markets and workplace concerned with relationships of so-called
relations focusing on areas where legal ‘dependent’ or ‘subordinated’ labor, that is,
regulation is intended, or could be expected, relations between employers and employees.
to play a role (for example, employers’ labour The concept of ‘subordination’is most explicit
use strategies; worker representation) without in civil law systems but is present in the
actively exploring or commenting on this common law too under different terminol-
aspect’ (Dickens and Hall, 2005: 32). ogy (such as the ‘control’, ‘integration’,
Against this background, our objective is and ‘economic reality’ tests used to denote
to give an analytical account of the principal employee status). This concept defines the
institutional features of labor law as a form legitimate scope of managerial prerogative –
of legal regulation, from an interdisciplinary the employer’s right to give orders and to
perspective which takes into account both the require loyalty of the employee – while also
internal workings of the labor law system providing protection to employees against
and the social and economic context within certain risks. These include physical risks
which it has evolved. To that end we will (the domain of early factory legislation and
seek to analyze, in the manner of an internal now of occupational health and safety) and
or ‘immanent’ critique (Supiot, 1994), the economic risks (such as interruptions to
categories which are generally used within earnings and employment from sickness,
labor law discourse to describe the social unjust dismissal, termination on economic
and economic relations of employment; to grounds, or old age). The genuinely self-
account for their emergence and evolution employed are excluded from this type of
in historical terms; to consider the origins regulation, on the grounds that they enjoy
of their diversity across different national autonomy over the form and pace of work
systems; and to consider future prospects for and over arrangements for their own economic
convergence or divergence. security. In this way, labor law is closely
We begin by tracing the historical emer- aligned with social security law and tax law,
gence of the contract of employment as which share with it many of the same risk-
the basic building block of labor law in shifting functions.
different jurisdictions. We then look at current The focus on the relationship of employ-
developments in relation to the individual ment seems self-evident as the basis for labor
employment relationship, before turning to law, but it is in fact both a controversial idea
a consideration of collective labor relations. and an historically contingent concept. The
This approach is justified by the continuing twin ideas that work relations under capitalism
relevance of some of the core concepts, are ‘contractual’, and that they can be captured
and by the need to consider just how far using the term ‘employment’, are more recent
they are changing as a consequence of than is often supposed. There is evidence
external pressures, and why. We conclude by that in the first phases of industrialization in
offering some observations on the prospects Europe and America, labor was not uniformly
for labor law in a period of organizational and or even generally ‘free’ and that contractual
institutional transition. concepts played a limited role in defining the
parties’ mutual obligations. The employment
model, as we have since come to know it,
was initially confined to a small segment of
ORIGINS OF THE MODERN LABOR the wage- or salary-dependent labor force.
MARKET: THE EVOLUTION OF THE The manner of the emergence of the ‘contract
CONTRACT OF EMPLOYMENT of employment’ to occupy a central place in
modern labor law systems is of interest from
One way in which labor law maintains its the point of view of the relationship between
boundaries with other subjects is captured by law and industrialization, and from the
288 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

perspective of comparative legal development occupational groups, a type of employment


under capitalism. contract did indeed emerge, to which the
courts attached status obligations in the form
of implied contractual terms. The common
The common law: Britain
law action for wages due as earned under
and America
the contract, and the action for damages for
The institutional roots of a market economy in wrongful dismissal, can be identified in cases
Britain can be found in the later middle ages from the early decades of the nineteenth
and in the early modern period; the stimulus century (Freedland, 1976). However, these
provided to innovations in governance by decisions were almost without exception
such events as the Black Death (Palmer, based on the employment of managerial,
1993) and the dissolution of the monasteries clerical, or professional workers. Manual
(Woodward, 1980) have been extensively workers fell under the distinctive legal regime
documented. England already had a mature of the Master and Servant Acts, under which
national legal system at this stage, the signifi- breach of the service contract was a criminal
cance of which for its economic development offence, for which thousands of workers were
is only now beginning to be understood. How- fined or imprisoned each year up to the 1870s
ever, wage labor in the modern sense of that (Deakin and Wilkinson, 2005: 61–74).
term did not exist at this point. The terms used The master-servant model was not a
by the pivotal Statute of Artificers of 1562 and hold-over from the corporative regime of
the poor law legislation of this period, includ- the Statute of Artificers and old poor law.
ing ‘servant’ and ‘laborer’, have to be treated On the contrary, most of the disciplinary
with care; it would be a mistake to see them as powers used by employers and courts were
simply the functional equivalents of the much additions from the mid-eighteenth century
later concept of the ‘contract of employment’ and early nineteenth century, the result
(Deakin and Wilkinson, 2005: Chapter 2). of parliamentary action to bolster the
The century after 1750 which is con- prerogatives of the new employer class. The
ventionally associated with the period of nature of the paradigm legal form of the labor
the ‘industrial revolution’ in Britain was, in relationship under early industrial capitalism
addition to being a time of rapid techno- in England was statutory and hierarchical,
logical and social change, also a period of rather than common law and contractual. The
legal innovation; hence Toynbee’s suggestion, legal influence of the master-servant regime
made in the 1860s, that the essence of the was just as far reaching as its considerable
industrial revolution was not to be found in social and economic impact. The model of a
the adoption of steam power or the advent command relation, with an open-ended duty
of factory labor, but in ‘the substitution of obedience imposed on the worker, and
of competition for the medieval regulations reserving far-reaching disciplinary powers to
which had previously controlled the produc- the employer, spilled over into the common
tion and distribution of wealth’ (Toynbee, law, so that long after the repeal of the last
[1864] 1969: 92). Competition in the labor of the Master and Servant Acts in 1875, not
market was promoted through the repeal just the terminology of master and servant
of the wage-fixing laws and apprenticeship but also many of the old assumptions of
regulations which had contained in the Statute unmediated control were still being applied
of Artificers (in 1813 and 1814 respectively). by the courts as they developed the common
It might be thought that this would have led to law of employment (Hay and Craven, 2004).
the contractualization of labor relations and US employment law took a divergent path
hence to the recognition in the courts of the at this point, but one which also resulted in
concept of the contract of employment as the the emergence of a general model for the
paradigm legal form of the work relationship. employment relationship based on contract.
However, this is not what happened. For some By the early twentieth century almost all
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 289

states had adopted an ‘employment at will’ employed under a ‘contract of service’, a term
rule, under which the contract of employment which gradually became interchangeable with
could be terminated by either party on a the term ‘contract of employment’, and those
moment’s notice, without giving a reason. who were ‘self-employed’ or independent
This conferred almost no job security upon the contractors, was then carried over into early
employee. Where the British and American employment protection statutes in the 1960s.
systems diverged in the final decades of the The term ‘contract of employment’ is a recent
nineteenth century was over the question innovation in British labor law, just as it is in
of whether all employment relationships civil law jurisdictions.
should be presumed to be at will unless
the contrary were stated. The American
courts, following Payne v. Western & Atlantic
The civil law: French and German
Railroad 1 and in particular Martin v. New
models
York Life Insurance Co.2 which concerned a
middle-class employee, began to apply just There is evidence from the civil law systems
such a general presumption. The extension of to support the suggestion that the modern
the at-will model was primarily a product of a contract of employment is an invention of the
constitutional debate over the legitimacy of late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries,
social legislation. The question of the con- associated with the rise of the integrated
struction of the terms of employment contracts enterprise and the beginnings of the welfare or
took on a general significance, far beyond social state. The emerging forms of wage labor
the immediate question of rights under the were grafted on to the traditional Roman law
wage-work bargain between employer and concept of the locatio conductio in the post-
employee (Njoya, 2007). No such presump- revolutionary codes of the early 1800s. The
tion developed in Britain, principally because adoption of contractual forms and language
there was no equivalent to the constitutional was more explicit than in the British case at
dimension to the issue which arose in the US. this time. In adapting the model of the locatio,
In Britain, the advent of the welfare state the drafters of the codes were grouping labor
and the extension of collective bargaining, relationships with other types of contracts,
neither of which was subject to constitutional the effect being to stress that, in common
constraints, saw employment law taking a with them, they were based on exchange
different path (see Deakin and Wilkinson, (Veneziani, 1986: 32). Labor, or in some
2005: 86–100). However, the persistence of versions labor power – as, for example, in the
the master-servant model, and the enduring German term Arbeitskraft – thereby became
influence of the principle of less eligibility a commodity which was linked to price (not
in the long transition from the poor law to necessarily the ‘wage’), through the contract.
social security, which was completed only in The notion of the personal ‘subordination’ of
the 1940s, delayed the advent of the modern the worker was absent from the formulae used
‘contract of employment’; if that idea is by the codes (Simitis, 2000). The reality was
identified, above all, with a classification of rather different, since more or less all systems
labor relations which incorporates the ‘binary acknowledged the power of the employer to
divide’ between employees and the self- give orders, to issue rules which had binding
employed, we have to look to the middle of the force (in the form, for example, of the French
twentieth century to find it in British labor law. livret or work book), and to retain the worker
The first statutes to adopt the binary divide in employment, without a testimonial, until
in a clear form were concerned with income they considered the work to be complete.
taxation and social insurance. The National However, this body of legislation and practice
Insurance Act 1946, which incorporated Bev- was formally separated from the general
eridge’s plan for social security, marked the private law of the codes, and administered
turning point; its clear division between those by police authorities and specialized labor
290 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

tribunals; as a result, it remained under- thereby placed in a position of ‘juridical


developed from a conceptual point of view. subordination’. In German-influenced sys-
The term contract of employment or, tems, on the other hand, a ‘communitarian’
in France, contrat de travail, only entered conception of the enterprise qualified the
general usage in the 1880s. The main impetus role of the individual contract. In contrast to
for its adoption was an argument by employers the French approach, German law came to
in larger enterprises that the general duty of recognize the ‘personal subordination’ of the
obedience should be read into all industrial worker in the form of ‘factual adhesion to
hirings. However, once the term became the enterprise’ (Tatbestand), a process which
established, it was used in turn of the century conferred ‘a status equivalent to membership
legislation on industrial accidents (Veneziani, of a community’ (Supiot, 1994: 18).
1986: 64), and its adoption was promoted
and systematized by commissions of jurists
charged with developing a conceptual frame- THE CONTRACT OF EMPLOYMENT
work for collective bargaining and worker TODAY: CONCEPTUAL EVOLUTION
protection (ibid.: 68). At the core of the AND CHANGE
concept was a notion of ‘subordination’ in
which the open-ended duty of obedience was Although the emergence of a coherent model
traded off in return for the acceptance and of the contract of employment was a consid-
absorption by the enterprise of a range of erable achievement, and a progressive one,
social risks (see Cottereau, 2000, 2002; Petit for its time, its legacy has been problem-
and Sauze, 2006). In Germany, a similar atic. We will consider two main challenges
process of evolution can be traced, through currently facing the law in its attempt to
which adaptations of the locatio model in the regulate individual aspects of the employment
codes of the nineteenth century, culminating relationship. First, we look at why the heavy
in the German Civil Code of 1896 (on which, reliance on the notion of ‘contract’ poses
see Sims, 2002), were in their turn modified to difficulties in regulating the termination of
produce the modern employment relationship employment. We note the special case of
or Arbeitsverhältnis in the legislation of the the employment relationship in the large,
Weimar period, with the advent of legal publicly held company. Second, we consider
recognition for collective bargaining and the question of balancing job security with
social legislation. flexibility, profitability, and competitiveness,
Both France and Germany, then, experi- a key issue in determining the scope of
enced the late development of the contract of employment protection legislation. Economic
employment. What emerged, however, were dismissals remain largely unregulated by law
forms which reflected the distinctive legal in the UK, on the basis that such regulation
cultures of the two systems (Mückenberger would impose rigidity and exacerbate unem-
and Supiot, 2000). In the French-origin ployment. We consider the social implications
systems, the power of the state to regulate of this approach, contrasting it with some of
conditions of work was instantiated within the approaches in continental Europe and the
the legal system through the concept of ordre US, and suggest that redefining the conceptual
public social, that is, a set of minimum, basis of the employment relationship may
binding conditions which applied as a matter provide a means of ensuring a better balance
of general law to the employment relationship. between job security and economic flexibility.
The implicit logic of this idea was that in
recognizing the formal contractual equality
Shifts in the contractual foundations
of the parties to the employment relationship,
of the employment relationship
the state also assumed, by way of symmetry,
a responsibility for establishing a form of One of the principal regulatory difficulties
protection for the individual worker who was currently facing labor law is that of identifying
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 291

the concepts best suited to defining and was that the employer would be within its
describing the employment relationship at a rights in terminating the contract for any
time when organizational form is in flux. As reason or none at all, subject to giving the
the organization and social context of work requisite notice or paying a monetary sum
change, so does the nature of the employment to the employee in lieu of notice. The only
relationship and the law constantly faces the exception would be where the terms of
challenge of adapting its own conceptual the contract specify that there will be no
framework in response to these changes. As dismissal except for just, or specified, causes.
we have seen, the law generally conceives Yet, the common law is not static. In the US,
of the employment relationship as a contract there have been recent suggestions that the
between employer and employee. This is common law might develop to allow breaches
coupled with the notion of freedom of of contractual terms other than the notice term
contract (based on the assumptions of perfect to give rise to a wrongful dismissal claim,
rationality, foresight, and information on the overcoming or at least qualifying the concept
part of both employer and employee) as well of employment at will (Stone, 2007). In the
as the assumption that both parties have UK, the implied term of ‘mutual trust and
equal bargaining power. These assumptions confidence’, under which the employer has an
are particularly influential in the context obligation to deal with the employee in good
of individual aspects of labor law – it is faith, has been seen as a potential way forward
usually only in the context of collective in developing norms preventing dismissal
action that these assumptions can be more without just cause (Brodie, 1996). Similarly,
directly addressed, and mitigated. In terms in the US, most states have developed limited
of the individual employment relationship modifications or exceptions to the at-will rule
one of the most pressing concerns is that of on the basis of an implied covenant of good
job security. In theory freedom of contract faith and fair dealing stone.
allows both parties to agree on terms that At the same time, there are limits to how
grant employment security to the worker, far the common law can go. In English
but in practice inequality of bargaining law, although the implied obligation to
power and the prevalence of ‘standard form’ maintain mutual trust and confidence has had
contracts mean that most workers are not a considerable impact on the interpretation
in a position to enter into an independent of the employer’s duty in the course of a
negotiation of the terms and conditions continuing employment relationship, so far
of employment. Moreover, many atypical this obligation has had little, if any, discernible
workers and semi-dependent workers are left effect on job security in terms of preventing
outside the framework of the ‘contract of dismissals. The main reason for this is that
employment’ altogether. They do not fall the scope of the implied term of mutual
within the strict legal definition of ‘employee’, trust and confidence is limited, so that it
and so are often not covered by employment applies during the continuing employment
protection laws. relationship but does not extend to the
As we have seen, the conceptual framework ‘manner of dismissal’. The courts continue to
of labor law is shaped both by private law draw a careful distinction between the action
concepts, principally that of contract, for damages for breach of the implied term
and by social legislation. In relation to of mutual trust and confidence as an ordinary
job security, the common law action for action for breach of contract, on the one hand,
‘wrongful dismissal’ is an action for breach and the action for wrongful dismissal on the
of contract. ‘Wrongful’ in the common other. Hence, as Freedland writes (2005: 361),
law refers simply to the failure to give ‘the view that wrongful dismissal is wrongful,
reasonable notice of dismissal, and does not and remediable in damages, only because
include any general notion of unfairness. The of its prematurity, its denial of a promised
traditional rule in common law jurisdictions period of notice or fixed term of employment,
292 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

has been and continues to be the dominant which more or less remained intact. Over
approach of English common law’. time, certain aspects of protection have been
strengthened, in particular those relating to the
category of inadmissible reasons or ‘human
Unfair dismissal legislation
rights’ dismissals (Deakin and Morris, 2005:
The notion of ‘unfairness’ in dismissal had Chapter 5).
to be introduced by legislative intervention At the outset of the debate over labor
in virtually all systems; it was not a flexibility in the early 1980s, most of the
natural offshoot or development of private civil law systems began from a position of
law norms or concepts. Unfair or unjust having strong dismissal laws, in contrast to
dismissal legislation originated in continental those in the common law world which were
European systems in the inter-war period and less highly developed. As efforts to increase
in the decade immediately after 1945, and flexibility in the labor market intensified, the
has since been adopted in some form by civil law systems have, in varying degrees,
most systems with the exception of the US. loosened controls over managerial decision-
ILO Convention No. 158 defines its core making, but have done so not through
elements which include a requirement that the changes of a far-reaching nature to the
employer should normally have a valid reason core of dismissal law, but through limited
for terminating the employee’s employment. exemptions in favor of ‘atypical’ forms of
Only one US state (Montana) has enacted work. A number of legislative initiatives
an unjust dismissal statute, even though a throughout the 1980s and 1990s sought to
model code is available in the form of the encourage the growth of part-time and fixed-
Model Employment Termination Act (1991) term employment by exempting employers
which was drafted under the auspices of the from dismissal protection in these cases and
National Conference of Commissioners for by subsidizing hirings under these contracts
Uniform State Laws. However, at the federal through other means such as the tax-benefit
level there is significant legislation in the system. The balance of opinion is that
area of human-rights dismissals; this includes these reforms may have had a positive but
federal statutes governing discrimination on minor overall impact on employment levels
the grounds of sex, race, age, and disability. (OECD, 2004); but they have also led to an
The levels of compensation payable by increase in the numbers employed in flexible
employers to victims of discrimination often or ‘atypical’ forms of work, and hence to
contain punitive elements, and far outstrip the growing segmentation between a secure ‘core’
sums which could be paid in most European and a less secure ‘periphery’ of workers. In
jurisdictions. reaction to this negative development, several
In Britain, unfair dismissal legislation dates recent EU initiatives have sought to strengthen
from 1971. Although this legislation was protection against inequality and structural
informed by the standards laid down by discrimination at work. These include mea-
the ILO, it was also heavily influenced by sures aimed at enhancing opportunities for
a perceived need to streamline industrial temporary and part-time work at the same
relations procedures at plant level and to time as entrenching a principle of equality
encourage employers to put in place disci- of treatment between these forms of work
plinary procedures for dealing with individual and full-time, long-term employment, and
disputes, one effect of which would be to recognition at EU level of a wider principle
reduce unofficial strikes over dismissals. The of non-discrimination in employment.
subsequent evolution of unfair dismissal law
was influenced by the growing debate over
Economic dismissals
flexibility, although deregulatory legislation
of the 1980s made only a marginal impact on The dismissal of workers for ‘economic’
the main body of unfair dismissal protection, reasons is one of the most controversial areas
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 293

of legal intervention into the employment should be enhanced is countered on the basis
relationship. The justification for limiting the that job security for the employed would
protective role of the law in this context allow core workers to become entrenched in
is that when employing entities undergo their positions, resulting in rigid labor markets
organizational restructuring, the sustainability in which certain marginalized groups, the
of the enterprise must take priority over job peripheral and atypical workers referred to
security. Thus the law generally respects the earlier, are perpetually unemployed. A related
‘managerial prerogative’ to dismiss workers argument is that employment protection
as a cost-cutting measure. This approach is legislation may impede the creation of new
reflected across international law, European jobs, as such legislation potentially ‘increases
law, and UK law. For instance the ILO the costs for the employer of adjusting
acknowledges that the ‘operational require- their workforce and can create a barrier
ments of the undertaking’ may justify termi- to hiring’ (OECD, 2006: paragraph 3.3).
nation of employment (ILO Recommendation These perspectives suggest that job security
No 119 of 1963, Art 2(1) and Art 12). EU should therefore be understood as simply
law, in the context of the Acquired Rights extending to the availability of jobs in the
Directive, allows dismissal for ‘economic, economy as a whole and especially widening
technical or organizational reasons’ as a access to employment opportunities, rather
defense to an unfair dismissal claim. At than being concerned with job protection
common law, in the words of Lord Hoffmann, for the employed in their specific or current
‘employment law requires a balancing of positions. However, while the concerns about
the interests of employers and employees, the entrenchment of secure core workers is
with proper regard not only to the individual legitimate, recent empirical studies published
dignity and worth of the employees but also by the OECD ‘generally have not found
to the general economic interest’.3 Similarly, robust evidence for a significant direct effect
in the US economic dismissals are justifiable of [employment protection legislation] on
in the context of collective bargaining law on unemployment’ (ibid.). The risks of adverse
grounds of ‘business necessity’.4 The current effects on opportunities for the unemployed
law governing employment security therefore appear to arise only when job protection is ‘too
contains ample scope for flexibility, often to strict’, and not simply from the mere existence
the detriment of job security. of job protection. The OECD therefore
It may be questioned why the law governing recommends that the implementation of such
termination of the employment contract legislation should be ‘quick, predictable and
offers workers virtually no protection to distort labor turnover as little as possible’, and
the individual worker when the dismissal is ‘should be carefully coordinated with reforms
for economic reasons. Economic dismissals to the unemployment benefits system …
during corporate restructuring geared toward so as to reconcile so far as is possible
boosting short-term share value arguably labor market flexibility with security for
impose significant social costs on workers workers’ (ibid.).
and their communities with knock-on effects The differences in levels of job protection
for other industries and the economy as a in different jurisdictions partly reflect varia-
whole. Concerns about job security in this tions in the overall economic, political, and
context are heightened where there is no institutional context of each country. This
suggestion of ‘fault’ on the part of the workers context has in turn given rise to different
– blame is laid instead on impersonal market responses to the issue of how to regulate
forces, which may intensify the sense of the employment relationship. Despite the
social displacement felt by those affected fact that industrialization and the increasing
particularly where the job cuts are not sophistication of production methods have
perceived to be inevitable. In response to these brought about a shift in the organization
concerns, the suggestion that job security of work globally, labor relations and labor
294 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

laws continue to diverge sharply in different impossible to find an alternative of compara-


jurisdictions and so far there is no reason to ble worth, an effect often felt for the remainder
expect this trend to change. The UK and US of the worker’s career. Where the worker is
have among the lowest levels of employment compelled to take the next best alternative,
security legislation in the world (Botero empirical studies demonstrate ‘substantial and
et al., 2004). This is largely attributable long-lasting effects of job loss on annual
to the continuing influence of private law earnings and wages’ over the long term, from
concepts, in particular freedom of contract, which many workers never recover (Topel,
as already noted. Conversely, in most EU 1990: 181). This has been defined as the
member states employment protection has its real cost of job loss, that is, ‘the difference
origin in industrial traditions which, while between the utility value of being in the
they conceptualize employment as being current job and that of the next best alter-
founded upon a private law contract, also native’ (Green and McIntosh, 1998: 365–6).
define it, as we have seen, as a special The question then becomes whether the
relationship regulated by principles of public overall social cost of job loss is necessary
law or mandatory public regulation (ordre in the interests of efficiency or overall
public social), which grant workers a form wealth benefits to society. In situations where
of quasi-constitutional entitlement to remain jobs are cut in order to boost short-term
in their jobs unless there is just cause for gains for the firm’s shareholders it could
their dismissal. For instance in German law be said that the corporation is ‘effectively
dismissal, even with notice, must be ‘socially transferring to the public sector the costs
justified’ otherwise it is ‘illegal’; selection of maintaining these displaced workers’
of employees for redundancy ‘must take (Singer, 1993: 496).
into account so called “social aspects” [so]
that those who suffer the most from the
effects of the dismissal should be the last Alternatives to contract: the use of
ones to be dismissed … social justice for
property-based concepts to enhance
each individual case’ (Weiss, 1998: 86–8,
legal job security
discussing the Act on Dismissal Protection
of 1951 (s.1)). Several commentators have noted that there
Criticisms that the European approach to are inherent difficulties in relying on the
job security is too rigid have prompted reform concept of ‘contract’to define the employment
proposals by the European Commission. relationship, and that there is a good case
Although the Commission still refers to ‘full to be made for moving beyond contract.
employment’ as one of the goals of its In the context of job security in the firm
employment agenda, this is now giving way to the concept of property may prove more
concepts such as adaptability, responsiveness, helpful than that of contract, in the following
and employability. Flexibility on the workers’ way. Understood as an analogy rather than
side is understood as the workers’ capacity as a ‘category’ of property rights as such,
to anticipate change and move readily from the notion of property implies that the
one type of job to another. As European employee has a claim of ‘ownership’ in
employment policy emphasizes the creation the form of an expectation of continued
of ‘more and better jobs’ the focus is on employment without fear of arbitrary dispos-
ensuring that workers who lose their jobs session (Meyers, 1964). Compensation for
will find alternative opportunities within a wrongful or unfair dismissal would be based
dynamic and vibrant economy. not simply on the ‘notice period’ defined by
Yet there are inherent difficulties in this the contract, but on the real value of the job
focus on flexibility. For many highly skilled lost. This approach is particularly helpful in
workers who have invested years of work understanding the employment relationship in
in a particular firm or trade it may prove the large firm. The dominant presumption is
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 295

that the corporation is owned exclusively by COLLECTIVE LABOR RELATIONS:


its shareholders (who have rights of property WORKER REPRESENTATION AND
in the firm) and that the workers’ interests CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
are fully defined by and limited to the terms
of their employment contracts. However, a Worker representation and the
historical analysis of the employment rela- coverage of labor standards
tionship reveals that property rights have not
traditionally been associated exclusively with Representation of workers through indepen-
the rights or status of the employer. Notions dent trade unions which negotiated pay and
of respect for private property have long been conditions of employment on their behalf with
invoked to support the rights of employees an employer or groups of employers became
(Njoya, 2007). the predominant model around which the
Recognition of the value of firm-specific collective labor law of the twentieth century
human capital has come to acquire important developed. It is reflected in the core principles
implications for law reform. The statement of freedom of association of the ILO and
in the European Commission’s Employment in the practice of many systems. However,
in Europe (2006, at 81 et seq), that ‘workers systems differ in the nature and extent of
feel better protected by a support system in state encouragement for collective bargaining
case of unemployment than by employment provided, the levels at which bargaining takes
protection legislation’ presents only part of place, and the mechanisms for determining the
the picture. It remains the case that job representativeness of unions.
security in the job actually held is paramount: There is a case for seeing a division
‘a secure job is still an essential aspect, for of systems along the lines suggested by
most individuals, of their long-term economic the ‘varieties of capitalism’ approach (Hall
security’ (Deakin and Morris, 2005: 569). and Soskice, 2001). In so-called ‘liberal
In drawing the boundaries of its regulatory market’ systems, the predominant form of
scope the law already recognizes that not all employee representation is collective bargain-
dismissals which take place during corporate ing between employers and trade unions.
restructuring are justifiable, and that in certain From a legal perspective, collective bargain-
situations employees may have property-like ing operates in manner akin to setting up a
claims on the firm, for instance interests which contractual mechanism for negotiation. This
go beyond the terms of their employment can be done by the employer voluntarily
contracts. The best example of this in the UK recognizing a particular union or unions,
is the Transfer of Undertakings (Protection or through various regulatory mechanisms
of Employment) Regulations 2006, which which, as in the US since the 1930s,
recognize that workers have a claim to remain have required the employer to negotiate
in their jobs with a particular firm when with a certified bargaining agent which can
it is sold. Such a proprietary approach is demonstrate that it has majority support in
more compatible with an understanding of the relevant bargaining unit. On the face of
employment security as much more than it, the US system offers strong legal support
ensuring that workers are ‘adaptable’ and for a union which can demonstrate in a
‘employable’ in different jobs. It goes further workplace election that it has majority support
by understanding employment security as ‘a in a bargaining unit. The union becomes the
form of regulatory intervention designed to certified bargaining agent for that unit, and
protect workers against arbitrary managerial as a result has a statutory monopoly over
decision-making’, a protection which rec- bargaining for pay and conditions in respect
ognizes the valuable long-term relationships of the employees in question. However, this
which arise between employees and the firms arrangement, put in place by the federal
for which they work (Deakin and Morris, National Labor Relations (or Wagner) Act
2005: 388; Njoya, 2007). of 1935 and subsequently amended by the
296 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Taft-Hartley Act of 1947, is less favorable critical differences, in particular the greater
to unions than it might seem. Enforcing role accorded to encouragement for voluntary
the employer’s duty to bargain is often agreements outside the framework of the
problematic, and employers are permitted legislation (Wood and Godard, 1999).
to deploy a powerful array of weapons in Whatever the degree of state compulsion
frustrating unionization drives and in pressing used to bring about recognition or certifica-
for decertification. Attempts to reform the law tion, there are strict limits to how far collective
so as to allow alternative forms of employee bargaining can go in relation to the core areas
representation to emerge and to soften the of managerial ‘prerogative’, so that it stops
rigidly adversarial quality of the certification short of co-decision making or codetermina-
process have failed. The deficiencies of the tion (for the US, see Weiler, 1990; for Britain,
law are thought to be a contributing factor Wedderburn, 1986: Chapter 4). Outside those
in the decline of union density in the US to areas where employers concede collective
its current level of only 7 per cent in the bargaining or have it forced on them by public
private-sector, compared with 36 per cent in regulation, there is no legal obligation to
the public sector where institutional support deal with employee representatives. In their
for collective bargaining is stronger (Kolins emphasis on collective bargaining as a form
Givan, 2007). of regulated contractual co-ordination, these
In Britain, for most of the twentieth systems may continue to be characterized as
century, the ‘recognition’ of trade unions by voluntarist.
employers – agreement to enter into collective Voluntarism at the level of the enter-
bargaining over pay and conditions, among prise tends to go hand in hand with a
other things – was a matter of consent rather partial approach to regulation at market
than of statutory imposition. The law imposed level. Thus although both Britain and the
no duty to bargain and, conversely, played US have national minimum wage laws
no role in certifying unions as bargaining and some legislation governing basic terms
agents, hence Kahn-Freund’s insistence on and conditions such as working hours, the
seeing its role as ‘marginal’ in relation to tendency has been for statutory regulation
autonomous sources of regulation. The law to impose only minimal constraints on the
preserved a wide freedom to strike, and to employment contract outside those sectors
lock-out, by granting unions and individuals which are governed by collective bargaining.
immunities from liability in tort for organizing As collective bargaining has shrunk, since the
strike action. The absence of direct legal 1950s inAmerica and the late 1970s in Britain,
intervention was seen to be the system’s so the uneven and partial character of labor
principal strength. However, since the 1970s, market regulation has been accentuated within
the system of collective bargaining has these systems (for the US, see Weiler, 1990;
undergone a process of decline, with falling for the UK, see Deakin and Wilkinson, 1991).
coverage of collective agreements (down to ‘Co-ordinated market’ systems, on the
below 40 per cent from over 80 per cent other hand, tend to combine an integra-
in 1979) and falling union density (now tive approach to the role of employees in
below 30 per cent from a peak of nearly the enterprise with universalism in labor
60 per cent in 1979). It is not entirely market regulation. ‘Integration’ implies the
clear that the legal reforms of the 1980s, incorporation of employee voice directly
which cut back on the freedom to strike into the decision-making structures of the
and encouraged decentralization of collective firm. In many civil law systems, particularly
bargaining, were the critical factor in precipi- those located in Western Europe, sectoral
tating this decline, but there is some evidence bargaining ensures that a basic floor is set
that they were (Freeman and Pelletier, 1990). to terms and conditions of employment, with
Since 2001 Britain also has had a system of legal support. In addition, legislation normally
compulsory recognition, based superficially mandates some form of collective employee
on aspects of the US model, but with some representation at plant or enterprise level.
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 297

The function of works councils (in Germany, businesses between employers. Transnational
in particular) is not (on the whole) to enterprises are required to enter into regular
enter into collective bargaining, but rather consultation with employee representatives
to engage in the explicitly cooperative goal under the terms of the European Works
of ‘codetermination’ of the working process. Councils Directive of 1995, a model which
This involves representing employee voice to was extended to other companies above a
the employer and monitoring the application certain size threshold by the Information and
of laws and agreements within the workplace, Consultation of Employees Directive of 2002
functions which are intended to complement (ICE). The ICE Directive has introduced
collective bargaining operating at a multi- significant changes to collective labor law in
employer level. In Germany, collective bar- systems such as the UK and Ireland which
gaining between trade unions and associations had traditionally relied on a ‘single channel’
of employers to set basic terms and conditions model of collective representation in which
mostly takes place at industry or sector level; the sole mechanism for consulting workers
in that sense, codetermination within the was the recognized trade union. This left
enterprise is complementary to trade union non-unionized workers unable for a while to
autonomy both from management interests benefit from rights of information and con-
and from state interference at industry level. sultation granted by European law. Moreover,
The effects of collective agreements can in the absence of any general framework
be extended to non-federated employers by for consultation, even those workers who
statutory order. In France, where enterprise were unionized would only have such rights
committees and other representative bodies in specific situations such as redundancies
operate at enterprise level in rather different and transfers of undertakings. For these
fashion from the German works council reasons, in so far as it goes against the pre-
(they have fewer legal powers and also existing tradition of collective representation,
have employer representation), we again the possible impact of the ICE Directive in
find strong multi-employer bargaining at Ireland and the UK is likely to prove more
sectoral level. France also has a statutory controversial and problematic than in other
minimum wage which is linked to wage member states.
(and not just price) increases and legis- One of the difficulties in assessing the
lation on working time and other aspects role of the ICE Directive within the legal
of terms and conditions of employment framework of liberal market economies is
which is enforced by a well-resourced labor that strong rights of employee consultation
inspectorate. and representation in decision-making in the
firm are perceived as incompatible with the
notion that a company’s directors are solely
Information and consultation
accountable to their shareholders, not the
of employee representatives
employees, for the decisions they make.
A key element of the continental European Decision-making is an essential attribute
model is the obligation of the employer to of ownership and control. Within a legal
enter into processes of ‘information and con- tradition in which ownership and control are
sultation’ with the workforce representatives. assumed to vest exclusively in shareholders
This principle is incorporated in Article 27 (and in managers as the shareholders’ agents),
of the European Charter of Fundamental the general understanding has been that
Rights and has now been embodied in a employee decision-making rights should not
series of European Union directives. This be prescribed by legislation. As we saw above,
has the effect of institutionalizing a role for in view of the limits on how far collective
employee representation when decisions are bargaining can go in relation to the core areas
taken which affect the form and operation of managerial prerogative the tradition in both
of the enterprise, such as large-scale restruc- the UK and the US has been to limit the scope
turings leading to dismissals and transfers of of mandatory collective bargaining to wages,
298 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

hours, and terms and conditions of work. In directors. Employee membership of corporate
contrast, the emerging European framework boards is not mandated by European Union
of information and consultation extends to law, and is also the exception at national
core managerial matters. For instance under level; Germany is the most prominent system
Article 12 of the Works Councils Directive the to make this a requirement. However, many
matters over which workers have information systems have some combination of two-
and consultation rights include the firm’s tier board structures and employee consul-
‘structure, economic and financial situation, tation requirements. Rights of information
the probable development of the business and consultation which fall short of board
and of production and sales … investments membership may still be understood within
and substantial changes concerning organiza- the framework of ownership rights, but only
tion … [and] transfers of production, mergers, where they are coupled with sanctions which
cut-backs or closures of undertakings, estab- ensure that failure to observe these rights will
lishments or important parts thereof’. Critics invalidate the managers’ unilateral decision.
of this approach argue that while it is good This is the case in some member states such
managerial practice to consult employees and as Germany and France, where a managerial
listen to their ideas and suggestions, any decision arrived at without prior consultation
rights of information and consultation should with employee representatives is generally
be limited to an opportunity for employees (subject to specified conditions) voidable or
to express their viewpoint (understood as even void (Laulom, 2001). By contrast, in
rights of ‘voice’) but should not extend to the UK the regulations implementing the
a right to influence the final decision. As ICE Directive impose a maximum financial
expressed by the US Supreme Court, in penalty of £75,000 for non-compliance with
introducing a ‘duty to bargain’ with employee the consultation requirement, payable not to
representatives under the NLRA ‘Congress the affected employees but to the Secretary
had no expectation that the elected union of State. In the absence of any direct remedy
representative would become an equal partner available to workers for the firm’s failure to
in the running of the business enterprise in consult them the regulations fall far short of
which the union’s members are employed’; conferring proprietary rights on employees.
ultimately, ‘management must be free from The question may be posed whether
the constraints of the bargaining process to the participatory rights falling short of property
extent essential for the running of a profitable or ownership rights are sufficient to protect
business’.5 employees’ firm-specific human capital. One
This perspective has nevertheless been perspective is that ‘voice’ rights respect the
challenged as overlooking the fact that in the dignity of workers by allowing their views
modern knowledge and skills based economy to be heard, and if job security is understood
employees who make valuable investments simply as the need to respect the dignity and
of firm-specific human capital are just as autonomy of workers while dismissing them
entitled to participate in decision-making (Collins, 1992) then the existing framework
as shareholders who invest finance capital of information and consultation under the UK
(Njoya, 2007). If ownership of the firm is regulations would appear to meet this need.
understood as a ‘bundle of rights’ which Another argument is that there is nothing
includes the right to participate in controlling to prevent employees bargaining for rights
the firm’s operations and strategy, then such of ownership and control, so that there is
ownership may be understood as shared no need for prescriptive legislation. This
between employees and shareholders. This perspective accepts that employees make
would imply that employee participation in valuable investments in the firm but reasons
decision-making goes beyond ‘voice’ rights, that ‘all are left to protect themselves through
extending to a role in determining outcomes contract’ (Easterbrook and Fischel, 1991: 38).
for instance by sitting on the firm’s board of In practice, however, such bargaining is
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 299

inevitably incomplete (Kim, 1997; Stone, 1999). In Britain and other common law
2002). countries such as Australia, the model of
This is not to suggest that the property- the takeover code, originating in the city of
rights model is necessarily more effective London, plays a key role, and shareholder
at protecting human capital investments than litigation is rare. This reflects, to a large
a contractual model. There are potential degree, the collective voice exercised by
governance costs associated with partici- institutional investors in the British context,
patory decision-making. However, controls which is not matched to the same degree,
over restructuring which impede management historically, in the US (Black and Coffee,
and reduce financial returns also provide 1994; Armour and Skeel, 2007). Shareholder
the basis for long-term co-operation between litigation and takeover codes therefore appear
management and labor in systems reliant on to be substitutes in providing a mechanism
investments in firm-specific human capital. In for protecting minority shareholders; the
this context it is significant that in German presence of one means that there is less need
debates about the benefits and costs of for the other.
codetermination, there does not appear to be By contrast, in the case of ‘insider-
any conclusive view on whether the arms- orientated’ or ‘co-ordinated market’ systems,
length contractual model associated with the the concentration of ownership allows for
Anglo-American firm is superior in terms of direct monitoring and observation of manage-
efficiency: ‘there have been no undisputed rial performance, thereby overcoming some
econometric studies on the (negative or pos- of the agency problems which are inherent
itive) correlation between co-determination in the separation of ownership and control
and company performance’ (Baums, 2003: in outsider-based régimes (although this need
185). Germany’s 1998 Codetermination Com- not imply the absence of laws protecting
mission considered that empirical evidence shareholder interests, which are often quite
pointed to efficiency gains as well as costs strong in civil law countries: see Siems, 2005).
(Addison et al., 2004: 394). Concentration or ‘blockholding’ takes differ-
ent forms, depending on context; in varying
degrees, corporate cross-shareholdings, bank-
Corporate governance and its
led governance and the residue of family-
interface with labor law
based control and state control can be
A further aspect of the apparent divergence observed (see the contributions in Hopt
between ‘liberal’ and ‘co-ordinated’ market et al., 1997). Again, specific legal institutions
systems concerns the interaction of collective have developed to complement the presence
labor law with the predominant structures of of mechanisms of direct control (Rogers
corporate ownership and control (‘corporate and Streeck, 1994). In German-influenced
governance’) in systems. In liberal market systems, there is a role for employee-
systems, dispersed ownership and market nominated directors on a supervisory board as
liquidity enable outside investors to diversify part of a two-tier board structure. Employee
their holdings, thereby spreading the risk representation within company organs is by
of being subject to managerial opportunism, no means the general rule, however. In France,
while at the same time using the capital most companies have not taken up the option,
market to hold management to account, via provided in legislation, of having a dual
the mechanism of the hostile takeover bid. In board, and employee voice, while significant,
different systems, different institutions have mostly operates outside corporate structures
evolved which facilitate these processes. In (Goyer and Hancké, 2003). In Japan, a highly
the US, a range of mechanisms, including integrative approach to the participation of
shareholder litigation and an intensively employees in the firm almost entirely takes
regulatory regime of securities law, serves to the form of social norms rather than legal
protect minority shareholder interests (Coffee, prescription (Learmount, 2002: Chapter 7).
300 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

In the context of co-ordinated market market pressures in a way which has left
economies, this more direct form of employee intact (so far at least) the social compromises
involvement appears to be complementary embodied in those systems (Jacoby, 2005;
to concentrated share ownership. Employee Höpner, 2005). Thus it is far from clear
representatives may aid investors in the that a tendency to convergence of either
process of monitoring managers, and may form or function is being observed (Amable,
also bring valuable information on organi- 2003). Even during a period when national
zational processes to bear on the decision- systems are increasingly exposed to the effects
making process, notwithstanding possible of transnational capital flows, regulatory
costs arising from more extended or protracted competition and the growing acceptance,
decision-making processes (Pistor, 1999). among policy makers and business elites of a
Employee representation may also provide a ‘shareholder value’ norm (see Hansmann and
more broadly-based mechanism for building Kraakman, 2001), governance mechanisms
trust between workers and investors and in remain matched to local conditions and
particular for encouraging mutual investments reflect particular trajectories of economic
in firm-specific assets (Rogers and Streeck, development.
1994). Either way, institutionalized employee
involvement in the firm may be said to be com-
plementary to blockholding as a particular
form of corporate ownership and control. CONCLUSIONS: THE PROSPECTS
There is evidence of enterprises and sectors FOR LABOR LAW IN A TIME
which go against the trend in all varieties of OF TRANSITION
system; British and American pharmaceutical
firms behave very much along the lines In this chapter we have sought to explain some
predicted for stakeholder-orientated systems of the structures and concepts which distin-
(Gospel and Pendleton, 2003), as do many guish labor law as an autonomous institutional
utilities and service providers in regulated phenomenon; autonomous, that is from the
sectors (see Deakin et al., 2002). Conversely, industrial relations system, and from labor
some German and Japanese companies have market relations more broadly. The idea that
begun to adopt shareholder value metrics and labor law possesses this autonomy and so is
the business strategies associated with them not a mere appendage or expression of social
(Lane, 2003; Learmount, 2002). Thus legal and economic forces is one which labor law
institutions do not rigidly dictate firm-level scholars increasingly look to in an attempt to
practices. However, the balance of evidence give shape to their discipline (Rogowski and
suggests that a good case can be made for Wilthagen, 1994). This is not to argue that
the existence of complementarities across the labor law can be studied in isolation from the
linked domains of corporate governance and social sciences. Rather, it represents a return
labor law, and for the continuing influence to labor law’s methodological roots, and to a
of these linkages at firm level. (Parkinson, tradition which sought co-existence between
2003: 491). what we might now describe as an ‘internal’
In Germany and Japan, internal labor mar- (or juridical) perspective on the conceptual
kets, constructed around implicit promises of language of legal discourse and an ‘external’
job security and high levels of investment (or social science) understanding of labor law
in firm-specific training, have remained in as impacting on, and being impacted by, social
place during the 1990s and early 2000s, and economic relations. The essence of this
when they have become a rarity in the approach is that it is only by recognizing that
private sector in US and Britain. There is positive legal analysis, on the one hand, and
also evidence that Japanese and German the sociological or economic analysis of law,
companies have adjusted to the growing role on the other, are distinct techniques, that they
of external investors and to increased capital can be effectively integrated in the study of
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 301

labor law; one should not be dissolved into the law’s wider operation and impact, might
the other (Kahn-Freund, 1981: 97). help us in understanding its likely future
From this point of view, labor law can be development.
identified with the emergence of conceptual
forms for defining the employment relation-
ship, the business enterprise and structures of NOTES
worker representation. These forms were at
one and the same time the product of certain 1 81 Tenn. 507 (1884).
prior legal categories (those of contract and 2 148 NY 117 (1895).
3 Johnson v Unisys [2003] 1 A.C. 518 at para. 37.
property in private law, and the rationalization
4 National Labor Relations Act, 29 U.S.C.
of governmental power in public law), and 151–69.
the result of the influence on the law of 5 Justice Blackmun in First National Maintenance
the social and economic changes which Corporation v NLRB 452 U.S. 666, at 676 (1981).
accompanied the rise of industrial societies.
Divergence across labor law systems is in
part the legacy of the common law/civil REFERENCES
law divide, but it also reflects variations
in the timing of industrialization, the forms Addison, J., Bellmann, L., Schnabel, C. and Wagner, J.
of worker organization and the nature of (2004) ‘The reform of the German Works Constitution
industrial enterprise in different countries. Act: a critical assessment’, Industrial Relations, 43 (2):
Yet, there is also a high degree of functional 392–420.
Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism.
continuity across labor law systems, not least
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
in the common identification of ‘subordinated
Armour, J. and Skeel, D. (2007) ‘Who writes the rules for
labor’ within an ‘employment relationship’ as hostile takeovers, and why? – the peculiar divergence
the focal point of labor law regulation. of US and UK takeover regulation’, Georgetown Law
According to Sinzheimer (1922; cited in Journal, 95: forthcoming.
Kahn-Freund, 1981: 101), ‘in times of sudden Ashiagbor, D. (2005) The European Employment
change, where the old disappears and the new Strategy: Labour Market Regulation and New
craves recognition, a purely technical insight Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
into the existing legal order is not sufficient’. Barmes, L., Collins, H. and Kilpatrick, C. (eds) (2007)
At the start of the twenty-first century, labor ‘Reconstructing Employment Contracts’, special edi-
law seems to be going through just such a tion, Industrial Law Journal, 36: 1–140.
Baums, T. (2003) ‘Company law reform in Germany’,
period, when changes to organizational forms,
Journal of Corporate Law Studies, 3 (?): 181–9.
coupled with the delocalization of production,
Black, B. and Coffee, J. (1994) ‘Hail Britannia? Insti-
are undermining familiar conceptual cate- tutional investor behavior under limited regulation’,
gories. It is not surprising therefore that some Michigan Law Review, 92: 1997–2087.
scholars identify at the core of labor law a Brodie, D. (1996) ‘The heart of the matter: mutual
‘failing paradigm’ (Hyde, 2006: 45), which trust and confidence’, Industrial Law Journal, 25:
has to be corrected by a fundamental re- 121–36.
evaluation of core concepts. In this chapter we Botero J., Djankov S., La Porta R., Lopez-de-Silanes F.
have provided concrete examples of the way and Shleifer A. (2004) ‘The regulation of labor’,
in which these concepts have constrained the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119: 1340–82.
capacity of labor law to address contemporary Coffee, J. (1999) ‘The future as history: prospects
for convergence in corporate governance and its
problems, while also pointing out how even
implications’, Northwestern University Law Review,
such foundational notions as those of contract
93 (?): 641–747.
and property are being adapted to new Collins, H. (1997) ‘The productive disintegration of
conditions. A methodology which seeks to labour law’, Industrial Law Journal, 26: 295–309.
understand how labor law’s conceptual core Collins, H. (2001) ‘Regulating the employment relation
came to be as it is, when allied to the for competitiveness’, Industrial Law Journal, 30:
techniques of the social sciences in explaining 17–47.
302 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Collins, H. (2002) ‘Is there a third way in labour law?’ in Freedland, M. (2003) The Personal Employment
J. Conaghan, R.M. Fischl, and K. Klare (eds) Labor Law Contract. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
in an Era of Globalisation: Transformative Practices Freeman, R. and Pelletier, J. (1990) ‘The impact
and Possibilities. Oxford: Oxford University Press. of industrial relations legislation on British union
pp. 449–69. density’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 28:
Collins, H. (2003) Employment Law. Oxford: Oxford 141–64.
University Press. Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (2003) ‘Finance,
Cottereau, A (2000) ‘Industrial tribunals and the corporate governance and the management of
establishment of a kind of common law of labour labour: a conceptual and comparative analy-
in nineteenth century France’, in W. Steinmetz (ed.) sis’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41:
Private Law and Social Inequality in the Industrial Age. 557–82.
Comparing Legal Cultures in Britain, France, Germany Goyer, M. and Hancké, B. (2003) ‘Labour in French
and the United States. Oxford: Oxford University corporate governance: the missing link’, in H. Gospel
Press. pp. 203–26 and A. Pendleton (eds) Corporate Governance and
Cottereau, A. (2002) ‘Droit et bon droit. Un droit Labour Management: An International Comparison.
des ouvriers instauré, puis évincé par le droit du Oxford: Oxford University Press.
travail (France XIXe siècle)’ Annales HSS, novembre- Green, F. and McIntosh, S. (1998) ‘Union power, cost
décembre no. 6: 1521–1557. of job loss and workers’ effort’ Industrial and Labor
Davies, P. and Freedland, M. (2007) Towards a Flexible Relations Review, 51: 363–83.
Labour Market: Labour Legislation and Regulation Hansmann, H. and Kraakman, R. (2001) ‘The end of
since the 1990s. Oxford: Oxford University Press. history for corporate law’, Georgetown Law Journal,
Deakin, S., Hobbs, R., Konzelmann, S. and Wilkinson, 89: 439–68.
F. (2002) ‘Partnership, ownership and control: the Hay, D. and Craven, P. (eds) (2004) Masters, Servants
impact of corporate governance on employment and Magistrates in Britain and the Empire. Chapel
relations’, Employee Relations, 24: 335–52. Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.
Deakin, S. and Morris, G. (2005) Labour Law 3rd edn. Hepple, B. and Brown, W. (1981) ‘Tasks for labour law
Oxford: Hart Publishing. research’, Legal Studies, 1: 56–67.
Deakin, S. and Wilkinson, F. (1991) ‘Labour law, social Höpner, M. (2005) ‘What connects industrial rela-
security and economic inequality’, Cambridge Journal tions and corporate governance? Explaining institu-
of Economics, 15: 125–48. tional complementarity’, Socio-Economic Review, 3:
Deakin, S. and Wilkinson, F. (2005) The Law of the 331–57.
Labour Market: Industrialization, Employment and Hopt, K. and Wymeersch, E. (eds) (1997) Comparative
Legal Evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Corporate Governance: Essays and Materials. Berlin:
Dickens, L. and Hall, M. (2005) ‘The impact of Walter de Gruyter.
employment legislation: reviewing the research’, in Hutchins, B. and Harrison, A. (1911) A History of Factory
L. Dickens, M. Hall and S. Wood (eds), Review of Legislation 2nd edn. London: P.S. King & Son.
Research into the Impact of Employment Relations Hyde, A. (2006) ‘What is labor law?’, in G. Davidov and
Legislation Employment Relations Research Series B. Langille (eds) Boundaries and Frontiers of Labour
No. 45 (London: DTI). Law. Oxford: Hart Publishing.
Dickens, L., Weekes, B., Jones, M., and Hart, M. (1985) Jacoby, S. (1985) ‘The duration of indefinite employment
Dismissed: A Study of Unfair Dismissal and the contracts in the United States and England: an
Industrial Tribunal System. Oxford: Blackwell. historical analysis’, Comparative Labor Law, 5:
Easterbrook, F. and Fischel, D. (1991) The Economic 85–128.
Structure of Corporate Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Jacoby, S. (2005) The Embedded Corporation: Corporate
University Press. Governance and Employment Relations in Japan and
European Commission (2006) Employment in Europe the United States. Princeton: Princeton University
(Luxembourg: OOPEC). Press.
Finkin, M. (2006) ‘Comparative labour law’, in Kahn-Freund, O. (1954) ‘Legal framework’, in
M. Reimann and and R. Zimmermann (eds) A. Flanders and H. Clegg (eds) The System of Industrial
Comparative Law. Frankfurt: Springer. Relations in Britain. Oxford: Blackwell.
Fredman, S. (1997) Women and the Law. Oxford: Oxford Kahn-Freund, O. (1977) Labour and the Law 2nd edn.
University Press. London: Stevens.
Freedland, M. (1976) The Contract of Employment. Kahn-Freund, O. (1981) ‘Hugo Sinzheimer 1875–1945’,
Oxford: Oxford University Press. in O. Kahn-Freund, Labour Law and Politics in the
THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS 303

Weimar Republic (eds R. Lewis and J. Clark). Oxford: Prothero, I. (1979) Artisans and Politics in Early
Blackwell. Nineteenth Century London: John Gast and His Times.
Kim, P. (1997) ‘Bargaining with imperfect information: Folkestone: Dawson.
a study of worker perceptions of legal protection in Rogers, J. and Streeck, W. (1994) ‘Worker representation
an at-will world’, Cornell Law Review, 83: 105–60. overseas: the works council story’, in R. Freeman
Kolins Givan, R. (2007) ’Side by side we battle (ed.) Working Under Different Rules. Washington, DC:
onward? Representing workers in contemporary NBER.
America’, British Journal of Industrial Relations 45: Rogowski, R. and Wilthagen, T. (1994) Reflexive Labour
forthcoming. Law. Deventer: Kluwer.
Lane, C. (2003) Changes in the corporate governance Siems, M. (2005) ‘What does not work in securities
of German corporations: convergence on the Anglo- law: a critique of La Porta et al.’s methodology’
American model? Centre for Business Research International Company and Commercial Law Review,
Working Paper No. 259, University of Cambridge. 7: 300–5.
Laulom, S. (2001) ‘The European Court of Justice in Simitis, S. (2000) ‘The case of the employment relation-
the dialogue on transfers of undertakings: a fallible ship: elements of a comparison’, in W. Steinmetz (ed.)
interlocutor?’, in S. Sciarra (ed.) Labour Law in the Private Law and Social Inequality in the Industrial Age.
Courts: National Judges and the European Court of Comparing Legal Cultures in Britain, France, Germany
Justice. Oxford: Hart Publishing. and the United States. Oxford: Oxford University
Learmount, S. (2002) Corporate Governance: What Can Press. pp. 181–202.
We Learn from Japan? Oxford: Oxford University Singer, J. (1993) ‘Jobs and justice: rethinking the
Press. stakeholder debate’, University of Toronto Law
Mitchell, R. and Arup, C. (2006) ‘Labour law and labour Journal, 43: 475–531.
market regulation’, in C. Arup, P. Gahan, J. Howe, Sims, V. (2002) Good Faith in Contract Law:
R. Johnstone, R. Mitchell, and A. O’Donnell (eds) A Comparative Analysis of English and German Law.
Labor Law and Labor Market Regulation. Sydney: PhD. Thesis, University of Cambridge, 2002.
Federation Press. Stone, K. (2002) ‘Knowledge at work: disputes over
Mückenberger, U. and Supiot, A. (2000) ‘Ordre public the ownership of human capital in the changing
social et communauté. Deux cultures du droit du workplace’, University of Connecticut Law Review,
travail’, in B. Zimmermann, C. Didry and P. Wagner 34: 721–764.
(eds) Le travail et la nation. Paris: Éditions de la Stone, K. (2007) ‘Revisiting the at-will employment
Maison des Sciences de l’Homme. pp. 81–105 doctrine: imposed terms, implied terms, and the
Njoya, W. (2007) Property in Work: The Employment normative world of the workplace’, Industrial Law
Relationship in the Anglo-American Firm. Aldershot: Journal, 36: 84–101.
Ashgate. Supiot, A. (1994) Critique du droit du travail (Paris: PUF).
OECD (2004) Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Tawney, R.H. (1914) The Establishment of Minimum
OECD (2006) Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Rates in the Chainmaking Industry under the Trade
Palmer, R. (1993) English Law in the Age of the Black Boards Act of 1909. London: Bell.
Death, 1348–1381: A Transformation of Governance Tawney, R.H. (1915) The Establishment of Minimum
and Law. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Rates in the Tailoring Industry under the Trade Boards
Press. Act of 1909. London: Bell.
Parkinson, J. (2003) ‘Models of the company and the Tawney, R.H. (1967) The Agrarian Problem in the
employment relationship’, British Journal of Industrial Sixteenth Century. L. Stone, New York: Harper &
Relations, 41: 481–509. Row.
Petit, H., and Sauze, D. (2006) ‘Une lecture his- Topel, R. (1990) ‘Specific capital and unemployment:
torique de la relation salariale comme structure measuring the costs and consequences of job loss’,
de repartition des aléas. En partant du travail de in A. Meltzer and C. Plosser (eds) Studies in Labour
Salais’, in F. Eymard-Duvernay (ed.) L’économie des Economics in Honor of Walter Oi. Amsterdam:
conventions : méthodes et résultats. Tome II : Elsevier.
Développements. Paris: La Découverte. pp. 303–16. Toynbee, A. (1969) Lectures on the Industrial Revolution
Pistor, K. (1999) ‘Codetermination in Germany: a in England, in T.S. Ashton. (ed.) Newton Abbott: A.M.
socio-political model with governance externalities’, Kelley.
in M. Blair and M. Roe (eds) Employees and Veneziani, B. (1986) ‘The evolution of the contract of
Corporate Governance. Washington, DC: Brookings employment’, in B. Hepple (ed.) The Making of Labour
Institution. Law in Europe. London: Mansell.
304 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1910) English Poor Law Policy. Weiler, P. (1990) Governing the Workplace. Cambridge,
London: Longmans, Green & Co. MA: Harvard University Press.
Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1927a) English Poor Law Weiss, M. (1988) ‘Individual employment rights:
History: Part I. The Old Poor Law. London: Longmans, focusing on job security in the Federal Republic
Green & Co. of Germany’, Nebreska Law Review, 67 (?):
Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1927b) English Poor Law 82–100.
History Volume II: The Last Hundred Years. London: Wood, S. and Godard, J. (1999) ‘The statutory union
Longmans, Green & Co. recognition procedure in the Employment Relations
Wedderburn, Lord (1986) The Worker and the Law 3rd Bill: a comparative analysis’, British Journal of
edn. Harmondsworth: Penguin. Industrial Relations, 37: 203–45.
Weekes, B., Mellish, M., Dickens, L. and Lloyd, J. (1971) Woodward, D. (1980) ‘The background to the Statute
Industrial Relations and the Limits of Law. Oxford: of Artificers: the genesis of labour policy, 1558-63’
Blackwell. Economic History Review (NS), 33: 32–44.
16
The State as Employer
Marick F. Masters, Ray Gibney,
Iryna Shevchuk, and Tom Zagenczyk

The state’s role as employer depends on and practice. Amid such diversity, however,
several aspects of governance, including emerge recognizable cross-national trends.
questions regarding the functions of the The globalization of economic and political
state, the organizations through which the affairs creates common pressures to adjust
state operates, and the adopted management the role of the state at both the macro
approach (Lane, 2000). The functions a state and micro levels (Kettl, 2005). Events in
chooses to undertake affect the scope of one part of the world may rapidly influence
its employment both directly and indirectly. considerations in distantly located areas
Organizationally, states may opt to employ as the communication of new ideas and
workers directly or contract services through practices is nearly instantaneous given today’s
private entities. Government decides how it technology. Formal structures of economic
will manage its workforce, selecting a model and political integration, such as the European
of staffing, compensation, and employee Union, intensify existing tendencies for con-
involvement that it wants to follow. The nature vergence. New models of public management
of any given state’s role as employer reflects emerge to challenge the traditional within a
a confluence of economic, legal, political, and complex mosaic.
social factors. States may also use their role as In this chapter, we address developments
employer to engineer important public-policy and practices relevant to the multifaceted role
and societal goals. The role of the state thus of the state as employer. We focus mainly on
manifests the realities of interacting forces activities at the central level of government
and choices made in response to a changing in countries associated with the Organization
environment. for Economic Cooperation and Development
The state as employer varies widely (OECD), highlighting those nations that have
in function, organization, and management been at the cusp of change and influence on a
across countries (Bordogna, 2003). Diverging cross-national scale.
patterns of culture, history, and ideology We organize this paper into several
contribute to the variation evident in policy sections. The first presents a conceptual
306 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

framework to guide the analysis of trends governance issues and affect the resources
and developments in the role of the state as available to finance governmental operations,
employer on a cross-national basis. Section including personnel. Governance involves
two examines trends in the role and size of the decisions about
public sector, focusing on privatization and
the scope of public employment. We examine 1) functions and size of government and the
key trends in human resource management allocation of responsibilities across different levels
(HRM) practices in section three. Section four of the public sector;
addresses the public governance initiatives 2) how the state organizes its operations in terms of
undertaken in the US as an illustration of being a direct provider or contractor; and
recent public management trends. We focus 3) the management policies and practices which it
not only on the reinvention initiative of the chooses to follow.
Clinton-Gore years (1993–2000) but also on
President George W. Bush’s Management These decisions are highly interrelated, and
Agenda and the major reforms of his admin- the choices available are not necessarily
istration. We conclude in section five with a mutually exclusive. The other aspect of this
brief overview of how well the new public framework focuses on results, that is, the
management has performed at what needs to outputs and outcomes of what government
be addressed in the future. does. Public financing links the environment
to governance. Performance links governance
to those it serves. In this framework, variation
AN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS (IR) exists in the functions of government, how
FRAMEWORK OF THE STATE AS government should provide its operations, and
EMPLOYER the manner in which it should manage those
who perform its work.
We present an industrial relations (IR) systems
framework to examine the role of the state as
Environmental contexts
employer (see Figure 16.1). The framework
focuses on three main elements, of which Several major environmental trends have
governance is at the center. Various envi- impacted the role of the state as employer
ronmental contexts influence decisions about on a transnational basis: democratization and

Public financing

Economic
context Governance
Performance results
• Functions and
Political-legal size of
context government
Outputs
• Organization of
operations
Outcomes
Social-demographic • Management
context policies and
practices
Technological
context

Public financing

Figure 16.1 IR systems framework of the state as employer


THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 307

privatization; economic globalization; and burdens of excessive taxation and regulation.


demography. First, the collapse of the Soviet On the other hand, political realities make it
Union and the concomitant end of the Cold impossible for societies to abandon major seg-
War has unleashed the forces of democracy ments of social-welfare support, particularly
and free markets. Previously state-controlled with aging populations. Increasingly, states
societies have established democratic insti- must find ways to navigate these challenges.
tutions and de-nationalized industries. The A wave of governmental reforms, accelerated
shift to market-based economies has meant globally by the instantaneous communication
the role of the state as owner and employer of new ideas, is a major result of the changing
has shrank. In addition, the end of the Cold environment.
War has subdued international pressures to
build up enormous national defenses with
Governance
a supporting civilian sector, either publicly
employed or contracted. At the same time, As mentioned, governance involves three
however, the international wave of terrorism basic sets of questions for societies and their
has created a new set of defense burdens policymakers in particular (see Table 16.1).
which have required a global response. In the The first concerns the function and size
US especially, the interrelated requirements of of the state. States decide which functions
homeland and national security have changed to perform, how extensively they want to
how government proposes to operate large undertake them, and the degree to which
segments of its civilian federal workforce. responsibility will be centralized or decen-
Second, economic globalization has tralized across various levels of government
required that nations become more (for example, national or central; regional
competitive in order to sustain and promote or state; local or municipal). The range and
prosperity. Globalization has encouraged scope of functions a state chooses directly
states to reduce governmental barriers to affects its size as employer, with obvious
competition. For example, the European public-financing consequences.
Union has guidelines on acceptable levels of We may distinguish between two basic
government deficits. Societies must examine types of governmental activities: inherently
how the state can facilitate markets rather than governmental, or public, and commercial.
regulating them to conform to social-welfare, The former are those activities which provide
redistributionist models of governance. genuine public goods and therefore cannot
Third, in many societies, the changing be expected to be sufficiently served by
demographic composition of the population private markets. Common examples include
and workforce has stimulated rather than national defense, police and fire, primary
dampened demand for public services, with and secondary education and income main-
attendant employment implications. Across tenance. The second set includes activities
Europe, Japan, and in the US, for example, that produce benefits more directly tied to
aging populations have resulted in growing the user, and they may thus also be met via
health care needs, much of which have been the private sector. Airlines, railroads, energy,
traditionally met through public organiza- and telecommunications fall into this cate-
tions. Similarly, retiree pensions and health gory. There are arguably many ‘commercial’
care costs have grown and absorbed a growing activities in which there is a public interest. In
share of overall public expenditures in many addition, there are many commercial activities
societies. (for instance health care, post-secondary
These environmental trends, with their education) which serve government. Thus,
competing implications, put many states in the line between inherently governmental and
a difficult crosswind. On the one hand, they commercial is often unclear. The choices
must respond to the requirements of intense a state makes as to how much to cross
global competition by relieving markets of the the line – on one side or the other – reflects
308 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 16.1 Dimensions of governance


Function, size, distribution Organizational type Management model
Inherently governmental and Publicly owned and provided Bureaucratic civil service
commercial
Share of GDP and total Contracted or outsourced Collective bargaining
employment
Central or federal distribution Public-private hybrid Business process or
reinvention
New public management

its prevailing political ideology and notions by government to perform its functions.
of efficiency. The degree to which the state plays a role
A second aspect of governance concerns directly as employer varies, though it may
the form of organization adopted. The critical influence employment practices through its
issue is whether the state intends to own and regulatory powers where it is not the direct
operate the means of production. Three con- employer. Regardless, through governmental
ceptually distinguishable possibilities exist. charter, employment, or subsidization, the
First, government may choose to own the state may exert a significant role on a nation’s
assets of production and directly employ those employment picture across these organization
who provide the relevant good or service. types.
This approach seems consistent with those Finally, in choosing a managerial model,
inherently governmental functions. This is a the state makes additional choices since any
core sphere of governmental operations in model encompasses a set of policies and
which workers and managers are employees practices which give the model its conceptual
of the state. distinction. We identify several models to
Second, government may choose to con- capture the breadth of approaches a state
tract out or outsource the actual work of may take:
producing goods and delivering services
while still maintaining ownership of the
final product. Privately owned firms receive • bureaucratic-civil service;
• collective-bargaining;
payment for fulfilling the government’s req-
• business-process or reinvention; and
uisition. They also employ those who do the • the New Public Management (NPM) (see Godine,
work, though government may impose more 1951; Kettl, 2005; Lane, 2000).
labor-related regulations because the work is
being paid for by taxpayers.
A third organization type is a hybrid public- These approaches are not mutually exclusive.
private entity, of which there are several They differ, however, in focus and the extent
variants, some of which are similar to an to which they define the functions and size of
outsourced function. One example is a jointly government as employer.
owned and operated enterprise in which The bureaucratic-civil service model relies
profits are shared (Lane, 2000; Trebilock, on a permanent employment contract in
1995). Another is a franchise in which the which rewards are based largely on longevity;
work is contracted but paid for by users, not hiring is based on merit; and work duties
general revenues. The state may also choose are carefully defined within a hierarchical
to establish a government-owned corporation structure. Political entities establish budgets
that runs on a for-profit basis and that is not with funds earmarked for specific activi-
part of the general budget. ties over which there is limited discretion.
In short, there are several different types The collective-bargaining model involves
of organizational structures that can be used labor unions in setting various terms and
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 309

conditions of employment as opposed to a TRENDS IN THE ROLE AND SIZE


centralized civil service personnel agency OF GOVERNMENT
issuing employment regulations. Unions may
participate in compensation, work schedule, Globalization, international competition, and
and job classification decisions. They may advances in technology during the past
also enjoy, in some instances, access to dispute 25 years have led to higher levels of
resolution procedures, or the right to strike, downsizing, outsourcing, and restructuring in
though the latter is much more restricted today’s organizations (Csoka, 1995), result-
than in the private sector. By delegating ing in changes in the relationship between
collective-bargaining powers to unions and employer and employee (Kissler, 1994). The
managers, the state arguably voids claims of state has not been immune to pressures
exclusive sovereignty over such matters (for a faced by private-sector organizations. Since
discussion of sovereignty, see Godine, 1951; 1990, the state’s role as an employer in
Rosenbloom, 1971). OECD countries has changed in important
The business-process, or reinvention, ways, such as the size of government, which
model focuses on applying modern personnel functions government performs, the number
practices to maximize performance. These of individuals employed, and increased pri-
include employee involvement, incentive- vatization and outsourcing of government
based pay systems, job flexibility, and services.
increased training and skill development.
The objective is to make government more
Trends in the size of government
efficient and productive, with the focus
being on how government works not what One important trend that affects the role of
it does. the state as an employer is the size of the
The NPM model takes reinvention a step government, measured using the percentage
further. It focuses not only on how but of government expenditure relative to GDP
what. It questions the role of government, (Gwartney et al., 1998; OECD, 2005b).
whether functions should be privatized or Although the US economy performed well
outsourced. It also introduces more flexibility in the 1990s, the growth in GDP was less
into the work systems; incentives; short- than half that achieved during the 1960s.
term contracts; and performance management Some argue that economic growth has been
(at the individual and budgetary levels). slower than possible because the size of
In essence, NPM is more encompassing government is growing at a rate that restricts
than the business-process, or reinvention, economic performance (Gwartney et al.,
model. 1998). Gwartney et al. (1998) contend that
The final dimension of the IR framework the government should provide two main
focuses on results (Figure 16.1), or the outputs functions: (1) legal and physical infrastructure
and outcomes of governmental activities. for the operation of a market economy, and
Outputs are the immediate effects, such as (2) a limited set of goods. Economic growth
patients served by a governmental hospital, will be adversely affected when governments
the number of tax returns processed, etc. provide services beyond these core functions
Outcomes concern the quality and cost effec- because such involvement creates disincen-
tiveness of governmental operations; whether tives due to higher taxes. Freeman (2002),
government achieves the fundamental public- parenthetically, offers a different perspective,
policy goals that were intended in an efficient suggesting that institutional arrangements
manner. associated with labor protections may not
The framework provides a basis for exam- hinder economic performance. He (2002:19)
ining recent trends in governance. We begin argues that ‘once a country has a strong
with an examination of the role and size of the tradition of basic market freedoms … it has
state. considerable leeway in the precise way it
310 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

structures institutions.’ Moreover, markets been held by public sector employees are
can be more efficient in finding new ways to now in the realm of the private sector.
create value. Second, reformers have attempted to make
Despite these arguments, government size the employment relationship between public
has grown consistently between 1960 and the sector employees and their employers more
present. In recent years (1995–2004), even like the relationship between private sector
though reducing the size of government has employees and their employers: long-term job
been identified as a priority and privatization security has been reconsidered, public sector
and outsourcing have increased (OECD, jobs have become increasingly competitive,
2005b), the size of government relative to and site or individual wage bargaining has
GDP has grown in 17 of 30 OECD countries become increasingly prevalent relative to
(see Table 16.2). For example, in the UK, collective bargaining (OECD, 2005b).
government expenditures as a percentage of During the 1990s, many governments
GDP grew from 19.6 per cent in 1995 to attempted to reduce the size of government
21.1 per cent in 2001. by reducing the number of public sector
employees. In some cases, public sector
employment has been reduced at the central
Government functions
or federal administrative levels. In Japan,
Changes in size naturally affect the functions Spain, and the US, however, public sector
governments of OECD countries provide for employment has been cut at local and regional
their citizens. Across the OECD member levels (OECD, 2005b). Table 16.4 shows
countries, a core set of functions provided by public employment for OECD countries for
government includes the provision of defense, the years 1995 through 2003. The number
education, health, police, and social services of public sector employees has decreased in
(OECD, 2002b). However, the provision of 8 of the 14 countries, while it has increased
these core functions varies by the level of in 6 countries. However, when the percentage
administration across countries, except for of public sector jobs is considered relative
the provision of defense. As is evident in to total jobs (Table16.4), public sector jobs
Table 16.3, national defense is provided comprise a smaller portion of total jobs in
by the central or federal administration in 9 of 14 countries. For example, in the UK
all reporting OECD member countries. The overall employment increased from 5,368,000
provision of other core functions, however, in 1995 to 5,634,000 in 2003, but public
varies by country. For example, France has sector employment as a percentage of total
centralized the education process at the employment decreased from 21 per cent
national level, while the administration of to 20 per cent over the same time span.
education is maintained at the municipal or Overall, these numbers indicate that the
local and ‘state’levels, for instance California, relative number of public sector jobs is
in the US. decreasing. However, the results presented in
Table 16.2 suggest the size of government,
as a percentage of GDP expenditures, is
Public sector employment
growing in the majority of OECD countries.
The past 20 years have brought impor- Thus, the size of government is growing
tant changes to the employer-employee with respect to government expenditures as
relationship for public sector employees a percentage of GDP, but is decreasing in
(OECD, 2005b). Demands to reduce the terms of relative employment levels. At the
size of government and increase efficiency same time, there is some evidence that gov-
and responsiveness have led to questions ernments experience difficulty in contracting
regarding the nature of employment in the out work when governmental agencies may
public sector. First, due to privatization and bid for this work (Gansler and Lucyshyn,
outsourcing, many jobs that had traditionally 2004).
Table 16.2 General government final consumption expenditure (percent of GDP)
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Australia 18.5 18.1 18.1 18.3 18.1 17.9 17.8 17.8 – –
Austria 20.4 20.3 19.7 19.5 19.8 19.2 18.9 18.6 18.7 –
Belgium 21.4 21.7 21.2 21.1 21.2 21.2 21.7 22.3 22.8 –
Canada 21.5 20.7 19.7 19.8 19.2 18.6 19.0 19.2 – –
Czech Republic 21.7 21.2 21.8 21.0 22.3 22.1 22.2 23.0 24.0 22.8
Denmark 25.8 25.9 25.5 26.0 25.8 25.3 25.9 26.3 26.5 –
Finland 22.8 23.2 22.3 21.6 21.6 20.6 21.0 21.7 22.1 –
France 23.9 24.2 24.2 23.4 23.3 23.2 23.2 23.9 24.3 –
Germany 19.8 19.9 19.5 19.2 19.1 19.0 19.0 19.2 19.3 –
Greece 15.3 14.5 15.1 15.3 15.4 15.7 15.3 15.7 15.5 –
Hungary 11.0 10.2 10.5 10.2 10.2 9.7 10.2 10.8 10.8 10.5
Iceland 22.3 22.2 22.0 22.5 23.4 23.9 23.8 25.5 26.4 –
Ireland 16.4 15.8 15.1 14.4 14.0 13.9 14.8 15.1 – –
Italy 17.9 18.1 18.2 17.9 18.0 18.3 18.8 19.0 19.5 –
Japan 14.6 14.8 14.8 15.3 15.9 16.4 17.1 17.7 17.5 –
Korea 11.2 11.6 11.6 12.8 12.3 12.1 12.9 12.9 13.3 –
Luxembourg 18.4 18.9 17.9 16.8 16.8 15.7 17.0 17.8 18.6 –
Mexico 10.4 9.6 9.9 10.4 11.0 11.1 11.8 12.1 12.4 11.7
Netherlands 24.0 23.1 22.9 22.7 22.9 22.7 23.4 24.5 – –
New Zealand 17.7 17.5 18.3 18.3 18.6 17.6 17.6 17.6 – –
Norway 21.6 20.9 20.5 21.9 21.4 19.1 20.6 22.1 22.6 –
Poland 19.8 19.6 19.2 18.7 18.8 19.0 19.0 19.0 18.5 17.7
Portugal 18.6 18.9 19.0 18.9 19.7 20.5 20.8 21.1 – –
Slovak Republic 21.2 23.0 22.0 22.4 20.7 20.7 21.0 20.9 20.8 20.3
Spain 18.1 17.9 17.5 17.5 17.4 17.6 17.5 17.8 17.9 –
Sweden 27.2 27.8 27.2 27.4 27.4 26.6 27.1 28.1 28.3 –
Switzerland 11.7 11.8 11.5 11.3 11.1 11.1 11.6 11.7 – –
Turkey 10.8 11.6 12.3 12.7 15.2 14.1 14.2 14.0 13.6 13.1
UK 19.6 19.2 18.3 17.9 18.4 18.7 19.2 20.1 21.1 –
US 15.3 15.0 14.5 14.3 14.3 14.4 14.8 15.2 – –
Source: World Bank national accounts data, and OECD National Accounts data files.
312 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 16.3 Core government functions of selected OECD member countries


Sector Central or federal Regional Local
administration administration administration
Defense France
Finland
Greece
Hungary
Italy
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Spain
US
Education France Australia Finland
Hungary Germany Greece
Italy Ireland Hungary
Netherlands Spain Mexico
Luxembourg US US
Health France Australia Finland
Hungary France Germany
Spain Germany Greece
US Ireland Hungary
Japan Mexico
Spain US
US
Police Finland Ireland France
Hungary Japan Greece
Italy
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Spain
Social Hungary Australia Finland
Spain France France
Germany Germany
Ireland Greece
Japan US
US
Source: OECD (2002b).

Privatization (6) liberalization, or the removal of statutory


provisions which keep private sector firms from
Privatization, the transfer of assets from the entering public sector markets (Bach, 2000).
public to the private sector in terms of
ownership, management, finance, or control,
can occur in a number of ways, including Trends including pressures for effective and
efficient public services, technological change,
(1) the sale of assets from public to the private and public finance problems led to an increase
sector, the most common form of privatization; in the privatization of public services between
(2) the state contracting out services that it had 1995 and 2000 (see Table 16.5). During these
previously provided;
years, approximately US$650 billion worth
(3) internal market arrangements in which the purchase
of state-owned enterprises were transferred to
of services is separated from their provision;
(4) the assessment of user fees for state-provided the private sector in OECD countries alone.
services; Telecom companies were the largest source
(5) private-public partnerships, in which the of privatization revenue during this time
government finances, manages, and shares risk period, although manufacturing, banking,
with the private sector on joint projects; and defense, energy, transportation, and public
Table 16.4 Public employment
Country Public employment (thousands) Public employment as a percentage of total employment
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Australia 1545.9 1537.3 1457.8 1433.7 1427.5 1437.8 1427.5 1457.5 1468.6 19 19 17 17 17 16 16 16 16
Austria 545.9 526.6 525.1 525.4 519.1 518.3 503.4 490.1 484.2
Canada 2957.8 2851.3 2789.4 2779 2769.9 2785.8 2813.5 2847 2912.9 22 21 20 20 19 19 19 19 19
Czech Republic 1170 1110.7 1065.7 1110.9 1083.6 1058.4 24 23 23 23 23 22
Denmark 927.7 938.4 934.8 947.4 946 937.9 946.8 926.6 35 35 35 34 34 34 34 34
Finland 549.1 557.5 569 567.1 570.1 576.6 584.8 597.5 602.8 27 27 26 26 25 25 25 25 26
Germany 7116 6991 6846 6726 6631 6534 6259 6185 6079 19 19 18 18 17 17 16 16 16
Greece 825.4 842.6 841.4 845.5 849.6 841.7 22 22 22 21 22 21
Hungary 820.4 1063 967.9 947.1 933.8 837.7 839.4 863 876 35 47 44 42 37 31 31 31 31
Italy 3670.2 3633.9 3584.5 3543.3 3531.5 3508.2 16 16 16 15 15 15
Luxembourg 26.8 28 28.8 30.1
Mexico 4595.2 4626.6 4812.7 4812.1 4796.2 4785.3 17 16 15 15 15 15
Netherlands 1471.4 1500 1583.9 1648.8 1662.9 1704.8 26 25 25 25 26 26
New Zealand 245.6 251.2 247.2 247.7 244 216.3 223.6 233.2 239.2 19 19 18 18 18 20 20 20 20
Norway 798.3 814.8 836.1 850.1 861.5 854.8 847.5 866.1 865.1 38 38 38 37 38 37 37 37 38
Poland 5623.1 5412.5 5072.8 4671.3 4338.8 4318.1 4027.7 3905.1 3780.2 37 35 32 29 28 28 27 30 30
Slovakia 879.1 818.6 747.8 707.3 676.4 657.1 631.3 591.3 552.6 44 40 37 35 34 33 31 29 27
Spain 2219.5 2319.7 2359.4 2322.4 2354.2 2437 2495.2 2566.2 2687.6 18 18 18 17 16 16 15 15 16
Sweden 1263.1 1257.1 1237.1 1230.6 1246.3 1208.9 1203.7 1214.6 1235.2 41 39 37 36 36 34 34 34 34
Turkey 2888 2979 2881 3046 3103 3109 3157 3225 3213 14 14 14 14 14 14 15 15 15
UK 5368 5269 5175 5163 5206 5288 5378 5484 5634 21 20 20 19 19 19 19 20 20
US 19432 19539 19664 19909 20307 20790 21118 21513 21583 17 16 16 16 16 16 16 17 17
Source: ILO/ LABORSTA.
Table 16.5 Country breakdown of amounts raised by privatization (Billions of $US)
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Australia 19 1,042 1,893 2,057 2,055 8,089 9,052 16,815 7,146 15,220 6,273
Austria 32 48 49 142 700 1,035 1,302 2,438 2,537 70 2,086
Belgium − − − 956 548 2,745 1,222 1,842 2,288 10 −
Canada 1,504 808 1,249 755 490 3,998 1,768 − 11 − −
Czech Republic − 59 877 837 1,065 976 902 395 437 737 520
Denmark 644 − − 122 229 10 366 45 4,502 19 111
Finland − − − 229 1,120 363 911 835 1,999 3,716 1,827
France − − − 12,160 5,479 4,136 3,096 10,105 13,597 9,478 17,438
Germany 11 351 − 73 678 191 1,421 3,125 11,357 2,754 1,750
Greece − − − 35 73 44 558 1,395 3,960 4,880 1,384
Hungary 102 385 705 1,308 955 2,645 849 647 197 88 66
Iceland − − 21 10 2 6 − 4 128 228 1
Ireland − 515 70 274 − 157 293 0 0 4,846 1,458
Italy − − 759 3,039 9,077 10,131 11,230 23,945 15,138 25,594 9,729
Japan − − − − 13,875 − 2,039 − 6,641 15,115 −
Korea − − − 1,451 3,782 643 3,091 645 201 2,153 18
Luxembourg − − − − − − − − − − −
Mexico 3,124 10,747 6,864 2,531 766 170 73 2,670 988 279 406
Netherlands 716 179 − 780 3,766 3,993 1,239 842 335 1,481 310
New Zealand 3,895 17 967 630 29 264 1,839 − 441 1,331 −
Norway 73 − − − 118 521 660 35 − 454 1,039
Poland 23 171 373 433 725 1,101 1,442 2,043 2,079 3,422 6,262
Slovak Republic − − − 63 415 1,004 486 11 − − 1,313
Spain 172 − 830 3,222 1,458 2,941 2,680 2,532 11,618 1,128 1,079
Sweden − − 378 252 2,313 852 785 2,390 172 2,071 8,082
Switzerland − − − − − − − − 6,442 − −
Turkey 486 244 423 566 412 572 292 466 1,020 38 2,712
UK 4,219 5,346 7,923 8,114 4,632 5,648 2,426 4,500 − − −
US − − − − − − − 3,650 3,100 − −
Grand Total 16,112 20,925 25,586 40,461 55,885 54,599 53,022 96,282 100,633 96,735 67,119
Source: ILO/ LABORSTA.
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 315

utilities sectors were also affected. European process whereby governments contract with
Union countries which sought to meet the private sector providers for the provision
conditions of the Maastricht Treaty, including of services to government ministries and
Italy, Austria, France, Spain, Portugal, and the agencies or directly to citizens on behalf
UK, were responsible for nearly 60 per cent of the government’ (OECD, 2005b: 131).
of privatization revenues (OECD, 2001). Outsourcing is utilized because introducing
While privatization activity was high in the competition for the provision of services, in
1990s, it decreased considerably following the theory, increases efficiency, usually through
turn of the century. A number of factors were
responsible for the slow down in privatization, • cost reduction;
including a downward slide in equity markets, • access to expertise unavailable in-house;
poor economic performance, and the fact that • access to quantity and diversity of expertise over
OECD countries have sold off the majority time; and
of saleable assets (OECD, 2002c). In fact, • replacement of poor-performing government
in 2001, privatization revenues of OECD operations (OECD, 2005b).
countries dwindled to only US$20 billion.
The decline of privatization in the telecom Outsourcing has increased in OECD coun-
sector in the 1990s was particularly important tries in recent years. A 2005 OECD (OECD,
to the reduction of privatization revenues, 2005b) report observes that differences in
as it was previously responsible for nearly utilization of outsourcing across countries
one-third of all privatization revenues. For a results from differences in public sector labor
breakdown of the privatization initiatives of markets. In particular, countries with less
selected countries, see Table 16.6. flexible public services, such as continental
European countries, are less apt to use
outsourcing as it is particularly expensive to
Outsourcing or contracting downsize public servants. On the other hand,
government services English-speaking and Nordic countries such
as the UK, the US, Norway, and Sweden
One of the key mechanisms through
utilize outsourcing more extensively.
which the state is able to privatize its
In addition to considering the extent to
operations is through outsourcing, ‘the
which different countries outsource, it is
also important to examine what services or
Table 16.6 Privatization initiatives in activities are outsourced. Generally, these
selected countries activities/services can be classified into three
Austria Banking, oil and gas groups:
Belgium Banking, insurance
Canada Transport and telecommunications
(1) blue-collar support services, which include jani-
Denmark Banking and transport
Finland Power generation, telecommunications, torial services, facilities and waste management,
air traffic food service, and guard service provision;
France Banking (2) high-value services that are ancillary to an
Germany Automobiles, chemicals agency’s core mission, such as information
Ireland Telecommunications technology, human resources management,
Italy Banking and insurance banking, and financial services; and
Netherlands Banking, chemicals, steel, public utilities (3) activities viewed as inherently governmen-
New Zealand Privatization of may state enterprises tal, such as prisons, emergency rescue/fire
Portugal Utilities and communications
services, food inspection, audit services, health,
Spain Iron, steel, textiles, public utilities
education, and welfare services (OECD, 2005b).
Sweden Some privatization of elderly care
UK Telecommunications, gas, airways, water
and sewage, rail, electricity, energy Overall, available evidence indicates that
US Limited sales of state assets outsourcing is positively related to service
Source: ILO (2001). quality and negatively related to costs
316 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

(see OECD, 2005b for a review of studies Union density is the percentage of union-
conducted on outsourcing and outcomes). ized workers in the labor force and can
Despite the fact that empirical evidence be aggregated based upon different charac-
suggests that outsourcing is advantageous, teristics of the labor force. Union density
obstacles often make it difficult to imple- is higher in the public sector than in the
ment. Generally, these obstacles stem from private sector throughout OECD member
public concerns regarding the private sector’s countries and public sector union density
participation in activities that have tradi- in most OECD countries has declined from
tionally been provided by the government. 1980s levels (see Table 16.7). For example,
In particular, when outsourcing threatens in the US 36 per cent of public sector
traditional governmental service provision, employees were unionized in 2004, but only
government employees, unions, and political 8 per cent of private sector employees were
allies may present resistance (OECD, 2005b). unionized. France’s 10 per cent differential
Accountability is also an issue that arises in public and private sector density was
with respect to outsourcing, especially when the smallest reported difference in 2003.
a service is provided from a private sector However, between 1981 and 2003, public
source on behalf of the government directly sector union density in France declined by
to citizens (OECD, 2005b). nearly two-thirds. Austria, Canada, Norway,
and Spain reported increases in public sector
union density with Norway’s 9 per cent gain
HRM TRENDS being the largest. In comparison, Australia,
Belgium, Germany, Italy, and the UK all
With regard to common trends, OECD mem- reported decreases of 10 per cent or greater.
ber countries are not significantly different
with respect to the public sector. While each
Performance management
organization or state may address the situation
differently based upon its culture (OECD, Most OECD member countries have perfor-
2005a), common trends in human resource mance management systems in place (OECD,
practices across institutions are evident in both 2005a). Systems commonly include three
the public and private sectors. elements: performance management objec-
tives, performance appraisal methods, and
pay-for-performance plans (OECD, 2004a).
Labor relations and unions Countries vary on the degree of HR delegation
Three broad categories of labor relations in and the strength of the link between an
OECD member countries are: individual’s performance appraisal and pay
(OECD, 2004a). For example, New Zealand
(1) the same employment laws cover public and has a high degree of HR delegation and a
private sector employees; strong link between pay and performance,
(2) civil servants covered under separate civil service whereas Japan does not.
employment laws; and There appear to be three objectives for these
(3) some civil servants covered under separate performance management systems:
laws and others covered under private sector
employment laws (OECD Observer, 2004). • improving internal functioning and performance;
• improving mechanisms to distribute and clarify
However, under all three conditions, labor responsibilities and control; and
unions exert a strong influence on civil • reducing budgets (OECD, 1997).
servants’ working conditions and pay lev-
els, but have a limited role in employee Each member country’s system empha-
performance, recruitment, and staffing levels sizes a specific objective. The different
(OECD Observer, 2004). objectives require different techniques for
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 317

Table 16.7 Union density, private and public sector (percent of unionized workers)
Country Year Private Public Year Private Public
Australia 1982 39 73 2004 17 46
Austria 1980 49 68 1998 30 69
Belgium 1982 41 79 1991 45 67
Canada 1984 28 64 2004 18 72
France 1981 18 44 2003 5 15
Germany 1980 29 67 1997 22 56
Italy 1980 48 60 1997 36 43
Japan 1980 29 75 2003 18 58
Netherlands 1980 26 60 2001 22 39
Norway 1980 47 74 1998 43 83
Spain 1991 14 26 1997 15 32
Switzerland 1980 24 71 1987 22 71
United Kingdom 1980 45 69 2004 17 59
United States 1980 17 37 2004 8 36
Source: ILO, 2000; Visser, 2006.

managing performance, however, the required In addition, recruitment and selection


techniques are complementary and mutually policies are also influenced by the new focus
reinforcing (OECD, 1997). on organizational and individual performance
Most member countries are utilizing a (OECD, 2005b). The new focus on individual
form of management by objectives, wherein performance has lessened the differences
managers and employees agree upon perfor- between private and public sector employ-
mance evaluation criteria (OECD, 2005b). In ment which has created increased competition
addition, quantifiable numerical criteria are for employees (OECD Observer, 2004).
being employed less often. Job analyses are OECD member countries generally utilize
also broader in nature. four different staffing approaches. The tra-
ditional public sector employment includes
guaranteed lifelong employment protected
Recruitment and selection by law (OECD, 2005b). However, in many
countries, civil servant employment laws have
As is noted in Table 16.8, HRM systems
been abolished and the same laws cover
have unique implications for recruitment and
public and private sector employees. A second
selection policies (OECD, 2005a). A career-
approach provides employment protection but
based system allows employees to enter public
employees remain in a certain position only
service only at the early stages of their
as long as their performance is sufficient.
careers, while position-based systems allow
A third approach utilizes short-term contracts
employees to enter public service at different
with no guaranteed employment following
points in time and make lateral transfers. For
the term of the contract. The final approach
example, France most closely approximates
utilizes contract employees instead of internal
a career-based system. The recruitment prac-
employees. The loss of lifelong employment
tices in France tend to utilize competitive
protection has reduced the attractiveness
examination and education to gain access
of public sector employment and made it
to entry level positions with limited access
more difficult to recruit qualified employees
to some middle level posts, and no outside
(OECD Observer, 2004).
access to more senior positions. In contrast,
New Zealand’s recruitment and selection pro-
cess emphasizes competitive posting for posi-
Compensation
tions utilizing professional experience, with
both senior and middle level management Staffing level reductions were undertaken to
positions being open to outside competition. decrease the central or federal administrations
318 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 16.8 Characteristics of career-based, department-based, and position-based civil


systems
Career-based public Department-based public Position-based public
services services services
Tendencies of status Covered by civil service Some covered by public Covered by public
employment laws. employment laws and employment laws.
other covered by civil
service employment laws.
Trend toward term No No Yes
contracts within
the civil service
Recruitment Competitive examination. Mix of recruitment of pools Recruitment of
Mix of individual and and individuals depending individuals. Very
pool recruitment early in on country, but early in open systems to
career. Few lateral career. Few lateral entries. lateral entries.
entries.
Emphasis on entry Emphasis on training at Mix Lifelong training
training versus entry in the civil service.
lifelong training
Existence of a senior Yes No Mix – yes and no.
civil service with
differential
management rules
Existence of central Limited or very limited Large autonomy or absence Large autonomy or
HRM body and line autonomy vis-à-vis of central HRM body. absence of central
ministries central HRM body. HRM body.
autonomy vis-à-vis
central HRM body
Career development, Performance Emphasis on promotion Emphasis on pay and
promotion, incentives/sanctions on incentive/sanction. Some promotion as
incentives promotion. Few pay pay incentive. incentive/sanction.
based incentives.
Decentralization Centralization of pay Partial delegation of pay. Partial or extensive
of pay systems. Little Little individualization delegation of pay.
individualization. of pay. Extensive
individualization
of pay.
Examples France, Greece, Hungary, Austria, Belgium, Germany, Australia,
Ireland, Japan, Korea, Italy, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand,
Luxembourg, Spain. Poland, Portugal. Norway, UK, US.
Source: OECD.2005a; 2005b.

wage bill (OECD, 2005b). Overall, this of performance-related pay (PRP) (OECD,
appears to have been a successful strategy 1997; 2002a; 2004b). The main reasons for
since the ratio of compensation costs to GDP introducing PRP include:
of OECD member countries has decreased
since 1990 (OECD, 2002a). Interestingly, • attracting and retaining talent;
public sector employment in most OECD • improving motivation;
countries (Table 16.4) and compensation • creating more visible accountability; and
levels have been decreasing (OECD, 2002a), • facilitating management change (OECD, 2004b).
but the overall size, expressed as the ratio
of government expenditures to GDP, of Motivation for implementation of PRP plans
government has been increasing (Table 16.2). varies by country, but is strongly linked to the
The major trend regarding compensation degree of authority delegated to line managers
in the OECD member countries is the use to make personnel decisions (OECD, 2005a).
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 319

There is a general trend in most OECD involvement, incentive-based pay systems,


countries to focus on individual perfor- job flexibility, and increased training and
mance and decentralize HRM decisions. The skill development. These practices are
decentralization has been accomplished by intended to increase the efficiency and
(a) transferring responsibility for HR activity productivity of government. The objective
to line managers, (b) simplifying rules and is to make government more efficient and
procedures by developing the main policy in productive. However, reinvention centres on
the central HRM office and leaving details how the government operates, not on what it
to the line managers, or (c) developing more does.
flexible policies. By focusing on individual This illustrates the key difference between
performance and decentralized decision- reinvention and NPM. Unlike reinvention,
making, line managers can more closely NPM is concerned not only with how
link employee’s pay with their performance the government operates, but also on what
(OECD, 2005a). In contrast to position- it does. NPM questions the fundamental
based systems, career-based systems foster role that government plays in society, such
cohesiveness by utilizing rewards based on as whether functions should be privatized
group performance (OECD, 2005a). The or outsourced. NPM also provides greater
proportion of pay-for-performance relative to flexibility in work systems than does rein-
total compensation is, on average, less than vention; incentives; short-term contracts; and
10 per cent for employees and 20 per cent for performance management (at the individual
managers (OECD, 2005a), proportions that and budgetary levels). While reinvention and
are rather small. Bonuses are being used to NPM utilize similar means, such as employee
supplement or replace merit increments and involvement, NPM is more encompassing
are generally larger than merit increments. than the reinvention model.
The US provides an interesting illustration
of public management reform. It embraced
NEW PARADIGMS OF PUBLIC reinvention under the Clinton-Gore adminis-
GOVERNANCE tration, pushing toward a NPM conceptual-
ization. However, the Bush II administration
In The Global Public Management has reversed many of these initiatives. It has
Revolution, Kettl (2005) argues that recent focused on managing for results, with HR
government change has been rapid and reforms tied to improving performance and
widespread. The global revolution in reducing costs.
public management generally follows
the ‘reinvention’ model adopted by the
The US: reinvention and beyond
Clinton-Gore administration in the US and
reinvention
new public management model adopted in
the mid-1980s in New Zealand. While Kettl In the US reinvention encapsulated a
(2005) argues that these are distinct, these set of reforms in governance that gained
models share commonalities. considerable popularity across all levels
of government, particularly the federal, in
the 1990s. Osborne and Gaebler’s (1992)
Key points/trends related to NPM
Reinventing government focused on improv-
and reinvention
ing the management of government, or
Important similarities exist between the how of government, rather than the
reinvention and NPM. Fundamentally, what of government. In the US, reinvention
the purpose of reinvention and NPM is to became a program to save, not eviscerate,
apply proven business practices to maximize the public sector. Focusing on the applica-
the performance of large, often inefficient tion of business practices to governance, it
governments. Reinvention relies on employee gained ready acceptance by the Clinton-Gore
320 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

administration immediately after assuming The Republican victory in the 1994 con-
office in 1993. Clinton-Gore embraced gressional elections produced heated debates
reinvention as a means of simultaneously pro- over federal spending (Kettl, 1998; 2005)
moting popular reforms to make government and broadened the initial focus of reinvention
more efficient and less costly while at the on how government works eventually to
same time dampening political pressures to include what government should do. In reality,
scale back the domestic programs that served reinvention at the federal level concentrated
the needy and subsidized improvements in the on the ‘costs less’ rather than ‘works better.’
public infrastructure. Downsizing the federal workforce became
As originally conceived, reinvention the principal way of cutting costs. During
focused on making government more the Clinton White House years, federal
business-like in its processes, infusing an civilian employment dropped by over 300,000
entrepreneurial spirit into traditionally staid positions and to its lowest levels since John F.
bureaucracies. Osborne and Gaebler’s (1992) Kennedy was president.
purpose was not to make government a In terms of the employment relationship,
for-profit business, but to make it more the most significant aspect of reinven-
efficient and effective by using proven tion concerned promoting labor-management
business methods. They defined their cooperation. The NPR (1993) reported that
entrepreneurial model as one in which public adversarial labor-management relations in the
sector institutions ‘constantly use their federal service had hindered performance
resources in new ways to heighten both their and impeded positive change. To change
efficiency and their effectiveness’ (Osborne this situation, NPR recommended estab-
and Gaebler, 1992: xix). An entrepreneurial lishing a governmental labor-management
government followed 10 operating principles, partnership policy, citing the success of
including injecting competition into service such partnerships in transforming private
delivery; transforming rule-driven into sector organizations (NPR, 1993: 87). As
mission-driven organizations; focusing on per the NPR recommendation, President
results or outcomes, not inputs; meeting the Clinton issued Executive Order 12871, on
needs of the customer not the bureaucracy; October 1, 1993, which mandated federal
decentralizing power and authority; and agency heads to create partnerships at
making government market-oriented. appropriate organizational levels to ‘involve
When President Clinton assumed office in employees and their union representatives as
1993, he faced three then-chronic deficits: full partners with management representatives
budget, performance, and public confidence to identify problems and craft solutions to
(Kettl, 1994). To address these issues, he better serve the agency’s customers and
created the National Performance Review mission.’Partnerships proliferated throughout
(NPR) ‘to redesign, to reinvent, to reinvig- the federal service, where 60 per cent of the
orate the entire national government’ (NPR, workforce is represented by unions (Masters,
1993:1). The 1993 From Red Tape to Results: 2001). These partnerships helped improve
Creating a Government that Works Better the quality of labor-management relations.
and Costs Less embraced the philosophy of In selected cases, they also improved
reinvention with its entrepreneurial spirit. It organizational performance (Masters, 2001;
distilled the core operating principles to four Masters et al., 2006; US Office of Personnel
in number: Management, 2000). Philosophically, EO
12871 represented the most significant
shift in federal labor-management programs
(1) cutting red tape;
(2) putting customers first; since President Kennedy granted federal
(3) empowering employees to get results; and employees the right to unionize and bar-
(4) cutting back to basics: producing better govern- gain collectively through his 1962 EO
ment for less. 10988.
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 321

Beyond reinvention: Bush’s Service Labor-Management Relations


Statute, FSLMRS, or Title VII of the 1978
management agenda and homeland
Civil Service Reform Act). While Congress
security
eventually put most DHS employees under
Shortly after President Bush took office in Title VII when creating the DHS in 2002, it
January 2001, he began dismantling the gave the Secretary of DHS wide authority to
reinvention apparatus of the Clinton-Gore era. create a new, more flexible personnel system.
Among other things, he rescinded the labor- The goal was to enable the agency to frame
management partnership order. In August the managerial flexibility it needed to protect
2001, through his Office of Management the homeland.
and Budget (OMB), Bush unveiled his own For similar reasons, Congress gave the
Management Agenda. It promoted a citizen- Secretary of the Department of Defence
centered, results-oriented, and market-based (DoD) similar authority in 2003. By 2005,
government. Its goals ranged from strategic the DHS and DoD had issued regulations
human resource management to expanded establishing new personnel systems. While
electronic government (e-government). As the implementation of these regulations
mentioned, managerial flexibility received has been at least temporarily stalled by
special attention as a means of facilitating court injunctions, the proposals have far-
intended reforms. reaching impacts. Both DHS and DoD
Competitive sourcing has emerged as recommended significant changes in job clas-
central to President Bush’s approach to sification, compensation, performance man-
management. It has widely encouraged that agement, and labor-management relations.
much of what government does is subject They have proposed giving management
to competitive bidding. Competitive sources more flexibility to classify workers into
were intended to make government more jobs; introducing pay-for-performance sys-
market-based. OMB (2001:17) stated that ‘By tems; and substantially shrinking the bar-
rarely subjecting commercial tasks performed gaining rights and powers of labor unions.
by the government to competition, agencies These changes have led to considerable
have insulated themselves from the pressures labor-management confrontation. Federal-
that produce quality service at reasonable employee unions have aggressively opposed
cost.’ In July 2003, OMB (2003) identified the DHS and DoD reforms in both Congress
416,000 federal positions, or 26 per cent of and the courts.
the total civilian workforce, as available for A coalition of unions representing federal
competition. employees filed legal challenges to the Bush
For the most part, the President’s administration’s proposed personnel reforms
Management Agenda was silent on the in DHS and DoD. In August 2005, a
types of managerial reforms it sought federal district judge issued a ruling that
with regard to employees. It advocated enjoined the plan to reform the collective
competitive sourcing as a means of reducing bargaining system at DHS. A federal court
costs, including payroll. September 11, 2001, of appeals upheld this ruling in 2006, and
however, led to a dramatic emphasis on the DHS decided not to make a further
personnel reform in the civilian part of the appeal in September 2006. In February 2006,
federal service. In response to the terrorist another federal district judge enjoined DoD
attacks, President Bush recommended, by implementing the collective bargaining
after considerable Congressional prodding, provisions of its proposed National Security
creating a new Department of Homeland Personnel System. This decision is on appeal.
Security (DHS). In his recommendation, As another example of how things can change
he originally proposed to exempt DHS as a result of political and legal challenges,
employees from the law granting the right to and newly installed 110th Congress, which
bargain collectively (for instance, the Federal is controlled by Democrats, is considering
322 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

legislation to grant airport screeners the right This burst of public sector reform energy
to unionize, which the Transportation Security has produced results, albeit mixed. Focusing
Administration has denied by an agency attention on better performance and greater
memorandum. results merits commendation. But there are
drawbacks.
First, the public sector reforms almost
CONCLUSION invariably demand more from both managers
and employees. The luxury of ‘cushy’
Globally sweeping economic, political, and government jobs has gone by the wayside.
technological changes have caused organiza- Marsden (1999) reports that the pay-for-
tions of all kinds to change. Organizations performance efforts in the UK have caused
that produce goods and provide services managers to experience greater and more
have had to become more efficient and intense work loads. Schouteten (2004) has
effective, while still satisfying the customer. found that a team-based approach among UK
Public sector organizations in particular have home care workers did not yield a relatively
had to transform, squeezed by growing higher quality of work life, partly because of
political demands, on the one side, to shrink expansion in work load. There are obviously
government and intensifying needs, on the limits to how much more one can do no matter
other side, for efficient public services given how ‘incentivized.’
demographic realities. Second, privatization, outsourcing, devo-
New models of public management and lution, pay-for-performance, downsizing, and
governance have emerged. Societies have contracted employment have no doubt under-
had to rethink the role of government and mined confidence in the legitimacy of public
the distribution of resources and functions service among some in government as well
between the private and public sectors. In as the wider society. Indeed, new public man-
addition, governments have had to revamp agement, or its country-specific variants, has
managerial and HR practices to respond to often represented a political response to avoid
these demands. more draconian cutbacks in the public sector.
The global wave of public sector changes To some, it may represent a stopgap measure
cannot be gainsayed, though it may not have at best. A political psychology of doubt may
lived up to expectations. Privatization and surround the public sector, with the doubt
outsourcing (contracting out or competitive being the inherent capacity of government to
sourcing, etc.) have swept across societies. perform effectively. Witness the widespread
Managerial flexibility, pay-for-performance, criticisms of how the US government, at
and more contingent workforces have become all levels, responded to Hurricane Katrina
widely accepted. The line between govern- in New Orleans especially. This sentiment
ment and industry has become increasingly could hamper government’s ability to attract
blurred. More is expected of government, qualified employees, a dangerous proposition
yet less will be given willingly for it to in societies where huge bubbles of retirement
do the job. Government today suffers the are on the horizon.
consequences of its past failures. Further, Third, the excitement with the NPM has
it lacks the allure and financial reward of appeared to vaporize. Such is the case with
business. Nonetheless, governments perform all ‘experiments’in reform. Reality eventually
essential functions, from national defense sets in, as limitations become clear. The
and education to public health. The battles intrinsic complexities of existing working
against terrorism, including the omnipresent relationships are often underestimated (for
fear of biological or chemical warfare, and the example, Bach et al., 2004).
thread of pandemic flu make the relevance of The difficulties inherent in governing
government inescapable, no matter how much become inescapable, not the least of which
we may worship the dogma of free markets. are the political pressures on public servants.
THE STATE AS EMPLOYER 323

The conceptualization and implementation of Bach, Stephen (2000) Decentralization and Privatization
public management reforms, no matter how in Municipal Services: The Case of Health Services.
antiseptically phrased are political judgments. Sectoral Activities Programme Working Paper 164.
Changes in the political winds shift empha- Geneva: ILO.
sis in managerial reform. The transfer of Bordogna, Lorenzo (2003) ‘The Reform of Public Sector
Employment Relations in Industrialized Democracies,’
power from Clinton-Gore to Bush-Cheney
in Jonathan Brock and David B. Lipsky, (eds), Going
demonstrated this reality. Emphasis went from Public: The Role of Labor-Management Relations in
reinventing government to managerial flex- Delivering Quality Government Services. Champaign,
ibility, not mutually incompatible schemes IL: IRRA: pp. 23–68.
but different ones. One encouraged employee Cotterell, Bill (2006) Legislature may regulate privatiza-
involvement and labor-management coop- tion. Tallahassee Democrat. March 27, 2006.
eration while the other disbanded it with Csoka, Louis, S. (1995) ‘A New Employer-Employee
remarkable alacrity. One focused on shrinking Contract?’ Employment Relations Today, 22 (2):
the workforce while the other encouraged 21–31.
disembarking governmental functions of a Dunleavy, Patrick, Margetts, Helen, Bastow, Simon, and
Tinkler, Jane (2006) ‘New Public Management Is
commercial nature. In democratic societies, it
Dead-Long Live Digital-Era Governance’. Journal of
is hard to plan for the future. Public Administration Research and Theory, 16 (3):
Last, challenges facing government in the 467–94.
future are no less foreboding than those Freeman, Richard, B. (2002) Institutional Differences
of the past. They will demand more from and Economic Performance Among OECD Countries.
those who serve, both in terms of capability London: Centre for the Economics of Education,
and performance. The role of government October.
will undergo continually redefinition. Should Gansler, Jacque, S. and William Lucyshyn (2004)
vouchers replace public schools or should Competitive Sourcing: What Happens to Federal
education be outsourced (Cottrell, 2006; Employees? Washington, D.C.: IBM Center for the
Business of Government, October.
O’Reilly and Boorstin, 2002). Relatedly,
Godine, Morton Robert (1951) The Labor Problem in the
the ability of government to fund new Public Service. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
initiatives is often doubtful. Is there enough Press.
money for government to fund meaning- Gwartney, James, Lawson, Robert, and Holcombe,
ful pay-for-performance systems? Or, more Randall (1998) The Size and Functions of Government
fundamentally, should monetary incentives and Economic Growth. Joint Economic Committee
replace ‘public service’ as a driver of Report, Congress of the United States, May 1998.
performance. International Labour Organization (2001) The Impact
We can only say a few things with absolute of Decentralization and Privatization on Municipal
certainty. Governments across the globe will Services. Geneva: ILO, October.
Kettl, Donald, F. (1994) Reinventing Government
face serious challenges. How they perform
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
will directly affect public confidence in public Kettl, Donald, F. (1998) Reinventing Government:
institutions. Failure to perform will demand A Fifth-Year Report Card. Washington, D.C.:
new reforms and invite unrest. Before long, a Brookings Institution Press.
new mantra of change will replace the NPM Kettl, Donald, F. (2005) The Global Public Management
wave. Revolution, 2nd edn. Washington, D.C.: Brookings
Institution Press.
Kissler, G.D (1994) ‘The New Employment Contract.’
Human Resource Management, 33 (3): 335–52.
REFERENCES International Labour Office (2000) Trends in unioniza-
tion and collective bargaining. Geneva: ILO.
Bach, Stephen, Kessler, Ian, and Heron, Paul (2004) Lane, Jan-Erik (2000) New Public Management.
‘Support Roles and Changing Boundaries in the Public New York, NY: Routledge.
Services: The Case of Teaching Assistants in British Marsden, David (1999) ‘Managing Performance Now
Primary School,’ paper presented to the 22nd Annual Developments: A Senior Organized by IPD’s Public
Labour Process Conference, Amsterdam, April 5–7. Sector Forum,’ July 1st.
324 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Masters, Marick, F. (2001) A Final Report to the National OECD (2005b) ‘Organising and Motivating Public
Partnership on Evaluating Progress and Improve- Servants: Modernising Public Employment’ in
ments in Agencies’ Organizational Performance Modernising Government: The Way Forward. Paris:
Resulting From Labor-Management Partnerships. OECD Publications. pp. 157–84.
Masters, Marick, Albright, Robert, and Eplion, David OECD Observer, July 2004. Policy Brief Public
(2006) ‘What do Partnerships Do? Evidence from the Sector Modernisation: Modernising Public Employ-
Federal Sector.’ Industrial & Labor Relations Review, ment. Internet resource available at www.oecd.org/
59 (3): 367–85. publication/Pol_brief. Last verified September 2006.
NPR (National Performance Review) (1993) From Red OMB (Office of Management and Budget) (2001) The
Tape to Results: Creating a Government that Works President’s Management Agenda. Washington, D.C.:
Better and Costs Less. Washington, D.C.: Government Government Printing Office.
Printing Office. OMB (Office of Management and Budget) (2003)
OECD (1997) In Search of Results: Performance Competitive Sourcing: Conducting Public-Private
Management Practices. Paris: OECD Publications. Competition in a Reasoned and Responsible Manner.
OECD (2001) ‘Recent Privatisation Trends.’ Financial Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Market Trends, 79 (June): 43–65. O’Reilly, Brian and Boorstin, Julia (2002) Why Edison
OECD (2002a) Assessing Performance-oriented HRM doesn’t work. Fortune, 146 (12): 148–54.
Activities in Selected OECD Countries. Paris: OECD Osborne, David and Gaebler, Ted (1992) Reinventing
Publications. Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit is
OECD (2002b) Highlights of Public Sector Pay and Transforming the Public Sector. Reading, MA:
Employment Trends: 2002 Update. Internet resource Addison-Wesley.
available at www.oecd.org/gov/hrm. Last verified Rosenbloom, David, H. (1971) Federal Service and the
September 2006. Constitution. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
OECD (2002c) Recent Privatization Trends in OECD Schouteten, Roel (2004) ‘Does Group Work Improve the
Countries. Financial Market Trends, 82 (June): QWL in the Home Care Sector?’ Paper presented
43–58. to the 22nd Annual Labour Process Conference,
OECD (2004a) The Learning Government: Introduction Amsterdam, April 5–7.
and Draft Results of the Survey of Knowledge Trebilock, Michael (1995) ‘Can Government Be Rein-
Management Practices in Ministries/Departments/ vented?’ in Jonathan Boston (ed.), The State Under
Agencies of Central Government. Paris: OECD Contract. Wellington, New Zealand: Bridget Williams
Publications. Brooks Ltd. pp. 1–35.
OECD (2004b) Performance-related Pay Policies for US Office of Personnel Management (2000) A White
Government Employees: Main Trends in OECD Paper: A Fresh Start for Federal Pay: The Case
Member Countries. Paris: OECD Publications. for Modernization. Washington, D.C.: Government
OECD (2005a) Trends in Human Resources Management Printing Office.
Policies in OECD Countries An Analysis of the Results Visser, Jelle (2006) Union membership statistics in 24
of the OECD Survey on Strategic Human Resources countries, Monthly Labor Review, January, 129 (1)
Management. Paris: OECD Publications. 38–49.
17
International Actors and
International Regulation
Rebecca Gumbrell-McCormick

INTRODUCTION collective agreements normally seen as typ-


ical of national employment regulation? My
Industrial relations (IR), as a field of study, aim is to suggest answers to these questions.
is oriented around the nation-state. When When academic industrial relations became
Dunlop (1958) proposed the concept of an established in the mid-twentieth century, the
industrial relations system, this was nation- main collective actors and the main arena of
ally bounded; though his aim was in part regulation were clearly nationally based. But
to compare and contrast different national this primacy of the national level has been
systems, the idea of an international system challenged in recent years, both practically
was not addressed. Yet can we speak of and analytically. The spread of multinational
an international industrial relations system? companies (MNCs), and other aspects of eco-
Writing of developments within the European nomic internationalization, are widely seen
Union (EU), Jensen et al. (1999) argue that as weakening or undermining the capacity
we can identify supranational equivalents for regulation at a national level. While my
of Dunlop’s three actors – representative intention is not to focus on the debates over
organizations of workers and employers, the concept and extent of globalization (the
and government agencies – and that their theme of Chapter 6 in this volume), these
interactions are creating a supranational body processes have stimulated a growing interest
of rules. Hence, they conclude, a European in the possibility of international regulation
industrial relations system exists. The same of the employment relationship. But despite a
might be said of the global level, as growing body of international law and other
this chapter explains. But how far do the forms of regulation, and an expanding aca-
international ‘actors’match our understanding demic literature documenting and interpreting
of trade unions, employers’ associations and the implications of supranational action, this
governments at national level? And how far remains relatively unfamiliar to most students
do the rules they create match the laws and of mainstream industrial relations.
326 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

For this reason, this chapter needs to present few of their powers: much of the tension
considerable empirical detail as well as to within the United Nations (UN) system,
review existing theoretical debates. I shall and more recently within the World Trade
begin by addressing some key conceptual Organization (WTO), has to do with the
and definitional issues, before outlining the extent of supranational authority. This is also
background and structure of the international the case for national unions taking part in
industrial relations system and the actors trade union internationals: they agree to pay
within it. I will then discuss some of the dues and accept the collective choice of
motives for organization and action at this leadership, although not always with good
level, exploring similarities and differences grace, but in practice have rarely agreed to
as against national industrial relations. Next delegate substantial powers of policy-making
I will address some of the main instruments or negotiation. Employers’ associations have
of supranational regulation, again comparing been even more restrictive.
and contrasting with their national analogues.
My conclusion will be that it is indeed
National and international: parallels
meaningful to speak of international industrial
and differences
relations, but that it is a mistake to interpret it
as a national system writ large. As noted above, much analysis of the
international level of industrial relations has
proceeded by analogy with the national. This
DEFINITIONS, CONCEPTS is misleading. The state has citizens; despite
AND ANALYSIS the occasional rhetoric of ‘world citizenship’,
individuals do not possess an analogous
Most literature on the international level of set of rights and responsibilities vis-à-vis
IR tends to apply concepts and theoretical international institutions. Trade unions have
approaches originally developed at national members, who directly contribute to union
level. Before I consider how far this is funds and possess corresponding rights and
appropriate, it is necessary to clarify what obligations; international union organizations
we mean by the international level in the (leaving aside the special case of those
context of industrial relations. This question unions which bridge the US-Canadian border)
has probably been more extensively addressed possess members only indirectly, through the
in the EU than the global context (Böröcz and affiliation of national bodies. The same is
Sarkar, 2005; Dølvik, 1997; Schmidt, 2002; also true of most national confederations;
Wallace, 2000). but union internationals are one step further
There is a continuum in the division of removed from individual members. This
powers between national and international distance has been an important area of
levels. At one extreme is supranational debate, with some arguing that this has
authority, where higher-level institutions can allowed trade union internationals to misrep-
impose rules on national actors, at the other resent the concerns of individual members
is internationalism, where higher-level com- (Thompson and Larson, 1978). Likewise,
petence is conditional on consensus among international employers’ associations often
the national actors. In between are federal affiliate national organizations rather than
structures, with a clear functional division individual companies.
between the autonomy retained at national A related issue is the basis of legitimacy
level and that of supranational authorities, and nature of decision-making at international
which may itself depend on a large majority level. I will cover the issue of gover-
of support from lower-level actors. nance within intergovernmental organizations
In IR, with very few exceptions: the below. Looking at the other actors, while
international form of organization is the there are few expectations for individual
norm. Nation-states tend to delegate very employers to operate democratically, their
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 327

associations are expected to do so, much like of structures and their internal decision-
international trade unions. But the distance making processes, the time-scale of their
from their base makes this difficult; moreover development, the type of governance and the
international bodies must deal not only with extent of their regulatory powers are very dif-
the core issues which affect members at ferent, although questions of legitimacy and
national level, but also with world politics authority show many similarities. Since the
and political rivalries between nations. For Treaty of Westphalia in 1648, the sovereignty
employers’associations, this is not necessarily of nation-states has been a fundamental
a problem; for trade unions it is, because the principle of international politics; in normal
labor movement relies on its members and circumstances, the right of self-determination
their capacity to act (Coates and Topham, can only be voluntarily abrogated. In general,
1980: Chapter 11; Hyman, 2005a). For unions, nations have been willing to assign only
authority depends on democratic accountabil- tightly bounded powers to intergovernmental
ity to the members – their ‘internal authority’ institutions, imposing decision-making rules
(Martin, 1980); yet to be effective, unions which restrict the chances that they will
must be regarded as representative by outside be bound by policies to which they object.
bodies, such as employers and governments. Similar constitutional limitations apply in the
This external authority can be closely linked case of international organizations of unions
to internal authority: if members support the and employers. This principle of ‘subsidiarity’
union, employers and governments will take is reinforced by the long time gap between the
it seriously. Yet some argue that if unions consolidation of nation-states and the creation
pay too much attention to the agenda set and development of an international system
by external interlocutors, they may cease to (from approximately the mid-nineteenth to
represent their members’ interests effectively mid-twentieth centuries).
and may thus lose internal authority – which
in turn may erode their external representative
Governance and government
capacity. This issue has been discussed by
Dølvik (1997) as a tension between the ‘logic Even those international organizations with
of membership’ and a ‘logic of influence’. relatively strong sets of competence lack
key defining characteristics of governments.
National states, in Weber’s definition (see
The nature of international
Chapter 14), hold the monopoly of the
regulation
legitimate use of violence within a given
At international as at national level, the territory. International organizations lack this
industrial relations actors operate within a capacity (although the UN, in exceptional cir-
regulatory system which constrains their cumstances, may be empowered to intervene
actions. To some extent, the governmental forcefully if one state threatens the security
actors overlap with the regulatory system of another, or collapses into civil war). The
itself – national governments, for example, are international institutional order, as expressed
actors within intergovernmental institutions in the title of the study by Rosenau and Czem-
such as the International Labour Organiza- piel (1992), is a matter of ‘governance without
tion (ILO), and these intergovernmental government’; while Bulmer (1998: 366) has
bodies themselves formulate policies and argued, in the context of the EU, that the latter
programmes that in turn have an effect on the ‘does not resemble, or have, a government, so
nature and scope of international regulation, governance offers some descriptive purchase
but it is important to maintain a conceptual on the character of the polity’.
distinction between their role as actors and as The elusive concept of governance –
components of the supranational system. ‘an archaic term become newly fashionable’
The international regulatory system is not (Leisink and Hyman, 2005: 277) – is
identical to that at the national level: the type also commonly used with reference to
328 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

decision-making by companies – ‘corporate ‘civil society actors’. Of key significance are


governance’ – and other bodies. Its practical the institutions that have been established
meaning is often unclear, since the concept to regulate the international economy and
leaves open questions of power relations, polity. These include the ILO, the Bretton
means of enforcement and implementation. Woods institutions and the rest of the UN
There is also a tension between the descrip- system, the Organization for Economic
tive or analytical use of the term ‘global Cooperation and Development (OECD) and
governance’, and the normative or program- the WTO, which are both actors and major
matic usage which calls for a regulatory order components of the regulatory framework
to compensate for a presumed loss of national or structure of the international system.
capacity (Dingwerth and Pattberg, 2006). I conclude this section by considering the
Precisely because international organiza- regional dimension of international indus-
tions rarely possess the ultimate sanction trial relations, with particular attention to
of force to implement their decisions, the the EU.
distinction between government and gover-
nance links to that between ‘hard’ and ‘soft’
States and intergovernmental
law (Abbott and Snidal, 2000). ‘Soft’ law
organizations
indicates decisions which those to whom
they are addressed are expected to observe There has been much recent debate on the
but which cannot be juridically enforced; supposedly declining powers of nation-states
their efficacy depends on peer pressure and in the era of globalization (Berger, 2000;
the possibility of less formalized means of Strange, 1996; Weiss, 1998). My focus here,
retaliation, and on the extent to which the however, is not on the autonomy of states to
underlying norms of conduct are ‘internalized’ regulate their own internal affairs, but rather
by decision-makers at national level (Koh, on their role at the international level.
1999). Much international regulation in the International organizations of states and
field of industrial relations is precisely of this governments were formed after the first
nature. There is considerable disagreement and then after the second world wars. The
as to whether non-binding norms can exert oldest major organization still in existence
hard effects; those who assert the value of is the ILO, founded in 1919 as part of
such approaches insist that ‘soft’law may help the League of Nations and incorporated in
‘frame’ the political debate at national as well the UN system in 1946 (Alcock, 1971;
as international level, providing an important Hughes, 2005; ILO, 1931; Shotwell, 1934).
resource for those actors pressing for stronger Most international organizations discussed
national regulation (Zeitlin and Pochet, 2005). here are formally intergovernmental, that is,
they represent the governments of national
states directly, although the forms of rep-
THE INTERNATIONAL SYSTEM: THE resentation and selection may vary. The
MAJOR ACTORS AND INSTITUTIONS ILO is distinctive, representing workers and
employers as well as states in a tripartite
This section gives a ‘snapshot’ of the inter- system.
national industrial relations system. I identify Intergovernmental organizations, while
the key characteristics of the international acting on behalf of nation-states, do not enjoy
level of industrial relations; its actors and analogous powers or legitimacy. The UN
the relations between them; its structure system is recognized by and represents the
and its regulatory setting and its evolution largest number of nation-states on a perma-
over time. I focus on the three actors nent basis and is granted the legitimate right
comprising Dunlop’s model but also refer to use force under very limited conditions.
more briefly to a putative fourth actor, No other intergovernmental body — at least
non-governmental organizations (NGOs) or at the world level – enjoys such powers, and
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 329

nation-states are rarely willing in practice to (GATT), which promoted trade liberalization
grant the UN the freedom in theory to act in the and was transformed into the WTO in 1995.
way that is allowed in emergency situations. The latter is not part of the UN system
The UN system has been rife with inter- but functions in some respects in parallel
state and interregional rivalries and has been with the WB and IMF. With some 150
subject to the veto power of individual states, members, it has a cumbersome governance
in particular the US. structure and positions are often polarized,
The ILO has a direct influence on national as is evident from the deadlock in a number
industrial relations practices, but possesses of recent attempts to achieve further trade
fewer powers than the UN system as a whole. liberalization. Also separate from the UN
Much of the literature focuses on its effects system is the OECD, the predecessor of which
rather than its structure, functions and gover- was established in 1948. Today it includes
nance, with debate polarized between those some 30 of the world’s richest countries, and
who emphasize its positive achievements while it possesses fewer formal powers that
(Kyloh, 1998; Langille, 2005; Sengenberger, the UN institutions, it is often seen as a
2002) and those who stress its limitations vehicle of ‘soft’ law;1 by its own description it
(Elliott and Freeman, 2003; Standing, 2004). ‘produces internationally agreed instruments,
I explore the efficacy of the ILO regulatory decisions and recommendations to promote
instruments in a later section. rules of the game in areas where multilat-
Many would argue that an even greater eral agreement is necessary for individual
impact on industrial relations is exerted by countries to make progress in a globalized
the international financial institutions (IFIs) economy’. It is notable for possessing an
which define the rules of the global economic element of tripartism in its governance,
game. The Bretton Woods agreements of 1944 with Advisory Committees representing both
resulted in the creation of the International employers and trade unions. The Trade Union
Monetary Fund (IMF) and what was to Advisory Committee (TUAC) is independent
become the World Bank (WB). Their orig- of the ITUC but works closely with it.
inal mission, as integral parts of the new The international economy is, inevitably,
UN system, was the reduction of poverty strongly influenced by the policies of its most
and inequality between nations; but from powerful actors; and since the collapse of
the 1950s, financial support to developing the Soviet empire, this has given the US
countries was made conditional on ‘structural a hegemonic role in the functioning of the
adjustment programmes‘. With the advance of IFIs, accelerating the liberalization of trade
the neo-liberal ‘Washington consensus’, these in both goods and services and of cross-
involved radical measures of privatization, national flows of finance and investment. In
reduction in public expenditure, removal of other words, those dynamics characterized as
barriers to external trade and investment and globalization, and their impact on employ-
flexible labor market policies. Such policies ment conditions at national level, are to an
have been widely blamed for causing unem- important extent the outcome of the policies
ployment, insecurity, reduced living standards of the IFIs and those nation-states which
and increased poverty (Cammack, 2005; dominate their governance.
Chorev, 2005; Germain, 2002); critics have
included the former WB chief economist,
Employers’ associations and
Joseph Stiglitz (2002). However both institu-
multinational corporations
tions, especially the WB, may now be moving
towards closer co-ordination within the UN The International Organization of Employ-
system (with the ILO) and the pursuit of their ers (IOE), formed in 1920 after the ILO
original goals (Panić, 2003; Toye, 2003). was established (Rojot, 2006), represents
The Bretton Woods conference also led to employers’ interests within the ILO and
the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade the UN system as a whole. It comprises
330 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

national associations in some 140 countries and Levinson (1971, 1972) – have long
and cooperates with a variety of regional regarded MNCs as a serious threat. For some
employers’ organizations, and also with the contemporary writers, they impose irresistible
Business and Industry Advisory Committee to downwards pressure on national employment
the OECD (BIAC). Another influential body regulation through their ability to shift
is the International Chamber of Commerce production to low-cost and weakly regulated
(ICC), established in 1919. It is a strong locations (Gray, 1998). Others argue that there
advocate of neo-liberalism. While it lacks the is little evidence that MNCs give priority in
legitimacy as a ‘social partner’ enjoyed by their investment decisions to low labor costs:
the IOE, it has nevertheless been allowed a they want a productive and efficient labor
significant role within the UN system (Kelly, force, and also need infrastructure, possibly
2005). Numerous organizations also represent access to local markets, as well as political
employer interests in individual industries and stability and secure property rights – all of
sectors. which are typically associated with countries
One reason for the low profile of with advanced labor standards. However,
international employers’ organizations is there is compelling evidence that MNCs shift
that individual employers are important labor-intensive, low valued-added activities
international actors in their own right, espe- to low-wage countries; and though there
cially (but not exclusively) if they are large is little evidence that they frequently close
MNCs. They are often seen as acting with down existing operations to move to low-
more power and autonomy at the international wage locations (which in some fields of
level than many national governments, and economic activity is difficult), they may well
as exerting a significant influence on the successfully threaten to do so in order to force
actions of such governments. As an example, workers and their unions to make concessions
Balanyá et al. (2003: 3) report that over on pay and working practices.
200 corporations have European government
affairs offices in Brussels, alongside some
Workers and trade unions
500 corporate lobby groups. There is a much-
quoted statistic that just over half of the National unions are sometimes important
100 largest economic entities in the world actors at the international level, generally
are MNCs, not nation-states (Hertz, 2001). those based in the wealthiest countries or
The growth in mergers and acquisitions those with the highest union density, but it
(facilitated by the liberalization of takeover is dedicated international trade union bodies
rules) has accelerated the trend. that carry out most union action and policy-
MNCs are not ‘embedded’ in the norms making at the international level. These
and institutions of most of the countries organizations can be classified by struc-
in which they operate, they often ensure ture, geographical coverage and ideology.
frequent mobility of key managers across Structurally, we can distinguish between orga-
countries to prevent them ‘going native’, nizations based on industrial sectors and those
and they have the capacity to pursue inter- based on national centers. The earliest trade
national strategies while most trade unions union internationals, founded at the end of
and other employee representative institutions the nineteenth century, were industry-based,
are nationally bounded. Many writers see becoming known as International Trade
their dominance in the global economy, Secretariats (ITSs), and recently renamed
not only in manufacturing but increasingly Global Union Federations (GUFs). The first
in service industries, as undermining both cross-sectoral body was founded in 1901 and
the practical and theoretical coherence of reconstituted as the International Federation
national industrial relations systems (Katz of Trade Unions (IFTU) in 1913. There
and Darbishire, 2000). Leading international developed a division of labor, with the ITSs
trade unionists – for example, Fimmen (1924) concentrating on practical organizing and
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 331

solidarity work within their sectors, and the which had formerly belonged to WFTU. It
confederations of national centers addressing is worth noting that the split in WFTU in
broader political issues (Reinalda, 1997; Van 1949 reflected both a political confrontation
Goethem, 2000). between communists and anti-communists,
Geographically, we can distinguish and a conflict over plans to subordinate the
between regional and global bodies. The ITSs to the control of the Confederation
first international organizations were almost (MacShane, 1992). Within the new ITUC, ide-
exclusively European in coverage, and the ological frictions overlap with regionalism,
weight of membership and financial resources most notably whether Latin American unions
has always ensured strong European influence should enjoy regional autonomy (as in the
in global unionism. After the Second World WCL) or be part of a broader pan-American
War, decolonization gave a spur to the structure in which the US unions exert major
creation of regional union organizations in influence (as in the ICFTU).
the rest of the world. The split in international
trade unionism in 1949 reinforced this
Non-governmental organizations
trend as three confederations competed for
membership across the globe. From the There is a growing literature on the role of
1950s, the process of European integration ‘civil society’, ‘social movements’ or ‘non-
led to the establishment of formal regional governmental organizations’ (NGOs) as a
trade union structures in Europe. fourth category of industrial relations actor
Ideological divisions have received the (Heery and Frege, 2006; Chapter 19 in this
most attention in studies of international trade book). Such bodies are particularly impor-
unionism. The IFTU mainly encompassed tant at the international level of industrial
unions with a social-democratic orientation, relations, where arguably some NGOs have
together with more ‘business unionist’ acquired a greater impact than trade unions
affiliates in Britain and the US. After 1920 it or employers’ organizations (Elliott and
faced two smaller rivals, the mainly catholic Freeman, 2003). We are concerned here with
International Federation of Christian Trade NGOs working in industrial relations areas,
Unions (IFCTU) and the communist Red such as the relatively worker-oriented War on
International of Labour Unions. A new Want, Amnesty and Oxfam, faith-based char-
global organization, the World Federation ities and development bodies. Certain NGOs
of Trade Unions (WFTU), was founded as can be considered more employer-oriented,
a unitary confederation in 1945, but never devoted to corporate social responsibility
included the Christian unions. In 1949, most and related themes. Others, not specifically
non-communist affiliates broke away to oriented to employment issues, also have an
form the International Confederation of Free impact in this area, for example feminist
Trade Unions (ICFTU). In 1968 the IFCTU or environmental NGOs (Cockburn, 1997;
‘deconfessionalized’ and became the World Waterman, 1998).
Confederation of Labour (WCL) (Pasture, Much recent literature suggests that NGOs
1994). Meanwhile WFTU, consisting mainly are able to campaign more forcefully and
of national centers from communist and/or effectively than trade unions against the
developing countries, lost membership adverse impact of neo-liberal globalization on
rapidly with the rise of ‘Eurocommunism’ work and employment. It is widely argued
followed by the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989. that individuals are increasingly likely to
Ideological differences remain important define themselves in a number of ways – as
despite the foundation at the end of 2006 of consumers, citizens, women or members of
a new unitary organization, the International other particular groups – rather than in terms
Trade Union Confederation (ITUC), bringing of their role in the production process (Munck,
together the ICFTU and WCL along with 2002). Most of the older democracies have
a number of independent centers, some of seen to a decline in membership and activism
332 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

within trade unions and political parties, and increasingly active participants; the same is
an increased role of ‘single-issue’or ‘pressure’ true of the European Social Forum, first held
groups (Koenig-Archibugi, 2003). Many of in Florence in 2002.
these have a direct or indirect concern with
industrial relations issues.
The regional dimension
Waterman (1998) argues that trade union
internationals have become ‘institutionalized’ Some critics of the globalization thesis
and have been captured by the official insist that the most notable feature of
institutions whose policies they seek to international economic restructuring has been
influence. Organizational demarcations and the intensification of trade relations and
administrative procedures have to be tran- corporate activity within regional blocs.
scended in order to create a ‘new’ labor Few of these have an explicit industrial
internationalism within which social move- relations competence, though their role in
ments play an equal role. However, official trade liberalization has obvious industrial
union representatives typically respond that relations consequences. The North American
NGOs and social movements, whether oper- Free Trade Area (NAFTA), as its name
ating nationally or internationally, are often indicates, is essentially a free trade zone: its
small and unrepresentative, and lack the sta- main function is to eliminate cross-national
bility, accountability and transparency of trade obstacles to trade and investment. It has a
unions or political parties. Yet many NGOs minimal ‘social dimension’ (the ‘side agree-
do possess clearer representative structures ments’ on labor and environmental standards)
and greater accountability. A good example and establishes no significant supranational
is Amnesty, which has played a significant institutions with the important exception
role in highlighting abuses of human and of the dispute adjudication machinery. The
social rights, both within nations and at the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC),
international level. It has often cooperated which groups 21 countries in or bordering
with UN bodies and with the ICFTU and other on the Pacific, is a purely intergovernmental
trade union bodies (Gumbrell-McCormick, organization with no independent powers.
2000: 454–8). More generally, it is clear that Its membership partly overlaps with that of
‘social-movement’-oriented campaigns have the Association of Southeast Asian Nations
been important in shifting the international (ASEAN), comprising 10 South-East Asian
trade union agenda towards more serious countries, which is designed to encourage
attention to issues such as gender equality, trade but also the coordination of social
home-working and the ‘informal sector’ more (including labor) policies. It has few effective
generally. Significantly, the Self Employed supranational powers. There is also a variety
Women’s Association, an Indian organization of regional trading blocs in Latin America
with a bridging role as trade union and (Mercosur), Africa and the Middle East.
campaigning NGO, was given a platform slot The one regional entity with a substantial
at the ITUC founding congress. industrial relations role is in Europe. The
Thus we can see a growing rapprochement European Economic Community (EEC), cre-
between international trade unionism and ated with six member states in 1957, has
international NGOs as actors in a ‘global civil developed into the contemporary European
society’ (Waterman and Timms, 2005). This Union (EU) with 27 members. From one per-
can be seen, for example, in the experience spective it constitutes a free trade area, under-
of the annual World Social Forum, first pinned by the principle of the free movement
convened, mainly by Third World NGOs, in of goods and services, capital and labor. Yet
Porto Alegre, Brazil in 2001 as a movement unlike NAFTAit is more than a ‘common mar-
for ‘globalization from below’ (Sen et al., ket’: it has an elaborate politico-institutional
2004). Initially the official trade union orga- framework, even if it lacks many of the key
nizations largely held aloof, but have become attributes of national states, with governing
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 333

powers divided between the Commission, regulation at EU level; but arguably there is a
appointed for a five-year term, and the Coun- lack of internal consensus on what, and how, to
cil, comprising ministers from each of the regulate. It is interesting to note that the ETUC
member states. There is a parliament, though superseded the former European structures of
with weaker powers than national legislatures, the ICFTU and hence escaped the authority of
a supreme court (the European Court of Jus- the global organization; it retains its autonomy
tice, ECJ) and a European Central Bank which despite the creation of the new ITUC.
largely controls monetary policy. Economic The notion that trade unions and employers’
integration is accompanied by a ‘social dimen- organizations are ‘social partners’ is familiar
sion’, and the legal competence of the EU in most European countries. This does not
to regulate employment issues has increased necessarily mean that unions and employers
considerably over time. This has had a notable cooperate in a spirit of mutual friendship;
impact on industrial relations in the UK, for rather, that the organizations of capital and
example triggering legislation on such issues labor are ‘partners’ of the state in formulating
as equal opportunities, working time and and administering social policy. This concep-
information and consultation. I discuss EU tion was reflected at EU level in the creation
employment regulation in more detail below. of what is now the European Economic and
Two employers’ organizations have an Social Committee (EESC), representing a
important formal role in EU policy-making wide variety of economic interest groups but
and legislation. UNICE (Union of Industrial with no real power and little influence.
and Employers’ Confederations of Europe) The concept of ‘social dialogue’ was
was founded 1958; since renamed Busi- invented, and strongly promoted, by the Com-
nessEurope, it comprises national business mission in the run-up to the Single Market
and employer confederations, and is as much of 1992 and Economic and Monetary Union
(or more) concerned with issues of trade which was launched by the 1991 Maastricht
and business as with employment. It is Treaty. The ‘constitution’ of the EU states
resistant to social regulation, and its national that ‘the Commission shall endeavour to
affiliates are often reluctant to give it a develop the dialogue between management
mandate to negotiate. CEEP (Centre européen and labour at European level which could,
des entreprises à participation publique) if the two sides consider it desirable, lead
covers public enterprises and has shown to relations based on agreement’. Maastricht
more support than UNICE for the ‘social boosted the role of the social partners: as
dimension’ of European integration. There well as being guaranteed consultative input
are also representative bodies for commercial during the framing of Commission legislative
undertakings and the small-firm sector. proposals, they acquired a new right to opt to
On the trade union side there is just deal with an issue by means of European-level
one major player, the ETUC (European agreements. Some EU legislation has indeed
Trade Union Confederation). Founded in been adopted through this route.
1973 by ICFTU affiliates, it soon admitted
the main European members of the WCL,
and subsequently all main (ex-)communist INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATION:
confederations were allowed in. It has a dual MOTIVES AND CONSTRAINTS
structure, including national confederations
and European Industry Federations (ElFs); There is an influential argument in indus-
hence national trade unions have a dual trial relations (first expounded by Commons
channel of representation. It covers the in 1909) that the expansion of product
large majority of unionized workers in EU markets results in a parallel extension of
countries, and in the 1990s it admitted employment regulation. Yet this never occurs
members and associates from Eastern Europe. automatically: the actors concerned must
It is strongly in favor of enhanced social regard higher-level (in our case, international)
334 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

regulation as in their mutual interest, or those employment conditions. Many critics of


who favor such an extension must have the globalization argue similarly: a neo-liberal
power to impose their will. Hence it is nec- project of eliminating inhibitions to interna-
essary to examine the purpose or motivation tional trade and investment is antagonistic
for the actions of the key international actors. to the creation of new international labor
Much of the literature which addresses this standards and indeed implies the weakening
question adopts a rational-choice approach, of those which currently exist at national
though this has serious limitations. We level. A rather different distinction is proposed
may also distinguish ‘bottom-up’ and ‘top- by Langille (2005), who contrasts a negative
down’ perspectives. The former asks why view of international labor standards as
national actors agree to transfer some of their a defense against a ‘race to the bottom’
sovereignty to supranational bodies; the latter, with a positive conception of high standards
starting from the fact that such bodies do exist, as economically productive. The conflict
explores how institutional self-interest can between these two perspectives is central to
encourage those who manage these to expand much academic, and public policy, debate.
their own authority and competence. This Given the very limited academic atten-
has been an important theme in the literature tion to international employers’ organizations
on EU governance. I should also note that (partly because of the limited transparency of
much of the writing on the international level their operations), it is impossible to analyze
of industrial relations concentrates on trade their motivations in detail. One should also
unionism. The discussion below reflects this, note that many of these bodies are primarily
but first I consider the other parties. representatives of companies’ commercial
Governments may participate in intergov- interests with only a subsidiary concern for
ernmental bodies for negative and defensive industrial relations issues. Often their function
or positive and constructive reasons (as will seems negative in the strong sense of resisting
be seen, a similar distinction applies to the projects of transnational regulation, or at least
other actors). Many international agencies or those seen as threats to employers’ interests.
treaties are designed to prevent the destructive Yet we should note that those who represent
consequences of the unregulated pursuit employers at international level may be
of national interests: from war to global inspired by the more positive visions indicated
warming to retaliatory tariff barriers. Others above, and may also absorb the progressive
may be intended to facilitate commonly culture of bodies such as the ILO. In addition,
desired objectives which single states lack the sectoral employers’ organizations – in the
capacity to achieve, or even to establish a ‘new maritime industry, for example – may be
world order’ – a goal proclaimed at the end powerfully motivated by the need to establish
of both world wars (and reiterated after the rules of the game essential for international
collapse of communism). The ILO, and the industries to thrive.
whole UN system, were explicitly assigned Trade unions are most likely to articulate
such idealistic aims. positive, idealistic reasons for internation-
One common view is that the bias of alism. Skeptics argue that more mundane
international economic regulation is negative interests have typically inhibited purely ide-
(reducing or removing barriers to cross- alistic projects of international solidarity, and
national trade and financial movements) that the real foundations of international trade
whereas the thrust of employment regulation unionism are more pragmatic. What divides
is positive (enhancing the conditions of most analysts, however, is whether these
working life). Scharpf (1999) refers to a ten- interests are primarily economic or political.
sion between these two aspects of European The economic self-interest approach has
integration; in his view the negative dynamic taken many forms. Fimmen (1924), writ-
of market liberalization has overridden the ing in an early era of ‘globalization’,
positive goal of upward harmonization of believed that trade unions would organize
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 335

internationally because the development of hence the perception of self-interest of leaders


capitalism obliged them to do so. Logue have been intermingled. Here we may note
(1980), in an essay highly influential among Hyman’s argument (2005a) that political logic
students of the international labor movement, seems best to explain the development of
saw trade unions as organizations representing international trade unionism at cross-sectoral
the short-term economic interests of their level, while a more economic logic is reflected
members. More subtly, Ramsay and Haworth in the history of industrial organizations.
looked in detail at the changing patterns of A third consideration is institutional self-
ownership and control of individual com- interest, whereby trade unions (or their
panies and industrial sectors, exploring the leaders) seek to defend their own interests as
varying interests of workers in different sec- institutions. It is understandable that leaders of
tors at different times (Haworth and Ramsay, the international union organizations should
1986, 1988; Ramsay, 1997, 1999). Anner et al. seek to protect their own institutional self-
(2006) argue that contrasts in the form and interest, but why do national centers feel the
extent of cross-national union solidarity in need to defend them? The answer to this
shipping, textiles and car manufacturing can question is usually linked to the protection of
be explained by differences in production political self-interest, by which small elites in
organization and product and labor market control of national centers seek to maintain
competition. Yet this does not explain why their control over the international sphere. We
workers such as typographers, who were may also note Visser’s discussion (1998) of
scarcely exposed to international competition, ‘push’ and ‘pull’ factors in transnational union
were among the pioneers of international trade organization: national unions may be ‘pushed’
unionism (van der Linden, 2000: 526–7). towards supranational activity by the factors
Political self-interest has been seen by mentioned previously, but they may also be
many students of the labor movement as ‘pulled’ by the opportunities and resources
the primary motivation for international trade (material assistance or status and legitimacy)
union action. Studies of the international available though a role on the international
labor movement in the post-war period have stage. For example, it is widely remarked
either concentrated on the motivations of that the European Commission is anxious to
labor leaders themselves, growing out of cultivate interlocutors at EU level and thus
their ideological convictions or war-time provides significant resources to the ETUC
experience (Carew, 1987; MacShane, 1992), (Gobin, 1997; Hyman, 2005b). More recently,
or on the motivations of governments, in it may be added, parallel assistance has been
explaining their support to international trade given to a range of European NGOs.
union activities (Logue, 1980; Thompson and While economic, political and institutional
Larson, 1978). Most of the debate on this self-interest all have some explanatory value
issue has been between those who see labor in the study of the purpose of action and
as an unwitting tool of the great powers and organization at the international level, all
those who see it as a willing participant, three confront the problem of how interests
even an initiator of the Cold War. Wedin’s are to be identified, and hence run the risk
study of the ICFTU in the early 1960s of circularity (Devin, 1990: 72–3). Lorwin,
stands out in its portrayal of the complex who wrote one of the first studies of
interdependence between political and trade international trade unionism (1929), took a
union leaders and interests (Wedin, 1974). different approach by concentrating on the
While the nature of this debate is ideological, efforts of the international labor movement
empirical research, such as Carew’s study of to regulate labor at the international level,
labor under the Marshall Plan (1987), has through its role as a major component in
shown the subtle interpenetration of political an international industrial relations system.
and trade union elites in the post-war world, Reinalda (1997: 18–23) makes a similar
and the degree to which the values and point when he identifies participation in an
336 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

international industrial relations system as a international boycotts, but Lorwin and others
dimension beyond the simple accumulation of have since pointed out limitations to this form
different individual and national interests. of action. International strikes have been even
The capacity to act and the means of rarer, a leading example being European-wide
action available to trade unions provide the solidarity with striking workers at Ford in
most striking contrast between the national Belgium and the UK in the early 1970s (Piehl,
and international levels. Commonly it is 1974b) although the provision of assistance to
assumed that a union exerts leverage through workers on strike in other countries has been
the threat to withdraw its members’ labor; fairly widespread, alongside attempts to put
its goal is to reach a satisfactory deal for pressure on the head offices of the companies
its members through collective bargaining. involved. Regarding collective bargaining as
This model does not apply in many national a key function of international trade unionism
situations; often, action such as lobbying demonstrates the danger of false analogies
of public opinion and government is more with national trade unionism.
important. This observation applies a fortiori The function and means of action of
to action at the international level. While international organizations are closely related
there have been a few cases of international to their purpose. One of the main functions
strike action and, more rarely, of international is to represent the interests of the national
collective bargaining, these are exceedingly constituency at world level, to provide a
rare and limited in scope (Etty and Tudyka, voice, whether for workers or employers or
1974; Northrup and Rowan, 1979). Even citizens, within intergovernmental bodies, and
the possibilities that have been created for to organize or coordinate any other actions
international collective bargaining at EU level that may be taken in pursuit of their interests
have been limited (Dølvik, 1997; Martin and (Devin, 1990). This latter point is rather
Ross, 1999; Visser, 1996). The GUFs have different for trade unions and for employers’
a stronger collective bargaining orientation, organizations. While employers often do act
but despite their focus on industrial issues together, whether through trade or employers’
they also are obliged to act politically within associations or informal groupings, they have
a largely international and intergovernmental many means of action at their disposal
system. within their own corporations and in political
Neither Fimmen nor Lorwin regarded connections at the national or international
international collective bargaining as immi- level. Trade unions tend to have fewer
nent, but Levinson (1971, 1972), head of the opportunities.
chemical workers’ ITS, made this the focus Trade unions (like employers’ organi-
of his influential writings; and such authors zations) face particular difficulties at the
as Northrup and Rowan evaluated interna- international level. At national level, capac-
tional trade unionism negatively against this ity is ultimately determined by members’
yardstick. However, even without collective willingness to act, the internal cohesion of
bargaining there is considerable potential the organization and its responsiveness to
for international solidarity action, such as members’ concerns. This cannot apply in the
assistance in industrial disputes, and for same way to the international level, which is
greater coordination of action, for example composed of organizations of organizations.
of national collective bargaining demands. While national action must depend ultimately
Lorwin (1929: 468) made an interesting on individual members, in practice for the
comparison of these instruments of action, international organization the main question is
referring to early successes in preventing the willingness to act of the national affiliates,
workers from one country being brought in as based on their view of the legitimacy and
strike-breakers in a dispute in another country representativity of the international body and
as the ‘international equivalent of picket- their estimate of the advisability of the action
ing’. Fimmen promoted the organization of proposed. National rivalries proved a major
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 337

obstacle to international action in the Cold and from other actors in the international
War period, particularly for the trade unions, system; and access to appropriate instru-
but also for employers and intergovernmental ments of action. These factors apply equally
organizations (Etty, 1978a; Piehl, 1974a). to employers’ and some other types of
Differences between national organizations in international organizations.
the industrialized and developing countries
have also created many problems for inter-
nal cohesion (Haworth and Ramsay, 1988: INSTRUMENTS AND OUTCOMES
311–21; Olle and Schöller, 1987: 37–9).
International organization is clearly necessary The major international actors form a network
for representation within intergovernmental of relationships, norms, rules and regulations
institutions, but only international workers’ or that provide the basis for the international
employers’ organizations that are seen as truly industrial relations system. But as I have
representative have the legitimacy required shown, the international actors are not
and the capacity to develop common strategies endowed with the same powers or sense of
out of disparate interests. legitimacy as national actors; international
Another key function for any international law is not enforceable in the same way as
organization is information and representation national law; and the main instruments of
to members or constituent groups. Again, the action are not always directly comparable.
means available to employers and trade unions However, an international industrial relations
are very different, but the function itself is the system with at least some instruments of
same. As with the external function discussed action and some rules does exist. Below, I
above – voice and representation to outside consider three types of international regula-
bodies, this internal function – servicing tion: international law, including conventions
and informing members – is particularly of the major intergovernmental institutions;
difficult at international level, because of voluntary forms of regulation, such as codes
the greater difficulties in communicating, of conduct; and international framework
achieving cohesion and representing a larger agreements based on collective bargaining.
variety of interests when covering a greater Together these three mechanisms shape, or
area of the globe. Observers of the interna- at least influence, the operations of the
tional labor movement claim that its capacity international economy in all areas related to
has expanded radically with the advent of industrial relations.
modern communications technology (Lee,
1997); it has been used to great effect in
International law and international
the coordination of international disputes,
labor standards
such as those at the international mining
concern Rio Tinto, but it is often used Prior to the creation of the ILO in 1919, a
more effectively by small, single-issue NGOs small number of international legal instru-
than by large, heterogeneous international ments adopted by the major European
organizations. The open access and essentially nations regulated certain health and safety
non-governable nature of the internet creates issues (Shotwell, 1934: 492–6). These set
new possibilities for international action, but the precedent for international standards in
challenges existing chains of communication industrial relations matters alongside those
and authority within international bodies. governing the actions of states in wartime
The main factors in the effectiveness and other international issues, and marked
of the international labor movement were an important step in the development of
well summarized by Windmuller (1967): the the intergovernmental system as a whole.
importance of internal cohesion, on the basis From the beginning, government ministers
of shared ideology and goals; recognition and other industrial relations actors were
and legitimacy, from the movement itself conscious of the difficulties of assuring the
338 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

implementation of international law by nation social regulations, for example concerning


states without infringing their sovereignty; health and safety standards or a living wage.
for this reason, international law generally Like all ILO conventions, these have the
requires transposition into national law and force of international law, and must be
enforcement by national governmental agen- adopted through legislation by all member
cies. The nature, purpose and means of states that have ratified them; they are given
enforcement of international legal instruments added weight by the 1998 Declaration, which
have been much debated by legal and requires states to observe them irrespective
industrial relations scholars (Langille, 2005; of formal ratification. As with other ILO
Valticos, 1998; Wedderburn, 2002). conventions, the means of ensuring imple-
Not all international legal instruments need mentation are limited, and rely mostly on
concern us here: some ILO conventions are the carrot of technical assistance and the
purely technical in nature or narrow in scope, stick of ‘naming and shaming’. However,
and many other international instruments have the ILO considers one core convention, that
no direct link to industrial relations issues. on Freedom of Association (no. 87), so
The most important for this discussion are the important that it created a Committee on
group of conventions adopted by the ILO that Freedom of Association in 1951 to monitor its
have won international recognition as essen- implementation, whether or not member states
tial for the protection of the legal and social had ratified it, on the basis of complaints raised
rights of workers and their representatives. by recognized representatives of workers
These ‘core’ conventions were first identified or employers as well as by other states.
at the World Social Summit in Copenhagen in Cases have been taken against governments
1995 and were formally adopted in the ILO’s in every region of the world and have
Declaration on Fundamental Principles and often led to substantial improvements in such
Rights at Work (1998). areas as union organizing rights (as with
These conventions are significant, not Japan in 1973: see Gumbrell-McCormick,
only because they have been recognized as 2000: 434). Other governments have been
‘core’ by the ILO itself, but because of the ostracized as a result of condemnation by
legitimacy they have acquired within world the Committee, including that of Chile under
public opinion. They form the basis of most Pinochet, sometimes contributing to change
of the voluntary codes of conduct adopted towards democracy.
by individual companies or industries and Some other international legal instruments
are accepted by governments in north and outside the ILO conventions are relevant to
south alike. Further, the implementation of our purposes. The most influential are prob-
these conventions is not considered to affect ably the guidelines on the conduct of MNCs
the comparative advantage of countries with included in the 1976 OECD Declaration on
low labour costs (Elliott and Freeman, 2003: International Investment and Multinational
11–13; Sengenberger, 2002), as could other Enterprises (Gumbrell-McCormick, 2000:
392–3; Murray, 2001). These guidelines,
updated in 2000, allow OECD member states,
Box 17.1 Core ILO Conventions recognized trade unions and employers’
representatives to ask for ‘clarification’ of
No Forced Labour (No. 29, 1930; No. 95,
their implementation by individual MNCs.
1957)
A number of high-profile cases were brought
Freedom of Association (No. 87, 1948)
in the first years after their adoption, such
Free Collective Bargaining (No. 98, 1949)
as the successful complaint brought by the
Equal Pay and Equal Treatment (No. 100,
government of Belgium against the Badger
1951; No. 111, 1958)
company, a subsidiary of a US multinational
No Child Labour (No. 138, 1973; No. 182,
(Blanpain, 1977). Here, too, the main form
1999)
of implementation has been ‘naming and
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 339

shaming’, and the guidelines have been (Tsogas, 2001). Some clauses have been
hampered by applying to OECD member inserted in regional agreements, such as those
states only. The influence of TUAC has of NAFTA (Elliott and Freeman, 2003: 84–9;
no doubt played a role in the successful Stanford, 2003) and in EU external trade
use of these guidelines. The ITUC has also agreements.
long pressed for a more general application As indicated earlier, the EU has a major
of codes of conduct (Keohane and Ooms, role in adopting supranational labor standards.
1975: 200). One of the key instruments is the directive,
The inclusion of ‘social clauses’ in interna- which as its name implies has stronger regu-
tional trade agreements is not strictly speaking latory force than ILO conventions: directives
a legal instrument, but is closely related in are instructions to member states, which
that such clauses require implementation by retain discretion in how they transpose them
intergovernmental organizations such as the into national law. The EU explicitly lacks
WTO, or through international or regional competence to adopt directives on general
agreements, such as NAFTA or ASEAN. As levels of pay or on trade union rights (though
with most international instruments, social the ill-fated Constitutional Treaty did include
clauses are based on ILO core conventions, references to both issues). Regulation on other
but the mode of implementation and enforce- employment issues (except those relating
ment is different. The threat of exclusion to health and safety) formerly required
from an international trade agreement is unanimous support in Council, but Treaty
potentially more persuasive than any of the changes in the 1990s increasingly enabled
sanctions available to the ILO or OECD, legislation by qualified majority. Before then,
but it is also more controversial and difficult most directives reflected a ‘lowest common
to adopt. Originally an initiative by the denominator’ of existing law in continental
International Metalworkers’ Federation and Europe – though the UK, with its ‘voluntarist’
the ICFTU during the negotiations for trade traditions, was more often obliged to make
liberalization in 1973 (Gumbrell-McCormick, legislative changes. From the 1990s there
2000: 508–11), the concept was soon taken up have been more substantial developments
by leading NGOs, trade unions in many indus- in EU law, covering in particular equal
trial countries and some social-democratic employment opportunities (covering issues
governments. of gender, race, disability, age and sexual
The ‘social clause’ was not welcomed, orientation); the treatment of ‘non-standard’
however, by most developing country work situations; working time; and employee
governments or by unions in those countries. information and consultation. The latter has
The main bone of contention has been the created a new industrial relations institution,
argument that the quest for international the European Works Council, obligatory if
labor standards is ‘protectionist’ (Gumbrell- employee representatives so demand in all
McCormick, 2004: 44–6; Tsogas, 2001). larger European MNCs. There is by now a
The ITUC, ILO and many academics have large literature on the impact of this legislation
challenged this argument, and Elliott and (Fitzgerald and Stirling, 2004). The obligation
Freeman (2003: 17–22, 80–3) have provided to introduce formal mechanisms of employee
convincing evidence that protectionism has information and consultation at national level
not been a motive for most actors, yet this has also required a major change in UK
contention has been a powerful obstacle to legislation.
the adoption of social clauses. As a result, Many observers feel that the era of exten-
a shifting coalition of developing country sive EU employment regulation is now past.
governments and conservative western For a decade the Commission appears to have
governments has always managed to block adopted a more neo-liberal, de-regulationist
the inclusion of a social clause in GATT stance; while achieving even a qualified
and subsequently in WTO agreements majority in the Council for new directives has
340 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

become more problematic, particularly after in the ‘Global Compact’ proclaimed by


the major enlargement of EU membership in UN secretary-general Kofi Annan in 1999
2004. The emphasis has shifted to the ‘open (Ruggie, 2003; Thérien and Pouliot, 2006),
method of coordination’ (OMC) and other and has also been strongly supported by the
forms of soft law, exemplified by the European EU (European Commission, 2001).2
Employment Strategy which sets guidelines The effectiveness of codes is another
for member state policy but has no explicit important area of debate. The wording is
binding effect. often vague and the content limited, excluding
support for rights to union organization and
collective bargaining. They are concentrated
Voluntary measures – codes
in consumer industries, while less high-
of conduct
profile industries are rarely covered. They
Recent years have seen a rapid growth of are uncoordinated, leading to multiple codes
voluntary forms of regulation, usually by in some industries and companies, each
individual companies or groups within an with its own detailed, sometimes conflicting,
industrial sector. There is now a substantial provisions. Monitoring is left to a number
body of academic and practitioner literature of agencies, mainly private accounting and
on these measures, which include corporate auditing firms, and is therefore inconsistent
codes of conduct, corporate social responsibil- and often weak, too closely linked to the
ity initiatives and other company-led schemes employer’s interest (Justice, 2002; for a
(Elliott and Freeman, 2003; Tsogas, 2001). detailed study of monitoring and application
This growth has accompanied the rise of in Mexico and Guatemala see Rodríguez-
neo-liberalism and the focus, by academics Garavito, 2005.) One possible solution has
as well as employers and governments, on been proposed by Kyloh (1998), that the
the agenda of ‘deregulation’ and increased ILO should become the monitoring body for
autonomy of the firm. These voluntary codes the implementation of all international labor
are usually based on the ILO core conventions standards and codes. A centralized inspec-
(although significantly less often on conven- torate would have the potential of improving
tions 87 and 98). They are most common the coordination and implementation of the
in high-profile industries, especially the gar- current plethora of different codes, a problem
ment, textile and food industries, where brand for employers as well as workers, as Elliott
names play a large role in consumer choice. and Freeman also point out (2003: 132–3).
Some academics and practitioners have This would require a degree of cooperation
stressed the self-interest of the firms involved, between individual corporations, the ILO and
seeking to avoid mandatory regulation by the IFIs that does not yet exist (Verma, 2003;
international or national legal instruments and Vosko, 2002).
often responding to campaigns by trade unions
and NGOs that threaten bad publicity for the International framework
brand (Elliott and Freeman, 2003; Justice,
agreements and international
2003). Others emphasize altruistic motives in
collective bargaining
the adoption of a CSR agenda, the leadership
of committed individual entrepreneurs, or International collective bargaining is the basis
the firm’s own benefits from higher labor for the third form of international regulation
standards (Jenkins, 2002; Murray, 2002). we consider here. As noted above, this was
Examples can be found to suit both argu- strongly advocated in the 1970s by Levinson
ments, and indeed motives are often complex and other international trade union leaders.
and interwoven, and enlightened self-interest Many academic observers indeed insisted
often bridges the gap between altruism and that international trade unionism would only
selfishness. In any event, corporate social be effective in so far as it was able to
responsibility was an important element engage in international collective bargaining
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 341

(Ramsay, 1997, 1999). This was largely the basis of the ILO core conventions, and
ineffectual: almost universally, MNCs refused these appear to be shared by wide sectors of
to bargain cross-nationally on core issues such public opinion. Further, there are international
as rates of pay. institutions involved in regulating industrial
However, from the late 1980s a number relations matters: the ILO and the rest of
of international ‘framework’ agreements have the UN system, the WTO and OECD. These
been concluded between the ICFTU and ITSs too have proved fairly stable over the past
(or GUFs) and leading MNCs, mainly in 50 years, and in the case of the ILO,
the food, hotel, textile and other consumer nearly over a century. But these international
industries. One of the first was with the French institutions lack key characteristics of states –
multinational BSN-Danone in 1988 (Justice, democratic accountability (if not legitimacy),
2003: 97–8). Such framework agreements the ability to monitor compliance and the
are usually based, like corporate codes, on power to impose sanctions on those who
the ILO core conventions. Unlike corporate breach the requirements.
codes, they do include references to con- If an international industrial relations
ventions 87 and 98, on union representation system simply means a larger version of
and collective bargaining. They also tend national systems, we would have to conclude
to provide for independent monitoring, by that it does not (yet) exist. But as I have
NGOs or by the trade unions themselves. argued, the two are not analogous. Trade
Framework agreements – which have been unions at the international level may not
endorsed by the EU – are a potentially carry out collective bargaining or strikes
important form of regulation combining the (although they sometimes do), but they
best features of international labor standards pursue much the same ends through other
and voluntary codes of conduct. There are means: international campaigns, coordination
still too few of them in operation to be of national or sectoral demands, coordi-
able to judge their effectiveness, though nated approaches to corporate head offices.
numbers are increasing (Miller, 2004; Wills, International employers’ associations are
2002). weak, but individual employers do operate
on an international scale, with more flex-
ibility, greater means and a higher degree
CONCLUSION AND FUTURE of coordination than trade unions. The most
DIRECTIONS problematic element here is the state: the
ILO cannot simply send in international
I conclude with brief reflections on both the inspectors any more than the UN can send in
theory and the practice of international indus- peace-keeping forces, without the consent of
trial relations, but first return to my opening member states. But, as Langille argues (2005,
point, that there is at least the beginning of an 20–2), international law does not have to be
international industrial relations system, but it enforceable in the same way as national law –
is a mistake to see it as a national system writ the implementation of ILO conventions, for
large. example, depends on employers and states
The preceding pages have introduced the understanding that this is in their best interests.
reader to international industrial relations This is essentially the European approach
actors – trade unions, NGOs, employers and of ‘soft’ law or OMC applied on a world
their organizations. To be sure, these actors scale.
operate primarily at the national level, but they Until recently at least, academic analysis
have by now built up a set of institutions at of the field has been weakened by a triple
the international level that has remained intact set of demarcations. In terms of analyt-
throughout most of the past century. These ical approach, there have been valuable
actors, along with those at the national level, contributions by those working in the disci-
possess a limited common set of norms, on plines of international relations, constitutional
342 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and labor law, trade union history and REFERENCES


labor economics; but their work has rarely
interconnected to any substantial degree. The Abbott, K.W. and Snidal, D. (2000) ‘Hard and Soft
problem of separate worlds applies equally in Law in International Governance’, International
terms of language: most academics writing in Organization 54 (3): 421–56.
English are unfamiliar with the considerable Alcock, A. (1971) History of the International Labour
Organization. London: Macmillan.
literature written in other languages; in the
Anner, M., Greer, I., Hauptmeier, M., Lillie, N. and
reverse direction the problem is less serious
Winchester, N. (2006) ‘The Industrial Determinants
but still exists. Ideologically, there has tended of Transnational Solidarity: Global Inter-Union Politics
to be a polarization between ‘optimists’ in Three Sectors’, European Journal of Industrial
and ‘defeatists’ regarding the possibilities of Relations 12 (1): 7–27.
consensual regulation of the global economy Balanyá, B., Doherty, A., Hoedeman, O., Ma’anit, A. and
and its employment outcomes. Hence the Wesselius, E. (2003) Europe Inc., 2nd edn. London:
future of the theory of international indus- Pluto Press.
trial relations requires further development Berger, S. (2000) ‘Globalization and Politics’, Annual
of cross-disciplinary research and analysis, Review of Political Science 3 (?): 43–62.
greater familiarity with the linguistic variety Blanpain, R. (1977) The Badger Case and the OECD
of existing literatures and more sophisticated Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises. Deventer:
Kluwer.
exploration of ways in which the governance
Böröcz, J. and Sarkar, M. (2005) ‘What is the EU?’,
of globalization, though difficult, may yet be
International Sociology 20 (2): 153–73.
possible. Bulmer, S.J. (1998) ‘New Institutionalism and the
In the world of practice, it is inevitable Governance of the Single European Market’, Journal
that regulation at international level remains of European Public Policy 5 (3): 365–86.
highly contested. There is some basis for the Cammack, P. (2005) ‘The Governance of Global
criticism that the official trade union institu- Capitalism: A New Materialist Perspective’ in
tions have been too ready to pursue a ‘com- R Wilkinson, ed., The Global Governance Reader.
posite resolution’ approach (Hyman, 2005b) London: Routledge. pp. 156–73.
which locks them into the dominant logic Carew, A. (1987) Labour under the Marshall Plan.
of the IFIs and of neo-liberal governments. Manchester: Manchester UP.
Conversely, anti-capitalist social movements Chorev, N. (2005) ‘The Institutional Project of Neo-
liberal Globalism: The Case of the WTO’, Theory and
have more frontally challenged the main
Society 34 (3): 317–55.
drift of globalization but have offered few
Coates, K. and Topham, T. (1980) Trade Unions in
persuasive visions of how to shift the Britain. Nottingham: Spokesman.
outcomes. There are however signs of a new Cockburn, C. (1997) ‘Gender in an International
accommodation, in which international trade Space: Trade Union Women as European Social
unionism recognizes the need for a more Actor’, Women’s Studies International Forum 20 (4):
combative stance, while many international 459–70.
NGOs prepare for the long march through Commons, J.R. (1909) ‘American Shoemakers,
the institutions. If such a synthesis evolves, 1648–1895: A Sketch of Industrial Evolution’,
perhaps a new world – or a new international Quarterly Journal of Economics 24 (1): 39–84.
industrial relations system – is possible? Devin, G. (1990) ‘La Confédération Internationale
Des Syndicats Libres: Exploration d’un Réseau’ in
G. Devin, Syndicalisme: Dimensions Internationales.
La Garenne-Colombes: Editions Européennes
ERASME. pp. 69–99.
NOTES
Dingwerth, K. and Pattberg, P. (2006) ‘Global
1 http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/15/33/
Governance as a Perspective on World Politics’,
34011915.pdf Global Governance 12 (2): 185–203.
2 Promoting a European framework for corporate Dølvik, J.E. (1997) Redrawing Boundaries of Solidarity?
social responsibility http://ec.europa.eu/employment_ ETUC, Social Dialogue and the Europeanisation of
social/soc-dial/csr/greenpaper_en.pdf Trade Unions in the 1990s. Oslo: Arena.
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 343

Dunlop, J.T (1958) Industrial Relations Systems. Hyman, R. (2005a) ‘Shifting Dynamics in International
New York: Holt. Trade Unionism: Agitation, Organization, Diplomacy,
Elliott, K.A. and Freeman, R.B. (2003) Can Bureaucracy’, Labour History 46 (2): 137–54.
Labor Standards Improve under Globalization? Hyman, R. (2005b) ‘Trade Unions and the Politics
Washington: Institute for International Economics. of European Integration’, Economic and Industrial
Etty, T. (1978a) ‘Gewerkschaftliche Weltkonzernauss- Democracy 26 (1): 9–40.
chüsse: Ein Überblick’, in W. Olle (ed.), Einführung Ietto-Gillies, G. (2005) Transnational Corporations and
in die internationale Gewerkschaftspolitik, 1, Berlin: International Production. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Olle & Wolter, pp. 68–78. ILO (1931) Dix ans d’Organisation Internationale du
Etty, T. and Tudyka, K. (1974) ‘Wereldkoncernraden: Travail. Geneva: ILO.
Vakbonden en hun “kapitaalgerichte” Strategie Jenkins, R. (2002) ‘The Political Economy of Codes of
Tegen Multinationale Ondernemingen’, in T. Etty, Conduct’ in R. Jenkins, R. Pearson and G. Seyfang,
K. Tudyka and P. Reckman (eds), ‘Naar een eds, Corporate Responsibility and Labour Rights.
Multinationale Vakbeweging’, Kosmodok 7 (2): 3–39. London: Earthscan. pp. 13–30.
Fimmen, E. (1924) Labour’s Alternative: The United Jensen, C.S., Madsen, J.S. and Due, J. (1999) ‘Phases
States of Europe or Europe Limited. London: Labour and Dynamics in the Development of EU Industrial
Publishing Co. Relations Regulation‘, Industrial Relations Journal
Fitzgerald, G. and Stirling, J. (eds) (2004) European 30 (2): 118–34.
Works Councils: Pessimism of the Intellect, Optimism Justice, D. (2003) ‘The International Trade Union
of the Will. London: Routledge. Movement and the New Codes of Conduct’ in
Germain, R.D. (2002) ‘Reforming the International R. Jenkins, R. Pearson and G. Seyfang, (eds),
Financial Architecture: The New Political Agenda’ in Corporate Responsibility and Labour Rights. London:
R. Wilkinson and S. Hughes, eds, Global Governance, Earthscan. pp. 90–100.
Critical Perspectives. London: Routledge. Katz, H. and Darbishire, O. (2000) Converging
pp. 17–35. Divergences: Worldwide Changes in Employment
Gobin, C. (1997) L’europe Syndicale. Brussels: Labor. Systems. Ithaca: ILR Press.
Gray, J. (1998) False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Kelly, D. (2005) ‘The International Chamber of
Capitalism. London: Granta. Commerce’, New Political Economy 10 (2): 259–71.
Gumbrell-McCormick, R. (2000) ‘Facing New Keohane, R.O. and Ooms, Van D. (1975) ‘The
Challenges: The International Confederation of Free Multinational Firm and International Regulation’,
Trade Unions (1972–1990s)’ in A. Carew, M. Dreyfus, International Organization 29 (1): 169–209.
G. Van Goethem, R. Gumbrell-McCormick and M. van Koenig-Archibugi, M. (2003) ‘Global Governance’ in
der Linden, (eds) The International Confederation of J. Michie, ed., The Handbook of Globalisation.
Free Trade Unions. Bern: Peter Lang. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 318–30.
Gumbrell-McCormick, R. (2004) ‘The ICFTU and Koh, H.H. (1999) ‘How Is International Human Rights
the World Economy: A Historical Perspective’, in Law Enforced?’, Indiana Law Journal 74 (?):
R. Munck, (ed.) Labour and Globalisation, Liverpool: 1397–17.
Liverpool University Press. pp. 34–51. Kyloh, R. (1998) ‘The Governance of Globalization: The
Haworth, N. and Ramsay, H. (1986) ‘Matching the ILO Contribution’ in R. Kyloh, ed., Mastering the
Multinationals: Obstacles to International Trade Challenge of Globalization: Towards a Trade Union
Unionism’, International Journal of Sociology and Agenda. Geneva: ILO. pp. 1–35.
Social Policy 6 (2): 55–82. Langille, B. (2005) What is International Labour Law
Haworth, N. and Ramsay, H. (1988) ‘Workers of For? Geneva: IILS.
the World United: International Capital and Some Lee, E. (1997) ‘Globalization and Labor Standards:
Dilemmas in Industrial Democracy’, in R. Southall (ed), A Review of the Issues’, International Labour Review
Trade Unions and the New Industrialisation of the 136 (2): 173–89.
Third World. London: Zed, pp. 308–21. Leisink, P. and Hyman, R. (2005) ‘Introduction: The
Heery, E. and Frege, C. (2006) ‘New Actors in Industrial Dual Evolution of Europeanization and Varieties of
Relations’, British Journal of Industrial Relations Governance’, European Journal of Industrial Relations
44 (4): 601–04. 11 (3): 277–86.
Hertz, N. (2001) The Silent Takeover: Global Capitalism Levinson, C. (1971) Capitalism, Inflation and the
and the Death of Democracy. London: Heinemann. Multinationals. London: Allen & Unwin.
Hughes, S. (2005) ‘The International Labour Organiza- Levinson, C. (1972) International Trade Unionism.
tion’, New Political Economy 10 (3): 413–25. London: Allen & Unwin.
344 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Logue, J. (1980) Toward a Theory of Trade Reinalda, B. (1997) ‘The ITF in the Context of
Union Internationalism. Gothenburg: University of International Trade Unionism’ in B. Reinalda
Gothenburg. (ed.), The International Transportworkers’ Federation
Lorwin, L. L. (1929) Labour and Internationalism. 1914–1945: The Edo Fimmen Era. Amsterdam: IISG.
London: Allen & Unwin. Rodríguez-Garavito, C.A. (2005) ‘Global Governance
MacShane, D. (1992) International Labour and the and Labor Rights: Codes of Conduct and Anti-
Origins of the Cold War. Oxford: Clarendon. Sweatshop Struggles in Global Apparel Factories in
Martin, A. and Ross, G. (1999) ‘In the Line of Fire: The Mexico and Guatemala’, Politics and Society 33 (2):
Europeanization of Labor Representation’ in A. Martin 203–33.
and G. Ross et al., The Brave New World of European Rojot, J. (2006) ‘International Collective Bargaining’
Labor. New York: Berghahn. pp. 312–67. in M.J. Morley, P. Gunnigle and D.G. Collings,
Martin, R. (1980) TUC: Growth of a Pressure Group. eds, Global Industrial Relations. London: Routledge.
Oxford: Clarendon. pp. 254–72.
Miller, D. (2004) ‘Negotiating International Framework Rosenau, J.N. and Czempiel, E.-O., (eds) 1992.
Agreements in the Global Textile, Garment and Governance without Government: Order and Change
Footwear Sector’, Global Social Policy 4 (2): 215–39. in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.
Munck, R. (2002) Globalisation and Labour: The New Ruggie. J.G. (2003) ‘The United Nations and Globaliza-
‘Great Transformation’. London: Zed. tion: Patterns and Limits of Institutional Adaptation’,
Murray, J. (2001) ‘A New Phase in the Regulation of Global Governance 9 (3): 301–21.
Multinational Enterprises: The Role of the OECD’, Scharpf, F. (1999) Governing in Europe: Effective and
Industrial Law Journal 30 (3): 255–70. Democratic? Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Murray, J. (2002) ‘Labour Rights/Corporate Respon- Schmidt, V.A. (2002) The Futures of European
sibilities: The Role of ILO Labour Standards’ in Capitalism. Oxford: OUP.
R. Jenkins, R. Pearson and G. Seyfang, (eds), Sen, J., Anand, A., Escobar, A. and Waterman, P. (eds)
Corporate Responsibility and Labour Rights. London: (2004) World Social Forum: Challenging Empires.
Earthscan. pp. 31–42. New Delhi: Viveka Foundation.
Northrup, H. and Rowan, R. (1979) Multinational Sengenberger, W. (2002) Globalization and Social
Collective Bargaining Attempts: The Record, the Progress: The Role and Impact of International Labour
Cases and the Prospects. Philadelphia: Wharton Standards. Bonn: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung. pp. 30–70.
School. Shotwell, J.T., ed. (1934) The Origins of the International
Olle, W. and Schöller, W. (1987) ‘World Market Labour Organization. New York: Columbia UP.
Competition and Restrictions upon International Standing, G. (2004) ‘Global Governance: The Demo-
Trade Union Policies’, in R. Boyd, R. Cohen and P. cratic Mirage?’, Development and Change 35 (5):
Gutkind (eds), International Labour and the Third 1065–72.
World, Aldershot: Avebury. Stanford, J. (2003) ‘The North American Free Trade
Panić, M. (2003) ‘A New Bretton Woods?’ in J. Michie, Agreement: Context, Structure and Performance’ in
ed, The Handbook of Globalisation. Cheltenham: J. Michie, (ed.), The Handbook of Globalisation.
Edward Elgar. pp. 370–82. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 261–82.
Pasture, P. (1994) ‘Christian Trade Unionism in Europe Stiglitz, J. (2002) Globalization and its Discontents.
Since 1968’. Aldershot: Avebury. London: Allen Lane.
Piehl, E. (1974a) ‘Multinationale Konzerne und die Strange, S. (1996) The Retreat of the State: The
Zersplitterung der internationalen Gewerkschaftsbe- Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge:
wegung’, Argument-Sonderbände AS2: 230–55. Cambridge UP.
Piehl, E. (1974b) ‘Gewerkschaftliche Basismobilisierung Thérien, J.-P. and Pouliot, V. (2006) ‘The Global
kontra multinationale Kapitalstrategie: am Beispiel Compact: Shifting the Politics of International
Ford’, in O. Jacobi, W. Müller-Jentsch and E. Schmidt Development?’, Global Governance 12 (1): 55–75.
(eds), Gewerkschaften und Klassenkampf: Kritisches Thomson, D. and Larson, R. (1978) Where Were You
Jahrbuch 1974. Frankfurt: Fischer. pp. 235–48. Brother? London: War on Want.
Ramsay, H. (1997) ‘Solidarity at Last? International Toye, J. (2003) ‘The International Monetary Fund
Trade Unionism Approaching the Millennium’, and the World Bank’ in J. Michie, ed., The
Economic and Industrial Democracy 18 (4): 503–37. Handbook of Globalisation. Cheltenham: Edward
Ramsay, H. (1999) ‘In Search of International Union Elgar. pp. 358–69.
Theory’ in J Waddington (ed.), Globalization and Tsogas, G. (2001) Labor Regulation in a Global Economy.
Patterns of Labour Resistance. London: Mansell. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.
INTERNATIONAL ACTORS AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION 345

Valticos N (1998) ‘International labour standards Wallace, H. (2000) ‘Europeanisation and Globalisation:
and human rights: approaching the year 2000’ Complementary or Contradictory Trends?’, New
International Labour Review, 137 (2): 135–47. Political Economy 5 (3): 369–82.
van der Linden, M (2000) ‘Conclusion: The Past and Waterman, P. (1998) Globalization, Social Movements
Future of International Trade Unionism’ in A Carew, and the New Internationalisms. London: Mansell.
M Dreyfus, G Van Goethem, R Gumbrell-McCormick Waterman, P. and Timms, J. (2005) ‘Trade Union
and M van der Linden, The International Confedera- Internationalism and a Global Civil Society in the
tion of Free Trade Unions. Bern: Peter Lang. Making’ in H. Anheier, M. Glasius and M. Kaldor,
Van Goethem, G (2000) ‘Conflicting Interests: The Inter- (eds), Global Civil Society 2004/5. London: Sage.
national Federation of Trade Unions (1919–1945)’ in pp. 175–202.
A Carew, M Dreyfus, G Van Goethem, R Gumbrell- Wedderburn, K.W. (2002) ‘Common Law, Labour
McCormick and M van der Linden, The Interna- Law, Global Law’ in B. Hepple, ed., Social and
tional Confederation of Free Trade Unions. Bern: Labour Rights in a Global Context. Cambridge: CUP.
Peter Lang. pp. 19–54.
Verma, A. (2003) ‘Global Labor Standards: Can We Wedin, Å (1974) International Trade Union Solidarity:
Get from Here to There?’, International Journal of ICFTU 1957-1965. Stockholm: Prisma.
Comparative Labor Law and Industrial Relations Weiss, L. (1998) The Myth of the Powerless State. Ithaca:
19 (4): 515–34. Cornell UP.
Visser, J. (1996) ‘Internationalism in European Trade Wills, J. (2002) ‘Bargaining for the Space to Organise in
Unions’ in Patrick Pasture, Johan Verberckmoes and the Global Economy: A Review of the Accor–IUF Trade
Hans De Witte (eds), The Lost Perspective? Vol 2. Union Rights Agreement’, Review of International
Aldershot: Avebury. pp. 176–99. Political Economy 9 (4): 675–700.
Visser, J. (1998) ‘Learning to Play: The Europeanisation Windmuller, J P (1967) ‘International Trade Union
of Trade Unions’ in P. Pasture and J. Verberckmoes Organizations’ in S Barkin (ed.), International Labor.
(eds), Working-Class Internationalism and the Appeal New York: Harper & Row.
of National Identity. Oxford: Berg. pp. 231–56. Zeitlin, J. and Pochet, P., eds (2005) The Open Method of
Vosko, L.F. (2002) “‘Decent Work”: The Shifting Role Co-ordination in Action: The European Employment
of the ILO and the Struggle for Global Social Justice’, and Social Inclusion Strategies Brussels: P.I.E.-Peter
Global Social Policy 2 (1): 19–46. Lang.
18
Works Councils
Jean Jenkins and Paul Blyton

INTRODUCTION limited scale) South Africa (Kim and Kim,


2004; Rogers and Streeck, 1995; Wood and
Works councils continue to attract consid- Mahabir, 2001). There has also been interest,
erable interest from industrial relations (IR) though limited progress, in the potential for
scholars. As the fortunes of other IR arrange- ‘intermediate organizations’ such as joint
ments have faltered in many countries – committees and works council arrangements
notably the coverage of collective bargaining as possible mechanisms for workforce rep-
and levels of trade union membership – resentation and mutual gains in the US
other forms of employee representation, such (see Freeman, 2005: 663). If every form of
as works councils, have gained an added representation-based worker consultation is
significance. Indeed, Frege (2002: 221) goes included, the list of countries operating such
so far as to assert that works councils have arrangements is a comparatively long one.
come to be ‘widely regarded as the most However, as Marginson and Sisson (2006: 46)
prominent, widespread and powerful form note in their discussion of European indus-
of industrial democracy in contemporary trial relations, even within those European
capitalist societies’. It is certainly the case that contexts where works councils operate at
this prominence has been further advanced workplace level, the precise arrangements
in Europe over the recent period by the vary considerably from country to country,
promotion of works council structures by the making direct comparisons hazardous. The
European Union (EU) as the way to secure most notable variations include whether the
more extensive employee information and councils are trade union or employee based,
consultation, both within transnational corpo- whether they are underpinned by voluntary
rations and in nationally-based organizations. or statutory provision and what their different
Works council arrangements of one form rights and responsibilities cover. For example,
or another act as vehicles for employee in Austria, Germany, Luxembourg and the
workplace representation in many countries, Netherlands, legislation has led to works
particularly within Europe but also elsewhere, council systems that involve elections of
such as South Korea and (on a more representatives by all employees and also that
WORKS COUNCILS 347

the works councils form the main vehicle outcomes of works councils will act as a useful
for local worker representation. Elsewhere, starting point not only for considering future
however, in countries such as Belgium, challenges to works council arrangements
France, Portugal and Spain, works councils more generally, but also the prospects for
operate alongside union committees as paral- higher level (transnational) works council
lel local-level representation systems (ibid). systems that have been shaped, in part, by the
In the UK and Ireland, the general absence German experience.
in the past of a statutory requirement for
consulting employees is reflected in a lack of
any uniform pattern of consultation, though WORKS COUNCIL DEVELOPMENT
consultative arrangements of one form or IN GERMANY
another are long established. For example
in the UK, workplace consultation structures Within Europe, the German system of
can be traced back almost a century, and in industrial relations continues to represent a
2004 just over two-fifths (42 per cent) of all prime example of one where legal regulation
employees were located in a workplace with a underpins worker representation. Germany
workplace-level joint consultation committee conforms to Hall and Soskice’s classification
(Kersley et al., 2005: 14). In addition, the UK of a co-ordinated market economy (2003:
has long standing, issue-specific consultation 241), where the ‘insider’ model of corporate
arrangements in the area of health and safety, governance prevails. Within such systems, far
as well as requirements on employers to more scope exists for influence to be exerted
consult over redundancy and transfer. by different stakeholder interests in the firm,
Of the different works council systems in including workers and their representatives,
operation, those operating in parts of Europe than prevails in less regulated, ‘outsider’
remain more highly developed than else- models of liberal market economies (such as
where. Of these, the most extensive rights to the US and UK), where shareholder interests
information, consultation and joint decision- dominate. In Germany, the roots of worker
making exist in Austria and Germany. Given representation in the workplace are long
the more detailed evaluative literature avail- established. During and immediately after the
able on the latter, we will consider the German First World War, official union structures were
experience in more detail (for a discussion supplemented at the workplace by Arbeiter-
of the Austrian system, see Traxler, 1998). atte or unofficial workers’ councils (Hyman,
It is worth noting, however, that even by 2001: 24). To varying degrees, these councils
narrowing the focus to a single country challenged official trade union policies (in a
(and one where the works council system similar way that early shop steward systems
has been strongly supported and shaped did in Britain) and were viewed as a source of
by legal regulation) the diversity in how disorder – even potential social revolution –
works councils function in practice, and their both by employers and official trade unions
varying impact on management activity, have (Clegg, 1976: 58–60; Hyman, 2001: 44). In
frequently been acknowledged and hamper different national contexts various ‘solutions’
generalized conclusions (see for example, to grass-roots worker militancy evolved, and
Haipeter and Lehndorff, 2005; Jirjahn and in 1920s Germany this involved enacting laws
Smith, 2006: 650–2; and Kotthoff, 1994 which separated workers’ representation at
cited in Frege, 2002). Such diversity is less the workplace from the sectoral, regional or
surprising when one considers the very large national collective bargaining system, and
number of works councils in operation in channeled local activities into formal works
Germany – over 40,000 in the private sector councils. After the Second World War the
alone in the 1990s, for example (Jacobi et al., works councils, which had originally been a
1998: 211). Nevertheless, a review of recent means of containing socialist revolutionary
German evidence on the developing role and fervor, became a vehicle for safeguarding
348 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

democracy and preventing a return of fascism. Unions have typically provided works
It was judged as important to have trade councillors with training and legal
union involvement and worker participation advice, while works councillors (who in
enshrined in the constitution for the rebuilding most cases are themselves trade unionists)
of Germany, and indeed, Europe (Hyman, have contributed to union membership by
2001: 116–7). recruiting on the unions’behalf (French, 2001:
The system of dual channels of repre- 562; Jacobi et al., 1998: 191–2). However,
sentation for workers became increasingly as we will discuss, the dual system has come
formalized: one channel by means of col- under increasing pressure in more recent
lective bargaining by trade unions, the other years as a result of growing international
by consultation and co-determination via competition, as well as other factors (see
works councils. The Works Constitution Act Frege, 2002: 241; and Hassel, 1999).
(Betriebverfassungsgesetz, 1952, amended Yet, despite the way in which the German
1972/1988/2001) gave employees at estab- works council system has been widely cele-
lishments with more than five employees brated as a model to emulate, within Germany
the right to a works council where three its coverage is far from comprehensive.
employees (or a union represented in the Despite the mandatory nature of establishing
establishment) initiated an election (French, a works council where a small number of
2001: 560). Works council functions are employees initiate an election, in practice
legally distinct from areas of union activity it is estimated that only between one-half
and works council representatives are elected and three-fifths of employees in eligible
by all workers, not just union members. workplaces are covered by a work council
The same Act also provides for worker (Addison et al., 2004b: 402; Frege, 2002: 234;
representation on the supervisory boards Weiss, 2006). While works council presence
of companies. The activities of supervisory is very high in larger establishments (councils
boards will not be considered in this chapter, are present in over 95 per cent of workplaces
however. with more than 1,000 employees, for example)
The upshot of the development of laws on it is very much lower in small workplaces.
employee representation is a highly juridified Addison (2005: 428) notes that in firms with
system of management-worker relations in between five and twenty employees, less
Germany. As part of this, works councils than one in ten has a works council. In
have rights to information, consultation and many respects, this lack of coverage in small
co-determination over different areas of workplaces is not surprising. Not only is
organizational activity. Crucially, in return, the threshold for eligibility set comparatively
they are charged with supporting the employer low (5 employees) but also the power of
in achieving the aims of the enterprise. In works councils, and specifically their statutory
this way, distributive collective bargaining rights to information, become significantly
is left to trade unions while works council stronger in establishments with over 21, and
representatives are charged with representing particularly over 100 employees. Likewise,
workers’ interests in a spirit of ‘mutual resources to support the activities of the works
trust’ with employers. Works councils cannot council (for example, additional rights to
lawfully lead or organize industrial action; time off for councillors) become operable in
peaceful negotiations only are permitted, with establishments with more than 200 employees
any disputes settled by labor courts or an (Addison et al., 2004b).
arbitration committee. Probably of more concern for the future
The dual system has served Germany well. of the works council system in Germany,
Despite tensions during different periods, however, is not their low frequency in small
and problems of achieving full coverage (see firms, but the indications of declining cover-
below), works councils and unions have gen- age since the 1980s. Addison et al. (2004b) for
erally maintained a symbiotic relationship. example, to quote national statistics indicating
WORKS COUNCILS 349

that between the mid-1980s and mid-1990s A series of other developments acting to
the proportion of employees not enjoying reduce collective organization and increase
works council coverage rose by more than more individualized employment systems are
a quarter. Haipeter and Lehndorff (2005: also evident in Germany. One example of
141) note a similar decline occurring in even these is the increasingly widespread use
the well-organized engineering and metal- of individual working time accounts where
working sector: a fall in works council hours worked in excess of contractually-
coverage from 77 to 63 per cent of employees agreed hours are ‘banked’ and converted into
between 1980 and 2000. The tendency toward time off at a later stage, rather than paid
smaller company sizes appears to be one as overtime (Haipeter and Lehndorff, 2005;
factor accounting for this reduced works Croucher and Singe, 2004). These individual
council presence (Keller, 2004: 226). time accounts have acted not only to reduce
Works councils in Germany face challenges overtime costs for employers, but at the same
not only in maintaining and extending their time have reduced works council rights to co-
coverage in medium and smaller enterprises, determination in respect of overtime (Haipeter
but also in retaining an influential presence and Lehndorff, 2005: 145) and generally
within the organizations in which they are undermined the collective organization of
present. Both coverage and influence of works working time in those organizations using
councils have also been relevant issues in the time banking arrangements (see also
former Eastern German enterprises following Chapter 27 Working Hours and Work-Life
reunification. While Frege (1999) points to Balance, in this volume). This is not to deny
the success of the works council system in the possibility of works councils playing
gaining widespread acceptance in the former an active part in the regulation of time-
Eastern regions, Gumbrell-McCormick and banking arrangements, particularly on issues
Hyman (2006), together with Frege herself relating to the limits of employer or employee
and others, question the degree to which influence over the use of time credits (for
works councils have been able to develop examples in engineering, see Haipeter and
their role and influence employers in a similar Lehndorff, 2005; and financial services, see
way to their counterparts in Western German. Croucher and Singe, 2004). However, it is
The particularly difficult economic conditions also evident that in other situations, a less
and high redundancy and unemployment effective works council response to problems
rates that have faced many enterprises and arising from time banking has diminished the
communities in the former Eastern regions role of the works council in certain sectors
appear to have severely hampered the ability (Croucher and Singe, 2004) and occupational
of many newly-constituted works councils to groups (Haipeter and Lehndorff, 2005).
exert an independent influence within their Yet while some working time developments
workplaces. More generally in Germany, the appear to be challenging the role of many
growth of international competition and the works councils in Germany, other working
influence of incoming foreign multinational time issues can be seen to have enhanced the
companies, represent further challenges to role of works councils in the recent period.
the status and representation of worker In part, these developments reflect a more
interests in Germany, as they have proven general issue that pressures to decentralize
to be elsewhere. These challenges manifest industrial relations (pressures that are noted
themselves in various ways. Royle (1998) for at several points throughout this volume) can
example, highlights the extent to which those work in favor of extant local IR institutions,
multinational firms entering Germany that are such as works councils. In Germany, this is
averse to co-determination, have been able exemplified in the expanded role of works
successfully to deploy avoidance strategies councils over certain aspects of working
to minimize works council development (see hours. Historically, works councils have
also Ferner and Edwards, 1995). played a role in the determination of actual
350 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

working time patterns, including the shift moves to decentralize industrial relations
arrangements, the scheduling of paid leave activities in Germany have bolstered the role
and the regulation of overtime (Addison and scope of works councils.
et al., 2004c: 128). However, working time In terms of any evaluation of the impact
settlements in the 1990s – most notably or outcomes of works councils in Germany,
the negotiation of a 35-hour week in the three problems are evident at the outset.
metal-working industry in former Western First, as Frege (2002: 237) points out,
Germany – were accompanied by agreement a general methodological problem is the
that implementation of the shorter week distribution of works council activity: almost
would be subject to detailed local negotiations all large workplaces have a works council,
between management and works councils which therefore restricts comparisons of those
(Haipeter and Lehndorff, 2005). In subsequent with or without a works council mainly to
local negotiations, management have sought medium and smaller establishments. Second,
increased working time flexibility as a means the outcomes that have been considered
to offset the cut in hours. The metal-working have tended to be primarily issues relating
settlement for example, provided scope not to firm performance – the effect of works
only for local agreement over the proportion council presence on productivity, wage levels,
of the workforce who could hold contracts investment and so on. As Frege points out,
exceeding 35 hours (up to a 40-hour limit) but however (ibid: 239) these outcomes fail to
also over the length of the averaging period reflect the central reasons why works councils
(up to 6 months and in certain cases 1 year) were introduced and supported by the state
within which the agreed 35-hours could be in Germany in the first place: to increase the
achieved. level of employee participation and industrial
The upshot of these developments has democracy in the workplace. Yet, overall there
been that the decentralization of important has been little enquiry into the impact of
aspects of working time negotiation has works councils on the distribution of influence
significantly enhanced the potential role of between management and workforce. The
works councils in determining this aspect third problem, and related to the previous
of work, buttressing the councils’ role in a point, is that there has been an overall lack of
period when other temporal developments study of how the presence of a works council
(such as individual time accounts) have affects individual worker perceptions of their
the potential to erode collective relations working environment (though exceptions
between management and worker represen- include Bartölke et al., 1982; and Wever,
tatives. Further, the importance to employers 1994).
of securing greater temporal flexibility has, In terms of the main focus of evaluation in
in some cases at least, given works councils recent years – the impact of works councils
a wider ability to exercise influence in other on firm performance – the findings offer a
areas of work organization and arrangement. mixed picture, but overall suggest that the
The overall effect, according to Haipeter impact has been a fairly modest one. In a
and Lehndorff, (2005: 141) has been that, series of studies drawing on large-scale survey
‘Collective agreements on working time data, Addison and colleagues (Addison, 2005;
gradually gave the actors in the workplace Addison and Teixeira, 2006; Addison et al.,
increased scope for bargaining and thereby 2004a, 2004b, 2004c, 2007) have found
helped to make the firm or establishment an works council presence to be associated with,
important locus within the German industrial among other things: lower quit rates and
relations system’ (see also French, 2001: dismissals, reduced employment growth, and
563). The overall picture therefore is that a higher level of plant closures, but with no
while there have been some pressures to identifiable effect on investment patterns. In
de-collectivize aspects of the employment terms of the impact on productivity, Addison’s
relationship within many workplaces, other analyses detect a small positive effect of
WORKS COUNCILS 351

works council presence on productivity (see transfer of undertakings, overall workers’


also Hübler and Jirjahn, 2003). As Addison representatives did not gain rights ‘to alter
et al. (2004a) point out, however, different substantially the position taken by manage-
periods of investigation and different types of ments’ (Waddington, 2006: 682).
study have tended to produce different results The European Works Council Directive
regarding productivity and works councils. in 1994 sought to increase the pressure on
Given the nature of most of this enquiry, employers, and in particular transnational
based on cross-sectional surveys – further employers, to consult with employee rep-
investigation is needed to establish under resentatives over a range of cross-national
what circumstances and in what ways works issues including restructuring and employ-
councils can impact on firm outcomes, either ment developments. The Directive requires
positively or negatively. Further, given the that undertakings employing more than 1,000
changing role of works councils (for example, people in member states, of which 150 must
in relation to working time issues; see above) be employed in each of two member states,
there would be value in further study that should establish a European-wide Works
focuses on the functioning of works councils Council (EWC Directive, 1994, Article 2).
in particular contexts – examining more Though information and consultation were
extensively, for example the circumstances at the heart of the Directive, the notion of
where works councils have successfully exactly what the terms meant was left ‘loosely
exerted influence over emerging agenda, and defined’ (Lorber, 2004: 191).
those where they have been less successful Assessments of the operation of EWCs
(Croucher and Singe, 2004). broadly concur on several general features
In addition to the continuing significance evident during the first decade of the
of the works council system in Germany Directive’s existence. First, compliance with
and several neighboring countries including the national legislation passed to implement
Austria and the Netherlands, in latter years the Directive has been patchy. Overall,
the German works council model has acted approximately one-third of companies cov-
as ‘the prototype of works councils in ered by the Directive have established EWCs
Europe’ (Frege, 2002: 222) and a key vehicle (Kerckhofs, 2002; Marginson et al., 2004).
for developing a European social model Compliance is higher among larger compa-
that acknowledges the need for independent nies and in certain sectors such as financial
worker representation (Hyman, 2001: 118–9; services and hotels and catering (Addison
Gumbrell-McCormick and Hyman, 2006: and Belfield, 2002). Second, it is clear that
474) A brief overview of these Europe-wide EWCs vary considerably in how they operate
developments will provide a broader platform in practice. Waddington (2006: 683), for
for assessing some of the issues facing works example, refers to a continuum ranging from
councils in the coming period. highly restricted consultation and information
practices, to much more extensive involve-
ment of worker representatives in company
EUROPEAN WORKS COUNCILS decision-making. Similarly, Marginson et al.’s
(2004: 223) results underline the variation
In Europe, attempts to introduce measures in activity across the cases they studied, as
to support employee rights to information do Weiler (2004) and Voss (2006). Factors
and consultation were first made in the early associated with different levels of information
1970s, though concerted employer opposi- and consultation activity include the strength
tion prevented significant progress (Burchill, of employee-side organization; country-of-
1997: 196). Hence, in the following two origin effects (particularly the influence of
decades, whilst European regulations did companies from countries with a tradition of
place consultation requirements on compa- worker involvement and cooperative indus-
nies contemplating redundancies and the trial relations) and a company industrial
352 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

relations effect (for example the positive the workforces in different locations (Voss,
effect of companies having a longer tradition 2006: 43).
of works councils and where the EWC is more The tendency for management to min-
integrated with extant IR structures) (Weiler, imize the role of the EWC and consult
2004: 96–97; see also Gilman and Marginson, after rather than before decisions are taken,
2002). underlines the widespread absence of a
Third, notwithstanding the diversity of clear managerial commitment to effective
operation noted above, the vast majority consultation (a lack of commitment that also
of studies point to the very limited impact finds expression in the small number of
of EWCs on company decision-making. The managerial representatives that are present
patchiness of compliance (see above) is on many EWCs). As Weiler (2004) points
relevant here, but even where compliance out, however, this lack of commitment is
has been secured, it is clear that this has not only identifiable within management. It
frequently been at a minimal level. In her is evident too that employee representatives
overview of more than forty case studies frequently demonstrate a limited willingness
drawn from five countries for example, to develop joint European positions on issues,
Weiler (2004) highlights widespread limita- with the prioritizing by representatives of their
tions reflected in, among other things, the own locality tending to be more prominent
(in)frequency of meetings, the inadequacy of than any development of a common sense of
much of the training provision for worker purpose (ibid: 62,97; for a notable exception,
representatives and language barriers imped- see Whittal, 2000).
ing communication, particularly outside the Overall, the weakness of regulation govern-
formal council meetings. More significant ing the nature, scope and function of EWCs,
still, however, is the apparent widespread coupled with the ambivalent view of the
use of EWCs by management to inform parties to the arrangements established, has
worker representatives of decisions already resulted in EWCs generally operating in a way
taken, and to gain legitimacy for those that varies considerably from the prototypical
decisions. Where consultation does take German works councils discussed earlier.
place, it is more likely to be over the processes Among other things, the restricted nature of
of implementation of decisions rather than much EWC activity highlights the difficulties
consulting over decisions yet to be made that the EU faces in seeking to advance con-
(Marginson et al., 2004; Waddington, 2006). sultative employment mechanisms that apply
As Weiler (2004: 81) concludes, ‘All the across member states, whose national systems
case studies [that formed the basis for her of provision for employee consultation vary
report] reveal that the EWCs had little or no considerably.
influence on general management practices
and on transnational decisions’. A subsequent
analysis of companies in new EU member RECENT NATIONAL-LEVEL
states by Voss (2006) largely mirrors this DEVELOPMENTS
finding of the overall paucity of the consul-
tative process, and the quality and timing To complement the EWC Directive’s require-
of information made available to employee ments in respect of transnational corporations,
representatives. Further, as Voss points out, the possibility of an EU framework to support
in countries such as the Czech Republic, provisions for information and consultation
Hungary, Poland and Slovakia, this generally within nationally-based undertakings, was
minimalist strategy toward information and first raised by the European Commission in
consultation is given added significance by the 1995. After much negotiation and opposition
scale of company relocation and restructuring on various grounds from several member
occurring between older and newer EU states, the EU Information and Consultation
members, and the resulting implications for Directive (ICD) was eventually adopted
WORKS COUNCILS 353

in 2002. The aim of this Directive is to worker representatives (Hall, 2005, 2006;
require employers to: inform employees on Truter, 2003).
the recent and probable development of This last point is an issue for commentators
the establishment’s activities and economic concerned about the independent representa-
situation; inform and consult with employees tion of workers’ interests in an era of relative
on the situation and probable development of union weakness. In this context, the question
employment in the establishment; and inform is whether works councils offer a new oppor-
and consult with employees on decisions tunity for a stronger labor voice to develop, or
likely to lead to substantial changes in work whether they provide employers with greater
organization or in contractual relations (from scope to marginalize and undermine unions
Article 4 of the Information and Consultation and incorporate worker representatives. For
Directive). Kelly (1996: 54–7) the dangers for labor (and
The EC allowed member states discretion a factor in the evident union ambivalence
and flexibility in the introduction of the toward works councils in many contexts) lie in
regulations in the interests of not chal- the ideological and power issues underpinning
lenging or supplanting existing mechanisms the operation of works councils, namely:
for consultation or bargaining (Hall, 2005: their lack of independence in comparison
107–8). The resulting variation, however, in with unionized representation; their relative
how member states are able to implement unassertiveness; their foundation in employee
the Directive, coupled with the lengthy obligations to engage with employers in
period allowed for compliance (up to 2008 a spirit of peace, trust and co-operation;
for smaller establishments; see Blyton and and finally, their potential for encouraging
Turnbull, 2004: 266–7) makes any general- employees to identify their interests ‘ever
ized analysis of the impact of the Directive to more closely with employers’ and to therefore
date difficult. The ICD’s potential significance be attractive to employers as a ‘roadblock
is greater in those countries such as the to union growth’ (ibid: 57). There is also
UK and Ireland, where statutory requirement the associated issue, in the context of the
for informing or consulting with employees decentralization of collective bargaining, for
was largely absent (other than over certain works councils to reinforce the tendency
specific issues such as redundancy) (Dundon towards ‘company egoism’ (see French 2001:
et al., 2006; Sisson, 2002). But, just as the 563–4; Gumbrell-McCormick and Hyman,
assessments of the development of European 2006: 478–9; see also, Heery, 2002: 22), and to
Works Councils have generally pointed to undermine wider solidarity between workers
only very restricted development of effective by focusing on the interests of established
consultation, there is considerable potential ‘core’ employees at a particular workplace.
for a similarly minimalist development of While acknowledging such dangers, however,
national works council systems under the Hyman (1996: 80–2), argues that assertive
ICD, particularly in those countries lack- works councils could still offer an effective
ing any existing regulatory foundation for channel for employee voice in the context
consultation. Indeed, in the UK, the initial of union weakness, and could be one aspect
signs are not particularly encouraging in of a set of ‘positive rights’ for employee
terms of building a more comprehensive representation that might provide a ‘spring-
consultation architecture. The UK govern- board for unionization’. Hyman makes the
ment has not provided a strong lead in the point that where unions have little opportunity
development of a consultation culture: not to make advances in securing full collective
only did it support a diluted rather than bargaining rights, an institutional framework
a more extended version of the ICD, but for works council might facilitate power as
has subsequently established considerable well as voice and represent ‘the least worst
scope for employers to rely on forms of option for British unions’ (ibid: 65). To a
workforce consultation other than through very large extent, no conclusion can yet be
354 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

drawn on these matters, and the detail of the by statute. In the German case (and other
operation of works councils established under similar European cases) what this has meant
the terms of the ICD, will require ongoing is that whilst the industrial relations system
evaluation. has experienced similar pressures to those
Thus, it would seem that in those European exhibited elsewhere – in particular, pressures
countries where legislation over consultation to decentralize and de-collectivize different
requirements has in the past been weak, or parts of the employment relationship – the
absent altogether, the recent regulation deriv- works council system has been sufficiently
ing from the ICD represents the beginning of robust largely to withstand those pressures.
a journey of consultation, rather than its end. Indeed, in more organized works council
In countries like Germany, the works council contexts at least, the pressures to decentralize
system has been effective precisely because it the determination of industrial relations issues
is embedded in a broader statutory framework has stimulated a new and broader role
of participation and collective representation. for works councils within the local IR
Also important has been the willingness structure. Given the statutory requirement to
of many employers actively to engage in involve works councils in decision-making,
workplace-based participation; and that works many companies in Germany have shown
councils have been given sufficient statutory a preference for channeling more industrial
rights to maintain an independence from relations activity through the integrative
management (Truter, 2003; Wever, 1995). bargaining system represented by the works
Elsewhere, these conditions are met to a councils, rather than via more centralized
greater or lesser extent. In this regard, the UK bargaining involving negotiations with trade
is an extreme case for none of these conditions unions.
currently prevail in the UK, and the ICD does Elsewhere, however, and particularly in
not in itself provide any of them. Whether or those contexts such as Australia, the US and
not the consultation arrangements that stem the UK, where adversarial relations have been
from the ICD will initiate a significant degree more evident in past industrial relations, the
of change, either in the UK or more widely, likelihood of any thoroughgoing develop-
remains to be seen. ment of representative employee participation
looks a distant prospect (notwithstanding that
in the UK, for example, employers have
CONCLUSION a statutory duty to consult over specific
issues such as large-scale redundancies). The
Workplace committees, involving either ICD has been significant for the UK (and
elected or nominated worker representatives, Ireland) in introducing a statutory platform
are a widespread form of management- for employees to insist on being informed
workforce interaction. In those countries and consulted by management over a much
that have witnessed a decline in collective broader range of issues than currently prevails
bargaining coverage in the recent period, (Hall, 2005: 103). However, the compara-
such committees could well become yet tively restricted nature of the directive, and the
more evident, together with other, direct scope it allows management to minimize the
forms of employee involvement (Lansbury extent to which they are required to embrace
and Wailes, in this volume; Pyman et al., 2006; a more consultative approach to decision-
Taras and Kaufman, 2006). Many of these making, is likely to mean that its effects
workplace committees carry the title of works will remain modest. In practice, this limited
councils, or a similar term such as company impact is likely to be the case not only
council. Yet, in many cases, they remain a in countries where no previous legislation
far cry from those works council structures exists, but also in many cases where a more
that exist in contexts where the presence regulatory framework has been in place,
and powers of works councils are regulated for in the main in these latter countries
WORKS COUNCILS 355

this extant regulation is likely to be more REFERENCES


comprehensive than that represented by the
ICD. A similar picture also appears to be the Addison, J.T. (2005) ‘The determinants of firm
case in relation to European Works Councils. performance: unions, works councils and employee
As we have discussed, though companies involvement/high-performance work practices’,
vary considerably in the extent to which they Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52 (3):
406–50.
actively utilize the EWC structure to inform
Addison, J.T. and Belfield, C.R. (2002) ‘What do we
and consult with worker representatives, in the
know about the new European Works Councils? Some
main EWCs have not so far fundamentally preliminary evidence from Britain’, Scottish Journal of
altered the pattern of corporate decision- Political Economy, 49 (4): 418–44.
making, nor led to significant consultation Addison, J.T., and Teixeira, P. (2006) ‘The effect of works
with worker representatives before important councils on employment change’, Industrial Relations,
decisions have been taken. 45 (1): 1–25.
Overall, in the absence of a regulatory Addison, J.T., Schnabel, C. and Wagner, J. (2004a) ‘The
requirement to engage in consultative behav- course of research into the economic consequences of
ior, managers have tended to express their German works councils’, British Journal of Industrial
interest in only very limited participatory Relations, 43 (2): 255–81.
devices. Such an attitude towards limiting Addison, J.T., Bellmann, L., Schnabel, C. and Wagner, J.
(2004b) ‘The reform of the German Works Constitu-
the sharing of influence over decisions has
tion Act: a critical assessment’, Industrial Relations,
been evident for example in various studies
43 (2): 392–420.
of management attitudes (see for example, Addison, J.T., Bellmann, L. and Kolling, A. (2004c)
Freeman and Rogers, 1999; and Poole and ‘Works councils and plant closings in Germany’,
Mansfield, 1992). In Europe, it remains to British Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (1): 125–48.
be seen whether there is the political will to Addison, J.T., Schank, T., Schnabel, C. and Wagner, J.
increase the degree of industrial democracy in (2007) ‘Do works councils inhibit investment?’,
organizations through extending the powers Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 60 (2):
initially set down in directives relating to 187–203.
transnational and national works councils. Bartölke, K., Eschweiler, D., Flechsenberger, D. and
Given the prominence of the political rhetoric Tannenbaum, A.S. (1982) ‘Workers’ participation and
on the importance of management having the distribution of control as perceived by members
of ten German companies’, Administrative Science
the ‘flexibility’ to compete internationally,
Quarterly, 27 (3): 380–97.
however, for the foreseeable future it may
Blyton, P. and Turnbull, P. (2004) The Dynamics
well be the case that we have already wit- of Employee Relations, Third Edition, Basingstoke:
nessed the high-water point of works council Palgrave Macmillan.
development in terms of the influence they Burchill, F. (1997) Labour Relations, Basingstoke:
are able to wield. If so, future developments Macmillan.
are more likely to be based on the expansion Clegg, H. (1976) Trade Unionism Under Collective
of forms of works council in which there Bargaining: A Theory Based on Comparisons of Six
is more emphasis on discussing how best Countries, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
to implement decisions already taken, and Croucher, R. and Singe, I. (2004) ‘Co-determination
less opportunity for challenging management and working time accounts in the German finance
action or for shaping decisions before they industry’, Industrial Relations Journal, 35 (2):
have been taken in another place. 153–68.
Dundon, T., Curran, D., Ryan, P. and Maloney, M.
(2006) ‘Conceptualising the dynamics of employee
information and consultation: evidence from the
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Republic of Ireland’, Industrial Relations Journal,
37 (5): 492–512.
The authors would like to thank Nicolas Ferner, A. and Edwards, P. (1995) ‘Power and the diffu-
Bacon and Ed Heery for their useful com- sion of organizational change within multinationals’,
ments on an earlier version of this chapter. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 1 (2): 1–35.
356 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Freeman R.B. (2005) ‘What do unions do? – the Hyman, R. (eds) Changing Industrial Relations in
2004 M-Brane Stringtwister edition’, Journal of Labor Europe, Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 190–238.
Research, 26 (4): 641–68. Jirjahn, U. and Smith, S.C. (2006) ‘What factors
Freeman, R.B. and Rogers, J. (1999) What Workers lead management to support or oppose employee
Want, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. participation – with and without works councils?
Frege, C.M. (1999) ‘Transferring labor institutions to Hypotheses and evidence from Germany’, Industrial
emerging economies: the case of East Germany’, Relations, 45 (4): 650–80.
Industrial Relations, 38 (4): 459–81. Keller, B. (2004) ‘Employment relations in Germany’,
Frege, C. M. (2002) ‘A critical assessment of the in G.J. Bamber, R.D. Lansbury and N. Wailes
theoretical and empirical research on German works (eds) International and Comparative Employment
councils’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Relations, 4th edn, London: Sage, pp. 211–53.
40 (2): 221–48. Kelly, J. (1996) ‘Works councils: union advance or
French, S. (2001) ‘Works councils in unified Germany: marginalization?’ in McColgan, A. (ed.) The Future
still loyal to the trade unions?’, International Journal of Labour Law, London: Cassell, pp. 46–63.
of Manpower, 22 (6): 560–78. Kerckhofs, P. (2002) European Works Councils –
Gilman, M. and Marginson, P. (2002) ‘Negotiating Facts and Figures, Brussels: European Trade Union
European Works Councils: contours of constrained Institute.
choice’, Industrial Relations Journal, 33 (1): 36–51. Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H.,
Gumbrell-McCormick, R. and Hyman, R. (2006) Dix, G. and Oxenbridge, S. (2005) Inside the
‘Embedded collectivism? workplace representation in Workplace: First Findings from the 2004 Employment
France and Germany’, Industrial Relations Journal, Relations Survey, London: DTI.
37 (5): 473–91. Kim, D-O. and Kim, H-K. (2004), ‘A comparison of the
Haipeter, T. and Lehndorff, S. (2005) ‘Decentrailsed effectiveness of unions and non-union works councils
bargaining of working time in the German automotive in Korea: can non-union employee representation
industry’, Industrial Relations Journal, 36 (2): substitute for trade unionism?’, International Journal
140–56. of Human Resource Management, 15 (6): 1069–93.
Hall, M. (2005) ‘Assessing the Information and Kotthoff, H. (1994) Betriebsratte und Burgerstatus:
Consultation of Employee Regulations’, Industrial Wandel und Kontinuitat betrieblicher
Law Journal, 34 (2): 103–26. Co-determination, Munich: Rainer Hampp Verlag.
Hall, M. (2006) ‘A cool response to the ICE Regulations? Lorber, P. (2004) ‘Reviewing the European Works
Employer and trade union approaches to the new Council Directive: European progress and United
legal framework for information and consultation’, Kingdom perspective’, Industrial Law Journal 30 (2):
Industrial Relations Journal, 37 (5): 456–72. 191–9.
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2003) ‘Varieties of capitalism Marginson, P. and Sisson, K. (2006) European
and institutional change: a response to three critics’, Integration and Industrial Relations, Basingstoke:
Comparative European Politics, XX (1): 241–50. Palgrave Macmillan.
Hassel, A. (1999) ‘The erosion of the German system Marginson, P., Hall, M., Hoffman, A. and Müller T.
of industrial relations’, British Journal of Industrial (2004) ‘The impact of European Works Councils on
Relations, 37 (3): 483–505. management decision-making in UK and US-based
Heery, E. (2002) ‘Partnership versus organising: alter- multinationals: a case study comparison’. British
native futures for British trade unionism’, Industrial Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (2): 209–33.
Relations Journal, 33 (1): 20–35. Poole, M. and Mansfield, R. (1992) ‘Managers’ attitudes
Hubler, O. and Jirjahn, U. (2003) ‘Works councils and to human resource management: rhetoric and reality’,
collective bargaining in Germany: the impact on in P. Blyton and P. Turnbull (eds) Reassessing
productivity and wages’, Scottish Journal of Political Human Resource Management, London: Sage.
Economy, 50 (4): 471–91. pp. 200–14.
Hyman, R. (1996) ‘Is there a case for statutory works Pyman, A., Cooper, B., Teicher, J. and Holland, P. (2006)
councils in Britain’, in McColgan, A. (ed.) The Future ‘A comparison of the effectiveness of employee
of Labour Law, London: Cassell, pp. 64–84. voice arrangements in Australia’, Industrial Relations
Hyman, R. (2001) Understanding European Trade Journal, 37 (5): 543–59.
Unionism – Between Market, Class and Society, Rogers, J. and Streeck, W. (1995) ‘The study of works
London: Sage. councils: concepts and problems’, in J. Rogers and
Jacobi, O., Keller, B. and Muller-Jentsch, W. (1998) W. Streeck (eds) Works Councils, Chicago: University
‘Germany: facing new challenges’, in Ferner, A. and of Chicago Press. pp. 3–26.
WORKS COUNCILS 357

Royle, T. (1998) ‘Avoidance strategies and the German Waddington, J. (2006) ‘The performance of European
system of co-determination’, The International Works Councils in engineering: perspectives of
Journal of Human Resource Management, 9 (6): the employee representatives’, Industrial Relations,
1026–47. 45 (4): 681–708.
Sisson, K. (2002) ‘The Information and Consultation Weiler, A. (2004) European Works Councils in Practice,
Directive: Unnecessary “Regulation” or an Oppor- Dublin: European Foundation for the Improvement of
tunity to Promote ‘Partnership’?’, Warwick Papers Living and Working Conditions.
in Industrial Relations No. 67, Industrial Relations Weiss, M. (2006) ‘The effectiveness of labour law:
Research Unit, Warwick University. reflections based on the German experience’,
Taras, D.G. and Kaufman, B. (2006) ‘Non-union Managerial Law, 48 (3): 275–87.
employee representation in North America: diversity, Wever, K. S. (1994) ‘Learning from works councils:
controversy and uncertain future’, Industrial Relations five unspectacular cases from Germany’, Industrial
Journal, 37 (5): 513–42. Relations, 33 (4): 467–81.
Traxler, F. (1998) ‘Austria: still the country of Wever, K.S. (1995) Negotiating Competitiveness:
corporatism’, in Ferner, A. and Hyman, R. (eds) Employment Relations and Organizational Innovation
Changing Industrial Relations in Europe, Oxford: in Germany and the United States, Boston, MA:
Blackwell, pp. 239–61. Harvard Business School Press.
Truter, G.M. (2003) Implementing the Information Whittal, M. (2000) ‘The BMW European Works Council:
and Consultation Directive in the UK: Lessons a cause for European industrial relations optimism?’,
from Germany, London: Institute for Employment European Journal of Industrial Relations, 6 (1):
Rights. 61–84.
Voss, E. (2006) The experience of European Works Wood, G. and Mahabir, P. (2001) ‘South Africa’s
Councils in new EU Member States, Dublin: European workplace forum system: a stillborn experiment in
Foundation for the Improvement of Living and the democratisation of work?’, Industrial Relations
Working Conditions. Journal, 32 (3): 230–43.
19
The Evolution of Stakeholder
Regimes: Beyond
Neo-Corporatism
Charles Heckscher

A central phenomenon of industrial relations Research and theory have not yet caught
(IR) since the 1960s has been the pluralization up with this sea change. The arena of new
of the field – in practice, if not in theory. associational actors has been very poorly
Where the Dunlopian paradigm envisioned a mapped: there is as yet little agreement even
tripartite model, with unions and government on the major categories, and still less on the
as the sole representatives of non-market numbers of people involved or the importance
values, recent decades have seen a rapid of these groups (Carré and Joshi, 2000).
expansion of the cast. Many of the emergent Although it is clear that the tripartite ‘neo-
actors are ‘new movements’, formed around corporatist’ model is now a poor description
social identities such as race, gender, dis- of reality, no replacement has emerged.
ability, and other markers of status; though I will make the case that to understand
not centered on the workplace, these groups the current scene we need to abstract from
have had enormous impacts on employment the system described by classic IR theory,
through civil rights legislation and publicity building a new theory that treats that approach
campaigns. Others are more clearly ‘labor’ as just one way of organizing the demands of
groups, such as immigrant worker centers that multiple stakeholders.
have emerged, largely independent of unions,
to meet the needs of temporary laborers
(Fine, 2006). As the power of NLRA-framed STAKEHOLDER REGIMES
unionism has declined, these diverse and
mostly fragmented actors have tried to fill in At times transition theory should help us pull
the growing gaps in the system of employment back from the familiar ways of framing events
representation. to construct new ones. The traditional frame
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 359

now keeps us within a narrow space: it sug- Second, what decision-making process
gests that since unions and the welfare state are should be used? The notion of majority vote
in decline they should be strengthened again – is not useful for a stakeholder analysis: the
so that things in the future might look more players are not equal individuals, but groups
like they did in the 1950s. Yet the tripartite of varying degrees of stability and size. In
neo-corporatist model is merely one historical general a notion of negotiation seems more
way of solving a more permanent problem: on the mark than voting, but that leaves
how to give voice to conflicting interests a huge range of problems: how to manage
and values in the economy (Schmitter, 1983; the differences in power and identity among
Williamson, 1985). the players, how to manage multilateral
Neo-corporatism (as I will use the term) negotiations, how to deal with impasses, and
has been a successful stakeholder regime so on.
that balanced multiple positions.1 It is These problems are the focus of institution-
characterized by organized relations among alization of stakeholder systems. While it is
three principal actors: large corporations, a possible to create stakeholder dialogs ‘on the
state supporting some form of social-welfare fly’, with no prior agreement on the nature of
model, and unions oriented to collective the process, this is not a reliable way to assure
bargaining. Other actors are represented only that consensus is reached and people accept
through one of these ‘primary’institutions and the legitimacy of the outcomes. In order to
had to accept the results of negotiations among achieve these two purposes there needs to be
them. In the era before the dominance of large an accepted way of dealing with the issues just
corporations, there was a different stakeholder raised, with the backing of relevant authorities
regime with different actors – principally craft including courts and government regulators.
unions and guilds-based structures rather than A regime (again, in my usage) is a set of
industrial unions. societal institutions that involves stakeholders
The concept of ‘stakeholders’ is relatively in decision-making, leading to legitimate
undeveloped. Most treatments are still based and enforceable outcomes.2 The concept
on Freeman’s (1984: 46) strikingly vague covers a wide range of institutional forms,
definition of a stakeholder as ‘any group or including collective bargaining but also, for
individual who can affect, or is affected by, example, regulatory negotiation or certain
the achievement of a corporation’s purpose’. regional development mechanisms. It is not
Two central problems are generally blurred even specific to a capitalist society: in
or left unresolved. First, how can one identify principle any complex system with multiple
a stakeholder? It is not too hard to identify overlapping groups must consider how to
individuals, but groups with shared values define and involve stakeholders. Indeed,
are much harder to pin down. In practice from this perspective, capitalism is defined
they ebb and flow, forming and dissolving, simply as a regime in which owners are
splitting and merging, depending on the a dominant stakeholder group with strongly
particular constellation of problems. Some institutionalized legal rights.
are more self-aware than others, some are The stakeholder literature has so far
more visibly powerful than others; yet those largely ignored the analysis of institution-
are not sufficient criteria in themselves, since alized decision-making regimes. The term
it is often those who are not highly self- ‘stakeholder’ has been used to help managers
aware or influential who have the strongest and policy-makers think about particular
claims to justice. Freeman’s definition does conflicts, but it has rarely been extended to
nothing to tackle this problem; indeed, it the consideration of how these relations can
leaves us with essentially infinite numbers be formed into systems that are stable and
of stakeholders, with no way to sort out reflective of the full range of societal concerns
who should or should not be part of the and values. The field of IR, meanwhile, has
process. remained fixated on a particular regime dating
360 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

from the interwar period, and has not adopted my knowledge, in all industrialized countries.
the larger frame offered by the stakeholder There are important varieties within this
perspective. framework: negotiation processes may range
My core argument is that we are currently in character from cooperative to highly con-
experiencing a transition between stakeholder flictual, and government can base regulations
regimes in employment relations, from the on dialog or on bureaucratic expertise. But
neo-corporatist system which dominated the all industrial democracies, from Sweden to
industrial era to an as-yet uninstitutionalized the US, share the essential characteristics just
and unnamed system for the future. This sketched.
argument involves first the description of Although today many think of the US as
the prior regime, which is now coming purely econometric or managerial rather than
apart but whose outlines are relatively clear; neo-corporatist, that view is something of
from there, an abstraction of the general a retroactive reading of history. During the
characteristics of stakeholder regimes; and on 1950s and 1960s unions reached densities of
that basis, an attempt to model some core over 35 per cent, which would be considered
characteristics of a regime responsive to the quite respectable today and certainly large
current configuration of needs. enough to set the basic standards for the
economy. Large employers almost never tried
to push their ability to operate during strikes
THE NEO-CORPORATIST or fire people during organizing drives; they
STAKEHOLDER REGIME AND widely accepted that the compromise was
ITS DECLINE working and did not seek to rock the boat.
And, as Jacob Hacker has calculated, the
We can learn a good deal about the current amount spent on welfare in the US in the post-
situation by looking at the construction of WWII period has been very similar to that
the prior regime. Neo-corporatism, treated as of European nations like the Netherlands and
an ideal-type, is characterized by particular Denmark; only the method of provision was
answers to the problems described above. different, with a higher proportion provided
through union-management negotiations and
• There are three institutionalized actors: employers,
a smaller proportion through direct state
labor unions, and government. programs and regulations (Hacker, 2002).
• Decision-making processes are a mixture of What was most distinctive to the US was
two basic kinds: periodic bilateral negotiation a relatively decentralized image of the good
between employers and unions, and regulation by society: the labor federation had relatively
government. little power over its members, and employers
• The process seeks a balance of values between never formed the kind of strong associations
economic productivity and values of concern to the that were found in Scandinavia and elsewhere.
other stakeholders. That is, economic value is one Sweden and Germany adopted a much more
key concern, but not the only one which measures centralized version of the neo-corporatist
the success of the outcomes. Non-economic values
compromise. In general these highly cen-
are legitimate in the process.
• The collective bargaining piece of the regime
tralized institutionalizations strove for direct
deals with issues of workplace governance; dialog and consensus and had relatively low
it has generally been restricted to issues of rates of conflict. In the less centralized forms –
wages and working conditions. The government France or Italy, for example – it was more dif-
regulation piece deals with the concerns of other ficult to maintain consensus, and agreements
stakeholders and is far more open, with few could more easily be destabilized by shifting
predefined limits on the issues. power alignments; thus there was more of
a tendency for periodic large-scale clashes
This pattern describes the institutional rela- to erupt. In the most decentralized systems,
tions throughout the OECD nations and, to such as the US or UK, conflict was nearly
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 361

continuous and generally much more local, circumstances not because they have felt it
though in these countries occasional large- to be fundamentally the best way to organize
scale clashes served to define the parameters society.
within which everyone worked as well. It The last few decades have seen such a
should be emphasized, however, that even shift in conditions. The economic scene has
in these least stabilized institutions, conflict increasingly moved away from mass produc-
became highly ritualized and manageable – tion as the central motor of value; ‘commodity
moving from the fierce and unconstrained production’ is viewed in many industries as
battles of the 1930s to the periodic games of unprofitable and something to be avoided.
threats, counter-threats, brinksmanship, and In its place has arisen a growing sector
eventual agreement. of the economy for which profit is driven
The neo-corporatist regime in all its primarily by innovation and responsiveness.
variants met the needs of the major active In this sector the neo-corporatist compromise,
stakeholders well enough to last for many with its emphasis on stability and contractual
years. In particular, the most organized and rules, is a poor fit – to the degree that
entitled stakeholder, corporate management, managers have felt it was more in their
found that this system helped to guarantee interests to break with the deal than to go
the stability and quality of the workforce and along with it. They have had a relatively
increase the reliability of the hierarchy – partly easy time doing so in the US because the
by forcing managers to be consistent and legal framework supporting neo-corporatism
fair in dealing with employees. Many studies is comparatively weak; employers who resist
have shown that under conditions of mass unionization or fire organizers suffer few legal
production and bureaucratic management, penalties, so that when the economic incentive
economic performance is improved by union- is lost there is nothing left. In other countries
ization (Freeman and Medoff 1984; Slichter where the legal and institutional props of
and Livernash, 1960). Though managers, neo-corporatism are stronger, employers have
like all those with power, never like having been slower to show open hostility to unions;
their authority challenged, they could ‘live but the pendulum is swinging in this direction
with’ neo-corporatist institutions under those in virtually all industrial nations.
conditions. Meanwhile, the most organized
social force, that of workers in large industrial
workplaces, got improved wages and working A GENERAL MODEL OF CHANGE
conditions; and the society at large got a broad IN STAKEHOLDER REGIMES
increase in purchasing power that helped drive
economic expansion and the growth of a There is in these events a suggestive pattern.
strong middle class (or skilled working class) In the nineteenth century economy many
during the postwar period. stakeholders made claims, such as anarchist
Such a win-win compromise is not eternal, and communal models, but one regime
however, any stakeholder regime is essen- became dominant: that of regularized nego-
tially a concrete balance of forces rather than tiations between craft unions and employers.
a tightly integrated system based on shared In the first decades of the twentieth century
values. When conditions shift sufficiently that this relatively stable relation was blown apart
one party or another thinks it can better by a profound economic transformation that
achieve its own interests and values without destroyed the old relationships and bases
these institutions, there are few communal of power. This led to a transitional era of
or moral bonds keeping it from trying to low regulation, in which economic values
get out of the deal. Both worker movements became dominant at the expense of other
and managers have for the most part held important social values; this imbalance led to
to the neo-corporatist frame because they growing inequality, a rise in corruption and
saw it as the best they could do in the public cynicism, and a loss of community.
362 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Finally, out of the turmoil there emerged a new If we accept that preferences and values
stakeholder pattern, with government playing are shaped by groups, then the nature of
a more active role as a regulator and the these groups must be analyzed as a vital
union presence shifting from the craft to the element in explaining social dynamics. The
industrial form. concept of ‘interest groups’ has become
It seems plausible that there is a greater increasingly accepted as essential to political
universality to this pattern which can be put analysis. The authors of the US Constitution
in the form of general propositions. feared that such ‘factions’ would lead to
fragmentation of the body politic; and insofar
• Stakeholder regimes stabilize social orders by as there is no regularized relation among
balancing values of diverse stakeholders, ensuring such interests, they are right. Sometimes
relative predictability and social stability. interest fragmentation has caused major social
• Stakeholder regimes can be disrupted by major disruption. One such period, in the US, was the
economic or social change. late 1920s and early 1930s, when competing
• Such disruption leads to a destabilization of
worker groups began fighting with each other,
communal norms such as public service and equity,
as much as with management, making it
and to a decline in the regulatory institutions that
implement them. The result is an unbalanced focus
impossible to reach any stable agreements.
on economic values driven by corporate interests. The National Labor Relations Act was largely
• These shifts produce social and economic instabil- intended to organize those interests into a
ity and pathology as many stakeholders feel that stable regime that could resolve conflicts and
their concerns are ignored. create consensus.
• There follows an assertion of new stakeholder In the current phase, moreover, the
claims appropriate to the existing situation, importance of group claims is greater than
and the establishment of a new regime to ever for both social stability and economic
institutionalize those claims. productivity.

In advanced capitalist societies, effective


Stakeholder regimes stabilize
stakeholder regimes are increasingly
(modern) social orders
necessary for economic and social stability
Some theories of modern society see no need As capitalism has advanced, group member-
for stakeholders – particularly neoclassical ships have become both more plural and
economic theory and, in the political realm, complex. In agricultural and early modern
varieties of utilitarianism. But it has been a societies people had a single hierarchically-
steady and growing theme of social theory nested set of affiliations, from family through
that such individualist views lack something village to tribe or nation. Capitalism differen-
essential: a moral force that is vital both for the tiated occupation from family, so that wage-
stabilization of personal identity and for the earners were faced with often-conflicting
maintenance of social trust and motivation. loyalties (Parsons, 1971). Thus the first
Emile Durkheim showed a century ago that major stakeholder claim was historically that
social order requires a sense of shared com- of occupations, organized in unions and
munity and solidarity, and that intermediate professional groups. During the nineteenth
groups between the state and individual were century, regulatory systems and negotiating
needed to build and institutionalize these frameworks were created to stabilize the
solidarities. Economists have been reluctant to relation of these groups to firms and the rest
accept the importance of collective behavior, of society.
but in the last decades work on imperfect In the last few decades these claims on
information has increasingly drawn out the individual loyalty have become far more
significance of organizations and group norms differentiated, with gender, race, sexual
in shaping economic behavior (Olson, 1971; preference, political orientation, and other
Philips, 1989; Solow, 1990). dimensions creating a web of identities that
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 363

are not by any means stably ordered. This range of stakeholders is able to do harm
explosion of claims to identity and rights to companies – not just unions, but identity
has disrupted the rather simple stakeholder groups, issue groups, consumer groups, and
framework of collective bargaining: the others. Conversely, an increasing range of
democratic process is increasingly shaped by stakeholders (though not always the same
the growing role of interest groups, identity ones) can help in the co-ordination of
groups, and deliberate associations. Thus the resources: for example, universities, standards
stabilization of the political sphere requires groups, and so on.
ways to build agreements among complex and As this range of stakeholders grows, the
often overlapping stakeholders. possibility of management internalizing them
all grows even more remote. Thus the ability
Stakeholder regimes are necessary to work with stakeholder groups becomes
to economic performance more central to the economic success of
Stakeholder regimes are also essential from firms and to the overall productivity of
the narrower perspective of economic pro- the economy (Ramirez and Wallin, 2000).
duction. Economies are always highly inter- A relatively organized method for negotiation
dependent on other social institutions: They and building agreement among the main
require workers who will commit their labor claimants – that is to say, a stakeholder
and who have sufficient education to perform regime – is essential to the predictability
effectively; they require consumers who and risk-assessment on which successful
believe in the value of what is offered and trust businesses depend.
the offering; they require a general trust in the
soundness of the legal system and regulatory Stakeholder regimes can be
mechanisms; and so on. These conditions for
disrupted by economic or social
economic success involve the realization of
change
values that are not in themselves economic.
One theory is that businesses should Major changes in the structure of the
themselves represent these outside values: economy can disrupt established networks
the Japanese model was once touted as one of stakeholder relations. Indeed, any major
in which businesses have a sense of social shift in stakeholder power or interests can
responsibility which tempers the economic be disruptive to a regime; but in advanced
view (Vogel, 1979). The Japanese experience capitalist systems the most solidly estab-
since then is one of many, however, which lished stakeholder, backed by legal rights
shows that one organization cannot effectively and strong institutions, is always corporate
represent multiple competing values without management. Thus no stakeholder regime can
distortion and loss of credibility (Shikawa, succeed without at least persuading this key
2002). The Wagner Act, and the neo- stakeholder that it is worth participating; and
corporatist order in general, are based on the when management needs shift fundamentally
opposite approach: encouraging a system of this equation is likely to be invalidated.
stakeholder representation and regular forums Management’s core interests as a stake-
for discussion and negotiation among them. holder can be captured largely by an analysis
As markets mature the dependence of firms of strategic imperatives. Until a century ago
on social institutions grows – educational most companies focused on local markets
needs increase, webs of interdependence with and needed to maintain strong communal
outside suppliers and contractors become relationships, which was favorable to a regime
more elaborate; firms need to draw on which involved local players and craft unions.
knowledge developed in universities and But the strategic shift toward scale and scope
other non-economic institutions; customers in a mass-production economy in the early
become more demanding and willing to twentieth century meant that the established
exercise choice. As a result an increasing relations no longer met corporate needs.
364 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

There followed a decades-long process of both societal and business success. In freeing
undermining craft unions and government themselves from the constraints of existing
legitimacy. For a few decades in the US, stakeholder regimes, managers may feel
especially in the 1920s, companies operated liberated for a time; but they will soon
virtually without needing to pay attention to find problems on two fronts: the erosion of
competing stakeholder claims. trust and the quality of social relations on
which businesses depend; and the rise of
Such a disruption leads to a uncoordinated and unpredictable attacks and
destabilization of public norms claims for which no agreed-on method of
negotiation and agreement exist.
and to a decline in the regulatory
institutions that spring from them
As stakeholder institutions are weakened, THE DYNAMICS OF THE CHANGE
values that go beyond the narrowly economic, PROCESS
such as public service and equity, lose power.
What was visible in the 1920s, and again The development of new claims into a new
today, is a lessening of corporate contribution regime is not a smooth and predictable
to public welfare and even of business accep- process. At least three complicated dynamics
tance of fundamental values like integrity have to be worked through. First, old stake-
and honesty. The pressure of competition, holders, those whose positions were institu-
without the counterweight of pressure from tionalized in the old regime, must change their
stakeholders representing other values, begins status – possibly by disappearing entirely, but
to drive behavior in a one-sided direction. possibly by shifting strategies and the nature
of their interaction with other players. Second,
These declines produce instability new stakeholders must develop to a point
and social pathology where they can be reliable representatives
in an institutionalized regime. Finally, a set
Pursuit of one-sided values leads to a general of rules and procedures for negotiation and
loss of trust and public spirit. Growing agreement must be established and accepted
inequality – again a feature of both the by all the players.
1920s and the present period (Plotnick There are significant obstacles to these
et al., 1998) – is disruptive economically changes. The old players are generally far
and socially. Corruption tends to increase, more organized and stable than the new,
leading to a vicious circle of increasing and are also likely to be ‘locked into place’
withdrawal from the public sphere. The loss in the system by a combination of norms,
of confidence in the long-run stability of habits, and formal legal supports. There is
the system leads to increasing degrees of likely to be especially a heavy resistance
short-term speculative risk, producing market to change from the weaker stakeholders –
bubbles. In the 1920s and1930s phase this those who are most heavily ‘propped up’ by
contributed to the economic destabilization societal institutions and who would be most
leading to the Depression. likely to lose position. As a result, existing
regimes are highly sticky and slow to change,
There follows an assertion of new and players may maintain substantial social
stakeholder claims appropriate influence even when their real support from
to the existing situation, and the members and other constituencies erodes.
To take one example, there is a good deal
establishment of a new regime
of evidence that even in Scandinavia the
to institutionalize those claims
foundations of industrial unions have greatly
This follows from the first argument: that weakened – they are having trouble in
effective stakeholder regimes are necessary to recruiting younger workers and in penetrating
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 365

growing economic sectors. Nevertheless, they to take the lead before being formalized
are such powerful players in the political by the second. Craft unionism developed
arena, have such a large pool of resources, and with very little government intervention and
in many cases have such links to critical social was almost entirely a pragmatic series of
welfare programs such as unemployment agreements between particular unions and
insurance, that the weakness at the base companies, evolving slowly into a regime
has not yet shown itself in normal societal of informal norms and ‘ways of doing
negotiations (Boeri et al., 2001; Hyman, business’. Industrial unionism developed for
2001). decades through battles inside and outside
On the other side, ‘new’ stakeholders must the framework of organized labor, until the
go through a difficult process of development. Wagner Act gave it a formal institutional
In their early phases stakeholder groups status.
necessarily lack elaborated and accepted One key problem in institutionalization
internal processes for decision-making; thus is to decide which groups will participate
they typically have significant problems in in stakeholder discussions. In a turbulent
maintaining internal discipline, developing transitional period, where new groups are
coherent strategies, and following through on emerging and shifting all the time, there is
commitments. This makes it difficult for any no formula for doing this. A few companies
group to establish enough credibility either have tried to reach out to stakeholders to
to convince other stakeholders – especially establish some kind of consensus-building
management – that they are worth dealing forum on key issues – examples include
with, or to gain enough political weight to Shell’s environmental forums and efforts
win formal rights. The process of building at Texaco or Coca-Cola to bring together
stable organizations to represent unstable groups around race issues; but such initiatives
social identities and issues can be long and have trouble in reaching binding agreements,
painful. In the case of the US labor movement because anyone can say they disagree with
in the 1920s, as craft unionism declined, many the results and go off and battle with them.
groups contended for the representation of The other approach would be for government
worker interests; John L. Lewis’ charisma and (legislatively or judicially) to determine
his solid, long-established base in the mining which groups have been ‘standing’. This has
industry combined to give him a substantial the advantage of putting the enforcement
advantage over the others and contributed to powers of government behind some particular
the eventual success of industrial unionism. configuration, but it also risks leaving out
The development of new stakeholders has important emergent players; if government
an external as well as an internal dimension steps in too soon it may find its rules miss
(though they are closely linked): their matura- the ‘real’ social forces and create more trouble
tion involves getting more engaged in reliable than they resolve.
links to other players, and participation in
forums for reaching agreement. The ability
Stages of development
to modify positions to win allies, without
creating internal fissures, is vital to long-term of stakeholder regimes
success. The emergence of new stakeholder regimes
Finally, the building of an accepted frame- can be formalized in a sequence of stages,
work of procedures may be equally a matter observable in the history of the development
of lengthy trial-and-error. There are two basic of industrial unionism and in the development
ways this can be done: either through negotia- of various movements for civil rights and
tion among the powerful stakeholder groups, other issues in the last century.
or through the imposition of a government-
defined framework. Given the realities of a • Stakeholders emerge to represent issues that
democratic political system, the first is likely are not adequately dealt with through existing
366 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

decision-making processes. In this first phase THE CURRENT DISCONTINUITY


the stakeholder groups are driven by very
concrete grievances or goals, and they have little The challenge to the neo-corporatist stake-
internal stability; they are typically organized by holder regime since at least the 1970s has
charismatic leaders, which is in effect a very been driven in part by the economic shift away
simple form of organization – but also one that
from mass and toward knowledge production
is very prone to factionalization and splits. In
the absence of institutionalized dialog, violence
(Piore and Sabel, 1984; Best, 1990). Mass
is a frequent element. The black Civil Rights production has increasingly declined as a
movement formed around powerful leaders like source of profit – a victim of something very
Martin Luther King, and has since fragmented; much like Marx’s ‘tendency of the rate of
today even the most developed organizations, like profit to fall’ – with the result that in almost
Jesse Jackson’s Rainbow/PUSH Coalition, are still every industry large companies have fled that
person-dependent and fragile. sector, passing it off to smaller subcontractors
• As stakeholders begin to stabilize – if they in lower-wage areas. But (something Marx
in fact represent social values with lasting did not foresee) knowledge production has
constituencies – they become somewhat more moved to fill the void: profit can still be drawn
predictable. They must generally broaden their from novelty, customization, and the ability
self-definition in order to integrate a reasonable
to address customers’ particular and changing
range of views and limit secessions, and they
problems. This has led to the rise of ‘solutions’
must elaborate their internal processes to gain
reliable support from their members. In the US, strategies, which aim to combine services
the women’s movement, and more recently the and products flexibly around customer needs,
environmental movement, have begun exploring and which draw profits mainly from the
this terrain, trying to frame their issues more knowledge that they provide in helping
inclusively and as contributing to the good customers navigate an increasingly complex
of all. and fast-changing market-place (Foote et al.,
• At this point a series of battles with existing status 2001). Thus IBM, for example, is drawing
groups is likely to lead to some sort of concrete less of its profit from selling equipment, and
modus vivendi, in which the various players have more from selling integrated solutions that
gotten to know and understand each other well may include its own equipment and that of
enough that they can anticipate each other’s others along with consulting and maintenance.
moves and know which is likely to succeed. This
Solutions strategies and focus on
is an unstable situation, though, because in the
absence of binding agreements all parties are still
knowledge-value bring deep changes to
looking for new ways to get an edge. the organization of production. Large-scale
• The next stage is the development of regular bureaucratic integration, which is particularly
discussions seeking binding agreements. The strong on stability and reliability, is less
potential for instability remains in that there is not important than before; more important is
yet a way of preventing other groups from making flexibility, the capacity to combine resources
other claims. Today the closest to this may be in the in changing ways from many sources. Thence
environmental realm, where some groups engage the explosion of innovation around teams,
in regular dialog with companies and regulators task forces, alliances, supplier networks, and
and have developed some consistent influence, supply chain management.
but there are no regularized ways of making and The neo-corporatist stakeholder regime is
enforcing agreements.
a casualty of these fundamental shifts. Both
• A fourth stage, not always reached, involves
industrial unionism and government regula-
engaging social groups and values beyond the
tion are essentially ways of bringing values
immediate stakeholders. Usually this means a
successful political campaign, gaining support of fairness and honesty to a bureaucratic
from the government, as a representative of the structure; they rely heavily on rules and
society as a whole, in establishing a regime that tight definition of responsibility through
establishes standing for particular players and position and office. Industrial unions focus on
enforces agreement between them. drawing sharp job boundaries and establishing
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 367

formal equality between equivalent jobs; than before to support it; second, many other
government, similarly, assumes individual- groups are less willing to fall in behind the
ized liability for responsible positions, and labor movement in pressing their demands,
they also depend on stable industries and preferring instead to break free and seek their
companies. own sources of power.
These forms of regulation are increasingly None of the existing solutions built up
unworkable for many reasons. The high level during the industrial era works very well in
of turbulence due to industrial change means managing this new set of problems. Whether
that government rules and union contracts are it be the strong systems of codetermination
often equally ineffectual as forms of control. in Scandinavia, the decentralized regimes of
Flexible team structures are less amenable the US, the decentralized-conflictual system
to control through job definition. Complex of France, the managerial form in Japan, or the
alliances and networks continually challenge powerful welfare-state institutions of northern
the boundaries of contractual agreements Europe and New Zealand, all are suffering
(Heckscher, 2001). from the same essential problems: loss of
This turbulence has also thrown up a support for unions among the young, failure to
set of new players making value claims penetrate new and growing economic sectors,
on corporations. These fall into two main and a delegitimization of government’s role
categories: issue groups and identity groups. as regulator. The erosion is most visible in
Issue groups are simple to understand: the systems like the US which have relatively
most important currently are probably those weak governmental mechanisms stabilizing
focused on environmental and consumer the industrial system, but the most careful
safety. They increase gradually in significance studies of the European scene have concluded
with social interdependence and political that the same essential forces are acting there
maturity. Identity groups are somewhat more as well and will lead to a continuing decline of
complicated. It is empirically clear that in neo-corporatist institutions (Boeri et al., 2001;
the last 40 years their impact has grown Hyman, 2001.)
exponentially. This is particularly visible in Most analysts – that is, those who accept
the US, where while legal protection for the need for stakeholder involvement – are
collective bargaining has steadily retreated, looking to other forms of neo-corporatism
laws guaranteeing rights to identity groups to solve their problems: America may envy
have equally steadily advanced – starting with the seeming strength of Scandinavia, the
the Civil Rights laws of 1964, to the women’s French admire the effectiveness of pragmatic
rights amendments, to the Americans With American collective bargaining, and so on.
Disabilities Act of 1990. States have passed But it follows from this analysis that no
many further laws protecting sexual orienta- solution from the existing portfolio will work;
tion, religious beliefs, and other identities, and we need to be looking at the conditions for
courts have also extended such protections creation of a new regime.
through judicial rulings. The assertion of
rights by identity groups has by now become
visible in most industrialized nations. It REQUIREMENTS FOR AN EMERGENT
is less clear why this increase has been REGIME
occurring, and how deep its roots run; there is
some disagreement among sociologists about What can we say about the emergent stake-
whether they represent fundamental shifts in holder regime – or, to put it in the terms of
the nature of social movements (Castells, this discussion, about the form of industrial
1997; Touraine, 1985; Zald, 1988). democracy appropriate to this socio-economic
In any case the neo-corporatist regime is moment?
being attacked from two different angles. The critical structural element is that
First, corporate managers see less reason the emergent regime will almost certainly
368 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

involve more players than the current one. is moving from the model of indepen-
The tripartite structure of the past has been dent professional entrepreneurs toward a far
increasingly seen as too limiting by many more bureaucratized structure with a heavy
important social actors who have felt their focus on cost and scale. To the extent
needs were not being adequately represented. that these developments continue in these
More importantly, many of these actors are extremely important sectors, the essential
not centrally identified with the workplace; structure of industrial unionism continues
their claims on corporations come not from to be appropriate. But there is reason to
the perspective of workplace dignity but from doubt that these sectors will continue along
that of broader societal values and identities. the classic industrial line. More complex
Given this focus, it is fundamentally implau- knowledge-based services such as health care
sible that these groups would subordinate are less amenable than manufacturing by
themselves to the labor movement, as they did a scale/mass production approach, because
in the heyday of industrial unionism, using they cannot escape ongoing interaction with
unions as the primary vehicle for expressing end consumers; thus there is already great
their concerns. The values of unions and new resistance to organizing health-care delivery
social movement groups may overlap, and on the basis of detailed rules. Though the
may certainly allow for alliances, but they industrial logic does seem to fit better with
cannot be reduced to a tripartite structure as low-knowledge services such as Wal-Mart or
in the past. McDonald’s, even in those cases there is some
It also seems certain that the emergent tendency to move toward models emphasizing
regime will need to move away from models customer responsiveness and innovation. To
of formalized rule-making, including strong the degree that such solutions approaches
work rules and job protections, toward more develop, unions and government will face
continuous engagement and negotiation. The the same problems of regulation as in other
pace of technological and social change knowledge sectors.
seems unlikely to slow for the foreseeable
future: the effects of the microprocessor
are just beginning to make their way into THE CURRENT IMPASSE
the economy; the biotechnology revolution
coming right behind will be equally powerful; The stakeholders of the neo-corporatist
the huge leap in global interdependence will regime have varying relations to the change
take many decades to sort out. Thus, as many process. Management is, of course, a driver of
have noted, it is increasingly hard for any change because it stands to benefit most from
company in any industry to give long-term it. Unions, however, have almost universally
assurances of stable jobs and careers. A central dug in their heels and proclaimed the need to
feature of the emergent regime must therefore go back to the familiar forms of regulation.
be the ability to continually review and discuss They have remained (with few exceptions)
new challenges. fundamentally ambivalent and ineffective in
There are, to be sure, major parts of dealing with the spread of team-based work
the economy where all this change is less organizations, which necessarily challenge
visible – where the traditional strategic contractual regulations. They have failed
dynamics of cost, scale, and scope are still to appeal to the growing sector of part-
dominant or even becoming more dominant. time and contingent workers. They have not
Retail sales, for example, have historically penetrated branches of the economy based
been structured by relatively small and local on solutions production, such as information
companies; but Wal-Mart has transformed technology and the rapidly-growing field of
this pattern and is shifting the retail sector biotechnology. They have been unable to
to something much more like the industrial build effective alliances with identity and
production model. Similarly, health care issue movements whose center is outside the
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 369

workplace and they have been largely unable aimed at particular groups, often state-by-
to broaden their scope beyond the national state or jurisdiction-by-jurisdiction. Groups
borders that have supported them in the past that have backed and sought to enforce
(Boeri et al., 2001). the laws have been unstable and unreliable.
Government, as the other main player in the Thus managers on the one hand can often
neo-corporatist framework, is in a more con- ‘get away’ with things that much of the
tradictory position. In almost every country society would see as unfair, and on the
of the industrialized world there have been other hand they may ‘get hit with’ lawsuits
moves to weaken government regulation. Yet that seem irrational. This has been going
the size of governments everywhere continues on long enough now that it has reached
to grow with the increased complexity of the second stage of development described
economic and social activity. Government above: some rough rules are beginning to
regulation is widely perceived as necessary emerge, drawn on all sides from pragmatic
but distasteful; there is a casting-about for new assessment of experiences, but since they are
roles and ways of performing the necessary implicit and unenforceable they are frequently
kinds of co-ordination. violated.
Many new stakeholder groups have been Another major unregulated conflict, even
emerging – or more exactly, groups making earlier in development and less structured,
claims to stakeholder status – but very few is the growing resistance to globalization.
of them have moved beyond the stage of Here the groups and coalitions are extremely
factionalism, charismatic leadership, and nar- fluid and organizationally immature, and their
rowness of issues characteristic of immature views vary widely. So far there are far fewer
organizations. Even the most respected issue forums for discussion of these issues and
and identity groups remain fragile and have attempts to reach agreement than there is in
only begun to play more regular roles in soci- the employee-rights area. The combination
etal debates. Overall the constellation looks of anger and lack of reliable expression
somewhat like the American labor movement has led at times to open violence, as in
of the 1920s, which was characterized by the Seattle anti-globalization demonstrations
many scattered organizations with uncertain of 1999 (comparable, in fact, to the early
prospects and extremely different agendas, days of the civil rights movements which
often very narrow and partisan. constituted stage one of the employee-
Thus we have reached a point of seeming rights development). Even more recently,
impasse: existing stakeholder processes are immigration and employment have become in
inadequate to build an agreement in the many countries a third area of growing conflict
current situation, and there are as yet only and instability.
scattered indicators of what new ones might
look like; old institutions still fighting for
position and new ones not yet strong enough WAYS FORWARD
to make their way into the game.
The lack of a legitimate stakeholder regime The way forward, in terms of the analytic
at the moment is apparent in the growth scheme proposed here, involves three main
of relatively uncontrolled conflict – that is, components: changing ‘old’ stakeholders;
conflict that does not move toward a widely developing ‘new’ stakeholders; and formulat-
acceptable balancing of values. In the US, ing processes for discussion and agreement.
this has largely taken the form of employee
rights litigation. Though there is clearly a
Old stakeholders
growing sense that rights of citizenship –
equal treatment, free speech, and so on – The issues are different for the main
should apply to the workplace, this has led not stakeholders in the neo-corporatist regime.
to a unified set of norms but to particular laws Corporate management has made considerable
370 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

strides in defining new kinds of organization further developed it will make it easier to
that can support a solutions strategy: the involve a wide range of stakeholder groups
level of invention around temporary task in a more flexible ways around different types
forces and process management has been of issues.
impressive. But they have not successfully
connected this to policies that will maintain
New stakeholders
employee commitment and ensure efficient
labor markets in the long run. As a result they For new stakeholders the problem has two
are moving toward a highly dualistic career related components: internal organization
system where everyone is fighting over a development and external involvement in
few valued employees and leaving the rest processes of coalition-building and negotia-
to fend for themselves. This will certainly tion. Internally such groups need especially
undermine the ability to develop knowledge to be able to mobilize volunteer effort,
competencies and flexible resource allocation a subject that has generated considerable
over time (Heckscher, 2000). To the extent research recently. There is less analysis, to
that management comes to recognize this my knowledge, of the problems involved in
long-term interest, it will be more willing to moving from the charismatic-founder stage
engage in stakeholder discussion processes, to the ‘routinization of charisma’, or of the
which will make the transition easier. difficulties involved in shifting from purist
Industrial unions are still oriented to focus on member concerns to engagement and
stabilizing large bureaucratic corporations consensus-building with other stakeholder
through job security and clear protective groups. Such literature as there is seems to
rules. To the extent that they can broaden be split between those criticizing associations
this view to encompass a view of career for being too democratic and egalitarian for
development and flexibility, they will find their own good (Merton, 1966) and those
more overlap both with management and with who criticize them for being too bureaucratic
many other identity groups and will be better (Cnaan, 1991), and in general is characterized
able to engage in stakeholder dialogs. This is, by a sense of their fragility (Flament, 1991;
however, an extremely difficult prescription, Gittell, 1980; Scully and Segal, 2002; Smith
since the structure of these unions – as well and Freedman, 1972).
as their histories and identities – are built very
strongly around the preservation of jobs in situ
Processes for discussion and
(Heckscher, 1988: introduction; Heckscher
decision-making
et al., 2003, Chapter 11).
Government in the neo-corporatist era There has been substantial recent experi-
took primarily the roles of rule-maker and mentation and innovation with multiparty
arbitrator, standing ‘above the fray’. Recently consensus-building processes. Over the last
there have been some experiments with decades it has progressed from simple
the relatively new role of convener – that consensus-building within small work teams
is, establishing fora and inviting parties to to processes for large-scale community
work out agreements among themselves. discussions involving at times thousands of
‘Reg-neg’ (regulatory negotiation) efforts people or many groups (Weisbord, 1987;
have attempted to revise the rule-making Dannemiller Tyson Associates, 2000). These
process to engage the parties themselves in techniques have emerged in large part
discussion of the rules. The advantage of this because of the social factors described above:
approach, at least potentially, is that it helps increases in the complexity of social actors, in
to stabilize the process of reaching agree- the need for co-ordinated social co-operation,
ments without rigidifying it through elaborate and in the need for flexibility. Shell is, at
rule-making and enforcement bureaucracies. least among large companies, the one that has
To the extent that the convener role can be done the most to apply them to stakeholder
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 371

management in the sense described here; passing through a period of destabilization,


they have begun to host frequent ‘stakeholder we have an interest in asking how the evident
forums’ with 50 or more organizations, conflicts arising from economic transforma-
including NGOs (non-governmental orga- tion can be institutionalized in a new regime
nizations) and governmental agencies, in of negotiation and consensus.
various countries, to try to build agreement The analysis of stakeholder regimes opens
on a sustainable approach to energy policy and a number of complex problems that have
the environment (Lawrence, 2002). been only been touched on in interest-group
These processes are not sufficient: they theories of modern democracy. The rules
essentially help move only to stage 2 of governing systems of negotiation must define
the stakeholder development process sketched the actors, the issues, and the codes of
above. That is, they move understanding discussion and decision; in practice these rules
forward and thus help to reduce conflicts are not eternal but rather adapted to concrete
born out of miscommunication or lack of sets of actors and issues.
foresight. But they do not have the leverage The key problem for any new regime
to produce real modifications of values on will be to encompass new actors that have
the part of different stakeholders that could developed in the last few decades. This creates
help bring them together in agreements. In serious organizational problems: it is harder
terms of the two major issues raised at the to organize relations among many players
beginning of this essay, they have no clearly than among the three of the neo-corporatist
accepted way of defining who should be in or model. There has been a good deal of learning
out, and they have no way to reach decisions in recent years about the management of
when consensus is impractical. Since they are multiparty systems, but not yet enough to
relatively unstructured and non-binding, they resolve the problem.
cannot sustain the longer-running kinds of The most difficult obstacles, however, may
relationships needed to bring together parties be attitudinal. Leaders of the old order have a
who start far apart. hard time accepting new actors as legitimate:
To move to the third stage of a stakeholder unions in particular have a tendency to think
regime, one where negotiations can be struc- that other ‘progressive’ groups should follow
tured to produce agreements, more progress their lead, as they did through much of the
must be made around defining mechanisms last century. It is equally hard for new actors,
of accountability and enforcement. This is for their part, to give up their initial purity
traditionally the realm of governance rather of purpose and to accept compromise with
than process management. It is likely to others who have different priorities. These
involve government authority, though this is attitudes are a constant source of friction and
not essential: professional associations have conflict among groups that should be allies in
had binding accountability mechanisms for building a new stakeholder order to balance
centuries independent of government. the economic values of corporations.

CONCLUSION
NOTES
For all the power of the ideology of free 1 The concept of ‘neo-corporatism’ is sometimes
markets, industrial societies have always been used to refer to systems with high levels of co-
characterized by conflict among groups with operation and partnership. I am using it more broadly
different values. When these conflicts are to refer to all tripartite systems characteristic of
unregulated they destabilize both economies industrial capitalism, of which the ‘partnership’ type
is one variant.
and societies; when institutionalized they can 2 The concept of ‘regime’ has been used in various
lead to pragmatic balances that for a time meet fields, most relevantly by Esping-Andersen (1990) and
most stakeholder needs. Since we are clearly others in studies of welfare states. I am in a sense
372 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

adapting that usage to IR, though I intend it more Freeman, R.E (1984) Strategic Management: a stake-
as an expression of institutional theory à la Parsons holder approach. Mass: Pitman, 1984.
(1971). Freeman, Richard B. and Medoff, James L (1984) What
Do Unions Do? NY: Basic Books.
Gittell, Marilyn (1980) Limits to Citizen Participation:
REFERENCES the decline of community organizations. Beverly Hills:
Sage.
American Society of Association Executives and Hacker, Jacob (2002) The Divided Welfare State: The
Chamber of Commerce of the United States (1975) Battle over Public and Private Social Benefits in the
Principles of Association Management. Washington, United States. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
DC: ASAE & CCUS. Press.
Boeri, Tito, Brugiavini, Agar and Calmfors, Lars (eds) Heckscher, Charles (1988) The New Unionism: Employee
(2001). The Role Of Unions In The Twenty-First Involvement in the Changing Corporation. Cornell
Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press. University Press, 1995 (second edition).
Best, Michael H (1990). The New Competition: Heckscher, Charles (2000) ‘HR strategy and contingent
Institutions of Industrial Restructuring. Cambridge, work: dualism vs. true mobility’. in Carré, Françoise;
MA: Harvard University Press. Ferber, Marianne; Golden, Lonnie; and Herzenberg,
Carré, Françoise and Joshi, Pamela (2000) ‘Looking for Stephen A. (eds) Nonstandard Work: the Nature
leverage in a fluid world: innovative responses to and Challenge of Changing Employment Arrange-
temporary and contracted work’. in Carré, Françoise; ments. Industrial Relations Research Association:
Ferber, Marianne; Golden, Lonnie; and Herzenberg, pp. 267–90.
Stephen A. (eds) Nonstandard Work: The Nature Heckscher, Charles C (1995) The New Unionism:
and Challenge of Changing Employment Arrange- Employee Involvement in the Changing Corpo-
ments. Industrial Relations Research Association: ration. Cornell University Press, 1995 (second
pp. 313–39. edition).
Castells, Manuel (1997). The Power of Identity. Oxford:
Heckscher, Charles, Maccoby, Michael, Ramirez, Rafael
Blackwell.
and Tixier, Pierre-Eric (2003) Agents of Change:
Cnaan, Ram A. (1991) ‘Neighborhood-representing
Crossing the Post-Industrial Divide. Oxford: Oxford
organizations: how democratic are they? A review
University Press.
of the literature’. Social Service Review, 65: 614–34.
Hyman, Richard (2001) Understanding European Trade
Cobble, Dorothy Sue (1991) Dishing It Out: Waitresses
Unionism: Between Market, Class, and Society.
and Their Unions in the Twentieth Century. Urbana,
London: Sage Publications.
Ill: University of Illinois Press.
Lawrence, Anne T. (2002) ‘The Drivers of Stake-
Dannemiller Tyson Associates (2000) Whole-Scale
holder Engagement: Reflections on the Case of
Change: Unleashing the Magic in Organizations.
Royal Dutch/Shell’. Journal of Corporate Citizenship,
Berrett Kohler.
Durkheim, Emile (1947/1893) The Division of Labor in 6 (Summer).
Society. NY: The Free Press, 1947; orig 1893. Left Business Observer (2000) ‘Income and
Ebbinghaus, B (1990) ‘Does a European social model Poverty.’ 93, February; available at http://www.
exist and can it survive?’. in Huemer, G. et al. (eds) leftbusinessobserver.com/Stats_incpov.html (viewed
The Role of Employer Associations and Labour Unions 5/10/06)
in the EMU. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 1–26. Merton, Robert K (1966) ‘Dilemmas of democracy in the
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. (1990) Three Worlds of voluntary associations’. American Journal of Nursing,
Welfare Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University May: 1055–61.
Press, 1990. Olson, Mancur (1971) The Logic of Collective Action:
Fine, Janice (2006) Worker Centers: Organizing Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge,
Communities at the Edge of the Dream. NY: Cornell MA: Harvard University Press.
University Press, forthcoming (January). Parsons, Talcott (1971) The System of Modern Societies.
Flament, Catherine (1991) ‘Associations-réseaux et Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
réseaux d’associations: une approche formelle de Philips, Louis (1989) The Economics of Imperfect
l’organisation réticulée’. Sociétés Contemporaines, Information. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
5 (March): 67–74. Press.
Foote, Nathaniel W., Galbraith, Jay, Hope, Quentin and Piore, Michael J. and Sabel, Charles F. (1984) The
Miller, Danny (2001) ‘Making solutions the answer’. Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity.
The McKinsey Quarterly 3: 85–93. New York: Basic Books.
THE EVOLUTION OF STAKEHOLDER REGIMES: BEYOND NEO-CORPORATISM 373

Plotnick, R. D., Smolensky, E., Evenhouse, E. and Smolensky, Eugene and Plotnick, Robert (1992) Inequal-
Reilly, S. (1998) ‘Inequality and poverty in the ity and Poverty in the United States: 1900 to 1990.
United States: The twentieth-century record’. Focus University of California, Berkeley, Graduate School of
19 (3): 7–14. Public Policy: Working Paper #193 (July 8).
Ramirez, Rafael and Wallin, Johan (2000) Prime Movers: Solow, Robert (1990) The Labor Market as a Social
Define Your Business or Have Someone Define It Institution. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell.
against You. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. Touraine, Alain (1985) ‘An introduction to the study of
Schmitter, Philippe C (1983) ‘Democratic theory and social movements’. Social Research 52 (4) (Winter):
neocorporatist practice’. Social Research 50 (4) 749–87.
(Winter): 885–928. Vogel, Ezra F. (1979) Japan as Number One: Lessons for
Scully, Moreen and Segal, Amy (2002) ‘Passion with America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
an Umbrella: grass roots activism in the workplace’. 1979.
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 19: Weber, Max (1968) Economy and Society. New York:
125–68. Bedminster Press, 1968/1921. Translated and edited
Shikawa, Akihiro (2002) ‘Modernization: Westernization by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich.
vs. Nationalism – a Historical Overview of the Weisbord, Marvin R. (1987) Productive Workplaces:
Japanese Case’. Development and Society 31 (2) Organizing and Managing for Meaning, Dignity, and
(December): 281–88. Community. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Slichter, Sumner H., Healy, James J. and Livernash, E. Williamson, Peter J (1985) Varieties of Corporatism:
Robert (1960) The Impact of Collective Bargaining on a Conceptual Discussion. Cambridge: Cambridge
Management. Washington: Brookings Institution. University Press.
Smith, Constance and Freedman, Anne (1972) Zald, Mayer N (1988) ‘The trajectory of social move-
Voluntary Associations: Perspectives on the Litera- ments in America’. Research in Social Movements,
ture. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Conflicts and Change 10: 19–41.
PART THREE

Industrial Relations Processes


20
Union Formation
John Godard

Research into the formation of unions has or more of the variation in actual voting behav-
been conducted primarily in liberal market ior (Getman et al., 1976; Premack and Hunter,
economies (especially the US, but also 1988; Montgomery, 1989; Davy and Shipper,
Canada and the UK), where union represen- 1993). Even outside of an organizing drive,
tation is determined chiefly by the level of voting propensity may be seen as indicative
worker support. It has involved four relatively of untapped union growth potential and hence
disparate bodies of literature, addressing: of latent unionism (Fiorito et al., 1995).
Analysis of variation in voting propensity
1) individual level propensities to vote for a union; is thus potentially useful for understanding
2) the organizing process; the main reasons workers support unions and
3) labour law; and identifying the conditions under which they
4) macro-level economic and political conditions. are more likely to do so. Below, I review the
research relevant to each of these questions
This chapter addresses each of these in in turn, distinguishing between ‘internal’ (for
turn.1 It then discusses their implications for instance, attitudes, and beliefs) and ‘external’
understanding the formation of unions and (for instance, demographic, contextual, and
suggests a future direction for work in this social) determinants. Because the literature
area. is vast, I focus on studies employing large,
representative data sets and multivariate
analysis, as identified in Table 20.1; where
WORKER VOTING PROPENSITIES AND a study does not meet these criteria but is
THE PRECONDITIONS FOR UNION referred to, the sample and method are noted.2
FORMATION
The internal determinants of voting
The stated propensity to vote for a union by no
propensities
means determines how workers will actually
vote. However, the available evidence does There have been a number of attempts to
suggest that voting propensity at the early theorize voting propensities, drawing on
stages of an organizing drive accounts for half frustration-aggression (Klandermans, 1986),
378 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 20.1 Major studies and data sets employed in voting propensity analyses
US studies and data sets
Kochan, 1979; Fiorito, 1987; 1977 Quality of Employment Survey (QES), national survey of 804 union and 711
Evansohn, 1989; Fiorito & Greer non-union workers, by the University of Michigan Survey Research Centre.
1986.
Getman et al., 1976; Farber & Saks, Getman, Goldberg, and Herman data set (GG&H), collected by the University of
1980; Dickens, 1983; Davy & Illinois Survey Research Laboratory in 1973, from 1004 employees subject to
Shipper, 1993. 31 NLRB elections in 1972 and 1973; merged with NLRB election data.
Cornfield et al., 1998. 1991 General Social Survey (GSS), national survey of 910 non-union and 517 union
employees, by the National Opinion Research Centre (University of Chicago).
Deshpande & Fiorito, 1989; Jarley Union Image Survey, national survey of 830 non-union and 622 union workers,
& Fiorito, 1989; Fiorito et al., conducted in 1984 by Louis Harris & Associates for the AFL-CIO.
1987; Schur & Kruse, 1992;
Cornfield & Kim; 1994
Fiorito & Young, 1998; Fiorito & 1991 General Social Survey /National Organizations Survey, matched data from
Greer, 1986*. national surveys of 484 employees and employers (non-union = 383), by the
National Opinion Research Centre and the University of Illinois Survey
Research Lab.
Freeman et al., 2000; Fiorito 2001. Worker Participation and Representation Survey, national survey of 1,929
non-union and 479 union employees in private or non-profit organizations,
conducted in 1994 by Princeton Survey Research for R. Freeman and J. Rogers.
Youngblood et al., 1984. Consumer panel survey in two southeastern states, n=400 non-union workers.

UK studies and data sets


Wood & Machin, 2005; Belfield & 1998 Work Employee Relations Survey, national matched surveys of 2,191
Haywood, 2004. employers and 28,237 employees, conducted by Social and Community
Planning Research.
Wood & Machin, 2005. Work and Industrial Relations Survey, national surveys of 3,312, 3,209, and 3,023
employers conducted in 1980, 1984, and 1990 by Social and Community
Planning Research (UK) for the UK government; predecessor to WERS 98.
Charlwood, 2002; 2003. 1998 British Social Attitudes Survey, national survey of 3,146 adults (755 were in
non-union employment, 653 in union employment), by the National Centre for
Social Research (UK).
Charlwood, 2003. 2001 British Workers Representation and Participation Survey, national survey of
693 non-union and 662 union workers, designed by the Centre for Economic
Performance, London School of Economics, conducted by BMRB International.

Canadian studies and data sets


Gomez et al., 2001. 1996 Lipset-Meltz survey, national survey of 1,495 adults, by the Angus-Reid
Group.
Source: *Studies identified more than once are those using more than one data set.

cognitive dissonance (Wheeler and McClendon, 3) perceived benefits relative to costs of union
1991: 60), rational choice (Farber and Saks, formation, or union ‘instrumentalities’.
1980), and interactionist (Montgomery, 1989)
theory, and on various other social science I begin by considering these explanations, and
frameworks (see Wheeler and McClendon, then turn to alternative possible explanations
1991). But although the specific terminology that have generally received less attention in
employed may have varied, most have the literature.
generally focused on one or more of three
conventional explanations (for example, Conventional explanations
Kochan, 1979; Klandermans, 1986; Wheeler Of the three conventional explanations, dis-
and McClendon, 1991): satisfaction is hypothesized to matter only if
individuals believe that a union can address
1) dissatisfaction with one’s job or aspects thereof; the sources of their dissatisfaction. Thus, its
2) general beliefs about unions; and effects are often viewed as conditional on
UNION FORMATION 379

instrumentalities (Wheeler and McClendon, conventional explanations once the latter are
1991). In contrast, union beliefs have typically broken into sub-dimensions.
been viewed as operating independently, The evidence is also unclear as to
although one study (Youngblood et al., 1984; the relative importance of specific issues
also see Summers et al., 1986) has postulated encompassed within the three conventional
that negative beliefs can have a ‘veto effect,’ explanations. In their analyses of the 1977
negating the effects of dissatisfaction and QES, Kochan (1979: 26) found dissatisfaction
instrumentalities, while another (Park et al., with bread and butter issues to have a
2006) has argued that general beliefs operate somewhat larger effect than dissatisfaction
in part through their implications for instru- with the nature of work, while Fiorito (1987)
mentalities. Finally, instrumentalities have found dissatisfaction with working conditions
been viewed as operating independently as and wages and benefits to bear relatively
well as in interaction with dissatisfaction and, strong associations, yet dissatisfaction with
possibly, general beliefs. supervision, job challenge, role support, and
Almost all of the relevant research has been promotion opportunities to bear statistically
in the US. In general, it has found global insignificant ones. Again, these findings may
measures of all three general explanations to be seen as consistent with the US tradi-
be associated with both voting propensities tion of business unionism. However, using
and voting behavior (Barling et al., 1992: 54), the 1984 Union Image Survey (UIS) data
with instrumentalities generally bearing a set, Deshpande and Fiorito (1989) reported
larger coefficient than general beliefs, and ‘intrinsic’ (that is, job content) issues to have
general beliefs a larger coefficient than dis- an effect similar to that for their ‘extrinsic’
satisfaction (for example, Kochan, 1979: 25; counterparts. In addition, Jarley and Fiorito
Fiorito, 1987; Deshpande and Fiorito, 1989; (1991) found the importance of job content
Youngblood et al., 1984: 583). These results issues to be greater in this data set than in the
may be seen as consistent with the US tradition QES data set, collected seven years earlier.
of business unionism and the instrumental They argued that this could reflect an ongoing
orientation associated with it. shift in what motivates workers to support
When the measures are broken into unions.
sub-components, however, the results There is some evidence of different asso-
become murkier. Results reported by Kochan ciations outside of the US. In an analysis of
(1979: 29) and by Fiorito (1987), both using UK data collected in 1998, Charlwood (2002)
1977 Quality of Employment Survey (QES) found dissatisfaction with pay to matter only
data, revealed dissatisfaction with each of a for manual workers reporting their pay to
number of facets of the employment relation be ‘very low.’ He found no associations for
(for example, pay and benefits) to have other categories. This may reflect the weak
coefficient sizes that were in combination bargaining power of UK unions as of the late
similar to that of for instrumentality. Their 1990s (for example, Brown et al., 2000). It
results also suggested a similar combined may also reflect a different traditional role
effect size for two sub-dimensions of for UK unions, one that focuses more on
dissatisfaction (with ‘bread and butter’ fairness and support at work (see Waddington
issues and with the ‘nature of work’). Finally, and Whitson, 1997). However, an analysis of
Fiorito (1987), again using QES data, reported survey data from workers in two Canadian
coefficient sizes for two sub-dimensions of cities (Krahn and Lowe, 1984) found general
general beliefs (‘political instrumentality’ and instrumentality perceptions to have stronger
‘negative image’) that were in combination effects than ‘big labor image,’ suggesting
equivalent to those for instrumentality. Such little difference from the US despite Canada’s
comparisons should be treated with caution. stronger tradition of social unionism.
But they suggest that instrumentality may Attempts to find support for the hypothe-
not be more important than the other two sized relationships between the three general
380 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

explanations have met with mixed success. made, including not just the structure of
Both Charlwood (2002: 481; 2003: 61) and the employment relation at law, but also
Youngblood et al. (1984: 585) found little evi- the broader system of laws and norms that
dence of such relationships. In a meta-analysis frame this relationship. As suggested by
of data from previous studies, Premack and Charlwood’s analysis of UK workers, differ-
Hunter (1988) found that dissatisfaction may ences in these environments have possible
have an indirect effect, operating through implications for the ability to generalize
instrumentalities. But they also found strong research findings across nations. Failure to
direct effects for dissatisfaction, and evi- address these environments may also limit
dence as to an indirect effect was based the extent to which research findings actually
on correlation analysis and hence did not contribute to our understanding of why
establish causality. Park et al. (2006) found workers do or do not vote for a union
general beliefs to have a significant effect on within a particular nation and how this may
instrumentalities (labeled ‘specific beliefs’), be related to matters of institutional design.
with no converse relationship, and the total In this regard, much may ultimately depend
(direct and indirect) effect of the former to be on national differences in union identities and
three times that of the latter. But their sample perceptions of ‘what unions do.’However, this
was comprised of pharmacists in the US, and possibility has not been considered.
so these results may not generalize.
There has been little research into the extent Alternative explanations
to which appealing to various attitudes and Although researchers have tended to focus on
beliefs is likely to enhance the likelihood of the three general explanations as identified
union success. For example, high levels of above, a number of alternative possible
dissatisfaction may be positively associated explanations have been addressed. Many of
with voting propensity, but may not be these explanations may be captured in part by
sufficiently widespread to really matter (see the three general explanations. But they tend
Kochan, 1979: 25), and may be difficult to to be more specific and more institutionally
influence without union organizers appearing informed.
to be ‘trouble makers’ and hence enhancing
the fear of conflict (see below). Yet the Distrust. In capitalist economies, the
opposite may be the case for instrumentalities employment relation is one of subordination
and general beliefs, which lend themselves under conditions of interest conflict (Godard,
to more positive appeals. If so, targeting 1998, 2004c). As such, one would expect
the latter, rather than attempting to foster distrust and insecurity as to the exercise
dissatisfaction, may be more effective for of authority to form an important rationale
improving the rate of union formation. for union formation, with the union largely
In addition, there does not appear to have selling itself as a source of ‘conflict insurance’
been any research specifically distinguishing (van de Vall, 1970; Adams, 1974). But only
between dissatisfaction with the job or one study (Zalesny, 1985) has addressed
facets thereof and dissatisfaction with the the role of trust, and it relied on a single
employer.3 One might expect the latter to item measure and was based on a survey
matter more, because it involves attribution of faculty in a single university. It found a
and hence a belief that something can statistically significant but weak association
be done through collective representation with propensity.
(Kelly, 1998).
An underlying problem with analyses of Desire for voice and representation. In
these three general explanations and com- view of the nature of the employment relation,
ponents thereof is that they have tended to the desire for collective representation and
abstract the decision to unionize from the voice should also form a major explanation
institutional environment within which it is for voting propensities – especially in liberal
UNION FORMATION 381

market economies, where alternative forms However, both Deshpande and Fiorito (1989)
of representation are weak or non-existent. and Fiorito (2001) found employee expecta-
In this regard, US evidence reveals a high level tions of union suppression activities to bear a
of demand for such representation (Freeman positive rather than negative association with
and Rogers, 1999). Yet, there would appear to voting propensity, possibly because pro-union
have been no research explicitly addressing workers have a more negative view of their
how or the extent to which this desire matters employer to begin with (Fiorito and Bozeman,
to union formation. At least two analyses, one 1997). More direct evidence of the importance
using UK (Charlwood, 2003) and one using of fear of reprisal may, however, be contained
US data (Kochan, 1979), have found ‘desire in a 2004 poll of Canadian workers, even
for influence’ to bear positive associations though Canadian labor law protections are
with voting propensity. The former found this generally stronger than in the US. It found
association to be substantially smaller than voting propensity to increase from 33 to 43
for either instrumentality or general beliefs, per cent when non-union respondents were
while the latter found it to be roughly half asked how they would vote if they could
that for instrumentality but roughly equivalent be assured there would be no reprisal from
to that of general beliefs. These measures the employer (CLC, 2004). Research into the
might be seen as proxies for the desire implications of employer anti-union tactics,
for representation and voice, but the extent addressed below, also suggests that fear of
to which they capture desire for collective reprisal matters.
influence rather than simply individual, job
level influence is not clear.4 Fear of conflict. Employees may also fear
increased conflict once a union has been
Perceived injustice. Fairness has long been organized (Cohen and Hurd, 1998). Again,
identified as important in the IR literature, this may be especially important in North
especially in the UK (for example, Hyman America, where adversarial relations are the
and Brough, 1975), where there has been a norm (Adams, 1993) and employers have
tradition of ‘informality’ in the employment been known to play on this fear in order
relation. Conversely, injustice perceptions to discourage workers from voting for a
have been considered critical prerequisites to union. In a study of 320 NCR customer
collective action in IR (Kelly, 1998). Again, engineers subject to a recent organizing
this likely reflects the nature of the employ- attempt, Cohen and Hurd (1998) found fear
ment relation in liberal market economies. of conflict to be the most frequently identified
However, there has been little attempt to reason not to join any employee organization
specifically explore the importance of injus- and argued, based on corresponding case
tice and fairness perceptions on the propensity analysis, that it was more important than
to vote for a union.5 One US study did include fear of employer retaliation. But only one
a measure of pay equity (Kochan, 1979) and multivariate study has addressed fear of
another of discrimination (Deshpande and conflict (Farber and Saks, 1980: 364), finding
Fiorito, 1989). Neither was found to have an concern over a possible deterioration in
effect. But whether these adequately capture worker-supervisory relationships to increase
perceptions of injustice is unclear. the likelihood of a negative vote in union
certification elections.
Fear of reprisal. Employer reprisal, or fear
thereof, has been identified as perhaps the Work orientations. Worker orientations and
major factor influencing the outcome of a consciousness of conflicts underlying the
union organizing drive. This is especially so employment relation may be central to their
in the US, where employers have traditionally willingness to challenge employer author-
been hostile towards union recognition and ity, which may in turn be critical to the
labor law protections are weak (see appendix). unionization decision. For example, where
382 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

workers possess oppositional orientations, paid to the importance of national institutional


they should be more likely to view unions environments, even though these may shape
as means to resist managerial domination. what unions do and ultimately the internal
However, there have been only two studies determinants of voting propensity.
that include measures of work values and
orientations, both Canadian. Gomez et al.
(2002) found traditional union values (for External determinants
example, regarding seniority) to be positively External explanations of voting propensities
associated with voting propensity, while can be grouped into six categories:
Barling et al. (1991) found both ‘Marxist’
work beliefs (for example, about exploitation) (1) employer practices;
and ‘humanist’ work beliefs (for example, (2) job characteristics;
about whether work should be gratifying) to (3) pay;
be positively associated with student voting (4) working conditions;
propensities. (5) social influences; and
(6) individual and demographic characteristics.
Political beliefs and affiliations. Political
beliefs and affiliations should be useful All may be hypothesized to operate through
a priori predictors of voting propensity, one or more of the internal explanations
especially to the extent that they reflect a identified above, although attempts to explore
consciousness of broader class relationships the extent to which this is the case have been
embedded in the employment relation. This limited.
relationship should be strongest in nations
where unions have had stronger political Employer practices
party affiliations than otherwise (for example, Initial interest in employer practices
Canada vs. the US). Yet, although a number addressed whether a ‘union substitution’
of studies have found a general association approach (Kochan, 1980), involving practices
(Fiorito and Young, 1998; Fiorito, 2001; similar to those negotiated by unions, lowered
Charlwood, 2002; Gomez et al., 2002), the support for unions. However, although one
measures employed have varied, and most study (Evansohn, 1989) found some support
have been single item and typically ad hoc. for this thesis, another (Fiorito and Young,
Perhaps as a result, they have yielded only 1998) found measures of individual practices
weak associations. There has also been believed to be associated with a union
no attempt to explore for cross-national substitution strategy (for example, grievance
differences. systems) to bear weak and often insignificant
associations, and a composite index of five
Overall such practices to be statistically insignificant.
Overall, the research reveals that, each of More recently, focus has been on prac-
the three general explanations for union tices associated with the so-called ‘high
propensity is important, even if their relative performance paradigm,’ including team work,
importance and the associations between them problem solving groups, direct forms of com-
are not clear. However, there has been little munication, and supportive selection, train-
research into the importance of alternative ing, and reward practices (Godard, 2004c).
and more specific possible explanations, These can be hypothesized to reduce propen-
many of which can be said to derive from sity not only through their implications for
the institutional design of the employment union substitution, but also through selection
relation and which may therefore provide for processes that are biased towards workers
a more institutionally informed and nuanced with anti-union orientations and through work
understanding of the determinants of union designs and practices that enhance satisfaction
formation. In addition, little attention has been and lower instrumentalities.
UNION FORMATION 383

The US research generally supports this the two relevant UK studies are based on
argument. Freeman et al. (2000) found that data collected prior to the introduction of
only a quarter of non-union workers with an recognition laws in 1999.6
employee involvement scheme would vote for It is also possible, once again, that
a union, compared with four in ten for those the effects of these practices depend on
without. Fiorito (2001) found a statistically institutional environments. For example,
significant but modest association between an employer resistance towards unions, although
index of 12 high performance HRM practices not unheard of, has traditionally been less
and union voting propensity. Cornfield et al. intensive in the UK than in North America,
(1998) found performance based pay raises and a number of factors have combined to
to be associated with a 22 per cent lower encourage more collaborative relationships
propensity to join a union. Kochan et al. with employers (Oxenbridge et al., 2003;
(1986) found high performance practices Oxenbridge and Brown, 2004, 2005; Godard,
to lower the likelihood of union formation 2008). If so, we would expect high per-
in recently opened establishments, although formance practices in the UK to be more
Fiorito et al. (1987), using the same data set, amenable to union representation and hence
found mixed effects. Finally Bronfenbrenner characterized by lower employer resistance to
(1997) found that, where a participation unions. Yet this possibility has received little
program is in place, the estimated likelihood attention in the literature.
of union organizing success declined by A 2003–2004 telephone survey of 750
22 per cent. Canadian and 450 English workers (Godard,
Results have been more uneven outside of 2006a) was designed to address these limita-
the US. Gomez et al. (2002) found high perfor- tions. Analysis of the data from this survey
mance practices to bear a negative association found:
with voting propensity in Canada, but only for
youth. Belfield and Heywood (2004) found 1) high levels both of high performance work prac-
only one of eight practices (performance- tices and of high commitment HR practices (both
related pay) to bear a consistent negative multi-item indices) to be positively associated
association with desire for a union in the UK. with the propensity to vote for a union in Canada,
One (problem solving groups) actually bore but to bear no significant associations in England;
a positive association. Using UK workplace 2) an index of more traditional HR practices to
level data, Wood and Machin (2005) found bear a strong negative association with voting
propensity in Canada yet no association in
high performance practices to bear no associ-
England;
ation with the likelihood of union recognition, 3) high commitment HR practices and union
and some evidence of a complementarity representation to bear no significant association
between unions and HRM practices. between in Canada but a positive association in
The research on employer practices has, England, and
however, been of uncertain overall quality 4) contingent pay schemes to bear a strong negative
(also see Godard, 2004c). In a number of cases association with voting propensity in Canada, but
(for example Bronfenbrenner, 1997; Cornfield no association in England.
et al., 1998; Freeman et al., 2000; Gomez et al.,
2002), researchers have relied on a single The different findings across the two samples
binary measure of employer practices. Where were argued to reflect an adversarial institu-
multiple items have been employed, these tional logic in Canada compared to a more
items often do not include key work or HRM collaborative logic in England, especially in
practices (for example, Fiorito, 2001; Fiorito so-called ‘best practice’ workplaces.
and Young, 1998; Belfield and Heywood,
2004; Wood and Machin, 2005) or controls Job characteristics
(Kochan et al., 1986), or they are imprecise Job characteristics have been closely identi-
(see Fiorito et al., 1987: 116). In addition, fied with the high performance model (for
384 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

example, Appelbaum et al., 2000). Although Studies of certification elections have also
the causal direction of this linkage is unclear addressed the implications of pay for union
(Handel and Gittelman, 2004: 90–94), they success, but with mixed results. Fiorito et al.,
are also viewed as of major importance in (1987) found absolute pay levels to bear
the literature on job attitudes, and hence a positive association with win rates, and
can be expected to have implications for Bronfennbrenner (1997) found low pay to
voting propensity. The research on internal bear a positive association. But Cooke (1983)
determinants indirectly supports this expecta- and Bronfenbrenner and Juravich (1998)
tion, finding dissatisfaction with job content found no association. It is possible that low
and intrinsic instrumentality to both be wage employers have more to loose if a union
associated with voting propensity, as reported is successful and hence engage in stronger
earlier. resistance, offsetting any direct implications
The implications of three characteristics low wages have for voting propensity.
have been addressed: autonomy, complexity,
and influence. Three studies (Cornfield et al., Working conditions
1998; Evansohn, 1989; (Lowe and Raskin, The only working condition to receive
2000) have found the first to bear nega- attention in the literature has been workplace
tive associations with propensity, although hazards. Using the QES data set, Kochan
another study (Fiorito and Young, 1998) found (1979; also see Fiorito, 1987) reported
no association. Studies addressing the impor- perceived job hazards to bear a strong positive
tance of the second have found no significant association with voting propensity, smaller
association (Youngblood et al., 1984; Lowe in magnitude than for instrumentality, but
and Raskin, 2000). Finally, the third has been larger than for general beliefs. Using data from
found to bear a negative association with the US Young Men’s/Women’s Longitudinal
voting propensity (Kochan, 1979; Charlwood, Surveys, Robinson (1988) found a significant
2003) and with union support (Belfield and positive association for young women, but
Heywood, 2004). It would thus appear that not for young men. Much likely depends,
autonomy and influence matter, but that job however, on whether a union is perceived
complexity does not. This may be because as able to address hazards, which again may
autonomy and influence convey trust, which depend on workplace characteristics and on
is reciprocated by the employee (Fox, 1974), institutional differences, especially the role
yet complexity does not. health and safety laws allow for unions.

Pay Social influences


In view of the traditional economic role of At least two studies, one using US data
unions, it is plausible to expect low pay to be (Deshpande and Fiorito, 1989: 893), and one
positively associated with voting propensity. using Canadian data (Gomez et al., 2002) have
Yet only a few studies have directly addressed found support for a union to be associated with
the importance of pay, in some cases finding whether a member of the respondent’s imme-
no association (Haberfield, 1995; Youngblood diate family is already represented by one.
et al., 1984) and in others finding a negative Perceptions that family and friends support a
but typically weak one (for example, Premack union have also been found to be associated
and Hunter, 1988; Cornfield and Kim, 1994: with respondent support, especially for young
528). It may, however, be relative rather workers, presumably because they have yet
than absolute pay levels that matter (Premack to form strong views of their own (Gomez
and Hunter, 1988). Consistent with this et al., 2002). Canadian research (Barling
argument, Farber and Saks (1980) found et al., 1991; Kelloway and Watts, 1994) has
workers at the low end of the intra-firm wage also found student perceptions of parental
distribution to be more likely to vote for a union attitudes to be associated with voting
union. propensity, and these perceptions to in turn
UNION FORMATION 385

be strongly associated with actual parental union member can be important to organizing
attitudes and participation. success.
Co-worker support for a union may be
particularly important (Brief and Rude, 1981) Individual and demographic characteristics
given that union organizing is more likely to Individual and demographic characteristics
be successful if workers develop solidarity may be viewed as potentially important
and ‘come together as a group’ (Weikle ‘markers’ for locating pockets of latent
et al., 1998). A number of US studies unionism. However, research findings have
(Dickens, 1983; Davy and Shipper, 1993, been uneven.
Youngblood et al., 1984) have found support Research conducted in the US generally
for this argument. One of these (Davy and suggests that public sector workers and past
Shipper, 1993) found perceived co-worker union members are more predisposed to vote
support to not only have strong direct and for a union, that white collar workers are less
indirect associations, but also to substantially predisposed, and that seniority, marital status,
reduce the observed independent effects and rural background do not make much
for job satisfaction. Another (Youngblood difference (Kochan, 1979; Farber and Saks,
et al., 1984) found it to matter more 1980; Fiorito and Greer, 1986; Youngblood
than general beliefs. Yet another, of 125 et al., 1984; Deshpande and Fiorito, 1989;
university employees, (Montgomery, 1989) Cornfield et al., 1998). Although most studies
found both perceived co-worker and family control for age, only a few have found it
normative pressures, in interaction with the to matter (Farber and Saks, 1980; Dickens,
subjective importance of these pressures, to 1983; Fiorito, 2001), and the observed effects
be associated with the intention to vote for a have been weak. The findings have also been
union. generally weak for gender, although at least
Absent from the research literature has one study (Friedman et al., 2006) has found
been analysis of how information provided women to be more favorable to unions, and
by managers, union organizers, or co-workers another (Bronfenbrenner and Hickey, 2004)
alters attitudes or beliefs as they pertain to has estimated union success rates in National
the various internal determinants discussed Labor Relations Board (NLRB) elections to
earlier. In their classic work on social be 70 per cent higher in predominantly female
information processing, Salancik and Pfeffer workplaces.
(1977) show that job satisfaction is strongly Results for race have been ambiguous.
influenced by social information. Consistent Some studies have found non-whites to
with this argument, Davy and Shipper (1993) be substantially more prone to vote for a
found perceived peer support for a union union (Kochan, 1979; Farber and Saks, 1980;
to be indirectly as well as directly linked Cornfield and Kim, 1994: 528; Cornfield et al.,
to propensity, through a negative association 1998; Fiorito, 2001; Friedman et al., 2006) and
with satisfaction. It is likely that other union success to be higher in predominantly
determinants can be similarly influenced, non-white workplaces (Bronfenbrenner and
with potentially important implications for Hickey, 2004), but others have found little or
understanding how various employer or union no association for either dependent variable
tactics may alter union organizing success. (Deshpande and Fiorito, 1989, Youngblood
This may be especially the case for general et al., 1984; Dickens, 1983).
beliefs and instrumentalities, which for non- Region of residence has been found to
union workers are less likely to be based matter in some US studies (Kochan, 1979;
on direct experience (Devinatz and Rich, Cooke, 1983; and Deshpande and Fiorito,
1996). In this regard, Lopez (2004: 285) 1989) and in the UK (Charlwood, 2002: 483),
concluded, based on ethnographic analysis, yet other US studies have found that it does
that the ability to debunk negative general not (Farber and Saks, 1980; Heneman and
beliefs about unions and what it is like to be a Sandver, 1989; also see Cornfield et al., 1998).
386 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

The same is true of education, with some these determinants, the result may be to under-
studies (Deshpande and Fiorito, 1989; Fiorito, state their combined (for instance indirect as
2001) having found a negative association, well as direct) effects and hence to undermine
yet others (Kochan, 1979; Dickens, 1983; their value as markers for latent unionism.
Cornfield et al., 1998) having found no This is confirmed by Cornfield and Kim
association. (1994), whose results reveal that coefficient
It is possible that more refined catego- sizes on most demographic variables decline
rizations, based on multiple characteristics, by a half or more once attitudinal variables
are necessary. For example, Schur and Kruse are controlled.7 A further, related problem
(1992) found that white collar women are is that this research may only be picking
twice as likely to support a union as are both up representation gaps arising from unmet
their male and their blue collar counterparts, demand for unions at the time of data
but only in the private sector. Fiorito and Greer collection (for example, among public sector
(1986) found race to bear weaker associations and white collar workers in the 1970s). Yet
with voting propensity among females than these gaps may either close or shift over
among males. time, potentially rendering research findings
There is also evidence that individual and obsolete.
demographic characteristics matter for the
importance of various internal determinants. Overall
For example, Kochan (1979) found dissat- It would appear that individuals who perceive
isfaction to matter for manual workers only influence and autonomy in their job are less
with respect to supervision, yet for white likely to support a union, and that the same
collar workers only with respect to ‘bread and is the case for workers in private sector and
butter’ and ‘nature of work’ issues. Fiorito white collar jobs – possibly because the latter
(1987) found union political instrumentality are likely to score higher on the former. Family
to matter more for public sector workers than and co-worker influences also matter. Finally,
for private sector workers, and workplace so-called high performance practices appear
instrumentality to matter only for private to be (negatively) associated with support for
sector workers. Fiorito et al. (1996) found unions, but possibly only in the UA.
instrumentalities and satisfaction to matter Overall, however, research on the external
more for private than public sector workers, determinants of voting propensities would
and general beliefs to matter less. Gomez appear to yield surprisingly slim pickings.
et al. (2002) found social influences (labeled This is especially true with regard to individ-
as ‘social capital’) to matter more for workers ual and demographic characteristics, which
between 16 and 25 years of age than for those may have substantively important effects,
between 25 and 65 years of age. yet the findings for which often vary across
Attempts to explore for these differences studies and may operate in interaction with
often border on little more than fishing other variables. It is also possible that some
expeditions and hence may suffer from type II of these findings reflect representation gaps
errors. Nonetheless, they do suggest a case that existed at the time of the research but
for more complex analysis. From a practical have since closed. But a similar assessment
standpoint, they also suggest that research applies with regard to employer practices,
may be of limited value to union organizing where research to date has typically suffered
unless it is tailored to the specific group that a from a number of limitations, including a
union is targeting. failure to account for the role of institutional
More generally, measures of individual environments in shaping employer motives or
and demographic characteristics are typically employee responses where various practices
included in regressions with measures of have been implemented. Finally, although the
the various internal determinants addressed literature establishes that social influences
earlier. To the extent that they operate through matter (as one would expect), it does not
UNION FORMATION 387

address how social informational influences 195 NLRB elections, Reed (1989) found
can be used to alter voting propensities. significant associations for a variety of
personality characteristics. He also found
organizers to be more successful if they
THE ORGANIZING PROCESS had experienced downward mobility, were
moderately educated, were former rank-and-
Research into the implications of the orga- file union members, and spent a higher
nizing process for union success may be percentage of their work time organizing.
considered as follows: 1) the immediate orga- Bronfenbrenner and her colleagues (see
nizing context, including union, organizer, below) found no association between orga-
and bargaining unit characteristics, 2) union nizer ‘representativeness’ and union win rates
strategies and tactics, and 3) employer in one of three studies (Bronfenbrenner,
strategies and tactics. Again, almost all of 1997), an estimated 20 per cent increase in
this research has been conducted in North another (Bronfenbrenner and Juravich, 1998),
America, especially the US. and an estimated 110 per cent increase in
another (Bronfenbrenner and Hickey, 2004).
However, the latter study used a combined
The immediate organizing context
measure of number of organizers and repre-
A number of factors may enhance union sentativeness.
success during the actual organizing process, Finally, a number of studies have explored
beginning with the characteristics of the union the implications of bargaining unit size for
itself. Using data from 111 national unions, union organizing success. Although some
Fiorito et al. (1995) found that national have revealed a negative association (Farber,
union decentralization, use of innovative 2001; Thomason, 1994: 222; Gilson and
organizing tactics, and specialization in par- Wagar, 1995: 78; Scott et al., 1996), others
ticular industries were associated with union have suggested little effect (Lawler and
NLRB win rates, but that democratic union West, 1985; Bronfenbrenner and Juravich,
structures were not. In a subsequent study 1998; Bronfenbrenner and Hickey, 2004).
of 74 national unions, Fiorito et al. (2002) Still others have found size to have a
also found that union leaders reporting their curvilinear effect, increasing the likelihood
union to have a broad message, to place of union success up to a point (65 workers
considerable emphasis on new organizing, or less, depending on the study), beyond
and to make extensive use of information which its effects diminish or even become
technology were also likely to perceive higher negative (Cooke, 1983; Dickens et al., 1987;
levels of organizing effectiveness. However, Florkowski and Schuster, 1987; Thomason
none of these variables was associated with and Pozzebon, 1998: 761). This has been
NLRB win rates. interpreted as showing that group dynamics
Devotion of resources to new organizing increasingly play a role up to a certain point,
has also been argued to enhance organizing reflecting greater group cohesiveness, beyond
success (Voos, 1984). In support of this which they make little further difference
view, Dickens et al. (1987) found that unions and may be offset by increased diversity
with higher levels of organizing effort, which (Thomason and Pozzebon, 1998) and more
may be seen as a proxy for resources, sophisticated employer opposition (Cooke,
obtain a higher percentage of favorable votes. 1983).
However, Heneman and Sandver (1989)
found no relationship between the dollars Union organizing activities
spent per election and certification success in There has been widespread advocacy for a
NLRB elections as of the late 1970s.8 more activist, ‘organizing’ model, one that
Organizer characteristics may also matter. involves workers themselves more fully in
Using data from a survey of organizers in the organizing campaign, creating a sense
388 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of collective identity and support (also see The three studies by Bronfenbrenner and
Boxall, this volume, and Fiorito and Jarley, her colleagues referred to earlier represent
this volume). This model is largely consis- the most comprehensive attempts to explore
tent with mobilization theory, especially as the effects of union tactics. In the initial
advanced by Kelly (1998). However, it may study, Bronfenbrenner (1997) obtained data
be inconsistent with worker identities and on union and employer tactics from lead
norms, especially in the US, where ‘bread organizers for 261 NLRB elections held in
and butter’ unionism has been most prevalent 1986–1987. Of ten union tactics, she found
and potential members may prefer a servicing five to be significantly associated with the
model (Hurd, 2004). Consistent with this likelihood of union success, in combination
possibility, Cohen and Hurd (1998), in a case roughly doubling this likelihood. In the
study analysis of US professional workers, second study, Bronfenbrenner and Juravich
found that such tactics may alienate workers. (1998) used data from 165 campaigns
Based on three cases, Heery et al. (2000) conducted in 1994. Six of ten tactics were
find that, in the UK, this model may enhance associated with statistically significant
the likelihood of union success, but tends to increases in union win rates, again in
be resource intensive and as such may not combination roughly doubling the likelihood
be viable. Hurd (2004) has made a similar of union success, and an additive index
argument for the US. combining the ten tactics yielded an
There is also emergent evidence that an estimated 9 per cent increase in union
important tactic may be to build support success rates for each additional practice
outside of the election unit, through coalitions adopted. In the third study, Bronfenbrenner
with various community groups and various and Hickey (2004) used data collected from
tactics to place public pressure on employers. lead organizers involved in each of 412
The paradigm case for this strategy has been organizing attempts in 1998–1999. Three
the Justice for Janitors campaign conducted in of ten tactics were significantly associated
Los Angeles in the mid-1990s (Erickson et al., with organizing success, in combination
2002; Waldinger et al., 1998). However, in this almost quadrupling the likelihood of union
case, there was a history of bargaining in the success, and an additive index combining all
industry, which may limit the ability to gener- ten tactics yielded an estimated increase of
alize. Moreover, Rudy (2004) found that, even 34 per cent in the likelihood of union success
within California, local political contexts and for each additional tactic adopted.
histories may make an important difference to In Canada, Martinello and Yates (2004)
the success of community campaigns. found that union campaign strategies that
In a study of 211 NLRB elections involving could be classified as ‘the maximum’ did
a large national union, Peterson et al. (1992) not win significantly more votes than those
found ‘working closely with community that eluded classification, while those that
leaders’ to be positively associated with union focused on small group meetings, house calls,
success. But it was not associated with the or simply communications with workers, did.
percentage voting in favor of the union. Only a ‘house call’ strategy was significantly
They also found isolating the employer and associated with success rate.
conducting boycotts, both of which can be said There may be important limitations to this
to entail community support, to be negatively research. For example, the items included in
rather than positively associated with the the Bronfenbrenner studies varied consider-
percentage voting for the union. This suggests ably by study, making comparisons difficult.
that some community tactics may actually Their estimated effects were also uneven,
backfire. Reed (1989) also found that building which may reflect co-linearity problems. So
coalitions increased the likelihood of success, the main conclusion to be drawn is from the
but that the use of paid advertising decreased findings for the indices. As one would expect,
it, again suggesting a backfire effect. they reveal that the resources and effort put
UNION FORMATION 389

into a campaign and the ability to mobilize considered a proxy for the initial likelihood
volunteers yield a higher likelihood of union of success. The remaining significant tactics
success. Yet the estimated effect size in the accounted, in combination, for slightly more
third study is so large as to strain credulity, than a 50 per cent increase in the likelihood
and it is not clear why it is so much greater of success. This is substantially below that
than for the second, the data for which were suggested by her second and third studies,
collected only four years earlier. This could which did not include card sign-ups.
be explained if these tactics are synergistic A further possible problem with the union
(Sherman and Voss, 2000: 312) and if union tactics research is that unions may adopt
organizers had discovered this and so had different sets of strategies depending on
begun to adopt higher numbers of tactics. employer tactics and internal support levels.
The former possibility is consistent with the For example, boycotts and advertising may be
main conclusion drawn by Bronfenbrenner employed as external tactics where employers
and Hickey (2004: 53), which is that their have successfully used intimidation and
results show the need for a ‘multifaceted, internal support remains weak. This would
comprehensive’campaign. However, possible explain why some studies have observed
synergies are not explored in this research. apparent backfire effects for these tactics.10
The latter possibility also does not appear Finally, it is again not clear how well
to bear support: Bronfenbrenner and Hickey US research generalizes to other institutional
(2004: 41) report that even unions with environments. It may be that limited campaign
national reputations for effective organizing periods in Canada (see appendix) render com-
used more than five tactics in only a third or prehensive, US style strategies superfluous.
less of their campaigns as of 1998–1999. This would be consistent with the Martinello
More generally, the data used in union and Yates findings. The US research also
tactics research have been retrospective. It may not generalize to the UK. Because
is possible that organizers (from whom the employers have tended to be less hostile
data are collected) rationalize unsuccessful towards unions in the UK, US-style strategies
drives by discounting the extent to which may actually alienate both employers and
various tactics were effectively used, biasing workers, lowering union success. However,
estimates upward. there has been no multivariate research on this
In addition, the number of tactics may topic in the UK.
be higher where the chances of success
justify the required resource expenditure per Employer activities
worker (which may often be high: Voos, Employer tactics have long been held to have
1983, 1984; Farber and Western, 2001), and major implications for union success. Yet,
where there is sufficient internal and external research results have been mixed. The first
support for them to be effective – something major (and still most comprehensive) study of
that may only be determined during the this question, by Getman, et al. (1976), found
course of a campaign and may be shaped by such practices to have only small effects on
employer tactics (see Cooke, 1983).9 Indeed, both voting intentions and voting behavior.
the adoption of these tactics may reflect (as In a re-analysis of their data, Dickens (1983)
much as determine) a successful drive, with found employer tactics – especially employer
unions adopting these tactics only as the threats and actions against union supporters,
drive proceeds and only if a win appears certain communications, and captive audience
within reach. If so, this could result in further speeches – to bear negative associations,
upward biases (and may explain why unions in combination reducing the likelihood of
typically adopt only a limited number of union success by 17 per cent or more.
tactics). In this regard, Bronfenbrenner’s first Lawler and West (1985) found only 3 of
study included a measure of per cent signing 12 practices (small group meetings, use
union cards prior to application, which may be of surveys, employee list irregularities) to
390 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

have statistically significant negative effects, per practice (computed by this author).
in combination lowering the likelihood of Bentham (2002) found two practices (lim-
union success by 24 per cent. They also iting employee-union communication and
found discrimination for union activities to managerial training) to lower the likelihood of
be associated with an 11 per cent increase, union success, two other practices (tightened
suggesting backfire effects. Peterson et al. supervision and contesting the bargaining
(1992) also found that, of 15 employer unit) to increase it, and seven other practices
tactics, only two (spreading rumors about to not matter (she did not compute an index).
store/plant closing and distributing right to Neither study controlled for union tactics,
work literature) bore significant negative again potentially resulting in downward
associations with win rates of a large national biases. However, Martinello and Yates (see
union, and that two (delaying an election earlier) did. Their results reveal a simple
and shifting work elsewhere) bore posi- ‘communication strategy’ to be associated
tive associations, again suggesting backfire with a 26 per cent decline in union success
effects. Reed (1989) also found that, of twelve rates (as computed by this author) and to be
tactics, none was statistically significant. But about as effective as a more comprehensive,
none of these studies adequately controlled ‘do everything’ strategy.
for union tactics, which may co-vary with As for the union tactics results, the
their employer counterparts, thus potentially retrospective nature of these studies may
yielding downward biases. give rise to recall bias, especially where
The three US studies conducted by the data are collected from union organizers
Bronfenbrenner and her colleagues did (see Thomason and Pozzebon, 1998: 755).12
include union tactics, potentially addressing A further possible problem, also similar to one
this problem. The first (Bronfenbrenner, for union tactics research, is that employers
1997) revealed a number of employer tactics – may be less likely to engage in anti-union
including wage or benefit increases, promises, tactics where support for a union is either low
anti-union letters, captive audience meetings, (because the tactics are not needed and could
and letters to employees – to bear negative backfire) or high (because there is little point
associations with union certification success, and it could cause unnecessary antagonism),
in combination yielding a 42 per cent decrease or where the union effort is tepid, hence posing
in the likelihood of success.11 The second and little threat (see Cooke, 1985: 434).13,14 Thus,
third (Bronfenbrenner and Juravich, 1998; there is a possible endogeneity problem. In
Bronfenbrenner and Hickey, 2004) relied exploring this question, Freeman and Kleiner
only on additive indices, yielding estimates (1990) found strong evidence that firms with
of, respectively, a 7 per cent and a 13 per cent workforces having the greatest innate prob-
decline in the likelihood of union success ability to vote for a union (measured by card
for each practice adopted. The third study sign-ups and by an index summing answers to
contained substantially more items than the a series questions asked of organizers) devote
second (22 compared to 12), and as such the fewer resources to opposing a union, and some
differences in these two results suggest a major evidence that those with the lowest innate
difference in overall effect size, as was also probability also devote fewer resources. They
the case for the union effects results. Again, also found the sign for unfair labor practices
however, it is unclear as to why. It is also unclear to switch from positive to negative when
as to why both of these studies suggest much they used an instrumental variable. Although
larger effects than did the first study. neither the initial nor the instrumental variable
In Canada, where restrictions on employers estimate was significant, this not only suggests
are stronger and the campaign period more possible specification bias in other studies,
limited, Thomason and Pozzebon (1998) but also that backfire effects found in
reported an index of ten practices to decrease some studies reflect such biases (also see
union success rates by an estimated 14 per cent Cooke, 1985: 433). Apparent backfire effects
UNION FORMATION 391

may also, however, once again reflect a the appendix, Canadian labor law regimes
tendency for some employer tactics to be have remained relatively strong in comparison
adopted primarily where a union victory is to their US counterpart, providing the primary
already more likely. explanation for why density decline has been
Finally, the research on employer tactics moderate in Canada yet catastrophic in the US
may also be sensitive to the institutional (see Godard, 2003: 462).
environment within which organizing occurs. There have been a number of analyses
This is illustrated by the differences between illustrating the importance of US-Canadian
the US and the Canadian results, though it differences.15 Rose and Chaison (1996: 83;
is likely even more important for the UK, also see Riddell, 2001: 401) found that,
where there has traditionally been a greater from 1976 to 1985, unfair labor practice
expectation that employers will respect the complaints against employers in Canada were
right of workers to join a union and hence one-fourth to one-tenth (depending on the
‘play by the rules.’ This may not only mean jurisdiction) the US rate, even though they
that employers are less likely to resort to anti- were easier to file and win in Canada (Bruce,
union tactics, but also that any backfire effect 1993, 1994). Meltz and Verma (1996: 6)
could be much stronger. computed that, from 1980 to 1995, union
success rates for certification applications
Overall were almost 50 per cent higher in Canada
Research on the organizing process yields than the USA (69 vs. 48 per cent). Finally,
some information on the importance of con- available estimates reveal that a third or more
textual factors such as union characteristics, of all first negotiations failed to reach an
organizer characteristics, and unit size. But agreement in the USA in the 1980s and early
the research on both union and employer 1990s (Commission on the Future of Worker
tactics would appear to suffer from potentially Management Relations, 1994; Weiler, 1983,
significant methodological and interpretive 1984; Cooke, 1985), compared to less than
problems. These problems are probably not 10 per cent as of the mid-1990s in Canada
sufficient to reject the main findings of this (Bentham, 1999: Chapter 4, lviii), where there
research, which are that union and employer was provision for first contract arbitration.
activities generally have the expected effects Lipset and Meltz (1998) reported
and that these effects may be stronger with that almost 50 per cent more US than
regard to union activities. But they do mean Canadian non-union workers (47 per cent vs.
that the estimated effect sizes, both for 33 per cent) would have voted for a union as
individual tactics and for additive indices, of 1996, suggesting a much higher untapped
should be interpreted with caution. demand for unionism in the US (see Godard,
2003: 479–82). Both Godard (2003) and
Gomez et al. (2001), using their data but
LABOR LAW relying on different methods of calculation,
computed that US union density would have
Almost all of the research undertaken on been roughly equivalent to Canadian density
the differences in labor law has been in the if US workers faced the same conditions as in
US and Canada. In both countries, labor Canada. Although a variety of explanations
law is based on the ‘Wagner’ model (see other than labor law (for example, Canada’s
appendix) and premised on the assumption of ‘social unionism’ and cultural differences)
employer hostility (and may, paradoxically, have been advanced for these differences,
perpetuate this hostility: see Adams, 1993). they are not well supported by the available
In Canada, there are eleven separate private evidence (see Godard, 2003).
sector labor law jurisdictions, compared to One aspect of labor law believed to be
one in the US. This limits what can be said especially important has been provision for
about Canada in general. But, as outlined in card certification, under which a ballot can
392 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

be avoided and hence the opportunity for A problem may be that employers are more
employer interference minimized. In a study likely to challenge the bargaining unit and
comparing Canadian jurisdictions with and introduce delays when union support appears
without card certification, Johnson (2000, to be moderate or high. This could result in
2002, 2004) estimated that mandatory ballot downward biases. These biases are less likely
laws reduce union success rates by from for Riddell’s study, because it is difficult for
6 to 9 percentage points. She also estimated employers to introduce such delays in Canada.
that, as of 1998, this alone accounted for Yet shorter time delays, coupled with stronger
17 to 26 per cent of the US-Canada density restrictions on employers, may also lessen the
gap. Bentham (1999: Chapter 7) found the implications of delays in Canada, limiting the
availability of card certification to lower the generalizability of his results to the US.
probability of illegal employer tactics by Finally, longitudinal analyses have found
10 per cent, and increase the probability of changes in labor law in general to be
certification by 11 per cent. Slinn (2004) associated with union density. Freeman and
found a shift to mandatory ballots in Ontario Pelletier (1990) found legal changes to be a
in the mid-1990s to be associated with a major determinant of UK density from 1945 to
21.7 percentage point decline in the proba- 1986. Martinello found changes in labor laws
bility of union success, while Riddell (2004) to be more important than changes in either
found a similar shift in British Columbia to government or the economy for explaining
be associated with a 19 per cent decline. variation in union density over time in three
He also found management opposition to be Canadian provinces (Martinello, 1996). In a
twice as successful as under card certification. subsequent analysis, Martinello (2000) found
Only one study (Martinello and Meng, changes in labor law and in political party
1992) has not found an effect for card to have had significant effects on both union
certification.16 organizing activity and success in Ontario.
A number of multivariate studies have also One limitation to research into the effects
investigated the implications of the length of labor law has been a failure to establish
of time from application to election. Those just why labor law matters. The assumption
measuring delays in months (Cooke, 1983; is that employers can be expected to engage
Prosten,1978; Thomason, 1994) have found in intimidation if allowed involvement in
each month of delay to be associated with the organizing process. Yet proponents of
only small declines (of 2.5 per cent or laws that allow involvement – especially
less per month) in union success rates. Of mandatory ballot requirements – claim that
those measuring delays in days, at least this only allows for a more informed decision
three studies (Hurd and McElwain, 1988; on the part of workers and a more democratic
Cooke, 1985; Cooper, 1984) have not found decision process (Yager et al., 1998). The
a significant effect. However, other studies failure to test this argument has meant
have. Florkowski and Schuster (1987) found something of a lacuna for debates over labor
a 26 per cent greater change of winning if law reform.
the election is held within 12 days, but that With the exception of the Freeman and
delays much beyond this period made little Pelletier study, it is also not clear that
difference. In the first of her three studies, this research generalizes beyond the North
Bronfenbrenner (1997) found each day of American environment. In the UK, recogni-
delay to be associated with a 0.1 per cent tion laws have (since 1999) been designed
lower likelihood of union success. Riddell to build on the tradition of lower employer
(2001: 407) found an approximately 1 per cent opposition to unions and to avoid the
lower probability of success for every two adversarial climate found in North America
days of delay in British Columbia (Canada), (Wood and Godard, 1999). Partly as a result,
though only where unfair labor practice these laws allow substantial opportunity for
charges had been filed. employer involvement (see appendix). Yet, as
UNION FORMATION 393

of 2003, anti-union tactics remained much the macro determinants of union growth
less pervasive than in North America (Gall, (for example, see Chaison and Rose, 1991;
2003: 92), and 88 per cent of new recognitions Kochan, 1980: 133–142; Schnabel, 2003).
were still voluntary (Gall, 2005: 2). Primary concern has been with changes in
It is also not clear how much specific membership levels and union density rather
labor laws and changes therein can matter. than with union formation. But the tendency
For example, in Canadian jurisdictions with has been to assume that the former portends
even the most favorable laws, union density the latter.17
levels remain below 40 per cent overall, and A variety of models have been proposed,
30 per cent in the private sector. In the UK, typically based on arguments consistent
density has stalled at around 30 per cent with the conventional internal determinants
despite the introduction of recognition laws. identified earlier (also see Stepina and Fiorito,
Thus, there may be a ceiling on what 1986). For example, Ashenfelter and Pencavel
labor laws can do. The broader problem (1969) argued that price inflation and employ-
may be with the institutional regimes in ment growth increase the benefits from union
which these laws are embedded, especially formation (for instance, obtaining wage gains
the requirement of formal certification and to catch up to inflation) while lowering the
the decentralization of bargaining, but also costs (for instance, tight labor markets mean
broader institutional environments and norms, lower employer retaliation), that a higher
especially as these influence employer orien- unemployment rate in a preceding recession
tations towards unions (Godard, 2004d). means a higher stock of worker grievances,
and that the percentage of Democrats in the US
Overall House of Representatives captures pro-union
Differences in labor law regimes would sentiments. Based on a time series analysis
appear to provide a key explanation for of US data from 1904 to 1960, they found
US-Canada differences in employer behavior support for all of their arguments. Although
(for instance, unfair labor practices), union their model did not perform well for the
success rates, and ultimately union density. post-WWII period in the US (Moore and
It would also appear that specific provisions, Pearce, 1976), Sharpe (1971) found similar
especially for card certification, make a results for Australia, as did Swidinsky (1974)
major difference in union success rates. This for Canada. In addition, Adams and Krislov
research may therefore be seen to provide (1974) successfully applied their model to
some evidence not only that labor law analyze new union organizing in the USA
matters to the prospects for union formation, from 1949–1970, although political climate
but also that employer activities matter. (Democratic Party membership) was not
However, it may not generalize beyond the significant in this analysis.
North American environment, where there is Using a somewhat different specification
tradition of intensive employer resistance to and a longer time period (1897 to 1970) than
union formation. It is also possible that the Ashenfelter and Pencavel, Bain and Elsheikh
effects of specific components of labor law (1976) found increasing wages, low employ-
are less important than, or conditioned by, ment, and high inflation to be associated
the broader institutional environment within with union density growth in an analysis of
which they operate. four different countries (the US, the UK,
Sweden, and Australia). Their specification
represented an improvement for the post war
MACRO ECONOMIC, POLITICAL, AND period up to 1970 in the US, although it
INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS did not perform well for the US for the
decade after 1970 (Fiorito, 1982), and political
Beginning with Commons (1918), there has variables were not significant for Sweden or
been a long history of attempts to establish the UK. However, using a different definition
394 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of union density and UK data for 1896 to a tipping point, at which unions have the
1984, Carruth and Disney (1988) found the resources to organize more aggressively and
election of Conservative governments to be employer opposition declines. Kelly (1998)
associated with an average density decline argued that density should grow fastest during
of 2.5 percentage points. Finally, Booth strike waves, followed by the beginning of
(1983) developed a substantially different major economic (for instance, Kondratieffian)
specification for the UK, finding business upswings or downswings, because these are
cycle variables to successfully account for most conducive to perceptions of injustice and
short-term but not long-term growth.18 hence mobilization.
An obvious limitation of much of this These explanations offer possible insights
research has been that it relies on a limited into the preconditions for labor movement
number of variables to capture complex revitalization. However, they have not been
economic, social, and political developments. well supported empirically. For example,
A great deal depends on the operationalization Freeman draws on data from specific unions
of relevant constructs, the isolation of relevant to establish the conditions for growth, but his
variables’ effects, and the time period exam- analysis is not well linked to his initial theory.
ined (see Stepina and Fiorito, 1986: 262). As Kelly’s explanation is not well supported by
such, it has been criticized as ad hoc and the historical data, although he argues that it
deterministic (see Moore and Pearce, 1976; may bear stronger support in non-corporatist
also see Schnabel, 2003: 21–22; Riley, 1997: countries (1998: 94). Price and Bain do not
267–269). Nonetheless, this research gener- provide a test of their argument, nor do Dunlop
ally appears to confirm that low inflation, or Bernstein.
low wage growth rates, high unemployment, Finally, Western (1997) has argued that,
and conservative governments are inimical to although economic conditions matter, the
union formation, especially in liberal market extent to which this is so depends on insti-
economies. In view of the problems inherent tutional conditions. He finds general support
to this research, it is surprising that researchers for his model across 18 OECD countries
have been able to demonstrate consistent (1997:120–21). But his model essentially dis-
effects at all, and the ability to do so may tinguishes between economies where unions
demonstrate that these variables play a greater grow through formal certification processes
role than the findings themselves reveal. (the primary concern of this chapter) and those
Amore important criticism is that this research where they are more institutionally embedded
tends to be successful for periods of ‘normal’ (for instance with centralized bargaining,
growth, but it does not do a very good job of Ghent systems, and strong political ties). As
accounting for periods of rapid union growth, such it does not provide much insight into
which is when union revitalization tends to union formation in liberal market economies.
occur. One largely overlooked possibility is that
There have been a number of attempts to major ruptures or changes do not just alter
account for these periods. For example, both the rate of union growth, they may also
Dunlop (1948) and Bernstein (1954, 1961) change the way in which economic and
argued that they tend to occur during wars and political variables influence worker attitudes
social unrest, although the former explained and behavior. For example, Stepina and
this with reference to economic conditions Fiorito (1986) found considerably different
(for example, high labor demand) and the lat- results prior to the Wagner/Depression era
ter with reference to labor policy (for example, in the US than after it. A similar shift may
labor law). Price and Bain (1983) argued that have occurred in recent decades, particularly
such periods reflect paradigm shifts that allow within liberal market economies. Workers in
for radical change in the institutional envi- these economies are not well insulated from
ronment. Freeman (1998) argued that growth market forces and so may be more susceptible
spurts occur once density reaches (in effect) to neoliberal globalization ideologies, which
UNION FORMATION 395

attribute economic hardship and insecurity to caution (Godard, 1994). A number of gaps
immutable economic forces that are beyond also remain – particularly as they apply to our
the reach of employers in particular (also understanding of union formation.
see Clawson and Clawson, 1999: 101). It Research into voting propensity has been
may as a result be increasingly difficult extensive and establishes the importance of
to successfully mobilize workers against three general internal determinants (dissatis-
employers, thus weakening the effects of faction, instrumentalities, and union image).
economic and political conditions that would However, the relative importance of each
otherwise be positive for union growth, remains unclear and little attention has been
while strengthening the effects of negative paid to a number of alternative, typically
ones.19 more specific, determinants arising from
Also important may be the failure of this the nature of the employment relation in
research to adequately address differences in liberal market economies. These include
institutional environments and the norms that distrust, injustice perceptions, oppositional
underpin them (even across liberal market work orientations, and others. The research on
economies: see Godard, 2004d), especially as external determinants reveals that employer
they pertain to the orientations and identities practices can affect union formation, as may
of both employers and unions (Locke and job characteristics, pay, working conditions,
Thelen, 1995) and hence to worker expec- various social influences, and individual and
tations of unions and employer responses demographic characteristics. But the results
to union organizing. These differences may are often weak, inconsistent, or methodolog-
as a result condition the extent to which ically suspect, and how these factors operate
and ways in which changes in economic through internal determinants has for the most
and political conditions, including historical part been unexplored.
ruptures, matter. Research into the organizing process and
the role of labor law both tell a somewhat
Overall more coherent story. Union and employer
The research suggests that, at least until tactics matter, especially in the USA, where
recently, ‘normal’ variation in union growth there tend to be lengthy and often acrimonious
(and hence formation) can be accounted for union election campaigns. However, possible
in part by economic and political variables. specification problems and inconsistent find-
But accounting for growth spurts and longer ings limit both what can be said about specific
term trends is more difficult. To fully account tactics and the confidence that can be placed
for variation in union formation, including the in overall effect sizes. Labor law also clearly
conditions under which it occurs and how it matters, at least in North America. But even
occurs, it may ultimately be necessary to adopt with substantial reforms, union density is not
a broader perspective, one that addresses likely to reach much beyond a third of the
the importance of institutional environments, labor force in the absence a major regime
norms, and traditions in accounting for the change.
behavior of the parties. Finally, there is evidence that macro eco-
nomic, political, and institutional conditions
matter, even if precisely how they matter may
CONCLUSIONS: WHAT CAN BE SAID? depend on the model used. But the importance
of globalization ideologies and of broader
Each of the bodies of research reviewed in institutional environments that shape the role
this chapter has much to offer if judged as a of, and level of acceptance for, labor unions
specific area of empirical inquiry addressing have been largely unexplored. Moreover, this
specific empirical questions. But as is the research still does not (and perhaps cannot)
case for most such research, any conclusions provide much insight into the preconditions
from it should be drawn with considerable for a resurgence in union fortunes, although
396 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

attempts to explain periods of rapid growth and all that activists can hope to influence,
offer some promise in this regard. may be short term variation on a longer path
A problem with much of the literature has trajectory that is alterable only at the margins.
been the failure to account for the role of This may substantially limit the possibilities
institutional environments. To be sure, all for labor union formation in that country
modern capitalist economies are capitalist (Godard, 2006b), even in comparison to other
economies. Yet there is reason to think that, liberal market economies. Of course, this
in general, institutional environments and argument is oversimplified and may under-
norms matter. This may be so even within estimate the importance of union agency
liberal market economies, as differences in the (Sherman and Voss, 2000; Clawson and
experience with the UK recognition system Clawson, 1999) and of historic ‘junctures’
and with its North American counterparts (Krasner, 1988) during which this agency may
would seem to suggest. Yet institutional be particularly important. The point, however,
differences do not just explain employer is that there is a need to move beyond the
behavior. They also explain differences in empiricist orientation of much of the existing
union identities (Locke and Thelen, 1995), research to address these sorts of issues and
in the functions unions serve (Hyman, 2001), explanations.
and in the organizing problems unions face In short, a more comprehensive understand-
(Heery and Adler, 2004: 63–65). These differ- ing of union formation and the conditions
ences may have important implications for the that give rise to it will likely require a
attitudes, beliefs, and expectations of workers more explicitly institutional approach. This
towards unions, for the reasons they join approach might begin with the recognition
them (for instance internal determinants), and of the nature of the employment relation
for the role of various external determinants in capitalist economies and its implications
of union formation (for example employer for the rationale underlying union formation.
practices). They are also likely to have But it would then address the implications
important implications for the organizing of different institutional environments and
process, including the extent to which each the norms that underpin them, and take
party adopts various tactics and the likely into account differences in the identities,
effects of these tactics. These implications are types, and problems of unions and of other
likely to be greatest across different ‘varieties’ representative bodies, seeking to establish
of capitalism (Hall and Soskice, 2001), but the extent to which these matter and how.
they cannot be ignored when comparing Rather than generating lists of determinants,
individual countries within the same variety the task would be to develop an institutionally
(for instance, liberal market economies). informed approach to understanding and
For those concerned with the future researching the essential conditions for union
of unions, the critical question may not formation, how and why these may vary both
even involve differences in union identities, within and across nations, and, ultimately,
functions, or organizing problems. Rather, how these may be influenced.
it may involve the broader institutional
environments and norms within which unions
operate and the possibilities they do or APPENDIX
do not offer for increased rates of union
formation. It would seem, for example, that
US, Canadian, and UK labor law
the US institutional environment and the
regimes compared
norms that have historically underpinned it
(for instance, economism, individualism, and These regimes are all based on the majority
‘free’markets) have given rise to severe biases principle and administered by a labor relations
against union formation (Godard 2006b). board or, in the case of the UK, the Central
If so, all that researchers can hope to capture, Arbitration Committee (CAC). However, the
UNION FORMATION 397

assumptions and philosophy underlying the deterioration of the law, beginning in the late
Canadian and US regimes differ considerably 1980s, but especially after 1995. However, in
from those underlying the UK regime, and six jurisdictions, covering roughly 50 per cent
the Canadian regime is considered to be much of the labor force, there is provision for
stronger than its US counterpart. Focus here automatic card certification, without a ballot.
is on private sector laws, which in the US in Where a ballot is required, there is no
particular differ from those for public sector requirement for a final decision on the
workers. For more in-depth comparisons, see bargaining unit prior to a ballot, and the
Godard (2004b: 11–37), Wood and Godard ballot must normally be held within 5 to
(1999) and Bogg (2004). 10 days of a union’s application, depending
Both the US and Canadian systems on the jurisdiction, thus minimizing delays.
are predicated on the assumption that the Unfair labor practices are also more stringent.
recognition process will be adversarial and Although captive audience meetings are legal,
that employers may engage in considerable one-on-one meetings are not, and there are
resistance both during and immediately after strong restrictions on employer speech. It is
this process. However, in the US, there is extremely difficult for an employer to appeal
substantial opportunity for an employer to do a ruling of the board to the courts, and
so. A ballot is required in all cases, and may employers can be ordered to begin bargaining
not be held until after the appropriate election before any such appeal is settled. If a first
unit is determined and any appeal of this agreement is not reached within a reasonable
determination has been held. This can mean period and bargaining appears to have broken
substantial delays, providing an employer down, the union may in most jurisdictions
with considerable opportunity to dissuade request first contract arbitration, thus ensuring
workers from joining a union. While they are a settlement is achieved. Finally, it is illegal
prohibited from threatening, disciplining, or in all jurisdictions to hire permanent striker
dismissing individual union supporters during replacements, and temporary replacements
this period, the remedies tend to be weak, are either banned or restricted in three.
largely involving either injunctive relief or In the UK, the underlying assumption is
make whole remedies. Employers can also that the recognition process should essentially
legally hold captive audience meetings and involve a negotiation by the union and the
may submit employees to one-on-one meet- employer, and that this negotiation should
ings with supervisors. They may also resort give rise to a voluntary agreement in which
to anti-union propaganda, even where this the employer recognizes the union and the
propaganda is untrue, and union organizers parties agree on the appropriate unit and both
have no legal access to employer premises the procedure for and scope of bargaining.
in order to respond. In addition, it is legal to To encourage this, the legislation requires the
‘predict’to workers that a union will render the union to first approach the employer (as is,
workplace economically unviable and hence technically, also required in the US), and
will result in its closure. Should a union allows for up to 38 days before the CAC
succeed in winning a certification election, it is subsequently becomes involved. The CAC
possible to instigate a lengthy appeals process, may either certify the union if a majority of
and there is no requirement to bargain with the eligible workers has signed a union card, or
union until this process has been completed. call a ballot. However, it must first attempt
Moreover, the requirement to bargain is weak to broker voluntary agreement between the
and virtually unenforceable. Finally, in the parties. In total, there can be up to 6 stages
event of a strike or lockout, the employer may and 86 days or more before the CAC decides
hire permanent replacement workers, subject to grant recognition, and another 20 days if
to no time restrictions. it determines that a ballot is called for. The
In Canada there are eleven separate CAC may also specify the bargaining unit
jurisdictions, and there has been some and the scope of bargaining if the parties
398 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

cannot agree on these. But the CAC can only reflecting justice but also instrumentality perceptions,
require the parties to bargain over wages, to be positively associated with voting behavior.
6 This may be especially problematic for the
hours, and holidays. There is no provision
Belfield and Heywood (2004) study, whose dependent
for first contract arbitration, but in the event variable measured perceptions of who would best
of a strike or lockout, the employer must represent the respondent about getting pay increases,
wait eight weeks before hiring permanent and so may have captured union instrumentalities
replacement workers. Employers are subject more than voting propensity per se. Wood and Machin
address union recognition, which should be less
to unfair labor practices (ULPs) similar to
problematic, but at the time their data were collected
those in the US and Canada, but these roughly a third of all workplaces with recognition in
only apply once a ballot has been formally the UK did not even have bargaining over pay (Brown
arranged. In addition, the employer may et al., 2000).
require captive audience meetings, but if it 7 Their results are also of interest because they
suggest that pro-union sentiment is strongest among
does it is also required to grant the union
socially diverse, low socio-economic status workers.
equal time, during working hours. Finally, the They argue that this reflects the tendency for unions
grounds for appealing a CAC decision are to legitimize themselves by appealing to the identities
narrow, as in Canada. of these workers.
8 Bronfenbrenner and Hickey (2004: 56) include
a variable referred to as “adequate and appropriate
staff and financial resources,” but it does not appear
to include any information on financial resources,
NOTES and “appropriate staff” refers to representativeness,
limiting its value for present purposes.
1 This chapter does not address the determinants 9 Brofenbrenner’s (1997) discussion of her theoret-
of union membership in non-majority, open shop ical framework also suggests that union tactics are
systems predominant within Europe. In these systems, endogenous, yet this is not addressed in any of her
collective bargaining coverage may be as much a analyses.
determinant of membership as vice versa, and union 10 I thank Jack Fiorito for this insight.
formation per se is not closely linked to membership 11 The estimates for captive audience meetings
levels. For recent reviews of this literature, see Riley and company letters items referred to the number of
(1997) and Schnabel (2003). each, yet both had a large range (0–200 and 0–5).
2 See Fiorito and Greer (1982), Wheeler and I therefore multiplied the coefficient by twice the
McClendon (1991), and Barling et al. (1992) for earlier sample mean for each (5.50 and 4.5, respectively) to
reviews. These reviews also cover studies with small compute the combined effect score.
samples and that use only bivariate analysis. 12 This may explain why Bentham’s findings, which
3 In their meta analysis, Premack and Hunter (1988) would appear to be the only ones based on employer
did find “satisfaction with administration” to have a data, are much weaker than those of other studies,
larger effect size than “extrinsic satisfaction.” But the although her surveys were not sent out until three
item content of these two measures was not reported to six years after the organizing drives in her study
and so it is unclear what they actually measured. occurred, affecting recall. It is also possible that
4 Another analysis, of UK data collected between employer respondents are hesitant to admit to some
1991 and 1993 (Waddington and Whitston, 1997), tactics and/or that their recall is affected by the
found that almost three quarters of new union election outcome in ways that differ from organizer
members (n=10,823) reported “support if I have a recall biases.
problem at work” – which may be seen to entail 13 Against this possibility, Dickens argues that the
voice and representation – to be a major reason for latter tend to be less visible to employers than vice
joining, identified twice as often as “improved pay versa and that employer anti-union campaigns pretty
and conditions.” However, at the time of this survey much follow preset formulae provided by consultants
union membership in the UK was more likely to entail and lawyers, minimizing any endogeneity (1983:
individual support at work than coverage by a union 563–4). But there is widespread variation in reported
agreement (and hence improved pay and conditions). employer tactics.
Thus, these findings may not generalize. 14 As noted earlier, Bronfenbrenner’s first study
5 Charlwood (2003) explored the linkage between included a measure of initial card sign-ups and hence
perceived injustice and the likelihood of joining a a partial proxy for support. She found weaker rather
union, but his injustices measure addressed political than stronger effects for employer practices than in
rather than employment specific beliefs. Farber and her other two studies. Both Reed (1989) and Dickens
Saks (1980: 364) found perceptions that a union (1983) also included card sign-ups and reported weak
will improve fairness at work, which may be seen as effects. None of these studies explored for possible
UNION FORMATION 399

curvilinearity. Also as noted earlier, the latter two also Adams, Roy (1993) ‘The North American Model of
did not control for union tactics. Employee Representational Participation: “A Hollow
15 Most of this evidence is from the mid-1990s Mockery”.’ Comparative Labor Law Journal 15 (4):
or before. However, it may actually provide a better 4–14.
indication of the importance of law than if it was more
Appelbaum, E., T. Bailey, P. Berg and A. Kalleberg (2000)
recent, because it predates a substantial weakening
Manufacturing Advantage: Why High Performance
of labour laws in the largest Canadian jurisdiction
(Ontario) during the second half of the 1990s. Work Systems Pay Off. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
16 There is also descriptive data as to the impor- Press.
tance of card certification. In the US, a Wall Street Ashenfelter, Orley and John Pencavel (1969) ‘American
journal article reported that only 73 per cent of those Trade Union Growth, 1900–1960.’ Quarterly Journal
signing a union card vote in favor of the union of Economics 83 (3): 434–48.
by the time a ballot is held (Wall Street Journal, Bain, George, and Elsheikh, Farouk (1976) Union
1991: A16). In Canada, Riddell (2001) observed Growth and the Business Cycle. Oxford: Basil
that success rates were substantially higher (92 vs. Blackwell.
73 per cent) in the province of British Columbia when
Bain, George, and Robert Price (1983) ‘Union Growth:
card certification was allowed than when it was not,
while Godard (2000: 299) reported similar evidence Dimensions, Determinants, and Density.’ In George
for the provinces of Ontario (77 vs. 59 per cent) and Bain (ed.) Industrial Relations in Britain. Oxford: Basil
Manitoba (75 vs. 64 per cent). These statistics apply Blackwell. pp. 3–33.
to the public as well as the private sector, and so may Barling, Julian, Fullagar, Clive and Kelloway, Kevin E.
understate the implications of card certification for the (1992) The Union and its Members: a Psychological
latter. Approach. New York: Oxford University Press.
17 I do not consider the literature on how com- Barling, Julian, Kelloway, Kevin E. and Bremmerman,
positional shifts account for density changes, as this Eric (1991) ‘Pre-employment Predictors of Union
literature really tells us little about union formation –
Attitudes’ Journal of Applied Psychology 76 (5):
rather, it likely picks up the effects of variables
associated with sectoral differences (e.g., white collar
725–31.
vs. blue collar), as reviewed throughout this chapter. Belfield, Clive R. and Heywood, John S. (2004) ‘Do
The evidence also suggests that compositional shifts HRM Practices Influence the Desire for Unionization?’
are of less importance than sometimes assumed, Journal of Labor Research 25 (2): 279–300.
although much may depend on how encompassing Bentham, Karen (1999) The Determinants and Impacts
the definition of compositional shift is (e.g., see Green, of Employer Resistance to Union Certification in
1992). See Western (1997: 150–155) and Goldfield Canada, Ph.D. diss. University of Toronto.
(1987) for the USA, Meltz and Verma (1996) for Bentham, Karen (2002) ‘Employer Resistance to Union
Canada, and Carruth and Disney (1988) for the UK.
Certification: A Study of Eight Canadian Jurisdictions.’
For Europe, see Calmfors et al (2001: 26).
18 I do not address business cycle research on
Relations Industrielles 57 (1): 159–85.
single, open shop European countries due to its limited Bernstein, Irving (1954) ‘The Growth of American
relevance to union formation and to space limitations. Unions.’ American Economic Review 44 (June):
19 Reinforcing this dampening may be the weak- 301–18.
ened economic and political power of unions, in Bernstein, Irving (1961) ‘The Growth of American
part because changed worker ideologies have meant Unions.’ Labor History 2 (Spring): 131–51.
less willingness to strike or to back pro-labor public Bogg, Allan (2004) ‘The Employment Relations Act
policies. As a result, unions appear no longer able 2004: Another False Dawn for Collectivism?’
to achieve substantial gains during an upturn, thus
Industrial Law Journal 34 (1): 72–82.
lessening their “demonstration” effects.
Booth, Alison (1983) ‘A Reconsideration of Trade Union
Growth in the United Kingdom.’ British Journal of
Industrial Relations 21 (3): 377–91.
REFERENCES Brief, A. P. and Rude, D.H. (1981) Voting in
Union Certification Elections: A Conceptual Analysis.
Adams, Avril V. and Krislov, Joseph (1974) ‘New Academy of Management Review. 6 (2): 261–68.
Union Organizing: A Test of the Ashenfelter-Pencavel Bronfenbrenner, Kate (1997) ‘The Role of Union
Model.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 88 (May): Strategies in NLRB Certification Elections.’ Industrial
304–11. and Labor Relations Review, 50 (2): 195–212.
Adams, Roy (1974) ‘Solidarity, Self-Interest and the Bronfenbrenner, Kate and Juravich, Tom (1998)
Unionization Differential Between Europe and North ‘It Takes More than House Calls: Organizing to
America.’ Relations Industrielles 29 (3): 497–512. Win with a Comprehensive Union-Building Strategy,’
400 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in Kate Bronfenbrenner et al. (eds) Organizing to Win. and Ronald Seeber (eds) Organizing to Win. Ithaca:
Ithaca: ILR Press. ILR Press.
Bronfenbrenner, Kate and Hickey, Robert (2004) Commission on the Future of Worker Management
‘Changing to Organize: A National Assessment of Relations (1994) Report and Recommendations.
Union Strategies.’ in Ruth Milkman and Kim Voss Washington: US Dept. of Labor and Dept. of
(eds), Rebuilding Labor. Ithaca: Cornell University. Commerce.
pp. 17–61. Commons, John R. (1918) History of Industrial Relations
Brown, William, Deakin, Simon, Nash, David and in the United States, vol. I New York: Macmillan.
Oxenbridge, Sarah (2000) ‘The Employment Contract: Cooke, W (1983) ‘Determinants of the outcome of union
From Collective Procedures to Individual Rights.’ certification elections.’ Industrial and Labor Relations
British Journal of Industrial Relations 38 (4): Review 36 (3): 402–14.
611–30. Cooke, W (1985) ‘The Rising Toll of Discrimination
Bruce, Peter (1993) ‘State Strategies and the Processing Against Union Activists.’ Industrial Relations 24 (3):
of Unfair Labor Practice Cases in the U.S. and 421–42.
Canada.’ In The Challenge of Restructuring: North Cooper, Laura (1984) ‘Authorization Cards and Union
American Labor Movements Respond. Edited by Jane Representation Election Outcome.’ Northwestern
Jenson and Rianne Mahon, Philadelphia: Temple University Law Review 79 (1): 87–139.
University Press. pp. 180–204. Cornfield, Dan, McCammon, Holly, McDaniel, Darren
Bruce, Peter (1994) ‘On the Status of Workers and Eatman, Dean (1998) ‘In the Community or in
Rights to Organize in the United States and the Union? The Impact of Community Involvement
Canada.’ In Restoring the Promise of American on Non-union Worker Attitudes about Unionizing.’ in
Labor Law. Edited by Kate Bronfenbrenner, Sheldon K. Bronfenbrenner, S. Friedman, R. Hurd, R. Oswald,
Friedman, Richard W. Hurd, Rudolph A. Oswald, and and R. Seeber (eds), Organizing to Win: New
Ronald Seeber, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Research on Union Strategies. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
pp. 147–72. pp. 102–19.
Cornfield, Dan, and Hyunhee, Kim (1994) ‘Socioeco-
Calmfors, Lars, Booth, Alison, Burda, Michael, Checchi,
nomic Status and Unionization Attitudes in the United
Daniele, Naylor, Robin and Visser, Jelle (2001) ‘The
States.’ Social Forces 73 (2): 521–32.
Future of Collective Bargaining in Europe.’ in Tito
Davy, Jeanette A. and Shipper, Frank (1993) ‘Voter
Boeri, Agar Brugiavini, and Lars Calmfors (eds) The
behavior in union certification elections: A longitudi-
Role of Unions in the Twenty-First Century. Oxford:
nal study.’ Academy of Management Journal 36 (1):
Oxford University Press. pp. 1–156.
187–201.
Carruth, Alan, and Disney, Richard (1988) ‘Where Have
Deshpande, Satish and Fiorito, Jack (1989) ‘Specific and
Two Million Trade Union Members Gone?’ Economica
General Beliefs in Union Voting Models.’ Academy of
55 (?): 1–19.
Management Review 32 (4): 883–97.
Chaison, Gary, and Rose, Joseph (1991) ‘The Macrode- Devinatz, Victor and Rich, Daniel (1996) ‘Information,
terminants of Union Growth and Decline.’ in George Disinformation, and Union Success in Certification
Strauss, Dan Gallagher, and Jack Fiorito (eds) The and Decertification Elections.’ Journal of Labor
State of the Unions. Madison: IRRA. pp. 3–45. Research 17 (1): 199–210.
Charlwood, Andy (2002) ‘Why Do Non-union Employees Dickens, W (1983) ‘The Effect of Company Campaigns
Want to Unionize?’ British Journal of Industrial on Certification Elections: Law and Reality Once
Relations. 40 (3): 463–92. Again.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review 36 (4):
Charlwood, Andy (2003) ‘Willingness to Unionize 560–75.
Amongst Non-union Workers.’ in Howard Gospel and Dickens, William, Wholey, Douglas and Robinson,
Stephen Wood, (eds) Representing Workers. London: James (1987) ‘Correlates of Union Support in NLRB
Routledge. pp. 51–70. Elections.’ Industrial Relations 26 (3): 240–52.
CLC (Canadian Labor Congress) (2004) Canadians Talk Dickens, Linda, Hall, Mark and Wood, Stephen (2005)
about Unions. Ottawa: CLC. Review of research into the impact of employment
Clawson, Dan and Clawson, Mary Ann (1999) ‘What relations legislation. Employment Relations Research
Has Happened to the US Labor Movement? Union Series No. 45, Department of Trade and Industry,
Decline and Renewal.’ Annual Review of Sociology UK Government.
25: 95–119. Dunlop, John T. (1948) ‘The Development of Labor
Cohen Larry, and Hurd, Richard W. (1998) ‘Fear, Conflict, Organization: A Theoretical Framework.’ In Richard A.
and Union Organizing.’ in Kate Bronfenbrenner, Lester and Joseph Shister (eds), Insight into Labor
Sheldon Friedman, Richard Hurd, Rudoph Oswald, Issues. New York: Macmillan. pp. 163–93.
UNION FORMATION 401

Erikson, Chris, Fisk, Catherine, Milkman, Ruth, Mitchell, Characteristics, and Attitudes.’ In Kate
Daniel and Wong, Kent (2002) ‘Justice for Janitors Bronfrenbrenner, S. Friedman, Richard W. Hurd,
in Los Angeles: Lessons from Three Rounds of Rudolph A. Oswald, and Ronald Seeber (eds),
Negotiation.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations Organizing to Win. Ithaca: ILR Press.
40 (3): 543–68. Florkowski, Gary and Shuster, Michael (1987) ‘Predict-
Evansohn, John (1989) ‘The Effects of Mechanisms of ing the Decisions to Vote and Support Unions in
Managerial Control on Unionism.’ Industrial Relations Certification Elections: An Integrated Perspective.’
28 (1): 91–103. Journal of Labor Research 8 (2): 191–207.
Farber, H. (2001) ‘Union Success in Representation Fox, Alan (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power, and
Elections: Why Does Size Matter?’ Industrial and Trust Relations. London: Farber.
Labor Relations Review 54 (2): 329–48. Freeman, Richard (1998) ‘Spurts in Union Growth:
Farber, H. and Saks, D. (1980) ‘Why Workers Want Defining Moments and Social Processes.’ in Michael
Unions: The Role of Relative Wages and Job D. Bordo, Claudia Goldin, and Eugene White (eds)
Characteristics.’ Journal of Political Economy, 88 The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and
(2)BE: 349–69. the American Economy in the Twentieth Century.
Farber, Henry, and Western, Bruce (2001) ‘Accounting Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
for the Decline of Unions in the Private Sector, Freeman, R. and Kleiner, M. (1990) ‘Employer Behavior
1973–1998.’ Journal of Labor Research 22 (3): in the Face of Union Organizing Drives.’ Industrial and
459–85. Labor Relations Review 43 (4): 351–65.
Fiorito, Jack (1982) ‘Models of Union Growth: a Test Freeman, R., Kleiner, M. and Ostroff, C. (2000) The
of the Bain-Elsheikh Model in the US.’ Industrial Anatomy of Employee Involvement and its Effects on
Relations 21 (1): 123–27. Firms and Workers. Working Paper 8050, National
Fiorito, Jack (1987) ‘Political Instrumentality Perceptions Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.
and Desires for Union Representation.’ Journal of Freeman, Richard and Pelletier, Jeffrey (1990) ‘The
Labor Research 8 (3): 271–89. Impact of Industrial Relations Legislation on British
Fiorito, J. (2001). ‘Human Resource Management Union Density.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations
Practices and Worker Desire for Representation.’ 28 (2): 145–64.
Journal of Labor Research 12 (2): 334–54. Freeman, Richard and Rogers, Joel (1999) What Do
Fiorito, J. and Dennis P. Bozeman (1997) ‘Fear Workers Want? Ithaca: ILR Press.
and Loathing (and Bribery) in the Workplace: Friedman, Barry A., Abraham, Steven B. and Thomas,
Worker Perceptions of Employer Responses to Union Randall K. (2006) ‘Factors Related to Employees’
Organizing,’ Journal of Individual Employment Rights Desire to Join a Union.’ Industrial Relations 45 (1):
5 (2): 137-52. 102–10.
Fiorito, Jack, and Greer, Charles R. (1982) ‘Determinants Gall, Gregor (2003) ‘Employer Opposition to Union
of US Unionism: Past and Future Research Needs.’ Recognition.’ In Gregor Gall (ed.) Union Organizing:
Industrial Relations 21 (1): 1–32. Campaigning for Trade Union Recognition. London:
Fiorito, Jack, and Greer, Charles R. (1986) ‘Gender Routledge.
Differences in Union Membership, Preferences and Gall, Gregor (2005) Trade Union Recognition in Britain:
Beliefs.’ Journal of Labor Research 7 (2): 145–64. A Corner Being Turned? paper presented at the
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul and Delaney, John (1995) 2005 annual meetings of the Labor and Employment
‘National Union Effectiveness in Organizing.’ Indus- Relations Association, Philadelphia, PA.
trial and Labor Relations Review 48 (4): 613–25. Getman, J., Goldberg, S. and Herman, J. (1976) Union
Fiorito, Jack, Jarley, Paul and Delaney, John (2002) representation elections: Law and Reality. New York:
‘Information Technology, Union Organizing, and Russell Sage Foundation.
Union Effectiveness.’ British Journal of Industrial Gilson, Clive and Wagar, Terry (1995) ‘The US/Canada
Relations 40 (4): 627–58. Convergence Thesis: Contrary Evidence from Nova
Fiorito, J., Lowman, C. and Nelson, F. (1987). ‘The Scotia.’ Relations Industrielles 50 (1): 66–85.
Impact of Human Resource Policies on Union Godard, J. (1994) ‘Beyond Empiricism: Towards a
Organizing.’ Industrial Relations 26 (2): 113–26. Reconstruction of IR Theory and Research.’ In David
Fiorito, Jack, Stepina, Lee and Bozeman, Dennis (1996) Lewin and Donna Sockell (eds) Advances in Industrial
‘Explaining the Unionism Gap: Public-Private Sector and Labor Relations. (JAI Press) VI: 1–36.
Differences in Preferences for Unionism.’ Journal of Godard, J. (1998) ‘An Organizational Theory of Variation
Labor Research 27 (3): 463–78. in the Management of Labor.’ In David Lewin and
Fiorito, J., and Young, A. (1998). ‘Union Bruce Kaufman (eds) Advances in Industrial and Labor
Voting Intentions: HR Policies, Organizational Relations. (JAI Press) VIII: 25–66.
402 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Godard, John (2000) Industrial Relations, the Economy, Haberfield, Yitchak (1995) ‘Why do Workers Join
and Society (2nd. edn) Toronto: Captus Press. Unions? The Case of Israel.’ Industrial and Labor
Godard, J. (2003) ‘Do Labor Laws Matter? The Density Relations Review 48 (4): 656–70.
Decline and Convergence Thesis Revisited.’ Industrial Hall, Peter and Soskice, David (2001) ‘An Introduction
Relations 42 (3): 458–92. to Varieties of Capitalism.’ In Peter Hall and
Godard, J. (2004a). ‘The U.S. and Canadian Labor David Soskice, eds, Varieties of Capitalism: The
Movements: Markets vs. States and Societies,’ In Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage.
Trade Unions and the Crisis of Democracy: Strategies Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 1–68.
and Perspectives. ed. Geoffrey Wood and Mark Handel, Michael, and Gittleman, Maury (2004) ‘Is there
Harcourt, Manchester: Manchester University Press. a Payoff to Innovative Work Practices?’ Industrial
pp. 159–90. Relations 43 (1): 67–97.
Godard, John (2004b). Trade Union Recognition: Heneman, Herbert and Sandver, Marcus (1989) ‘Union
Statutory Unfair Labor Practice Regimes in the Characteristics and Organizing Success.’ Journal of
USA and Canada. Employment Relations Research Labor Research 10 (4): 377–89.
Series No. 29, Department of Trade and Industry, Heery, Ed and Adler, Lee (2004) ‘Organizing the
UK Government. Unorganized.’ in Carola Frege and John Kelly
Godard, John (2004c). ‘A Critical Assessment of the High (eds) Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Union
Performance Paradigm.’ British Journal of Industrial Revitalization in a Global Economy. Oxford: Oxford
Relations 42 (2): 349–78. University Press. pp. 45–70.
Godard, John (2004d) ‘The New Institutionalism, Heery, Edmund, Simms, Melanie, Simpson, Dave,
Capitalist Diversity, and Industrial Relations.’ In Delbridge, Rick and Salmon, John (2000) ‘Organizing
Bruce Kaufman (ed.), Theoretical Perspectives Unionism Comes to the UK.’ Employee Relations
on Work and the Employment Relationship. 22 (1): 38–60.
Urbana-Champaign: IL: Industrial Relations Research Hurd, Richard (2004) ‘The Rise and Fall of the Organizing
Association. pp. 229–64. Model in the US.’ In G. Wood and M. Harcourt (eds)
Godard, John (2006a) ‘Institutional Environments, Work Trade Unions and the Crisis of Democracy: Strategies
and Human Resource Practices, and Unions: Canada and Perspectives. Manchester: Manchester University
vs. England,’ unpublished manuscript, the University Press.
of Manitoba. Hurd, Richard and McElwain, Adrienne (1988) ‘Orga-
Godard, John (2006b) ‘Institutional Norms, Mobilization nizing Clerical Workers: Determinants of Success.’
Bias and the Decline of the US Labour Movement,’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review 41 (2):
unpublished manuscript, the University of Manitoba. 350–73.
Godard, John (2008). ‘An Institutional Environments Hyman, Richard (2001) Understanding European Trade
Approach to IR?’ In Industrial Relations as an Unionism. London: Sage.
Academic Enterprise: Roads to Revitalization, ed. Hyman, Richard and Brough, Ian (1975) Social Values
Charles Whalen, Northampton MA: Edward Elgar, and Industrial Relations. Oxford: Blackwell.
forthcoming. Jarley, Paul and Fiorito, Jack (1991) ‘Unionism and
Goldfield, Michael (1987) The Decline of Organized Changing Employee Views Toward Work.’ Journal of
Labour in the United States. Chicago: University of Labor Research 12 (3): 223–30.
Chicago Press. Johnson, Susan (2000) The Growth and Decline
Gomez, Rafael, Gunderson, Morley and Meltz, Noah of Unions in Canada and the United States
(2002) ‘Comparing Youth and Adult Desire for Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Economics, McMaster
Unionization in Canada.’ British Journal of Industrial University.
Relations 40 (3): 521–42. Johnson, Susan (2002) ‘Card Check or Mandatory
Gomez, Raphael, Lipset, Seymour Martin and Meltz, Representation Votes? How the Choice of Union
Noah (2001) ‘Frustrated Demand for Unionization: Recognition Procedure Affects Union Certification
The Case of the United States and Canada Success.’ Economic Journal 112 (April): 344–61.
Revisited.’ In Proceedings of the 53rd Annual Johnson, Susan (2004) ‘The Impact of Mandatory Votes
Meeting, Champaign IL: Industrial Relations Research on the Canada-US Density Gap: A Note.’ Industrial
Association. pp. 163–72. Relations 43 (2): 356–63.
Green, Francis (1992) ‘Recent Trends in British Trade Kelly, John (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations.
Union Density: How Much of a Compositional London: Routledge.
Effect?’ British Journal of Industrial Relations 30 (3): Kelloway, Kevin and Watts, Laura (1994) Pre-
445–58. employment Predictors of Union Attitudes: Replication
UNION FORMATION 403

and Extension.’ Journal of Applied Psychology 79 (4): (eds) Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations 13:
631–34. 157–90.
Klandermans, B. (1986) ‘Perceived costs and benefits of Meltz, Noah and Verma, Anil (1996) ‘Beyond Union
participation in union action.’ Personnel Psychology Density: Union Organizing and Certification as
39 (2): 379–97. Indicators of Union Strength in Canada and the
Kochan, T. (1979) ‘How American workers view labor United States.’ Paper presented at the 33rd
unions.’ Monthly Labor Review 102 (4): 23–31. annual meeting of the Canadian Industrial Relations
Kochan, T. (1980) Collective Bargaining and Industrial Association, Brock University, St. Catherines, Ont.,
Relations. Homewood, IL: Irwin. May 29–31.
Kochan, T., McKersie, R. and Chalykoff, J. (1986) Montgomery, B. Ruth (1989) ‘The Influence of Attitudes
‘The Effects of Corporate Strategy and Workplace and Normative Pressures on Voting Decisions in a
Innovations on Union Representation.’ Industrial and Union Certification Election.’ Industrial and Labor
Labor Relations Review 39 (4): 487–501. Relations Review 42 (2): 262–79.
Krahn, Harvey and Lowe, Graham (1984) ‘Public Moore, William and Pearce, D.K. (1976) ‘Union Growth -
Attitudes Towards Unions: Some Canadian Evidence.’ A Test of the Ashenfelter-Pencavel Model.’ Industrial
Journal of Labor Research 5 (2): 149–63. Relations 15 (2): 244–47.
Krasner, Stephen D. (1988) ‘Sovereignty: An Institutional Oxenbridge, Sarah and Brown, William (2004) ’Devel-
Perspective.’ Comparative Political Studies 121 (1): oping Partnership Relationships.’ in Mark Stuart
66–94. and Miguel Martinez Lucio (eds) Partnership and
Lawler, John and West, Robin (1985) ’Impact of Modernization in Employment Relations. London:
Union Avoidance Strategy in Union Representation Routledge.
Elections.’ Industrial Relations 24 (3): 406–20. Oxenbridge, Sarah and Brown, William (2005) ‘Achiev-
Lipset, Seymour Martin and Meltz, Noah (1998) ing a New Equilibrium? The Stability of Cooperative
‘Canadian and American Attitudes Toward Work and Employer-Union Relationships.’ Industrial Relations
Institutions.’ Perspectives on Work 1 (3): 14–19. Journal 35 (5): 388–402.
Locke, Richard and Thelen, Kathleen (1995) ‘Apples and Oxenbridge, Sarah, Brown, William, Deakin, Simon and
Oranges Revisited: Contextualized Comparisons and Pratten, Cliff (2003) ‘Initial Response to the Statutory
the Study of Comparative Labor Politics.’ Politics and Recognition Provisions of the Employment Relations
Society 23 (3): 337–67. Act 1999.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations
Lopez, Steven (2004) Reorganizing the Rust Belt: the 41 (2): 315–34.
Inside Story of the American Labor Movement. Park, Heejoon, McHugh, Patrick and Bodah, Matthew
Berkley, CA: University of California Press. (2006) ‘Revisiting General and Specific Beliefs: the
Lowe, Graham and Raskin, Sandra (2000) ‘Organizing Union Voting Intentions of Professionals.’ Industrial
the Next Generation: Influences on Young Worker Relations 45 (2): 270–89.
Attitudes.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations Peterson, Richard, Lee, Thomas and Finnegan, Barbara
38 (2): 203–22. (1992) ‘Strategies and Tactics in Union Organizing
Maranto, Cheryl and Fiorito, Jack (1987) ‘The Effect Campaigns.’ Industrial Relations 31 (2): 370–82.
of Union Characteristics on the Outcome of NLRB Premack. S. and Hunter, J (1988) ‘Individual unionization
Certification Elections.’ Industrial and Labor Relations decisions.’ Psychological Bulletin 103 (2): 223–34.
Review 40 (2): 225–40. Price, Robert and Bain, George (1983) ‘Union Growth
Martinello, Felice (1996) ‘Correlates of Certifica- in Britain: Retrospect and Prospect.’ British Journal of
tion Application Success in British Columbia, Industrial Relations 21 (1): 46–62.
Saskatchewan, and Manitoba.’ Relations Industrielles Prosten, Richard (1978) ‘The Longest Season: Union
51 (3): 544–62. Organizing in the Last Decade.’ Proceedings of
Martinello, Felice (2000) ‘Mr Harris, Mr Rae and Union the Thirty-First Annual Meetings of the Industrial
Activity in Ontario.’ Canadian Public Policy 26 (1): Relations Research Association (IRRA). Madison:
17–33. IRRA.
Martinello, Felice and Meng, Ronald (1992) ‘Effects Reed, Thomas (1989) ‘Do Union Organizers Matter?
of Labor Legislation and Industry Characteristics on Individual Differences, Campaign Practices, and
Union Coverage in Canada.’ Industrial and Labor Representation Election Outcomes.’ Industrial and
Relations Review 46 (1): 161–75. Labor Relations Review 43 (1) (Oct.): 103–19.
Martinello, Felice and Yates, Charlotte (2004) ‘Union Riddell, C. (2001) ‘Union Suppression and Certification
and Employer Tactics in Ontario Organizing Success.’ Canadian Journal of Economics 34 (2):
Campaigns.’ In David Lewin and Bruce Kaufman 396–410.
404 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Riddell, Chris (2004) ‘Union Certification Success Under Industrial and Labor Relations Review 47 (2):
Voting Versus Card-Check Procedures: Evidence from 207–26.
British Columbia, 1978–1998.’ Industrial and Labor Thomason, Terry and Pozzebon, Sylvana (1998)
Relations Review 57 (4): 493–517. ‘Managerial Opposition to Union Certification in
Riley, Nicola-Maria (1997) ‘Determinants of Union Quebec and Ontario.’ Relations Industrielles 53 (4):
Membership: A Review.’ Labor 11 (2): 265–301. 750–71.
Robinson, James (1988) ‘Workplace Hazards and Troy, Leo (2000) ‘U.S. and Canadian Industrial Relations:
Workers’ Desires for Union Representation.’ Journal Convergent or Divergent?’ Industrial Relations
of Labor Research 9 (3): 237–49. 39 (4)(December): 695–713.
Rose, Joseph and Chaison, G. (1996) ‘Linking Union van de Vall, Mark (1970) Labor Organizations.
Density and Union Effectiveness: The North American Cambridge: the University Press.
Experience.’ Industrial Relations 35 (1): 78–105. Visser, Jelle (2002) ‘Why Fewer Workers Join Unions in
Rudy, Preston (2004) ‘Justice for Janitors,’ Not Europe: A Social Custom Explanation.’ British Journal
‘Compensation for Custodians’: The Political Context of Industrial Relations 40 (3): 403–30.
and Organizing in San Jose and Sacramento’ in Voos, Paula (1983) ‘Union Organizing: Costs and
Ruth Milkman and Kim Voss (eds), Rebuilding Labor. Benefits.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review
Ithaca: Cornell University. pp. 133–50. 36: 576–91.
Salancik, G. and Pfeffer, J. (1977) ‘An Examination Voos, Paula (1984) ‘Does it Pay to Organize? Estimating
of Need-Satisfaction Models of Job Attitudes.’ the Costs to Unions.’ Monthly Labor Review
Administrative Science Quarterly 22 (3): 427–56. 107 (June): 43–44.
Schnabel, Claus (2003) ‘Determinants of Trade Union Voss, Kim and Sherman, Rachel (2000) ‘Breaking the
Membership.’ in John T. Addison and Claus Schnabel Iron Law of Oligarchy: Union Revitalization in the
(eds) International Handbook of Trade Unions. American Labor Movement.’ American Journal of
Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Sociology 106 (2): 303–49.
Schur, Lisa, and Kruse, Doug (1992) ‘Gender Differences Waddington, J. and Whitston, C. (1997) ‘Why do
in Attitudes Towards Unions.’ Industrial and Labor People Join Unions in a Period of Membership
Relations Review 46 (1): 89–103. Decline?’ British Journal of Industrial Relations 35 (4):
Scott, Clyde, Seers Anson and Culpepper, Robert (1996) 515–46.
‘Determinants of Union Election Outcomes in the Waldinger, R., Erikson, C., Milkman, R., Mitchell, D.,
Non-Hospital Health Care Industry.’ Journal of Labor Valenzuela, A. and Zeitlin, M. (1998) ‘Helots no More.
Research 17 (4): 701–15. A Case Study of the Justice for Janitors Campaign
Sharpe, Ian G. (1971) ‘The Growth of Australian Trade in Los Angeles.’ In K. Bronfenbrenner, S. Friedman,
Unions: 1907–1969.’ Journal of Industrial Relations R. Hurd, R. Oswald, and R. Seeber (eds), Organizing
13 (June): 144–53. to Win: New Research on Union Strategies. Ithaca,
Sherman, Rachel and Voss, Kim (2000) ‘Breaking the NY: ILR Press. pp. 102–19.
Iron Law of Oligarchy: Union Revitalization in the Wall Street Journal, April 25, 1991, A16, cited in Sexton,
American Labor Movement.’ American Journal of Patricia, The War on Labor and the Left. Boulder:
Sociology 106 (2): 303–49. Westview Press.
Slinn, Sarah (2004) ‘The Effects of Compulsory Weikle, Roger, Wheeler, Hoyt and McClendon, John
Certification Votes on Certification Applications in (1998) ‘A Comparative Case Study of Union
Ontario: An Empirical Analysis.’ Canadian Labor and Organizing Success and Failure: Implications for a
Employment Law Journal 11: 259–99. Practical Strategy.’ In K. Bronfenbrenner, S. Friedman,
Stepina, Lee P. and Fiorito, Jack (1986) ‘Toward a R. Hurd, R. Oswald, and R. Seeber (eds), Organizing
Comprehensive Theory of Union Growth and Decline.’ to Win: New Research on Union Strategies. Ithaca,
Industrial Relations 25 (3): 248–64. NY: ILR Press.
Summers, Timothy P., Betton, John H. and Decotiis, Weiler, Paul (1984) ‘Striking a New Balance: Freedom of
Thomas A. (1986) ‘Voting for and Against Unions: Contract and the Prospects for Union Representation.’
A Decision Model.’ Academy of Management Review Harvard Law Review 98 (2): 351–420.
11 (3): 643–55. Weiler, Paul (1983) ‘Promises to Keep: Securing
Swidinsky, R. (1974) ‘Trade Union Growth in Workers’ Rights to Self-Organization Under the
Canada: 1911-1970.’ Relations Industrielles 29 (3): NLRA.’ Harvard Law Review 96 (8): 1769–1827.
435–49. Western, Bruce (1997) Between Class and Market:
Thomason, Terry (1994) ‘The Effect of Accelerated Certi- Postwar Unionization in the Capitalist Democracies.
fication Procedures on Union Organizing Campaigns.’ Princeton: Princeton University Press.
UNION FORMATION 405

Wheeler, Hoyt and McClendon, John (1991) ‘The Yager, D.V., Bartl, T.J. and LoBue, J.J. (1998) Employee
Individual Decision to Unionize.’ In George Strauss, Free Choice: It’s Not in the Cards. Washington, D.C.:
Dan Gallagher, and Jack Fiorito (eds) The State of the Labor Policy Association.
Unions. Madison: IRRA. Youngblood, S., DeNisi, A., Molleston, J. and Mob-
Wood, Stephen and Godard, John (1999) ‘The Statutory ley, W. (1984) ‘The impact of work environment,
Recognition Procedure in the Employee Relations instrumentality beliefs, perceived labor union image,
Bill: A Comparative Perspective.’ British Journal of and subjective norms on union voting intentions.’
Industrial Relations 37 (2): 203–45. Academy of Management Journal 27 (3): 576–90.
Wood, Stephen and Machin, Steve (2005) ‘Human Zalesny, Mary D. (1985) ‘Comparison of Economic
Resource Management as a Substitute for Trade and Non-economic Factors in Predicting Faculty
Unions in British Workplaces.’ Industrial and Labor Vote Preference in a Union Representation Election.’
Relations Review 58 (2): 201–19. Journal of Applied Psychology 7(2): 243–56.
21
The Changing Structure of
Collective Bargaining
Robert J. Flanagan

The relative bargaining power that labor and by technology and the organization of
management bring to the table is influenced production. The aspirations of these work
by both the structure of collective bargaining groups define a union’s objectives, but the
negotiations and specific bargaining tactics, as groups themselves often lack the power to
conditioned by the prevailing economic and conduct effective bargaining. As a result,
political environment. This chapter focuses on informal work groups generally combine
the determinants and effects of collective bar- to establish broader negotiating units and
gaining structure, which varies enormously those are the chief concern of this chapter.
around the world. After defining collective Negotiating units typically conduct collective
bargaining structure, the chapter explains bargaining and are bound by the terms of the
how structure influences relative bargaining resulting agreement. In Canada and the US,
power, discusses evidence on the impact of where union membership is normally decided
bargaining structure on microeconomic and by union representation elections, casual
macroeconomic outcomes, and interprets the observers sometimes confuse the election
evolution of bargaining structures over time. unit – the group of workers eligible to vote
Of particular interest is whether increased eco- in union representation elections – with the
nomic integration is producing a convergence negotiating unit. Election units also may
of bargaining structures around the world. include several informal work groups in
plants or companies, but they are usually
smaller than the negotiating unit when there
THE CONCEPT OF BARGAINING are industry wide or multi-plant collective
STRUCTURE bargaining agreements. Once an agreement
has been negotiated, contract extension proce-
Bargaining structures originate in the informal dures or emulation by other firms or industries
work groups of union members defined may produce a unit of direct impact that
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 407

exceeds the scope of the negotiating unit well as the bargaining level. There is a
(Weber, 1967). Indeed, in most countries, the further complication: Seemingly centralized
number of workers covered by a collective bargaining systems usually include significant
agreement exceeds the number of union elements of decentralized determination of
members. The gap between coverage and working conditions. These points receive
union membership is particularly large in more attention later in the chapter.
several continental European countries with Bargaining structure is sometimes confused
contact extension laws or procedures (OECD, with the much vaguer concept of corporatism.
2004). Concerns that the economic impact of Corporatism, in its many definitions, pertains
collective bargaining might spread beyond the to institutional arrangements and negotiating
negotiating unit have also stimulated an active processes that facilitate bargaining between
literature, reviewed later in the chapter, on the labor, management, and the government
relationship between bargaining structure and over economic policies and pay settle-
macroeconomic performance. ments that may support them. Centralized
Collective bargaining occurs in an impres- bargaining levels are one component of
sive variety of negotiating units around the corporatist institutional arrangements, which
world, but three concepts summarize the dis- may account for the confusion of terms.
tinctions in bargaining level that have proved But the concept of bargaining structure
most important for analyzing how bargaining excludes the government and focuses on
structure may influence bargaining outcomes. labor-management negotiations.
In decentralized collective bargaining struc-
tures (most common in North America, Japan,
Korea, New Zealand, and the UK), most DETERMINANTS OF BARGAINING
negotiations occur between employer and STRUCTURE
employee representatives in a company or
plant. Intermediate level collective bargaining Viewing the institutional differences as ‘his-
between industry wide unions and employ- torical accidents’ begs the question of what
ers’ associations historically was the domi- determines bargaining structure. Why the
nant bargaining arrangement in continental ubiquitous institution of collective bargaining
Europe. These negotiations established a floor should acquire so many different forms merits
under working conditions within an industry. more research attention than it has received.
Centralized collective bargaining, common Most institutions have some rational basis
at times in Scandinavian countries, involves at the time of their development, although
negotiations between national labor and they may become less suitable as economic
employer federations to establish nationwide and political conditions change over time.
working conditions. Much of this chapter con- Institutions may reflect social preferences and
cerns how these distinctions in the bargaining underlying cultural norms, for example. In
level influence the relative power that labor a rare effort to consider influences on bar-
and management bring to the bargaining table. gaining arrangements, Teulings and Hartog
Detecting the effective collective bargain- (1998, Chapter 3) examined how indices
ing structure can be a subtle business, requir- of corporatism, the concept that includes
ing careful distinctions between the form but is broader than bargaining structure,
and substance of bargaining arrangements. varied with measures of national cultures
In some countries, seemingly decentralized developed by Hofstede (1980).1 They find
bargaining may be so highly coordinated that corporatist arrangements, which include
that one or two key negotiations effectively relatively centralized collective bargaining
determine the contract terms agreed to in structures, appear more often in societies that
other negotiations. Understanding bargaining place high value on equality and the quality of
structure therefore requires an assessment life. This link between cultural attributes and
of the degree of bargaining coordination as collective institutions is consistent with the
408 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

positive correlation between more centralized BARGAINING STRUCTURE AND


bargaining systems and pay equality that will BARGAINING POWER
be discussed later in this chapter.
Economic and legal influences supplement Bargaining power is the ability to strike or
cultural predispositions. The balance between take a strike. Most unions wish to raise
domestic and international competition can the real wage of their members without
be an important economic influence on a reducing membership employment; hence the
country’s bargaining structure. When compe- attraction of bargaining structures that pro-
tition is mainly domestic, broader bargaining duce an inelastic demand for the services of
structures that take the wage out of com- union members. Attaining that goal amounts
petition offer advantages to both employers to developing bargaining arrangements that
and unions, as discussed more fully in limit (1) the ability of producers to substi-
the next section. For many years follow- tute other inputs for the services of union
ing WWII, industry wide and centralized members and (2) the ability of consumers to
bargaining – the most common bargaining purchase cheaper substitutes for the goods
arrangements – coexisted with relatively high, or services provided by union labor. For
albeit declining, barriers to international trade. most employers, the short-run ability to take
Later sections of this chapter describe and a strike varies inversely with the ability
interpret a considerable decentralization of of customers to shift (perhaps permanently)
collective bargaining that has occurred in to similar products or services produced
many countries since 1980, however. The by other companies. Looking to the long-
spread of international competition in product run consequences of a collective bargaining
markets appears to be an important element in agreement, the employer’s willingness to take
this development. a strike will also depend on whether non-
Two aspects of the legal environment of union competition (or unionized competition
collective bargaining condition bargaining from abroad) is likely to enter the market and
structure. Laws governing the determination undercut the company’s prices.
of union membership and the conduct of The earliest analytical contribution to
collective bargaining provide one influence. the debate over the relationship between
Legal systems in which union membership is bargaining structure and power in labor
usually determined by union representation negotiations isolated the key role of the
elections at the place of employment (as in elasticity of demand for the services of
the US and Canada) encourage comparatively union members. The most powerful unions
decentralized bargaining, for the representa- face inelastic labor demand curves and
tion elections tend to be held at the company or incur small employment losses from their
plant level. More subtle, and ultimately more negotiated wage increases. Drawing on Alfred
important, are laws or policies that protect or Marshall’s (1923: 518–38) famous conditions
provide opportunities for union rents on an for inelastic labor demand,2 Milton Friedman
industry or national basis. Regulatory policies (1951) argued that only craft unions – unions
in which prices to consumers are marked that organized workers with a particular
up a certain amount over costs provide a skill – could have significant bargaining
common example. By establishing a pricing power. Friedman noted that unions of craft
rule that permits all producers in an industry workers gain power because (a) it is difficult
to pass through costs, such regulatory policies to substitute for their services and (b) they
facilitate the formation and maintenance of constitute a small percent of total costs (so
industry bargaining units. Later in this chapter, that their wage increases have little impact
we shall see how changes in both types of on prices and sales). In contrast, he argued
legislation contributed to the decentralization that industrial unions of dominantly unskilled
of collective bargaining structures in the late labor, such as those that emerged in the auto
twentieth century. and steel industries in the US during the
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 409

Great Depression, could never have much alternative bargaining structures. The sensi-
impact because they lacked these advantages. tivity of the employment of union members
Presumably, the same reasoning would apply to changes in their compensation influenced
to general unions. future reasoning and research into the relative
Lloyd Ulman (1955) countered that the merits of plant, multiplant, company, and
application of labor demand elasticities in industry wage agreements. As a rough rule of
fact led to rather different conclusions when thumb, the demand for union labor becomes
the institutional features of some unionized less elastic as the level of bargaining increases.
labor markets were fully considered. Noting Without clarity about the specific product and
the rigid relative wage relationships between labor markets in which negotiations occur,
many craft unions in the construction and however, it is difficult to reach definitive
printing trades, Ulman noted that patterns conclusions about the effects of a particular
of wage emulation among crafts meant that bargaining structure on the relative power
a seemingly small wage negotiation could of labor and management. Moreover, the
ultimately have a large impact on labor costs goals of the bargaining participants regarding
as other craft unions subsequently insisted the scope of the labor agreement and the
on similar wage increases. Moreover, the importance of wage equality or other distri-
‘importance of being unimportant’ (a small butional objectives may influence bargaining
percent of total costs) only holds when structures.
consumers can shift purchases from products Company bargaining illustrates many of
made by union labor more easily than these points. Bargaining with a particular
producers can substitute for union labor in employer (and at the individual plants of
production. an employer) characterizes decentralized col-
Industrial unions may create less elastic lective bargaining systems. The appeal of
demand for their members’ services when company bargaining will vary with the com-
they limit the scope for consumer substitution pany’s market environment. In competitive
by organizing all producers in a particular industries, companies are in a weak position
industry. When all domestic producers of a during a strike. Product demand is highly
product or service are subject to the same elastic, since consumers can easily shift
labor agreement, consumers effectively have their purchases to other companies producing
no (domestic) place to go to escape price identical products or very close substitutes.
increases that may follow union wage nego- The possibly permanent loss of business to
tiations. Bargaining structures that effectively other firms is less threatening to the union,
reduce the elasticity of product demand also because members who lose their jobs can
suit employers’ interests; labor agreements find jobs at the firms that captured the
negotiated in those structures are less likely company’s business. Industry employment
to produce a loss of customers. Industrial will change little. These aspects of company
unions may also limit the scope for producer bargaining provide employers in competitive
substitution when they broaden bargaining industries with strong incentives to strengthen
structures to encompass producers of capital their position by seeking multi-employer
goods or other potential substitutes for union bargaining units. Historically, many multi-
labor. In short, the choice of bargaining employer bargaining structures have emerged
structure can have a large influence on the in competitive industries even in countries
relative bargaining power of employers and with comparatively decentralized bargaining
unions. structures.
Beyond the specifics of the debate about Single employer bargaining units have been
craft vs. industrial union power, the exchange more common in oligopolistic product mar-
between Friedman and Ulman elevated the kets, which offer less scope for substitution by
elasticity of labor demand to a central role consumers. Employers nonetheless remain in
in future discussions of the consequences of a relatively uncomfortable economic position.
410 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

On the one hand, they do not want to Historically, European employers generally
risk a permanent loss of market share to supported multi-employer bargaining units,
rivals by taking a strike alone. On the which effectively took the wage out of
other, an expensive contract that avoids a competition and guaranteed that key com-
strike may expose them to the same risk. petitors would also be shut down in the
The incentives to develop multiemployer event of a strike. While such formal multi-
bargaining arrangements remain strong. employer bargaining arrangements exist in
Countering these general economic forces some competitive unionized industries in
is the fact that bargaining at the plant North America, a variant known as ‘pattern
or company level permits negotiators to bargaining’dominated oligopolistic industries
address a wide range of company- or plant- for many years. Under pattern bargaining, a
specific issues that would be ignored in more union first negotiated with a target company
centralized bargaining. Many non-monetary and then negotiated substantially similar
aspects of work life that influence a company’s agreements with other companies in the
productive efficiency and workers’ job sat- industry. Multi-employer contracts are also
isfaction are unique to specific workplaces. less constraining than company contracts.
Issues surrounding the introduction of new Faced with member companies who vary in
technology, changes in the organization of their efficiency and needs, multi-employer
work, the pace of production and job safety negotiations often produce contracts whose
vary substantially across companies and terms permit the least efficient firms to remain
plants, and centralized bargaining systems are solvent. Comparatively efficient companies
poorly suited to address the variety of conflicts may earn higher profits or pay higher wages
that emerge over these issues. While raising than the contract requires. For both sides,
the time devoted to negotiations, company broad units offer economies of scale in
bargaining permits joint resolution of many negotiations.
issues that influence the long-run viability Multi-employer bargaining effectively cre-
of a firm. Company- and plant-specific ates a bilateral monopoly in the relevant
efficiency issues become more important as labor market. The outcome of such bar-
industries encounter greater product market gaining is theoretically indeterminate, resting
competition, for they govern the wages that on the relative bargaining skill of labor
a viable company can pay. The demand for and management. Whether multi-employer
decentralized bargaining arrangements should bargaining associations use their market
increase with the necessity of plant level power to resist union bargaining demands
solutions to workplace problems. or to accept them and pass the higher costs
Multi-employer bargaining holds appeal on to consumers is an empirical question.
for both unions and employers. Including Several studies indicate that relative to single
all employers in the same negotiating unit employer bargaining, wages tend to be higher
reduces the elasticity of demand for labor under multi-employer bargaining in local
by effectively reducing the opportunity for product markets (Hendricks and Kahn, 1984;
consumers to shift to less costly producers Hendricks, 1975).
in the event of wage and price increases. Centralized bargaining occurs in a few
A given increase in compensation should countries between nationwide labor and
produce smaller employment losses for union employer federations. The nationwide scope
members in multi-employer negotiating units of such negotiations has a number of
than company units. Moreover, ‘[T]o have immediate consequences. The elasticity of
a common front throughout an industry also labor demand is even lower, since labor
accords with the unionist’s desire for solidar- agreements in principle cover all domestic
ity, and his sense that it is only fair to have substitutes. Nationwide collective bargaining
one and the same rate for the job wherever is particularly well suited for pursuing greater
it is done.’ (Phelps Brown, 1962, p.170) wage equality, and empirical analyses report
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 411

a robust negative cross-country correlation of bargaining, and there is a certain, regular


between bargaining level and wage dispersion tendency for the decentralized implementa-
(OECD, 2004). Greater equality emerges tion to exceed the centralized intention. Wage
from central negotiations that restrain the drift has two main consequences in centralized
bargaining power of the most powerful unions bargaining systems. First, it adds uncertainty
(that typically represent high-wage workers), to the evolution of earnings. Second, it
while providing extra wage payments to low- tends to reverse the greater wage equality
wage workers. Sweden’s postwar ‘solidaristic that these systems try to establish in formal
wage policy’ provides a clear illustration centralized negotiations. Work groups whose
of how centralized bargaining can increase bargaining power is effectively restrained
wage equality, and the internal tensions such in central negotiations try to reassert their
policies can create. power during the implementation process.
More broadly, centralized collective bar- The most convincing evidence indicates that
gaining inevitably produces contracts that this effort is only partially successful; wage
address fewer issues than decentralized col- drift unwinds some, but not all, of the
lective bargaining. (See previous discussion greater pay equality established in central
of company bargaining.) Negotiations must negotiations (Hibbs and Locking, 1996).
focus on issues that are common to the Finally, nationwide negotiations produce
workplaces covered by an agreement. If macroeconomic concerns that are discussed
company bargaining can address a wide more fully in the following section. Such
array of compensation, health and safety, negotiations have the potential to produce
and work rule issues that are unique to inflation or (under fixed exchange rate
an organization, nationwide bargaining must systems) balance of payments disequilibria,
limit itself to issues shared by most work- unless they are conducted with attention
places. This largely limits bargaining to to a country’s macroeconomic scope for
changes in compensation and work hours. non-inflationary pay increases. Union and
In short, centralized contracts cannot address employer negotiators must either internal-
workplace-specific issues that may be of great ize the macroeconomic concerns in their
concern to workers. Effectively, centralized negotiating processes and outcomes or risk
bargaining raises the demand for additional government intervention to restrain the full
levels of bargaining, and officially or unoffi- utilization of the power implicit in centralized
cially, multiple tiers of bargaining typically bargaining. Over the years, examples of both
emerge in centralized bargaining systems. private restraint and government intervention
(Multiple bargaining levels also can emerge to protect macroeconomic objectives can
in industry bargaining. In Germany, works be found in nations practicing centralized
councils, which are legally mandated to limit bargaining.
their negotiations to issues not addressed in To summarize, a country’s bargaining struc-
industry collective bargaining negotiations, ture reflects the outcome of several distinct
provide an example.) forces. Because the level of bargaining influ-
As a result, centralized labor agreements ences the elasticity of demand for the services
provide a less reliable evolution of earnings of union labor, bargaining structure is a prime
than labor agreements under decentralized determinant of power in collective bargaining.
bargaining. ‘Wage drift,’ the tendency for As such, bargaining structure is vulnerable to
actual earnings to increase more rapidly than economic developments – notably changes in
negotiated wage rates reflects a variety of product market competition – that alter the
forces. Companies are free to pay more than power implied by a given level of bargaining.
the negotiated increase and some do in order The economic environment also influences
to improve their recruiting prospects. On the bargaining structure through its influence on
union side, the centrally negotiated wage the range of issues that collective bargaining
increase is often implemented in lower levels must address. Centralized structures can only
412 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

address a short list of issues common to increase in the prices of the goods and
all participating units. When non-monetary services produced by that company, there
issues involving the organization or restruc- will be little impact on the real wage
turing of work and production processes gains of union members. The company’s
become paramount, decentralized bargaining price increase has a small impact on the
becomes more important. These topics grow national price level, and union negotiators
in importance with increased product market can safely ignore that effect. Nationwide
competition. collective bargaining negotiations produce
Second, legal influences on both the a very different calculus. Compensation
conduct of collective bargaining and its increases in excess of productivity growth
economic environment influence the level at will now produce increases in the overall
which bargaining can be sustained. Finally, price level that limit the real wage gains
bargaining structure may reflect a society’s that workers obtain from negotiations. With
cultural attributes and particularly its goals union negotiators facing stronger incentives
regarding equality. As a public good, greater to limit wage pressure in nationwide negoti-
equality must be delivered by broad bargain- ations, countries with centralized bargaining
ing structures or by government action. arguably should have less inflation. In fact,
this ‘internationalization’ hypothesis predicts
that inflation and some other measures of
MACROECONOMIC OUTCOMES AND macroeconomic performance should improve
BARGAINING STRUCTURE with the level of bargaining.
Of course, one must also consider the
Governments periodically express concern relationship between bargaining structure and
with the potential macroeconomic conse- bargaining power discussed earlier in this
quences of collective bargaining. In industrial chapter. With the incorporation of bargaining
countries, such concerns have sometimes power considerations, an inverted U-shaped
produced public policy efforts to restrain the relationship between macroeconomic perfor-
advance of negotiated wages through the mance and bargaining structure emerges. That
implementation of various forms of incomes is, intermediate level (industry wide) bar-
policy. Most reviews of such policies express gaining provides the worst macroeconomic
doubts about their long-term effectiveness performance (Calmfors and Driffill, 1988).
(Ulman and Flanagan, 1971; Flanagan et al., Other analysts have stressed the importance
1983). A notable feature of the incomes policy of bargaining coordination, however, noting
approach is that it takes collective bargaining that some seemingly decentralized bargaining
institutions as given. systems, such as Japan’s, actually have
In contrast, a significant theoretical and highly coordinated bargaining, because a few
empirical literature (reviewed in Calmfors, key settlements set the pattern for most
1993; Flanagan, 1999, 2003 and Boeri negotiations.
et al., 2001) examines the links between These predictions emerge from analyses
macroeconomic outcomes and the details of of completely unionized, closed economies
national industrial relations systems. Promi- in which employers maximize profits and
nent among these details are the level unions are concerned with both the real wage
and degree of coordination of collective levels and employment of their members.
bargaining. Several important ideas inform Shifting to open economies or economies
this literature. with a significant non-union sector compli-
Bargaining structure influences incentives cates the analyses and alters the predicted
for union negotiators to internalize the relationship between bargaining structure and
external (third-party) effects of negotiated macroeconomic outcomes. With significant
wage pressures. If wage increases negotiated imports or a large non-union sector, the
by a union with a company result in an relationship between bargaining structure and
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 413

economic performance weakens and may structure include indicators of both the level
disappear. Centralized negotiators now face of bargaining and the degree of bargaining
weaker incentives to restrain wage demands coordination.
because overall consumer price increases The earlier discussion of centralized col-
(which include the prices of imports and lective bargaining structures indicated the
domestic goods and services produce by non- second difficulty. Formally centralized bar-
union labor) will be smaller than the price gaining systems usually have several levels
increases of products made with union labor. of negotiations – sometimes over similar
That is, the real wage of union workers will issues, sometimes over different issues. The
increase because overall prices increase less same may be said of ‘tripartite’ negotia-
rapidly than wages. tions, invariably centralized, in which the
Empirical analyses of these hypotheses government enters discussions with labor and
must rely on a rather limited database con- management in an effort to limit the maximum
sisting of industrialized countries during the compensation increase that emerges from
last third of the twentieth century. Institutions collective bargaining (Katz et al., 2004).
change infrequently within countries, so most Tripartite bargaining typically emerges to
of the variation in bargaining arrangements confront particular ‘emergencies’ such as
comes from differences between 15–20 preventing or limiting inflation or meeting
countries. The possibilities for sharp tests the requirements for entry into the European
are thus limited, and empirical findings Union.
have proven to be rather fragile. It seems One finds examples of a variety of
likely that further progress in delineating bargaining structures among the OECD club
the relationship between bargaining arrange- of mainly industrialized countries during
ments and macroeconomic outcomes will the last three decades of the twentieth
rest on more careful consideration of how century (Table 21.1). At one extreme is
interactions between the level of bargaining the predominantly company and plant level
and the economic and political environments bargaining in North America, Japan, Korea,
of collective bargaining interact to influence and (in later decades) New Zealand and the
bargaining power. UK. At the other extreme, Finland, Norway,
and (in earlier decades) Sweden have had
predominantly centralized agreements. For
MEASUREMENT OF BARGAINING much of the twentieth century, there was no
STRUCTURE tendency for these structures to converge to a
single institutional form. Countries coexisted
Most efforts to characterize country’s bargain- with a variety of bargaining structure. Much
ing structures empirically utilize the levels the same may be said about the degree of
of bargaining distinctions described in the bargaining coordination (Table 21.2).
previous section. Two difficulties confront Table 21.1 also shows a tendency for this
such efforts. Some bargaining systems that stability to give way in several countries
appear decentralized in form may be more beginning in the 1980s and carrying forward
centralized in substance if most settlements into the early years of the twenty-first
closely emulate the outcome of one or century. Looking across columns, one sees
a few key negotiations. Japan provides a clear evidence of decentralization over the
key example of such ‘pattern following’ or thirty-year period. Denmark, Portugal, Spain,
coordinated bargaining. Although the formal and Sweden began the period with cen-
structure of bargaining includes thousands of tralized agreements but entered the twenty-
company negotiating units, in practice a few first century with predominantly industry
key settlements define the outcome of the level bargaining. Other countries (Australia,
Shunto each spring. In an effort to address New Zealand, and the UK) moved from a vari-
this issue, some descriptions of bargaining ety of intermediate level bargaining structures
Table 21.1 Bargaining structures in OECD countries, 1970–2000
1970–1974 1975–1979 1980–1984 1985–1989 1990–1994 1995–2000
Australia 4 4 4 4 2 2
Austria 3 3 3 3 3 3
Belgium 4 3.5 3 3 3 3
Canada 1 1 1 1 1 1
Denmark 5 5 3 3 3 2
Finland 5 5 4 5 5 5
France 2 2 2 2 2 2
Germany 3 3 3 3 3 3
Ireland 4 4 1 2.5 4 4
Italy 2 2 3.5 2 2 2
Japan 1 1 1 1 1 1
Korea 1 1 1 1 1 1
Netherlands 3 3 3 3 3 3
New Zealand 3 3 3 3 1 1
Norway 4.5 4.5 3.5 4.5 4.5 4.5
Portugal 5 4 3 3 4 4
Spain 5 4 4 3.5 3 3
Sweden 5 5 4.5 3 3 3
Switzerland 3 3 3 3 2 2
UK 2 2 1 1 1 1
US 1 1 1 1 1 1
1 = Company and plant level bargaining predominant.
2 = Combination of industry and company/plant bargaining.
3 = Industry level bargaining predominant.
4 = Industry bargaining with recurrent central agreements.
5 = Central bargaining predominant.
Source: OECD 2004 p. 151.

Table 21.2 Bargaining coordination in OECD countries, 1970–2000


1970–1974 1975–1979 1980–1984 1985–1989 1990–1994 1995–2000
Australia 4 4 4.5 4 2 2
Austria 5 5 4.5 4 4 4
Belgium 4 3.5 4 4 4 4.5
Canada 1 3 1 1 1 1
Denmark 5 5 3 4 3 4
Finland 5 5 4 5 5 5
France 2 2 2 2 2 2
Germany 4 4 4 4 4 4
Ireland 4 4 1 2.5 4 4
Italy 2 2 3.5 2 3 4
Japan 4 4 4 4 4 4
Korea 1 1 1 1 1 1
Netherlands 3 4 4.5 4 4 4
New Zealand 4 4 4 4 1 1
Norway 4.5 4.5 3.5 4.5 4.5 4.5
Portugal 5 4 3 3 4 4
Spain 5 4 4 3.5 3 3
Sweden 4 4 3.5 3 3 3
Switzerland 4 4 4 4 4 4
UK 3 1 1 1 1 1
US 1 1 1 1 1 1
1 = Company and plant level bargaining predominant.
2 = Combination of industry and company/plant bargaining.
3 = Industry level bargaining predominant.
4 = Industry bargaining with recurrent central agreements.
5 = Central bargaining predominant.
Source: OECD 2004 p. 151.
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 415

closer to company and plant bargaining. appropriate frame of reference. The interwar
Even the apparent stability of official indus- period saw a general retreat from international
try bargaining in some countries obscures economic integration with increased levels of
decentralizing tendencies. Employer partici- trade protection that insulated many domestic
pation industry wide bargaining arrangements product markets from significant import com-
declined in Germany (Thelen, 1998), and petition. Postwar trade negotiations under the
company level bargaining expanded in Italy: auspices of the General Agreement for Tariffs
and Trade (GATT) and its successor, the
There has been a more or less strong tendency
towards decentralization of collective bargaining World Trade Organization (WTO), produced a
in almost all countries that still have a dom- sequence of reductions in tariff and non-tariff
inance of intersectoral or sectoral bargaining. barriers to international trade that increased
In many countries, such as Austria, Denmark, the exposure of most product markets to
Finland, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway
foreign competition. This development was
or Sweden, the higher-level agreements have
widened the scope for additional bargaining at particularly strong in industrialized countries,
company level and/or have introduced opening where tariff rates were lowest and where there
clauses that allow companies to diverge from were no special provisions to facilitate the
certain collectively agreed standards. Following this development of ‘infant industries.’ (At the
process of organized or controlled decentralization,
same time, most industrial countries retained
many countries have seen the emergence of rather
differentiated and flexible multi-level bargaining restrictions on permanent international migra-
systems (EIRO, 2005). tion that had arisen in the late nineteenth and
early twentieth centuries.)
Also not reflected in the tables is the The industry wide bargaining structures
decentralization implied by the continuing that protected firms from domestic labor
decline in union density in most industrialized cost competition also left entire industries
countries. For countries without contract vulnerable to foreign competition. As foreign
extension procedures, this trend signals a fur- companies captured domestic market shares,
ther shift toward non-union pay determination many domestic companies now found the
of working conditions through the human wage floors of industry bargaining a com-
resource management policies and practices petitive hindrance and sought discounts from
of individual companies. Finally, no country’s the industry wage or other company-specific
collective bargaining structure became more solutions.
centralized during this period. What accounts Changes in the regulation of labor rela-
for the growing decentralization of bargaining tions and the economic regulation of some
in the last third of the twentieth century? industries provided an additional force for
What are the likely consequences of this decentralization in several countries (Katz,
development? 1993). After almost a century of collective
bargaining in an environment of compulsory
arbitration awards, Australia (in workplace
THE DECENTRALIZATION OF reform statutes in 1988, 1993, and 1996) and
COLLECTIVE BARGAINING New Zealand (with the 1991 Employment
STRUCTURES Contracts Act) fundamentally revised their
labor laws in ways that encouraged more
Collective bargaining structures weaken as decentralized collective bargaining. In the
economic, political, and legal developments US and some European countries, the
limit a union’s span of control over the deregulation of transportation, communica-
relevant product market. Thus far, the dis- tions, and other industries with competitive
cussion of bargaining structure pertains to market structures provided another force
control of domestic product markets, and for for decentralization. Deregulation reduced
the period from the onset of WWI to the barriers to entry and removed common
immediate post-WWII period, this was the regulated prices that had facilitated industry
416 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

wide and even national bargaining structures. longer to produce fewer achievements than
Increased domestic competition challenged in earlier decades. Globalization’s critics
the maintenance of such high labor cost notwithstanding, a reversal of the post-WWII
arrangements and led many employers to seek trend toward greater international economic
company level bargaining. Moreover, in some integration seems unlikely. Much the same
countries many new entrants were able to may be said of national efforts to deregulate
remain non-union. some industries. The economic conditions
Increased pay dispersion is the most visible that support relatively centralized bargaining
consequence of the decentralization of collec- arrangements are increasingly rare.
tive bargaining. In fact, the decentralization of Future interactions between the legal
pay determination in the late twentieth century environment and bargaining structure are
actually exceeded the decentralization of bar- less predictable. To some extent, legal rules
gaining, given the decline in union representa- follow economic necessity, a pattern that
tion that accompanied the decentralization of would predict more of the same. Even so,
bargaining in many countries. The growth of political changes raise the odds of at least
the non-union sector effectively decentralizes partial reversals in the legal environment, as
pay determination decisions to the company evidenced by changes in labor legislation in
level. Yet, not all aspects of decentralization the UK in the late 1990s. What bargaining
produce greater pay dispersion. A diminishing structure responses to the future economic and
difference between average union and non- legal environment might be expected?
union wages should counter some of the
increased pay dispersion among individual
workers. On balance, dispersion increases, TRANSNATIONAL BARGAINING
however. Whether the increased pay disper- STRUCTURES
sion associated with decentralized collective
bargaining provides stronger incentives for The apparent connection between increased
skill acquisition and production efficiency international trade and decentralization of col-
remains an important unresolved research lective bargaining in industrialized countries
question. Other consequences of decentral- seems puzzling in historical perspective.
ized bargaining are less visible to the public. Faced with expanding product and labor
The earlier discussion noted the necessar- markets and the rise of multi-plant firms
ily limited scope of centralized collective within countries in the late nineteenth and
bargaining agreements. Increasing decen- early twentieth centuries, many local labor
tralization of collective bargaining permits unions formed national organizations to coor-
consideration of many non-monetary issues dinate and implement similar labor standards
that concern workers and employers but are across the relevant market areas and all units
not sufficiently general to be addressed in of a company. Whether by the development
more central negotiations. Decentralization of industry wide bargaining structures or the
may produce labor agreements of greater coordination of multiple local negotiations,
scope. the national unions sought to thwart the
incentive for employers to whipsaw unions
with high-wage contracts by threatening to
THE FUTURE OF BARGAINING move business to low-wage areas of the
STRUCTURE country.
In the face of expanding international
Looking forward, economic pressures for product and labor markets, the development
decentralized bargaining are likely to con- of transnational collective bargaining – the co-
tinue for the foreseeable future, albeit at ordination of collective bargaining demands
an abated pace. International negotiations among workers in the same industry but
to reduce trade barriers continue but take in different countries – would continue
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 417

and extend this historical defensive tactic. latter countries understand that transnational
Many difficulties confront such an extension bargaining has the potential to protect jobs
of traditional union tactics to international in rich countries at the expense of jobs in
markets, however, and after some 40 years poor countries. Unions in the rich countries
of experimentation, transnational bargaining have little to offer in return. Even if unions
structures have failed to produce the durable moved beyond the lack of reciprocity, the
coordination of contract terms associated with choice of international contract standards
national industry level bargaining. remains more challenging than the task of
Two considerations motivate labor unions choosing contract standards within a country.
to form transnational bargaining structures. Wage differences around the world are
In the short-run, unions that bargain with huge in comparison to differentials within
many multinational companies worry that a country. Moreover, international wage
the companies will shift production to plants differentials rest on equally large international
in other countries. In principle, unions in productivity differentials. Productivity levels
any country may share the concern that in poor countries do not match the pay
multinationals are better able to take a standards of rich countries, so that any effort
strike by shifting their production beyond to establish the latter through transnational
the jurisdiction of any particular national bargaining would reverse the flow of jobs and
union. Unions in high-wage countries have diminish employment opportunities in poor
the further long-run interest in preventing the countries. Transnational bargaining structures
permanent reallocation of jobs to countries offer the same risks to countries with a
with lower labor costs per unit of output. comparative advantage in low-wage labor as
In principle, transnational collective bar- international labor standards, and unions in
gaining structures could reduce the elasticity poor countries are understandably wary of
of demand for the services of a multina- such proposals.
tional’s workers in a country by limiting Recognizing this stance, unions in some
the scope for substitution of production to rich countries, notably the United States,
other countries. While a few instances of have abandoned serious efforts to develop
strikes to resist production shifting have transnational collective bargaining structures
been recorded, coordinating labor resistance and instead have either opposed free trade
across national boundaries encounters much agreements or insisted on the inclusion of
more resistance than coordination within a labor clauses committing the signatories to
country. National labor movements differ enforce and improve their national labor laws.
significantly in their objectives. The single- A bargaining strategy for unions in high-wage
minded focus on economic objectives so countries would be to facilitate productivity
common in North American unions seems improvements that (at least) offset their
almost unique in international perspective, relative wage. The decentralization of many
for example. On other continents, competing collective bargaining structures provides an
labor movements have their roots in political improved setting for lowering unit labor costs
or religious beliefs that broaden the scope through productivity deals rather than wage
of their activity and limit their inclination to concessions.
support unions with different, more narrowly
focused goals. There are definite limits to
international solidarity. CONCLUSIONS
Transnational co-operation to prevent job
reallocation seems even less likely. A lack This chapter has reviewed the determinants
of opportunity for reciprocity presents one and impacts of collective bargaining structure
significant problem. Potential job losses and offered interpretations of the widespread,
flow in one direction – from high-wage to if not unanimous, decentralization of bar-
low-wage countries. Labor unions in the gaining structures that occurred beginning
418 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in the 1980s. The focus has been on devel- the employment of union members, divided by the
opments in the private sector of industrialized percent change in the union wage. Given the tradeoff
nations, a choice mainly dictated by available between the wage and employment levels described
by labor demand curves, labor demand elasticities
evidence. The growing literature on collective are typically negative. As later refined by John Hicks
labor action in developing countries has not (1966:241–47), the demand for the services of any
yet isolated the nature and role of bargaining group of union workers is more inelastic when (1) it is
structures, and the applicability of the analysis easy to substitute other inputs, such as capital, for
of the relationship between bargaining power the union workers, (2) efforts to use substitutes for
union labor do not provoke large increases in the
and the level of negotiations discussed in price of the substitute inputs, (3) union labor is a
this chapter to labor markets dominated small percent of total costs, and (4) the price elasticity
by agriculture and informal sectors remains of the product that labor produces is low (meaning
uncertain. that most consumers lack acceptable substitutes for
Two analytical themes pervade this chapter. the product or service produced by union labor).
Where these conditions exist, union bargaining power
Most importantly, distinguishing between the is relatively high.
form and substance of collective bargaining
structure remains crucial for understand-
ing the outcomes of collective bargaining.
Descriptions of average bargaining level REFERENCES
rarely capture the bargaining reality in a
country. The second key theme pertains to Boeri, Tito, Brugiavini, Agar and Calmfors, Lars (eds)
the variety of bargaining structures that have (2001) The Role of Unions in the Twenty-First Century.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
survived in the world. Until recently, the
Calmfors, Lars and Driffill, John (1988) ‘Bargaining struc-
historical record has not indicated an inter-
ture, corporatism and macroeconomic performance’,
national convergence of bargaining structures Economic Policy, 3: 13–61.
that might be expected if one institutional Calmfors, Lars (1993) ‘Centralization of wage bar-
arrangement were unambiguously superior. gaining and macroeconomic performance: A survey’,
This chapter has tried to indicate why no OECD Economic Studies, 21: 161–191.
bargaining structure offers a free lunch for EIRO (2005) ‘Changes in national collective bargaining
all issues. Each offers different strengths and systems since 1990.’ http://www.eiro.eurofound.ie/
weaknesses. To the extent that the decentral- 2005/03/study/tn0503102s.html (accessed July 25,
ization that began in the late twentieth century 2005).
signals a convergence, it will be because Flanagan, Robert J. (1999) ‘Macroeconomic per-
formance and collective bargaining’, Journal of
countries increasingly face a common set
Economic Literature, 37 (3): 1150–75.
of problems in labor markets and seek the
Flanagan, Robert J. (2003) ‘Collective bargaining and
institutional arrangement that best addresses macroeconomic performance‘, in J. T. Addison and
those problems. C. Schnabel (eds) International Handbook of Trade
Unions. Northampton, MA: Elgar. pp. 172–96.
Flanagan, Robert J., Soskice, David W. and Ulman,
NOTES Lloyd (1983) Unionism, Economic Stabilization and
Incomes Policies: European Experience. Washington:
1 In Hofstede’s parlance, ‘masculine’ societies Brookings Institution.
emphasize achievement over the quality of life; Friedman, Milton (1951) ‘Some comments on the
societies with high ‘power distance’ tolerate sig- economic significance of labor unions for economic
nificant inequality in society; ‘individualistic’ soci- policy’, in David McCord Wright (ed) The Impact of
eties prefer individual over collective activity; and the Union. New York: Harcourt Brace. pp. 204–35.
societies with high ‘uncertainty avoidance’ have a
Hendricks, Wallace E. (1975) ‘Labor market structure
low tolerance for risk. Updated values of national
cultural norms are available at: http://www.geert-
and union wage levels’, Economic Inquiry, 13 (3):
hofstede.com/index.shtml 401–16.
2 The labor demand elasticity, a measure of the Hendricks, Wallace E. and Kahn, Lawrence M. (1984)
responsiveness of the demand for union labor to ‘The demand for labor market structure’, Journal of
a change in its wage, is the percent change in Labor Economics, 2 (3): 412–38.
THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 419

Hibbs, Douglas A. and Locking, Håkan (1996) ‘Wage Teulings, Coen and Hartog, Joop (1998) Corporatism
compression, wage drift and wage inflation in or Competition? An International Comparison of
Sweden’, Journal of Labor Economics, 3 (2): 109–41. Labor Market Structures and Their Impact on Wage
Hicks, John R. (1966) The Theory of Wages. 2nd edn Formation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
New York: St. Martins Press. Thelen, Kathleen (1998) ‘Why German employers cannot
Hofstede, Geert H. (1980) Culture’s Consequences: bring themselves to abandon the German Model’,
International Differences in Work-related Values. in Torben Iversen, Jonas Pontusson, and David
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications. Soskice (eds) Unions, Employers, and Central Banks:
Katz, Harry C. (1993) ‘The decentralization of collective Wage Bargaining and Macroeconomic Policy in an
bargaining: A literature review and comparative Integrating Europe. Ann Arbor: U. Michigan Press.
analysis’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Ulman, Lloyd (1955) ‘Marshall and Friedman on union
47 (1): 3–22. strength’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 37 (4):
Katz, Harry C. , Lee, Wonduck and Lee, Joohee (eds) 384–401.
(2004) The New Structure of Labor : Tripartism and Ulman, Lloyd and Flanagan, Robert J. (1971) Wage
Decentralization. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Restraint: A Study of Incomes Policies in Western
Marshall, Alfred (1923) Principles of Economics. 8th edn. Europe. Berkeley: University of California Press.
London: Macmillan. Weber, Arnold R. (1967) ‘Stability and change in the
OECD (2004) Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. structure of collective bargaining’, in Lloyd Ulman
Phelps Brown, E. H. (1962) The Economics of Labor. (ed) Challenges to Collective Bargaining. Englewood
New Haven: Yale University Press. Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. pp. 13–36.
22
The High Performance
Work Systems Literature in
Industrial Relations
Ann C. Frost

Over the last decade and a half, the high of high performance work systems research
performance work system literature has has engendered a number of fair critiques.
become a major stream of interest in the Is it redirecting attention away from more
field of industrial relations (IR). Whether important things to be studied in IR? Does
the new system of work organization is this research come from a unitarist perspective
called high involvement, transformed, mutual and has it taken on a managerialist tone?
gains, or high commitment, this body of Are the prescriptive findings of this research
work has generated much attention – both good for workers? For unions? Are the largely
by researchers engaged in studying high American-based findings generalizable to the
performance workplace practices and by the rest of the world and to other industrial
parties themselves in trying to understand relations systems?
how to implement the new forms of work There is little argument that the high
organization that are seen to be the way performance work systems literature has been
out of their competitive difficulties. The well-developed and considerable learning
attention devoted to high performance work about ‘what works at work’1 has emerged as
practices has sparked a renaissance and a result. We know much about the conditions
brought vibrancy to the field of IR, a field that enable high performance forms of work
whose traditional focus of attention – unions organization in many organizations. We also
and collective bargaining – have seen a great know something about the outcomes of
diminution in both numbers and relevance such work organization choices and sup-
over this same time period. porting human resource practices not only
However, this stream of literature has for firms, but also for workers and their
not been without its controversy. The field unions.
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 421

What has become clear though more small firms, flexibly deployable technology,
recently is that the scenario of ‘mutual gains’ and multi-skilled artisanal workers, flexible
(Kochan and Osterman, 1994) is not at all specialization would be able to produce small
as widespread as much of the early work lots of high quality, niche goods as mass
in this stream argued. The high performance markets fragmented and economic conditions
work system paradigm is not always the became more unstable. In particular, the use
light shining at the end of the tunnel to take of labor appeared quite distinct in contrast
the parties into workplace and competitive to the traditional use of labor under mass
nirvana. A much more critical view of the high production. Workers were highly skilled,
performance paradigm has emerged. In some often worked in autonomous teams, and
cases, so-called high performance practices engaged in decentralized decision making on
are in fact ‘mean’or coercive in nature, used to the job.
retaylorize the workplace and exert increased Kochan et al., (1986) similarly documented
control over workers and take power and changes taking place in American industry
control away from their unions. Over time, a in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Not only
more tempered view of the high performance did they witness the breakdown in American
workplace and high performance practices manufacturing hegemony, but they recorded
has emerged. We have become much more the changes management was leading in
muted in our assessments of the good that such adjusting its workforce and manufacturing
systems at work can deliver. practices to compete in the new environment.
In this chapter, I review the high perfor- In part, what was new about what Kochan et al.
mance work systems literature, tracing in a observed was that workplace changes were
largely chronological way, the emergence and now managerially driven, seeking to change
development of this stream of work. In the the post war labor accord – in contrast to the
chapter I also highlight the development of findings of much of the industrial relations
the critique of the mainstream of this literature research in the 1950s and 1960s in which
and argue here that the critique has served union demands drove changes in employment
to strengthen this literature rather than to practices.
have detracted from it. I conclude the chapter Kochan et al. documented some of the
with an overall assessment of this stream of earliest attempts at simplifying union collec-
literature and its contribution to the larger field tive agreements, moving to team forms of
of IR research. work organization, tying pay to performance
outcomes, and implementing cross training
and job rotation at firms such as General
LITERATURE REVIEW PART I – THE Motors, Xerox, TRW, and Corning. The
GENESIS AND EARLY KEY PIECES authors also highlighted the positive outcomes
that accrued to the parties who were able to
Two books published in the mid-1980s laid the make the transition successfully.
foundation upon which the subsequent high Kochan and Osterman (1994) in The
performance work systems literature would Mutual Gains Enterprise argued that the
be laid: Piore and Sabel’s (1984) The Second emerging high performance model should
Industrial Divide and Kochan et al.’s (1986) become the standard new paradigm along
The Transformation of American Industrial whose lines organizations ought to be
Relations. Piore and Sabel (1984) argued that designed and work ought to be organized.
the dominance of mass production was being Kochan and Osterman (1994) argued that
severely challenged by a series of changes in through this model all parties stood to gain –
the macro political economy. In its place, a firms to prosper and workers to enjoy better,
new form of organization they termed ‘flexi- more satisfying and secure work. Unions, too,
ble specialization’ would become dominant. would enjoy higher levels of influence in the
Characterized by decentralized networks of workplace and face a more secure future under
422 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

this system. The mutual gains enterprise the MacDuffie (1995) argued that particular
authors described was ‘win-win’. human resource practices in isolation did not
From the understanding provided by Piore lead to better performance. Rather, only by
and Sabel (1984) about why things on the shop ‘bundling’ groups of mutually reinforcing and
floor had to change, the evidence provided complementary practices together did man-
by Kochan et al. (1986) that such changes ufacturers see the benefits to outcomes. The
were happening in the US and arguments notion of ‘bundling’ becomes a mainstay of
from Kochan and Osterman (1994) for the the high performance work systems literature.
positive outcomes to accrue to the parties as Ichniowski et al.’s (1997)2 evidence on
a result, research began in earnest to learn productivity in steel finishing lines solidified
more about the phenomenon. In particular, the ‘bundling’ argument. Their work, using
researchers were eager to move beyond a sample of 36 homogeneous steel finishing
single case studies, to compile more con- lines, found that lines employing a bundle
vincing statistical evidence that such changes of innovative human resource practices (such
in work organization and human resource as incentive pay, teams, broadly defined
practices could make such a difference to and flexible job assignments, high levels of
performance outcomes. For the most part, training, and job security) had substantially
this early statistically oriented work was higher levels of productivity than did lines
highly concentrated in heavy manufacturing: employing more traditional practices (such as
autos and steel primarily. In part this was narrowly defined jobs, strict work rules, close
driven by the fact that both industries found supervision, and hourly pay) (Ichniowski
themselves in competitive crises during the et al., 1997).
1980s and 1990s, putting great pressure on Arthur (1992) found similar results in the
these industries to restructure and to reor- mini-mill sector of the US steel industry.
ganize. As well, both were highly unionized Arthur (1992) linked mini-mill strategy to
industries making these workplaces attractive human resource strategy and found that
to industrial relations researchers. Finally, those mills which adopted a flexible man-
and not inconsequentially, both industries ufacturing strategy combined with human
had inputs and outcomes that were easily resource practices that encouraged decentral-
measured. ized decision making by shopfloor workers,
The work from MIT’s International Motor employee participation in problem solving
Vehicle Program (IMVP) led to the pub- initiatives, and that provided general training
lication of The Machine that Changed the outperformed their more traditional Taylorist,
World (Womack et al., 1990), the work in mass production oriented counterparts.
which the contours of lean production were Huselid (1995), with careful econometric
described and the mechanisms by which analysis, provided compelling evidence from
they served to increase productivity and a sample of 1000 US firms that manag-
quality (and thereby overall competitiveness) ing workers with high performance human
in the automotive industry were laid out. resource practices including comprehensive
MacDuffie and Krafcik (1992) began to recruitment and selection procedures, contin-
spell out the human resource practices side gent compensation, and extensive employee
of the equation by specifying how human involvement and training positively impacted
resources had to be used in conjunction firm performance as measured by corporate
with technology to enable high performance financial performance, employee turnover,
manufacturing. MacDuffie (1995) developed and productivity. Moreover, the effect size
the human resource side of the high perfor- he found was substantial: a one-standard
mance manufacturing paradigm even further deviation increase in his index of high
in his later work in the automotive industry. performance HR practices was associated
Using survey evidence drawn from 62 IMVP- with US$27,044 more in sales/employee,
affiliated assembly plants around the world, US$18,641 more in market value/employee,
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 423

and US$3,814 more in profit/employee. This two or more practices at the 50 per cent level of
survey-based research examined firms of penetration. In 1997, the figure had increased
all sizes in a wide range of industries, to 38.3 per cent. In this paper Osterman also
helping to broaden the high performance work investigated whether or not high performance
system literature beyond autos and steel and work practices were able to deliver ‘mutual
manufacturing in general. gains’ to both labor and management. He
Huselid’s (1995) work capped off much of found that establishments that had adopted
the early anecdotal and case-based evidence high performance practices in 1992 had a
that high performance models of work higher probability of layoffs in subsequent
organization and supporting HR practices years and experienced no gain in real wages
had a real and significant impact on firm over that period (Osterman, 2000). Thus, no
performance. So, if these models were so real evidence emerged of mutual gains.
clearly superior, how widespread was the
adoption of these practices in the broader
US economy? Osterman (1994) sought to DEVELOPMENTS IN THE STREAM
answer this question, using data from 694 US
manufacturing establishments he surveyed in Much of the early work in the high per-
1992. Focusing on what he termed the ‘core formance work systems literature focused
workforce’ – employees doing the main work on outcomes for employers in terms of
of producing the firm’s good or service – improved productivity, quality, and lower
Osterman (1994) examined the incidence of costs. Eventually interest emerged as to what
the adoption of teams, job rotation, quality these new models of work organization looked
circles, and total quality management as well like for workers, how unions effected their
as the human resource practices supporting efficacy, and their generalizability outside of
these new work models. manufacturing.
Osterman (1994) found surprisingly
widespread adoption of these practices at a
The impact on workers
superficial level – if a given practice was
adopted by any core employees. Over half An early and comprehensive review of the
of the survey respondents reported the use high performance work systems and work-
of teams and roughly one third reported place transformation literature by Appelbaum
using Total Quality Management (TQM) and Batt (1994) argued that two distinct
techniques (Osterman, 1994). However, models of transformed workplaces were
requiring at least half of all core workers to be emerging in the US. One form, American
engaged in the practice before it was counted Lean Production, focused on quality and
dropped the adoption rate by 15 percentage customer service and the re-engineering of
points (Osterman, 1994). What is also notable work processes to ensure deliverables. The
from Osterman’s work is that the practices other model was American Team Production,
were not being adopted in bundles. Rather, characterized by the use of self-directed work
employers appeared to be adopting single teams, total quality management techniques,
practices. Only 16 per cent of establishments pay for performance, and labor-management
surveyed reported having one HR practice partnership (Appelbaum and Batt, 1994). Best
in each of the four major HR areas (flexible practice cases of lean production tended to
job design, contingent pay, training, and be found in non-union settings, while best
employment security) (Ichniowski et al., practice cases of team production appeared in
1996). unionized workplaces.
Osterman repeated his survey in 1997 and Performance effects of the two systems
found that the practices continued to diffuse appeared, from the empirical evidence, to be
over the five-year interval (Osterman, 2000). comparable. Outcomes for workers, however,
In 1992, 24.6 per cent of establishments had appeared to be different. Work organized
424 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

around team forms of work organization Hodson (1996) assessed new models of
provides more opportunities for employees to work organization in terms of their effect on
exercise discretion on the job and involves worker dignity. Participative forms of work
all workers in such activities. In contrast, organization, such as those found under high
under the lean production model, only a select performance work systems, found workers
number of chosen workers left the production working harder, but provided with greater
floor to participate in off-line problem solving. dignity on the job. Workers experienced
Often, conflict emerged between those who greater pride and job satisfaction, things
left and those who were left behind to ‘do the that were diminished under earlier forms
work’ (Appelbaum and Batt, 1994). of work organization that were monitored
Appelbaum et al. (2000), in their study of through direct supervision, or paced by
new models of work organization in steel, assembly-line technology, or governed by
apparel, and medical electronic and imaging bureaucratic forms of organization (Hodson,
instruments, investigated five outcomes of 1996). However, the earliest model of work
interest to workers: trust in their employer, organization, that of craft production, still
the intrinsic reward afforded by their work, provided the highest levels of dignity at work
organizational commitment, job satisfaction, in Hodson’s (1996) assessment.
and work-related stress. In all three indus- Generally, the evidence on the impact of
tries, the authors found generally that high high performance work practices on workers
performance models of work organization appears fairly positive – as long as the worker
enhanced levels of worker trust of their retains his or her job. Black et al. (2004) found
employer, the intrinsic reward they received that the implementation of high performance
from their jobs, organizational commitment, workplace practices, in particular the use of
job satisfaction, and lowered levels of work- teams, was associated with greater reductions
related stress (Appelbaum et al., 2000). Using in employment. In contrast, the implementa-
data from the same study, Bailey et al. (2001) tion of job rotation practices were associated
found high performance work practices to with lower employment reductions. Of course
be positively associated with higher worker the job losses may have been even larger if
wages in the steel and apparel industries. work organization had not been transformed;
In medical electronics and imaging, the pos- the counterfactual is not known.
itive association disappeared when a control
for education was added suggesting that there
The effects of unions
is a strong link between formal education
and high performance work systems in that What about the effects that unions have
industry (Baily et al., 2001). on the implementation of high performance
Batt (2004) found that workers organized work systems? Early research in this stream
into self-managed teams in a large union- indicated that most innovations occurred in
ized telecommunications company reported non-union settings (Kochan et al., 1986).
significantly higher levels of perceived dis- Later work determined that, in fact, work
cretion, employment security, and satisfaction innovations were taking place equally across
on the job. In contrast, participation in off- both union and non-union sectors (Eaton and
line problem solving teams had no statistically Voos, 1994).
significant effect on outcomes for workers in Much of the initial literature was interested
this study (Batt, 2004). Quit rates are another in whether unions could be considered
indicator of worker satisfaction on the job. a barrier to successful implementation or
Batt (2002) found quit rates were lower for call whether they were supportive and useful
centre workers in workplaces that emphasized in creating sustainable workplace changes.
high skills, organized workers into teams, and On the one hand, some argued that only with
enabled workers to participate in workplace- the discipline forced upon management by a
related decisions. union would a firm be able to satisfactorily
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 425

implement the changes in work organization proactive. Only in the latter case did mutually
and supporting human resource practices that beneficial outcomes emerge for the parties.
a high performance work system demanded The empirical evidence is somewhat
(Kochan et al., 1986; Eaton and Voos, 1994). mixed. Osterman (1997) found no association
Eaton and Voos (1994) pointed out that unions between the adoption of high performance
helped support new forms of work organiza- work practices and the presence of unions. In
tion because they are able to protect workers contrast, work by Bacon and Blyton (2000) in
from job loss due to any resulting productivity the UK found that managers were less likely
improvements or from management reprisal; to introduce team forms of work organization
unions are able to provide workers with voice where trade unions were present. And, in
so their concerns are also addressed in any contrast to the ‘mutual gains’ perspective
workplace undertakings so that outcomes are (Kochan and Osterman, 1994), Bacon and
likely to be better balanced; and unions are Blyton (2000) reported that more conflict with
able to extend the reach of high performance unions appeared in the unionized enterprises
work system to a strategic level enabling the where team forms of work organization had
union voice to be heard at levels well beyond been introduced.
the shop floor. McNabb and Whitfield (1997), using data
On the other hand, others argued that from the 3rd Workplace Industrial Relations
union resistance to the proposed changes of a Survey and the Employer Manpower Skills
high performance work system would render Practices Survey in the UK, reported variation
the process impracticable. Either through even among unionized facilities. They found
blocking the changes outright, or by ignoring that the presence of a closed shop hindered
the program and waiting for it to die due to lack the adoption of flexible work practices, but
of uptake, unions were viewed as antithetical the presence of a union that management
to the successful implementation of a high recognized (but that did not have a closed
performance work system. Others still have shop) facilitated the introduction of high per-
taken a more nuanced view arguing that it formance practices (McNabb and Whitfield,
depended on the union and its relationship 1997). Moreover, Cooke (1994) found from
with management whether the presence of a a survey of 841 manufacturing firms in
union would facilitate or inhibit the adoption Michigan that the performance benefits of
of a high performance work system (Eaton and high performance work systems in unionized
Voos, 1989; Frost, 2000). plants were higher than those found in non-
Eaton and Voos (1989) identified a number union firms.
of union responses to the implementation
of high performance work practices: block
Generalizability to industries
and destroy; let the program proceed but not
outside of manufacturing
be involved with it; protective involvement
meaning that the union seeks to maintain A great deal of the initial work in the
existing collective bargaining institutions high performance work system literature was
without having the new work system impinge conducted in manufacturing – in auto, in steel,
upon this area of the labor-management and in manufacturing generally. The contours
relationship; and finally, use the joint work of what comprised a high performance work
around the implementation of the new work system emerged largely from these initial
system to advance the interests of workers empirical investigations. The components that
and the union. Similarly, Frost (2001) moved eventually came to be agreed upon were some
beyond the militant/co-operative dichotomy form of job expansion (enlargement, enrich-
in describing union positions vis a vis the ment, and often job rotation), skill enhance-
move to a high performance work system ment (multi-skilling and skill upgrading),
to conceptualize and describe three distinct worker participation in workplace decision-
union responses: apathetic, reactive, and making, the use of self-organized teams, and
426 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

off-line problem solving of production-related problem solving groups) in conjunction with


problems (Wells, 1998). The set of supporting IT that supported sales efforts was associ-
human resource practices consisted of pay ated with higher wage levels for customer
for performance, some form of employment service representatives in bank branches. In
security, rigorous selection criteria, improved contrast, where IT was used to automate
communication between labor and manage- processes and there were no high involvement
ment, and a means of consultation between work practices, wages of customer service
labor and management over workplace issues. representatives were lower.
A great deal of evidence was amassed In all three examples cited above, the
describing systems such as the ideal type workers possessed fairly high levels of skill
described above in a range of manufacturing and in both the telecommunications examples,
settings. But what about beyond that? Were the workforces were unionized. In contrast,
there forms of high performance work systems Berg and Frost (2005) look for the existence of
in services, or in low-skilled occupations, or a high performance model in low skill services
in the public sector? If so, what did they look by exploring changes in work organization
like? made to the jobs of food service workers,
Batt (1999) was an early investigator housekeepers, and nursing assistants in US
of the high performance model outside of hospitals. These workers are at or near the
manufacturing, investigating the model and its bottom of the US wage distribution. Turnover
effects in telecommunications services. She rates for these workers approach 100 per cent
investigated the effects of total quality man- in some hospitals. The work they do is
agement and team forms of work organization perceived to be low skilled and they are
for sales and customer service agents and deemed to be virtually disposable.
found that team forms of work organization In the late 1990s, on the recommendation
improved both reported service quality as well of consultants, several hospitals adopted
as increased sales per employee. TQM, in a Patient Care Associate (PCA) form of
contrast, had no effect on performance (Batt, work organization that combined the nursing
1999). Worker participation in off-line prob- assistant, food service, and housekeeping
lem solving groups and self-directed work roles. These PCAs were multi-skilled, worked
teams also lowered quit rates in her sample as part of the patient care team, were afforded
of call centre workers (Batt et al., 2002). small wage increases, and were asked to
Hutchinson et al. (2000) studied the participate in unit meetings and problem
implementation of a high performance work solving teams in their work areas.
system in a UK call centre. They, too, found For the most part, these experiments were
that the implementation lowered quit rates a failure. Patients did not like the multi-
and absenteeism, while producing higher skilled nature of the job (the person cleaning
quality customer service, greater customer the toilet was the same person delivering
retention, and lower costs. The high perfor- lunch); nurses had little time to appropriately
mance work system in this instance involved supervise the cleaning aspect of the PCA
the move to 10–15 member teams, a new role, and the PCAs themselves often did
pay-for-performance system, more sophisti- not have the requisite level of social skills
cated recruiting and selection procedures, an to interact with the patients and rest of
increase in training expenditures, and worker the nursing team in ways that added value.
involvement in quality improvements at the Moreover, workers in these broadened jobs
workplace. reported more job-related stress and lower
Hunter and Lafkas (2003) studied work levels of job satisfaction – in contrast to
practices and their effects on wages and the much of the earlier high performance work
use of technology in the US banking industry. system research in which workers reported
The use of high performance models of work better outcomes being associated with the
organization (specifically the use of off-line enhanced jobs (c.f. Appelbaum et al., 2000).
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 427

Instead, the more successful model in this about such employee-focused activities as
setting appeared to be much more traditional: quality circles and self-managed teams being
narrowly defined functional jobs in which used by management as a union substitute and
the incumbent was adequately trained, in the means by which to develop a company
which pay was provided at a living wage union. Very often, the move to implement a
level, and in which workers were provided high performance work system in a unionized
enough resources (supplies, help, and time) to environment was seen as the first step in erad-
complete their work competently (Berg and icating the union. First, the union would be
Frost, 2005). marginalized in the workplace as management
Once outside of manufacturing, the high dealt directly with workers, bypassing the
performance work systems literature becomes union to negotiate new terms and conditions
more mixed in its assessment of how of employment. Second, workers would soon
‘good’ high performance models of work adopt the same inward focus on outcomes
organization are – both for firms and for of primary concern to management such as
workers. Although from much of the earliest profit and productivity. Thus, union solidarity
manufacturing-based research, it appeared across workplaces would be left in ruins as
that the adoption of high performance models workers and workplaces would be pitted one
of work organization and the necessary against another in a race for the bottom.
supporting HR practices were a singularly (Parker and Slaughter, 1988). Empirically,
good way for firms (and unions where Pulignano (2002) drew on evidence from
present) to assure their success in the now the British and Italian auto industries, to
more competitive landscape, once researchers argue that new high performance forms of
looked beyond manufacturing, the vision work organization and the accompanying
became much less clear. Not only was it less management strategies to support them, led
clear what the high performance model looked to the marginalization of the union and its
like outside manufacturing, but it was also influence in the workplace.
less clear that the model was indeed good for The high performance workplace was also
workers. implemented in a number of non-union
settings – in particular in the automotive
industry in the Japanese transplants. These
THE CRITIQUES EMERGE studies highlighted the potential downsides
to workers from the implementation of the
Critiques of the high performance work system. Graham (1995) wrote of her expe-
systems literature first emerged from studies riences as a participant observer employed
conducted in the automotive industry studying as an Associate at Subaru-Isuzu, a non-
the implementation of the lean production union Japanese transplant built in Lafayette,
system and charting workers’ experiences Indiana. While there she documented her
under it. Research of this kind took place in experiences and those of her co-workers under
both union and non-union settings. In union lean production and Japanese management.
settings, much of the initial concern was In particular, she sought to address the debate
in regard to the effects of the new work concerning the nature of lean production.
system on the union as an effective institution Was it, on the one hand, a factory utopia
for representing workers’ interests – both in which the Japanese model will create a
narrowly in the workplace and more broadly harmonious system of collaboration between
in society as a whole. management and workers in which workers
Early fears in the American labor move- willingly expand their responsibilities and
ment saw many unions refusing to participate increase their work loads by rotating jobs and
in the negotiation and implementation of the revealing their hidden knowledge about work
high performance workplace. There is a long processes; in exchange for their collaboration
history of distrust in the US, in particular, they get job security and more challenging
428 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

work (Graham, 1995: 131). Or, on the other any reunification of mental and manual
hand, as labor process theorists claimed, was labor, or that multi-tasking required any
it nothing more than an extension of Fordism more skill than did work in a traditional
(Dohse et al., 1985)? plant (most jobs still were quickly learned
Graham (1985) found that the Subaru- and remained mind-numbingly repetitive).
Isuzu experience was something else. It Work in a lean production plant was ardu-
certainly was not a factory utopia. Graham ous and intense given the lean staffing
(1985) documented numerous repetitive strain ratios and an insatiable demand for over-
injuries, constant peer pressure to keep up and time.
to continue to work injured, the insecurity Both Graham (1995) and the CAMI
maintained through the use of a significant research team (Rinehart et al., 1997) noted
number of temporary workers, and the bitter the important role played by teams in
reality associated with input to workplace a lean production plant. But, both noted
decisions and process improvements (it was that teams were not needed for technical
non-existent). reasons; their role lay in their social function.
At Subaru-Isuzu there was no union Barker (1999) described and documented
to represent workers or to bargain with this phenomenon in great detail. Barker
management over the implementation of the (1999) studied the implementation of teams
system. Perhaps the negative aspects of lean in a non-union manufacturing plant. His
production in that case could be attributed work described the increasingly coercive
to Subaru-Isuzu’s non-union status. Research nature of peer monitoring and control exerted
examining lean production in a unionized by team members on one another. Barker
setting could assess whether this was the documented how workers in self-managed
case. Work by Rinehart et al. (1997) carefully teams developed a set of normative, value-
documented the experiences of workers at based rules that controlled members’behavior
CAMI, the Suzuki-GM joint venture located more closely and completely than did the
in Ingersoll, Ontario and organized by the former bureaucratic control system.
Canadian Auto Workers union (CAW). Concertive control did not free the workers
The research team conducted one-week from the iron cage of rational control.
visits to the plant every six months for Instead, the concertive system, as it became
nearly two years (early 1990 through late manifest in this case, appeared to draw
1991). In addition, they conducted surveys the iron cage tighter and to constrain the
of workers about their experiences at four organization’s members more powerfully.
specific points in time. They also observed (Barker, 1993: 408).
work throughout the plant and interviewed Lean production is also seen as a means
managers, union leaders, team leaders, and of work intensification. Fairris (2002) linked
skilled trades representatives. On the basis transformed workplaces to worsened levels
of their data, the research team concluded, of health and safety, increased labor effort,
as Graham (1995) had, that lean production and greater worker stress. He argued that the
was not a transcendence of Fordist mass pro- productivity improvements attributed to many
duction. Rather than a committed workforce high performance work systems are in fact due
and harmonious labor-management relations, to the worsened conditions to which workers
the researchers found a low and declining find themselves exposed (Fairris, 2002). In
level of worker commitment over the two- other writing, Fairris and Tohyama (2002)
year time frame and mounting work irritations argued that the lean production model in
that culminated in a five-week strike in Japan is mediated by important institutional
1992 (Rinehart et al., 1997). The authors measures that are missing when the system
found no evidence that worker knowledge is imported to North America. As a result,
under lean production was any greater lean production becomes ‘mean’ in the North
than under mass production, that there was American context, improving productivity
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 429

and quality only through increased worker high performance work systems are being
stress, additional effort, and reduced health implemented.
and safety. Another branch of research in the high per-
Work intensification is also associated with formance work systems stream has explored
high performance models of work organi- the robustness and longevity of these new
zation outside North America. In the UK, forms of work organization and labor-
Green (2004), using establishment level data, management relations. The levels of trust and
argued that technological and organizational co-operation needed to sustain these programs
changes have been important sources of work are significant and make these programs
intensification in Britain in the 1990. Green extremely fragile to maintain. There is
(2004) cited the use of high performance considerable evidence that even the most
models of work organization, in particular, successful programs eventually fail.
as stimulating work intensification. Bryson Early work indicated that this was indeed
et al. (2005) used British data describing the case. Lawler and Mohrman (1985) noted
work organization, trade union representation, that an early workplace innovation, quality
and financial performance. The authors found circles, almost always, after implementation
that high performance models of work and some early successes, eventually declined
organization had a positive effect on labor and disappeared. Preuss and Frost (2003)
productivity, but only in unionized work- charted the rise and decline over almost two
places. In these workplaces, however, the decades of labor-management cooperation
gains appeared to come from accompanying and workplace restructuring in health care in
concessionary bargaining, rather than any Minneapolis/St. Paul. The authors noted the
‘mutual gains’. inability of cooperative structures to adapt
Danford et al. (2004) used case study to new issues and challenges over time
evidence from the aerospace industry in and the eventuality of conflict overwhelming
the United Kingdom to argue that high the cooperation needed to sustain the joint
performance models of work organization initiatives (Preuss and Frost, 2003). Even
and labor-management partnership failed to the highly touted model of co-management
increase worker empowerment and participa- at Saturn, has shown cracks in its shiny
tion. Rather, they found evidence of weaken- exterior. In 1999, the original leadership
ing workplace democracy and a deteriorating of the local union (that had supported and
quality of work life in this setting. implemented the partnership model) was
Other scholars critical of the high perfor- voted out by a two-to-one margin and
mance work system model and its efficacy replaced by a more traditional group of union
have highlighted a number of reasons why leaders seeking to provide union members
it has failed to deliver its promised out- with more conventional union protections
comes in many cases. Godard (2001) argued around scheduling, workload, and guaranteed
that it is not incomplete implementation (rather than partially contingent) pay (Hopp,
or flawed implementation (by not having 2000).
all the appropriate supporting HR practices Despite this evidence from unionized
in place) that causes the variable success settings, Voos and Eaton (1994) argue that
rates noted for high performance models of union supported programs may in fact be
work organization. Rather, he argued using more durable as the union’s presence ensures
data from 78 Canadian workplaces, that workers’ as well as managements’ interests
pre-existing HR conditions and workplace are taken into account and that changes in
context variables are associated with success. work systems are made without detriment to
Similarly, Vallas (2003) found that imple- workers. The prognosis for the longevity of
mentation is difficult because management is high performance work organization models
often not willing to provide the very flexibility in non-union settings would appear even more
being demanded of workers in contexts where dismal.
430 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION that appear especially important include


employment security, extensive investments
In contrast to what some critics have claimed, in training, relatively high pay contingent on
that the focus on high performance work sys- performance, sharing of financial and perfor-
tem models in the field of industrial relations mance information, and selective recruitment
has been misplaced (Godard and Delaney, and selection of personnel into the new work
2000), I believe that the high performance system (Pfeffer, 1998).
literature has been a very valuable area of Third, we also now know that this model
focus in the field. The work, by and large, has is not generalizable across all work settings.
displayed a continued interest in employers, It seems especially suited to manufacturing
in workers, their unions (where they exist), and to skilled, relatively well-paid service
and many authors have addressed issues of occupations. However, in conditions where
policy concern – either policy barriers or pay is low (and is constrained to be low) the
recommendations for policy changes that high performance model appears to have little
would facilitate the transition to a high success. Turnover in these situations is gener-
performance workplace. ally high, making the established work groups
The past nearly two decades worth of that are needed for productive team behaviors
work in the high performance work system and for off-line problem solving exchanges
stream of research has produced a wealth to take place, difficult to maintain. Neither
of knowledge for both industrial relations are workers in these workplaces persuaded
researchers and for practitioners. This has to provide high levels of commitment to the
been, and continues to be, a rich stream. employer – not the levels of commitment
Substantively, we can conclude a number of certainly that engagement in problem solving
things. and to getting the job done right the first time
First, new ways of organizing work in many would require.
cases do have positive performance effects for Finally, we also now know that certain
companies and beneficial effects for work- institutional contexts are more favorable
ers. Team forms of work organization and for the development and sustainability of
the opportunity to participate in workplace such models of work organization. Japan is
decision making and problem solving provide the origin of many of these practices and
several benefits. Giving those closest to the its institutional landscape – which includes
work and who understand it best the authority lifetime employment, enterprise unions, and
to decide how that work gets done and how a long-term investment focus – appears ideal
work-related problems should be resolved to support these high performance models.
makes logical sense. In addition, granting Appelbaum and Batt (1994) and Kochan
additional authority, discretion, and providing and Osterman (1994) all argue that critical
outlets for the use of creativity and problem changes in the American policy landscape are
solving skills on the job often increases necessary to support and diffuse the imple-
the intrinsic reward associated with people’s mentation of high performance models of
work. Often, too, the resulting broadened and work organization throughout the American
upskilled jobs are better paid, contributing as economy. Kochan and Osterman (1994) focus
well to increased levels of extrinsic rewards. their critique on current American labor
Second, successful transformation appears law in which employee committees that
to result from aligning the organization’s discuss workplace-related policies and issues
structure and supporting HR practices with with the employer are deemed illegal –
the new model of work organization. Adopt- a contravention of section 8(a)2 of the
ing bundles of appropriately supportive National Labor Relations Act.Appelbaum and
HR practices appears central to successful Batt (1994) point to the need for publicly
implementation and sustainability of high per- delivered worker training, institutional forms
formance work practices. The HR practices for employee and union participation in firm
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 431

and workplace decision making, a decrease considerable value. Studies in call centres
in the primacy of shareholders compared to in health care, in education, and in new
other firm stakeholders, the construction of media and the arts are all growing and are
interfirm collaboration and cooperation, and emerging, I would argue, in response to
institutional mechanisms by which the low the growing desire to know ‘what works at
wage path can be ruled out. work’ in a broad range of workplaces. This
Similarly, much of the literature critical work has grown directly out of the high
of the high performance workplace stream performance work systems stream. Although
has also added considerable value to and has the research questions are evolving and the
strengthened the industrial relations literature settings are changing, we owe much to the
as a whole. It has brought with it a reminder legacy of this very vibrant and important
to not be solely focused only on performance stream of research in the field of industrial
outcomes of consequence to firms. Later relations.
research in the high performance work
systems stream examined in detail what high
performance models of work organization NOTES
meant for workers and for unions. Researchers
interested in these questions explored the 1 ‘What Works at Work’ is the title of the lead paper
benefits, the downsides, and the conditions in a 1996 special issue of Industrial Relations devoted
under which each occurred for both workers to high performance work systems research and an
and unions. The critical literature also brought assessment of what had been learned from the stream
to date.
with it a healthy dose of cynicism about 2 Although this piece is cited here as 1997 (when
the ‘win-win’ nature of high performance it appears in AER), this same work is often cited with
models of work organization. It became dates ranging from 1993 to 1995 as it passed through
quite clear that all high performance models various stages as a working paper. Its being so often
of work organization were not universally cited in these earlier forms speaks to the paper’s
inherent value being so quickly perceived by those
good for all participants. In many cases, working in the field at the time.
the benefits to employers came at significant
costs to the work force through increased
workloads, additional work-related stress, and
more insecure employment. REFERENCES
So where does this leave us? Has this
Appelbaum, E. and R. Batt. (1994) The New American
stream of work run its course? Have we
Workplace. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
learned all that we can and now find ourselves
Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg, A.
at a point from which we must move on? (2000) Manufacturing Advantage: Why High Per-
The answer, I think, is ‘Perhaps’. We do formance Work Systems Pay Off. Ithaca, NY: ILR
know a lot about high performance models Press.
of work organization and their effects on Arthur, J. (1992) ‘The link between business strategy and
various stakeholders. However, there is still industrial relations systems in American steel mini-
much about the world of work that we do mills’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 45 (3):
not know. The high performance literature has 488–507.
in fact pushed researchers to look past the Bacon, N. and Blyton, P. (2000) ‘Industrial relations
traditional strongholds of industrial relations and the diffusion of teamworking: Survey evidence
from the UK steel industry’, International Journal
research in automobiles, steel, and other
of Operations and Production Management, 20 (8):
heavily unionized manufacturing industries to
911–31.
study non-manufacturing work – in services Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Sandy, C. (2001) ‘The
and the public sector and increasingly in non- effect of high performance work practices on
union settings as well. As a greater portion employee earnings in the steel, apparel, and medical
of the workforce finds itself employed in electronics and imaging industries’, Industrial and
settings such as these, such research is of Labor Relations Review, 54 (2): 525–43.
432 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Barker, J. (1993) ‘Tightening the iron cage: Concertive United States’, Economic and Industrial Democracy,
control in self-managing teams’, Administrative 23 (4): 529–55.
Science Quarterly, 38 (3): 408–38. Frost, A. (2000) ‘Explaining variation in workplace
Barker, J. (1999) The Discipline of Teamwork: Partici- restructuring: The role of local union capabilities’,
pation and Concertive Control. Thousand Oaks, CA: Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 53 (4):
Sage Publications. 559–79.
Batt, R. (1999) ‘Work organization, technology, and Frost, A. (2001) ‘Reconceptualizing local union
performance in customer service and sales’, Industrial responses to workplace restructuring in North
and Labor Relations Review, 52 (4): 539–65. America’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Batt, R. (2002) ‘Managing customer services: Human 39 (4): 539–64.
resource practices, quit rates, and sales growth’, Godard, J. (2001) ‘Beyond the high-performance
Academy of Management Journal, 45 (3): 587–98. paradigm? An analysis of variation in Canadian
Batt, R. (2004) ‘Who benefits from teams? Comparing managerial perceptions of reform programme effec-
workers, Supervisors, and managers’, Industrial tiveness’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Relations, 43 (1): 183–212. 39 (1): 25–52.
Batt, R., Colvin, A. and Keefe, J. (2002) ‘Employee voice, Godard, J. and Delaney, J. (2000) ‘Reflections on
human resource practices, and quit rates: Evidence the ‘high performance’ paradigm’s implications for
from the telecommunications industry’, Industrial and industrial relations as a field’, Industrial and Labor
Labor Relations Review, 55 (4): 573–94. Relations Review, 53 (3): 482–501.
Berg, P. and Frost, A. (2005) ‘Dignity at work for Graham, L. (1995) On the Line at Subaru-Isuzu: The
low wage, low skill service workers’, Relations Japanese Model and the American Worker. Ithaca,
Industrielles, 60 (4): 657–83. NY: ILR Press.
Green, F. (2004) ‘Why has work effort become more
Black, S., Lynch, L. and Krivelyova, A. (2004) ‘How
intense?’, Industrial Relations, 43 (4): 709–42.
workers fare when employers innovate’, Industrial
Hodson, R. (1996) ‘Dignity in the workplace under
Relations, 43 (1): 44–67.
participative management: Alienation and freedom
Bryson, A., Forth, J. and Kirby, S. (2005) ‘High
revisited’, American Sociological Review, 61 (5):
involvement management practices, trade union rep-
719–39.
resentation and workplace performance in Britain’,
Hopp, T. (2000) ‘Saturn workers get standard
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52 (3):
GM-UAW contract’, Labor Notes (online), Feb.
451–91.
http://www.labornotes.org/archives/2000/0200/0200.
Cooke, W. (1994) ‘Employee participation programs,
html#story (accessed August 2, 2006.)
group-based incentives, and company performance: Hunter, L. and Lafkas, J. (2003) ‘Opening the box:
A union-nonunion comparison’, Industrial and Labor Information technology, work practices, and wages’,
Relations Review, 47 (4): 594–610. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 56 (2):
Danford, A., Richardson, M., Stewart, P., Tailby, S. and 224–43.
Upchurch, M. (2004) ‘High performance work systems Huselid, M. (1995) ‘The impact of human resource
and workplace partnership: A case study of aerospace management practices on turnover, productivity,
workers’, New Technology, Work, and Employment, and corporate financial performance’, Academy of
19 (1): 14–29. Management Journal, 38 (3): 535–70.
Dohse, K., Jurgens, U. and Malsch, T. (1985) ‘From Hutchinson, S., Purcell, J. and Kinnie, N. (2000) ‘Evolving
‘Fordism’ to ‘Toyotaism’? The social organization high commitment management and the experience of
of the labor process in the Japanese automobile the RAC call centre’, Human Resource Management
industry’, Politics and Society, 14 (2): 115–46. Journal, 10 (1): 63–79.
Eaton, A. and Voos, P. (1989) ‘The ability of unions Ichniowski, C., Kochan, T., Levine, D., Olson, C.
to adapt to innovative workplace arrangements’, The and Strauss, G. (1996) ‘What works at work:
American Economic Review, 79 (2): 172–77. Overview and assessment’, Industrial Relations,
Eaton, A. and Voos, P. (1994) ‘The survival of employee 35 (3): 299–334.
participation programs in unionized settings’, Indus- Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G. (1997) ‘The
trial and Labor Relations Review, 47 (3): 371–90. effects of human resource management practices on
Fairris, D. (2002) ‘Are transformed workplaces more productivity: A study of steel finishing lines’, American
productively efficient?’, Journal of Economic Issues, Economic Review, 87 (3): 291–313.
36 (3): 659–71. Kochan, T., Katz, H. and McKersie, R. (1986) The
Fairris, S. and Tohyama, H. (2002) ‘Productive efficiency Transformation of American Industrial Relations.
and the lean production system in Japan and the New York, NY: Basic Books.
THE HIGH PERFORMANCE WORK SYSTEMS LITERATURE IN INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS 433

Kochan, T. and Osterman, P. (1994) The Mutual Gains Parker, M. and Slaughter, J. (1988) Choosing Sides:
Enterprise. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Unions and the Team Concept. Boston, MA: South
Press. End Press.
Lawler III, E. and Mohrman, S. (1985) ‘Quality circles Pfeffer, J. (1998) The Human Equation. Boston, MA:
after the fad’, Harvard Business Review, 63 (1): Harvard Business School Press.
65–71. Piore, M. and Sabel, C. (1984) The Second Industrial
MacDuffie, J.P. (1995) ‘Human resource bundles and Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York, NY:
manufacturing performance: Organizational logic Basic Books.
and flexible production systems in the world auto Preuss, G. and Frost, A. (2003) ‘The rise and decline of
industry’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, labor-management cooperation: Lessons from health
48 (2): 197–221. care in the Twin Cities’, California Management
MacDuffie, J.P. and Krafcik, J. (1992) ‘Interacting tech- Review, 45 (2): 85–106.
nology and human resources for high performance Pulignano, V. (2002) ‘Restructuring of work and
manufacturing: Evidence from the international auto union representation: A developing framework for
industry’, in T. Kochan and M. Useem (eds), workplace industrial relations in Britain and Italy’,
Transforming Organizations. New York: Oxford Capital and Class, 76 (Spring): 29–66.
University Press. Rinehart, J., Huxley, C. and Robertson, D. (1997)
McNabb, R. and Whitfield, K. (1997) ‘Unions, flex- Just Another Car Factory? Lean Production and its
ibility, team working, and financial performance’, Discontents. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Organization Studies, 18 (5): 821–39. Vallas, S. (2003) ‘Why teamwork fails: Obstacles to
Osterman, P. (1994) ‘How common is workplace workplace change in four manufacturing plants’,
transformation and who adopts it?’, Industrial and American Sociological Review, 68 (2): 223–50.
Labor Relations Review, 47 (2): 173–88. Wells, D. (1998) ‘Are strong unions compatible with
Osterman, P. (2000) ‘Work reorganization in an era the new model of human resource management?’,
of restructuring: Trends in diffusion and effects on Relations Industrielles, 48 (1): 56–85.
employee welfare’, Industrial and Labor Relations Womack, J., Jones, D. and Roos, D. (1990) The Machine
Review, 53 (2): 179–97. That Changed the World. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
23
Employee Involvement and
Direct Participation
Russell D. Lansbury and Nick Wailes

INTRODUCTION (Huselid, 1995; Becker and Gerhart, 1996).


As Gill and Krieger (1999: 572) put it this
Employee involvement and direct participa- ‘rediscovery’ of the human factor in work
tion by workers in decisions which affect organizations can be seen as a response
their working lives have long been a focus to the increasing competitive pressures in
of industrial relations (IR) scholarship. In international product markets. Management
the late 1960s and early 1970s, direct increasingly recognized the need to involve
participation was promoted by state agencies employees, to grant them greater work
in many developed countries as a means discretion and great commitment in order
to ‘humanize’ work and reduce industrial to render organizations more flexible and
conflict (Ramsay, 1977). Since the early 1980s productive.
there has been growing attention focused on While these arguments suggested that a
the economic benefits of direct participation common pattern of involvement and partic-
and management has been at the forefront of ipation would diffuse across countries, the
introducing employee involvement schemes findings of empirical research show continued
in a number of countries. During the 1980s, for and persistent national differences in both the
example, there was considerable experimen- form and incidence of participatory practices.
tation with Japanese- style joint consultation Thus, for example, recent studies estimate that
in a number of countries (see Bradley and almost 25 per cent of US workers are involved
Hill, 1983). During the 1990s arguments that in some form of employee stock ownership
suggested that employee involvement and plan, whereas less than nine per cent of firms
direct participation were central to creating in Europe have employee share ownership
high performance work systems (HPWS) schemes (Blasi et al., 2003b; Poutsma and
produced heightened management interest Huijgen, 1999). Moreover, despite efforts
in various forms of employee involvement by the European Union (EU) to encourage
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 435

financial participation, there are considerable direct participation, whereas forms of direct
differences in the extent and nature of and indirect participation linked to production
financial participation adopted in countries systems are likely to more sustainable in co-
across Europe (see, for example, Poutsma ordinated market economies (CMEs). The
and de Nijs, 2003). In Japan, employee share VoC approach may also help explain why
ownership plans (ESOPs) are widespread but there appears to be much greater levels
differ in character from those in the US and of experimentation with different forms of
profit-sharing programs are more common involvement and participation in LMEs than
(Kato and Morishima, 2003). Similarly there in CMEs.
are considerable national differences in pat- The chapter is structured as follows. The
terns of direct participation. In reviewing the next section briefly examines some of the
findings of the 1996 European Participation in different forms of employee involvement and
Organizational Change (EPOC) survey, Gill direct participation and reviews theoretical
and Krieger (1999: 577–579) noted that while explanations of involvement and participa-
the incidence of direct participation in Europe tion. The third section outlines the VoC
was high, with 82 per cent of respondents approach and its implications for understand-
to the survey reporting that they practiced at ing differences in national patterns of par-
least one form of direct participation, there ticipation. Section four provides a historical
were significant differences between coun- overview of involvement and participation
tries in both the forms of direct participation practices in the US and Australia which
adopted and the involvement of employee are two examples of LMEs. Section five
representatives in their introduction (see also, examines involvement and participation in
Poutsma and Huijgen, 1999). Research in CMEs, focusing on Germany and Japan. The
the US suggests that while some of the final section returns to current debates about
participative practices associated with HPWS employee involvement and HPWS and argues
diffused widely during the 1990s, the number that, when viewed from a VoC perspective,
of US organizations that have adopted a there are reasons to question the sustainability
coherent bundle of participatory HR practices of the participatory practices associated with
remains relatively limited (Osterman, 2000; HPWS especially in LMEs.
Godard, 2004).
This chapter examines the contribution
of a varieties of capitalism (VoC) approach DIRECT PARTICIPATION: FORMS AND
to explaining divergent national patterns THEORETICAL FRAMEWORKS
of involvement and participation despite
seemingly common international pressures. Direct forms of employee involvement and
The VoC approach argues that the practices participation are extremely diverse. They
adopted by organizations are influenced by include both formal and informal modes
the national institutional matrix within which of involvement, such as employee profit-
they operate (see Hall and Soskice, 2001 and sharing schemes and engagement in semi-
Hamann and Kelly, this volume). One of the autonomous work groups within an enterprise.
implications of this argument is that some Direct forms of participation are distinguished
forms of participation and involvement will from indirect (or representative) forms which
be more widely adopted and sustainable in include employees being elected to works
some countries and less prevalent, or more councils and other formal bodies involved
difficult to sustain, in other countries where in governance at the workplace or enterprise
the institutional context is less favorable. level. While the terms participation and
In particular, it can be argued that the involvement are often used interchangeably
institutional matrix associated with liberal in the literature (and in this chapter), as Wall
market economies (LMEs) is consistent with and Lisherson argue (1977), the concept of
extensive financial participation and limited participation implies that workers share a
436 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

degree of influence and power over decisions in the amount and variety of management-
not implied by the concept of involvement. initiated direct and financial participation
While many of the management-initiated taking place in concert with the declining
practices which are the focus of the current strength of organized labor and state provision
literature, like employee share ownership, of labor market protection.
are often described as forms of participation, The cyclical approach, which developed as
they appear to lack the degree of power and a critique of evolutionary accounts, represents
influence-sharing that this label implies and a second major explanation of patterns of
many would more accurately be described as participation and involvement and is closely
forms of employee involvement. associated with the work of Harvie Ramsay
It is possible to delineate two broad sets (1977, 1982, 1983). Ramsay disputed the
of approaches to historical developments in extent to which participation was genuine
both direct and indirect forms of participation. and argued that management’s interest in
The first are sociological and include evo- different forms of direct and financial partic-
lutionary, cyclical and complex multivariate ipation followed a cyclical pattern: managers
approaches. The second set of explanations introduced participation in periods when
are economic in character. Economic argu- labor had the power to challenge managerial
ments underpin much of the contemporary prerogative and withdrew their support when
management interest in HPWS. Debates about labor’s power waned or economic pressures
participation and involvement often turn increased. While the cyclical thesis countered
on two interrelated and recurring issues: the naivety of evolutionary accounts, and
first, whether different forms of participation drew attention to the importance of under-
(direct, indirect and financial) reinforce or are standing the historical and social context
antithetical to one another and; second, the within which participation takes place, as
extent to which participation or involvement Harley et al. (2005: 5) have recently argued
is ‘real’ or not, in the sense of giving ‘participative practices have evolved in ways
workers control over important aspects of that the cycles theory has been unable to
their working lives. predict’.
The evolutionary approach to participation More recent sociological approaches to par-
is closely linked to the notion of ‘industrial ticipation reflect a more complex multivariate
democracy’ and sees workers’ direct and approach which differs from the evolutionary
financial participation as a consequence of and cyclical positions in that it is based on the
the spread of the ‘democratic current’ from isolation of factors that help to explain the rise
political to economic and industrial life of employee participation (see, for example,
(Dachler and Wilpert, 1978). This approach Poole, 1986, 1989; Poutsma et al., 2003; and
suggests that forces such as a growing role Strauss, 1986, 1990, 1996). This approach is
for the state and legislature in industrial consistent with traditional industrial relations
relations, advances in technology, the rise approaches and with historical interpretations
of a managerial elite well versed in human where the analyst focuses on how things come
resource techniques and the changing values together at particular moments in time. Strauss
and aspirations of a more educated workforce (1986, 1996), for example, advocates a focus
will contribute to growing levels of partici- on the particular historical circumstances
pation and democracy. However, as Pateman that have led to variations in participatory
(1970) argued, much of this thinking has been forms and an appreciation of the need to
utopian, with little account being taken of the incorporate contingency and a role for agency
diverse patterns of power relations that, in in explaining the nature of participation. The
practice, constrain the advance of employee emphasis is, thus, on a broad set of variables
involvement. It is particularly difficult for (including the power of the actors), on diverse
the evolutionary approach to explain the initiating agents (labor and the state, as well
contemporary pattern of significant increases as management) and on institutional forces
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 437

in addition to the environment-enterprise idea that there is one best way to organize
linkages of a contingencies approach (see, for capitalism, they argue that there are at least
example, Poole et al., 2001). two possible solutions to these co-ordination
While these multivariate approaches have problems: liberal market economies (LMEs),
drawn attention to the broad range of factors in which firms rely on markets and hier-
which might influence national patterns of archies to resolve co-ordination problems,
participation and involvement, in general they and co-ordinated market economies (CMEs),
stop short of developing causal hypotheses of in which firms are more likely to use non-
the relationships between variables. Without market mechanisms to co-ordinate external
this theoretical development there is a danger and internal relationships.
that multivariate theories of participation and Central to Hall and Soskice’s argument,
involvement will become little more than and of particular significance for under-
elaborate contingency frameworks and, as standing the implications of this framework
a consequence, will provide little insight for involvement and participation, is the
into contemporary cross national patterns of concept of institutional complementarities.
participation and involvement. Hall and Soskice (2001: 18) argue that
‘nations with a particular type of co-ordination
in one sphere in the economy should tend
VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM, to develop complementary practices in other
PARTICIPATION AND INVOLVEMENT spheres as well’ (see also Amable, 2003:
54–66). As Gospel and Pendleton (2005) have
As Harley et al. (2005: 14) note, while recently demonstrated, there appear to be
issues of agency and contingency are impor- close relationships between forms of firm
tant in explaining patterns of participation, financing and labor management practices.
institutional context ‘shapes and constrains This suggests that patterns of participation and
local contingencies’. This section elaborates involvement are likely to vary systematically
on potential causal relationships between across varieties of capitalism. In LMEs, where
institutional context and forms and patterns there is a heavy reliance on equity markets for
of participation and involvement using the firm finance and outsider forms of corporate
varieties of capitalism (VoC) framework, governance, labor management practices and
which distinguishes national capitalisms on production systems tend to be market-based
the basis of institutional arrangements. While and short term in character. Forms of financial
it is possible to identify a number of theories participation, which give workers market-
of capitalist diversity (see Hamann and Kelly, based rewards but limit the long-term com-
this volume; Crouch, 2005; Godard, 2005), mitment of the firm to workers, appear to be
the focus in this chapter is largely on Hall more consistent with the institutional matrix
and Soskice’s (2001) VoC approach. This is of LMEs than other forms of participation
because it is the best known and because it is and involvement, which are predicated on a
firm-centric and therefore has the potential to longer term relationship between workers and
explain the relationship between institutional the firm. In CMEs, which are characterized by
context and management-initiated participa- patient capital, insider forms of corporate gov-
tion practices. ernance and production strategies based on
Hall and Sosckice (2001: 6–9) argue that exploiting firm-specific skills developed over
firms are faced with a series of co-ordination long periods of time, forms of participation
problems, both internally and externally. which build on long-term commitment and
They focus on five spheres of co-ordination elicit worker contribution to decision making
that firms must address: industrial relations; and work design are likely to be more common
vocational training and education; corporate than those which reduce the relationship to
governance; inter-firm relations and relations short-run, market exchanges. Thus, if the
with their own employees. Rejecting the VOC approach holds, we would expect more
438 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

evidence of long-term direct participation by Hill (1983: 308) put it, this, in part, reflected
workers in decision making in CMEs than is the fact that Japanese ‘management culture
the case for LMEs. To the extent that there is and worker behaviour is based on a different
evidence of ongoing employee involvement set of rules and institutions’.
in LMEs, we expect that it is likely to be This section has argued that patterns of
concentrated on financial participation, which participation and involvement are likely to
will be less prevalent in CMEs. vary systematically across varieties of capi-
Nonetheless, the VoC approach also implies talism, reflecting the impact of institutional
that there are likely to be higher levels context on the contingencies faced by social
of experimentation with different forms of actors. The next section tests this argument
involvement and participation, both direct and by providing brief historical overviews of
financial, in LMEs than in CMEs. It has patterns of participation and involvement in
been widely argued that in CMEs competitive two LMEs (the US and Australia) and two
advantages are likely to arise from the CMEs (Japan and Germany).
development of firm specific assets associated
with the long-term commitment of capital
and labor (see Aoki, 2000). The institutional PARTICIPATION AND INVOLVEMENT
matrix of CMEs produces conditions for IN LIBERAL AND CO-ORDINATED
diversified quality production systems where
MARKET ECONOMIES
the main focus is on incremental improve-
ments to existing products and technologies
United States
(Streeck, 1991). Lacking certainty in the
long-term financial commitment of investors, The concept of employee participation in
and unwilling to provide employees with management has been perceived quite differ-
the commitment necessary to encourage ently in the US than in the other countries
investment in firm specific human capital, covered in this chapter. Derber (1980:171)
the competitiveness of firms in LMEs are provided one possible explanation when he
less likely to be based on the development argued that ‘the predominant view [in the US]
of firm specific assets and more likely to be is that industrial democracy has been widely
derived from innovation and experimentation achieved through the system of collective
(Jurgens, 2003). While the main focus of bargaining. Only a small minority of labor
the literature has been on innovation in activists call for new routes to industrial
products and technologies, this argument can democracy [by other means]’. Yet, as collec-
also be extended to management practices, tive bargaining coverage has declined in the
including those associated with involvement US, in parallel with shrinking union mem-
and participation. Thus, we expect that LMEs bership, there has been considerable exper-
are more likely to be characterized by imentation with various forms of employee
high levels of experimentation with, and participation of a more direct kind.
abandonment of, different forms of employee The terms high-involvement workplaces
involvement and participation than is the and high-performance workplaces have
case in CMEs. Research on the adoption gained currency in the US as descriptions
of Japanese-style involvement processes by of ‘new’ and ‘innovative’ approaches to the
US and UK companies during the 1980s organization of work in which there is greater
appears to provide empirical support for flexibility, co-operation between workers
this proposition. While US and UK man- and management and worker participation
agers eagerly adopted participation based in the decisions and financial well-being
on Japanese quality control systems during of the firm (Appelbaum and Batt, 1994;
the 1980s, the results were disappointing Appelbaum et al., 2000; Pil and MacDuffie,
and these schemes were rapidly abandoned 1996). Kochan and Osterman (1994) coined
(see Ackroyd et al., 1988). As Bradley and the phrase ‘mutual-gains enterprise’ to
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 439

describe organizations that have taken a of production, such as stock ownership.


comprehensive and integrated approach to Support for employee stock ownership plans
implementing participatory practices and (ESOPs) grew in the 1980s, in part because
other activities designed to satisfy the needs some thought that giving employees stock
of workers and management. Yet, while in a company would increase their sense of
many US businesses have adopted some ownership and hence their participation in
forms of innovative work practices aimed performance improvements. An ESOP is a
at enhancing employee participation, only benefit plan through which employees receive
a small percentage has adopted a full and company stock either in trade for various
integrated set of workplace innovations. wage and benefit concessions or as an addition
Some of the reasons advanced to explain this to existing compensation. ESOPs cover over
situation include the problems encountered 11 million employees. Studies of the impacts
when changing from traditional work of ESOPs yield mixed results, but research
systems, resistance from those with a vested to date has not determined whether ESOP
interest in retaining the former systems, firms become more prosperous as a result of
and lack of a supportive institutional and employee ownership or whether prosperous
public-policy environment (Ichniowski et al., firms are more likely to establish ESOPs (for
1996: 325–29). a review of recent research on ESOPs in the
The second category of participative pro- US see Blasi et al., 2003a) . The empirical evi-
grams concerns job redesign activities that dence suggests, however, that ownership and
change the nature of work organization and other forms of direct participation together
enable workers or groups of workers to do more to raise productivity than ownership
exercise greater discretion in the way they does by itself. Furthermore, stock ownership
conduct their work activities. New United alone is unlikely to stimulate worker commit-
Motor Manufacturing Inc. (NUMMI) is a joint ment. Tying ESOP tax subsidies to worker
venture between General Motors and Toyota, representation, however, could establish this
located at a former GM plant in Fremont, critical link. Meaningful employee partic-
California, that had experienced major prob- ipation occurs when appropriate structures
lems with productivity, quality and industrial are in place to provide the vehicle for
relations. A new work system was devised, participation (Eaton, 1994). Unions tend to
in which the UAW participated, that involved argue, however, that stock ownership gives
new workers being hired to operate in teams, workers the illusion of ownership without any
responsible for planning and conducting work real control and that it is chiefly a management
as well as engaging in kaizen (‘continuous technique to replace superannuation plans,
improvement’) activities. Team leaders were to reduce union influence, or to cut wages.
chosen on the basis of recommendations of a In practice, however, stock ownership has
joint union-management committee (Kochan little impact on industrial relations at the
and Rubenstein, 2001). Although the work corporate level, and it does not appear to
teams could balance work assignments and make unionists any less loyal to their unions.
rotate tasks, the fundamental assembly-line It simply does not have a major impact on
technology of repeated short job cycles was employee involvement or participation at the
maintained. This caused some observers to workplace level (Strauss, 1996:190).
describe NUMMI as ‘humanized Taylorism’
(see Adler and Cole, 1993). Nevertheless,
Australia
NUMMI was hailed as a more participative
and effective work system than the traditional The ascendance of a neo-liberal agenda
mass-production assembly line (see Adler occurred somewhat later in Australia than
et al., 1997). in many other Anglo-Saxon countries. The
A third area of direct employee partici- Australian Labour Party (ALP) held power
pation is through ownership of the means at the national level from 1983 to 1996,
440 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

aided by an Accord between the Australian workplaces believed that such schemes gave
Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) and the employees increased say at the workplace
Labor government (Lansbury and Wailes, level. Yet when managers were asked whether
2004). Although the Accord underwent a they had consulted staff about important
number of modifications during this period, it changes that had affected their workplaces
emphasized union involvement in macroeco- during the previous year, only 29 per cent
nomic and social policy decision making. To responded positively, and only 18 per cent
this end, the government established various said that employees had a significant input
tripartite committees and councils at national into decisions. This would appear to indicate
and industry levels. that while the degree of participation by
The election of a conservative Liberal- employees has increased (both in indirect
National Coalition government in 1996 ush- and direct forms), there continues to be
ered in new industrial relations reforms that important issues on which they are not
ostensibly sought to increase deregulation. consulted by management (Morehead et al.,
The new coalition government moved further 1997: 244).
away from a collectivist approach to industrial This finding is reinforced by Harley (1999)
relations (and industrial democracy) in which who argues that there is little evidence of
there had been a strong role for unions employee empowerment in Australia. Using
and tribunals. Its Work Choices Act 2006 AWIRS 1995 data he shows that while many
privileges individual non-union agreements of the practices associated with ‘employee
ahead of collectively bargained agreements empowerment’ are present in a substantial
between employers and employees (see Ellem minority of Australian workplaces, there is
et al., 2005). The unionized workforce has little evidence to suggest that these practices
declined from around 40 per cent in 1990 to increased employee autonomy or reduced
less than 25 per cent in 2005. the significance of organizational hierarchy.
Data from the second (and last) Australian In particular Harley (1999: 53) finds that
Industrial Relations Survey (AWIRS95) pro- ‘employees who work in workplaces with any
vides the best available data on participa- of the empowerment mechanisms in place
tion and involvement practice in Australian do not report any differences in their level
workplaces (see Morehead et al., 1997). of autonomy from employees who work in
AWIRS95 demonstrated that direct forms of workplaces without the mechanisms’. Rather
employee participation in Australia tend to he finds continued close associations between
be oriented around an employee’s tasks and measures of hierarchy and reported levels of
are designed to improve the performance of autonomy.
individuals and groups within the workplace. Financial participation through employee
The most common direct form was found to share ownership and profit-sharing schemes
be team building, reported in 47 per cent of has not increased as significantly in Australia
workplaces. Semi- or fully-autonomous work as it has in some other countries. In 1990,
groups were seen in 43 per cent of workplaces, only 16 per cent of private-sector workplaces
whereas total quality management (TQM) offered share ownership schemes to their
was reported in 37 per cent of workplaces. employees. By 1995, this had increased
As with indirect forms of participation, to 22 per cent. The likelihood of having
large workplaces tended to have more direct a share ownership scheme was greater in
participation than smaller ones. private-sector workplaces that were part of
According to AWIRS95, the majority of a larger organization compared with single-
managers believed that direct forms of workplace organizations (29 and 3 per cent,
employee participation led to improvements respectively). Of the 16 per cent of private-
in workplace performance, the introduction sector workplaces with schemes, fewer than
of change and improved product or ser- 10 percent of employees actually held shares.
vice quality. Most delegates in unionized Indeed, only 28 per cent of workplaces with
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 441

share schemes had more than half their the automobile industry) have undergone
employees as shareholders (Morehead et al., extensive organizational restructuring involv-
1997: 222). ing both the centralization and decentral-
An inquiry into employee share ownership ization of decision-making structures. Some
in Australia by the House of Representa- strategic decisions, such as the location of
tives Standing Committee on Employment, production facilities, have been centralized,
Education and Workplace Relations (2000) whereas decisions dealing with arrangements
reported that the concept had been less at particular plants have been decentralized.
enthusiastically embraced than in the US This latter development has opened up
or the UK. This was despite support from possibilities for more employees at lower
both major political parties and shared views levels in the hierarchy to be involved in
by successive governments that employee decision-making processes. On the other
share ownership had the potential to improve hand, regional union representatives who
net contributions to national savings. An previously had served as a counterbalance
investigation into two major corporations with to management no longer have an effective
considerable experience with employee share means of influencing decisions that have
ownership, Lend Lease and Woolworths, been moved from middle management to
found that they had achieved only limited headquarters management. New forms of
success in these two firms. Rysiok (2004) rationalization by firms also have created
argued that there appeared to be little problems for works councilors. Management
sense of ‘ownership’ or genuine employee has used group or team work, quality circles
involvement by employees who participated and the like to enable employees to influence
in the share ownership schemes in both and directly participate in decision making,
organizations. effectively bypassing the works councilors
(Roth, 1997: 118).
New systems of production also have had
Germany
consequences for direct participation.Accord-
Any account of German industrial relations in ing to Auer (1996), German managers took
the recent period must take into account the up ‘lean production’ with great enthusiasm
momentous industrial relations consequences following publication of The Machine that
of reunification. The outcome has been Changed the World (Womack et al., 1990),
the transfer of West Germany’s industrial arguing that it was necessary to abandon work
relations system to East Germany (Frege, practices that were inflexible and to combat
1999). Germany is characterized by a ‘dual ‘overmanning’ in automobile plants. German
system of interest representation’ that com- trade unions and works councils have been
prises collective bargaining between unions placed in a dilemma by lean production. While
and employers at the industry level and co- they have welcomed the opportunity for more
determination at the level of the enterprise. Yet participative work organization – as espoused
the system is under strain, particularly since by some proponents of lean production –
unification between West and East Germany, unions have opposed rationalization that has
which involved significant economic burdens led to ‘downsizing’ of the workforce. While
for the ‘new’ Germany, increasing levels works councils are entitled, under the Works
of unemployment and a waning of union Constitution Act, to be consulted on the
influence in both the political and economic introduction of lean forms of production,
spheres. many employers have sought to use the
New forms of production and work orga- opportunity to involve employees directly
nization in German industry have created a rather than through representative bodies. In
number of new challenges for unions and any case, works councils are not empowered
works councils. Since the late 1980s, large to refuse changes in work organization. Roth
enterprises and conglomerates (particularly in (1997) argues that unions have embraced
442 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

direct forms of participation that have empha- seniority-based wages, only ever applied to
sized ‘self-organization by improving skills around one-third of the labor force in larger
or professional competence’. The unions organizations. Similarly, trade union density
have urged employers to introduce ‘group in Japan declined from 31 per cent in 1980
work’ based on Swedish experiences with to 19.6 per cent in 2003 and unionization
semi-autonomous groups rather than ‘team is generally confined to large-scale industrial
work’ based on the Japanese or American employers. Furthermore, many of the innova-
approaches. tive workplace practices, such as TQM and
Wever (1995) notes that by acknowledging quality circles, were imported from the West
the growing importance of direct forms of in the 1950s and 60s when Japan was not
participation and seeking to accommodate regarded as a leading economic power. Yet
rather than oppose this trend, IG Metall risks the ‘Japanese model’ was widely cited at
conflict with some of its members as well evidence of the contribution which employee
as works councils because it will ‘place into participation and involvement makes to eco-
question past conceptualizations of worker nomic performance at the enterprise level.
interest representation’. However, this may The Japanese experience also illustrates that
not necessarily mean a ceding of power by the effectiveness of participative practice is
the union but rather a shift of roles. By embedded in the political economy of a nation
adapting to direct participation, the unions and and its enterprise cultures.
works councils may provide an alternative to Participation by employees in small group
unilateral approaches by management. activities, such as quality control circles
(QCCs) or total quality control (TQC), have
long been associated with the Japanese system
Japan
of management and employment relations.
During the rise of the Japanese economy More recently, however, attention has focused
in the late 1970s and early 1980s, consid- on the Japanese bonus payment system
erable attention was focused on Japanese and profit-sharing plans as a means by
management and employment relations sys- which employees can financially participate
tems. In particular, cooperative approaches to in enterprises. In addition to their regular
labor-management relations were ascribed to monthly pay, most Japanese workers receive
several practices, which included: life-time two large seasonal payments worth about
employment, seniority-based wage systems 2.8 months’ salary a year, although this varies
and various forms of employee participation between industries. The practice originated
in enterprise-based activities such as quality from the Buddhist ‘bon festival’ in summer
circles and consultative committees. Japan’s and the lunar New Year celebrations which
system of enterprise-based unionism was required extra expenditure. The amount of
also regarded as contributing significantly these payments fluctuates according to the
to low-levels of industrial disputation and financial performance of each company as
strong collaboration between management well as the individual employee’s contribution
and workers in order to achieve high levels to the success of the enterprise. However, the
of productivity (Kuwahara, 2004). Much of size of the bonus has generally declined with
the literature on high performance work sys- economic stagnation in Japan over the past
tems (HPWS), in Western literature, implic- decade. Various studies have indicated that
itly draws upon Japanese experience with there is a modest productivity gain from the
total quality management (TQM) practices, bonus system (Jones and Kato, 1995) and that
team work, multi-skilling of workers and bonuses tend to increase employees’ interest
information-sharing by management with the in the operation and performance of their firm
workforce (Faris and Varma, 1998). Yet some (Freeman and Weitzman, 1987). Yet other
of the key elements in the so-called ‘Japanese studies have viewed the bonus as a mixture
model’, such as life-time employment and of a disguised form of regular pay, investment
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 443

in firm-specific human capital and a means rules compared with those found in other
of compensating effort (Hart and Kawasaki, similar economies, long-term merit ratings for
1995). managers and employees and widespread use
Recent studies have indicated that, contrary of annual bonus payments. Informal systems
to the assumption that profit-sharing is almost of employee involvement and participation, in
universal among Japanese firms, only about combination with increased flexibilities of the
one in four traded firms has a profit-sharing labor market, will facilitate reforms of Japan’s
plan (PSP) in place. A PSP defined as a bonus economic structure.
payment system with a formal contract stipu-
lating the presence of a profit-sharing scheme
(Kato and Morishima, 2003). PSPs appear to CONCLUSIONS
be most popular among smaller firms, without
unions but with employee participation at the Recent decades have witnessed renewed
grassroots. Such participation, it is argued, interest in direct participation and employee
tends to promote an employment relations involvement and their contribution both
approach and a corporate culture that is to improved productivity and increased
conducive to labor-management cooperation flexibility in increasingly competitive mar-
and strong company loyalty by workers (Kato kets. Despite an increase in the number
and Morishima, 2002). of management-initiated participation and
Substantial changes in Japanese corpo- involvement schemes in many countries,
rate governance are currently in progress, empirical evidence suggests that there contin-
partly in response to the prolonged eco- ues to be considerable diversity in patterns of
nomic recession, which may introduce sim- participation at the national level. The previ-
ilar shareholder-based corporate governance ous section provided some brief summaries
systems to those which operate in US and of patterns of participation in four countries,
European companies. Revisions to company two of which are LMEs and two are CMEs.
law in 2001 and 2002 introduced committee- As these summaries indicate, the relationship
based systems for nominating director can- between varieties of capitalism and forms
didates, an audit committee and a directors’ of participation is not a simple one. It is
remuneration committee which nominates apparent that labor market institutions play an
officers responsible for particular aspects of important role, as does historical experience.
the business. Large companies are gradually Indirect forms of participation also influence
changing, as illustrated by Matsushita and direct forms, as illustrated by the importance
Toyota both decided to introduce a modified of long-established systems of works councils
version of the new model in 2003. This and co-determination in Germany in fostering
may ultimately mean that Japanese companies certain types of direct participation. Similarly,
move away from the traditional ‘Illyria’ the century-old tradition of compulsory arbi-
model, which maximized the dividend or tration in Australia affected the degree to
net income per worker, to the Western- which direct forms of participation were given
style model which seeks to maximize profits an opportunity to flourish. These findings
and in which greater weight is given to are consistent with the view, advanced by
‘shareholder prerogatives’ (Kuwahara, 2004). Gospel and Pendleton (2005: 9) amongst
However, it is likely that many elements of others, that the VoC approach is too formal
Japanese employment relations will persist and simplistic to capture all of the factors
while gradually changing. These include char- that produce differences between and change
acteristics which have promoted direct forms within national patterns of labor management.
of participation and are historically embedded Despite these limitations, the empirical
in Japanese enterprises, such as: relatively evidence presented in this chapter is broadly
vague and wide job descriptions, flexibility consistent with the propositions drawn from
of workforce allocation, lack of rigid work the VoC framework outlined above and
444 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

suggest that the national institutional matrix Australia and the US. However, if labor
has a significant impact on the adoption and market institutions continue to be weakened
sustainability of different forms of employee in Germany and Japan, and corporate gover-
involvement and participation. There are nance reforms mean that managers in these
two implications that can be drawn from countries become more susceptible to short-
these findings. First, it suggests that the term investor pressure, they are likely to
adoption of employee involvement practices become less distinguishable from the liberal
associated with HPWS in LMEs may be market economies of the US and Australia.
limited. Thus, despite evidence that elements Hence, the sustainability of their participative
of the HPWS have been widely adopted practices in the workplace will be less
across a number of US industries (Osterman, certain in the future unless there is stronger
2000) and some initial findings which report institutional support for their continuation and
positive associations between the adoption further development.
of key aspects of the HPWS model and
firm performance (see Huselid, 1994 and
Becker and Gerhart, 1996), more recent
studies question both the extent to which REFERENCES
US firms have derived improved performance
from these practices (see Combs et al., 2006) Ackroyd, S., Burrell, G., Hughes, M. and Whittaker, A.
and the extent to which any performance (1988) ‘The Japanisation of British industry?’,
gains are associated with empowerment as Industrial Relations Journal, 19 (1): 11–23.
Adler, P. and Cole, R. (1993) ‘Designed for learning:
opposed to work intensification (see Cappelli
A tale of two auto plants’, Sloan Management
and Neumark, 2001). This is consistent with
Review, 34 (3): 85–94.
research on HPWS in two other LMEs, the Adler, P., Kochan, T.A., MacDuffie, J.P., Pil, F.K. and
UK and Australia, and suggests that the Rubenstein, S. (1997) ‘United States: Variations on
extent to which HPWS enhance productivity a theme’, in T.A. Kochan, R.D. Lansbury, and J.P.
is achieved by increasing pressure on workers MacDuffie (eds) After Lean Production: Evolving
rather than empowering them (on the UK Employment Practices in the World Auto Industry.
see, for example, Bryson et al., 2005 and, Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. pp. 61–83.
on Australia, see Harley, 1999. For a review Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism.
of this research see Godard, 2004). Given New York: Oxford University Press.
the institutional matrix within which firms Aoki, M. (2000) Information, Corporate Governance and
Institutional Diversity: Compeitiveness in Japan, the
operate in LMEs, where investors focus
USA and the Transitional Economies. Oxford: Oxford
on short-term performance and managers
University Press.
are encouraged to experiment with different Appelbaum, E. and Batt, R. (1994) The New American
forms of work organization in pursuit of short- Workplace. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
term competitive advantage, these results Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg,
suggest that many of the direct participatory A. (2000) Manufacturing advantage: Why High
practices associated with HPWS not produc- Performance Systems Pay Off. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
ing the empowerment which their advocates University Press.
claim and may be difficult to sustain. Auer, P. (1996) ‘Co-determination in Germany: Insti-
Second, our survey of the literature on tutional stability in a changing environment’, in
employee involvement in the four countries E. Davis and R.D. Lansbury (eds)Managing Together:
Consultation and Participation in the Workplace.
studied has revealed that where the con-
Melbourne: Addison-Wesley Longman. pp. 160–72.
junction of historical and institutional factors
Becker, B. and Gerhart, B. (1996) ‘The impact of
are favorable, direct forms of participation human resource management on organizational
are more likely to be sustainable. In the performance: progress and prospects’, Academy of
past, this has characterized the co-ordinated Management Journal, 39 (4): 779–803.
market economies of Germany and Japan Blasi, J., Kruse, D. and Berstein, A. (2003a) In the
more than the liberal market economies of Company of Owners. New York: Basic Books.
EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT AND DIRECT PARTICIPATION 445

Blasi, J., Kruse, D., Sesil, J. and Kroumova, M. (2003b) B.E. Kaufman (ed.) Theoretical Perspectives on Work
‘An assessment of employee ownership in the United and the Employment Relationship. Champaign, IL:
States with implications for the EU’, International Industrial Relations Research Association.
Journal of Human Resource Management, 14 (6): Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (2005) ‘Corporate gov-
893–919. ernance and labour management: An international
Bradley, K. and Hill, S. (1983) ‘“After Japan”: The quality comparison’ in Gospel, H. and Pendleton A. (eds)
circle transplant and productive efficiency’, British Corporate governance and labour management: An
Journal of Industrial Relations, 21 (3): 291–311. international comparison. Oxford: Oxford University
Bryson, A., Forth, J. and Kirby, S. (2005) ‘High Press. pp. 1–32.
involvement management practices, trade union rep- Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001) ‘An introduction to
resentation and workplace performance in Britain’, varieties of capitalism’, in P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds)
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52 (3): 451–91. Varieties of capitalism: The Institutional Foundations
Cappelli, P. and Neurmark, D. (2001) ‘Do “high- of Comparative Advantage. New York: Oxford
performance” work practices improve establishment- University Press. pp. 1–69.
level outcomes?’, Industrial and Labor Relations Harley, B. (1999) ‘The myth of empowerment: Work
Review, 54 (4): 737–75. organization, hierarchy and autonomy in contempo-
Combs, J., Lui, Y., Hall, A. and Ketchen, D. (2006) ‘How rary Australian workplaces’, Work, Employment and
much do high performance work practices matter? Society, 13 (1): 41–66.
A meta-analysis of their effects on organizational Harley, B. (2005) ‘Hope or hype? High-performance
performance’, Personnel Psychology, 59 (3): 501–28. work systems’, in B. Harley, J. Hyman and
Crouch, C. (2005) ‘Models of capitalism’, New Political P. Thompson (eds) Participation and Democracy at
Economy, 10 (4): 439–56. Work: Essays in Honours of Harvie Ramsay. London:
Dachler, P.H. and Wilpert, B. (1978) ‘Conceptual Palgrave. pp. 20–37.
dimensions and boundaries of participation in Harley, B., Hyman, J. and Thompson, P. (2005) ‘The
organizations: A critical evaluation’, Administrative paradoxes of participation’, in B. Harley, J. Hyman
Science Quarterly, 23 (1): 1–39. and P. Thompson (eds) Participation and democracy
Derber, M. (1980) ‘Collective bargaining: The American at work: Essays in honours of Harvie Ramsay. London:
approach to industrial democracy’, in R.D. Lansbury Palgrave. pp. 1–19.
(ed.) Democracy in the Workplace. Melbourne: Hart, R.A. and Kawasaki, S. (1995) ‘The Japanese bonus
Longman Cheshire. pp. 171–82. system and human capital’, Journal of the Japanese
Eaton, A. (1994) ‘The survival of employee participation and International Economies, 9 (3): 225–44.
programs in unionized settings’, Industrial and Labor House of Representatives Standing Committee on
Relations Review, 47 (3): 371–89. Employment, Education and Workplace Relations
Ellem, B., Baird, M., Cooper, R. and Lansbury, R.D. (2000) Shared endeavours: An inquiry into employee
(2005) ‘Work choices: Myth making at work’, Journal share ownership in Australia, Canberra: Parliament
of Australian Political Economy, 56: 13–31. of the Commonwealth of Australia.
Faris, G.F. and Varma, A. (1998) ‘High performance work Huselid, M. (1995) ‘The impact of human resource
systems: What we know and what we need to know’, management practices on turnover, productivity and
Human Resource Planning, 21 (2): 50–55. corporate performance’, Academy of Management
Freeman, R. and Weitzman, M. (1987) ‘Bonuses and Journal, 38 (3): 635–62.
employment in Japan’, Journal of the Japanese and Ichniowski, C., Kochan, T.A., Levine, D., Olson, C.
International Economies, 1 (2): 168–94. and Strauss, G. (1996) ‘What works at work:
Frege, C.M. (1999) ‘Transferring labor institutions to Overview and assessment’, Industrial Relations,
emerging economics: The case of East Germany’, 35 (3): 299–333.
Industrial Relations, 38 (4): 459–81. Jones, D. and Kato, T. (1995) ‘The Productivity Effects
Gill, C. and Krieger, H. (1999) ‘Direct and representative of Employee Stock Ownership Plans and Bonuses:
participation in Europe: Recent survey evidence’, Evidence from Japanese Panel Data’, American
International Journal of Human Resource Manage- Economic Review, 85 (3): 391–414.
ment, 10 (4): 572–91. Jurgens, U. (2003) ‘Transformation and interaction:
Godard, J. (2004) ‘A critical assessment of the high Japanese, US and German production models in
performance paradigm’, British Journal of Industrial the 1990s’, in W. Streeck and K. Yamamura (eds)
Relations, 42 (2): 349–78. The end of diversity? Prospects for German and
Godard, J. (2005) ‘The new institutionalism, Japanese capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
capitalist diversity and industrial relations’, in pp. 212–39.
446 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Kato, T. and Morishima, M. (2002) ‘The productivity participative workplace’, Economic and Industrial
effects of participatory employment practices: Evi- Democracy, 24 (1): 45–76.
dence from new Japanese panel data’, Industrial Ramsay, H. (1977) ‘Cycles of control: Worker partic-
Relations, 41 (4): 487–520. ipation in sociological and historical perspective’,
Kato, T. and Morishima, M. (2003) ‘The nature, scope Sociology, 11 (3): 481–506.
and effects of profit sharing in Japan: Evidence from Ramsay, H. (1982) Evolution or Cycle? In Colin Crouch
new survey data’, International Journal of Human (ed.)First International Yearbook of Organisational
Resource Managements, 14 (6): 942–55. Democracy. London: Wiley.
Kochan, T.A. and Osterman, P. (1994) The Mutual Gains Ramsay, H. (1983) An International Participation Cycle:
Enterprise. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Variations on a Recurring Theme. In Stuart Clegg,
Kochan, T.A. and Rubenstien, P.R. (2001) Learning from Paul Boreham and Geff Dow (eds) The State, Class
Saturn. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. and the Recession. Canberra: Croom Helm.
Kuwahara, Y. (2004) ‘Employment relations in Japan’, Roth, S. (1997) ‘Germany: Labor’s perspective on
in G.J. Bamber, R.D. Lansbury and N. Wailes lean production’, in T.A. Kochan, R.D. Lansbury
(eds) International and Comparative Employment and J.P. MacDuffie (eds) After Lean Production:
Relations. London: Sage. pp. 277–305. Evolving Employment Practices in the World Auto
Lansbury, R.D. and Wailes, N. (2004) ‘Employment Industry. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
relations in Australia’, in G.J. Bamber, R.D. Lansbury pp. 117–36.
and N. Wailes (eds) International and Comparative Rysiok, E. (2004) ‘Shared endeavours: A case study
Employment Relations. London: Sage. pp. 119–45. of employee share plans at Woolworths and Land
Morehead, A. Steel, M., Alexander, M., Stephen, K. Lease’, Unpublished Honours Thesis. School of
and Duffin, L. (1997) Change at Work: The 1994 Business, University of Sydney.
Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey Strauss, G. (1986) ‘Workers participation in man-
(AWIRS 95). Melbourne: Addison-Wesley Longman. agement in the United States’, in E.M. Davis
Osterman, P. (2000) ‘Work reorganization in an era and R.D. Lansbury (eds) Democracy and Control
of restructuring: trends in diffusion and effects on in the Workplace. Sydney: Longman Cheshire.
employee welfare’, Industrial and Labor Relations pp. 313–31.
Review, 53 (2): 179–96. Strauss, G. (1990) ‘Participation and gain sharing
Pateman, C. (1970) Participation and Democratic systems: History and hope’, in M. Roomkin (ed.) Profit
Theory. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University and Gain Sharing. Metuchen, NJ: Rutgers University
Press. Press. pp. 1–45.
Pendleton, A. (1997) ‘The evolution of industrial Strauss, G. (1996) ‘Participation in the United States:
relations in UK nationalized industries’, British Journal Progress and barriers’, in E. Davis and R.D. Lansbury
of Industrial Relations, 35 (2): 145–72. (eds) Managing together: Consultation and Participa-
Pil, F.K. and MacDuffie, J.P. (1996) ‘The adoption of high tion in the Workplace. Melbourne: Addison-Wesley
involvement workplaces’, Industrial Relations, 35 (3): Longman. pp. 173–92.
423–55. Strauss, G. (1998) ‘Comparative international industrial
Poole, M. (1986) Towards a New Industrial Democ- relations’, in K. Whitfield and G. Strauss (eds)
racy: Workers’ Participation in Industry. London: Researching the World of Work. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Routledge. Streeck, W. (1991) ‘On the institutional conditions
Poole, M. (1989) The Origins of Economic Democracy. for diversified quality production’, in E. Matzner
London: Routledge. and W. Streeck (eds) Beyond Keynesianism: The
Poole, M., Lansbury, R.D. and Wailes, N. (2001) ‘A Socio-Economics of Production and Full Employment,
comparative analysis of developments in industrial Brookfield: Elgar, pp. 21–61.
democracy’, Industrial Relations, 40 (3): 490–525. Wall, T. and Lischeron, J (1977) Worker Participation:
Poutsma, E. and de Nijs, W. (2003) ‘Broad based a Critique of the Literature and Some Fresh Evidence.
employee financial participation in the European Maidenhead: McGraw Hill.
Union’, International Journal of Human Resource Wever, K. (1995) Negotiating Competitiveness: Employ-
Management, 14 (6): 863–92. ment Relations and Organizational Innovation in
Poutsma, E. and Huijgen, F. (1999) ‘European diversity Germany and the United States. Boston: Harvard
in the use of participation schemes’, Economic and Business School Press.
Industrial Democracy, 20 (2): 197–223. Womack, J., Jones, D.T. and Roos, D. (1990) The
Poutsma, E., Hendrickx, J. and Huijgen, F. (2003) Machine that Changed the World. New York: Rawson
‘Employee participation in Europe: In search of the Associates.
24
Resolving Conflict
David Lewin

RESOLVING CONFLICT and empirical research from North America,


Europe, and other world regions.
Conflict and the potential for conflict exists
in all human relationships, including the
Sources of employment relationship
employment relationship. Historically and
conflict
contemporaneously, various approaches to
and methods for resolving employment rela- For employment relationship conflict to exist,
tionship conflict have been developed. How an employment relationship must exist. While
effective are these approaches and methods this may appear self-evident, underdeveloped,
in actually resolving employment relation- developing, and even some portions of
ship conflict? That is the focal question developed economies feature small owner-
addressed in this chapter, which is organized operated businesses without specialization of
as follows. Section 1 briefly identifies key function – as examples, the nineteenth century
sources of employment relationship con- shoemaker (memorialized by Commons,
flict, section 2 discusses main approaches 1919), the twentieth century small farmer or
to resolving employment relationship con- family-owned retail store, and the twenty-first
flict, section 3 analyzes leading theories of century two-partner start-up financial con-
employment relationship conflict and conflict sulting business. As small businesses grow,
resolution, section 4 examines both older they hire paid labor to perform certain tasks
and newer forms of employment conflict that owner-operators previously performed,
resolution and evidence of their effectiveness, thereby creating an employment relationship.
and section 5 considers future directions for As these businesses grow further, they
employment conflict resolution research. In develop more specialized functions, promote
these respects, this chapter focuses largely some employees to serve as supervisors and
on formal individual employee-employer managers, and hire more paid labor to perform
workplace conflict resolution rather than on specialized tasks. In this developmental
more collective forms of conflict resolution, stage, a separation of ownership from (direct)
such as strikes,1 and draws on theoretical management has occurred, and there emerge
448 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

clearly identifiable ‘management’ and clearly (Mathewson, 1931). Further, to counter the
identifiable ‘employees’. dictates and power of business owners and
If and as these businesses grow still larger, managers, some workers went so far as
they may seek additional financial capital to organize into labor unions and to with-
through public ownership. Once this occurs, hold their labor (even without unions). For
the separation of business ownership from much of the twentieth century, employment
control deepens and both managers and relationship conflict largely meant union-
employees become the agents of their prin- management conflict, or collective conflict,
cipals. It is well known, however, that agents with strikes and the prevention of strikes
may not primarily serve the interests of their occupying the bulk of popular attention and
principals; instead, they may primarily serve public policy debates, respectively (see Gall
their own interests (Jensen and Meckling, and Hebdon, this volume, Chapter 31).
1976). From this perspective, managers have During the last quarter of the twentieth
certain interests, employees have certain century, however, the economic environment
interests, and the two sets of interests may for employment relationship conflict changed
well differ considerably even if they overlap dramatically. The two ‘oil shocks’ that
in some respects. Such differing interests occurred during the 1970s signaled the grow-
are a fundamental source of employment ing importance of a global rather than a strictly
relationship conflict – but hardly the only domestic economic perspective, with the
source. result that businesses in many nations became
Another source of employment relationship increasingly focused on global customers
conflict is a twin source, namely, hierarchy and competitors. For their part, national
and specialization. Hierarchy refers to a governments undertook the de-regulation of
pyramidal form of organization featuring such key industries as airlines, trucking,
several distinct levels in which those who telecommunications and financial services.
occupy the top levels – executives and Major advances in information and computing
managers – co-ordinate and control the work technology also occurred, with the advent of
of those who occupy the middle and lower personal computing during the 1980s and the
levels (Weber, 1947). Specialization refers to commercialization of the internet during the
the design of work such that any individual 1990s and continuing into the twenty-first
job features a few narrow, well-specified tasks century constituting watershed developments.
that an employee repeats on a continuous basis Most notable for employment relationship
and in which that employee takes instruction conflict, the practice of ‘continuous employ-
from a supervisor or manager (Taylor, 1911). ment with the company’ came undone as
In this organizational format, those at the employer after employer sought to reorganize,
upper levels ostensibly do the thinking and restructure, downsize, and ‘rightsize’. In
those at the lower levels do the work. this new economic environment, continu-
There is little question that the combina- ous employment with periodic layoff and
tion of organizational hierarchy and work recall was swiftly supplanted by outsourcing,
specialization enabled business enterprises including to offshore locations; by part-time,
worldwide, indeed, entire national economies, temporary and short-term employment; and
to grow and prosper, especially during the by market-driven employability (Bognanno
twentieth century. But these same organi- et al., 2007; Osterman, 1988).
zational characteristics often generated fun- The triplet of global economic competition,
damental employment relationship conflict. de-regulation and technological change has
Over time, workers expressed their dissatis- therefore contributed mightily to the reduction
faction with orders that they received from ‘on of concentrated power among employer
high’, and sometimes openly rebelled against and employee organizations. Today, most
such orders, including through restricting their industries are characterized by competition
output or working to rule or absenteeism rather than by oligopoly or monopoly, and
RESOLVING CONFLICT 449

most employees provide their labor indi- grievance procedure contained in collective
vidually and are neither members of nor bargaining agreements. This procedure typi-
represented by labor unions. Indeed, union cally specifies several formal steps, the first
membership has been declining globally of which calls for an employee grievance to
during the last quarter century or so, and be put in writing and the last of which calls
it appears that many more employees are for arbitration of the issue or issues specified
party to individual employment contracts than in the written grievance. Such grievance
to collective bargaining contracts (Lewin, arbitration can be distinguished from contract
1994). These developments do not, however, arbitration in which the third-party arbitrator
mean that employment relationship conflict sets the terms and conditions of a new
has faded from the scene or somehow been collective bargaining agreement between the
resolved. Rather, the focus of both research two direct parties, union and management, to
and practice has shifted from collective union- that agreement.
management conflict to individual conflict in The collectively bargained grievance pro-
the employment relationship. cedure has long been commended as a
One manifestation of this shifting emphasis peaceful mechanism for resolving employee-
is the rather widespread adoption by non- management disputes. In the absence of
union companies of grievance and grievance- a grievance procedure, according to this
like procedures for dealing with employment reasoning, disputes over existing terms and
relationship conflict. Several recent studies conditions of employment might lead to
suggest that a majority, perhaps a large major- strikes, work slowdowns, absenteeism, lock-
ity, of non-union companies have adopted one outs, and other overt behaviors that obviously
or more of these procedures (Lewin, 2005; interrupt the production and delivery of
Colvin, 2004, 2003). Another manifestation goods and services. From this perspec-
of this shifting emphasis is the work of orga- tive, the grievance procedure adds value
nizational behavior scholars, who typically to unionized businesses by mitigating the
study conflict at the individual and team potential costs of employee-management dis-
levels of analysis and who have importantly putes (Jacoby, 1986). Indeed, the grievance
differentiated relationship conflict from task procedure provisions of collective bargaining
conflict in organizations (Bendersky, 2003; agreements are almost always accompa-
Jehn, 1997). Still another manifestation of nied by (and thus traded for) provisions
this shifting emphasis is the voluminous that explicitly ban employee strikes and
litigation over claims by current and former employer lockouts during the life of those
employees that their employers violated agreements. In addition to this efficiency
one or another provision of laws aimed benefit, the grievance procedure provides
at preventing discrimination in employment equity to unionized employees by serving as
(Stone, 1999; Donohue and Siegelman, 1991). an institutionalized mechanism for addressing
In sum, there is much scholarly evidence and (perhaps) resolving the workplace con-
and much practical experience to suggest cerns voiced by these employees. In other
that conflict in the employment relationship words, there are both efficiency and equity
remains ever present, even as its particular (or voice) arguments for grievance procedures
forms and manifestations have changed over in unionized settings.
time in response to exogenous as well as In non-union settings, the rationale for
endogenous forces. grievance and grievance-like conflict reso-
lution procedures is rather different from
that in unionized settings. According to
Approaches to resolving
both survey and field research-based stud-
employment relationship conflict
ies, executives and managers of non-union
Surely the best known approach to resolving businesses primarily view the grievance
employment relationship conflict is the formal procedure as a mechanism for identifying
450 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

workplace and organizational issues and about 10 grievances are settled informally
as an information system for diagnosing, in employee-supervisor (or manager) discus-
addressing and resolving such issues (Colvin, sions (Lewin and Peterson, 1988). In the
2004; Feuille and Delaney, 1992; Delaney same vein, research on non-union grievance
et al., 1989). From this perspective, the procedures estimates that the ratio of informal
decisions by non-union businesses to adopt to formal grievance settlement is approxi-
a grievance (or grievance-like) procedure mately 12:1 (Lewin, 2004). On the basis of
are strategic or proactive decisions, which these estimates, the dynamics of employment
may be contrasted with the decisions of conflict resolution in business enterprises may
unionized businesses to adopt grievance pro- be analogized to the dynamics of employee
cedures only when ‘forced’ to do so through performance evaluation. While such formal
collective negotiations with union represen- evaluations are typically conducted annually
tatives, that is, reactive decisions. More- or in some cases, semi-annually, researchers
over and not widely recognized, grievance and practitioners emphasize that informal
procedures in non-union businesses have a performance evaluation is a more or less
broader scope of employee coverage than continuous process, especially when it comes
grievance procedures in unionized businesses. to supervisors and managers providing per-
In the latter, only those employees who formance evaluation feedback to employees
are represented by a union are eligible (Antonioni, 1994). Similarly, and despite the
to use the grievance procedure. In the presence of formal grievance and grievance-
former, there is no collective bargaining like systems in business enterprises, most
agreement so that employee eligibility to employment conflict resolution in such enter-
use the grievance procedure is bounded prises occurs informally in a more or less
only by the specifications of the particular continuous process of information exchange,
procedure adopted by a non-union business. feedback, and settlement.
Most non-union businesses have been rather In unionized enterprises, the grievance
expansive in this regard, and an instructive procedure has evolved over a long period
example is provided by Federal Express, a to the point where it may be characterized
prominent global overnight delivery com- as ‘mature’. In this procedure, the employee
pany. This company’s formal three-step represents him or herself only at the first
Guaranteed Fair Treatment (GFT) procedure stage of and does so by putting the grievance
applies to all employees except those who in writing. Thereafter, at subsequent steps,
occupy top management positions (Lewin, the employee is represented by a shop
1997). steward or grievance committee person or
Whether in unionized or non-union set- other union official or combinations thereof
tings, the presence of a formal grievance depending on how far the particular grievance
procedure implies that employee grievances proceeds through the grievance process. At
are put in writing and then progress through each of these steps, moreover, the company
the various steps of the procedure to set- is represented by successively higher levels
tlement. In fact, however, most employee of supervisory and management personnel
grievances never see the light of day, or combinations thereof. If a unionized
at least in terms of being reduced to employee’s grievance is not settled at the
writing. Instead, most employee grievances lower or intermediate steps of the procedure,
are taken up and ‘settled’ during informal the grievance is taken to and settled in arbitra-
discussions with management, typically with tion, which as noted earlier is the final step in
the employee’s immediate supervisor. In virtually all unionized grievance procedures.
this regard, research on unionized grievance In this setting, the costs of grievance handling,
procedures estimates that for every one processing and arbitration are shared equally
grievance that is actually reduced to writing by (that is, split between) the union and the
and that enters the formal grievance system, company.
RESOLVING CONFLICT 451

In non-union enterprises, by contrast, Research on grievance filing in both unionized


grievance procedures are more varied and may and non-union settings partially supports this
be characterized as being in a ‘developmental’ presumption. Specifically, the grievance filing
stage of evolution. There are typically fewer rate among unionized employees is approx-
steps in non-union than in unionized grievance imately 10 per cent, while the grievance
procedures, a non-union employee is consid- filing rate among non-union employees is
erably more likely than a unionized employee approximately five per cent (Lewin and
to represent him or herself beyond the first Peterson, 1988; Lewin, 1997). But in light
step of the grievance procedure, arbitration of the decline of unionism and grievance
constitutes the final step in approximately procedure coverage of unionized employees
20 per cent of non-union grievance procedures and the growth of and scope of employee
compared to about 97 per cent of unionized coverage by grievance procedures in non-
grievance procedures, and the non-union com- union enterprises, the vast bulk of grievances
pany typically pays all the costs of arbitration are now actually filed by non-union rather than
compared to the aforementioned split cost by unionized employees. When it comes to the
in unionized companies. The variation in progression of grievance cases through and
non-union grievance procedures encompasses the settlement of grievances at various steps of
both between-company and within-company grievance procedures, there are no significant
variation. Regarding between-company vari- differences between unionized and non-union
ation, some non-union company grievance employees. In particular, about 60 per cent
procedures culminate in arbitration, others of both unionized and non-union employee
culminate in peer review, and still others grievances are settled at the first step of the
culminate in an executive level decision, grievance procedure, about 25 per cent are
including in some instances by the Chief settled at the second step, about 13 per cent
Executive Officer (CEO). Further, some non- at the third step, and about two per cent at the
union grievance procedures specify that a final step (Lewin and Peterson, 1999; Lewin,
grievant may be represented by a third 1997).
party, such as an attorney or a co-worker, On balance, the fact that most grievances
at certain steps of the procedure. Regarding filed by both unionized and non-union
within-company variation, some non-union employees are settled at the early steps of the
companies have adopted one grievance pro- grievance procedure seems to accord closely
cedure covering all employees, while other with notions of industrial justice, specifically
non-union companies have adopted multiple that grievances should be settled swiftly and
grievance procedures, each of which covers as close as possible to their sources of origin.
a particular employee group or groups. This conclusion, however, is based largely on
A prominent example of the latter is TRW, a extant research into what might best be termed
diversified manufacturer of automotive parts, micro-level employment conflict resolution –
advanced electronic technology, and informa- that is, employee-employer conflicts that are
tion services, which has a peer review type resolved internally. A rather different con-
grievance procedure for non-union employees clusion emerges regarding what might best
of one of the company’s major business be termed macro-level or external employ-
units, and a grievance procedure culminating ment conflict resolution. In North American,
in arbitration for non-union employees of European, and Asian nations, numerous laws
another of the company’s major business units regulate certain aspects of private sector
(Colvin, 2004). employment and employment relationships,
By definition, non-union employees do not including hiring, compensation, promotion,
have union officials to represent them in termination, and the workplace environment.
grievance processing, and might therefore Chief among these laws are those that seek
be presumed to be significantly less likely to prevent employment discrimination on the
than unionized employees to file grievances. basis of race, color, national origin, religion,
452 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

gender, age, and disability. If an employee mediator has no power to make or enforce a
believes that he or she has been subject to grievance settlement, whereas the arbitrator
discrimination on one or more of these bases, has exactly such power. The leading US
the employee may file a lawsuit alleging and example of grievance mediation occurred
seeking redress of such discrimination. This during the 1980s in the highly unionized coal
litigation could conceivably be pursued all the mining industry. This initiative was under-
way to a court verdict. taken in the wake of numerous wildcat strikes
The likelihood of such an external adju- and widespread employee dissatisfaction with
dication process actually occurring is quite the industry’s long-standing grievance arbi-
low, however, and is becoming even lower. tration process. With the assistance of the
In the US, for example, the Supreme Court US Department of Labor, unions and coal
recently ruled that the entire range of companies in certain coalfield areas agreed
anti-discrimination in employment laws is to an experiment in which selected third-step
subject to arbitration provisions contained grievances would be informally discussed
in employment contracts between employers with a mediator during a mediation confer-
and employees. So strong is this deferral to ence. If these grievances were not settled
arbitration doctrine that it seemingly requires during the conference, the mediator would
the ‘diversion of all employment litiga- then issue an on-the-spot advisory opinion
tion…into an employer-designed arbitration indicating how the grievances would likely
procedure from which there is no right of be settled in arbitration. The main results of
appeal or only very limited possibility of court this experiment were that some 90 per cent
review’ (Colvin, 2003). Such internal arbitra- of mediated grievances were settled without
tion is the leading example of what has come arbitration, the time to decision and cost of
to be known as alternative dispute resolution decision were significantly lower in mediated
(ADR) – meaning an alternative to external than in arbitrated settlements, and the parties’
litigation (Lipsky et al., 2003). It is therefore satisfaction with grievance mediation was
not surprising that non-union employers have significantly higher than their satisfaction
increasingly adopted arbitration type internal with grievance arbitration (Feuille, 1999;
employment conflict resolution procedures. Goldberg, 1982).
Analytically, these adoption decisions can This particular coal mining experience
be seen to be primarily reactive, that is, spurred additional grievance mediation exper-
taken in response to litigation or litigation iments and activities in the US private
threats, rather than being primarily strategic and public sectors. Prominent in this regard
or proactive in nature. are the non-profit Mediation Research and
Another type of ADR that has grown in Education Project (MREP) and the US Federal
popularity, especially in the US, Canada, and Mediation and Conciliation Service (FMCS),
Britain, is grievance mediation. Here, a third which provide direct grievance mediation
party assists the two direct parties to an services to labor and management as well as
employment relationship conflict by training to union and management officials
in how to resolve employment relationship
1) communicating settlement proposals from one to conflict without third party intervention –
the other direct party; so-called ‘preventive mediation’ (Feuille,
2) posing one or another settlement proposal to both 1999). Though data on grievance mediation
parties; or in non-union settings are sketchy, it appears
3) offering an opinion about how a particular that grievance mediation is becoming more
grievance would be settled if it were to be common in ADR procedures involving non-
arbitrated. union companies and employees (Lipsky
et al., 2003). This said, the available data indi-
The key difference between grievance medi- cate that grievance mediation remains much
ation and grievance arbitration is that the less prominent that grievance arbitration
RESOLVING CONFLICT 453

as a mechanism for resolving employment hired by the parties jointly in the case of
relationship conflict in the US. unionized employees and by the employer
In Britain, employees who believe that they alone in the case of non-union employees.
have been unfairly dismissed from their jobs Despite its foray into grievance mediation,
may seek redress by filing written claims with the US FMCS continues to devote most
the Central Office of Industrial Tribunals or of its mediation – conciliation – efforts to
one of its regional offices within three months attempting to resolve strikes and lockouts
of dismissal. Under the 1999 Employment over new collective bargaining agreements,
Relations Act, such complainants must have though it has no mandatory settlement power
been continuously employed for a minimum in this regard. Probably the closest US analogy
of one year in an occupation covered by the to the British public tribunal approach to
law, and must also not have reached normal unfair workplace dismissal is the set of
retirement age. Once registered, such claims individual wrongful termination cases that
are forwarded to the Advisory, Conciliation have been heard and decided by certain courts.
and Arbitration Service (ACAS), which is Such cases, however, pale in comparison to
statutorily obliged to pursue a conciliated the much larger volume of cases that US
settlement between the parties and only courts have deferred to private arbitrators
thereafter (if conciliation is rejected by one for decisions – cases that largely involve
or another party or is unsuccessful) conduct a non-union employees.
full arbitration hearing. The volume of unfair
dismissal claims filed with British industrial
Theories of employment
tribunals rose almost three-fold during the
relationship conflict and resolution
1990s to more than 80,000 annually, and is
likely to rise even more markedly in light While some scholars have criticized grievance
of recent legislative relaxation of the criteria procedure research, per se, for being largely
for filing such claims. Recent evidence shows atheoretical (Bemmels and Foley, 1996),
about 37 per cent of British unfair dismissal there are in fact numerous extant theories
claims were settled through conciliation, that of employment relationship conflict (Lewin,
another 30 per cent were withdrawn by 1999). Chief among these are systems the-
complainants, and that most of the remainder, ory, exit-voice-loyalty theory, organizational
roughly one-third, were settled following a justice theory, compensating differentials
full tribunal hearing – meaning, arbitration. theory, due process theory, organizational
Moreover, these settlements were reached punishment-discipline theory, displacement
rather quickly, especially by US standards, theory, and strategic human resource theory.
with 52 per cent of all British unfair Grievance procedure systems theory
dismissal cases dealt with within 12 weeks focuses on interrelationships among key
and 92 per cent dealt with within 26 weeks antecedent, process and outcome variables.
of their receipt by the tribunals (Knight and As its name implies, research framed by this
Latreille, 2001). theoretical modeling has found systematic
By and large, conciliation is a synonym for relationships among characteristics of union
mediation, and therefore the British and US and management organizations, scope of
approaches to employment conflict resolution grievance issues and stage of grievance
or, more narrowly, claims of unfair dismissal settlement, and union (and management)
from work seem identical. In fact, however, grievance win-loss rates (Lewin and Peterson,
the British invest public authorities with the 1988). This framework and related empirical
responsibility for and power to settle unfair research also show that the parties involved in
dismissal claims involving private parties – grievance activity learn from this experience
employers and (former) employees – whereas in that they alter their subsequent behavior
in the US most such settlements are reached based on ‘feedback’ from prior grievance
by the parties themselves or by arbitrators dynamics and settlement (Knight, 1986).
454 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Further, grievance procedure systems theory performance evaluation, pay and promotion.
has been used to frame and measure post- An important finding from these studies is
grievance settlement outcomes, as examples, that employee perception of the fairness
employee job performance, internal mobility or justness of a decision process has a
(for instance, promotion), work attendance, significantly stronger effect than employee
and turnover. perception of the fairness or justness of a
Exit-voice-loyalty theory (Hirschman, decision outcome on employee perception of
1970) leads to the provocative hypotheses the overall fairness or justice of organizational
that employee voice will be negatively decisions (Sheppard et al., 1992). Stated
correlated with employee exit from (for succinctly, the decision process matters more
instance, quitting) the organization and that than the decision outcome when it comes
employee loyalty will be positively correlated to perceptions of organizational justice. This
with voice – and thus also negatively conclusion applies to and can be drawn
correlated with exit. Inferentially, therefore, as well from grievance procedure research
it is relatively more loyal employees who which finds that, in both unionized and non-
will file grievances and be more likely to union settings, employee perceived fairness
remain employed. Considerable empirical of the grievance process is significantly
research has been conducted using exit- negatively associated with employee intent
voice-loyalty theory (Freeman and Medoff, to exit, and significantly positively associated
1984), the main findings from which show with employee satisfaction with the grievance
that employee loyalty is indeed negatively procedure – and with the employer (Boroff
correlated with exit but also that employee and Lewin, 1997; Lewin and Boroff, 1996).
loyalty is negatively correlated with both exit Compensating differentials theory basi-
and voice (Boroff and Lewin, 1997; Lewin cally argues that employees compare the cost
and Boroff, 1996). Hence, some scholars and effectiveness of filing grievances with the
have concluded that relatively more loyal cost and effectiveness of alternative behav-
employees are prone to suffer in silence iors, notably quitting (Ichniowski and Lewin,
even when they have experienced unfair 1987). Empirical tests of this rational, utility
workplace treatment (Rusbelt, et al., 1988). maximization-based theory have shown that
Despite these rather contrary findings, the employee grievance filing is significantly
notion that employees seek to exercise voice positively associated with wage premiums
only after their employment relationships paid by current employers and with local labor
have deteriorated may be the most enduring market unemployment rates (Cappelli and
insight drawn from exit-voice-loyalty theory Chauvin, 1991). These findings can be readily
(an insight that will be taken up again in the integrated with exit-voice-loyalty theory by
next section). interpreting them to mean that employees will
Organizational justice theory, which was be more likely to file grievances – exercise
first used in studies of the criminal justice voice – when the cost of exit is relatively
system, importantly distinguishes between high, as signaled by lower-paying and/or
procedural justice and distributive justice meager alternative employment opportuni-
(Lind and Tyler, 1988). The former refers ties. Further, these findings are consistent
to the extent to which a decision making with those derived from organizational justice
process is perceived as fair or just by those theory-based and also expectancy theory-
subject to the decision, whereas the latter based grievance procedure research, which
refers to the extent to which a decision similarly concludes that employees compare
outcome is perceived as fair or just by those the costs and benefits of grievance filing with
subject to the decision. In the employment other alternatives in deciding whether or not
relationship, organizational justice theory has to file grievances (Klass, 1989).2
been used to analyze a wide range of decisions Industrial relations-due process theory
involving, as examples, work assignment, basically models grievance activity as a
RESOLVING CONFLICT 455

component of the larger collective bargaining that warnings to and dismissals of certain
relationship between union and management. employees signal to employees and managers
In particular, grievance activity has been more broadly the types of workplace behavior
found to increase significantly as the time to that are inconsistent with or opposed to
renegotiate a collective bargaining agreement prevailing organizational rules and norms
draws nearer, and to decline significantly after (O’Reilly and Weitz, 1980).
a new agreement has been reached (Lewin Displacement theory proposes that the time
and Peterson, 1988; Chamberlain and Kuhn, devoted to grievance activity – grievance
1965; Kuhn, 1961). Further, some of these filing, processing, and settlement – basically
grievances may be non-meritorious in the supplants productive work time. This theory
sense that they are fundamentally intended to is empirically supported by studies showing
influence or alter the parties’ relative bargain- that grievance activity is significantly neg-
ing power. From this perspective, grievance atively associated with manufacturing plant
activity represents a form of fractional or productivity and product quality, and signif-
continuous bargaining between the parties in icantly positively associated with labor costs
which due process objectives that were only (Ichniowski, 1992, 1986; Katz et al., 1983;
partially achieved in collective bargaining are Kleiner et al., 1995). It is further supported
pursued through grievance filing, processing, by research showing that labor-management
and settlement. A limitation of this theory is cooperation initiatives are significantly neg-
that it de-emphasizes the conflict that occurs atively associated with grievance filing rates
in day-to-day employment relationships and (Katz et al. , 1985). The main weakness of
that can be distinguished from the periodic this theory, however, is that it inferentially
conflict that attends the negotiation of a new postulates that the optimum level of grievance
collective bargaining agreement. activity is zero (because all grievance activity
Organizational punishment-industrial dis- represents lost work time). Stated differently,
cipline theory basically treats the grievance this theory gives scant attention to the
procedure as a rule enforcement mecha- potential lost work time and productivity that
nism, with a marked emphasis on sanctions may emanate from ‘felt’ grievances that are
for ‘deviant’ workplace and organizational never made manifest.
behavior (Arvey and Jones, 1985). This theory Strategic human resource theory can
appears equally applicable to unionized and be distinguished from other employment
non-union employment contexts, and more relationship conflict theories by its strong
than most other employment relationship emphasis on progressive or ‘high employee
conflict theories calls attention to post- involvement’ practices. These practices typ-
grievance settlement behavior and outcomes. ically include selective hiring, employment
For example, research by Lewin and Peterson continuity, team-based work, variable pay,
(1988), Lewin (1987) and Olson-Buchanan and information-sharing with employees,
(1996) finds that, following grievance set- which are modeled as a set, bundle or
tlement, grievance filers are more likely package that perforce reduces employment
than non-filers to experience higher turnover relationship conflict (Pfeffer, 1998). The
rates and lower job performance ratings, underlying reasoning in this regard is that
promotion rates and work attendance rates. the more employees are involved in decision-
US, Canadian, British, and Italian studies making and managing their own work –
find that employees reinstated to their jobs self-management – the lower the likeli-
following or as an explicit condition of hood that employment relationship conflict
grievance settlement subsequently experience will occur. Indeed, some versions of high
lower job satisfaction and higher turnover involvement human resource management
rates than non-grievance filers (Malinowski, include a grievance procedure as part of the
1981; Barnacle, 1991; Dickens et al., 1984; package (Huselid, 1995). Several studies have
Rocella, 1989). Still other research shows found that high involvement management
456 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

practices are significantly positively related to Grievance procedure dynamics


employee productivity, negatively related to Conceptually and empirically, the existence or
employee turnover, and positively related availability of a grievance procedure can be
to organizational performance, specifically, distinguished from the use of the procedure.
market value, return on invested capital, From the perspective of employment conflict
product quality, and production line ‘up time’ resolution, especially in North America and
(Huselid, 1995; MacDuffie, 1995; Ichniowski Europe, researchers and practitioners largely
et al., 1997; Arthur, 1994; Mitchell et al., agree that a grievance procedure that is avail-
1990). able but not used is an ineffective procedure,
Among all of these theories of employment likely indicating that conflict is being sup-
relationship conflict, strategic human resource pressed or that employees fear retaliation from
theory most clearly envisions and positions using the grievance procedure.3 Similarly, a
the grievance procedure as a reactive voice grievance procedure that is overused, that
mechanism, both in unionized and non- is, flooded with grievances, is regarded as
union settings (Kaminski, 1999). By contrast, an ineffective procedure, likely signaling the
strategic human resource theory envisions and absence of workplace supervision/ manage-
positions high involvement management as a ment or employee misunderstanding of the
positive voice mechanism in which conflict scope and purposes of the procedure.4
either does not occur or, more realistically, Empirical evidence indicates that grievance
occurs but can be anticipated and dealt with procedure usage rarely displays either of the
‘proactively’. Such proactive treatment may aforementioned extremes. Rather, in the US,
be rendered through work-centered teams the overall average grievance filing rate –
or joint labor-management committees or the number of grievances filed annually by
informal discussions between supervisors and 100 employees – is approximately 10 per cent
employees or employee forums and on- in unionized settings and five per cent in
line chat rooms or even through grievance non-union settings. In terms of industry
mediation. From a temporal perspective, variation, Lewin and Peterson (1999, 1988)
therefore, strategic human resource theory found annual average grievance filing rates
emphasizes early stage conflict manifestation among unionized US employees ranging
and resolution, in contrast to most other between 7.8 per cent in retail trade (that
theories of employment relationship con- is, department stores) and 16.3 per cent
flict that emphasize employment relationship in steel manufacturing. Among unionized
deterioration, displacement, discipline and a Canadian employees, Bemmels (1994) found
late stage, reactive search for organizational annual average grievance filing rates rang-
justice. ing between 0.6 per cent in education
and 48.2 per cent in railway transporta-
tion. Further, Cappelli and Chauvin (1991)
Employment conflict resolution
found that grievance filing rates among US
effectiveness
unionized employees varied significantly by
While there are myriad ways of assessing the industry labor market conditions but not by
effectiveness of employment conflict resolu- industry technology.
tion systems, methods, and practices, there is While grievance filing among non-union
not a firm consensus among researchers or employees occurs about half as often
practitioners about what exactly constitutes as among unionized employees, there is
such effectiveness. To bring coherence to also considerable variation in non-union
this matter, employment conflict resolution employee grievance filing rates. For exam-
effectiveness will be considered in terms ple, in a US-based five company study,
of grievance (and grievance-like) procedure Lewin (1997) found non-union employee
dynamics as well as individual and organiza- annual grievance filing rates ranging between
tional outcomes. 3.8 and 6.2 per cent, and in a more recent
RESOLVING CONFLICT 457

single-company study (Lewin, 2005) found subject to expedited arbitration, defined as


that non-union employee annual grievance the skipping of certain intermediate grievance
filing rates ranged between 4.6 and 8.2 per cent processing steps, or when subject to grievance
over a 50-year period. These findings indicate mediation.
not only that non-union grievance procedures While swifter justice may be preferable
are actually used by employees (rather then to slower justice in grievance settlement,
simply being available), but also that the speed of grievance settlement, per se, is a
volume of grievance activity is considerably quite limited measure of grievance procedure
greater among non-union than among union- effectiveness. Several scholars (for example,
ized US employees. This is because of the Gordon and Bowlby, 1988) have shown that
continuing decline of US union membership perceived fairness of grievance processing
and collectively bargained grievance proce- and grievance decisions are significantly
dures on the one hand, and the continuing more important than speed of settlement to
growth of management-determined grievance grievants’ overall assessment of the grievance
procedures among non-union companies on procedure. Clark and Gallagher (1988) found
the other hand. Hence, if actual grievance the perceived effectiveness of the grievance
procedure usage is taken as a measure of procedure in terms of workplace equity,
employment conflict resolution effectiveness, fairness of grievance processing, and extent
then recent experience with both unionized to which the grievance procedure represents
and non-union grievance procedures indicates employee interests to be significantly pos-
that these procedures are at least moderately itively associated with employee attitudes
effective. toward the grievance procedure, whereas
A particularly widely used measure of speed of settlement was unrelated to such
grievance procedure effectiveness is speed attitudes. Clark et al. (1990) and Bemmels
of settlement. A standard maxim in the area (1995) found that union member attitudes
of employment relationship conflict is that toward and assessment of grievance proce-
such conflict should be settled as quickly dure effectiveness are strongly influenced by
and as close as possible to its source of their commitment to the union, commitment
origin. From this perspective, quicker lower- to the employer, and dual commitment, but
level grievance settlement is preferable to not by speed of grievance settlement.
slower, higher-level grievance settlement – Grievance procedure dynamics conclude
though clearly speed and level of grievance with grievance decisions therefore the
settlement are highly correlated. Studies of grievance decision win-loss rate may be
grievance settlement in both unionized and considered a measure of employment
non-union settings find that the vast bulk of conflict resolution effectiveness – but
formal grievances are settled at the first two largely a one-sided measure. A priori,
(typically, out of four) steps of the grievance employee perceptions (ratings) of grievance
procedure, with only about two to three per procedure effectiveness can be expected to
cent of grievances settled at the final step. be positively correlated with the percentage
Regarding speed of grievance settlement, of grievances decided in favor of employees,
Lewin and Peterson (1999) found an average and management perceptions of grievance
of 52 days to grievance settlement in four procedure effectiveness can be expected to be
large unionized companies during the 1990s, positively correlated with the percentage of
with the average days to settlement having grievances decided in favor of management.
declined by about 25 per cent from the 1980s. Surprisingly, there is scant empirical evidence
Similarly, among non-union companies with that bears upon these propositions. Instead,
grievance procedures most grievances are empirical work in this area finds that the
settled about 45 days after their initial filing employee grievance decision win rate rises
(Lewin, 2004). Grievance settlements are with the level of grievance settlement.
reached more quickly when grievances are For example, in a study of five non-union
458 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

companies, Lewin (1997, 1992) found that turnover rates among these two employee
the employee grievance decision win rate groups. The researchers found no significant
rose from about 40 per cent at the lowest between-group differences on these measures
step to about 60 per cent at the highest step during the pre-grievance and grievance filing
of the grievance procedure. Moreover, in a periods, but found significant differences
study of four unionized companies, Lewin during the one-to three-year post-grievance
and Peterson (1999) found that grievances settlement periods. Specifically, and com-
over disciplinary actions were far more likely pared with non-filers, grievance filers had sig-
than grievances over all other issues to be nificantly lower job performance ratings and
taken to and decided at the highest step of promotion rates (though not work attendance
the grievance procedure (that is, arbitration), rates), during the period following grievance
thereby suggesting a more parsimonious, settlement.5 Further, post-grievance settle-
issue-based framing of grievance decision ment employee voluntary turnover rates
win-loss rates in the parties’ assessments of were significantly higher among grievants
grievance procedure effectiveness. Even this than among non-grievants. Identical analyses
framing, however, does not address the matter conducted among samples of supervisors of
of whether employment conflict resolution is grievance filers and non-filers in the same
more effective when there is a 50-50 overall unionized organizations yielded closely simi-
grievance decision win-loss rate than when a lar results. That is, whereas as the two groups
more unbalanced grievance decision win-loss of supervisors did not differ significantly with
rate prevails. respect to job performance ratings, promotion
rates and work attendance rates during the
Post-grievance settlement outcomes pre-grievance and grievance filing periods,
A broadened perspective on employment supervisors of grievants had significantly
conflict resolution effectiveness is offered by lower job performance ratings and promotion
extant research on post-grievance settlement rates (though, again, not work attendance
outcomes. Much of this work focuses on rates) and significantly higher turnover rates
employee performance, internal mobility and than supervisors of non-grievants during the
retention following grievance settlement, on period following grievance settlement. In
management reprisal against grievants, and particular, supervisors of grievants had signif-
on the reinstatement of dismissed employees. icantly higher involuntary turnover rates than
Consequently, this research shifts the focus supervisors of non-grievants, meaning that
of grievance procedure study and prac- supervisors of grievants were significantly
tice from grievance procedure dynamics to more likely than supervisors of non-grievants
the consequences of grievance procedure to be terminated from employment following
involvement for employees and to the grievance settlement.
behavior of management following grievance This same research design was used by
settlement. Lewin (2005, 1997, 1992, 1987) to study
In a series of studies, Lewin and Peterson post-grievance settlement outcomes in non-
(1999, 1988) analyzed post-grievance settle- union organizations. The grievance proce-
ment outcomes in four unionized organiza- dures in these organizations varied in several
tions over two separate three-year periods. respects, especially the final settlement step.
The quasi-experimental research design used Nevertheless, the findings from this research
in these studies permitted comparisons are strikingly similar to the aforementioned
between samples of grievance filers and non- findings regarding post-grievance settlement
filers of employee job performance ratings, outcomes in unionized organizations. In
promotion rates and work attendance rates particular, and once again using matched
during pre-grievance, grievance filing and samples of grievance filers and non-filers in
post-grievance settlement periods as well each organization, there were no significant
as comparisons of post-grievance settlement differences between these two employee
RESOLVING CONFLICT 459

groups in job performance ratings, promotion to the probability of an employee filing a


rates and work attendance rates during the pre- grievance (including when employee loyalty
grievance and grievance filing periods. During to the employer was controlled), and from
the (one to three year) post-grievance settle- Lewin’s (2005) study of a large non-union
ment period, however, grievance filers had aerospace company that found a similarly
significantly lower job performance ratings significant inverse relationship.
and promotion rates and significantly higher There is, however, an alternative to the
voluntary and involuntary turnover rates than management reprisal explanation of grievance
non-filers. A very similar pattern of post- filing and post-grievance settlement out-
grievance settlement outcome differences comes, which may be termed ‘revealed
prevailed as between supervisors of grievants performance’. The argument underlying this
and supervisors of non-grievants in these explanation is that grievants and their super-
non-union organizations. The supervisors of visors are systematically poorer performers
grievants, who did not differ significantly than non-grievants and their supervisors. For
from the supervisors of non-grievants on any this argument to hold sway, and recalling
of the outcome variables measured prior to that grievants and their supervisors do not
and during grievance filing, had significantly differ significantly from non-grievants and
lower job performance ratings and promotion their supervisors in terms of job performance
rates and significantly higher voluntary and ratings, promotion rates and work attendance
involuntary turnover rates during the post- rates prior to grievance settlement, the actual
grievance settlement period. filing and processing of grievances must
This body of research accords most closely cause management to pay closer attention to
with employment relationship conflict sys- the assessment of employee and supervisor
tems theory, exit-voice-loyalty theory, and job performance. If and as this occurs,
organizational punishment-discipline theory. management discovers ex-post that grievants
In particular, the research supports the notion and their supervisors are (systematically)
of systematic relationships among grievance poorer performers than non-grievants and
procedure antecedent, process and outcome their supervisors.
variables, indicates that grievance proce- There is some theoretical and empirical
dure involvement contributes to additional support for this alternative explanation. For
deterioration of employment relationships, example, the shock theory of unionism
and strongly implies that participants in the posits that the unionization of a firm’s
grievance process are punished for their employees spurs the management of that
involvement in such activity. Baldly stated, firm to improve organizational performance,
management appears ultimately to exercise and to do so in such ways or to such an
reprisal against employee-grievants and the extent that the value added from improved
supervisors of grievants. This conclusion is organizational performance at least offsets
further supported by Klass and DeNisi’s the costs (typically, pay and fringe benefit
(1989) research, which found that employees costs) of unionization (Rees, 1977). By
who file grievances against their direct analogous reasoning, the filing of grievances
supervisors subsequently receive significantly by employees shocks management into taking
lower job performance ratings than employ- actions that improve organizational perfor-
ees who file grievances over management mance, but in this instance by paying closer
policies. Still further evidence for the manage- attention to performance evaluation and by
ment reprisal explanation of post-grievance terminating employees and supervisors whose
settlement outcomes is provided by Boroff ‘revealed performance’ is low. Experimental
and Lewin’s (1997) study of a large unionized support for this alternative explanation is
telecommunications company, which found provided by Olson-Buchanan (1997, 1996),
that employee fear of reprisal for filing whose laboratory studies found that grievants
grievances was significantly inversely related had significantly poorer job performance
460 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

after grievance settlement than comparably story, or both. On its face, employee rein-
matched non-grievants. On the basis of this statement seems especially consistent with
finding, Olson-Buchanan (1996) concludes organizational justice theory, but on deeper
that because conflict between an employee reflection is perhaps most consistent with exit-
and her supervisor serves to reduce the voice-loyalty and organizational punishment-
employee’s job performance, there may be discipline theories. This is because reinstated
‘a real difference between grievance filers’ employees appear for the most part to
and non-filers’ [job performance] behavior’ experience additional deterioration of their
(p. 62). employment relationships, and to be more
The literature on reinstatement of dismissed likely than continuing employees to be
employees can be interpreted to support disciplined by and voluntarily quit (exit) their
either the management reprisal explanation employers. More broadly, this reasoning is
or the revealed performance explanation of consistent with evidence drawn from North
post-grievance settlement outcomes. Most America and to a lesser extent Europe,
such reinstatement occurs as a result of which shows that monetary settlements of
arbitration awards in grievance cases, so individual employment relationship conflict
that considerably more is known about the are far more prevalent, and perhaps more
reinstatement and post-reinstatement experi- effective, than reinstatement to work and the
ence of unionized than non-union employees. intended resumption of original employment
While reinstatement of dismissed employees relationships.
occurs in about half of sampled arbitration
awards, the proportion of dismissed employ- Grievance procedures and organizational
ees actually returning to work following performance
reinstatement decisions ranges widely, from Beyond their effects on individual employ-
negligible in Britain (Knight and Latreille, ees, supervisors, and managers, grievance
2001; Dickens et al., 1984) to an estimated procedures have certain consequences for
46 per cent in a Canadian study, (Malinowski, organizational performance. In this regard,
1981) to an estimated 88 per cent in a US study the aforementioned distinction between the
(Barnacle, 1991).6 Reinstated employees are availability and use of a grievance procedure
often reluctant to return to work and often (or equivalent employment conflict resolution
have relatively low job performance and mechanism) is especially relevant. Succinctly
relatively high turnover after they return stated, and to preview the main conclusion of
to work (Bemmels and Foley, 1996). In this section, the availability of a grievance or
these respects, studies by Rocella (1989) grievance-like procedure as part of a bundle
and Shantz and Rogow (1984) found post- of high involvement type human resource
reinstatement employee turnover rates of 28 management practices has been shown to be
per cent and 55 per cent, respectively, during positively associated with such organizational
the two-year period following reinstatement performance measures as market value, rate of
of dismissed employees to their jobs, and a return on invested capital, productivity, and
study by Labig et al. (1985) found that post- product quality, whereas the actual use of
reinstatement job performance was signifi- a grievance or grievance-like procedure has
cantly positively associated with employees’ been shown to be negatively associated with
prior (pre-dismissal) job performance. these and other measures of organizational
On balance, the extant literature on performance.
employee reinstatement to work following To illustrate, Katz et al. (1983) found the
grievance settlement, as with the literature grievance rate to be significantly positively
on post-grievance settlement employee job associated with labor costs and significantly
performance, internal mobility, and turnover, negatively associated with productivity and
can be interpreted to support a management product quality in a sample of US automobile
reprisal story or a revealed performance manufacturing plants. These researchers
RESOLVING CONFLICT 461

interpreted their findings to support the this index and several measures of financial
concept of a displacement effect, meaning performance among 495 US-based busi-
that time devoted to grievance filing and nesses. These researchers found significant
settlement is time taken away from productive positive relationships between the index and
activity, thereby resulting in lower plant return on assets, return on investment and
performance. In a related longitudinal study revenue per employee in these businesses.
of automobile manufacturing, Northsworthy In a related study, Huselid (1995) included
and Zabala (1985) found the grievance rate the percentage of employees covered by a
to be significantly negatively associated with grievance procedure in an index of high-
total factor productivity and significantly involvement human resource management
positively related to unit production costs. In practices, and found a significant positive
studies of paper manufacturing that controlled relationship between this index and employee
for the effects of other variables, Ichniowski productivity, a significant negative rela-
(1992, 1986) found a significant negative tionship between this index and employee
relationship between the grievance rate and turnover, and a significant positive relation-
monthly production in nine unionized paper ship between this index and company market
mills over a six-year period. Instructively, value and return on capital investment. In
Katz, et al. (1985) found that a quality a study of steel manufacturing, Ichniowski
of working life improvement program sig- et al. (1997) included the presence of a
nificantly reduced the grievance rate and formal grievance procedure in their index
thus the displacement effect in automobile of an innovative bundle of human resource
manufacturing, and Ichniowski (1992) found management practices, and found significant
that a labor-management cooperation initia- positive relationships between this index and
tive significantly reduced the grievance rate plant up time, productivity, and product
and significantly improved the labor relations quality. Similar findings have been produced
climate and plant performance in paper by Arthur (1994, 1992) and MacDuffie (1995)
manufacturing. These findings are closely in their studies of steel and automobile
consistent with those of Belman (1992), manufacturing, respectively, all of which
who concluded that employment relationship are empirically consistent with conceptual
conflict measured by the grievance rate has arguments advanced by Levine (1995) and
significant negative effects on manufacturing Eaton and Voos (1994, 1992) for the pos-
performance, and with a case study of New itive effects of innovative human resource
United Motor Manufacturing, Incorporated management practices, especially enhanced
(NUMMI), conducted by Levine (1995), that employee participation in decision making, on
attributed improved manufacturing perfor- organizational performance.
mance to lower grievance rates. Taken as From this research on the grievance
whole, this research provides strong evidence procedure as a mechanism for employment
that grievance procedure usage/activity is conflict resolution, one conclusion appears
significantly negatively associated with orga- dominant, namely, the presence or availabil-
nizational performance. ity of a grievance procedure is positively
Another substantial body of research, associated with organizational performance,
however, indicates that the availability of whereas actual use of a grievance procedure –
a grievance or grievance-like employment grievance activity – is negatively associated
conflict resolution procedure is significantly with organizational performance.
positively associated with organizational per-
formance. To illustrate, Mitchell et al. (1990)
Future directions: a research
constructed an index of human resource
roadmap
management practices that included the
presence of a formal grievance procedure, A major limitation of employment conflict
and then analyzed the relationship between resolution research is that some, perhaps most,
462 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

employment relationship conflict is not made For employees who have few or no
manifest through the filing of formal written alternative employment opportunities, and
grievances. In both unionized and non-union for relatively long service employees who
organizations, it appears that only relatively are tied to their employers through deferred
small proportions of actual conflicts enter compensation, pension benefit accumulation
into and are settled through formal grievance and other ‘handcuffs’, quitting and seeking
and grievance like-systems. This, in turn, alternative employment as a solution to
suggests that even the strongest findings from deteriorated employment relationships is a
employment relationship conflict research are limited or non-existent option. While, con-
fundamentally limited by what may be termed ceptually, such employees can seek redress
the omitted or unobserved variables problem. of employment-related grievances through
If formal grievance filing and settlement formal grievance filing, organizational justice
indeed represent only the tip of the employ- and organizational punishment-discipline the-
ment relationship conflict iceberg, then a ory and research imply that these employees
major research challenge is to make greater will choose silence – suffering in silence,
use of observation, participant-observation as some put it – as the dominant response
and other primary research methods that to employment relationship conflict.7 In this
potentially permit greater documentation and regard, a challenge to researchers is to
analysis of the informal settlement of employ- document and assess the extent to which
ment relationship conflict. silence in the face of employment relationship
Following strategic human resource theory, conflict is, on the one hand, an effective
low grievance rates imply that employ- coping mechanism, and, on the other hand, a
ment relationship conflict is anticipated costly suppression mechanism that generates
and proactively managed through the use unanticipated deviant behavior, including
of high involvement practices which, in workplace and family violence.
turn, positively contribute to organizational The argument that grievance filing shocks
performance (see Gollan et al., 2007). management into paying closer attention
From other theoretical perspectives, how- to performance evaluation – an argument
ever, including exit-voice-loyalty theory, due offered as an explanation of empirical
process theory, compensating differentials findings regarding post-grievance settlement
theory, and displacement theory, the costs outcomes – raises an important research issue.
of making employment relationship conflict This issue is the validity and reliability of
explicit through grievance filing exceed the performance evaluation systems, methods
the benefits to be obtained there from. and techniques used by business (and non-
Consequently, employees who experience business) enterprises. It has long been known
employment relationship conflict (that is, that traditional performance evaluation in
deterioration) may ‘resolve’ such conflict which a superior (boss or manager) alone
by quitting and taking jobs elsewhere, if periodically evaluates his or her subordi-
in fact they have alternative employment nates leads to upwardly skewed rather than
opportunities. This line of reasoning under- normally distributed performance evaluation
scores another important limitation of extant ratings (Lewin and Mitchell, 1995). Newer
employment relationship conflict research, 360 degree type performance evaluation is
which is to have largely ignored the often claimed to generate relatively more valid
labor market as a protector of employee and reliable performance assessments, but if
rights. In this regard, employment-at-will, this is so and given the widespread use of
which is most often characterized as a 360 degree performance evaluation by busi-
strongly management-oriented doctrine, can ness and non-business organizations alike,
potentially serve the interests of employees the shock explanation of grievance filing and
who experience deteriorated employment post-grievance settlement outcomes appears
relationships. doubtful, perhaps even wrongheaded. A ‘test’
RESOLVING CONFLICT 463

of this shock explanation could therefore of employee rights, most employment rela-
be conducted by using performance evalu- tionship conflict research has ignored the
ation ratings to predict employee grievance potential for litigation to serve as a protector
filing, with the operating hypothesis being of employee rights.
that performance evaluation ratings will be While employment relationship conflict
significantly negatively correlated with (sub- research has shifted from being dominated
sequent) grievance filing. Such a test could be by industrial relations scholars to human
refined and potentially produce more robust resource management scholars and, more
findings if it incorporated data from traditional recently, organizational behavior scholars,
as well as 360 degree type performance and while research on labor law has largely
evaluation methods. Empirical confirmation become supplanted by research on employ-
of the aforementioned hypothesis would serve ment law, insufficient research attention has
as evidence for the shock explanation of nevertheless been paid to the vastly expanded
grievance filing, whereas empirical refutation scope of contemporary employment relation-
of the hypothesis would serve as evidence ship conflict (Lewin, 2001). Today, such con-
against the shock explanation. flict involves not only lower-level employees
While, for some, quitting deteriorated (‘organizational participants’), but middle-
employment relationships is a viable solution and especially upper-level employees as well.
to employment relationship conflict, and, for Most employees at all levels of organizations
others, suffering in silence may be an effective do not belong to unions and are therefore not
mechanism for coping with employment covered by collective bargaining contracts.
relationship conflict, still another response Ironically, however, non-union grievance
to employment relationship conflict has been procedures typically cover a far broader range
invoked by a growing segment of the work of employees, up to and often including
force, namely, litigation. In this instance, mid-level managers, than are covered by
employees and former employees seek to collectively bargained grievance procedures.
redress one or another type of employment In the US, moreover, and perhaps elsewhere,
discrimination or wrongful termination by a far larger proportion of the workforce is
suing their employers or former employers, covered by individual employment contracts
and do so by ‘employing’ an agent – a than by collective bargaining contracts. Such
plaintiff’s attorney – to represent them. In the individual employment contracts often con-
US, where separate laws ostensibly protect tain procedures for the internal resolution of
the employment rights of racial and ethnic employment-related conflict, but also provide
minorities, women, older workers, and the the basis for external litigation to settle claims
disabled, litigation to redress employment- of contractual violations brought by employee
related actions, issues and grievances has or employer. Researchers should therefore
grown enormously in recent years. While, in raise their sights a bit to focus attention on the
theory, such litigation is aimed at restoring or dynamics and outcomes of employment rela-
correcting severely deteriorated employment tionship conflict that occurs at intermediate
relationships, including by reinstatement to and higher levels of organizations irrespective
work, in reality, which is to say practice, of whether or not a grievance procedure is
most such litigation concludes with mon- the mechanism through which such conflict
etary settlements without (or in place of) resolution is pursued. In this regard, studies
reinstatement. An important research issue using samples of executive and professional
in this regard is determining the extent employment contracts would be especially
to which external litigation has supplanted helpful and potentially illuminating.
internal grievance filing and settlement as The argument that unionized and non-
an institutional mechanism for resolving union grievance procedures alike are reactive,
employment relationship conflict.8 As with ex-post type conflict resolution mechanisms
the labor market as a potential protector that ultimately exacerbate rather than mitigate
464 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

deteriorated employment relationships, and In this limited circumstance, the union (employees)
the contrasting companion argument that high would likely regard the grievance procedure as highly
involvement management enables employ- effective, whereas management would likely regard
the grievance procedure as highly ineffective.
ment relationship conflict to be anticipated 5 Other studies, however, find significant effects of
and therefore dealt with ex-ante in a relatively grievance activity on employee work attendance. For
more proactive fashion, requires broader and example, Klass et al. (1991) report a significant positive
deeper empirical investigation. In this regard, relationship during an eight-year period between
researchers should document the specific grievance filing over management policies and
employee absenteeism in a unionized public sector
ways in which employment relationship con- organization, but a significant negative relationship
flict is anticipated and resolved under varying between grievance filing over disciplinary issues and
degrees of high involvement management, employee absenteeism.
and should also do so in comparison with 6 A provocative finding from British and North
conflict anticipation and resolution under American studies is that in cases of alleged unfair
dismissal from work, arbitrators, who are predom-
conditions of low involvement management.9 inantly male, are significantly more likely to render
It would also be helpful for the pur- favorable decisions for female than for male grievants.
pose of advancing research on employment These same studies, however, find no significant
relationship conflict to know more about differences between ‘successful’ female and male
perceptions of organizational justice as well as grievants in the financial compensation awarded
to them by arbitrators (Knight and Latreille, 2001;
employment relationship deterioration among Bemmels, 1990; Bemmels, 1988).
employees who work under conditions of high 7 Some researchers refer to such silence as
involvement management. Finally, the claim ‘neglect’. See Rusbelt et al. 1988.
that the presence or availability of a grievance 8 The notion that litigation may be supplanting
procedure is positively associated with orga- internal grievance and grievance-like procedures for
the resolution of employment relationship conflict
nizational performance while the actual use of runs counter to a dominant theme in the literature on
a grievance procedure is negatively associated ADR, which is that ADR is, by definition, an alternative
with organizational performance is hardly to litigation!
a robust claim. Further inquiry into this 9 For a definition of low involvement manage-
intriguing yet sobering claim is sorely needed ment and evidence of its relationship to business
performance, see Lewin and Dotan, 2007
lest it be concluded that, when it comes
to employment conflict resolution, the ‘best’
grievance procedure is one that is least used!
REFERENCES

Antonioni, D. (1994) ‘The Effects of Feedback Account-


NOTES ability on Upward Appraisal Ratings,’ Personnel
Psychology, 47 (2): 349–55.
1 For a systematic treatment of collective forms of
Arthur, J.B. (1994) ‘Effects of Human Resource
conflict, including strikes, see Gall and Hebdon, this
volume, Chapter 31.
Systems on Manufacturing Performance,’ Academy
2 Compensating differentials theory (of grievance of Management Journal, 37 (3): 670–87.
activity) is referred to by some scholars as efficiency Arthur, J.B. (1992) ‘The Link Between Business Strategy
theory, for example, Bacharach and Bamberger and Industrial Relations Systems in American Steel
(2004), who also conclude that the effects on Minimills,’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
grievance filing of such labor market variables as the 45 (2): 488–506.
wage premium are moderated by work context and Arvey, R.D. and Jones, A.P. (1985) ‘The Uses of
labor power variables. Discipline in Organizational Settings,’ in Staw, B.M.
3 The distinction between availability and use of and Cummings, L.L. (eds), Research in Organizational
a conflict resolution mechanism has been most
Behavior, 7: 367–408.
pointedly made in studies of public sector contract
arbitration (Lewin et al. 1988, Chapter 5).
Bacharach, S. and Bamberger, P. (2004) ‘The Power
4 Massive grievance filing sometimes occurs as a of Labor to Grieve: The Impact of the Workplace,
tactic intended to influence the power relationships Labor Market, and Power-Dependence on Employee
and hence the results of collective negotiations over Grievance Filing,’ Industrial and Labor Relations
new contracts between union and management. Review, 57 (4): 518–39.
RESOLVING CONFLICT 465

Barnacle, P. (1991) Arbitration of Discharge Grievances Colvin, A.J.S. (2004) ‘Adoption and Use of Dispute
in Ontario: Outcomes and Reinstatement Experiences. Resolution Procedures in the Non-union Workplace,’
Kingston, ON: Industrial Relations Center. in Lewin, D. and Kaufman, B.E., (eds), Advances in
Belman, D. (1992) ‘Unions, the Quality of Labor Industrial and Labor Relations, 13: 71–97.
Relations, and Firm Performance,’ in Mishel, L. Colvin, A.J.S. (2003) ‘Institutional Pressures, Human
and Voos, P.B. (eds), Unions and Economic Resources Strategies, and the Rise of Nonunion
Competitiveness. Armonk, NY: Sharpe. pp. 41–107. Dispute Resolution Procedures,’ Industrial and Labor
Bemmels, B. (1995) ‘Shop Stewards’ Satisfaction With Relations Review, 56 (3): 375–92.
Grievance Procedures,’ Industrial Relations, 34 (1): Delaney, J.T., Lewin, D. and Ichniowski, C. (1989)
578–92. Human Resource Policies and Practices in American
Bemmels, B. (1994) ‘The Determinants of Grievance Firms. Washington, D.C.: US Department of Labor,
Initiation,’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, BLMR #137.
47 (2): 285–301. Dickens, L., Hart, M., Jones, M. and Weeks, B. (1984)
Bemmels, B. (1990) ‘Gender Effects in Grievance ‘The British Experience Under a Statute Prohibiting
Arbitration,’ Industrial Relations, 29 (3): 313–25. Unfair Dismissal,’ Industrial and Labor Relations
Bemmels, B. (1988) ‘Gender Effects in Discharge Arbi- Review, 37 (4): 497–514.
tration: Evidence from British Columbia,’ Academy of Donohue, III, J.J. and Siegelman, P. (1991) ‘The
Management Journal, 31 (3): 251–62. Changing Nature of Employment Discrimination
Bemmels, B. and Foley, J.R. (1996) ‘Grievance Litigation,’ Stanford Law Review, 43 (4): 983–1033.
Procedure Research: A Review and Theoretical Eaton, A.E. and Voos, P.B. (1994) ‘Productivity-
Recommendations,’ Journal of Management, 22 (3): Enhancing Innovations in Work Organization, Com-
359–84. pensation, and Employee Participation in the Union
Bendersky. C. (2003) ‘Organizational Dispute Resolution versus the Nonunion Sectors,’ in Lewin, D. and
Systems: A Complementarities Model,’ Academy of Sockell, D., (eds), Advances in Industrial and Labor
Management Review, 28 (4): 643–56. Relations, 6: 63–109.
Bendix, R. (1956) Work and Authority in Industry. Eaton, A.E. and Voos, P.B. (1992) ‘Unions and
New York: Wiley. Contemporary Innovations in Work Organization,
Bognanno, M.F., Budd, J.W. and Kleiner, M.M. (2007) Compensation, and Employee Participation,’ in
‘Symposium Introduction: Governing the Global Mishel, L. and Voos, P.B., (eds), Unions and Economic
Workplace,’ Industrial Relations, 46 (2): 215–21. Competitiveness. Armonk, NY: Myron E. Sharpe.
Boroff, K.E. and Lewin, D. (1997) ‘Loyalty, Voice and pp. 173–215.
Intent to Exit a Union Firm: A Conceptual and Feuille, P. (1999) ‘Grievance Mediation,’ in Eaton, A.E.
Empirical Analysis,’ Industrial and Labor Relations and Keefe, J.H., (eds), Employment Dispute Reso-
Review, 51 (1): 50–63. lution and Worker Rights in the Changing Work-
Cappelli, P. and Chauvin, K. (1991) ‘A Test of an place. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research
Efficiency Model of Grievance Activity,’ Industrial and Association. pp. 187–217.
Labor Relations Review, 45 (1): 3–14. Feuille, P. and Delaney, J.T. (1992) ‘The Individual
Chamberlain, N.W. and Kuhn, J.W. (1965) Collective Pursuit of Organizational Justice: Grievance Proce-
Bargaining, 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill. dures in Nonunion Workplaces,’ in Ferris, G.R. and
Clark, P.F. and Gallagher, D.G. (1988) ‘Membership Rowland, K.M., (eds), Research in Personnel and
Perceptions of the Value and Effect of Grievance Human Resource Management, 10: 187–232.
Procedures,’ Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Freeman, R.B. and Medoff, J.L. (1984) What Do Unions
Meeting. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations Research Do? New York: Basic Books.
Association, pp. 406–15. Gollan, P.J., Poutsma, E. and Veersma, U. (2007)
Clark, P.F., Gallagher, D.G. and Pavlak, T.J. (1990) ‘Editors’ Introduction: New Roads in Organizational
‘Member Commitment in an American Union: The Participation?,’ Industrial Relations, 45 (4): 499–512.
Role of the Grievance Procedure,’ Labor Studies Goldberg, S.B. (1982) ‘The Mediation of Grievances
Journal, 21 (2): 147–57. under a Collective Contract: An Alternative to
Commons, J.R. (1919) ‘American Shoemakers: Arbitration,’ Northwestern University Law Review,
1648–1895: A Sketch of Industrial Evaluation,’ 77 (1): 270–315.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 25, reprinted and Gordon, M.E. and Bowlby, R.C. (1988) ‘Propositions
revised in Commons, J.R., (ed.), A Documentary About Grievance Settlements: Finally, Consultation
History of American Industrial Society, Vol. 3. With Grievants,’ Personnel Psychology, 41 (2):
New York: Russell and Russell. pp. 18–58. 107–23.
466 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Hirschman, A.O. (1970) Exit, Voice and Loyalty. Behavior: An Integrative Perspective,’ Academy of
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Management Review, 14 (3): 445–58.
Huselid, M.A. (1995) ‘The Impact of Human Resource Klass, B. and DeNisi, A. (1989) ‘Managerial Reactions
Management Practices on Turnover, Productivity, to Employee Dissent: The Impact of Grievance Activity
and Corporate Financial Performance,’ Academy of on Performance Ratings,’ Academy of Management
Management Journal, 38 (2): 635–72. Journal, 32 (4): 705–18.
Ichniowski, C. (1992) ‘Human Resource Practices Klass, B., Heneman, H.G. and Olson, C. (1991) ‘Effects
and Productive Labor-Management Relations,’ in of Grievance Activity on Absenteeism,’ Journal of
Lewin, D., Mitchell, O.S. and Sherer, P.D., (eds), Applied Psychology, 76 (6): 818–24.
Research Frontiers in Industrial Relations and Kleiner, M.M., Nickelsburg, G. and Pilarski, A. (1995)
Human Resources. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations ‘Monitoring, Grievances and Plant Performance,’
Research Association. pp. 239–71. Industrial Relations, 34 (2): 169–89.
Ichniowski, C. (1986) ‘The Effects of Grievance Activity Knight, T.R. (1986) ‘Feedback and Grievance Initiation,’
on Productivity,’ Industrial and Labor Relations Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 39 (4):
Review, 40 (1): 75–89. 585–98.
Ichniowski, C. and Lewin, D. (1987) ‘Grievance Knight, K.G. and Latreille, P.L. (2001) ‘Gender Effects
Procedures and Firm Performance,’ in Kleiner, M.M., in British Unfair Dismissal Tribunal Hearings,’
Block, R.N., Roomkin, R. and Salsburg, S.W., Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54 (4):
(eds), Human Resources and the Performance of 816–34.
the Firm, Industrial Relations Research Association. Kuhn, J.W. (1961) Bargaining in Grievance Settlement:
Washington, D.C.: Bureau of National Affairs. The Power of Industrial Work Groups. New York:
pp. 159–93. Columbia University Press.
Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G. (1997) ‘The Labig, Jr., C.E., Helburn, I. and Rogers, R. (1985)
Effects of Human Resource Management Practices ‘Discipline History, Seniority, and Reason for
on Productivity: A Study of Steel Finishing Lines,’ Discharge as Predictors of Postreinstatement Job
American Economic Review, 87 (3): 291–313. Performance,’ The Arbitration Journal, 40 (1): 44–52.
Jacoby, S.M. (1986) ‘Progressive Discipline in American Levine, D.I. (1995) Reinventing the Workplace.
Industry: Origins, Development, Consequences,’ in Washington, D.C.: Brookings.
Lipsky, D.B. and Lewin, D., (eds), Advances in Lewin, D. (2005) ‘Unionism and Employment Conflict
Industrial and Labor Relations, 3: 216–60. Resolution: Rethinking Collective Voice and its
Jehn, K. (1997) ‘A Qualitative Analysis of Conflict Consequences,’ Journal of Labor Research, 26 (2):
Types and Dimensions in Organizational Groups,’ 209–39.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 42 (4): 530–57. Lewin, D. (2004) ‘Dispute Resolution in Non-union
Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976) ‘Theory of Organizations: Key Empirical Findings,’ in S. Estreicher
the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and and D. Sherwyn, (eds), Alternative Dispute Resolution
Ownership Structure,’ Journal of Financial Economics, in the Employment Arena. New York: Kluwer.
3 (2): 305–60. pp. 397–403.
Kaminski, M. (1999) ‘New Forms of Work Organization Lewin, D. (2001) ‘IR and HR Perspectives on Workplace
and Their Impact on the Grievance Procedure,’ in Conflict: What Can Each Learn from the Other?,’
Eaton, A.E. and Keefe, J.H., (eds), Employment Human Resource Management Review, 11 (Fall):
Dispute Resolution and Worker Rights in the 453–85.
Changing Workplace. Champaign, IL: Industrial Lewin, D. (1999) ‘Theoretical and Empirical Research on
Relations Research Association. pp. 219–46. the Grievance Procedure and Arbitration: A Critical
Katz, H.C., Kochan, T.A. and Gobeille, K.R. (1983) Review,’ in Eaton, A.E. and Keefe, J.H., (eds),
‘Industrial Relations Performance, Economic Perfor- Employment Dispute Resolution and Worker Rights
mance, and QWL Programs: An Interplant Analysis,’ in the Changing Workplace. Champaign, IL: Industrial
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 37 (2): 3–17. Relations Research Association. pp. 137–86.
Katz, H.C., Kochan, T.A. and Weber, M.R. (1985). Lewin, D. (1997) ‘Workplace Dispute Resolution,’ in
‘Assessing the Effects of Industrial Relations and Lewin, D., Mitchell, D.J.B. and Zaidi, M.A., (eds),
Quality of Work Life Efforts on Organizational The Human Resource Management Handbook, Part
Effectiveness,’ Academy of Management Journal, II. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. pp. 197–218.
28 (2): 509–27. Lewin, D. (1994) ‘Explicit Individual Contracting in the
Klaas, B. (1989) ‘Determinants of Grievance Activity Labor Market,’ in Kerr. C. and Staudohar, P.D., (eds),
and the Grievance System’s Impact On Employee Labor Economics and Industrial Relations: Markets
RESOLVING CONFLICT 467

and Institutions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Productivity: A Look at the Evidence. Washington,
Press. pp. 401–28. D.C.: Brookings. pp. 15–89.
Lewin, D. (1992) ‘Grievance Procedures in Non-union Norsworthy, J.R. and Zabala, C.A. (1985) ‘Worker
Workplaces: An Empirical Analysis of Usage, Dynam- Attitudes, Worker Behavior, and Productivity in the
ics, and Outcomes,’ Chicago-Kent Law Review, 66 (3): US Automobile Industry, 1959–1976,’ Industrial and
823–44. Labor Relations Review, 38 (4): 544–57.
Lewin, D. (1987) ‘Dispute Resolution in the Non-union Olson-Buchanan, J. (1997) ‘To Grieve or Not to
Firm: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis,’ Journal of Grieve: Factors Relating to Voicing Discontent in an
Conflict Resolution, 31 (3): 465–502. Organizational Simulation,’ International Journal of
Lewin, D. and Boroff, K.E. (1996) ‘The Role of Loyalty Conflict Management, 8 (2): 132–47.
in Exit and Voice: A Conceptual and Empirical Olson-Buchanan, J. (1996) ‘Voicing Discontent: What
Analysis,’ in Lewin, D., Kaufman, B.E. and Sockell, D., Happens to the Grievance Filer After the Grievance?,’
(eds), Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations, Journal of Applied Psychology, 81 (1): 52–63.
7: 69–96. O’Reilly, C.A. and Weitz, B.A. (1980) ‘Managing
Lewin, D. and Dotan, H. (2007) ‘The Dual Theory of HRM Marginal Employees: The Use of Warnings and
and Business Performance,’ Working Paper, UCLA Dismissals,’ Administrative Science Quarterly, 25 (2):
Anderson School of Management. 467–84.
Lewin, D. and Mitchell, D.J.B. (1995) Human Resource Osterman, P. (1988) Employment Futures: Reorganiza-
Management: An Economic Approach, 2nd ed. tion, Dislocation, and Public Policy. New York: Oxford
Cincinnati, OH: South-Western. University Press.
Lewin, D. and Peterson, R.B. (1999) ‘Behavioral Pfeffer, J. (1998) The Human Equation: Building Profits
Outcomes of Grievance Activity,’ Industrial Relations, by Putting People First. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
38 (4): 554–76. School Press.
Lewin, D. and Peterson, R.B. (1988) The Modern Rees, A. (1977) The Economics of Trade Unions, 2nd ed.
Grievance Procedure in the United States. New York: Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Quorum. Rocella, M. (1989) ‘The Reinstatement of Dismissed
Lewin, D., Feuille, P., Kochan, T.A. and Delaney, J.T. Employees in Italy: An Empirical Analysis,’ Compara-
(1988) Public Sector Labor Relations: Analysis and tive Labor Law Journal, 10 (2): 166–95.
Readings. Lexington, MA: Heath. Rusbelt, C.E., Farrell, D., Rogers, G. and
Lind, E.A. and Tyler, E.R. (1988) The Social Psychology Mainous, III, A.G. (1988) ‘Impact of Variables
of Procedural Justice. New York: Plenum. on Exit, Voice, Loyalty and Neglect: An Integrative
Lipsky, D.B., Seeber, R.L. and Fincher, R.D. (2003) Model of Responses to Declining Job Satisfaction,’
Emerging Systems for Managing Workplace Conflict. Academy of Management Journal, 31 (3): 599–627.
San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Shantz, E. and Rogow, R. (1984) ‘Post-reinstatement
MacDuffie, J.P. (1995) ‘Human Resource Bundles and Experience: A British Columbia Study,’ Paper
Manufacturing Performance: Organizational Logic presented at the annual meeting of the Canadian
and Flexible Production Systems in the World Auto Industrial Relations Association.
Industry,’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Sheppard, B.H., Lewicki, R.J. and Minton, J.W. (1992)
48 (2): 197–221. Organizational Justice. New York: Lexington.
Malinowski, A.A. (1981) ‘An Empirical Analysis of Stone, K.V.W. (1999) ‘Employment Arbitration Under
Discharge Cases and the Work History of Employees the Federal Arbitration Act, in Eaton, A.E. and
Reinstated by Labor Arbitration,’ Dispute Resolution, Keefe, J.H., (eds), Employment Dispute Resolution
36 (1): 31–46. and Worker Rights in the Changing Work-
Mathewson, S.B., (ed.), (1931) Restriction of Output place. Champaign, IL: Industrial Relations Research
Among Unorganized Workers. Carbondale, IL: Association. pp. 27–65.
Southern Illinois University Press, reprinted Taylor, F.W. (1911) The Principles of Scientific
1969. Management. New York; Harper and Bros.
Mitchell, D.J.B., Lewin, D. and Lawler, III, E.E. (1990) Weber, M. (1947) The Theory of Social and Economic
‘Alternative Pay Systems, Firm Performance, and Organization. Henderson, A. and Parsons, T.,
Productivity,’ in Blinder, A.S., (ed.), Paying for translators. New York: Free Press.
PART FOUR

Industrial Relations Outcomes


25
Contingent Work Arrangements
Daniel G. Gallagher

During the past few decades there has public policy-based factors which, to varying
been a gradual international trend toward a degrees, have contributed to the growth
fundamental restructuring of the employment (or resurgence) of fixed-term contracts. An
contracts between organizations and workers. overview will be provided to describe the
At the broadest level there has been the scope and focus of research that has been
suggestion that the ‘normal’ or ‘standard’ conducted and published on the individual
work arrangements of most workers during and organizational consequences associated
the twentieth century has increasingly been with contingent work contracts, as well
replaced with ‘alternative’ or ‘non-standard’ as the underlying theoretical perspectives
work arrangements (Bergstrøm and Storrie, which have driven such research. The chapter
2003; Gallie et al., 1998; Kalleberg et al., will conclude with observations concerning
2003; Quinlan and Bohle, 2004; Smith, 2001; theoretical and methodological issues found
Voudouris, 2004; Zeytinoğlu, 1999). One such within the literature on contingent work and
growing form of non-standard employment, specify issues which should be addressed in
by contemporary standards, is the hiring future research.
of workers on ‘contingent’ or ‘fixed-term
contracts.’
The objective of this chapter is to provide a THE MEANING OF CONTINGENT
brief description, explanation, and evaluation WORK
of the growing worldwide presence of con-
tingent employment contracts as part of the The US Bureau of Labor Statistics uses
worker-organization relationship. As part of the following definition to delineate con-
this objective, an initial effort will be made tingent employment from other forms of
to define the meaning of contingent work alternative or non-standard employment. The
and how such arrangements are distinct from bureau’s definition characterizes contingent
other forms of non-standard or alternative work as ‘…any job in which an individ-
employment arrangements. The chapter will ual does not have an explicit or implicit
then identify organization-, worker-, and contract for long-term employment or one
472 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in which the minimum hours worked can the contingent work definition, including
vary in a nonsystematic manner’ (Polivka temporary-help staffing firm arrangements,
and Nardone, 1989: p11). Gallagher (2002) direct-line temporaries, and independent
mentions that some definition inaccuracy or contractors.
variability may exist over the interpretation
of the meaning of ‘long-term employment.’
Temporary-help staffing firm
From both organizational and worker
arrangements
perspectives, the meaning of long-term has
an indeterminate value. For such reasons, First, and perhaps one of the most visible con-
contingent work has more frequently been tractual arrangements fitting the parameters
referenced in the context of the absence of of contingent work, is fixed-term employment
an ongoing employment relationship rather established through the use of an intermediary
than as long term (Hipple, 1998). Moreover, organization such as a temporary-help service
Polivka and Nardone’s (1989) effort at defin- firm or temporary staffing agency (Adecco,
ing contingent work realizes that contracts Manpower, Olsten, Randstad, for example).
may be both emphatic (for example, ‘explicit’ Through the utilization of temporary-help
verbal or written terms) or involve an element staffing firms, an organization contracts labor
of individualized perception (for example, either for a specified period of time or until a
an ‘implicit’ understanding). The inclusion particular event or project is complete. Within
of these elements into contractual definitions these staffing arrangements, there is a con-
suggests the possibility that equally situated tractually explicit understanding that workers
workers could reach different understandings will be dispatched to the client organizations
about the perceived permanency of their for fixed durations. In many countries, there
relationships with employer organizations are statutory limitations placed on how long
(Gallagher, 2002). However, as reflected in a particular worker may be continuously
much of the psychological contract research assigned to a user or client organization by a
(Guest, 1998; Rousseau, 1995), how an temporary firm. Furthermore, the contractual
individual perceives the arrangement or ‘the and compensation agreement that a worker
deal’ may be more important to understanding has with a temporary-help staffing firm lasts
the attitude and behavior of a worker than the for a fixed duration and depends on the avail-
ability to precisely slot a worker into a well- ability of assignments for which the worker
defined employment category (McLean Parks is qualified (Gallagher, 2002; Gallagher and
et al., 1998). Sverke, 2005). There are rare exceptions in
Consideration of the extent to which some countries where temporary workers may
‘minimum hours can vary in a non-systematic hold an ongoing employee status with the
manner’ is another important component of staffing firm.
contingent work. For example, a worker There are two trends within the temporary-
could have an agreement with a local school help services industry that are important to
district to work as a substitute or supply note. First, although the percentage of workers
teacher and be called into work on an ad actually hired through temporary-help firms
hoc or as-needed basis. There may be a long- is a small share of total employment in
standing or ongoing relationship between the most economies, the temporary-help service
substitute/supply teacher and the school, but industry and the employment of agency-based
there is no guarantee of work hours or a temps has been one of the fastest growing
reasonably predictable schedule. In effect, segments of the workforce in many countries
the level and regularity of work is entirely over the past few decades (Delsen, 1999;
dependent on the variable needs of the Gallie et al., 1998; Kalleberg and Marsden,
employer organization (Gallagher, 2002). 2005). Second, the image of temporary
Accordingly, there are three broad workers as legions of unskilled day laborers,
groupings of work arrangements that fit receptionists, and conference staff is no longer
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 473

universally applicable. Often overlooked in employment suggests the absence of a long-


the economic literature are the increasing term contractual arrangement, many types of
number of staffing agencies that focus on the seasonal work can be viewed as fitting the
short-term placement of professional workers aforementioned definition of contingent work.
such as accountants, engineers, information However, in some industries, as McDonald
technology experts, nurses, and other medical and Makin (2000) point out, seasonal work
and scientific personnel (Carnoy et al., 1997). may be viewed as an opportunity for future
fixed-term contracts (next season) or as the
port of entry for long-term employment. Most
Direct-hire temporaries
seasonal contracts are short-term in duration
A second and expanding category of con- and thus within the realm of contingent
tingent workers is comprised of individuals work (Aronsson et al., 2002; Connelley and
who are employed through direct-hire or Gallagher, 2004b).
in-house temporary staffing arrangements
with the immediate employer organization
Independent contractors
(Gallagher, 2002; Connelly and Gallagher,
2004b). Direct-hire arrangements are most The diversity of occupational types and
often found in large organizations where arrangements which have been incorporated
irregular staffing requirements result in the under the scope of contingent work includes
frequent use of workers for short-term assign- organizational hiring of independent con-
ments. These temporary workers may be hired tractors. Within most countries, indepen-
on a specified fixed-term basis or on a more dent contractors or freelance workers are
ad hoc or casual basis. The organization legally defined as self-employed persons who
chooses to hire temporary workers directly contract or sell their services to a client
rather than exclusively using the services of organization on a fixed-term or project basis.
a temporary-help service firm. In practice, Most often, independent contractors are well
many direct-hire temporary workers may have educated and professionally trained with skills
an implicit or explicit understanding of an that are either in short supply or for which the
ongoing relationship with the same employer organization has an immediate but not long-
(for example, future temporary assignments). term need (Gallagher, 2002). Independent
However, direct-hire temporary employment contractors generally set their own hours
assignments are characterized as ‘contingent’ and decide how to complete a project. They
because they meet the second defining are directly compensated on the basis of a
characteristic of contingent work which states negotiated or bid contract with a prospective
that ‘…the minimum hours worked can vary client organization. The client organization
in a nonsystematic manner’ (Polivka and often has very limited, if any, responsibility
Nardone, 1989: p 11). A further and often for non-direct compensation (for example,
overlooked variation of direct-hire contingent healthcare, insurance, superannuation, etc.),
contracts entails hiring-hall arrangements in and the client organization is not responsible
unionized sectors of the construction and for employment-related taxes and levies. Such
entertainment industries. Although the union responsibilities rest with the independent
may operate as an intermediary, the resulting contractor as a form of sole proprietorship.
employment relationship is directly between In recent years, there has been increasing
the employee and the employer. evidence of organizational downsizing, which
A subcategory of direct-hire contingent has led to the termination of employees who
workers includes individuals directly hired are then rehired by their organizations as inde-
by an organization for seasonal contracts pendent contractors. Similarly, other organi-
(for example, resorts, tourism, etc.) (Polivka zations are relying on the large and growing
and Nardone, 1989). Because the num- percentage of independent contractors who
ber of assigned or contracted weeks of are trained in knowledge-based occupations
474 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and areas requiring substantial craft and a shield against the application of rights and
technological skills (for example, information benefits provided to non-contingent workers
technology). These organizations have used (Marlin, 2000).
the independent contracting arrangements as
a means of extending their pool of technical
knowledge without making an implicit or STRUCTURAL DIFFERENCES IN
explicit guarantee of ongoing employment CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS
(Matusik and Hill, 1998).
As evidenced in a 1996 US Federal Tax The utilization of a commonly accepted
Court ruling with the Microsoft Corporation, definition of contingent work can result in the
there is a concern that client organizations identification of fundamentally different clas-
may overly structure or control the duties and sifications or groupings of contingent work.
responsibilities of independent contractors The three primary groupings, temporary-help
to the point that the contractors are more staffing firms, direct-hire temporaries, and
akin to employees than contingent workers independent contractors, fit under the realm
(Fragoso and Kleiner, 2005; Kondrasuk of contingent work and can exist in most
et al., 2001). Under the US Tax Code, industrialized countries, although the relative
the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) has proportions of the three groupings may differ
established detailed guidelines concerning among countries’employment profiles (Booth
the proper legal classification of independent et al., 2002a; Brewster et al., 1997).
contractors. The IRS guidelines are based on It is also important to note that each of
the common law principle of the worker’s the three groupings of contingent work rep-
‘right to control’ how, where, and when resents varying degrees of departure from the
work is performed to some extent (Fragoso structure of the prevailing twentieth century
and Kleiner, 2005). If a client organization ‘employer-employee’ relationship. Further-
exercises an exorbitant amount of control more, the structure of the work relationship
over an individualized contractor’s work, across each of the groupings contributes to
the individualized contractor’s relationship potential differences regarding the status and
with the client organization may exceed rights of individual contingent workers.
stipulations of an independent contractor Looking across the groupings of contin-
arrangement to become a more traditional gent work, the notion of an identifiable
employer-employee relationship or direct- employer-employee relationship is not always
hire temporary arrangement. Both the IRS immediately apparent. For example, in the
and international labor experts share the case of contingent or ‘fixed-term’ workers
concern that independent contractors who hired through the intermediary services of
are heavily reliant upon a single client a temporary-help staffing firm, the question
organization as a source for contracting may arise as to which entity is the ‘employer’
income may constitute a form of dependent organization. If an employer is characterized
rather than independent contracting. (Greene, as the organization that does the hiring and
2000; International Labour Office, 2000; provides the compensation, then it would
Marlin, 2000). For governmental purposes, appear that the temporary-help firm holds the
single client dependency is likely to move employer status. Conversely, if an employer
an independent contractor to employee status is defined in terms of the organization
with all organizational employment protec- that sets the work and job responsibili-
tions and taxation requirements associated ties, then the temporary-help staffing firm’s
with traditional employees. Within the context client organization may hold the status of
of a broader ethical principle, organizations employer. Under different legal regimes, it
that incorrectly classify employee workers is possible to argue that the temporary-
under the category of independent contractor help staffing firm and the client organization
may be using the occupational classification as share co-employer obligations pertaining to
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 475

the employment of the temporary workers likely to occur between contingents and more
(Gonos, 1997). The hiring of contingent traditional workers in the same organization.
workers through the use of temporary- There is also the question of the
help staffing firms establishes a ‘triangular’ applicability of labor law practices to the
employment relationship consisting of three employment of contingent workers directly
principle parties, including the worker, the hired through independent contractor arrange-
temporary-help staffing firm, and the client ments. Independent contractors represent
organization. The first side of the triangle a particular challenge to the traditional
signifies that while a worker is employed, he employer-employee relationship because
or she usually holds a contractual relationship independent contractors are not employees
with the temporary-help firm rather than but rather are ‘self-employers.’ In this context
the client organization where the work is most, if not all independent contractors, fall
being performed. Meanwhile, the second outside the scope of statutory definitions of
side involves the contractual relationship that employer-employee relations. Ironically for
exists between the temporary-help staffing independent contractors, the importance of the
firm and the client. The third side of the traditional employer-employee relationship
triangle represents the day-to-day working may become prominent to them if and when
relationship that exists between the temporary independent contractors hire support staff
worker and the client organization to which workers, thereby becoming employers.
they have been dispatched. In circumstances The ‘self-employer’ status of independent
where the temporary-help staffing firm dis- contractors and the triangular nature of
patches a large number of workers to a temporary-firm contingent work arrange-
single client location, the temporary-help firm ments raise questions relating to the appli-
may actually take direct on-site responsibility cability of contemporary Industrial Relations
for the day-to-day tasks performed by the (IR) and behavioral theories of employ-
temporary workers. Gallagher and McLean ment to the understanding of work-related
Parks (2001) note that a further level of dis- attitudes and behaviors of independent
identification with the employer-employee contractors.
concept may exist for contingent workers
associated with temporary-help staffing firms
because of the mechanics of the industry. CONTINGENT Vs. STANDARD WORK
Temporary workers will not only rotate ARRANGEMENTS
between client organizations, but they may
also be associated with and dispatched by Making the claim that contingent work
multiple temporary-help firms. As a result, the represents a variation or departure from the
contingent workers hired through temporary- standard employment contract requires some
help staffing firms may have an unclear notion clarification on the customary interpretation
of who represents their employer and what has of standard work arrangements. As Kalleberg
been issued as their job. (2000) writes, the standard arrangement
In contrast, the employment of contingent during most of the twentieth century stipulated
or fixed-term workers through direct-hire that work was performed full-time, would
arrangements is similar in structure to the continue indefinitely, and was performed at
traditional employer-employee relationship. the employer’s place of business under the
Despite the insecurity that is still associated employer’s supervision. Using such criteria, it
with contingent worker status, direct-hire tem- is clear that the forms of contingent employ-
poraries are, in most countries, included under ment fall outside the definition of standard
the umbrella of statutory projections provided employment. Furthermore, most forms of
to other ‘employees’ of the organization. part-time employment are more characteristic
Differentials, including wage levels and scope of the image of ‘normal’ employment than
of compensation and benefit coverage, are contingent work.
476 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

However, there are other types of orga- the extent to which long-term employment
nizational staffing arrangements that fall is on the decline (Doogan, 2001). Efforts
outside the realms of contingent and standard to explain this growth have looked at the
work arrangements. In particular, employee relative importance of demand vs. supply-
leasing, outsourcing, and subcontracting are based factors. Demand-side explanations
increasingly popular means for organizations have emphasized the role of changing market
to meet staffing needs while emphasiz- forces. These forces influence the desire of
ing their core functions. In the case of organizations to increase their reliance on
outsourcing or subcontracting, a client or contingent workers. Using time-series data
customer organization achieves flexibility on US based establishments, Golden and
by contracting services or production to a Appelbaum (1992) found that the demand
third party organization (Greer et al., 1999; for temporary workers was closely associated
Lepak and Snell, 2002). The employees of with three major factors: cyclical fluctuations
the third-party organization (outsource firm in output, increased foreign competition, and
or subcontractor) have a more traditional the magnitude of non-wage labor costs. These
arrangement; they have a clear and identifiable findings comply with prescriptive and case-
employer and the expectation of an ongoing based studies which indicate that employers
work relationship subject to satisfactory turn to contingent work contracts as a
individual performance and organizational means of increasing flexibility in not only
survival. Even in the case of more complicated the number but also the types of workers
employee leasing arrangements, there is often which are hired on an ‘as needed’ basis
an intermediary or professional employee (Barley and Kundra, 2004; Cully et al.,
organization (PEO). The employment rela- 1999; Geary, 1992; Kalleberg and Marsden,
tionship is open to long-term employment 2005; Klein and vanVuuren, 1999; Nollen
with a single, identifiable employer, and and Axel, 1996; Reilly, 1998). Many orga-
transfer between clients still retains an nizations’ strategies for restructuring include
ongoing contractual relationship between the an increasingly larger share of variable cost
leasing firm and the worker (Drucker, 2002). workforces over fixed cost labor (Cappelli
Similarly, increased organizational interest in and Neumark, 2003). Evidence also suggests
focusing on core competencies has led many that the use of temporary workers, particularly
organizations to turn over non-core functions those hired through temporary-help staffing
to subcontracting organizations (Hamel and firms, remain a major resource used by
Prahalad, 1994; Nesheim, 2003). Although employers to replace workers on short-term
subcontractors are providers of services for absences (Galup et al., 1997; Houseman,
client organizations, they are themselves 2001).
employer organizations, and in most cases Moreover, the literature points to an
they employ their own workers on more increasing employer emphasis on contingent
traditional and ongoing employer-employee work for functional flexibility, which is
based arrangements. associated with the desire of employers to
achieve a balance between the changing
skill needs of an organization and the skills
FORCES DRIVING THE GROWTH OF possessed by an organization’s workforce.
CONTINGENT WORK In workplaces where technology is rapidly
changing, locating a match between the
There is considerable international literature work demands and the skills of the standard
exploring the growth of contingent work workforce may be increasingly difficult. For
arrangements (Bergstrøm and Storrie, 2003; many organizations, turning to technolog-
Brewster, et al., 1997; Kalleberg, et al., 2003; ically savvy independent contractors may
Quinlan and Bohle, 2004; Zeytinoğlu 1999). represent an efficient approach for gaining
As well as some research which questions immediate access to necessary skills without
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 477

adding to the organization’s long-term labor implemented major changes in job-related


costs (Nishikawa, 2000). Such a finding computer technology.
fits well with prior observations that there With regard to the relationship between
is a growing cadre of professional tempo- unionization and firm use of contingent
raries and independent contractors who are workers, the results are rather ambiguous.
appealing to employers because they provide Davis-Blake and Uzzi (1993) reported a
technical services to employers without orga- positive effect of unionization on the use
nizations having to invest in human resource of direct-hire temporaries in the US. Within
development. The use of independent contrac- a study of British organizations, Uzzi and
tors is also attractive to organizations as a Barsness (1998) found that the level of
means of gaining access to intellectual capital union-management conflict was positively
and first-hand knowledge of industry trends related to the use of contingent workers.
which may offer a competitive advantage to Abraham (1998) reported a positive effect of
the employing organization (Matusik and Hill, unionization on the use of contractors and a
1998). negative effect on the use of temporary help
Studies have also enhanced the under- workers in the US. Meanwhile, many other
standing of the growth of contingent work studies reported no effect of unionization
arrangements by seeking to identify firm on flexible staffing in the US (Houseman,
characteristics and organizational practices 2001; Kalleberg et al., 2003). In a study
which either contribute to or limit the of the UK and Norway, Gooderham and
use of contingent workers. Davis-Blake Nordhaug (1997) determined that organiza-
and Uzzi (1993) studied the relationship tions that perceived unions as being powerful
between firm-level characteristics and the were less prone to implement strategies for
use of temporary workers and independent staffing flexibility. More recent research by
contractors, finding that firm-specific training, Olsen (2003) of Norwegian organizations
government oversight, bureaucratic practices, concluded that unionization was negatively
establishment size, and ongoing requirements related to the use of temporary workers for
for high-level technical skills have negatively longer term staffing and positively related
affected the demand for temporary work- to the use of temporaries to fill short-term
ers. Meanwhile, their results indicate that vacancies.
bureaucratic structures, establishment size, Surveys of organizational managers and
and participation with multi-site organiza- human resource professionals show that they
tions had a positive impact on the use of tend to believe that contingent workers hired
independent contractors. These findings help through temporary-help firms are sought
link organizational characteristics with the primarily to fill short-term vacancies due to
use of contingent workers theoretically and leave time or the need to adjust to seasonal
empirically. The findings also indicate that or unexpected changes in staffing needs
different forms of contingent work may have (Galup et al., 1997; McAllister, 1998; Nollen
different organizational level determinants and Axel, 1996). Similarly, there is limited
(Gallagher, 2002). Uzzi and Barsness (1998) survey feedback that indicates that some
performed a similar study on British estab- organizations employ temporary workers as
lishments and found that the intensity of part of an elongated interview process for
fixed-term contracts was positively related to more permanent positions (Bernasek and
organizational size. In terms of organizational Kinner, 1999; Hardy and Walker, 2003).
control mechanisms, Uzzi and Barsness found Again, reflective of differences among the var-
that organizations capable of systematically ious types of contingent work arrangements,
measuring and monitoring performance were employer reliance on independent contractors
more inclined to employ temporary workers. tends to be tied with an expressed need to
They also observed that there was a higher gain short-term access to skill sets which
use of fixed-term hires in organizations that may not immediately be available within the
478 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

organization or as means to quickly resolve Pink (2001) points out in Free Agent Nation,
an immediate crisis (Barley and Kunda, 2004; for some workers, the selection of contingent
Reilly, 1998; Wheeler and Buckley, 2000). or fixed-term work arrangements represents a
There also exists some opinion that deliberate career decision to adopt a more per-
employer demand for contingent worker sonally flexible work schedule, allowing for
arrangements may, in part, be driven by a better work-family balance. Furthermore,
governmental policy. In particular, among contingent work may be appealing to more
studies that address the growth and conse- boundaryless workers who are interested in
quences of temporary employment in many avoiding the restraints of being employed
European countries, incidental commentary by a single employer organization (Marler
has often been made that contingent work et al., 2002). However, it is important to
contracts have been used by employers as a realize that the voluntary supply-side choice
means of circumventing governmental polices to work through contingent contracts is more
which restrict the ability of employers to lay pronounced among more educated and skilled
off or discharge workers or impose a high professionals and craft workers than among
economic cost associated with such actions marginally skilled workers. For workers
(Alba-Ramirez, 1998; Segal and Sullivan, with skills in high market demand (for
1997). Along similar lines, Olsen (2003) example, information technology, medical
has suggested that social rights, including services, etc.), independent contracting often
extensive worker access to paid absences represents a financially more lucrative career
from work, are particularly generous in many path while also enhancing personal control
Scandinavian countries, thus creating a short- over work schedules (Kunda et al., 2002).
term demand for labor necessary to staff Conversely, among less skilled workers,
the positions of absent workers. In contrast, contingent employment is viewed as the
there is research indicating that the role of better strategy so that they may re-enter the
government regulation may have a negligible workforce or attain work experience to barter
systematic impact on the use of contingent for more permanent or traditional types of
and alternative work arrangements (Brewster employment.
et al., 1997). Such research generally implies
that contingent and short-term employment
are more sensitive to market forces than
government regulation. Within the US, the CONSEQUENCES OF CONTINGENT
paucity of government programs guaranteeing WORK
workers periods of paid leave, combined
with the legal principle of ‘employment An effort to fully understand the individual
at will’ suggest limited employer interest and organizational consequences associated
in contingent work arrangements from a with the growth of contingent work arrange-
regulatory perspective. However, contrary ments is constrained because contingent work
to this expectation, contingent work is a covers a range of contractual arrangements
thriving form of contractual arrangement in and encompasses an array of reasons for
the US which individuals undertake such work.
Consideration of the supply-side of the Furthermore, individual worker responses
equation is also necessary when discussing to contingent work arrangements are likely
the growth of contingent work. In many to be functions of organizational practices
respects, parallel to the growth of part- pertaining to the management of contingent
time work, some portion of the contingent workers. However, economic and behavioral
work phenomenon has been spurred on by research supports a number of broad obser-
the number of people who are actively vations which provide some useful insights
seeking work outside of the traditional single into the world of contingent employment
employer-employee relationship. As Daniel arrangements.
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 479

As Cohany (1998) explains, the most disad- the worker a qualified candidate for more
vantaged workers laboring under contingent permanent employment. However, among
employment contracts work through the ser- many of the top-end forms of fixed-term
vices of temporary-help firms. The traditional employment, in particular for many inde-
vision of clerical and day-laborers performing pendent contractors, the desire to remain
work at low hourly rates at less than full- self-employed and appeal to potential clients
time hours is actually affirmed (Cohany). The depends on the currency of their skills sets.
lower end or ‘dark side’ of contingent work Barley and Kunda (2004) explain that among
is also characterized by extremely limited highly-skilled independent contractors in the
access to employment benefits. Within the area of information technology, there is a
US, contingent workers employed through continuous need for skill upgrading which is
intermediary firms have very limited direct contingent on the personal time and financial
access to health insurance, and when such resources of individual workers rather than the
access is available, it is often at a prohibitive client organizations.
cost. Among direct-hire temporaries, access In addition to the economic consequences
to employer-operated benefit plans also tends of contingent work, a considerable amount
to be limited or offered on a costly pro-rata of research attention has been given to the
basis. As Cohany notes, when workers in less psychological impact of contingent work
stable and lower skill contingent jobs have contracts on worker well-being. At the level
access to insurance coverage in the US, it of workers employed through the services
is usually through family-based insurance. of temporary staffing firms, there exists
While a partial solution to insurance coverage considerable case-based and anecdotal evi-
for some low-wage contingent workers, dence to suggest that contingent workers are
the absence or associated costs of benefit frequently subject to adverse working con-
coverage can be seen as a particular economic ditions (Henson, 1996). Research by Rogers
burden for single or self-supporting temporary (2000) indicates that lower-skill temporary
workers. workers are often physically, and more often
Investing in personal human resource psychologically, distanced from the standard
development represents another economic workforce in the organizations to which they
consequence for workers employed in con- have been assigned. Rogers adds that in addi-
tingent contracts. As a result, throughout the tion to being assigned demeaning tasks with
lower and higher echelons of the contingent low motivating potential, these workers are
workforce, responsibility for skill mainte- most often excluded from organizationally-
nance and development rests with the indi- based social events. However, it is important
vidual worker (Hanratty, 2000; Heckscher, to note that exclusionary treatment of con-
2000; Virtanen et al., 2003; Zeytinoğlu, 1999). tingent workers can also be evidenced in
When training is provided to these workers the more prestigious independent contracting
by employer organizations, the level tends to arrangements. For example, Carnoy et al.
be significantly less than what is provided (1997) found that among top-end independent
to more permanent employees (Booth et al., contractors in information technology, it was
2002b). The extent to which an individual not unusual for contractors to be denied access
worker may feel compelled to invest in to organizational meetings or proprietary data,
his or her skill development may, in large even when such information affected the
part, be a function of his or her career performance of their jobs.
objectives. In the situation where a worker Over the past decade there has been a
undertakes contingent work as a short-term dramatic increase in the number of empirical
arrangement or as a means of gaining access research studies which have sought to exam-
to the internal labor market of the firm, self- ine the job-related attitudes and behaviors
investment may be limited to achieving a of contingent workers. Often the research
level of technical competence which makes designs have focused on comparative analysis
480 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

of contingent workers versus workers on more contingent work arrangements (Nollen and
standard employment contracts. The research Axel, 1996).
has covered a scope of issues such as organi-
zational commitment, job satisfaction, organi-
zational citizenship behaviors, and well-being A THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVE
role conflict and ambiguity. For example,
many studies found contingent workers to be Behavioral research on contingent work has
as committed to their client organizations and focused on the comparative attitudes and
work as more permanent counterparts in the behaviors of contingent vs. standard workers,
same organization (De Witte and Näswall, or variations in attitudes and behaviors among
2003; Linden et al., 2003; Pearce, 1993; and samples of contingent workers. However,
Van Dyne and Ang, 1998). most research on individual and organiza-
Although research findings may be frag- tional consequences of contingent work is
mented, and at times contradictory, two based on well-established theories of organi-
important and closely-related findings con- zational behavior. Almost two decades ago,
sistently surface. First, workers vary in their Pfeffer and Baron (1988) raised the concern
motivations for undertaking contingent or that organizational theory was primarily
short-term work assignments. Research indi- developed in a context when organizational
cates that workers who undertake temporary models of bureaucratic control were prevalent
assignments as a means of gaining access and, as such, may not have been fully
to more permanent or ongoing work in applicable to less structured organizations
organizations are more likely to maintain and workers outside of more traditional
positive work attitudes and, most importantly, employment arrangements. Similarly, some
express more positive and supportive work researchers have commented that much
behaviors than temporary workers with lim- of our academic knowledge, organizational
ited interest in securing ongoing employment strategies, and public employment policy
contracts. Second, there is support for the are based on the assumption of a stable
importance of volition in understanding the and ongoing employer-employee relationship
attitudes of contingent workers. Workers (Brewster et al., 1997; Gallagher, 2002;
who voluntarily choose to work on fixed- Kochan et al., 1994). Implicit within the pre-
term contract bases are significantly more vailing view of the employment relationship
positive in their job-related attitudes than is the accepted assumption that employees
those who work as contingents due to hold varying levels of attachment to a single
the absence of more standard employment identifiable employer and that work roles,
opportunities (Di Natale, 2001; Ellingson attitudes, and behaviors are nested within
et al., 1998; Krausz et al., 1995). Collectively, the organization, the department, and the
the motivation and volition arguments may work group. Based on Gallagher and McLean
seem contradictory, but a distillation of the Parks (2001), many of these underlying
literature suggests that motivation is closely assumptions, as well as the meaning of
related to reported worker behaviors, while employer’s role, can be more complex and
volition is more broadly tied to overall work ambiguous within the context of contingent
attitudes. contract relationships (especially workers
Although there is a tremendous amount dispatched through temporary-help staffing
of prescriptive literature pertaining to the firms and independent contractors).
benefits of fixed-term or contingent employ- Similar to Pfeffer and Baron (1998), Beard
ment contracts, empirical research of the and Edwards (1995) recognize the need to
relationship between organization perfor- reconsider the framework accounting for
mance and reliance on contingent work conditions under which contingent workers
arrangements is virtually absent from the view and react to their work status. Beard and
assessment of benefits and limitations of Edwards point out five key areas in which the
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 481

contingent work experience may differ from represents the ‘idiosyncratic set of reciprocal
standard or core workers, including expectations held by employees’ concerning
their obligations (what they expect to do for
1) job insecurity; the employer) and their entitlements (what
2) predictability concerning job performance and they expect to receive in return) (McLean
associated outcomes; Parks et al., 1998: 698). Psychological con-
3) control over how and when the work is performed; tracts can exist with or without the presence of
4) the nature of the psychological contract; and more formally written employment contracts.
5) the social comparison process with non- They specify how the worker defines the
contingent workers. perceived deal with the employer and whether
or not the worker feels that the deal has been
Of Beard and Edwards’ five, the first three, honored or violated. According to Rousseau
are limited because they are characteris- (1995), psychological contracts can be both
tics which are present in all employment transactional and relational. Transactional-
relationships. For example, while traditional based contingent contracts are characteristic
workers may not hold contingent or fixed- of employment relationships where a worker
term contracts, they do hold perceptions of has a basic understanding of his or her
job insecurity. Some research suggests that responsibilities and anticipates that if these
in certain circumstances, core workers may expectations are met then the employer will
feel more insecure about their employment reciprocate with the agreed upon rewards. In
status than contingent workers. Ironically, the context of contingent employment, such
this may reflect that security is measured a transactional contract could exist among
in terms of finding replacement work rather workers dispatched by temporary-help firms
than simply losing current positions for many who anticipate delivering a fixed number of
types of contingent workers. Hence, it may hours of work in exchange for an agreed
not so much be a function of insecurity but upon compensation and the expectation of
rather how different groups of workers define future assignments from the temporary firm
job security (DeWitte and Näswall, 2003; (De Cuyper et al., 2005; Krausz et al., 1995;
Mauno et al., 2005). Similarly, the dimensions Marler et al., 2002; Smith, 2001). Guest and
of predictability and control can vary as Conway (2003) point out that professional and
much among contingent workers as there is knowledge workers on fixed-term contracts
variability between contingent and standard may report more positive evaluations of the
workers. This point is well demonstrated state of their psychological contracts because
when low-skill workers who are dispatched the contracts tend to be more transactional
through temporary-help firms are more often due to the explicit and bounded nature of
assigned to simple and well-structured job the tasks which they perform for client
tasks while contingent workers employed as organizations.
independent contractors usually exercise a In contrast, psychological contracts that are
great deal of control over when, where, and more relational indicate that workers believe
how they complete their work. that positive changes in their behavior (extra-
Beard and Edward (1995) also suggest that role behaviors, co-worker support, organi-
psychological contracts and social compari- zational citizenship) should be reciprocated
son processes may be useful constructs for by positive employer responses. In many
improving the understanding of individual respects, relational contracts are less focused
reactions to contingent work and associated on the employment relationship, are more
consequences. Psychological contracts have fluid in nature, and are based on expectations
been viewed as unwritten contracts which and rewards that gradually evolve between
exist between a worker and his or her the worker and employer. With direct-hire
employer organization (Rousseau, 1995). temporary workers, it is conceivable that a
Broadly defined, the psychological contract worker may come to expect that his or her
482 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

willingness to regularly accept assignments arrangements. Social comparison theory is


on short notice, work beyond scheduled hours, based on the principle that individuals
and perform at above-average levels should evaluate their own situations by compar-
be reciprocated by an employer through not ing themselves to others both within and
only expected compensation but also the outside of an organization (Kruglanski and
eventual reassignment of the worker to a Mayseless, 1990). Workers are more likely
permanent position within the organization. to hold more positive attitudes toward their
McLean Parks et al. (1998) report on the jobs when they see themselves being treated
dimensions on which psychological contracts similarly to other workers doing comparable
may differ (for example, scope, stability, work. Social comparison theory suggests
tangibility, duration, etc.) and suggest that that contingent workers who see themselves
a better understanding of 1) differences in as being treated the same as core workers
behaviors between contingent and traditional in employing organizations or better than
workers, 2) different forms of contingent contingent workers in other work settings
work, and 3) differences among workers are more likely to hold positive attitudes
performing similar types of contingent work toward their assignments. In past research,
can be achieved with a more thorough social comparison theory was viewed as
knowledge of the formal contractual terms a framework for understanding the job-
of employment, as well as the psychological related attitudes of part-time workers in
contract forged by individual contingent comparison to full-time workers (Barling
workers (De Cuyper et al., 2005; Guest, 2004). and Gallagher, 1996). However, the extent
As also noted by Drucker and Stanworth to which contingent workers are able to
(2004), among workers dispatched through make meaningful social comparisons may
staffing firms, the nature of the psychological be limited by organizations’ strategies to
contract is even more complex due to the deliberately isolate contingent workers rather
presence of a three-way relationship. than integrate them with core employees
The underlying notion of reciprocity, which (Lautsch, 2003).
is a foundation of psychological contracts, Volition and motivation also contribute
is the theoretical underpinning of social to the theoretical framework of contingent
exchange theory (Blau, 1964). According worker attitudes and behaviors. Research
to Connelly and Gallagher (2004a), social has consistently supported the finding that
exchange theory has been one of the most workers who are involuntarily working on
applied theories used-to-date to understand contingent contracts are significantly more
the attitudes and behaviors of contingent negative toward their work experiences
workers. Although well developed in the (Connelly and Gallagher, 2004a; Ellingson,
context of traditional employment relation- et al., 1998; Krausz et al., 2000). Such
ships, social exchange theory suggests that a finding supports the principle of status
worker support to an organization is a congruency, which suggests that workers who
function of the extent to which a worker are employed in work arrangements that are
feels that an organization is supportive. Based inconsistent with their personal preferences
on the social exchange theory, contingent (full-time vs. part-time; contingent vs. per-
workers’ responses to assignments and their manent) are more likely to hold negative
willingness to undertake additional role views toward their employer organizations
responsibilities may be a function of how and work experiences. Therefore, contin-
supportive they perceive the actions of their gent workers who seek contingent work
employing organizations to be (Ang and contracts and find such contracts consistent
Slaughter, 2001; Liden et al., 2003). with their personal or professional interests
According to Beard and Edwards (1995), are more likely to hold positive attitudes
‘social comparison theory’ also has promise and demonstrate positive behaviors in the
for better understanding contingent work workplace.
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 483

Although research on contingent work SOME ISSUES FOR FUTURE


could be criticized for over-relying on existing CONSIDERATION
behavioral theories that were developed
in the context of standard employment Many of the topical issues which have been
arrangements, there is no evidence that these addressed in this chapter are in the early stages
theoretical perspectives do not apply to of development and will require additional
contingent work arrangements. It appears academic attention and eventual public policy
more reasonable for researchers to question debate. However, as part of the conclusion to
how existing theoretical frameworks can this chapter, an effort will be made to identify
adequately fit the context of contingent work. a short list of contemporary issues related to
Furthermore, Gallagher and McLean Parks the growth of contingent work arrangements
(2001) state that one of the more crucial which are in need of further academic and
theoretical issues that needs to be addressed practitioner attention.
is the extent to which common constructs
developed in the context of more traditional
employer-employee relationships is relevant
Contingent work and high
to contingent work. For example, contingent
performance work systems
work assignments, which are established
through temporary-help staffing firms, raise In recent years, a considerable amount of
theoretical and practical questions about research and practitioner attention in literature
the meaning of a ‘job’ and perceived ‘job and seminars has been directed to the organi-
satisfaction.’ It is conceivable that some zational development of ‘High Performance
contingent workers who attain employment Work Systems’ (HPWS). The advocacy of
through temporary-staffing firm based may HPWS as an effective and established means
perceive their jobs as temporary worker while of enhancing firm performance is well
others may identify their jobs as tasks that established by Pfeffer (1994) in Competitive
they are currently performing for their client Advantage Through People. In a more recent
organizations. In the latter case, workers’ articulation of the underlying principles
attitudes toward their jobs may evidence of HPWS and commitment-based models,
dramatic differences as the temporary worker Pfeffer and Veiga (1999) suggest that workers
moves between client organizations. Simi- are more involved and committed when
larly, the meaning of ‘employer’ and the they have greater control and responsibility
commitment to an employer organization may placed in their hands. One of the more
be questionable in the context of contingent interesting aspects of the work of Pfeffer
workers who are employed as independent (1994) and Pfeffer and Veiga (1999) is their
contractors. These contractors may have identification of human resource management
different levels of commitment, or even practices that are essential ingredients in
different attitudes toward their employers, the development of high performance work
because, unlike other workers, independent environments. Listed among these strate-
contractors may hold simultaneous client gies is enhanced organizational performance
relationships. through the more effective use of human
In sum, as noted by McLean Parks resources including selective hiring, increased
et al. (1998) the tasks at hand may not employment security, self-managed teams,
necessarily be to invent new theoretical higher compensation based on organizational
frameworks of study for contingent work performance, extensive training investments,
but rather to give careful attention to how reduction in status differences within the
the existing theoretical frameworks may, to organization, and the sharing of information
varying degrees, be modified to adjust to the within the organization.
nuances of the various forms of contingent Using contingent workers as resources for
employment. facilitating organizational flexibility seems
484 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

to contradict the advice found in the workers on contingent contracts. In effect,


commitment-based and HPWS models of the question arises as to whether or not
human resource management. Such a con- organizational policies that restrict the scope
tradiction raises several questions. How can of contingent worker access to information
organizations rely on an increasing number have the unforeseen effect of increasing the
of temporary workers and at the same time obligations of non-contingent workers and
espouse a philosophy of employment secu- negatively impacting their attitudes toward
rity? To what extent are organizations likely the organization (Pearce, 1993).
to extend the principle of extensive training Organizational migration toward increased
investment or information sharing to workers use of contingent workers may also raise
on temporary or fixed-term contracts? And concern among standard workers regarding
are not contingent work contracts a form organizational intentions and the extent to
of intra-organizational status differentials? In which their own jobs are secure. Such
effect, either contingent work is inconsistent a concern could be particularly salient in
with the principles of HPWS, or HPWS organizations where standard workers have
models are exclusive to an organization’s been terminated and rehired as independent
core workforce. From a research and practical contractors (Ho, Ang, and Straub, 2003).
perspective, attention should be given to the Although such workers would certainly be
long-term consideration of the extent to which placed into the status of objectively insecure
marginalization practices and HPWS models employment (fixed-term), the question arises
can effectively co-exist. concerning the extent to which the use of
contingent staffing arrangements ultimately
impact the subjective feeling of job insecu-
Spillover or unexpected
rity among standard workers (Davis-Blake
consequences
et al., 2003). Perhaps what is needed is a
Much of the early literature on the growth greater understanding of the extent to which
of contingent work contracts, as well as contingent employment strategies adopted by
literature on the use of alternative employment organizations have a ‘spillover’ effect on
arrangements (leasing, subcontracting, etc.), the attitudes and behaviors of the traditional
offered the promise that the use of non- workforce. Mauno et al. (2005) suggest that
standard employment arrangements could insecurity among workers on more allegedly
also be viewed as a layer of protection from permanent contract terms may have more
fluctuations in market demand for the organi- negative effects on worker well-being than
zation’s regular or standard workforce (Nollen is the case for workers who hold objectively
and Axel, 1996). However, within empirical insecure jobs.
literature there are some suggestions that,
contrary to intent, standard workers who are
Contingent work and unionization
part of a core organization could view the
organization’s increased usage of contingent From both the workplace and broader public
workers as a threat to both existing job policy perspectives, issues can be raised
responsibilities and their own employment concerning what, if any, relationship exists
security. between labor unionism and the increased
In particular, as Pearce (1993) and Ang organizational utilization of contingent work-
and Slaughter (2001) note, the introduction ers. There tends to be rather limited evidence
of contingent workers, especially independent as to whether or not increased organizational
contractors, as staffing alternatives to hiring use of contingent workers is systematically
workers under more standard contracts often related to the workplace presence of unions or
results in core employees taking on duties if unionization is itself a spur to organizational
and responsibilities which organizations wish reliance on contingent workers as a staffing
to omit from the job duties of peripheral strategy (Olsen, 2003). However, there is
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 485

objective data to suggest that the rate of union assistance through a servicing model of
representation among temporary workers (and representation which helps provide contingent
part-time workers) is significantly lower than workers with collective access to benefits,
the rate of standard or core workers (Gallie assistance, and professional resources which
et al., 1998; Riley, 1998; Sverke et al., they need to maintain their careers. Heery et al.
2004; Zeytinoğlu, 1999). As Cobble and (2004) suggest that among freelance workers,
Vosko (2000) observe, difficulty in organizing unions can help maintain the human capital
contingent workers may stem in part from of members through systems of vocational
their mobility or frequent transition from one education and training. However as Cobble
employer to another or the movement from (1994) notes, such forms of professional self-
temporary worker status to standard or ongo- help in organizations that are most often
ing employee status. Unionization is further organized on a collectivist principle, but
complicated because the distinction between outside the mainstream structure of unionism,
employer and employee is less definitive have been a past method for the representation
(Cobble and Vosko, 2000). Such an obser- of non-standard workers.
vation appears to be particularly relevant to Further extending the application of
the large segment of contingent workers who Hyman’s typology of union strategies, Heery
are self-employed as independent contractors and Abbott (2000) write that unions may
and by definition, under many national labor respond to the growth of insecure and
laws, may fall outside the scope of the right contingent work by entering in partnerships
to union representation. Furthermore, there with management to seek ways to make
is no substantial evidence to support that work less secure. On a broader basis, unions
contingent workers have a particular interest may also undertake the strategy of entering
or propensity to embrace unionization as into a social dialogue or mobilization to
it is currently structured. In fact, among respectively protect union jobs while simulta-
contingent workers in more professional jobs, neously seeking to achieve greater protection
the relationship with unionism has been rather for the security of contingent workers and
bleak (Benner and Dean, 2000). further informing society at large about the
Building upon research by Hyman (1994) potential negative consequences of insecure
on the typologies of union strategic choices, employment.
Heery (2004) and Heery and Abbott (2000) The study of contingent work can benefit
suggest that unions may choose to take one from future research if it makes the effort
of a variety of responses to the growing to determine the types of strategies, if any,
presence of ‘insecure jobs’ or contingent union movements are utilizing in response to
working arrangements. These strategies are the growth of contingent work arrangements
diverse and include such options as exclusion on an international basis (Heery, 2004). Of
where the union seeks to exclude contingent particular interest would be the consideration
workers from employment in organizations of the degree to which union responses are a
where unions have representational rights. function of the structure of union representa-
Such a strategy would not be unlike initial tion at the national level and extent of growth
union opposition to the growth of part- of contingent work within various industries.
time work in many industries. The exclusion Inherent within such an examination would
strategy implies the presence of a fundamental be consideration of how international dif-
union belief that contingent work represents ferences in basic labor legislation influence
a threat to traditional jobs. Alternatively, the potential impact of contingent work. It
Heery and Abbot (2000) and Cobble (1994) would also be especially useful to determine
explain that unions may recognize the rep- if union responses are different based on the
resentational needs of contingent workers form of contingent employment of concern.
but, as a reflection of the casual nature of Most notably, the focus should be on how
many contingent jobs, may seek to provide unions perceive differences in both threat
486 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and strategic responses with regard to the International Review of Industrial and Organizational
presence of direct-hire temporaries compared Psychology, 11: 243–277. John Wiley and Sons Ltd.
with displaced workers from temporary-help Beard, K. M., and Edwards, J. R. (1995) Employees
firms. at risk: Contingent work and the psychological
experience of contingent workers. In C. L. Cooper
and D. M. Rousseau (eds), Trends in organizational
behavior, 2: 109–26. Chichester, UK: Wiley.
CONCLUSION Benner, C. and Dean, A. (2000) Labor in the
new economy: Lessons from labor organizing in
A fundamental objective of this chapter Silicon Valley. In F. Carré, M. Ferber, L. Golden
has been to provide a broad overview of and S. Herzenberg (eds) Nonstandard work: The
the issues pertaining to the concept of nature and challenge of changing employment
contingent employment. Although contingent arrangements. Champaign, IL: IRRA.
employment contracts have, for a variety Bergstrøm, O. and Storrie, D. (2003) Contingent
employment in Europe and the United States.
of reasons, become an increasingly common
Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
aspect of the employment landscape, there Bernasek, A. and Kinnear, D. (1999) ‘Workers’ willing-
exists a large number of definitional, legal, ness to accept contingent employment’. Journal of
theoretical, and practical IR-based issues that Economic Issues, 33 (2): 461–70.
are in need of more systematic research Blau, P. (1964). Exchange and power in social life.
attention. It is hoped that this chapter has New York: Wiley.
provided readers with not only commentary Booth, A. L. Dolado, J. J. and Frank, J. (2002a)
pertaining to past issues and research but ‘Symposium on temporary work introduction’. The
also some seedlings for future research and Economic Journal, 112 (2): F181–F188.
subsequent policy debate on the merits and Booth, A. L., Francesconi, M. and Frank, J. (2002b)
dangers of contingent employment as a means ‘Temporary jobs: Stepping stones or dead ends?’ The
of achieving organizational flexibility and Economic Journal, 112 (2): F189–F213.
Brewster, C., Mayne, L. and Tregaskis, O. (1997)
competitive advantage.
‘Flexible working in Europe: A review of the evidence’.
Management International Review, 37 (1): 85–103.
Cappelli, P. and Neumark, D. (2003) ‘External churning
REFERENCES and internal flexibility: Evidence on the functional
flexibility and core-periphery hypotheses’. Industrial
Abraham, K. G. (1988) Flexible staffing arrangements Relations, 43 (1): 148–82.
and employers’ short-term adjustment strategies. In Carnoy, M., Castells, M. and Benner, C. (1997) ‘Labour
R. A. Hart (ed.), Employment, Unemployment, and markets and employment practices in the age of
Labour Utlization. London: Hyman. pp. 288–311. flexibility: A case of Silicon Valley’. International
Alba-Ramirez, A. (1998) ‘How temporary is temporary Labour Review, 136 (1): 27–48.
employment in Spain?’ Journal of Labor Research, Cobble, D. S. (1994) Making postindustrial unionism
19 (4): 675–710. possible. In S. Friedman et al. (eds) Restoring the
Ang, S. and Slaughter, S. A. (2001) ‘Work outcomes and promise of American labor law. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
job design for contract versus permanent information University Press.
systems professionals on software development Cobble, D. S. and Vosko, L. F. (2000) Historical
teams’. MIS Quarterly, 25 (3): 321–50. perspectives on representing non-standard workers.
Aronsson, G., Gustafsson, K. and Dallner, M. (2002) In F. Carré, M. Ferber, L. Golden, and S. Herzenberg
‘Work environment and health in different types (eds) Nonstandard work: The nature and challenge of
of temporary jobs’. European Journal of Work and changing employment arrangements. Champaign, IL:
Organizational Psychology, 11 (2): 151–75. IRRA. pp. 291–312.
Barley, S. R. and Kunda, G. (2004) Gurus, hired guns, Cohany, S. (1998) ‘Workers in alternative employment
and warm bodies: Itinerant experts in the knowl- arrangements: A second look’. Monthly Labor Review,
edge economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University 121 (?): 3–21.
Press. Connelly, C. E. and Gallagher, D. G. (2004a) ‘Emerging
Barling, J. and Gallagher, D. G. (1996) Part-time trends in contingent work research’. Journal of
employment. In C.L. Cooper and I.T. Robertson (eds), Management, 30 (6): 959–83.
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 487

Connelly, C. E. and Gallagher, D. G. (2004b) Managing contingent work relationship’. Human Resource
contingent workers: Adapting to new realities, In Management Review, 11 (3): 181–208.
R. Burke and C. Cooper (eds) Leading in turbulent Gallagher, D. and Sverke, M. (2005) ‘Contingent
times. Malden, MA: Blackwell. employment contract: Are existing employment
Cully, M., Woodland, S., O’Reilly, A. and Dix, G. (1999) theories still relevant?’ Economic and Industrial
Britain at work. London: Routledge. Democracy, 26 (2): 181–203.
Davis-Blake, A., Broschak, J. P. and George, E. (2003) Gallie, D., White, M., Cheng, Y. and Tomlinson, M.
‘Happy together? How using nonstandard workers (1998) Restructuring the employment relationship.
affects exit, voice, and loyalty among standard Oxford: Oxford University Press.
employees’. Academy of Management Journal, 46 (4): Galup, S., Saunders, C., Nelson, R. E. and Cerveny, R.
475–85. (1997) ‘The use of temporary staff and managers
Davis-Blake, A. and Uzzi, B. (1993) ‘Determinants of in a local government environment’. Communication
employment externalization: A study of temporary Research, 24 (6): 698–730.
workers and independent contractors’. Administra- Geary, J. F. (1992) ‘Employment flexibility and human
tive Science Quarterly, 38 (2): 195–223. resource management: The case of three American
De Cuyper, N., Isaksson, K. and De Witte, H. (eds) electronics plants’. Work, Employment and Society,
(2005) Employment contracts and well-being among 6 (2): 251–70.
European workers. Aldershot, Ashgate. Golden, L. and Appelbaum, E. (1992) ‘What was driving
Delsen, L. (1999) Changing work relationships in the the 1982–1988 boom in temporary employment?’
European union. In I. Zeytinoğlu (ed.) Changing American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 51 (4):
work relationships in industrialized economies. 473–93.
Amsterdam: John Benjamins. pp. 99–114. Gonos, G. (1997) ‘The contest over ‘employer’ status in
DeWitte, H. and Näswall, K. (2003) “‘Objective” vs
the postwar US: The case of temporary help-firms’.
“subjective” job insecurity: Consequences of tem-
Law and Society, 31 (1): 81–110.
porary work for job satisfaction and organizational
Gooderham, P. M. and Nordhaug, O. (1997) ‘Flex-
commitment in four European countries’. Economic
ibility in Norwegian and UK firms: Competitive
and Industrial Democracy, 24 (2): 149–88.
pressures and institutional embeddedness’. Employee
DiNatale, M. (2001) ‘Characteristics of and preference
Relations, 19 (6): 568–80.
for alternative work arrangements, 1999’. Monthly
Goslinga, S. and Sverke, M. (2003) ‘Atypical work and
Labor Review, 124 (3): 28–49.
trade union membership’. Economic and Industrial
Doogan, K. (2001) ‘Insecurity and long-term employ-
Democracy, 24 (2): 290–312.
ment’. Work, Employment and Society, 15 (3):
419–41. Greene, B. (2000) ‘Independent contractors: An
Drucker, P. F. (2002) ‘They’re not employees, they’re attractive option?’ New Zealand Journal of Industrial
people’. Harvard Business Review, 80 (2) February: Relations, 25 (2): 183–204.
70–77. Greer, C. R., Youngblood, S. A. and Gray, D. A.
Druker, J. and Stanworth, C. (2004) ‘Mutual expectation: (1999) ‘Human resource management outsourcing:
A study of the three-way relationship between The make or buy decision’. Academy of Management
employment agencies, their client organizations and Executive, 13 (6): 85–96.
white-collar agency “temps”’. Industrial Relations Guest, D. E. (1998) ‘Is the psychological contract worth
Journal, 35 (1): 58–75. taking seriously?’ Journal of Organizational Behavior,
Ellingson, J. E., Gruys, M. L. and Sackett, P. R. (1998) 19 (1): 649–64.
‘Factors related to the satisfaction and performance of Guest, D. E. (2004) ‘Flexible employment contracts,
temporary employees’. Journal of Applied Psychology, the psychological contract and employee outcomes:
83 (6): 913–21. An analysis and review of the evidence’. Interna-
Fragoso, J. L. and Kleiner, B. H. (2005) ‘How to tional Journal of Management Reviews, 5/6 (1):
distinguish between independent contractors and 1–20.
employees’. Management Research News, 28 (2/3): Guest, D. E. and Conway, N. (2003) The psychological
136–49. contract, health and well being. In M. J. Schabracq,
Gallagher, D. G. (2002) Contingent work contracts: J. A. M. Winnubst and C. L. Cooper (eds) The
Practice and theory. In C. Cooper and R. Burke (eds) handbook of work and health psychology. Chichester:
The new world of work: Challenges and opportunities. John Wiley and Sons, Ltd. pp. 143–58.
Oxford: Blackwell Publishers. pp. 115–36. Hamel, G. and Prahalad, C. K. (1994) Competing for
Gallagher, D. G. and McLean Parks, J. (2001) ‘I pledge the future. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
thee my troth…contingently: Commitment and the Press.
488 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Hanratty, T. (2000) ‘The impact of numerical flexibility on arrangements in US organizations’. Social Science
training for quality in the Irish manufacturing sector’. Research, 32 (4): 525–52.
Journal of European Industrial Training, 24 (9): Klein Hesselink, D. J. and van Vuuren, T. (1999)
505–12. ‘Job flexibility and job insecurity: The Dutch case’.
Hardy, D. J. and Walker, R. J. (2003) ‘Temporary but European Journal of Work and Organizational
seeking permanence: A study of New Zealand temps’. Psychology, 8 (?): 273–93.
Leadership and Organization Development Journal, Kochan, T. A., Smith, M., Wells, J. C. and Rebitzer, J. B.
24 (3): 141–52. (1994) ‘Human resource strategies and contingent
Heckscher, C. (2000) HR strategy and nonstandard work: workers: The case of safety and health in the petro-
Dualism versus true mobility. In F. Carré, M. Ferber, chemical industry’. Human Resource Management,
L. Golden and S. Herzenberg (eds) Nonstandard 33 (1): 55–77.
work: The nature and challenge of changing Kondrasuk, J .N., Reed, L. J. and Jurinski, J. J.
employment arrangements. Champaign, IL: IRRA. (2001) ‘The dangers of misclassifying ‘employ-
pp. 267–90. ees’: Microsoft litigation emphasizes distinctions
Heery, E. (2004) ‘The trade union response to agency between employees and nontraditional workers’.
labour in Britain’. Industrial Relations Journal, Employee Responsibilities and Rights Journal, 13 (4):
35 (5):434–50. 165–73.
Heery, E. and Abbott, B. (2000) Trade unions and Krausz, M., Brandwein, T. and Fox, S. (1995) ‘Work
the insecure workforce. In E. Heery and J. Salmon attitudes and emotional responses of permanent ,
(eds) The insecure workforce. London: Routledge. voluntary, and involuntary temporary-help employ-
pp. 155–80. ees: An exploratory study’. Applied Psychology: An
Heery, E., Conley, H., Delbridge, R. and Stewart, P. International Review, 44 (3): 217–32.
(2004) Beyond the enterprise: Trade union repre- Krausz, M., Sagie, A. and Biderman, Y. (2000) ‘Actual
sentation of freelances in the UK. Human Resource and preferred work schedules and scheduling control
Management Journal, 14 (2): 20–35. as determinants of job-related attitudes’. Journal of
Henson, K. D. (1996) Just a temp. Philadelphia: Temple Vocational Behavior, 56 (1): 1–11.
University Press. Kruglanski, A. W. and Mayseless, O. (1990) ‘Classic
Hipple, S. (1998) ‘Contingent work: Results from the and current social comparison research: Expanding
second survey’. Monthly Labor Review, 121 (11) the perspective’. Psychological Bulletin, 108 (2):
November: 22–34. 195–208.
Ho, V. T., Ang, S. and Straub, D. (2003) ‘When subor- Kunda, G., Barley, S. R. and Evans, J. (2002) ‘Why
dinates become IT contractors: Persistent managerial do contractors contract? The experience of highly
expectations in IT outsourcing’. Information Systems skilled technical professionals in a contingent labor
Research, 14 (1): 66–86. market’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
Houseman, S. N. (2001) ‘Why employers use flexible 55 (2): 234–60.
staffing arrangements: Evidence from an establish- Lautsch, B. A. (2002) ‘Uncovering and explaining
ment survey’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, variance in the features and outcomes of contingent
55 (1): 149–70. work’. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 56 (1):
Hyman, R. (1994) Changing trade union identities and 23–43.
strategies. In R Hyman, R. and A. Ferner (eds) New Lautsch, B. A. (2003) ‘The influence of regular work
frontiers in European industrial relations. Oxford: systems on compensation for contingent workers’.
Blackwell. Industrial Relations, 42 (4): 565–88.
International Labour Office (2000) Meeting of experts Lepak, D. P. and Snell, S. A. (2002) ‘Examining
on workers in situations needing protection. the human resource architecture: The relationships
MEWNP/2000, Geneva: International Labour Office. among human capital, employment and human
Kalleberg, A. L. (2000) ‘Nonstandard employment resource configurations’. Journal of Management,
relations: Part-time, temporary and contract work’. 28 (4): 517–43.
Annual Review of Sociology, 26 (1): 341–65. Liden, R. C., Wayne, S. J., Kraimer, M. L. and
Kalleberg, A. L. and Marsden, P. V. (2005) ‘Exter- Sparrowe, R. T. (2003) ‘The dual commitments of
nalizing organizational activities: Where and how contingent workers: An examination of contingents’
US establishments use employment intermediaries’. commitment to the agency and the organization’.
Socio-Economic Review, 3 (3): 389–415. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 24 (5): 609–25.
Kalleberg, A. L., Reynolds, J. and Marsden, P. V. Marler, J. H., Barringer, M. W. and Milkovich, G. T.
(2003) ‘Externalizing employment: Flexible staffing (2002) ‘Boundaryless and traditional contingent
CONTINGENT WORK ARRANGEMENTS 489

employees: Worlds apart’. Journal of Organizational and effects on employee coworkers’. Academy of
Behavior, 23 (4): 425–53. Management Journal, 36 (5): 1082–96.
Marlin, E. (2000) The perspectives for a new Pfeffer, J. (1994) Competitive advantage through
and comprehensive vision of the protection of people: Unleashing the power of the workforce.
workers. Proceedings of the 12th World Congress Boston: Harvard University Press.
of the International Industrial Relations Research Pfeffer, J. (1998) The human equation: Building profits
Association Tokyo, Japan. Champaign: IRRA. pp. by putting people first. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
151–59. School Press.
Matusik, S. F. and Hill, C. W. L. (1998) ‘The utilization Pfeffer, J. and Baron, N. (1988) Taking the work back
of contingent work, knowledge creation, and out: Recent trends in the structures of employment.
competitive advantage’. Academy of Management In B. M. Staw, and L. L. Cummings (eds) Research in
Review, 23(4): 680–97. organizational behavior, 10, 257–303.
Mauno, S., Kinnunen, U., Mäkikangas, A. and Nätti, J. Pfeffer, J. and Veiga, J. F. (1999) ‘Putting people
(2005) ‘Psychological consequences of fixed-term first for organizational success’. The Academy of
employment and perceived job insecurity among Management Executive, 13 (2): 37–48.
health care staff’. European Journal of Work and Pink, D. H. (2001) Free agent nation. New York: Time
Organizational Psychology, 14 (3): 209–37. Warner.
McAllister, J. (1998) Sisyphus at work in the warehouse: Polivka, A. E. and Nardone, T. (1989) ‘The definition of
Temporary employment in Greenville, South Carolina. contingent work’. Monthly Labor Review, 112 (12):
In K. Barker and K. Christensen (eds) Contingent 9–16.
work: American employment relations in transition. Quinlan, M. and Bohle, P. (2004) Contingent work
Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. and occupational safety. In Barling, J. and Frone,
McDonald, D. J. and Makin, P. J. (2000) ‘The M.R. (eds) The psychology of workplace safety.
psychological contract, organizational commitment Washington: American Psychological Association.
and job satisfaction of temporary staff’. Leadership pp. 81–105.
and Organizational Development Journal, 21 (2): Reilly, P.A. (1998) ‘Balancing flexibility, meeting the
84–91. interests of employer and employee’. European Journal
McLean Parks, J., Kidder, D. L. and Gallagher, D. G. of Work and Organizational Psychology, 7 (1): 7–22.
(1998) ‘Fitting square pegs into round holes: Mapping Rogers, J. K. (2000) Temps: The many faces of the
the domain of contingent work arrangements onto changing workplace. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
the psychological contract’. Journal of Organizational Rousseau, D. M. (1995) Psychological contracts in
Behavior, 19 (S1): 697–730. organizations: Understanding written and unwritten
Nesheim, T. (2003) ‘Using external work arrangements agreements. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
in core value-creation areas’. European Management Segal, L. M. and Sullivan, D. G. (1997) ‘The growth
Journal, 21 (4): 528–37. of temporary services workers’. Journal of Economic
Nishikawa, M. (2000) Diversification in the use Perspectives, 11 (2): 117–36.
of atypical workers in Japanese establishments. Smith, V. (2001) Crossing the great divide: Worker risk
Proceedings of the 12th World Congress of the and opportunity in the new economy. Ithaca: Cornell
International Industrial Relations Research Associa- University Press.
tion.Tokyo: Japan. Champaign: IRRA. pp. 160–68. Sverke, M., Hellgren, J., Näswall, K., Chirumbolo, A.,
Nollen, S. D. and Axel, H. (1996) Managing contingent De Witte, H. and Goslinga, S. (2004) Job insecurity
workers: How to reap the benefits and reduce the and union membership: European unions in the wake
risks. New York: AMACOM. of flexible production. Brussels: P.I.E. Peter Lang.
Olsen, K. M. (2003) Contingency reversed: The role Uzzi, B. and Barsness, Z. I. (1998) ‘Contingent
of agency temporaries and contractors in client- employment in British establishments: Organizational
organizations. Presented at Academy of Management determinants of the use of fixed-term hires and
meeting in Seattle, WA. part-time workers’. Social Forces, 76 (3): 967–1007.
Parker, S. K., Griffin, M. A., Sprigg, C. A. and Van Dyne, L. and Ang, S. (1998) ‘Organizational
Wall, T. D. (2002) ‘Effect of temporary contracts citizenship behavior of contingent workers in
on perceived work characteristics and job strain: Singapore’. Academy of Management Journal, 41 (6):
A longitudinal study’. Personnel Psychology, 55 (3): 692–703.
689–719. Virtanen, M., Kivimaki, M., Virtanen, P., Elovainio, M.
Pearce, J. L. (1993) ‘Toward an organizational behavior and Vahtera, J. (2003) ‘Disparity in occupational
of contract laborers: Their psychological involvement training and career planning between contingent and
490 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

permanent employees’. European Journal of Work Wheeler, A. R. and Buckley, M. R. (2000) ‘Examining the
and Organizational Psychology, 12 (1): 19–36. motivation process of temporary employees’. Journal
Voudouris, I. (2004) ‘The use of flexible employment of Managerial Psychology, 16 (5): 339–54.
arrangement: Some evidence from Greek firms’. Inter- Zeytinoğlu, I. U. (1999) Changing work relationships
national Journal of Human Resource Management, in industrialized economies, (ed.) Amsterdam: John
15 (1): 131–46. Benjamins Publishing.
26
The Theory and Practice
of Pay Setting
Alex Bryson and John Forth1

INTRODUCTION income paid as labor is supplied, but also


deferred payments, such as pensions, together
In modern economies employers purchase with non-monetary rewards such as health
labor power from workers who, in general, insurance, which employees often rate as
obtain their income from the sale of their more valuable than their monetary equivalents
labor. For the employer, the wage is the (Dale-Olsen, 2006).
price of labor: the cost of securing the Despite these complexities, this charac-
worker’s productive capacity. However, as terization nonetheless implies that ‘pay’ is
management theorists (and efficiency wage the outcome of a relatively straightforward,
theorists before them) tend to emphasize, pay private, economic transaction in which work-
can also be used to elicit greater worker effort. ers receive pay in return for effort. But
As Marx (1976) emphasized, employers this is not the case for three reasons. First,
generally purchase units of workers’ time social norms govern what is considered to
rather than discrete units of effort. Employers be the appropriate trade-off between effort
can create incentives for workers to work and reward. There is, for instance, a strong
more intensively over a given period – tradition of what constitutes a ‘fair day’s work
what Marx termed the ‘real subsumption of for a fair day’s pay’. Moreover, governments
labour’– or to work more extensively, by may intervene when market-set wages do
increasing their working hours over a given not meet the subsistence needs of workers,
day, or even over a career (through increased either requiring certain minimum pay levels
tenure). From the employee’s perspective, pay or supplementing pay from public funds (for
is the reward for labor, that is, the actual example, through tax credits).
effort of producing goods or services. The A second reason is that employers are often
nature of the payment varies greatly across judged by what they pay and employees by
workers, and may include not only monetary what they receive. Again, social norms play
492 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

a role, since employers may gain plaudits wages for unionized employees; and they
for socially responsible behavior. But equally reveal the earnings differentials that exist
their stock price may respond positively to between men and women.
a lowering of labor costs. For employees, Table 26.1 presents summary statistics on
one’s social status is often bound up with gross hourly earnings in the UK.2 The table
one’s wage and even how it is paid (hourly, shows a gender wage differential of around
weekly or as an annual salary). It may bear 20 per cent in favor of male employees, an
directly upon well-being, not only in terms of advantage for full-time workers over part-
what workers can wear and eat, but in terms time employees of around 30 per cent and
of what they can borrow, and how they are extensive variation between employees with
perceived by colleagues, friends and relatives. different academic achievements. There is
Workers’ well-being is highly correlated with also considerable wage variation within each
perceptions of their pay relative to their peers of these groupings. The employee at the
(Brown et al., 2005). 90th percentile of the distribution typically
Third, employers and employees some- has gross hourly earnings that are around
times involve others in wage setting. twice those of the median worker and around
Employees may join together to bargain with four times those of the employee at the
an employer, typically through a trade union. 10th percentile. This partly reflects variations
Similarly, employers may act collectively if in the way the employment relationship is
they wish to avoid outbidding one another formulated. Wages set in a purely competitive
for scarce labor, thus ‘taking wages out market would solely reflect a worker’s
of competition’ by setting single rates in productivity and would be independent of the
particular industries, localities or occupations. firm. However, as discussed later, there are
This chapter focuses on pay variance across many reasons why workers’ pay may vary
workers, employers and across time and across firms, such as the acquisition of firm-
illustrates how theories of pay determination specific human capital, union bargaining or
can shed light on this variance. We discuss the desire of employers to pay above market
the limitations of the orthodox economic wages to capture the rents that ‘good’ workers
approach to pay-setting and emphasize the generate. Table 26.1 shows, for example, that
importance of labor market imperfections, employees whose pay is negotiated by trade
the role of institutions and the uniqueness unions have wages that are 10 per cent higher,
of the labor contract in determining wage on average, than non-unionized employees.
outcomes. Two broad conclusions emerge: This raises the question of how much wage
first that no single theory has an overriding variance occurs within workplaces, and how
claim to virtue; and, second, that in spite much occurs across workplaces? The answer
of the knowledge generated within the field has important implications for labor mobility
of industrial relations (IR), as will become and productivity. If, for the sake of argument,
apparent, much remains to be understood. all workers in a firm are paid the same wage,
The chapter begins by examining the degree but all firms pay a different wage – that is,
of variance in pay levels. all variance is across workplaces – workers
would have to move to obtain higher wages,
and they may be particularly concerned about
PATTERNS OF PAY which firm they join when first entering the
labor market. At the other extreme, say all
Any cursory examination of earnings is likely firms are identical in the distribution of wages
to indicate some of the factors that play they pay their workers – that is, all variance
either a direct or indirect role in pay setting. is within firms – it would matter very little
Earnings statistics illustrate how wages vary which firm the worker joins since the rewards
by occupation or skill level; they point toward for advancement will be equivalent. Our own
the role of collective bargaining in raising analysis of linked employer-employee data for
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 493

Table 26.1 Gross hourly earnings in the UK, Autumn 2005


Mean Percentiles Percentile ratios
10th 50th 90th 50:10 90:10
All employees 10.90 5.00 8.84 19.22 1.77 2.17
Gender:
Men 12.21 5.40 10.32 21.92 1.91 2.12
Women 9.70 4.80 8.00 16.99 1.67 2.12
Hours worked per week:
Full-time (30 or more) 11.75 5.54 10.00 20.51 1.81 2.05
Part-time (1-29) 8.21 4.33 6.42 14.73 1.48 2.29
Highest qualification:
Degree or equivalent 16.16 7.00 14.58 27.03 2.08 1.85
Higher education 12.49 6.18 11.74 19.67 1.90 1.68
GCE A-level or equivalent 10.05 5.00 8.66 16.83 1.73 1.94
GCSE grades A-C or equivalent 8.67 4.69 7.56 14.16 1.61 1.87
Other qualifications 8.39 4.69 7.29 13.23 1.55 1.81
No qualifications 7.12 4.50 6.25 11.11 1.39 1.78
Unionization:
Collective bargaining 11.72 5.78 10.35 19.22 1.79 1.86
No collective bargaining 10.65 4.80 8.21 19.24 1.71 2.34
Source: UK Labor Force Survey, Autumn 2005.

Britain shows that workplace characteristics inequality between middle and top earners
can account for at least as much of the (the 90:50 percentile ratio), and between
variation in hourly wages as differences middle and low earners (the 50:10 percentile
in employees’ educational achievements and ratio). The trend was apparent for men and
work experience, indicating a major role for women. In the first half of the 1990s, the
firm-specific factors.3 male wage distribution continued to widen,
The figures in Table 26.1 take no account though more slowly, driven by increases
of non-pecuniary rewards, such as subsidized among top earners. Women, on the other hand,
or free health care, or employers’ pension experienced some wage compression. Under
contributions. These tend to increase the the recent Labour governments, male wages
differential between higher- and lower-paid have compressed a little whereas, among
workers, widening the gap between men women, there has been further compression at
and women (Joshi and Paci, 1998; Anderson the top and some compression between middle
et al., 2001) and increasing the premium and low earners.4
associated with collective bargaining (Forth Attempts to explain variations in wages
and Millward, 2000; Budd, 2004). For across workers and over time are only
employers, the picture is further complicated partially successful. Statistical analyses which
by the addition of indirect labor costs, such as account for differences in individual, job
social security contributions. These account and employer characteristics can typically
for around 13 per cent of total hourly labor explain little more than 50 per cent of
costs in the UK, compared with 25–30 per cent the cross-sectional variation in gross hourly
in the EU as a whole (Eurostat, 2001). earnings. This partly indicates the difficulties
Returning to the pattern of direct earnings, in devising adequate proxies for important
there have been notable changes in wage dis- factors such as employee productivity or
persion over time. Inequality in gross earnings bargaining power. But it also indicates the
grew in Britain in the 1980s after a century of limitations of our ability to understand the
relative stability (Gregg and Machin, 1994). complexity of pay setting. The rest of the
Klondylis and Wadsworth (2006) show that, chapter discusses what is generally known
during the 1980s, there was rising wage about this complexity.
494 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

NEO-CLASSICAL LABOR MARKET However, some argue that educational attain-


THEORY ment acts primarily as a signal of unobserved
ability, which is then rewarded appropriately
A conventional starting point in economics is in the labor market, rather than serving as
the neo-classical model of the labor market a productivity-enhancing investment (Arrow,
under which wages, like other prices, are 1973; Spence, 1973).
determined by the forces of supply and Estimates of the wage returns to ‘skills’
demand. Faced with a supply of workers (each are less common. Human capital theory
with their own preferences about how much distinguishes between generic skills, which
labor they will supply at given wage levels), can be applied in a wide range of jobs or
the employer decides how many and which industries, and firm-specific skills. Using a
types of workers to employ at wage levels detailed questionnaire covering a wide range
at which it can trade profitably. The firm of generic skills, Green and Dickerson (2004)
will hire increasing numbers of workers up showed that computing skills and high-level
to the point where their wage is equal to communication skills attract higher wages, as
their marginal product. Workers, for their part, do the ability to act without close supervision
will offer themselves for employment until and the capacity to manage varied tasks.
the next potential recruit considers the wage Others have identified returns to industry-
an insufficient inducement. Under perfect specific skills, which become apparent when
competition, and with freedom of entry and displaced workers take lower-paid jobs in
exit for firms and workers, these market forces other sectors (Neal, 1995).
produce a single wage at which supply and If wages are related to skill, changes in the
demand are in equilibrium. In this situation, skill distribution within the economy should
employers and employees are ‘price takers’ affect wage differentials. McIntosh finds no
without the power to set wages. A state of recent change in the return to academic
disequilibrium may arise from time-to-time, qualifications, despite the expansion of higher
in which wages do not lie on the intersection education (ibid). But others point to a wider
of the supply and demand curves. But this is process whereby technological change has
expected to be a short-run phenomenon whilst increased demand for skill and automated
prices adjust to changes in levels of demand intermediate low-skilled jobs, resulting in
or supply. congestion at the lower end of the labor
The theory predicts higher wages for market, which, in turn, pushes down wages
workers who generate more output given a in low-skilled jobs that cannot be automated.
fixed amount of capital. But it says little This is consistent with developments in the
about what determines worker productivity, 1980s in the US (Autor et al., 2003). However,
although there is a broad notion of ‘skill’ in the 1990s the US experienced growing
which implicitly equates with it in many demand for both high-skilled jobs and non-
instances. Adam Smith (1982) noted that automated lower-skilled jobs (Autor et al.,
output and wages were related not only to 2006) which, coupled with the passing of
innate abilities but also to acquired skills, the ‘glut’ of displaced routine labor, resulted
but human capital theory has more recently in wage increases at the bottom end of the
formalized the conception of education and labor market. The net effect is stabilization
training as investments which could generate in the lower half of the pay distribution
returns, both to employers through increased and continuing growth in pay disparities in
output and to employees through higher the upper half of the distribution. Goos and
wages (Becker, 1964).5 Estimates of the Manning (2003) and Spitz (2005) also point to
wage returns to educational investments are a ‘polarization of work’ over the last 25 years
widespread. Recent estimates for the UK in the UK and West Germany respectively.
indicate that possession of a degree raises Although this story seems plausible, one
wages by 26–29 per cent (McIntosh, 2006). might wonder, since technological innovation
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 495

is all-pervasive, why these forces have not suggest that there may be considerable
produced increasing wage inequality in more variation between firms (for example, Dunlop,
countries. 1957; Mackay et al., 1971; Brown et al., 1980;
Nolan and Brown, 1983; Gilman et al., 2002).
Whilst the theory allows for some short-
CRITICISMS OF THE NEO-CLASSICAL term variance, as employers and employees
APPROACH adjust to changes in the demand for labor,
longer-term differences should be impercep-
Commentators have rejected the neo-classical tible (Hicks, 1932: 24–27). However, the
model to different degrees. Almost all con- evidence suggests that differences may be
sider it an abstraction from reality, since few more pervasive and do not simply reflect
markets are perfectly competitive and firms returns to firm-specific skills. Rather, it is
and workers are rarely free to enter and suggested that the reality of wage setting
leave markets without delay. Some see it as rejects the neo-classical model in favor of a
a simplification which nonetheless provides a more complex account in which employers
good indication of general tendencies (Hicks, and employees may both play an active part.
1932: 5). Others are more categorical in
rejecting it as a meaningful approximation of
the wage-setting process which overplays the IMPERFECTLY COMPETITIVE
market’s invisible hand (for example, Rubery, MARKETS
1997; Manning, 2003).
Critics point to a range of empirical facts Relaxing the assumption of perfect compe-
that appear to contradict the neo-classical tition leads to different predictions of the
depiction of the labor market. First, they outcomes of pay setting and some plausible
point to long-term unemployment and wage explanations of wage variation. Imperfections
rigidities as evidence that markets do not clear. in product and labor markets are both relevant;
So whilst real wages of the lowest decile fell in either arena, some level of concentration or
between 1979 and 2000 in North America collaboration among either buyers or sellers
and Australia, this is virtually unheard of can generate a degree of control over the
elsewhere (Glyn, 2001). The combination of price of labor which may enable wages to
low unemployment and low wage inflation sustain departures from employees’ marginal
in the US and UK in the late 1990s also products.
cast doubt on the mechanics of the dise-
quilibrium adjustment process, depicted by
Monopoly or oligopoly
Phillips (1958). Furthermore, Blanchflower
and Oswald (2003) have demonstrated that, If a firm is a monopolist or oligopolist in
contrary to theoretical expectations whereby its product market, its control over product
higher wage levels are associated with greater pricing enables it to generate ‘excess’ profits,
unemployment (all other things being equal), which in turn provide the freedom to pay
it is common to observe the reverse. Dunlop wages above the level that would maximize
(1988), for his part, asserts that unemployment profits under perfect competition. The degree
has little if any role to play in influencing wage of concentration among producers tends to
reduction, except in small establishments. be capped by regulatory bodies, but the
A second empirical challenge comes from thresholds are set fairly high. In a wide range
studies indicating a range of indeterminacy of industries in the UK, the top five businesses
in wage-setting (Lester, 1952). The theory currently account for at least one-third of
suggests that a perfectly-competitive labor gross output and in some this proportion is
market will be characterized by a single wage above two-thirds (Mahajan, 2005), suggesting
for a particular type of labor. Instead, studies at least the potential for some control over
of similar occupations in specific localities prices.
496 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Although such product market power that increased competition induced by higher
means that the firm has less need to minimize import penetration has lowered union wage
labor costs, there is no guarantee that any premia. In fact, quite the reverse: Bratsberg
share of the additional income will be passed and Ragan (2002) and Blanchflower and
on to employees. However, this does happen Bryson (2004) show higher import penetra-
to some degree, with a number of empirical tion raises the premium, perhaps because
studies having demonstrated a positive asso- organized workers can resist the downward
ciation between wages and past profitability wage pressure this induces in non-union firms,
(for example, Blanchflower et al., 1996; at least in the short-term.
Van Reenan, 1996; Hildreth and Oswald, Unions can exert power over wage-setting
1997). There may be a number of alternative in perfectly competitive markets, but neo-
rationales for this behavior. The monopolist classical theory would predict that these firms
or oligopolist may pay higher wages of would have to raise product prices above
its own volition, perhaps to demonstrate market levels and would eventually go out
fairness, reduce turnover or boost recruitment. of business. However, some firms have a
Alternatively, it may be induced to do so by greater ‘ability to pay’ above-market rates
a trade union representing some or all of its than others. Slichter (1950) illustrated the
employees.6 point by drawing attention to the positive
Evidence points to a sizeable union wage rank correlation between industries with
premium in many countries (Blanchflower high profit-to-sales ratios and those with
and Bryson, 2003). Unions also raise non- high unskilled earnings. There is conflicting
pay fringe benefits (Forth and Millward, 2000) evidence as to whether unions affect the
so that the full costs of unionization are longevity of firms (Bryson, 2004a) and no
higher than those associated with pay alone. direct evidence that any negative effect is
The size of this premium is correlated with attributable to union-induced labor costs.
unions’ ability to monopolize labor supply, However, unions are associated with lower
often proxied in empirical investigations by employment growth (Bryson, 2004b).
the presence of a closed shop (Stewart, Union involvement in wage setting can
1987), union density (for example, Hirsch and also be expected to affect wage inequality.
Schumacher, 2001) or collective bargaining A priori, the direction is ambiguous. Unions’
coverage (Forth and Millward, 2002). Indeed, pursuit of ‘standard’ rates for jobs promotes
unions seem to procure no premium where pay equalization, as does the threat of union-
they have no monopoly power (see, for ization which forces non-union employers
example, Stewart, 1987). to raise pay or benefits to keep unions out
Changes in unions’ monopoly power may (Rosen, 1969). Nevertheless, unions bargain
also bring about changes in the union wage for higher rates for their members. Thus
premium. Stewart (1995) attributes part of the their impact on the wage distribution will
decline in the premium in Britain to the demise depend, in large part, on how many and which
of the closed shop. However, despite declining workers they organize, and on any variation in
union density in developed countries and the wage premium across workers. Freeman
the ability to out-source production to non- (1980) found that unions tended to reduce
unionized labor in less developed countries, wage inequality among men because the effect
there is little empirical evidence to support a of bargaining higher rates for members was
secular decline in the union wage premium in smaller than the effect of standardizing pay
Britain and the US. Instead, there has been within the union sector. This remained so for
counter-cyclical movement in the premium the last 30 years of the twentieth century in the
arising from unions’ ability to resist the down- US, Britain and Canada (Card et al., 2003).
ward wage flexibility experienced by non- However, unions do not reduce wage inequal-
union workers in recession (Blanchflower and ity for women in these countries because
Bryson, 2004). There is also no evidence unionized women are concentrated in the
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 497

upper end of the wage distribution, the union Neumark et al., 2005). It may also be a feature
wage premium tends to be larger for women of the labor markets for nurses (Sullivan,
than it is for men and, whereas the premium 1989) and university professors (Ransom,
is higher for lesser-skilled than higher-skilled 1993). Each example serves to indicate
men, this is not the case for women. that restricted mobility among employees
There are also gender differences in the can consolidate employers’ power in the
effect of unionization on trends in pay wage setting process. Employers may use
dispersion. Declining unionization among this power to different degrees. The dis-
men explained a significant fraction of the criminating monopsonist may practice wage
growth in wage inequality in the US and UK discrimination, paying each employee at their
whereas the decline in unionization was more individual reservation wage, whilst the simple
modest for women and had little impact on monopsonist will instead pay a uniform wage
female wage inequality (Card et al., 2003; that is just sufficient to fill all vacant posts. The
Gosling and Lemieux, 2004). Of course, theory predicts that simple monopsony will
declining unionization is not a universal result in levels of wages and employment that
phenomenon: countries such as Belgium, are both lower than in a competitive market
Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Norway and (a further feature described in Neumark et al.’s
Sweden have experienced increased union retail study), so monopsony has implications
density in recent decades and declining pay beyond wages alone.
dispersion. If monopsony power is depressing wages,
one would expect any action which reduces
the power of the employer to consequently
MONOPSONY AND OLIGOPSONY raise wages. Illustrations in the US literature
focus on the removal of the reserve clause
Whilst product or labor market monopo- in professional baseball, which tied players
lies are a common feature of the wage- indefinitely to the team for which they
setting literature, the role of monopsony or first signed; the change led to a significant
oligopsony – where significant power is held income transfer from owners to players in
by the buyer rather than the seller – is the form of higher wages (Kahn, 1993).
less extensively discussed. Product market An equivalent European example is the
monopsony, in particular, is given little atten- Bosman ruling which, since 1995, has allowed
tion. The industrial relations literature offers professional soccer players to negotiate their
examples of how dependence relationships own deals with a new employer once the
between small firms and large retailers may contract with their current club expires. In
affect work organization and the exercise cases of simple monopsony, a restriction on
of management authority (Moule, 1998), employer power may also result in greater
but there is little documented evidence of employment without lowering wages. Indeed,
an impact on wages, despite the potential monopsonistic labor markets are said to
implications for suppliers’ cost structures. explain why the introduction of regulations
One would expect the effect of product governing wage setting, such as the Equal Pay
market monopsony to be equivalent to that Act and the National Minimum Wage, in the
of labor market monopsony, where the UK, have not brought about wide-scale job
dominance of a single firm or small group of losses (Manning, 2003).
firms may drive down wages within a locality.
The commonly-cited examples are company
towns. These are a distant memory to most, THE UNIQUENESS OF THE LABOR
but labor market monopsony may explain CONTRACT
the present-day reduction in earnings that
can accompany the arrival of large retailers In the discussion thus far, the basic approach
into local labor markets (as described by to wage determination has differed little
498 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

from the approach that might be applied exists – the efficiency wage – where the
in commodity pricing. However, a richer marginal cost of increasing the wage equals
understanding of wages relies on recognizing the marginal gain in productivity. The notable
the uniqueness of the labor contract. The open- implication, from the perspective of this
ended nature of the employment contract is a review, is that this wage is set independently
key feature, bringing uncertainty and potential of labor market conditions outside the firm:
controversy over the terms of the exchange. the principal determinant is the influence
Wages can then feature among the devices of wage changes on worker effort within
that employers may use to raise effort levels. the firm.
The personal aspect of the exchange also The incentive to pay above the competitive
means that wages may be critically influenced market rate will differ according to production
by norms, social institutions and political technologies, which imply different gains
processes. An appreciation of these factors – from reduced turnover, higher-quality labor
which is one feature that sets the discipline of and so on. For instance, organizations reliant
industrial relations apart from some parts of on extensive firm-specific training will benefit
mainstream economics – means giving lower from pay policies that lower voluntary
priority to the process of market clearing, quits. Since production technologies differ
accepting that the formal economic analysis across industries, some point to efficiency
of supply and demand is too narrow and wages as a reason for inter-industry wage
that the social aspect of wages must also be differentials (Krueger and Summers, 1988;
carefully considered (Brown and Nolan, 1988; Gibbons and Katz, 1992). Others argue that
Dunlop, 1988). This leads to an emphasis on such wage differentials are largely due to
the context in which wages are determined and unmeasured differences in worker quality
skepticism regarding the degree of apparent (Murphy and Topel, 1990; Abowd et al.,
rationality that might be accorded to wage 1999). Nevertheless, Fehr et al.’s (1996)
outcomes. In the following sections, we laboratory experiments identify a clear causal
review a number of approaches that view pay relationship between efficiency wages and
setting from this general perspective. effort.
Shapiro and Stiglitz’s (1984) version of
efficiency wage theory focuses on the use
EFFICIENCY WAGES of high wages to reduce shirking among
employees. As employment contracts are
Efficiency wage theory abandons the concep- incomplete, employees have some discretion
tion of the spot market with a single wage over their effort. Where effort monitoring is
for a given type of labor, acknowledging that costly, firms may choose instead to pay higher
employers can choose different wage levels wages, thus increasing the cost of job loss to
to elicit different levels of effort. It therefore the worker. Krueger (1991) suggests that pay
provides one potential means of explaining is lower in franchised burger outlets than in
variations in wages among like workers. company-owned outlets within the same firm
If wages fall short of what the worker because local franchise owners monitor their
considers a fair reference wage (for example, employees more easily, thus having less need
the rate set in other firms) the theory posits to ‘buy’ worker co-operation. Freeman et al.
that a wage increase will raise workers’ effort (2006) have similarly shown that US workers
(Akerlof, 1982, 1984; Akerlof and Yellen, are more likely to intervene when co-workers
1990). It might also allow a firm to recruit are shirking if they believe that pay is at or
higher-quality workers (Weiss, 1980), reduce above the market level.
turnover (Salop, 1979) and improve employee This leaves the question of whether
morale, all of which can enhance productivity. marginal wage increases raise productivity
But the wage must not be set too high since sufficiently to pay for themselves. Levine
effort can only rise so far. Accordingly, a wage (1992) and Wadhwani and Wall (1991)
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 499

found that they did.7 Levine also found (Daniel and Millward, 1983: 200). In the
lower productivity effects of high wages in Donovan tradition, PBR was treated as part
the presence of unions, consistent with the of the problem of shop floor bargaining
proposition that unions push wages above and a cause of industrial unrest (Daniel and
the optimum efficiency level. Earlier evidence Millward, 1983: 292). As Blanchflower and
comes from Henry Ford who described the Cubbin (1986: 26) note, PBR is often included
doubling of wages to five dollars a day as ‘one in analyses of strike propensities since the
of the finest cost-cutting moves we ever made’ need for regular adjustments to pay increases
because it dramatically reduced turnover and opportunities for disagreement.
absenteeism and raised labor discipline and Marx (1976: 698–9) reports Factory
output quality (Raff and Summers, 1987: Inspectorate figures showing that, in the mid-
s59). Nevertheless, some have questioned 1800s four-fifths of employees in British
how much effort managers devote to devising factories were paid by the piece. Marx notes
incentive pay systems. Others have ques- that it is ‘the form of wage most appropriate to
tioned the whole basis of efficiency wage the capitalist mode of production’. Today pure
theory, contending that there is no necessary piece-rate pay is rare, confined to occupations
relationship between pay and productivity where outputs can easily be observed, such
(Brown and Nolan, 1988: 352). This latter as sales or fruit picking. Nevertheless, in
position raises substantial questions over the Britain in 2004, one-third of workplaces used
continued efforts of employers to link the two. some form of individual payments-by-results,
16 per cent used subjective merit pay and
one-quarter used group-based payments-by-
LINKING PAY TO PERFORMANCE results (Bryson and Freeman, 2006).
In the US shared forms of compensation
Paying a higher time-based wage is only one (share ownership plans, stock options, profit
way in which firms might tackle shirking and gainsharing) have been rising since the
when effort is difficult to monitor. An 1980s, a trend that has seemingly accom-
alternative is to offer a piece rate, which panied greater employee involvement in
allows the worker to decide how much to work decision-making (Dube and Freeman, 2006).
and thus how much to get paid. The trends are very different in Britain. Task
For economists, this induces greater effort discretion declined in the 1990s (Gallie et al.,
by equating the marginal value of an extra 2004) and, in any event, shared compen-
unit of output with the marginal cost of sation schemes are not strongly associated
producing it (Weitzman and Kruse, 1990). with employee decision-making (Bryson and
Sociologists, on the other hand, tend to view Freeman, 2006). Both profit-related pay and
piecework – and other forms of performance- share-ownership schemes grew in the 1980s,
based pay – as mechanisms for managerial with government tax incentives playing some
control when management cannot provide part, but their incidence has remained fairly
adequate supervision (Gallie et al., 1998: static since then (Bryson, 2006).
Chapter 3). Either way, one might anticipate In theory, performance-based pay will
less need for monitoring under piecework generate inequalities in output and thus
since, as Marx remarked, the ‘superinten- earnings where workers are heterogeneous
dence of labour becom[es] to a great extent in effort and ability, but this relies upon
superfluous’ (Marx, 1976: 695). a direct link at individual level between
The originators of the British Work- output and earnings. This is not always
place Industrial Relations Surveys reported present, as some forms of performance-related
their findings on payments-by-results (PBR) pay (particularly profit-sharing and share-
under the heading ‘Systems of payment and ownership) measure output at group or even
control’ alongside methods for controlling firm level. Belfield and Heywood (2001)
time keeping and payments while sick and Bryson and Freeman (2006) find that
500 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

individual performance-related pay increases where a system generates positive external-


wage dispersion at workplace level whereas ities – as in the case of group incentive
profit-sharing and share-ownership do not. schemes – this should generate still greater
In large firms employers may reward productivity. A further implication is that
effort through promotion, rather than directly notions of fairness are clearly important in the
through performance pay. In these internal labor market.
labor markets (Doeringer and Piore, 1971)
pay varies little within grades but increases
with job changes. Limited promotion slots FAIRNESS, NORMS AND RECIPROCITY
motivate workers to supply effort by virtue
of the wage increases they would earn if pro- In standard neo-classical economics actors
moted, with the competition for promotions are driven by self-interest and decisions are
then resembling a form of tournament where made to maximize financial gain. However,
‘winner takes all’ (Lazear and Rosen, 1981). exchanges between people are often con-
The advantage to an employer is that it is often ducted according to shared social norms of
easier to observe relative performance than fairness and reciprocity. These notions are
absolute performance. Additionally, it may formalized in equity theory where the ‘target
suit some companies to structure pay so that relationship’ sought by individuals is equality
the winner makes very large sums, as a way between their own reward per unit of input and
of spurring on those lower in the hierarchy as their cognition of others’ rewards. Employee
well as the CEO. Tournament theory therefore perceptions of what they contribute to the
provides one possible explanation for the high organization and what they get in return, and
wages of CEOs and, more generally, wage how this ratio compares to others inside and
inequality within firms. Tournaments might outside the organization, determines how fair
be viewed as one form of ‘deferred com- they perceive their employment relationship
pensation’ whereby worker and firm commit to be (Adams, 1963). Others in the same
to each other. Under schemes of deferred work-group, workplace or firm are likely to
compensation, workers are paid below their be the most salient comparators (Brown et al.,
marginal product when young and above it 1998), which may explain why employees’
when older. This may be because firms want pay satisfaction is so strongly associated with
to limit costly labor turnover (Salop and their wage rank within the workplace (Brown
Salop, 1976) or because distinguishing good et al., 2005). However, employees may also
from poor workers takes time. Lazear (1979) make comparisons with similar workers in the
shows how the common upward-sloping age- external labor market, as is common in union
earnings profile can discourage workers from bargaining. And when the union is dominated
shirking. by less skilled employees, as with general
However, tournaments may inhibit worker rather than craft unions, the pressure from the
collaboration. Freeman and Gelber’s (2006) union is generally to favor the lower paid and
laboratory experiment shows that total tour- to compress wage differentials among covered
nament output depends on pay inequality workers.
according to an inverse-U shaped function. The ‘inputs’ to the equity calculation
Thus inequality can be too high as well as too vary across occupations. In manual occu-
low for efficiency. One fruit farm registered pations it is common to prioritize physical
a 50 per cent increase in worker productivity effort, dexterity and skill in using tools and
after moving away from relative incentives to machines, whereas in non-manual occupa-
piece rates, the apparent explanation being the tions greater priority is accorded to literacy,
shift away from a system in which workers’ communication, information processing, and
individual efforts could have negative effects responsibility and so on. There is a broad
on co-workers’ earnings (Bandiera et al., correspondence between the ‘inputs’ forming
2005). One implication is, however, that the foundation of social norms of equity
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 501

and the ‘investments’ that increase human be predicted by neo-classical theory. For
capital. The pay premium for supervisory and instance, experiments support Solow’s (1990)
managerial jobs, compared with the workers contention that wage rigidity may be partially
they supervise, also rests upon a widely-held due to conformity with social norms. Falk
norm that responsibility for other peoples’ et al. (2006) show that the introduction of a
work should be rewarded. minimum wage law changes perceptions of
These concepts first came to the fore among a fair wage, forcing firms to increase wages
economists with Akerlof’s (1982) partial gift above the minimum wage and retain them
exchange model of the labor contract which even when the minimum wage is rescinded.
argues that worker effort depends on work This helps to explain why fast food restaurants
norms of a relevant reference group and that in the US increased wages for workers by
the firm can alter these norms and thus effort more than was necessary following increases
by paying workers a wages ‘gift’ in excess in the minimum wage (Card and Krueger,
of the minimum required in return for greater 1995; Katz and Krueger, 1992) and why the
effort. Akerlof and Yellen’s (1990) ‘fair wage- opportunity to pay sub-minimum wages to
effort’ hypothesis suggests that, if the actual youth workers has no discernible effect on
wage is lower than the workers’ notion of the teenage workers’ wages (Katz and Krueger,
fair wage, they will withdraw their effort in 1992).
proportion. The fair wage thus plays a role Wade et al. (2006) also show that norms
in wage bargaining where entitlements are of fairness are salient to top decision makers
fashioned by reference points. More broadly, and that over or underpayment of the CEO
notions of fairness can underpin the role of cascades down to lower organizational levels,
custom and practice in wage determination partly due to CEOs using their own power
(Brown and Nolan, 1988; Rubery, 1997) not only to increase their own salaries but
though, as Hicks (1932) points out, forces of also those of their subordinates. Further,
supply and demand can occasion changes in CEOs serve as a key referent for employees
customary structures. in determining whether their own situation
Greenberg (1990) presents evidence in is ‘fair’. They find that when lower-level
support of the fair wage-effort model, managers are underpaid relative to the CEO
recording employee thefts from a company (that is, underpaid more than the CEO or
in response to proposed pay cuts. Where overpaid less), they are more likely to leave
management explained the reasons for pay the organization.
cuts and expressed remorse, subsequent This discussion of fairness has focused on
employee thefts were significantly lower the ways in which levels of pay are influenced
than the situation where management pro- by the earnings of co-workers in the firm
vided inadequate information and showed no or wider labor market. But pay may also
remorse. Greenberg suggests that perceptions be influenced by comparisons of working
of inequity caused employees to take actions conditions.
to restore equity. Often what matters are
employee perceptions of distributive justice.
Thus Cowherd and Levine (1992) link COMPENSATING WAGE
a negative association between customer DIFFERENTIALS
perceptions of quality and pay differentials
between hourly paid employees and top The concept underlying ‘compensating wage
management to a diminution in citizenship- differentials’ is the idea that wages are not
type behavior. simply the reward for effort or skill, but that
Laboratory experiments repeatedly show the context in which that effort is delivered
individuals and firms behaving in accordance is important in determining the price of labor.
with norms of fairness and reciprocity, Thus one should not necessarily expect wage
leading to outcomes that would not otherwise equality between jobs of equal value, but
502 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

rather equality in the overall ‘job package’, because workers are not randomly allocated
which includes not only money wages but also across jobs of varying quality. One must
non-pecuniary benefits and the whole range of therefore account for biases arising from
working conditions. The principle also departs worker selection into good or bad jobs
from the traditional framework of supply when evaluating the compensating differen-
and demand by according workers some tials hypothesis. Compensating differentials
preference over issues other than monetary are underestimated where employees with
rewards. high earnings potential are able to secure
The theory is often expressed in terms of the ‘better’ jobs (Viscusi, 1978). Alternatively,
wage compensation for dangerous work. Most if workers may sort into jobs according
workers can be expected to value both higher to their productivity under particular con-
wages and greater levels of safety, but some ditions (Garen, 1988) – perhaps possessing
are presumed willing to accept additional experience or a ‘cool head’ which enables
risk in exchange for a higher wage that is them to be productive when others may
sufficient to maintain the same overall level of panic – then estimates may overstate the size
utility. Equally, a firm can choose to invest in of any compensating differential, which is
procedures that offer workers greater safety, instead a ‘return for skill’. One implication
or obtain the same level of profitability by is that someone in a non-risky job may not
economizing on safety and distributing the necessarily be able to attain the higher wage
savings to workers through higher wages. Yet of someone in a risky job simply by choosing
the principle of compensating differentials can to accept a higher level of risk; equally, it does
be extended beyond the issue of workplace not necessarily follow that seemingly under-
risk. This was clearly acknowledged in the paid employees undertaking meaningful work
writings of Adam Smith (1982: 202): in the voluntary sector could necessarily raise
their earnings by moving to equivalent jobs in
The wages of labour vary with the ease or
hardship, the cleanliness or dirtiness, the honorable-
the business sector.
ness or dishonorableness, of the employment…. A further area of empirical investigation
A journeyman blacksmith, though an artificer, has been the extent to which lower wages
seldom earns so much in twelve hours, as a collier, accompany the provision of fringe benefits.
who is only a labourer, does in eight. His work is Olson (2002) finds that married women in the
not quite so dirty, is less dangerous, and is carried
on in day-light, and above ground.
United States accept a wage penalty of around
20 per cent in return for employer-provided
One might therefore expect higher wages health insurance. However, higher wages
to be explained, in some instances, by the are more usually found in conjunction with
presence of negative job attributes such as dirt favorable levels of non-wage benefits (for
and insecurity. Similarly, one might expect example, Dale-Olsen, 2006, for Norwegian
lower wages to be associated with positive workers). Similarly, various studies find that
job attributes such as hours, flexibility or the degree of wage inequality between low
meaningful work. and high-wage groups tends to increase when
Empirical studies find evidence of wage one considers the complete compensation
premia that appear to compensate workers package (Joshi and Paci, 1998; Pierce, 2001).
for unsociable hours (Lanfranchi et al., 2002; The co-existence of high wages and good
Kostiuk, 1990), greater levels of job stress conditions might arise through trade unions’
(French and Dunlap, 1998) and job insecurity bargaining power (see Fairris, 1989) while
(Moretti, 2000). McNabb (1989) finds a wage the co-existence of low wages and poor
premium for unfavorable working conditions conditions could indicate employers’ monop-
among manual workers in Britain. But he sony power. However, a positive correlation
accepts (pp. 328–30), as do others (for between wages and working conditions might
example, Purse, 2004; Gunderson and Hyatt, also imply some segmentation of the labor
2001), that reliable estimation is difficult market.
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 503

SEGMENTATION AND have focused on the limited mobility of


DISCRIMINATION immigrant ‘guest workers’ in the German
economy (for example, Constant and Massey,
The theory of dual or segmented labor markets 2003).
proposes a primary sector where a worker’s The notion that employees’ mobility (and
effort is hard to measure and monitoring thus their wage) is restricted by factors other
is costly, plus a secondary sector where than abilities and preferences may be useful
output is measurable and supervision easy. In in attempting to understand the part-time
the primary sector, firms offer high wages, pay penalty among female employees in
good working conditions, secure employment Britain, which remains around 10 per cent
and career progression and in return obtain after accounting for various other factors that
higher levels of labor productivity. Firms in determine wages (Manning and Petrongolo,
the secondary sector are the mirror image. 2005). Part-time work is concentrated in
Whilst this echoes efficiency wage theories, occupations such as customer service, care
the distinction of the segmentation approach work or cleaning, and within such occu-
is to argue that structural features of the labor pations the part-time penalty is generally
market limit workers’ ability to transfer from low (3 per cent on average, according to
the secondary to the primary sector. Such Manning and Petrongolo). This points to
limits might arise because closed ‘internal distinct segments in the labor market, with
labor markets’ in the primary sector have few employees needing to offer full-time hours in
entry points or because employers place a low order to access better-paid segments.
(or negative) valuation on work experience An alternative view would see part-timers’
in the secondary sector. In consequence, the lower pay as part of an overall compen-
segment in which an employee is located sation package whereby wages are traded
partly determines their wage, both now and for flexibility, following the principles of
in the future. compensating wage differentials (or similarly,
The identification of labor market segments Hakim’s ‘preference theory’ (2000)). But
is, however, not straightforward. In their there is clear evidence of limited mobility
study of industrial organization and low pay, between part-time and full-time work (see
Craig et al. (1982) followed Piore (1979) White and Forth, 1998). Studies also show that
in distinguishing between primary industrial part-time work experience is poorly rewarded
sectors – characterized by large firms, using in comparison with experience in full-time
modern technology, facing a stable product work (Myck and Paull, 2004; Harkness, 1996;
market and enjoying market power – and sec- Swaffield, 2000). The lower rewards for part-
ondary sectors comprising the reverse. Wages time work might then be seen as a form of
in primary sectors were typically higher. discrimination, since workers are seemingly
But primary industrial characteristics pro- receiving a lower wage for reasons other than
vided no guarantee of ‘primary’ employment their personal abilities.
conditions, particularly where institutional There are a number of possible explanations
constraints prevented worker organization. for discrimination. Becker (1957) identifies
Craig et al. also found examples of two-tier the ‘tastes’ of prejudiced employers, employ-
workforces within primary firms. Other ees or consumers as potential sources, for
researchers have focused on occupational dis- example employers might pay lower wages
tinctions, including Theodossiou (1995) who to women to compensate themselves for the
examined differences in wage determinants disutility of employing women over equally-
among career and non-career workers, and qualified men. Wage discrimination might
Blackaby et al. (1995) who distinguished also come about in the absence of prejudice if a
between the wages of regular and marginal particular characteristic (for example, gender)
workers. The work of Atkinson (1984) is thought to signal a person’s productivity:
is also relevant. Alternative conceptions so-called ‘statistical discrimination’.
504 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

The wage effects of discrimination are Such social processes can, of course, serve to
difficult to discern, not least because some reinforce the segmentation tendencies noted
of the impact on wages may arise indirectly above.
through discrimination in access to employ-
ment, training opportunities or promotions.
The advent of the Equal Pay Act had a THE STATE AS EMPLOYER
dramatic impact in reducing the gender pay
gap in Britain in the 1970s (Manning, 2003: Many of the factors already discussed influ-
211). This partly came about through the ence pay determination in both the private and
re-negotiation of collective agreements that public sectors alike. But political influences
had previously specified lower wages for are more prominent in wage determination for
women than men within the same jobs (ibid). public sector employees. We expand briefly
But the gap between male and female full- upon this point here, leaving a more detailed
time wages nonetheless stood at 17 per cent discussion of public sector employment to
in 2006. Direct wage discrimination still Chapter 16.
explains some of this variance: a fact Whilst pay has a political dimension in
evident from the number of successful claims the private sector, this is generally the result
brought each year under equal pay legislation of pressures internal to the firm (see the
(3,722 in 2005/6) (Employment Tribunal earlier discussion of fairness). In the public
Service, 2006). But it is difficult to judge sector, however, the wider public has an
the prevalence of the practice in the wider interest because they fund state expenditure
population. Statistical analyses can generally via taxation and also choose the identity of the
explain around 50 per cent of the current ultimate paymaster – the government.8 This
gap by reference to differences in skills ‘public interest’ creates a number of tensions.
and other characteristics. But one needs First, it imposes an additional emphasis on
considerable faith in the comprehensiveness value for money, since the burden of funding
of the statistical specifications if one is to pay increases falls to the general public unless
attribute the whole of the unexplained portion rises pay for themselves through efficiency
to wage discrimination. gains. But attempts to constrain wages must
One of the most likely means of reducing also consider the impact on recruitment and
the gap further is perhaps through more retention, and thus service quality, since a
extensive use of equal pay audits within large percentage of public sector employment
individual firms, but in Britain progress is in areas such as education and health
has been most extensive in the public which impinge directly on people’s lives
sector where the state has either seen fit to and livelihoods. The critical nature of such
employ coercion (as in the case of central services, along with the high degree of
government) or has taken pre-emptive action unionization and the tendency toward national
on a national scale in response to high- pay scales, also mean that battles over wage
value equal pay claims (as in the NHS). settlements are fought out on the public
At the same time, the utility of current stage, further accentuating the politicization
legislation is becoming further compromised of public sector pay.
by the increasing fragmentation of enterprises Governments, for their part, have a further
through sub-contracting (Forth and Metcalf, interest in the stability of public finances,
2005). And more broadly, it is recognized that which promotes prudence when setting the
the notion of ‘comparable worth’ is limited parameters for public sector wage settlements.
in the extent to which it can tackle the social Governments also have a broader economic
valuation of skills, whereby jobs held by either interest to maintain price stability and, for
men or women may be considered unskilled this reason, incomes policies have tended
because they are dominated by female to bite more in the public sector in those
employees (Crompton and Sanderson, 1990). periods when inflation was a major issue.
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 505

Wage setting is also informed by the public has typically attracted the most attention.
sector ethos of ‘the good employer’, which Chief among the rationales espoused for
encourages it to do more than simply meet minimum wages are the alleviation of house-
statutory requirements in areas such as equal hold poverty and the guarantee of a ‘fair day’s
pay. However, there is considerable variation work for a fair day’s pay’. The former arises
in the extent to which central government from a concern that, even if market-set wages
can enforce these principles since some reflect workers’ marginal product, these may
public sector organizations operate at some be inadequate to meet what society deems the
considerable distance from the center. nutritional and material needs of a worker’s
Despite the commonly-held view that pub- family. The latter implies either that workers
lic sector employees are underpaid, statistical are not being paid their marginal product or,
analyses generally find a pay premium for if they are, society deems that wage ‘unfair’
public servants after accounting for differ- according to commonly-held precepts. The
ences in personal and job characteristics (see common concern is that minimum wages may
Lucifora and Meurs, 2004, for a short review bring job losses, although employer responses
of recent studies). However, this average are often at odds with the expectations
premium varies considerably by earnings of neo-classical theory. This is because
decile, tending to be larger at the lower employer responses are partly conditioned by
end of the earnings distribution and smaller norms, customs and perceptions of fairness
(or non-existent) at the higher end. The (which are themselves affected by minimum
premium is also generally found to be larger wages), and by what often appear to be
for women than for men.9 Changes in the monopsonistic market conditions (Gilman
public-sector premium in various countries et al., 2002).
appear to be counter-cyclical (Holmlund and Evidence confirms that minimum wages
Ohlsson, 1992; Elliott and Duffus, 1996; compress the wage distribution. The introduc-
Brooks, 2004), which may either reflect the tion of a national minimum wage in Britain
fact that the sector is sheltered from changing in 1999 seems to have halted the decline in
economic fortunes or serve to indicate the the wages of the lowest paid men relative to
prominent role of trade unions. median earners and increased the rate of real
wage growth among the lowest paid women
(Kondylis and Wadsworth, 2006). Similarly,
THE STATE AS REGULATOR increases in France’s minimum wage appear
to have prevented erosion in real wages at the
In addition to its role as an employer, the State low end of the French wage distribution (Katz
regulates pay levels and changes in the wider et al., 1995; Abowd et al., 2000). In contrast,
economy both directly through minimum the decline in the real value of the minimum
wages, equal pay legislation, incomes policies wage in the US in the 1980s accounts for
and so on, and indirectly through policies such a large part of the rise in wage inequality
as welfare-to-work programs and statutes between middle and low earners for both men
affecting union organizing and union bar- and women (DiNardo et al., 1996; Fortin and
gaining power. Policies relating to taxation, Lemieux, 1997; Lee, 1999; Card and Krueger,
employers’ social security contributions and 1995).
pensions affect wage and non-wage labor Wage subsidies are an alternative approach
costs as well as earned income. Again, these that has burgeoned in the last few decades
issues are dealt with elsewhere in this volume in the UK and the US (Blundell and
(Chapter 15) and so we restrict ourselves to Hoynes, 2004). However, they can limit
some of the most pertinent points relating earnings progression, trapping employees in
specifically to wages. long-term reliance on State assistance by
Among the various regulatory activities of creating disincentives to train, seek pro-
the State, the introduction of minimum wages motion or work longer hours due to the
506 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

withdrawal of the supplement as earnings rise CONCLUSION


(Bryson, 1998; Blundell and Hoynes, 2004:
455–6). Others criticize wage supplements This chapter revisits pay determination from a
on the grounds of equity when equally theoretical perspective and presents evidence
productive workers doing identical jobs take for and against alternative theories. This is
home different net income depending upon not the traditional approach adopted in most
their eligibility. industrial relations texts. These tend to focus
There are a number of other public policies on description, the main thrust being to
that affect the wage distribution. Prices and emphasize the centrality of institutions in pay
incomes policies were central to macro- determination. This is valuable but, in a sense,
economic management of the UK economy our chapter is written as a corrective to a
in the 1970s and sought to tackle wage- purely descriptive approach. This, we think,
push inflation through wage freezes, and is excusable, partly because Chapter 21 of
ceilings to both relative and absolute pay this Handbook is dedicated to the structures
increases, all of which tended to compress the of collective bargaining, but also because
pay distribution (Blackaby, 1978; Flanagan it is difficult to know what to make of
et al., 1983). Public support for industry- pay differentials, earnings progression and
level wage setting and the extension of so on if one does not start with testable
collectively bargained terms and conditions theoretical propositions about the underlying
also contributed to relative stability in the determinants. Without theory it is also difficult
wage distribution (Flanagan et al., 1983). The to make predictions about future trends and
reversal of these policies in the 1980s created the effects of policy on pay outcomes. We have
conditions in which the wage dispersion was also focused on micro-theory emanating from
likely to grow (Kessler and Bayliss, 1998). economics and industrial relations, rather than
It appears that moves to reduce the size macro-economic and macro-political theory,
of unemployment-related benefits relative to although we recognize the contribution that
earnings and the narrowing of entitlements other theoretical frameworks can make to
were also motivated by a desire to create more understanding pay setting.
jobs through the lowering of wages and an Two broad conclusions emerge from this
increase in labor supply at the bottom end of exercise. The first, hardly surprising, conclu-
the labor market (Bryson and Jacobs, 1992; sion is that the neo-classical economic theory
Kessler and Bayliss, 1998: 222–3). Yet, in of supply and demand can only take us so
spite of these policies – which in many ways far in understanding patterns of pay. There
resembled those pursued avidly in the US – are clear and systematic departures in pay
although wage dispersion grew, real wages differentials and trends from those we might
did not fall. This ‘wage-stickiness’ is a further expect through the application of standard
indication of the limitations of neo-classical micro-economic theory, which focuses on the
wage theory. dominance of market mechanisms and under-
State policy has targeted not only pay levels plays the variance generated by institutional
and changes in pay, but also the way in which settings, norms and customs, and idiosyn-
employers pay their workers. In particular, cratic arrangements for the determination of
governments have sought to encourage the pay. This has been recognized by industrial
spread of performance-based pay, such as relations academics for some time (see, for
share ownership schemes and profit-related example, Dunlop, 1988; Rubery, 1997; Brown
pay, through tax breaks. Evidence from et al., 2003), and labor economists have been
the Workplace Industrial Relations Surveys saying much the same thing for over half
indicates that these tax incentives were a century. As long ago as 1950 Slichter
important factors explaining the growth of (1950: 91) remarked: ‘the models used in
such schemes in Britain in the 1980s (Bryson, accepted wage theory are too simple and need
2006). to be supplemented. This is hardly news’.
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 507

This is evident, not least, in the ‘range of 6 Although it is possible for other forms of labor
indeterminacy’that seemingly allows workers organization to affect wages, empirical evidence for
with similar skill-sets in the same locality Britain indicates that only unions actually affect wages
(Millward et al., 2001).
to be paid very different wages. But at the 7 Both note that their finding would also be
same time, it is equally evident that other consistent with rent-sharing theories in which higher
theoretical perspectives, whilst each having productivity leads to higher wages.
something to offer, are inevitably limited in 8 Wage costs are clearly also of relevance to the
their ability to explain the full variety of consumers of private sector services but, in product
markets with some degree of competition, they can
wage outcomes. In truth, a reliance on any exercise pressure on wages by seeking out lower-
one theoretical position is likely to overstate cost producers. In contrast, the general public must
the coherence and functionality of wages, continue to pay for the wages of public sector
and those working in the field of industrial employees even if they do not personally use the
relations have long recognized that no single services that they provide.
9 The non-random selection of employees into
theory of pay setting has an over-riding claim public service activities and the limited overlap
to virtue. between some public and private sector activities
The second conclusion is that, in spite make the estimation of the pay premium difficult.
of the institutional knowledge generated Disney and Gosling (2003) take advantage of
by industrial relations, the discipline has employees’ movements between the two sectors to
control for otherwise unobserved differences. Their
contributed comparatively little theory about findings suggest that, for men, any public sector
pay determination which allows the analyst premium actually exists at the higher-end of the skill
to test alternative propositions regarding pay distribution, although their results for women are in
patterns. Others have made this point before line with the stylized facts.
(see, for instance, Brown and Nolan, 1988).
One might argue that, given the obvious
complexity of wage determination, gaining a REFERENCES
greater understanding of the general pattern
of wages need not be one of the primary Abowd, J., Kramarz, F. and Margolis, D. (1999) ‘High
challenges facing industrial relations at the Wage Workers and High Wage Firms’, Econometrica,
present time. We disagree. 67 (2): 251–333.
Abowd, J., Kramarz, F., Lemieux, T. and Margolis, D.
(2000) ‘Minimum wages and youth employment in
France and the United States’ in D.G. Blanchflower
and R.B. Freeman (eds) Youth Employment and
NOTES Joblessness in Advanced Countries. University of
Chicago Press and NBER.
1 The authors’ affiliations are the Policy Studies Adams, J. S. (1963) ‘Toward an Understanding of
Institute and the Centre for Economic Performance
Inequity’, Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 67 (5):
(Bryson) and the National Institute of Economic and
Social Research (Forth). Alex Bryson’s contribution was
422–36.
funded by the Wertheim Fellowship at the Harvard Akerlof, G. (1982) ‘Labor Contracts as Partial Gift
Law School and the National Bureau of Economic Exchange’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97 (4):
Research. The authors gratefully acknowledge the 543–69.
contribution made by Neil Millward to earlier work, Akerlof, G. (1984) ‘Gift Exchange and Efficiency-Wage
on which some of this material is based. Theory: Four Views’, American Economic Review,
2 See Anderson et al. (2001: Chapter 2) on the 74 (2): 79–83.
merits of different measures. Akerlof, G. and Yellen, J. (1990) ‘The Fair Wage-Effort
3 Full results available on request. Hypothesis and Unemployment’, Quarterly Journal of
4 Widening wage inequality since the 1980s is
Economics, 105 (2): 255–83.
not a universal phenomenon. Indeed, it was only
experienced in a few industrialized countries, notably
Anderson, T., Forth, J., Metcalf, H. and Kirby, S. (2001)
the US. The Gender Pay Gap. London: Women and Equality
5 Education was previously viewed primarily as Unit, Cabinet Office.
a consumption good or status good (Machin and Arrow, K. (1973) ‘Higher Education As a Filter’, Journal
Vignoles, 2005). of Public Economics, 2 (3): 193–216.
508 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Atkinson, J. (1984) ‘Manpower Strategies for Flexible Bratsberg, B. and Ragan, J. F. (2002) ‘Changes in the
Organizations’, Personnel Management, 16 (2): Union Wage Premium by Industry’, Industrial and
32–35. Labor Relations Review, 56 (1): 65–83.
Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F. and Kearney, M. S. (2006) ‘The Brooks, K. (2004) Pay and the Public Service Workforce.
Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market’, NBER Working London: Institute for Public Policy Research.
Paper No. 11986. Brown, D. A., Gardner, J., Oswald, A. and Qian, J. (2005)
Autor, D. H., Levy, F. and Murnane, R. J. (2003) ‘Does Wage Rank Affect Employees’ Wellbeing?’ IZA
‘The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: Discussion Paper No. 1505.
An Empirical Exploration,’ The Quarterly Journal of Brown, W., Deakin, S., Hudson, M., Pratten, C. and
Economics, 118 (4): 1279–1333. Ryan, P. (1998) The Individualisation of Employment
Bandiera, O., Barankay, I. and Rasul, I. (2005) ‘Social Contracts in Britain. London: Department of Trade
Preferences and the Response to Incentives: Evidence and Industry, Research Series No. 4.
from Personnel Data’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Brown, W., Hayles, J., Hughes, B. and Rowe, L.
130 (3): 917–62. (1980) ‘Occupational Pay Structures under Different
Becker, G. (1957) The Economics of Discrimination, Wage-Fixing Arrangements: a Comparison of Intra-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. occupational Pay Dispersion in Australia, Britain
Becker, G. (1964) Human Capital. Chicago: University and the United States’, British Journal of Industrial
of Chicago Press. Relations, 18 (2): 217–30.
Belfield, C. R. and Heywood, J. S. (2001) ‘Unionization Brown, W. and Nolan, P. (1988) ‘Wages and labour
and the Pattern of Nonunion Wages: Evidence for productivity’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
the UK’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 26 (3): 339–61.
63 (5): 577–98. Bryson, A. (1998) ‘Lone Mothers’ Earnings’, in Reuben
Blackaby, F. (1978) ‘Incomes Policy’, in F. Blackaby Ford and Jane Miller (eds) Private Lives, Public
(ed) British Economic Policy 1960–1974. Cambridge: Responses: Lone Parenthood and Future Policy in the
Cambridge University Press. UK. London: Policy Studies Institute.
Blackaby, D., Clark, K. and Leslie, D. (1995) ‘Dual Bryson, A. (2004a) ‘Union Effects on Workplace Closure,
Labour Markets and the Potential Earnings of the 1990–1998’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Unemployed’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 42 (2): 283–302.
42 (1): 37–52. Bryson, A. (2004b) ‘Unions and Employment Growth
Blanchflower, D. and Bryson, A. (2003) ‘Changes over in British Workplaces During the 1990s: A Panel
Time in Union Relative Wage Effects in the UK and Analysis’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy,
the US Revisited’, Chapter 7 in John T. Addison and 51 (4): 477–506.
Claus Schnabel (eds) International Handbook of Trade Bryson, A. (2006) WIRS Through the Ages, PSI Mimeo.
Unions. Cheltenham, England and Northampton MA.: London: Policy Studies Institute.
Edward Elgar. Bryson, A. and Jacobs, J. (1992) Policing the
Blanchflower, D. and Bryson, A. (2004) ‘Union Relative Workshy: Benefit Control, Labour Markets and the
Wage Effects in the United States and the United Unemployed. Aldershot: Avebury.
Kingdom’, Proceedings of the 56th Annual Meeting Bryson, A. and Freeman, R. (2006) Doing the Right
of the Industrial Relations Research Association, Thing? Does Fair Share Capitalism Improve Workplace
133–40. Performance?, mimeo. London: Department of Trade
Blanchflower, D.G. and Cubbin, J. (1986) ‘Strike and Industry Employment Relations Research Series
Propensities at the British Workplace’, Oxford Bulletin Number 81, Department of Trade and Industry.
of Economics and Statistics, 48 (1): 19–39. Budd, J. (2004) ‘Non-Wage Forms of Compensation’,
Blanchflower, D. and Oswald, A. (2003) The Wage Journal of Labor Research, 25 (4): 597–622.
Curve. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Card, D. and Krueger, A. (1995) Myth and Measurement:
Blanchflower, D., Oswald, A. and Sanfey, P. (1996) The New Economics of the Minimum Wage.
‘Wages, Profits and Rent-Sharing’, Quarterly Journal Princeton, NJ.: Princeton University Press.
of Economics, 111 (1): 227–52. Card, D., Lemieux, T. and Riddell, W. C. (2003)
Blundell, R. and Hoynes, H. (2004) ‘Has “In-Work” Unionization and Wage Inequality: A Comparative
Benefit Reform Helped the Labor Market?’, in Study of the US, the UK and Canada, NBER Working
D. Card, R. Blundell and R. B. Freeman (eds) Paper #9473. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Seeking a Premier Economy: The Economic Effects of Economic Research.
British Economic Reforms, 1980–2000. Chicago and Constant, A. and Massey, D. (2003) ‘Labor Market
London: University of Chicago Press. Segmentation and the Earnings of German
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 509

Guestworkers’, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) Falk, A., Fehr, E. and Zehnder, C. (2006) ‘The
Discussion Paper No. 774. Bonn: Institute for the Behavioral Effects of Minimum Wages’, forthcoming
Study of Labor. in the Quarterly Journal of Economics. 121 (4):
Cowherd, D. M. and Levine, D. I. (1992) ‘Product Quality 1347–1381.
and Pay Equity between Lower-level Employees and Fehr, E., Gächter, S. and Kirchsteiger, G. (1996)
Top Management: An Investigation of Distributive ‘Reciprocal Fairness and Noncompensating Wage
Justice Theory’, Administrative Science Quarterly, Differentials’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
37 (2): 302–20. Economics 152 (4): 608–40.
Craig, C., Rubery, J., Tarling, R. and Wilkinson, F. (1982) Flanagan, R., Soskice, D. and Ulman, L. (1983) Union-
Labour Market Structure, Industrial Organisation and ism, Economic Stabilization and Incomes Policies:
Low Pay. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. European Experience. Washington: The Brookings
Crompton, R. and Sanderson, K. (1990) Gendered Jobs Institution.
and Social Change. London: Unwin Hyman. Forth, J. and Metcalf, H. (2005) Comment on ‘How
Dale-Olsen, H. (2006) ‘Wages, Fringe Benefits and to close the gender pay gap in Europe’, Industrial
Worker Turnover’, Labor Economics, 13 (1): 87–105. Relations Journal, 36 (3): 214–16.
Daniel, W.W. and Millward, N. (1983) Workplace Forth, J. and Millward, N. (2000) ‘The Determinants of
Industrial Relations in Britain. London: Heinemann. Pay Levels and Fringe Benefit Provision in Britain’,
DiNardo, J.E., Fortin, N.M. and Lemieux, T. (1996) Discussion Paper No. 171, London: National Institute
‘Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of of Economic and Social Research.
Wages, 1973–1992: a Semi-Parametric Approach’, Forth, J. and Millward, N. (2002) ‘Union effects on pay
Econometrica, 64 (5): 1001–1044. levels in Britain’, Labor Economics, 9 (4): 547–61.
Disney, R. and Gosling, A. (2003) ‘A New Method for Fortin, N.M. and Lemieux, T. (1997), ‘Institutional
Estimating Public Sector Pay Premia: Evidence from Changes and Rising Wage Inequality: Is There a
Britain in the 1990s’, Centre for Economic Policy linkage?’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (2):
Research Discussion Paper No. 3787. London: Centre 75–96.
for Economic Performance. Freeman, R. B. (1980) ‘Unionism and the Dispersion of
Doeringer, P. B. and M. J. Piore. (1971) Internal Labor Wages’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 34 (1):
Markets and Manpower Analysis. Lexington, MA.: 3–23.
Heath Lexington Books. Freeman, R. B. and Gelber, A. M. (2006) ‘Optimal
Dube, A. and Freeman, R. (2006) ‘Complementarity Inequality/Optimal Incentives: Evidence from a
of Shared Compensation and Decision-making Tournament ’, NBER Working Paper No. W12588,
Systems: Evidence from the American Labor Market’, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
NBER mimeo. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Research.
Economic Research. Freeman, R. B., Kruse, D. and Blasi, J. (2006) ‘Worker
Dunlop, J. (1957) ‘The Task of Contemporary Wage responses to shirking’, Prepared for the Russell
Theory’, in J Dunlop (ed) The Theory of Wage Sage/NBER Conference in New York, October 2006.
Determination. London: Macmillan. French, M. and Dunlap, L. (1998) ‘Compensating Wage
Dunlop, J. (1988) ‘Labor Markets and Wage Determina- Differentials for Job Stress’, Applied Economics, 30
tion: Then and now’, Chapter 2 in B Kaufman (ed) (8): 1067–75.
How Labor Markets Work: Reflections on Theory and Gallie, D., Felstead, A. and Green, F. (2004) ‘Changing
Practice by John Dunlop, Clark Kerr, Richard Lester, Patterns of Task Discretion in Britain’, Work,
and Lloyd Reynolds, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. Employment and Society, 18 (2): 243–66.
Elliot, R. and Duffus, K. (1996) ‘What Has Been Gallie, D., White, M., Cheng, Y. and Tomlinson, M.
Happening to Pay in the Public-service Sector of (1998) Restructuring the Employment Relationship.
the British Economy? Developments over the Period Oxford: Oxford University Press.
1970–1992’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Garen, J. (1988) ‘Compensating Wage Differentials
34 (1): 51–86. and the Endogeneity of Job Riskiness’, Review of
Employment Tribunal Service (2006) Annual Report and Economics and Statistics, 70 (1): 9–16.
Accounts 2005–2006, London: The Stationery Office. Gibbons, R. and Katz, L. (1992) ‘Does Unmeasured
Eurostat (2001) ‘EU Labour Costs 1999’, Statistics in Ability Explain Inter-Industry Wage Differentials?’,
Focus, Theme 3/2001, Luxemburg: Eurostat. Review of Economic Studies, 59 (3): 515–35.
Fairris, D. (1989) ‘Compensating Wage Differentials Gilman, M., Edwards, P., Ram, M. and Arrowsmith, J.
in the Union and Non-Union Sectors’, Industrial (2002) ‘Pay Determination in Small Firms in the
Relations, 28 (3): 356–72. UK: the Case of the Response to the National
510 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Minimum Wage’, Industrial Relations Journal, 33 (1): Katz, L. and Krueger, A. (1992) ‘The Effect of the
52–67. Minimum Wage on the Fast Food Industry’, Industrial
Glyn, A. (2001) ‘Inequalities of Employment and Wages and Labor Relations Review, 46 (1): 6–21.
in OECD Countries’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Katz, L., Loveman, G. and Blanchflower, D. (1995),
Statistics, 63: 697–713. ‘A Comparison of Changes in the Structure of Wages
Goos, M. and Manning, A. (2003). Lousy and Lovely in Four OECD Countries’, in R.B. Freeman and
Jobs: the Rising Polarization of Work in Britain, L.F. Katz (eds) Differences and Changes in Wage
CEP Discussion Paper No. 604, London School of Structures. University of Chicago Press and NBER.
Economics. pp. 25–65.
Gosling, A. and Lemieux, T. (2004), ‘Labor Market Kessler, S. and Bayliss, F. (1998) Contemporary British
Reforms and Changes in Wage Inequality in the Industrial Relations. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
United Kingdom and the United States in D. Card, Kondylis, F. and Wadsworth, J. (2006) Wages and Wage
R. Blundell and R. Freeman (eds), Seeking a Premier Inequality since the 1970s. London: Royal Holloway
League Economy. The Economic Effects of British College, University of London, mimeo.
Economic Reforms 1980–2000. University of Chicago Kostiuk, P. (1990) ‘Compensating Differentials for
Press. Shift Work’, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5):
Green, F, and Dickerson, A. (2004) ‘The Growth and 1055–75.
Valuation of Computing and Other Generic Skills’, Krueger, A. B. (1991) ‘Ownership, Agency and Wages:
Oxford Economic Papers, 56 (3): 371–406. An Examination of Franchising in the Fast-Food
Greenberg, J. (1990) ‘Employee Theft as a Reaction Industry’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (1):
to Underpayment or Inequity: The Hidden Cost of 75–101.
Pay Cuts’, Journal of Applied Psychology, 75 (5): Krueger, A. B. and Summers, L. H. (1988) ‘Efficiency
561–68. Wages and the Inter-Industry Wage Structure’,
Gregg, P. and Machin, S. (1994) ‘Is the UK Rise in Econometrica, 56 (2): 259–93.
Inequality Different?’ in R Barrell (ed.) The UK Labor Lanfranchi, J., Ohlsson, H. and Skalli, A. (2002)
Market. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ‘Compensating Wage Differentials and Shift-Work
Gunderson, M. and Hyatt, D. (2001) ‘Workplace Risks Preferences’, Economics Letters, 74 (3): 393–98.
and Wages: Canadian Evidence from Alternative Lazear, E. P. (1979) ‘Why Is There Mandatory
Models’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 34 (2): Retirement?’ Journal of Political Economy, 87 (6):
377–95. 1261–64.
Hakim, C. (2000) Work-Lifestyle Choices in the 21st Lazear, E. P. and Rosen, S. (1981) ‘Rank-Order
Century: Preference Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts’, Journal
Press. of Political Economy, 89 (5): 841–64.
Harkness, S. (1996) ‘The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence Lee, D. (1999) ‘Wage Inequality in the US during the
for the UK’, Fiscal Studies, 17 (2): 1–36. 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling Minimum Wage?’,
Hicks, J. (1932) The Theory of Wages. London: Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (3): 977–1023.
Macmillan. Lester, R. A. (1952) ‘A Range Theory of Wage
Hildreth, A. and Oswald, A. (1997), ‘Rent-Sharing and Differentials’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
Wages: Evidence from Company and Establishment 5 (4): 483–500.
Panels’, Journal of Labor Economics, 15 (2): 318–37. Levine, D. (1992) ‘Can Wage Increases Pay For
Hirsch, B. T. and Schumacher, E. J. (2001) ‘Private Themselves? Tests with a Production Function’, The
Sector Union Density and the Wage Premium: Past, Economic Journal, 102 (414): 1102–15.
Present and Future’. Journal of Labor Research 22 (3): Lucifora, C. and Meurs, D. (2004) ‘The Public Sector Pay
487–518. Gap in France, Great Britain and Italy’, IZA Discussion
Holmlund, B. and Ohlsson, H. (1992) ‘Wage Linkages Paper No. 1041. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor.
between Private and Public Sectors in Sweden’, Labor, Machin, S.J. and Vignoles, A. (2005) What’s the Good
6 (2): 3–17. of Education? The Economics of Education in the UK.
Joshi, H. and Paci, P. (1998) Unequal Pay for Women and Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Men: Evidence from the British Birth Cohort Studies. Mackay, D., Boddy, D., Brack, J., Diack, J. and Jones, N.
Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. (1971) Labour Markets Under Different Employment
Kahn, L. (1993) ‘Free Agency, Long-Term Contracts and Conditions. London: Allen and Unwin.
Compensation in Major League Baseball: Estimates Mahajan, S. (2005) ‘Input-Output: Concentration Ratios
from Panel Data’, Review of Economics and Statistics, for Businesses by Industry in 2005’, Economic Trends,
75 (1): 157–64. 624: 52–62.
THE THEORY AND PRACTICE OF PAY SETTING 511

Manning, A. (2003) Monopsony in Motion. Princeton, Purse, K. (2004) ‘Work-Related Fatality Risks and
NJ: Princeton University Press. Neoclassical Compensating Wage Differentials’,
Manning, A. and Petrongolo, B. (2005) The Part-Time Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28 (4): 597–617.
Pay Penalty. London: Women and Equality Unit. Raff, D. and Summers, L. (1987) ‘Did Henry Ford Pay
Marx, K. (1976) Capital Volume One. Harmondsworth, Efficiency Wages?’, Journal of Labor Economics, 5 (2):
Penguin. 557–86.
McIntosh, S. (2006) ‘Further Analysis of the Returns Ransom, M. (1993) ‘Seniority and Monopsony in the
to Academic and Vocational Qualifications’, Oxford Academic Labor Market’, American Economic Review
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 68 (2): 83 (1): 221–31.
225–52. Rosen, S. (1969) ‘Trade Union Power, Threat Effects
McNabb, R. (1989) ‘Compensating Wage Differentials: and the Extent of Organization’, Review of Economic
Some Evidence for Britain’, Oxford Economics Papers, Studies, 36 (106): 185–96.
41 (1): 327–38. Rubery, J. (1997) ‘Wages and the Labour Market’,
Millward, N., Forth, J. and Bryson, A. (2001) Who calls British Journal of Industrial Relations, 35 (3):
the Tune at Work? The Impact of Trade Unions on 337–66.
Jobs and Pay. York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation. Salop, S. (1979) ‘A Model of the Natural Rate of
Moretti (2000) ‘Do Wages Compensate for Risk of Unemployment’, American Economic Review, 69 (3):
Unemployment? Parametric and Semi-Parametric 117–25.
Evidence from Seasonal Jobs’, Journal of Risk and Salop, J. and Salop, S. (1976) ‘Self-Selection and
Uncertainty, 20 (1): 45–66. Turnover in the Labor Market’, Quarterly Journal of
Moule, C. (1998) ‘The Regulation of Work in Small Economics, 90 (4): 619–27.
Firms: A View from the Inside’, Work, Employment Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. (1984) ‘Equilibrium Unem-
and Society, 12 (4): 635–54. ployment as a Worker Discipline Device’, American
Murphy, K. M. and Topel, R. H. (1990) ‘Efficiency Wages Economic Review 74 (2): 433–44.
Reconsidered: Theory and Evidence’ in Y. Weiss Slichter, S. H. (1950) ‘Notes on the Structure of
and G. Fishelson (eds.) Advances in the Theory Wages’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 32 (1):
and Measurement of Unemployment. New York: 80–91.
Macmillan. pp. 204–40. Smith, A. (1982) An Inquiry into the Nature and
Myck, M. and Paull, G. (2004) ‘The Role of Employment Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Penguin
Experience in Explaining the Gender Wage Gap’, Classics.
Institute for Fiscal Studies Working Paper 04/116. Solow, R. (1990) The Labour Market as a Social
London: Institute for Fiscal Studies. Institution. Oxford: Blackwell.
Neal, D. (1995) ‘Industry-Specific Human Capital: Spence, M. (1973) ‘Job market signalling’, Quarterly
Evidence from Displaced Workers’, Journal of Labor Journal of Economics, 87 (3): 355–74.
Economics, 13 (4): 653–77. Spitz, A. (2005) ‘Technical Change, Job Tasks and Rising
Neumark, D., Zhang, J. and Ciccarella, S. (2005) ‘The Educational Demands: Looking Outside the Wage
Effects of Wal-Mart on Local Labor Markets’, Working Structure’. Mimeo, Centre for European Economic
Paper No. 11782. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau Research (ZEW), Mannheim.
of Economic Research. Stewart, M. B. (1987) ‘Collective Bargaining Arrange-
Nolan, P. and Brown, W. (1983) ‘Competition and ments, Closed Shops and Relative Pay’, Economic
Workplace Wage Determination’, Oxford Bulletin of Journal, 97 (2): 140–56.
Economics and Statistics, 45 (3): 269–87. Stewart, M. B. (1995) ‘Union Wage Differentials
Olson, C. (2002) ‘Do Workers Accept Lower Wages in an Era of Declining Unionization’, Oxford
in Exchange for Health Benefits?’, Journal of Labor Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 57 (2):
Economics, 20 (2) (part 2): S91–S114. 143–66.
Phillips, A. (1958) ‘The Relation between Unemployment Sullivan, D. (1989) ‘Monopsony Power in the Market for
and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the Nurses.’ Journal of Law and Economics 32 (2) part 2:
United Kingdom, 1861–1957’, Economica, 25 (100): S135–S178.
283–99. Swaffield, J. (2000) ‘Gender, motivation, experience
Pierce, B. (2001) ‘Compensation Inequality’, Quarterly and wages’, Centre for Economic Performance,
Journal of Economics, 116 (4): 1493–525. London School of Economics, Discussion Paper
Piore, M. (1979) Birds of Passage: Migrant Labor in No. 457.
Industrial Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Theodossiou, I. (1995) ‘Wage Determination for Career
Press. and Non-Career Workers in the UK: Is There
512 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Labour Market Segmentation?’, Economica, 62 (245): Wadhwani, S. B. and Wall, M. (1991) ‘A Direct Test
195–211. of the Efficiency Wage Model using UK Micro-Data’,
Van Reenen, J. (1996), ‘The Creation and Capture Oxford Economic Papers, 43 (4): 529–48.
of Rents: Wages and Innovation in a Panel of UK Weiss, A. (1980) ‘Job Queues and Layoffs in Labor
Companies’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (1): Markets with Flexible Wages’, Journal of Political
195–226. Economy, 88 (3): 526–28.
Viscusi, W. (1978) ‘Wealth Effects and Earnings Weitzman, M. L. and Kruse, D. L. (1990) ‘Profit sharing
Premiums for Job Hazards’, Review of Economics and and productivity’ in A. S. Blinder (ed.) Paying for
Statistics, 60 (3): 408–16. Productivity. A Look at the Evidence. Washington DC:
Wade, J. B., O’Reilly, C. A., and Pollock, T. G. (2006) Brookings Institute.
‘Overpaid CEO’s and Underpaid Managers: Fairness White, M, and Forth, J. (1998) Pathways through
and Executive Compensation’, Organization Science, Unemployment: The Effects of a Flexible Labor
17 (5): 527–44. Market. York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation.
27
Working Time and
Work-Life Balance
Paul Blyton

INTRODUCTION Historically, in industrialized economies,


the employment relations of working time
The pattern of working time – its overall was a relatively straightforward affair. When
duration and arrangement within the day, daily and weekly hours were very long,
week and year – plays a central part not and for most workers spread across six
only in employees’ overall experience of (or in some activities, seven) days each
work, but also in how (and how well) time week, the primary objective for workers and
spent at work integrates with life outside their representatives was clear: to secure
work. Working time is a core issue within reductions in the amount of hours spent at
employment relations: for the majority of work and the creation of more free days.
employees, their weekly working hours, Reductions in working time, incorporating
together with the amount of holiday they campaigns for a shorter working day and the
are entitled to, are among the most clearly- elimination of compulsory (and often unpaid)
defined elements of the employment contract. overtime, represented a crucial early focus
Indeed, given the difficulty of specifying for trade union organization in countries such
in such contracts precisely how much work as Australia, the UK and the US (Burgess,
an employee is expected to perform, how 1975; Owen, 1979; Roedinger and Foner,
long an individual is required to work is 1989). Employers’ approach to working time
widely used as a proxy for the amount of was equally clear. Primarily this involved
work expected. Thus, the majority of employ- concertedly resisting demands for reduced
ment contracts (particularly for manual work hours, often argued on the basis that
occupations and non-managerial white-collar profitability lay in the final period of work.
work) specify a level of reward in return The result of this resistance was that in
for the supply of an agreed amount of some sectors, reductions in working time were
labor time. achieved only after protracted campaigns by
514 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

organized labor, whilst in others working patterns, but also in the processes involved in
hours at first increased rather than decreased regulating those arrangements. Substantively
as the factory system grew, substantially we can detect a shift toward a much more
delaying any significant reductions in working heterogeneous pattern of working time both
time (Bienefeld, 1972: 32). in terms of the duration of time that people
In many countries, the duration of working work, and the periods of the day (or night)
time continues to be a key temporal concern that they perform those hours. There are also
for workers and their representatives. As I notable examples of developments in statu-
discuss further below, working hours in some tory regulation relating to various aspects of
countries (particularly recent industrializing working time. In terms of processes, evidence
economies) remain substantially higher than points to a widespread shift away from stan-
in their longer-developed counterparts (ILO, dardized (industry or sector) collective union-
2004: 748; OECD, 2005: 255). Elsewhere management agreements on work hours and
however, two related developments are acting toward a greater role for more localized
to shift the degree and focus of attention being determination of actual hours patterns. Anxo
paid to working time, both within and outside and colleagues (2004: 2) sum up the main
the machinery of employment relations. First, aspects of these substantive and procedural
it is clear that many employers have become changes thus: ‘in most industrial societies,
more actively engaged with working time the historical trends toward a progressive
issues, and are according a greater signifi- standardization of working time have given
cance to working time than hitherto, partic- way to a diversification, decentralization and
ularly as it relates to the overall pattern of individualization of working hours’(emphasis
labor deployment and the relative cost of dif- in original). In combination, these shifts
ferent working time arrangements. As I shall are resulting in fundamental changes both
explore, this greater recognition of working to the overall character of working time
time in part reflects other temporal develop- arrangements and the nature of the regulation
ments taking place, including the expansion in of those arrangements.
operating times in manufacturing and partic- To explore these issues in more detail,
ularly service activities that has occurred, and the remainder of the chapter is divided into
employer moves to staff these longer periods seven sections. The following two sections
in more flexible and cost-effective ways than examine overall patterns of working time,
they have relied on in the past. In addition, considering first developments in duration,
and stemming particularly (though not solely) and second the scheduling of work hours
from the marked growths in female participa- together with (briefly) a consideration of the
tion in labor markets over the past generation, utilization of the work period: three aspects of
there has been a developing awareness of working time that Adam (1990) summarizes
how working time arrangements impact on the as the ‘time, timing and tempo’ of work.
ability of individuals and families to integrate Three further sections then explore the ways
their work and non-work lives. Hence, just in which work time is regulated, examining:
as the employers’ agenda over working time changes in the legal regulation of working
has broadened, so too for employees, have hours; the collective regulation by the parties
working time issues expanded to incorporate to employment relations and the individual
not only questions of duration but also the control over working time exercised by
degree of control and choice they enjoy over managers and employees. Throughout much
their working time pattern, and the scope of Europe, the overall effect of the changes
this provides to mesh successfully their lives in regulation is a slightly tighter set of
inside and outside the workplace. legal boundaries relating to working time,
Against this background of a broadening but within those boundaries a more localized
temporal agenda, significant changes are determination of actual work time patterns.
evident not only in the nature of working time Elsewhere, however, the decline in the joint
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 515

regulation of work time has not been offset by 40-hour week by the 1960s (Bienefeld, 1972;
stronger statutory control, resulting in greater Blyton, 1985). Paid holidays also developed
managerial control over work patterns and, in over this period, though considerable national
some countries, a growth in longer working variation on amounts of paid leave remained, a
hours. Before drawing some conclusions, variation that continues to exist (Blyton, 1985;
a penultimate section locates working time Green, 1997).
within a broader context by considering the Since the 1980s, there have been further
growth of work-life balance issues and the reductions in the average length of the basic
way that concerns over the integration of work week in the majority of countries.
work and non-work activity is encouraging In Europe, these have resulted both from
the employment relations of working time to high profile trade union campaigns (such
be considered in much broader terms than has as IG Metall’s campaign that achieved a
generally been the case in the past. 35-hour week in the German metalworking
industry in the mid-1990s), as well as by
more incremental developments as groups
have sought comparability with reductions
DEVELOPMENTS IN WORKING TIME
achieved elsewhere. In France, reductions
have also resulted from political interven-
Duration
tion and the controversial introduction of a
For most of the nineteenth and twentieth statutory 35-hour week in 2000 (Bouffartigue
centuries, and in the context of the emer- and Bouteiller, 2001; Freyssinet, 1998) as a
gence of large-scale industrial workforces, work-sharing attempt to safeguard and create
the employment relations of working time employment (I will return to the French
centered on attempts, via political campaigns, case below). Outside Europe, working hours
trade union action and direct pressure by remain comparatively long in a number of
workers themselves, to reduce the basic hours countries (particularly in parts of Asia) and
of work.1 These campaigns provided an have been the focus of campaigns both by
important focus for early trade union devel- individual trade unions and by international
opment. As Arrowsmith (2002: 84) comments union organizations such as the International
on the British case, ‘The question of hours Metalworkers’ Federation (IMF, 1997). Some
has shaped the labour movement over the last reductions in work hours have been evident in
two centuries. Working time was the issue many of these countries – for example average
that provided a boost to union membership work hours in Korea fell by 13 per cent
at critical times and it provided some of the between 1983 and 2004 (OECD, 2005: 255).
most enduring victories for organized labour’. Even so, considerable differences between
The campaigns for reductions in work hours, countries remain (OECD, 2006: 265).
which initially were often targeted at certain Yet, while long working hours is a particular
sections of the labor force (notably young concern for employees and their representa-
and female workers) eventually enjoyed sig- tives in various newer and emerging industrial
nificant success, despite concerted employer economies, it is not an issue confined to these
opposition (Bienefeld, 1972). Individual vic- contexts. In countries where the basic working
tories provided the platform for reductions week has been at or below 40 hours for a
elsewhere as trade unions used early gains considerable period, many individuals and
as the basis for comparable claims for other groups continue to work substantially longer
groups. The result was a growing degree of hours, usually as a result of working lengthy
standardization around a lower weekly norm. periods of paid or unpaid overtime over
In the UK for example, this was reflected and above contractually-agreed working time.
in the development of a 54-hour working In Britain for example, where the average
week by the early twentieth century, followed basic work week for full-time workers in 2004
later by 48 and 44-hour work weeks, and a was 37.2 hours (EIRO, 2005), approaching
516 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

one-in-five (18 per cent) of employees report whose contract specifies much fewer work
that they usually work over 48 hours per week hours. And as we shall explore, this degree of
(Office for National Statistics, 2006: 59). heterogeneity appears to be increasing over
Those undertaking long working hours are time, not least as a result of changes in
more likely to be male and located either the ways in which working time issues are
in the upper (managerial, professional) or regulated within employment relations.
lower (semi-skilled and unskilled) levels
of the occupational hierarchy; for example,
Arrangement and utilization
36 per cent of male managers and 28 per cent
of machine operatives in Britain reported that A major factor bringing about alterations in
they usually worked over 48 hours per week the arrangement and scheduling of working
in 2005 (ibid). Elsewhere, the existence of time has been the increase in operating times
long working hours is a feature of employment occurring in both manufacturing and service
noted particularly in Australia, Canada and the activities in recent years. In manufacturing,
US, with many reports suggesting a growing extending operating time is one way of
rather than diminishing prevalence of long improving returns in situations of increased
work hours (see, for example, Barrett et al., investment in technology and/or a faster
2005: 142; Bittman and Rice, 2001; Campbell, rate of technological obsolescence. However,
2002; Duxbury and Higgins, 2006; Schor, increased operating hours are particularly
1991). evident in service sector activities, reflecting
In the UK, the widespread incidence of the general extension of business hours and
long working hours has become a focus opening periods, including the spread of
of union concern over work hours, and in 24-hour trading in parts of retailing and
particular the amount of work performed as elsewhere. The upshot of the juxtaposition of
unpaid overtime (Heery, 2006: 44). Long a gradually declining basic work week on the
work hours also raise concerns regarding one hand, and an increase in operating times
the impact on workers’ health and safety. on the other, has been a greater de-coupling of
Reviewing over twenty health studies for individual work hours from operating hours,
example, Sparks et al. (1997: 401) highlight with the length of the latter far exceeding
a ‘small but significant’ association between that of the former. Such de-coupling is not
hours of work and various health symptoms new of course and many continuous and near-
including, among other things, greater sleep continuous process activities, from hospitals
disturbance, and heightened levels of tension, to hotels and postal services to steel plants,
stress and fatigue (see also Iskra-Golec et al., have long used shift systems to cover a long
1996). The health and safety implications operating period. What is new, however, is
of long working hours and particular shift the spread of such arrangements into areas
patterns has represented an important stimulus where, traditionally, shift working has been
to recent statutory regulation of working comparatively rare, such as retailing.
time, including the European Working Time The expansion of operating times into
Directive, discussed below. evenings and weekends has been one factor
This existence of long working hours stimulating a far greater diversity of work
among a significant minority also highlights patterns. In terms of weekend working,
a broader issue affecting the general analysis for example, a comparison of 16 countries
of working time patterns: that the picture in Europe and North America reported an
presented by any discussion of changes in average of around one-in-five workers usually
the basic working week (the contractually- working on Saturdays and a smaller propor-
agreed work period) considerably masks the tion (approximately between one-in-six and
extent of variation in actual hours worked, not one-in-ten) working on Sundays (Presser and
only by those working substantially longer Gornick, 2005). Another contributing factor
than the basic work week, but also by those to growing work time diversity has been the
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 517

spread of different patterns of part-time hours, the work period that employees actually spend
including very short (eight hours per week or working. Means of achieving increases in
less) part-time schedules (Noon and Blyton, utilization have included reducing break times
2007: 102–3). In combination, the result of and tightening the definition of the working
these developments has been that in the UK period, for example to be exclusive, rather
for example, only a minority of the workforce than inclusive, of preparatory activities such
now work what formerly was considered as as changing in and out of work clothes or
a ‘standard’ work day (full-time, Monday to walking to or from the work station. Latter
Friday, with no evening or weekend work) efforts to tighten the definition of the working
(Hewitt, 1993: 23; Hill, 2000). period have involved such practices as ‘bell-
Historically, hours worked that were not to-bell working’, referring to the signals for
part of the ‘standard’ work period (evenings, the start and end of shifts, with employees
nights, weekends) were paid at a premium rate required to be in position to begin work when
in acknowledgment of their greater impact the signal is given, and only terminating work
on non-work life. However, extensions to following an equivalent signal to indicate
operating periods in organizations have been a break or completion of the shift (Blyton,
accompanied, to a growing extent, by efforts 1994: 520).
to broaden the definition of standard hours, Having charted some of the main devel-
paid at a non-premium rate. This trend has opments in the nature of working time, we
been evident in several countries including the now turn to the regulation of work hours,
UK, Germany and Australia (see for example, and to developments evident at national (and
Blyton and Trinczek, 1995; and Deery and supra-national) level, as well as at more local
Mahoney, 1994: 333–5). The broadening of levels.
the definition of standard hours can also be
seen to reflect a growing inability on the part
of organized labor in the recent period to
THE REGULATION OF WORKING TIME
protect former definitions of premium-paid
hours.
Statutory regulation
One means of implementing a broader defi-
nition of standard hours, as well as increasing Laws on working time exist, to a greater or
employers’ flexibility over the deployment of lesser extent, in all industrialized countries,
those hours, has been through the introduction designed overall to ensure adequate time
of ‘annualized hours’ contracts which specify for workers to be away from work, and
agreed annual, rather than weekly, hours reduce deleterious health and safety conse-
of work. Such contracts typically include quences of long or unbroken work periods.
provision to vary hours to match fluctuations Yet, whilst at first glance these statutory
in demand, or leave some hours as non- regulations appear relatively wide-ranging,
rostered time, for which workers remain in practice they are more limited in effect;
‘on call’ to cover unplanned circumstances neither do they substitute for the important
(Arrowsmith and Sisson, 2000). In the UK in role of employment relations negotiation in
2005, around one-in-twenty full-time employ- determining and monitoring working time
ees were covered by annual hours contracts arrangements, nor prevent employers from
(Office for National Statistics, 2006: 59). determining key aspects of working time
As well as seeking to increase the flexibility arrangements unilaterally. The main compo-
of work hours and reduce the circumstances nents of working time legislation relate to:
under which premium payments are paid for the specification of normal daily or weekly
certain hours, employer interest in restrict- hours; the limits on overtime work; maximum
ing the cost of working time can also daily or weekly hours’ limits; rest periods and
be identified in initiatives to increase the annual vacation periods (McCann, 2005: 1).
utilization of working time – the amount of In terms of these different elements, countries
518 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

vary not only in terms of the extent and Over the past decade, there has been a range
main focus of any temporal regulation, but of statutory developments in the working time
also whether legal limits have come to field. In this area, Europe has been at the
act as the norm for working time in that forefront of changes, and four brief examples
country, or whether they represent a base illustrate the variety of the changes taking
(particularly a maximum) from which trade place and may point to possible working time
unions or other employee representatives have developments elsewhere in the coming period.
negotiated improvements upon, with the result First, the European Union (EU) has adopted
that legal limits act in practice to protect those several directives on time-related issues,
groups of workers whose positions are more including parental leave, part-time working
vulnerable (for example, not covered by trade and, most notably, the European Directive on
union representation). Working Time (Adnett and Hardy, 2000).2
In a review of over 100 countries, McCann In addition to setting out minimum levels of
(2005: 4) notes that almost half have adopted holiday entitlement and rest periods, the key
a legal standard working week of 40 hours component of the Working Time Directive
(that is, the number of hours to be worked is the establishment of a 48-hour maximum
before overtime payments are required for working week. In the case of several EU
those whose contract specifies payment for member states, this maximum is equal to,
overtime). The US is one such country, or greater than, extant national legislation
with the 40-hour work week and overtime on maximum hours, and so has had only a
payments for additional hours established limited impact. Its relevance has been greater,
by the Fair Labor Standards Act (Berg however, in countries such as the UK, where
et al., 2004: 341). Among the countries not previously the large majority of workers
operating a legal 40-hour work week, standard were not covered by any maximum hours
weeks of 42, 45 and 48 hours are the most regulation. Yet, as noted earlier, even more
common. Below the 40-hour norm, notable than a decade after the Directive was issued,
examples include France and Belgium which the work weeks of a substantial minority of
maintain 35- and 38-hour thresholds respec- workers in the UK continue to exceed the
tively. In addition, several countries, including 48 hours maximum, either because they have
Germany and Ireland, operate not a normal agreed with their employers to opt out of the
hours limit but a statutory limit on maximum regulations (an opt out that was agreed as a
hours. Other countries in contrast, including concession to the UK to gain its agreement to
Australia, India and Pakistan, operate with the Directive, and one that will presumably
no nationally-applied limits on weekly hours be removed at some point) or are deemed
(ibid). In terms of the statutory regulation to be individuals (such as professionals) who
of overtime, in a large number of countries determine their own work hours.
the most common regulation governs either A second example from Europe relates to
the maximum (weekly or annual) amount employers being obliged to accommodate, or
of overtime that an individual can work, or consider, requests from employees to alter
the overall maximum limits on daily and/or their working hours (OECD, 2006: 102).
weekly hours. Examples of the latter include European countries vary on the strength of this
the 12-hour day maximum in Spain, the obligation: it is strongest in countries such as
Czech Republic, Nigeria, Chile and Malaysia, the Netherlands, whilst in the UK the wording
the 48-hour maximum week common within of the requirement on employers is weaker.
Europe and a 60-hour weekly limit in Nigeria, Under the Employment Act 2002, employers
Egypt, Jordan, Brazil, Malaysia, Singapore in the UK are required to ‘seriously consider’
and Thailand. In contrast, a number of requests for flexible working from employ-
countries, including Japan, New Zealand and ees with young children (and from 2007,
the US, maintain no maximum overtime limits employees with adult caring responsibilities).
(ibid: 24–6). In the main, this has taken the form either of
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 519

requests to change from full-time to part-time Yet, as well as highlighting these different
working, or to work some form of flexible initiatives that have extended statutory cov-
work hours. Despite the apparent weakness erage of aspects of working time, it is also
in the wording, however, early assessments important to note the presence of other factors
of the provision show the large majority that act to limit the impact of different working
of such requests being accommodated by time laws. These include the exempting of
employers (Holt and Grainger, 2005). I return particular groups from different pieces of
to this below in the discussion of work-life legislation (McCann, 2005: 25, 27) and also
balance. the degree to which statutory regulations are
A third European example of statutory effectively enforced. A further factor that can
working time development is recent legis- mute the impact of any legislation is the length
lation in several Nordic countries to extend of the reference period over which work hours
paternity leave and father’s parental leave, are calculated (statutory limits on weekly
to encourage greater sharing of childcare hours typically include an averaging period
responsibilities. Parental leave legislation is within which the limits must be achieved).
long established in Nordic countries; Norway These averaging or reference periods vary
for example, has had parental leave since 1936 considerably; for example, they are typically
and paternity leave since 1977 (Hardy and thirteen weeks in the Netherlands, but up
Adnett, 2002: 166). In recent years, ‘father’s to one year in Japan and Spain (McCann,
leave’ provisions have been further extended, 2005: 7). Where reference periods extend as
ranging from six weeks in Norway to three long as a year (and thus in effect become
months in Iceland (Moss and O’Brien, 2006). annual hours contracts), this provides con-
Early evaluations in Norway found that when siderable scope for employees to be working
this leave was introduced on a transferable much longer than the weekly statutory limits
basis (that is, available to either parent) it on hours for a considerable period of time.
was primarily utilized as additional maternity
leave. To stimulate a more equitable sharing
Union-management relations
of early childrearing, this father’s leave has
subsequently been made non-transferable; As noted earlier, working time issues have
this has resulted, in a very short time period, been a common focus of union-management
in high rates of take-up by fathers in Norway relations over a long period. This continues,
(Brandth and Kvande, 2003). despite the substantial changes in the scope
A final example of statutory developments and coverage of those relations in many
in the working time field in Europe has been countries over the past two decades. In the
the introduction (by two laws and despite UK in 2004, for example, working hours
strong employer opposition) of a 35-hour remained the second most frequent topic
working week in France in 2000. Introduced (after pay) that managers negotiated with
as part of the socialist government’s measures trade unions; holidays represented the third
to address persistent high levels of unem- most frequent topic (Kersley et al., 2006:
ployment, this legislation has resulted in a 194). In those UK workplaces where unions
significant reduction in actual working hours were recognized, just over half (53 per cent)
in France, though the net effect on job creation normally negotiated over hours, and a similar
and job retention is much less clear (Durand proportion (52 per cent) over holidays.
and Martin, 2004; Fagnani and Letablier, A further 20 per cent of workplaces with rec-
2004: 554). In addition, as I discuss below, ognized unions normally consulted over hours
these working time laws in France have acted (ibid). Similarly in Germany, as Haipeter
as a major stimulus to local negotiations over and Lehndorff (2005: 141) comment, apart
working time by leaving much of the detail of from wages, working time has traditionally
the implementation of shorter weekly hours been the most prominent area of industrial
undetermined. relations regulation. A partial exception to
520 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

this pattern is the US where as Berg and but also a working time agenda at the local
colleagues comment, ‘working time has not level which has become more wide ranging
been a high bargaining priority’ for the than hitherto.
majority of unions in recent times (Berg et al., Examples of this growing decentralization
2004: 341). Elsewhere, however, working are widespread. In several European countries
time negotiations in different countries have for example, decentralization has accom-
involved not only weekly and annual hours, panied national framework agreements on
but also the length of working lifetimes, weekly hours. In France, the introduction of a
with the negotiation of early retirement statutory 35-hour week has been accompanied
provisions. As Ebbinghaus (2006) describes, by a major growth in company and local
in recent periods of restructuring and reces- collective bargaining to increase temporal
sion, both employers and trade unions have flexibility. Alis (2003) for example, reports
sought agreements on early retirement as that between 1998 and 2002, over 128,000
a way of securing a more popular means collective agreements on working hours
of workforce reduction than by compulsory were signed in France. Under the working
redundancies. time laws, collective agreements became the
While working time remains a prominent only means of implementing the 35-hour
topic in most countries where managers week, other than by a simple reduction in
continue to negotiate and consult with trade hours. Most commonly, these local collective
unions, what has changed in the joint agreements have focused on increasing the
regulation of hours is the level at which flexibility of working time to offset the cost
this regulation normally occurs: in particular, implications of the aggregate hours reduction.
there has been an evident decentralization In the main, this flexibility has taken the form
and a growing degree of local agreement of annual hours agreements (around an annual
and regulation of working time. In the past, level of 1600 hours) and amending work time
three things went together in the area of structures to cover longer operating or trading
working time: a lower level of differentiation hours (ibid).
of working hours than currently exists; a Similarly in Germany, the staged intro-
primary emphasis on duration (weekly hours duction of a 35-hour working week in the
and length of paid holidays) as the key issue metalworking industry by 1995 was accompa-
in working time and a trade union aim of nied by an agreement that the implementation
securing both standardization in relation to of the reduction would be subject to local
any working time changes, and overtime negotiations between management and works
payments for hours worked in excess of basic councils. Management increasingly sought to
weekly hours. Each of these elements acted offset the cost of the hours reduction by
both to simplify the treatment of working increasing the degree of temporal flexibility.
time issues, and facilitate a more centralized In the event, the main forms of flexibility
handling of many working time issues by both agreed related to: the proportion of the work-
parties, away from the particularities of the force who could voluntarily opt to work longer
workplace. However, build into this picture than the 35-hour week (up to 18 per cent of the
not only a growing tendency for managers to workforce); the length of averaging periods
utilize a wider range of working time patterns, to achieve the 35-hour norm (typically up to
but also a growing emphasis on issues other six months, and in some cases one year or
than simple duration, and the effect has even longer) and the use of individual time
been that the ability (and motivation) of the accounts to enable extra hours worked to be
parties to handle working time issues at a ‘banked’ and converted to time off (rather
more distant, centralized level, has become than overtime payments) at a later stage
considerably restricted. What has resulted has (Haipeter and Lehndorff, 2005: 143, 145).
been a growing tendency for a decentralized As Haipeter and Lehndorff point out, in
approach to the regulation of working time, highly unionized sectors such as automobile
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 521

manufacture, where works councils coverage by the relatively weak statutory framework
is comprehensive and well organized, this governing working time, and the reduced
growth in the local determination of actual significance of industry-wide regulation of
working time patterns has resulted in a process work hours (Barrett et al., 2005; Berg et al.,
of ‘regulated flexibility’ (ibid: 154). However, 2004: 339–341; Lee, 2004: 41).
in other areas, where unionism is weaker In general, more localized regulation of
and works councils less powerful – or not hours has been associated with the growth
in existence at all, as is the case in many of working time trade-offs, or ‘something
smaller establishments (see Addison et al., for something’ agreements: for example, a
2001) – the upshot of the decentralization has reduction in duration being conceded by man-
been a growth in managerial power over the agement either in return for greater flexibility
determination of actual working time patterns. over the scheduling of those hours, or in
In the UK, a substantial decentralization of exchange for a broader definition of ‘standard’
working time determination has also occurred hours not attracting overtime premia. In
over the past two decades, involving in part a this way the working time agenda has
shift away from multi-employer agreements broadened, and become more closely related
and toward organization-based arrangements to the particular working time requirements of
(either at company or workplace level) individual organizations.
(Arrowsmith and Sisson, 1999). As these
authors point out, however, this has not been
Management and employees
a universal trend; national frameworks have
continued to exist in some sectors (such as Any discussion of the regulation of working
health) whilst elsewhere (for example, engi- time by statutory instruments and employ-
neering) such frameworks were dismantled in ment relations agreements runs the danger of
the late 1980s and 1990s. Further, even where exaggerating the influence of each (and both,
such dismantling has taken place, Arrowsmith in combination) compared to other influences
and Sisson found that a standard working shaping actual patterns of work time. Here
time pattern often remained identifiable, or at we briefly examine not only the influence
least a significant clustering around a small of management, but also – less common
number of patterns. What is also evident in employment relations’ discussions – the
in their study, however, is the widespread influence of workers on their own work time
nature of the changes occurring in working patterns.
time arrangements, principally to enable In terms of managerial influence, though
employers to secure greater flexibility and evidence is somewhat patchy, it is neverthe-
reduce costs, through for example increased less clear that in many situations and over
shift working and the expansion of part-time many aspects, managers unilaterally regulate
schedules (Arrowsmith and Sisson, 1999: 63). their employees’ working time patterns. This
Outside Europe, changes in the employ- influence manifests itself in a variety of ways,
ment relations of working time are particularly from the initial determination of work time
evident in Australia. The increased impor- arrangements associated with job vacancies
tance of workplace agreements in Australia (for example whether the job vacancy is
from the mid-1990s onwards and the weak- advertised as full- or part-time), to the
ening of former sector-wide bargaining, has determination of work periods and shift
been accompanied by a widening range of systems, the demand for overtime working,
working time patterns, including both very the availability of flexible working hours
short and very long shift patterns (Barrett and any restrictions on the periods when
et al., 2005; Loudoun and Harley, 2001). staff can take paid leave. Further, as well as
More generally, several commentators have any formal authority to determine work time
highlighted the growth of long hours working patterns, it is clear that managers also exert
in recent years in Australia, made easier considerable informal powers of regulation.
522 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Different studies have shown, for example, Yet, while these findings underline the
the influence of immediate line managers on extent of managerial influence over work time
the working time culture within their area of issues and the restricted influence of trade
responsibility: whether employees feel under unions in this area, it is also important to
pressure to work long hours or work without recognize that employees themselves exercise
taking their rest breaks in full, or whether a significant degree of influence and control
they feel they would receive support if over their working time. We have noted
they requested flexible working, for example already in the discussion for example, how
(Batt and Valcour, 2003: 211; BRMB Social recent legislation has, in different countries,
Research, 2004; Houston and Waumsley, provided individual employees with a greater
2003: 36; Thompson et al., 1999). Other measure of influence – for instance to take
studies have also shown that over and above leave at the birth of their children, or to
any formal flexible work time arrangements seek changes in their work patterns. Further,
in operation (such as a flexitime system) arrangements such as flexitime and time-
much ad hoc adjustment of actual work time banking, act to extend individual control over
patterns occurs as a result of informal requests the work period. In addition, however, there
by management, for example for workers to are a variety of ways in which employees
stay on at work to complete a particular task can act to influence their work time patterns.
(Marsh, 1991). Indeed, in the field of work sociology, there
In the UK, the evidence from the WERS is a history of studies documenting the
2004 investigation underlines the extent of many and varied ways that workers regulate
managerial influence in the working time area. aspects of their working time. These include
For while, as noted earlier, hours and holidays taking time off through voluntary absence,
figure prominently as items for joint regu- a work behavior that may be individual
lation in those workplaces with recognized and unorganized or more collaborative and
trade unions, in practice not only are large organized (Edwards and Scullion, 1982;
numbers of workplaces devoid of a recognized Heyes, 1997). Also significant are the many
union presence but as we also noted, even ways of ‘fiddling’ time at work, ranging
in establishments where unions are present, widely from arriving at work late, leaving
only in just over half of these do management early and covertly extending rest breaks,
negotiate over working hours. Indeed, in to sabotaging equipment in order to create
approaching one-in-five (18 per cent) of pauses in the work process (Ditton, 1979;
workplaces with union representatives, there Noon and Blyton, 2007). In their turn,
was no union involvement at all in work managers deploy a variety of means to control
hours issues, and in a further 10 per cent some of these employee behaviors, including
of such workplaces, union involvement was direct surveillance, bell-to-bell working and
restricted to being informed by management the close monitoring of absence behavior,
of any changes (Kersley et al., 2006: 194). to attendance bonuses and other rewards for
Overall, the WERS 2004 results show that in accurate time-keeping. Yet the picture remains
over seven out of ten workplaces in Britain one of a considerable ability on the part of
(71 per cent) management did not engage with many employees to modify the standard work
unions or other employee representatives on time pattern to gain some control over their
any issues relating to working hours (ibid). working period. What is more, a number of
A similar picture is portrayed by Berg et al. studies of employee attitudes highlight the
in relation to the US, where a lack of union contribution to overall job satisfaction of this
coverage, coupled with a tendency for unions access to some discretion or control over
to prioritize issues other than working time, working time (see for example, Baltes et al.,
has resulted in ‘Control over working time 1999; Berg 1999; Macan, 1994). Indeed, it is
rest[ing] largely with employers’ (Berg et al., evident that for many workers, it is not the
2004: 341). overall length of the working period that is felt
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 523

most keenly, nor even the timing of that work, better ‘work-life balance’. Though criticized
but the degree to which these constraints are for its confused terminology (work being
open to some degree of worker influence and a major part of life rather than something
control. separate, as implied in the expression ‘work-
To sum up this part of the discussion, it life’) nevertheless ‘work-life balance’ has
is evident that working time continues to be come to refer to individuals’ ‘ability to
regulated in several ways: partly by statute, pursue successfully their work and non-work
setting various maxima and minima relating lives, without undue pressures from one
to hours, holidays and rest periods; partly by undermining the satisfactory experience of
employment relations, increasingly through the other’ (Noon and Blyton, 2007: 356).
local rather than national agreements; partly The work-life balance debate represents, in
by management, both by formally establishing many respects, a broadening of discussions
working time structures and by more informal in the 1980s and 1990s surrounding ‘family
ways that influence both the working time friendly’ work policies. The now widely-
culture and the actual patterns of hours worked preferred expression of ‘work-life balance’ is
and partly by employees themselves, both a recognition that all those in paid work, not
overtly (for example, via the use of flexitime just those with family responsibilities, have
arrangements) and also by more covert means an interest in reconciling competing work and
that act to modify the formal work time non-work demands.
structure. The relative influence of each of For the large majority of those in different
these appears to have shifted significantly in studies reporting a work-life imbalance, the
the recent past: there has been a somewhat source of that imbalance is a negative spill-
enhanced role for statutory regulation in over from work to non-work life, rather
many countries; a reduced (and certainly than the reverse. However, even among
a decentralized) role for trade unions and the former, what in practice constitutes
joint regulation (reflecting in important part ‘balance’ will vary considerably from person
the widespread decline in influence of trade to person, depending on a wide range of
unions) and an increased role for management factors including individuals’ economic and
in environments less subject to trade union domestic circumstances, their age, the nature,
influence. Overall, as a result of a growing demands and security of their job and the
fragmentation of work time patterns and characteristics of their non-work life. Indeed
a decline in standardization, together with for some, a key source of imbalance may lie in
an increased emphasis on the arrangement excessive work, while for others (those under-
and flexibility of work hours, management or unemployed) any imbalance is likely to be
appear to have gained significantly greater the result of too little paid work. However, it
control over the work time agenda, despite any is the former aspect of the work-life balance
extension in statutory provision. At the same issue that is most relevant to the present
time, workers themselves continue to exert an discussion: the ‘time squeeze’ that many
important influence on their own work time experience between their work and non-work
patterns, an influence that is constrained by lives. This includes working parents with
managerial action, but far from eliminated. paid work and family responsibilities, and the
working time demands of many jobs reducing
the time available for life outside work.
WORK-LIFE BALANCE The association between work time and life
outside work has been a long running theme
In many recent discussions on working time, in workers’ demands for better terms and
much has been made of the link between conditions. Various early calls for an eight-
aspects of work time and the ability of hour working day, for example, adopted as
individuals to achieve a successful recon- their campaign slogan the nineteenth century
ciliation of work and non-work demands: a maxim that advocated ‘eight hours of work,
524 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

eight hours of rest, eight hours of recreation’. approach and/or a high proportion of women
However, in recent years several coinciding in the workplace, that are more likely to have
factors have brought the issue of work-life implemented flexibility and other time-related
balance more to the fore both in public policies (Wood et al., 2003).
policy and popular debate. These factors Several of the aspects of working time
include the substantial growth in rates of that are most relevant to work-life concerns
women’s economic activity (in part reflecting have displayed significant change in recent
public policies to stimulate higher levels years. We have noted a number of these
of labor force participation); the resulting already and include first, a widespread and
rise both in dual-earner households and continuing growth in part-time working, with
in levels of employment of women with many working couples choosing to balance
dependent children; elements of working life in and out of paid work by one member
time patterns, particularly the continuation (mainly women) working part-time. Second,
(and in some countries the expansion) of there are various indications that the provision
long hours working and the changing expe- of more flexible work schedules is increasing.
rience of work, particularly the growing In Britain for example, the number of work-
experience among many workers of increased places operating flexitime arrangements grew
work intensification (Green, 2004; Johansson, significantly between 1998 and 2004 (Kersley
2002). et al., 2006: 252), though as Hyman and
Responses to concerns over work-life Summers (2004) note, the actual provision of
balance are identifiable at societal, commu- flexible work schedules is often characterized
nity, organizational and individual levels, by a lack of formalization. However, in recent
and range from statutory childcare and years, this access to flexible hours has been
nursery provision to individual decisions to bolstered by statutory rights to request flexible
‘downshift’ to a simpler lifestyle. Within working by parents of young children (see
work organizations, three types of response above). Elsewhere too, flexitime has become
are most in evidence: policies that provide extensive; indeed, in Germany over four
employees with leave for child-bearing and out of five larger organizations (over 500
care; arrangements that provide more choice employees) have introduced flexible working
and flexibility over working time (how much, time systems (Croucher and Singe, 2004: 153)
when and where work hours are fulfilled) and and a growing number are experimenting
workplace provision to support parents, such with far-reaching flexitime systems in which
as child-care facilities or subsidies (Glass and employees decide their own work patterns
Estes, 1997). With only very limited provision (Trinczek, 2006).
of the third of these in most countries (in the A third example of work time developments
UK in 2004 for example, only 3 per cent of relevant to work-life balance relates to the
workplaces provided a workplace nursery; see area of leave policies, particularly child-care
Kersley et al., 2006: 254–5), the two main leave (less so in relation to caring for adults).
forms of organizational response to work-life Following an extensive review of leave
balance concerns are closely connected with provisions in 22 countries, Moss and O’Brien
aspects of working time. This is also reflected (2006: 7) conclude that ‘leave policy is
in Heery’s (2006) study of different work- receiving much attention at present with most
life issues pursued by trade unions: of the 20 countries reporting significant recent changes
work-life issues that union representatives in or future changes’. As noted earlier, Nordic
the study had negotiated over, three-quarters countries have been particularly prominent
were work hours related (Heery, 2006: 51). in this development, substantially extending
Wood et al’s analysis of family-friendly both maternity and particularly paternity leave
management practices in Britain indicates provision in recent years.
that it tends to be larger organizations, with A final example of a working time develop-
personnel departments, an equal-opportunity ment with significant work-life implications is
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 525

the spread of retirement practices which pro- effectively with non-work demands. Further,
vide a greater flexibility than a fixed and final moves to increase productivity through the
retirement date. As discussed above, early implementation of ‘high performance’ prac-
retirement provision became more prominent tices could add further work pressures that
in the 1980s and 1990s as employers, trade spill over negatively into non-work life. This
unions and many older workers viewed a is one finding of the study by White et al.
voluntary early exit as a more acceptable (2003) which found individuals reporting
means of workforce reduction than com- a negative effect on home life not only
pulsory redundancy. As Ebbinghaus (2006) associated with the number of hours worked,
points out, the growth of early retirement but also related to the presence of various high
provision has since slowed as the cost of performance practices including appraisal
such schemes has become a more prominent systems, group-working and performance
issue. However, provisions for retiring before related pay (see also Hochschild, 1997, and
the age that state pensions become payable for a contrasting view see Berg et al.,
remains widespread, and represents for many 2003).
an important source of choice over work-life Thus, while work-life balance concerns
balance decisions. continue to be raised, and while certain
The work-life aspects of retirement could steps are taken to alleviate certain work-
potentially be increased further by greater life pressures – particularly in relation to
opportunities for older workers to make a time off to care for young children – at the
more gradual transition from work to retire- same time other aspects of organizational life,
ment. Yet, whilst various partial retirement such as increased work pressures and greater
initiatives have been attempted in several work intensification, represent potentially
European countries (allowing employees to significant obstacles for more adequately
continue working a reduced workweek and reconciling the demands of work and non-
have access to a partial pension), such work life for many workers.
schemes have to date been of limited success
due primarily to the inadequacy of support-
ing funding arrangements, and restrictions CONCLUSION
imposed by different occupational pension
rules (Delsen, 1996; Ebbinghaus, 2006). This The foregoing discussion has identified shifts
may change in the future, however, at least both in the overall working time agenda
in Europe. The spread of age discrimina- and in the patterns of regulation of working
tion legislation, together with the increased time. Overall, the agenda has broadened
right among other groups to secure (or at considerably in the recent period, away from
least request) more flexible working, could a primary focus on duration – though this
improve the future access of older workers to remains critical in certain contexts – to
modifying their work time patterns, thereby encompass a wider range of issues relating
creating a more gradual transition between to the scheduling of work time, the degree
work and retirement. of temporal flexibility available to both
Yet at the same time various other employer employers and employees and the scope
policies on working time, as well as other for individuals to adjust their work time
aspects of work experience, are likely to arrangements to achieve a more satisfactory
continue to clash with a work-life agenda. work-life balance.
In part this represents a divergence over These features of working time are likely
flexibility: employers’ desire for the variable to remain prominent on employer, trade
availability of labor potentially conflicts union and employee agendas in coming
with employees seeking greater choice and years. Further, the contested nature of many
discretion over their own working time in aspects of working time – the competing
order to coordinate their paid work more demands by employers and employees for
526 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

greater flexibility, for example, the conflicting Arrowsmith, J. and Sisson, K. (1999) ‘Pay and working
interests over the definition of standard and time: towards organization-based systems?’, British
non-standard work hours and the potentially Journal of Industrial Relations, 37 (1): 51–75.
conflicting interests over workers’ retirement Arrowsmith, J. and Sisson, K. (2000) ‘Managing working
decisions – highlight the continuing relevance time’, in S. Bach and K. Sisson (eds) Person-
nel Management, 3rd edition. Oxford: Blackwell.
of joint regulation in this important area
pp. 287–313.
of employment conditions. Yet, without a Baltes, B. B., Briggs, T. E., Huff, J. W., Wright,
significant revival of trade union coverage and J. A. and Neuman, G. A. (1999) ‘Flexible and
influence, many employees will need to rely compressed workweek schedules: a meta-analysis
more than hitherto on the power deriving from of their effects on work-related criteria’, Journal of
their own labor market position and – for those Applied Psychology, 84 (4): 496–513.
whose position is less strong – on statutory Barrett, S., Burgess, J. and Campbell, I. (2005) ‘The
provision to bolster their influence over work- Australian labour market in 2004’, Journal of
ing time, and secure work time arrangements Industrial Relations, 47 (2): 133–50.
that more satisfactorily reconcile the demands Batt, R. and Valcour, P.M. (2003) ‘Human resources
of work and non-work life. practices as predictors of work-family outcomes and
employee turnover’, Industrial Relations, 42 (2):
189–220.
Berg, P. (1999) ‘The effects of high performance work
practices on job satisfaction in the United States steel
NOTES
industry’, Relations Industrielles, 54 (1): 111–35.
Berg, P., Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T. and Kalleberg, A.L.
1 Basic working hours is the term frequently used
to refer to the contractually-agreed work period; this (2004) ‘Contesting time: international comparisons
is distinct from ‘usual’ working hours which includes of employee control of working time’, Industrial and
periods of paid or unpaid overtime. Labor Relations Review, 57 (3): 331–49.
2 Within the EU, directives are binding agreements Berg, P., Kalleberg, A.L. and Appelbaum, E. (2003)
but require legislation in each member state to comply ‘Balancing work and family: the role of high-
with the objectives of the directive; see Gennard and commitment environments’, Industrial Relations,
Judge, 2005. 42 (2): 168–88.
Bienefeld, M.A. (1972) Working Hours in British Industry:
An Economic History. London: Weidenfeld and
Nicolson.
REFERENCES Bittman, M. and Rice, J. (2001) ‘The spectre of overwork:
an analysis of trends between 1974 and 1997 using
Adam, B. (1990) Time and Social Theory. Cambridge: Australian time use diaries’, Labour and Industry,
Polity. 12 (3): 5–26.
Addison, J.T., Schnabel, C. and Wagner, J. (2001) ‘Works Blyton, P. (1985) Changes in Working Time: An
councils in Germany: their effects on establishment International Review. London: Croom Helm.
performance’, Oxford Economic Papers, 53 (4): Blyton, P. (1994) ‘Working hours’, in K. Sisson
659–94. (ed.) Personnel Management, 2nd edition. Oxford:
Adnett, N. and Hardy, S. (2000) ‘Reviewing the working Blackwell. pp. 495–526.
time directive: rationale, implementation and case Blyton, P. and Trinczek, R. (1995) ‘Working time
law’, Industrial Relations Journal, 32 (2): 114–25. flexibility and annual hours’, European Industrial
Alis, D. (2003) ‘The 35-hour week in France: the French Relations Review, No. 260, September: 13–4.
exception?’, Personnel Review, 32 (4): 510–26. Bouffartigue, P. and Bouteiller, J. (2001) ‘“Our own
Anxo, D., Fagan, C., McCann, D., Lee, S. and Messenger, worst enemy” – French management and the 35-hour
J.C. (2004) ‘Introduction: working time in industrial- week’, Transfer, 1 (2): 211–26.
ized countries’, in J.C. Messenger (ed.) Working Time Brandth, B. and Kvande, E. (2003): Fleksible
and Workers’ Preferences in Industrialized Countries: Fedre[Flexible Fathers]. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.
Finding the Balance. London: Routledge. pp. 1–9. BRMB Social Research (2004) A survey of workers’
Arrowsmith, J. (2002) ‘The struggle over working time in experiences of the Working Time Regulations,
nineteenth and twentieth-century Britain’, Historical Employment Relations Research Series No. 31,
Studies in Industrial Relations, 13: 83–117. London: Department of Trade and Industry.
WORKING TIME AND WORK-LIFE BALANCE 527

Burgess, K. (1975) The Origins of British Industrial industry’, Industrial Relations Journal, 36 (2):
Relations: The Nineteenth Century Experience. 140–56.
London: Croom Helm. Hardy, S. and Adnett, N. (2002) ‘The Parental
Campbell, I. (2002) ‘Extended working hours in Leave Directive: towards a “family-friendly” Social
Australia’, Labour and Industry, 13 (1): 91–110. Europe?’, European Journal of Industrial Relations,
Croucher, R. and Singe, I. (2004) ‘Co-determination 8 (2): 157–72.
and working time accounts in the German finance Heery, E. (2006) ‘Bargaining for balance: union policy on
industry’, Industrial Relations Journal, 35 (2): work-life issues in the United Kingdom’, in P. Blyton,
153–68. B. Blunsdon, K. Reed and A. Dastmalchian, (eds)
Deery, S. J. and Mahony, A. (1994) ‘Temporal flexibility: Work-Life Integration: International Perspectives
management strategies and employee preferences in on the Balancing of Multiple Roles. Basingstoke:
the retail industry’, Journal of Industrial Relations, Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 42–62.
36 (3): 332–52. Hewitt, P. (1993) About Time: The Revolution in Work
Delsen, L. (1996) ‘Gradual retirement: lessons from and Family Life. London: Rivers Oram.
the Nordic countries and the Netherlands’, European Heyes, J. (1997) ‘Annualized hours and the “knock”: the
Journal of Industrial Relations, 2 (1): 55–67. organization of working time in a chemicals plant’,
Ditton, J. (1979) ‘Baking time’, Sociological Review, Work, Employment and Society, 11 (1): 65–81.
27 (1): 157–67. Hill, R. (2000) ‘New Labour Force Survey questions
Durand, M. and Martin, J. (2004) ‘The 35-hour week: on working hours’, Labour Market Trends, January:
portrait of a French exception’, OECD Observer, 244: 39–47.
10–12. Hochschild, A.R. (1997) The Time Bind: When Work
Duxbury, L. and Higgins, C. (2006) ‘Work-life balance Becomes Home and Home Becomes Work. New York:
in Canada: rhetoric versus reality’, in P. Blyton, Metropolitan Books.
B. Blunsdon, K. Reed and A. Dastmalchian, (eds) Holt, H. and Grainger, H. (2005) Results of the Second
Work-Life Integration: International Perspectives Flexible Working Employee Survey, Employment Rela-
on the Balancing of Multiple Roles. Basingstoke: tions Research Series No. 39, London: Department of
Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 82–112. Trade and Industry.
Ebbinghaus, B. (2006) Reforming Early Retirement in Houston, D. and Waumsley, J.A. (2003) Attitudes to
Europe, Japan and the USA. Oxford: Oxford University flexible working and family life. Bristol: Policy Press.
Press. Hyman, J. and Summers, J. (2004) ‘Lacking balance?
Edwards, P. K. and Scullion, H. (1982) The Social Work-life employment practices in the modern
Organisation of Industrial Conflict. Oxford: Blackwell. economy’, Personnel Review, 33 (4): 418–29.
EIRO (European Industrial Relations Observatory on- ILO (International Labor Organization) (2004) Yearbook
line) (2005) ‘Working time developments – 2004’, of Annual Statistics, Geneva: ILO.
http://www.eurofound.ie/2005/03. IMF (International Metalworkers’ Federation) (1997)
Fagnani, J. and Letablier, M-T. (2004) ‘Work and family Metalworkers and Working Time in the World,
life in balance: the impact of the 35-hour laws Geneva: International Metalworkers’ Federation.
in France’, Work, Employment and Society, 18 (3): Iskra-Golec, I., Folkard, S., Marek, T. and Noworol, C.
551–72. (1996) ‘Health, well-being and burnout of ICU nurses
Freyssinet, J. (1998) ‘France: a recurrent aim, repeated on 12- and 8-h shifts’, Work and Stress, 10 (3):
near-failures and a new law’, Transfer, 4/98: 641–56. 251–56.
Gennard, J. and Judge, G. (2005) Employee Relations, Johansson, G. (2002) ‘Work-life balance: the case of
4th edition. London: Chartered Institute of Personnel Sweden in the 1990s’, Social Science Information,
and Development. 41 (2): 303–17.
Glass, J.L. and Estes, S.B. (1997) ‘The family Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H.,
responsive workplace’, Annual Review of Sociology, Dix, G. and Oxenbridge, S. (2006) Inside the
23: 289–313. Workplace: Findings from the 2004 Employment
Green, F. (1997) ‘Union recognition and paid holiday Relations Survey. London: Routledge.
entitlement’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Lee, S. (2004) ‘Working-hour gaps: trends and issues’,
35 (2): 243–55. in J.C. Messenger (ed) Working Time and Workers’
Green, F. (2004) ‘Why has work effort become more Preferences in Industrialized Countries: Finding the
intense?’, Industrial Relations, 43 (4): 709–41. Balance. London: Routledge. pp. 29–59.
Haipeter, T. and Lehndorff, S. (2005) ‘Decentralized Loudoun, R. and Harley, B. (2001) ‘Industrial relations
bargaining of working time in the German automobile decentralization and the growth of 12 hour shifts
528 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in Australia’, Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (4): Roediger, D.R. and Foner, P.S. (1989) Our Own Time:
402–21. A History of American Labor and the Working Day.
Macan, T. H. (1994) ‘Time management: test of a London: Verso.
process model’, Journal of Applied Psychology, 79 (3): Schor, J.B. (1991) The Overworked American: The
381–91. Unexpected Decline of Leisure. New York: Harper
Marsh, C. (1991) Hours of Work of Women and Men in Books.
Britain. London: HMSO. Sparks, K., Cooper, C., Fried, Y. and Shirom, A. (1997)
McCann, D. (2005) Working Time Laws: A Global ‘The effects of hours on health: a meta-analytic
Perspective. Geneva: Internal Labor Organization. review’, Journal of Occupational and Organizational
Moss, P and O’Brien, M. (2006) International Review Psychology, 70 (4): 391–408.
of Leave Policies and Related Research 2006, Thompson, C.A., Beauvais, L.L. and Lyness, K.S. (1999)
Employment Relations Research Series No. 57, ‘When work-family benefits are not enough: the
London: Department of Trade and Industry. influence of work-family culture on benefit utilization,
Noon, M. and Blyton, P. (2007) The Realities of Work, organizational attachment and work-family conflict’,
3rd edition. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 54 (3): 392–415.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Trinczek, R. (2006) ‘Work-life balance and flexible
Development) (2005) Employment Outlook, Paris: work hours – the German experience’, in P. Blyton,
OECD. B. Blunsdon, K. Reed and A. Dastmalchian, (eds)
OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Work-Life Integration: International Perspectives
Development) (2006) Employment Outlook, Paris: on the Balancing of Multiple Roles. Basingstoke:
OECD. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 113–34.
Office for National Statistics (2006) Social Trends White, M., Hill, S., McGovern, P., Mills, C. and
36: 2006 edition. London: Office for National Smeaton, D. (2003) ‘“High-performance” manage-
Statistics. ment practices, working hours and work-life balance’,
Owen, J.D. (1979) Working Hours: An Economic British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41 (2): 175–95.
Analysis. Lexington, MA.: D.C. Heath. Wood, S.J., de Menezes, L.M. and Lasaosa, A. (2003)
Presser, H.B. and Gornick, J.C. (2005) ‘The female share ‘Family-friendly management in Great Britain: testing
of weekend employment: a study of 16 countries’, various perspectives’, Industrial Relations, 42 (2):
Monthly Labor Review, August: 41–53. 221–50.
28
Worker Well-Being
David Guest

In recent years, the outcomes of employment detail. There are then sections on job sat-
relations in advanced industrial societies have isfaction, job insecurity, and workload and
broadened, reflecting a number of cultural stress, which have been identified as key
and economic changes as well as changes indicators of work-related well-being. Finally,
in the make-up of the workforce, changes there is a consideration of the aspects of
in the kind of work that people do and employment relations and the employment
changes in the nature of the employment relationship that appear to support worker
relationship. One consequence of this broader well-being and some discussion of the
focus has been an increasing interest in implications for contemporary employment
worker well-being and a number of allied relations.
concepts such as work-related stress, job
satisfaction and even happiness. This broader
focus does not imply that the importance WHAT EXPLAINS THE GROWING
of the traditional substantive outcomes of
INTEREST IN WORKER WELL-BEING
employment relations has diminished. But
it does mean that in any comprehensive
IN EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS?
analysis of employment relations, these rather
The focus on a wider range of workers’
different outcomes merit specific attention.
outcomes of employment relations is shaped
This chapter will therefore explore worker
by a number of changes in the contexts in
well-being and related issues in the context
which employment relations is played out.
of employment relations. It starts by setting
out some of the issues that have influenced
the shift towards a concern for worker well-
The changing nature of
being as an outcome of employment relations.
the workforce
It briefly considers the implications of this
shift in emphasis for traditional pluralist The workforce has changed in a number
perspectives on employment relations. The of important ways in recent decades in all
concept of well-being is explored in some advanced industrial societies. Firstly, it is
530 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

better-educated. Secondly, it contains a large


The shift from collective
number of female workers. Thirdly, there is a
to individual deals
wider age spread. Fourthly, in some countries
and in some sectors in particular, there is a The decline in collective arrangements in
large ethnic mix. More generally, and despite many countries, captured in the UK through
some considerable inequalities, the workforce the data provided in the Workplace Employ-
has become more affluent. The changing ment Relations Surveys (Cully et al., 1999;
make-up of the workforce brings with it Kersley et al., 2006), has been widely noted.
a change in priorities among the potential However this does not mean the end of
outcomes of employment relations. Indeed, employment relations. Allied to the growing
it means we need to re-define ‘the worker’ concern for flexibility, deriving in part from
in employment relations from a stereotype the changing composition of the workforce,
of a blue-collar, semi-skilled, male, full-time there has been a growth in individual ‘deals’.
worker to a new stereotype of a public-sector, This has been captured in the concept of
professional, female and possibly part-time the psychological contract. Rousseau (2005)
worker. If we adjust our stereotype in this way, has argued that there has been a shift from
then it is easy to accept that the orientations what she terms collective and positional deals
and the priorities among work outcomes may to idiosyncratic or individual deals. Whereas
also have shifted. collective deals were typically highly visible
and often written, the idiosyncratic deals
are likely to be more informal, implicit and
The changing nature of work
based on a local arrangement between the
The changing make-up of the workforce is worker and her boss. There may therefore be
closely associated with the changing nature an understanding that someone can have an
of work. Over many years, employment in extended lunch break on two days of the week
manufacturing and the primary sector has to check on an elderly relative but that this will
been declining while work in the service be made up on other days with a shorter lunch
sector has been rapidly expanding. This has break. Someone else will want to arrange to
been accompanied by a reduction in the attend a college course and miss a day of
physical demands of work; even the majority work each week, but only in term-time. An
of jobs that remain in the manufacturing sector analysis of the working hours arrangements
are likely to be less physically demanding in many supermarkets will reveal dozens of
than in the past. For those with an interest different deals that suit both the many part-
in health and safety at work, this has meant time workers but also meet the needs of the
a change in focus from physical to mental store to ensure that that staff are present in
health and well-being. By the year 2000, appropriate numbers to match the varying
stress-related illnesses had become the second levels of customer demand. This recognition
most common cause of absence from work of the need to make a range of individual
in the UK (Jones et al., 2003). One of deals, even if there is a collectively agreed
the areas of work that has seen the most framework, reflects the growing priority given
rapid expansion, the helping professions to personal concerns and personal well-being.
such as teaching, nursing and social work, Despite the apparent decline in collective
has attracted particular concern because of arrangements, the growth in individual deals
the risk of what has become known as indicates that workers have not lost all their
burnout, manifested in emotional exhaustion power. This is illustrated by recognition of
and depersonalization (Schaufeli and Buunk, the need to offer a degree of flexibility
2003) which can lead to long-term stress- and consideration for workers’ concerns as
related absence from work. Stress and mental a basis for attracting and retaining the right
health are core features of the contemporary quality of worker. The growth of knowledge
concern for well-being at work. workers and the related concept of the
WORKER WELL-BEING 531

boundaryless career (Arthur and Rousseau, and heavily promoted by some governments,
1996) has resulted in debates about the ‘war there has been a considerable concern for a
for talent’. Much of this reflects a tight healthy life style. The concern for physical
labor market, or at least tight pockets in the and mental well-being is promoted as an
labor market, and one outcome is the choice end in itself but also has implications for
made by some knowledge workers to become management and control of health costs. In
either self-employed or to work on temporary so far as work is a central life interest, then
contracts to maintain their independence and workplaces are not immune from this trend.As
employability and, by extension, their well- a result, there has been much more concern for
being (Barley and Kunda, 2004; De Cuyper healthy eating at work, for bans on smoking in
et al., 2005). workplaces and for the provision of gyms and
health checks. All these developments reflect
recognition of the importance of promoting
The shift from protection of workers
or being seen to promote worker well-being
to promotion of good work
in the workplace.
The last decades of the twentieth century saw
the promotion of a European social program
to protect workers from the vagaries of the
labor market and exploitation by employers. WORKER OUTCOMES, WORKER
Indeed, despite the language of social part- WELL-BEING AND TRADITIONAL
nership, it was recognized that employers EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS
could not be trusted to act responsibly and
therefore that legislation was necessary. The The focus on well-being has emerged in
result has been a series of steps to promote a context where the traditional pluralist
equal opportunities, to ensure communication industrial relations has arguably given ground
and consultation, to limit working hours and in the face of the emphasis on human
to protect those on fixed term contracts. resource management and partnership and
More recently, the emphasis has begun to the greater management dominance of the
switch from protecting workers to promoting employment relationship allied to the increase
good work. The Lisbon meeting of the Council in the proportion of non-union workplaces.
of Europe in 2000 set as one of its long- However the decline of a pluralist emphasis
term aims the promotion of the quality of in industrial relations should not be taken to
work. Echoing this, the OECD in 2003 called imply a unity of interest or shared priorities for
for ‘more and better’ jobs. These recent the outcomes of contemporary employment
concerns for good work have strong echoes relations. This can be captured in an analysis
of the ‘quality of working life’ movement that of what might constitute these outcomes from
flourished in the early 1970s. This was an the perspective of employer and employee,
evidence-based approach to the promotion of illustrated in Table 28.1.
certain features of work. One illustration of Contemporary human resource policy and
this is the recent emphasis placed by the UK practice is largely geared towards achieving
Health and Safety Executive on specific steps the outcomes that reflect the employer’s per-
to improve well-being at work in an attempt spective. A key question is how far the pursuit
to reduce the rapid growth in stress-related of these employer outcomes is compatible
absence (HSE, 1999; 2003). with promotion of worker outcomes. This is
an issue I return to below.
A wider societal concern for What this analysis implies is that we can
conceive of a range of worker outcomes of
a healthy life-style
the contemporary employment relationship.
Outside the workplace, but serving also to cre- Firstly, there is what we can term the
ate more employment in the service economy, traditional issues associated with collective
532 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 28.1 Perspectives on the outcomes of contemporary


employment relations
Employer perspective Employee perspective
Employee flexibility Job security
Knowledge sharing/learning organization Knowledge/skill protection
Low absence Positive physical and mental health
Performance-related pay Fair/equitable pay
Low conflict/strike-free Fairness of treatment; trust
Achieve high performance targets Reasonable autonomy and workload
Retaining valued employees Employability/potential for mobility
Low accidents Low stress/manageable pressures
Hours that meet work requirements Hours that suit personal requirements
Organizational commitment Work-life balance

arrangements that address the terms and of attention is paid to fairness of treatment and
conditions of employment. These include maintenance of mutual trust. In short, there
job security, knowledge/skill protection, fair is more risk of violation of the psychological
treatment and reward and health and safety. contract (Conway and Briner, 2005). There
These are a set of long-standing concerns are also distinctive challenges at both the
that may have altered in character but which general establishment level and the more
continue to be important. Secondly, there are local boss-subordinate level in managing
issues that have recently gained more promi- the employment relationship to ensure an
nence and are more likely to be concerned with acceptable level of both performance and
worker well-being. These include work-life well-being. With this in mind, I turn to a closer
balance, flexibility of working arrangements, examination of the concept of well-being.
and autonomy and stress in the workplace. In
practice all these ‘new’ issues have always
been addressed to some extent in some THE NATURE OF WORKER
organizations. What is new is the changes in WELL-BEING
the wider context that have meant that these
issues receive a higher priority. The term ‘worker well-being’ is widely
Another implication of this change in and loosely used to describe a range of
emphasis is that employment relations possible outcomes. Danna and Griffin (1999)
become a more diffuse and complex activity. in a review of the literature define well-
If there is a shift from the transparent, being as ‘comprising the various life/non-
collective exchange covering substantive, work satisfactions enjoyed by individuals,
concrete and relatively easily monitored work-related satisfactions, and general health’
issues to a series of more implicit, local, (p. 358). Despite embracing health in the
idiosyncratic deals over less tangible and definition, they also distinguish it as ‘a sub-
less easily monitored issues, the control of component of well-being and comprises the
employment relations slips away from the combination of such mental/psychological
employment relations specialists. They can set indicators as affect, frustration and anxiety
the context and, to some extent the boundaries and such physical/physiological indicators as
of the employment relationship. But in a world blood pressure, heart conditions and general
where work-life balance and local flexibility physical health’ (p. 358). There is a risk
become important, much more emphasis is that these definitions can become circular
placed on the local manager to deal with these since the World Health Organization defines
issues, often on a one-to-one basis. These health as ‘a state of complete physical,
idiosyncratic arrangements, particularly if mental and social well-being and not merely
agreed in a context of constant turbulence and the absence of disease or infirmity’ (World
change, run all sorts of risks unless a great deal Health Organization, 1998, cited in Danna
WORKER WELL-BEING 533

and Griffin, op cit). By implication, health Danna and Griffin (1999) identify three
and well-being overlap. However Danna and main types of antecedent of work-related well-
Griffin also cite the well-known study by being. These are the work-setting, broadly
Steffy and Jones (1988) which revealed only a defined, the potential stressors in the specific
low association between subjective measures job a person does and individual personality
of well-being and more objective indicators of characteristics. Employment relations can
health. have an impact on the first two of these sets of
Possibly the most rigorous analysis of the factors. Personality is less clearly related and
concept of work-related well-being has been there is good evidence that a variable such as
provided by Warr, in a series of publications positive or negative affect – the tendency to
(see, for example, Warr, 1987; 1990; 2002). see the glass as half full or half empty – can
Specifically, he has sought to operationalize have an influence on satisfaction and other
and measure work-related well-being. He attitudes (Watson and Clark, 1984). Danna
views well-being as essentially psychological and Griffin also address the consequences
rather than physical and therefore concerned of well-being, suggesting that the pursuit of
more with feelings than with physical symp- well-being has implications for individuals,
toms, although he recognizes that there for organizations and for society. With respect
may be some association between them. to society, they cite the potential benefits
Warr acknowledges that the traditional way to society of policies at work that address
to measure psychological reactions to, or smoking, drug habits and obesity, all of which
feelings about, work is through a measure are increasingly included in workplace well-
of job satisfaction. He argues that well- being programs.
being needs to go beyond job satisfaction Economists have begun to take consider-
by additionally taking into account the level able interest in well-being both in the context
of mental arousal. This then provides three of work and more broadly in life as a whole
dimensions; satisfaction – dissatisfaction, (see, for example, Layard, 2005). In the
which he labels pleasure – displeasure; enthu- context of work, the measure they have often
siasm – depression and comfort – anxiety. used as an indicator of well-being is job
Enthusiasm combines high satisfaction and satisfaction (Blanchflower and Oswald, 1999)
high arousal and is likely to be associated while the broader societal indicator has been
with strong motivation and involvement. some measure of happiness or life satisfaction.
Depression combines dissatisfaction with low The factor that has sparked this interest is
arousal and is likely to be associated with the failure to find an association between
low effort and possibly boredom. Comfort increased affluence and increased satisfaction
combines satisfaction with low arousal while or happiness. In other words, a core element
anxiety combines dissatisfaction with high of classic economic theory does not appear to
arousal and may be linked to stress. work. Economists have discovered what many
Warr notes that well-being may be general organizational psychologists have argued for
or context-specific and that there is the a number of decades, namely that money has
possibility of spill-over from one domain only a very tenuous link to job satisfaction and
to another. Indeed, he cites the research happiness.
by Judge and Watanabe (1993) suggesting Researchers have been using a variety of
that work-related well-being and well-being measures to compare and to track well-being
in life as a whole mutually influence each at the societal level for a number of years.
other but that life well-being has a slightly A typical question would be ‘Taking all
stronger influence on work-related well-being things together, would you say you were very
than vice-versa. Despite this, there is good happy, fairly happy or not very happy?’ Such
evidence of some spillover from work-related questions have been asked regularly in the
well-being to life well-being (for example Eurobarometer surveys across the member
Roxburgh, 1996). countries of the European Union (EU).
534 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

There have also been major international and well-being at work in some context.
surveys across considerably more countries Helliwell’s (2003) analysis of international
(see, for example, Veenhoven, 1999). These work values in over 40 countries identifies key
studies broadly confirm that there is a factors likely to reduce happiness, although
difference in well-being and happiness the survey is likely to be unable to capture
between the poor and the affluent countries in more than a small number of these. The three
the world. But once countries enter the affluent work-related factors that are identified are
group, an increase in affluence ceases to have being unemployed, a sense of job insecurity
any impact on happiness. Within affluent and the level of national unemployment.
countries such as the US and UK, the rich We must be cautious in accepting these
generally report higher levels of happiness factors, all related to unemployment, as
than the poor; but as the country as a whole necessarily comprehensive. However what
becomes more affluent, the gap between they do indicate is that having work is
the rich and the poor largely remains. By important for general well-being, a point also
implication, an important basis for happiness strongly emphasized by Warr (1987).
is social comparison, a point reported in With this in mind, we return to the
many studies by social psychologists and more specific focus on well-being at work.
highlighted in particular in the work of Warr, (2002) identifies ten antecedents of
Marmot and his colleagues (Marmot, 2004). work-related well-being. They include several
How large the gap remains in the happiness of features of job design and in addition he cites
the more and less well-off within an affluent ‘availability of money’, ‘physical security’,
country is a subject of debate. Veenhoven ‘environmental clarity’, ‘supportive supervi-
(2005) has produced longitudinal data to sion’ and ‘valued social position’ (p. 6). As
suggest that the size of the gap in happiness we have indicated, work-related well-being
has been slowly declining in many countries. can cover a wide range of issues. To explore
If income levels do not easily explain the topic in more depth, we will select three
happiness in advanced industrial countries, for particular attention. First, we will consider
what does? Research in America (Helliwell, the nature and antecedents of job satisfaction,
2003), based on large-scale national surveys since this comes closest to the general measure
of life satisfaction, and cited by Layard (2005, of work-related well-being. Secondly, we will
p. 63), highlights five factors, in order of explore job insecurity since, as we have noted
importance. These are: above, this appears to be a key element
affecting wider well-being. Thirdly, we will
• family relationships; explore the nature and antecedents of work-
• financial situation; related stress since this has become a major
• work; source of absence and shows some relation to
• community and health which, as we have seen, is a core com-
• friends and health. ponent of general well-being. In each case, we
will explore the evidence, using comparative
Personal freedom and personal values are research where possible, and consider the role
also important. Surveys in Europe reveal that employment relations, broadly defined,
broadly similar results (Di Tella et al., plays in shaping the level of job satisfaction,
2001). Researchers such as Veenhoven also job insecurity and work-related stress.
place some emphasis on cultural values
in explaining national differences in life
satisfaction. For example, there are consis- JOB SATISFACTION AND THE ROLE
tent differences between the happier north OF EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS
European countries and the less happy
southern European countries around the Job satisfaction is typically defined as ‘an
Mediterranean. These findings place work emotional state resulting from one’s appraisal
WORKER WELL-BEING 535

of the job’ (Arvey, 2004, p.200). It is and priorities and in particular whether work
recognized as having a number of facets is a central life interest. Since we know that
which are often divided into intrinsic and there are variations in this, we are not able to
extrinsic categories. The intrinsic elements state with any certainty how much influence
are concerned with the content of the job it is likely to have and, as noted above, the
while the extrinsic are concerned with the influence process is likely to be two-way.
context including the social context, the Job satisfaction also has to take into account
working conditions and the rewards. There are individual differences in personality. For this
many well-validated scales that measure these and other reasons, economists who have
various facets and also single more global become interested in job satisfaction as one
measures of job satisfaction based on either indicator of well-being argue that it is essential
a single item or a small number of items to focus as far as possible on longitudinal data
asking about general job satisfaction. Reviews sets that can monitor changes over time after
of the evidence (see, for example, Wanous allowing for these influences.
et al., 1997) suggest that a global measure, and The focus of research on job satisfaction has
even a single item, serves almost as well as a been changing. In the past, much of the interest
more sophisticated and more lengthy scale. lay in the association between satisfaction
However Wanous et al. also conclude that and outcomes of interest to organizations.
where feasible, it is preferable to use a scale These included job performance, absence and
rather than a single item. labor turnover. There have been interesting
The theory of job satisfaction is potentially debates about cause and effect, particularly in
important in this context. There are four relation to the link between job satisfaction
perspectives that are worth highlighting. and performance at firm level. In one of
Person-environment fit theory suggests that the most convincing longitudinal studies,
if you can find a job that matches what which has relevance to the current context,
you want, then you will be satisfied. Need it was found that the evidence supported
fulfillment theory suggests that if you have the view that performance shapes satisfaction
a job that fulfils a set of pre-determined needs at least as strongly as the alternative and
or requirements, then you will be satisfied. more traditional assumption that satisfaction
Expectations theories suggest that if a job influences performance (Schneider et al.,
meets your expectations, then you will be sat- 2003). By implication, and leaving aside any
isfied. Finally, effort-reward models suggest role for employment relations, working in a
that when your outputs or gains are greater high performance organization is an important
than your inputs, then satisfaction will occur source of satisfaction. The focus on well-
and the greater the advantage of outputs over being shifts the debate from a concern for
inputs, the greater the satisfaction. Concepts job satisfaction as a means to an end to job
such as expectations, inputs and outputs can satisfaction as an end in itself. This in turn
be socially determined and are potentially leads to an interest in its antecedents.
dynamic. Therefore social comparisons need A number of international studies provide
to be taken into account, resulting in a comparative information on job satisfaction
form of dynamic discrepancy model whereby and on trends in job satisfaction. Within
the gap between what you have and what Europe, the Eurobarometer provides a regular
you expect to have is constantly changing, source of information for EU countries. How-
usually in the light of rising expectations. This ever, probably the largest international data set
can help to account for the failure to show is the International Social Survey Programme
an association between rising affluence and (ISSP) which collects data from 21 countries
higher job satisfaction. and has been conducted approximately every
Job satisfaction is a component of life five years since 1985. The content varies
satisfaction. How important a component is from survey to survey, but in both 1989
likely to depend on individual orientations and 1997 there was a single seven-point
536 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

question asking for overall job satisfaction. long-term American data shows a decline
The 1997 survey provides information from in job satisfaction from the mid-1970s to
over 15,000 workers across 21 countries. This the early 1990s followed by a reversal in
material has been analyzed by Sousa-Poza and the trend in the decade up to 2002. In
Sousa-Poza (2000). There are a number of contrast, the UK data show a decline in job
key findings that they highlight. Firstly, in all satisfaction throughout the 1990s. A similar
countries, the great majority of workers report pattern has been found in Germany. Most
that with varying degrees of enthusiasm, other European countries show a slight decline
they are satisfied with their jobs. Those in job satisfaction during the 1990s but
reporting dissatisfaction range from 4 per cent the results vary a little across the different
in Switzerland to 16 per cent in Russia. surveys. Given the rise in affluence in most
Secondly, while the East European countries advanced industrial countries in the decades
reported some of the lowest levels of job up to 2000, how are we to explain the apparent
satisfaction, the link between national wealth decline in job satisfaction?
and satisfaction was weak. Thus Denmark Green (2006), in his excellent analysis of
reported the highest level of satisfaction, UK trends, concludes that half the decline
the US ranked seventh, Great Britain ranked in job satisfaction during the 1990s can
fifteenth and Japan ranked nineteenth. Thirdly, be accounted for by the decline in task
in making comparisons between 1989 and discretion, a further third is accounted for by
1997, they report a clear decline in job satis- increased intensification and associated effort
faction in West Germany and in Norway and and a small amount is accounted for by a
a slight decline in the US, while only Holland decreased fit between job demands and skills.
shows a clear increase in job satisfaction over No other personal or structural variables had
this period. In most other countries, there was any impact including union membership, bar-
little or no change. Finally, Sousa-Poza and gaining arrangements or size of establishment.
Sousa-Poza explored the factors associated On this basis, we cannot seek an explanation
with job satisfaction which might help to by associating the decline in job satisfaction
explain some of the variations. They found with a decline in trade union influence in
that the largest proportion of the variation the workplace. Germany shares with Britain
was explained by having an interesting job a decline in job satisfaction and Green has
followed by good relations with management. reported an attempt to determine whether the
These were followed by a high income and causes are the same (Green and Tsiksianis,
working independently. Fifth was having an 2005). In practice, the different data sets make
exhausting job, which was particularly likely any direct comparison impossible. The key
to reduce job satisfaction. Job security has results are that the British data confirm the
a very modest positive association with job role of reduced autonomy and increased effort
satisfaction. There were some interesting while the German data do not provide any
national variations. For example, in the US significant explanation. However this may be
and Great Britain, a high income had no partly because the German longitudinal data
significant association with job satisfaction do not include measures of discretion and
while in Russia it was as important as effort.
interesting work. The evidence reported by Green indicates
Some of the key trends in job satisfac- no association between any standard employ-
tion have been analyzed by Green (2006). ment relations indicators and job satisfaction.
He reports that according to the European A wider body of research has consistently
Community Household Survey, no country failed to find any evidence of an association
reported higher satisfaction in the year 2000 between a trade union presence and collective
than in the early 1990s. Looking at survey bargaining and job satisfaction. Some of
data from within certain countries rather this research goes further in suggesting that
than the comparative data, he notes that the union membership is associated with greater
WORKER WELL-BEING 537

job dissatisfaction. There is a logic to this to the organization were very highly inter-
if we assume that dissatisfied workers are correlated and emerged from factor analysis
more likely to look to union membership as a single factor. They therefore combined
to provide them with a voice (Freeman and them into a single measure. They then
Medoff, 1984). However it would only apply explored the presumed antecedents of this
in the short term, since unions should either broad satisfaction measure in both the public
address the source of dissatisfaction or, by and private sectors using the data collected
implication, fail to provide an effective voice. from managers. Responses on the four job
Analysis of the 1998 Workplace Employee satisfaction items were broadly similar in the
Relations Survey by Guest and Conway public and private sectors with the exception
(2004a) and by Bryson et al. (2004) confirm of the item on sense of achievement which
that using conventional bivariate analysis was slightly higher in the public sector.
and regressions with a range of controls, However the antecedents in the two sectors
union members report higher dissatisfaction are rather different. In the public sector, higher
whether we consider job satisfaction as a satisfaction/commitment was associated with
whole or separate pay satisfaction from an increase in employee involvement over the
other factors. Bryson et al. also consider past three years but it was negatively associ-
the possibility that unions provide a voice ated with a more sophisticated HR strategy. In
for dissatisfied workers by comparing union the private sector, it was positively associated
activists and non-active members and find with the presence of more HR practices, with
no evidence of greater dissatisfaction among a more sophisticated HR strategy, with a
activists. By implication, dissatisfaction is stronger consultative climate and with the
not leading to voice or different degrees of greater influence of the consultative process
union membership and involvement. Bryson over decisions. However in both the private
et al. extend their analysis, using a series and public sectors, job satisfaction was lower
of highly complex statistics, to argue that where trade union density was higher. To add
the association between union membership a level of complexity, trade union density
and job dissatisfaction is not a causal link was positively associated with the presence
but, rather, that both are caused by some of more HR practices in both the public and
other unexplained variable. In other words, private sectors, independently of the size of
the factors that cause people to belong to trade establishment. What these findings indicate is
unions also cause them to be more dissatisfied. that employee involvement, perhaps through
Despite this, the negative association remains consultation and not necessarily with trade
and there is no evidence that unions contribute union representatives, is associated with
to well-being, as defined by satisfaction. higher satisfaction.
Leaving aside the specific role of trade Cully et al. (1999) undertook a some-
unions, another step in the analysis is to what similar analysis but using only the
explore other aspects of employment relations responses of the non-managerial employees.
that might be associated with worker satisfac- These revealed that satisfaction was strongly
tion and well-being. One of the best sources associated with higher levels of discretion and
for this in Great Britain is the Workplace autonomy at work and where managers are
Employee Relations Survey. The 1998 survey perceived to be good at involving employees,
(Cully et al., 1999) collected information where they show an understanding of family
about employment relations practices from responsibilities and where they treat workers
a management representative and collected fairly. This again reinforces the importance
information on employee attitudes from about of job autonomy, an understanding and
28,000 workers. This included data on job supportive management, opportunities for
satisfaction. An analysis by Guest et al. development and fair treatment. These all lie
(2000) found that the four items on job at the heart of what is often advocated as good
satisfaction and the three on commitment contemporary employee relations and are
538 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

supported by the wider and well-established of national unemployment, most research on


literature on the antecedents of job satisfaction well-being focuses on subjective insecurity.
(Spector, 1997; Wright and Boswell, 2002). Job insecurity can then be defined as ‘the sub-
In summary, job satisfaction is a core jectively perceived likelihood of involuntary
indicator of work-related well-being. Despite job loss’(Sverke et al., 2005). Standing (1999)
rising affluence, which has been one of has reminded us that there are a wide variety
the traditional goals of the trade union of sources of employment-related insecurity
movement, job satisfaction has been static including income insecurity and working time
or even declining in recent years in many insecurity. Job loss incorporates many of these
advanced industrial countries. One major other aspects of insecurity and its impact on
reason for this appears to be that pay and well-being appears to be the result of a sense
extrinsic rewards are not closely associated of helplessness and loss of control. It can also
with this core dimension of work-related well- be exacerbated by uncertainty and there are
being in advanced industrial societies. This a number of studies of what is often termed
assertion requires some qualification; high the ‘survivor syndrome’ that have shown that
earners tend to be more satisfied than low those who remain in an organization after
earners. But as the earnings of both groups redundancies can also report a loss of well-
improve, neither becomes more satisfied. being. For this reason, De Witte (2005) argues
Instead, job satisfaction appears to be more that we need to consider both quantitative
closely associated with the job content and and qualitative job loss in any analysis of
in particular the demands of the job, the job insecurity. The topic has been widely
scope to develop and use knowledge and studied and there have been a number of books
skills and the degree of involvement and bringing together much of the evidence (see
autonomy. There are doubts about whether Burchell et al., 2002; De Witte, 2005; Hartley
these have been improving in recent years. et al., 1991; and Heery and Salmon, 2000).
There is no evidence that trade unions are The impact of job loss or the fear of job
associated with job satisfaction, perhaps as an loss on various indicators of well-being is
inevitable consequence of their role in raising widely supported in the literature, as Sverke
awareness of sources of dissatisfaction and et al. (2002) confirm through a meta-analysis
in raising expectations. On the other hand, of existing research. Much of the research
a work climate that encourages participation undertaken by Warr and his colleagues
and involvement and a work setting where (Warr, 1987) confirms that the experience of
high commitment HR practices are applied is unemployment is associated with significantly
associated with higher job satisfaction. These reduced well-being, measured on standard
findings are very much in line both with Warr’s scales of mental health. There is also some
review of the antecedents of work-related indication that as uncertainty about possible
well-being and with what is often advocated job loss extends over time; well-being con-
as best practice contemporary employment tinues to decline (Van den Berg and Masi,
relations. 2005). This is confirmed by Roskies and
Louis-Guerin (1990) who support a broader
definition of insecurity and report that the
JOB INSECURITY long term prospect of job loss, demotion and
poorer working conditions are all associated
Helliwell’s (2003) analysis of factors asso- with reduced well-being.
ciated with lower happiness highlighted the Objective indicators of job insecurity such
importance of unemployment and the fear of as the level of national unemployment or the
job loss. In other words, job insecurity appears proportion of workers on various types of
to be a key factor associated with well-being temporary contract are relatively easy to pro-
at work and more widely in life. Despite the duce on a comparative and longitudinal basis.
emphasis placed by Helliwell on the level Subjective indicators require comparative
WORKER WELL-BEING 539

attitude survey data, and this is harder to suggests that the concept of social support
come by. One source of evidence cited by provides a useful analytic framework. There
Burchell (2002) is the 1996 European Survey are then a series of questions about the type of
of Working Conditions which asked people support and the source of support.Anumber of
to respond yes or no to the statement ‘You studies of job insecurity also use Hirschman’s
have a secure job’. Across the 15 members (1970) exit, voice and loyalty model as a
of the European Union, an average of 70 framework within which to explore these
per cent said ‘Yes’. This ranged from 85 issues.
per cent in Luxembourg, 83 per cent in Research evidence from Finland (Natti
Denmark and 73 per cent in the UK to et al., 2005) and The Netherlands (Steijn,
59 per cent in Germany, 61 per cent in 2005) confirms the importance of information
France, 63 per cent in Portugal and, somewhat and notes the increase in information-seeking
surprisingly, 64 per cent in Sweden. Green that occurs as job insecurity and the possible
(2006) cites evidence from the International threat of job loss increases. In the Dutch
Social Survey Programme. In 1989 and 1997 study, workers tended to turn to the union in
it asked whether respondents agreed that their particular for information and advice. A study
job was secure. Insecurity can be measured by Isaksson et al. (2005) of downsizing
by the proportion who disagreed that their in a large retail store, in which staff with
job was secure. In 1997 this ranged from different outcomes (stay, retire, leave and
28 per cent in the UK to 12 per cent in unemployed, leave and find another job) were
Norway. Job insecurity had increased during compared. The results confirm that the social
the period between 1989 and 1997 in six support and advice of the union was valued.
of the eight countries covered, including However those who obtained employment
the UK, the US, West Germany and The were no more positive about the union role
Netherlands. It had decreased in Israel and than those who remained unemployed; indeed
Norway. The comparative evidence from satisfaction with the union among both groups
Green and the more recent UK evidence was rather low. Although the union adopted a
from skills surveys and elsewhere suggests collaborative role in managing the process, it
that subjective perceptions of insecurity quite did not appear to have been thanked for this
closely track the levels of unemployment in or to have enhanced the levels of commitment
most countries. Given the strong evidence that among its members as a result. A Swedish
insecurity is associated with a lower score on study of attitudes towards the union in the
indices of job satisfaction, mental health and context of downsizing (Hellgren et al., 2005)
well-being, for those experiencing chronic found that almost irrespective of the union
job insecurity and uncertainty, this must be role, the experience was likely to damage
a matter of concern. attitudes towards the union as well as the
While there has been extensive research on organization among those who stay as well
redundancies and the role of trade unions in as among those who lose their jobs.
the redundancy process, there has been much Evidence from another Dutch study
less research linking unions and the wider (Goslinga, 2005) found that faced with job
issue of job insecurity. This point is noted insecurity, workers preferred individual to
by De Witte (2005) who observes that ‘Since collective help from the union. In other
unions have a crucial position in defending words they wanted advice and support that
the interests of workers, it is remarkable that helped them to cope with and ameliorate
so little research has been devoted to analyse or address their personal situation; but they
whether unions can reduce job insecurity accepted the circumstances and did not want
or mitigate its negative consequences for to support collective action to change it. The
individuals (and organizations)’. (op cit p. 3). implication of the analysis is that the first
His edited book is devoted to an analysis reaction of a trade union is to try to change
of this issue. More broadly, Wickert (2002) the situation. In practice this may just prolong
540 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

the uncertainty which constitutes one of more likely, in Hirschman’s (1970) terms,
the more negative aspects of job insecurity. to lead to loyalty. Specifically, in a context
However there is strong evidence that union where there was uncertainty and the strong
involvement in the change process has possibility of job loss, union members tended
positive consequences. Firstly, as the study to stay with the organization while non-
by Hellgren et al. (2005) suggests, potentially union members chose exit. Although this
negative attitudes towards the union were study did not directly address well-being, it
considerably ameliorated if there was scope suggests that in the context of job insecurity,
for extensive employee involvement and a cooperative climate may provide some
participation in the process, so that workers benefits for workers, union and employer.
felt they were kept fully informed about what
was happening and why and were given a
chance to express views and influence the WORK-RELATED STRESS
process. In other words, voice has a positive AND WELL-BEING
impact on attitudes towards the union, even
if it cannot prevent job loss. Secondly, the There is a longstanding tradition of union
evidence from research on participation involvement in the promotion of health and
reported by Heller et al. (1998) confirms safety at work in most countries. In the UK,
the positive impact of participation in the the Health and Safety at Work Act, 1974,
process. Thirdly, a detailed study by Parker enshrined this in legislation and managers
et al. (1997) found that those who reported have been required to consult with trade
an opportunity for involvement and who union representatives, where they are present,
felt well-informed reported higher levels of about health and safety. Since an extension
well-being following workforce reductions. to the act in 1996, managers have been
The body of evidence supports the case that required also to consult with non-union
participation and involvement in decisions representatives or directly with the workforce.
affecting workforce reductions, as a specific The 1998 UK Workplace Employee Relations
and identifiable example of job insecurity, Survey (Cully et al., 1999) reported that only
has a positive impact on the well-being of 2 per cent of managers admitted that they
both those who leave the organization and failed to consult or inform workers in any way
those who stay. The research evidence quite about these issues. They were more likely to
consistently shows that although the process negotiate on health and safety with non-union
of participation may be collective, and the representatives and more likely to do nothing
union needs to be heavily involved, what by way of involving representatives where
workers want is support at an individual level there was a union presence. The same survey
rather than any idea of collective action. revealed that 64 per cent of representatives
This confirms the social support model. That had dealt with a health and safety issue in the
support will be informational but it may also past year, more than any other topic, but it
include more emotional support to help to was only listed as the third most important
cope with the experience. This extends to the issue they dealt with after fairness of treatment
survivors. There is also a suggestion that the of employees by management and aspects of
wider societal context will be able to buffer employment security.
the effects of potential job loss. Therefore In the past, the main focus of attention
these effects should be less in a country in the arena of workplace health and safety
like Sweden with its strong social security was the prevention of accidents and ill-
system. A comparative study of Sweden and ness in the context of difficult and often
Canada (van den Berg and Masi, 2005) failed unsatisfactory physical working conditions.
to support this. However what they did find However the nature of work-related illness
was that a co-operative industrial relations has changed along with the changing nature
climate, with a strong union involvement was of work and in the past decade, stress-related
WORKER WELL-BEING 541

illnesses have begun to dominate. These the longest hours, Greece and Australia, show
often ‘invisible’ illnesses present distinctive reductions from 1990 to 1938 and 1853 to
challenges for employment relations and 1814 respectively. In this context, the working
indeed for researchers who have for many hours in the UK, down from 1713 to 1673
years studied the evidence for a link between and the USA, down from 1819 to 1792,
stress, particularly work-related stress and look relatively modest. However they are
illness (for a brief review, see Cooper et al., still some distance from West Germany on
2001). 1429 and Norway on 1337 average annual
The importance of the growing problem of hours in 2004. We need to be cautious about
work-related stress, and its link to well-being these figures since they can hide considerable
and absence, as well as the soaring health-care variations and leave open the possibility that a
costs associated with stress-related problems, sizeable minority are still working extremely
has resulted in work-related stress becoming long hours. They can also be distorted by the
a priority issue for the UK Health and proportion of part-time workers.
Safety Executive which has produced a set of Shorter hours may be compensated by
management standards in an effort to limit the more intense working. The evidence amassed
scale of the problem (Cousins et al., 2004). by Green is convincing in demonstrating
These standards are evidence-based and have that subjective reports of effort levels have
at their centre the demand – control model of increased over a number of years in the UK.
stress developed by Karasek (Karasek, 1979; The comparative EU data using standard
Karasek and Theorell, 1990). This proposes questions about working at high speed and
that stress is likely to be at its highest among working to tight deadlines also show a rise
those who face high demands over which they between 1991 and 2000 across all countries.
have little control. Interestingly, in a number of countries,
Both work demands and control over including the UK, there is some indication
work are traditional issues at the heart of that this increase has slowed or even reversed
employment relations. Work demands are more recently, though it is too early to tell
closely allied to the concern about ‘a fair whether this is a temporary phenomenon or
day’s work for a fair day’s pay’ that has an indication of some sort of peak of input.
formed the core of the traditional effort- In 2000, the countries reporting the highest
reward bargain, while control is central to levels of intensity of work were Sweden,
the traditions of craft and professional jobs. Finland and the Netherlands while workers
Green (2006) has brought these two issues in Spain and Portugal reported the lowest. In
together in his analysis of contemporary work, the UK, despite a large jump between 1990
focusing on increases in effort and work and 1996, by 2000 the levels of intensity of
intensification and reductions in autonomy at effort were close to the EU average and the
work. Intensification can be operationalized UK ranked fifth equal with Austria (Green,
in two ways, namely though increases in op cit p. 60).
working hours and through working harder There is very limited evidence linking
during each hour at work. intensity of work to employment relations.
The evidence on working hours does not at Green reports that the UK 2001 Skills Survey
first sight support the case for intensification. found no link between work intensity and
Throughout the advanced industrial world, union representation. On the other hand,
average working hours have been coming Green and McIntosh (2001) found that in
down. The figures cited by Green (op cit the early 1990s work intensification was
p. 46) show that comparing 1983 and 2004, greatest in those EU countries which saw
hours have reduced everywhere. Korea, the the greatest decline in union membership.
highest with an annual average of 2390 hours In contrast Gallie (2005) reports that union
in 2004 has nevertheless come down from membership was associated with higher
2734 in 1983. The other two countries with reported levels of work pressure across a
542 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

number of European countries and that the affects health and well-being more generally,
association had grown stronger between 1996 he found in the Whitehall studies that control
and 2001. The picture is therefore rather mattered rather more than demand. This fits
confused and any associations are open to with the notion that people may work long
a variety of interpretations (Gallie, 2005, and hard and not experience too much stress
p. 363). if they are in control and choose to work this
The second dimension in the demand – way. The problem becomes greater when the
control model concerns the level of discretion demand lies outside their control.
or control over work. Some of the most Although it seems plausible that trade
compelling work on the importance of control, unions should help to limit the challenge to
allied to level in the organizational hierarchy, workers’ discretion, the evidence that they
has been produced by Marmot (2004) and his have done so is hard to find. While they have
colleagues in what are known as the Whitehall traditionally been more likely to represent
I and II studies. These are longitudinal studies those lower grade workers who have less con-
of large samples of UK civil servants and trol, some of the more powerful contemporary
they show a clear association between position unions, allied to crafts or professions have
in the organizational hierarchy and both among their objectives the maintenance of
objective and subjective indicators of level professional control and autonomy and pro-
of control and, in turn, a link between these tection of status differentials. Unions outside
and all forms of illness as well as longevity. Scandinavia have also tended to be suspicious
In other words, those employed in low status of job redesign programs that could increase
positions, with less control over their work, local control. One response of the unions is
are more likely to be ill in both the short and likely to be to ensure that if job demands
the long term. increase, workloads remain reasonable and
The civil service may be an extreme employees are trained to meet these demands.
example of hierarchy and there has been some Despite union reservations, there is some
discussion – though rather less evidence – evidence that increased control over the
about reductions in hierarchy and increased job through job redesign can reduce stress
autonomy at lower levels, allied to the impor- and illness at work. There is also evidence
tance of providing a flexible, customized that worker participation can increase the
service. However, as Green (2006) again sense of control at work (Cooper et al.,
illustrates, the European evidence, based on 2001). The 1998 UK Workplace Employee
Europe-wide data from 1996 and 2000, shows Relations Survey (Cully et al., 1999) found
that the level of discretion at work appears an association between influence in the job
to be declining across Europe. Indeed, during and experience of participation in decision-
this short period it declined in 11 of the making across all levels of worker.
15 countries, with Portugal, Belgium and the The employment relations context can also
UK leading the way. Only Germany, Austria, be important in other ways. The Management
the Netherlands and Sweden bucked the trend. Standards promulgated by the UK Health
Green (2006, p. 103) also draws attention to and Safety Executive emphasize a number
a direct comparison of rather better quality of areas that require attention. In addition to
data between Finland and the UK. It shows demand and control, these include support,
that over a number of years, discretion in the relationships at work, role clarity, change
UK has consistently declined while in Finland management and an organizational culture
it has consistently increased. The decline in reflecting fairness and openness. The standard
discretion is therefore not an inevitable trend. set for the first three, demands, control and
In the UK, the decline was sharpest among support, have been set at 85 per cent. In
professional workers. Although Marmot cites other words, when staff are surveyed, at least
data from the US and Sweden that indicates 85 per cent should provide a positive response.
that the interaction of job demand and control This level was determined on the basis of
WORKER WELL-BEING 543

a large-scale UK study of stress at work greatest. Set against this, the ‘new’ industrial
(Smith, 2001) which concluded that just over relations may be more effective in addressing
20 per cent of the working population reported some of these concerns. The study by Guest
very or extremely high levels of stress at work. and Conway suggests that the presence of
The aim was to get below this level. high commitment HRM is associated with
A survey in 2004 of a random sample of a higher quality workplace, where there is
1000 UK workers explored both the level of less intensification, more discretion and less
these standards and some of the antecedents stress. There is also evidence from this and
(Guest and Conway, 2004). Very similar other research, that higher levels of workers’
to the larger sample of Smith, they found participation in decision-making can result
that 21 per cent reported that their job was in higher levels of perceived influence and
very or extremely stressful. With respect to control and consequently in lower levels of
the management standards, they found that, work-related stress.
taking the average response of two items
covering each of the standards, 42 per cent
were uncomfortable with the demands of
their job and 34 per cent reported low levels DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS:
of control. 26 per cent said they did not WORKER WELL-BEING IN THE
receive much support from their supervisor CONTEXT OF THE ‘OLD’ AND ‘NEW’
though only 11 per cent said they did not EMPLOYMENT RELATIONS
receive the help and support they needed
from work colleagues. In other words, the This chapter has focused on workers as
results fall well short of the HSE standard stakeholders in employment relations and
of 85 per cent positive responses. Those on outcomes associated with workers’ well-
scoring higher on the management standards being. It has explained and charted the
and therefore reporting a higher quality of growing interest in work-related well-being
workplace also reported much lower levels and has explored the levels of well-being
of stress. The presence of a high quality and some of the determinants of well-
workplace was, in turn, associated with more being by focusing on job satisfaction, job
high commitment HRM practices in place insecurity and work-related stress. Despite
and more flexible employment practices; but this growing interest, there is little evidence
it was also less likely to be reported by of improvements in well-being.
union members. Those working longer hours In an earlier section, the potentially compet-
reported a poorer quality of workplace and ing goals of employers and workers under the
higher levels of stress. ‘new’employment relations were highlighted.
In summary, stress at work and stress- This review has revealed areas of persisting
related illnesses are manifestations of low conflict which can restrict improvements in
levels of work-related well-being. They are workers’ well-being. In particular, the search
provoked in particular by high demands, low for efficiency through labor force reductions
discretion and low social support. There is and the intensification of work alongside
little evidence that traditional employment reductions in autonomy are associated with
relations has done much to address this aspect lower satisfaction and higher work-related
of worker well-being. For example, unions stress.
have become less effective than in the past Set against these areas of conflicting inter-
in limiting workload or maintaining control. ests, there is evidence of greater alignment
In the UK, the most powerful trade unions where high commitment human resource
today are probably those in the public sector practices are in place. Patterson et al. (1997)
representing professional groups; yet it is showed an association between the greater use
among these workers that the loss of perceived of these practices and employee satisfaction in
discretion and control has recently been UK manufacturing firms. Guest (2002) using
544 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

large UK data sets reported an association reductions may hide the indirect but much
between a range of specific practices, notably more positive role played by the unions at a
those allied to job design, involvement and higher level in promoting well-being at work.
work-life balance and both work and life For example, as social partners in Europe,
satisfaction. Wright and Boswell (2002) and they have promoted pan-European legislation
Wright et al. (2005) review literature showing to protect and advance aspects of well-being.
a link between greater use of human resource Through processes of co-determination, con-
practices and more positive attitudes among sultation and communication, they can help
workers and between these practices and to safeguard aspects of well-being. There is
attitudes and outcomes such as lower absence scope to go further in promoting the aim
and labor turnover. One of the few negative of ‘more and better’ jobs; but as Leonard
findings is reported by Ramsay et al. (2000), (2005) observes, the processes of concerted
who find some indication that certain HR action between the social partners at national
practices may be associated with higher level in the EU are currently in a state of
stress. However Appelbaum et al. (2000) considerable flux.
explicitly considered this in their study of The studies cited in this chapter illustrate
US manufacturing workers and found no how the unions help to promote dialogue
evidence to support it. and involvement in workforce reductions;
These results based on studies of human and the processes of information sharing and
resource management highlight the potential involvement helped to mitigate some of the
for mutual gains. They are very much in negative effects. There is also some evidence
line with the findings of Green and others that a union presence is associated with greater
who show the negative effects of reducing adoption of high involvement human resource
autonomy. Despite the potential for mutual practices which, in turn, have been associated
gains, the evidence from the UK Workplace with higher levels of well-being. We should
Employee Relations Survey and other sources therefore be careful not to under-estimate
(Cully et al., 1999) shows that relatively few the influence of trade unions on workers’
organizations are seeking to implement these well-being.
practices on a large scale; and Guest and In summary, processes of direct partici-
Peccei (2001) find that even in contexts where pation and involvement, a sense of personal
there has been some move towards partnership control and autonomy, and clear supervisory
working, the balance of advantage tends to and organizational support, reflected in the
lie very much with management. To date, organizational climate, are all associated with
therefore, there is little evidence that a mutual higher job satisfaction, higher levels of job
gains model is gaining ground as a basis for security and lower levels of stress. High
promoting workers’ well-being. commitment human resource management
In the past, trade unions have made a major appears to support these practices, which
contribution to the improvement of working appear to have a similar association with
conditions and to the health of workers. well-being in union and non-union settings.
However, there is little direct evidence There is a risk that given a choice, most
that the traditional institutions of industrial managers will prefer not to deal with trade
relations have made a marked contribution unions and their representatives; and the
to contemporary workers’ well-being, largely drift away from union membership suggests
because very little research has explored that unions will face major challenges in
this relationship. The absence of evidence gaining and retaining the commitment of
is largely the result of research directly the next generation of workers. Given the
exploring this relationship. Furthermore the pressures outlined at the start of this chapter,
rather gloomy picture that emerges about contemporary employment relations is likely
unions and job satisfaction and commitment to be increasingly concerned with workers’
to the union in the context of labor force well-being. The evidence presented here
WORKER WELL-BEING 545

confirms that managers, faced with a wide Danna, K. and Griffin, R. (1999) Health and well-being
range of competitive challenges, may be in the workplace: a review and synthesis of the
tempted to give a relatively low priority to literature. Journal of Management, 25: 357–84.
workers’ well-being unless it can be clearly De Cuyper, N., Isaksson, K. and De Witte, H. (eds)
demonstrated that it is in their best interest to (2005) Employment contracts and well-being among
European workers. Aldershot, Hants: Ashgate.
promote it. This creates both an opportunity
Di Tella, R., MacCullough, R. and Oswald, A.
and a threat for trade unions; an opportunity
(2001) Preferences over inflation and unemployment:
if they can successfully promote well-being Evidence from surveys of happiness. American
and at the same time demonstrate their value Economic Review, 91: 335–41.
to employees; and a threat if they are unable De Witte, H. (ed.) (2005). Job insecurity, union
to do so. Addressing worker well-being will involvement and union activism. Aldershot: Ashgate.
be one of the challenges facing the social Freeman, R. and Medoff, J. (1984) What do unions do?
partners as they seek to meet the interests of New York: Basic Books.
both the organization and the workforce in the Gallie, D. (2005) Work pressure in Europe 1996–2001:
future. Trends and determinants. British Journal of Industrial
Relations, 43: 351–75.
Goslinga, S. (2005) Job insecurity, union participation
and the need for (new) union services. In H. De Witte
REFERENCES (ed.) Job insecurity, union involvement and union
activism. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 81–96.
Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P. and Kalleberg, A. Green, F. (2006) Demanding work. Princeton: Princeton
(2000) Manufacturing advantage. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
University Press. Green, F. and McIntosh, S. (2001) The intensification of
Arthur, M. and Rousseau, D. (eds) (1996) The work in Europe. Labour Economics, 8: 291–308.
boundaryless career: a new employment principle for Green, F. and Tsitsianis, N. (2005) An investigation
a new employment era. Oxford: Oxford University of national trends in job satisfaction in Britain and
Press. Germany. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43:
Blanchflower, D. and Oswald, A. (1999) Well- 401–29.
being, insecurity and the decline of American job Guest, D. (2002) Human resource management,
satisfaction. Mimeo. www.andrewoswald.com. corporate performance and employee well-being:
Bryson, A., Cappellari, L. and Lucifora, C. (2004) Building the worker into HRM. Journal of Industrial
Does union membership really reduce job satis- Relations, 44: 335–58.
faction? British Journal of Industrial Relations, 42: Guest, D. and Conway, N. (2004a) Exploring the para-
439–59. dox of unionised worker dissatisfaction. Industrial
Burchell, B. (2002) The prevalence and redistribution of Relations Journal, 35: 102–21.
job insecurity and work intensification. In B. Burchell, Guest, D. and Conway, (2004b) Employee well-being
D. Lapido, and F. Wilkinson (eds) Job insecu- and the psychological contract. London: CIPD.
rity and work intensification. London: Routledge. Guest, D., Michie, J., Sheehan, M. and Conway, N.
pp. 61–76. (2000) Employment relations, HRM and business
Burchell, B., Lapido, D. and Wilkinson, F. (2002) performance. London: CIPD.
Job insecurity and work intensification. London: Guest, D. and Peccei, R. (2001) Partnership at work:
Routledge. mutuality and the balance of advantage. British
Conway, N. and Briner, R. (2005) Understanding Journal of Industrial Relations, 39: 207–36.
psychological contracts at work. Oxford: Oxford Hartley, J., Jacobson, D., Klandermans, B. and Van
University Press. Vuuren, T. (1991) Job insecurity: coping with jobs
Cooper, C., Dewe, P. and O’Driscoll, M. (2001) at risk. London: Sage.
Organizational stress. Thousand Oaks, CA.: Sage. Health and Safety Executive (1999) Managing stress at
Cousins, R., Mackay, C., Clarke, S., Kelly, C., Kelly, P. work. DDE 10. Sudbury: HSE Books.
and McHaig, R. (2004) ‘Management Standards’ and Health and Safety Executive (HSE) (2003) Real solutions,
work-related stress in the UK: Practical development. real people: a managers’ guide to tackling work-
Work and Stress, 18: 113–36. related stress. Sudbury: HSE Books.
Cully, M., Woodland, S., O’Reilly, A. and Dix, G. (1999) Heery, E. and Salmon, J. (eds) (2000) The insecure
Britain at work. Routledge: London. workforce. London: Routledge.
546 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Heller, F., Pusic, E., Strauss, G. and Wilpert B. (1998) testing inside the black box. British Journal of
Organizational participation: myth and Reality. Industrial Relations, 38: 501–31.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Roskies, E. and Louis-Guerin, C. (1990) Job insecurity in
Hellgren, J., Sverke, M., and Stjernstrom, C. (2005) The managers: antecedents and consequences. Journal of
union side of downsizing: Investigating members’ Organizational Behavior, 11: 345–59.
union attitudes. In H. De Witte (ed.) Job insecurity, Rousseau, D. (2005) I-deals: idiosyncratic deals
union involvement and union activism. Aldershot: employees bargain for themselves. M.E. Sharpe.
Ashgate. pp. 117–34. Roxburgh, S. (1996) Gender differences in work and
Helliwell, J. (2003) How’s life? Combining individual and well-being: effects of exposure and vulnerability.
national variables to explain subjective well-being. Journal of Health and Social Behavior, 37: 265–77.
Economic Modelling, 20: 331–60. Schaufeli, W. and Buunk, B. (2003) Burnout: an overview
Hirschman, A. (1970) Exit, Voice and Loyalty. of 25 years of research and theorizing. In M.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Schabracq, J. Winnubst and C. Cooper (eds). The
Isaksson, K., Hellgren, J. and Pettersson, P. (2005) Union handbook of work and health psychology. New York:
involvement during downsizing and its relation to Wiley.
attitudes and distress among workers. In H. De Witte Schneider, B., Hanges, P., Smith, B. and Salvaggio, A.
(ed.) Job insecurity, union involvement and union (2003) Which comes first: employee attitudes or
activism. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 97–116. organizational financial and market performance?
Jones, J., Huxtable, C., Hodgson, J. and Price, M. Journal of Applied Psychology, 88: 836–51.
(2003) Self-reported work-related illness in 2001/02: Sousa-Poza, A. and Sousa-Poza, A. (2000) Well-being
Results from a household survey. Sudbury: HSE at work: a cross-national analysis of the levels and
Books. determinants of job satisfaction. Journal of Socio-
Judge, T. and Watanabe, S. (1993) Another look at the Economics, 29: 517–38.
job satisfaction – life satisfaction relationship. Journal Smith, A. (2001). Perceptions of stress at work. Human
of Applied Psychology, 78: 939–48. Resource Management Journal, 11 (4): 74–86.
Karasek, R. (1979) Job demands, job decision latitude, Spector, P. (1997) Job satisfaction: application, assess-
and mental strain: implications for job design. ment, causes, and consequences. London: Sage.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 24: 285–308. Standing, G. (1999) Global labour flexibility: seeking
Karasek, R. and Theorell, T. (1990) Healthy work. distributive justice. London: Macmillan.
New York: Basic Books. Steijn, B. (2005) The insecure middle class and
Kersley, B., Alpin, C., Forth, J., Bryson, A., Bewley, H., unionisation: an empirical investigation of class, job
Dix, G. and Oxenbridge, S. (2006) Inside the insecurity and union membership. In H. De Witte (ed.)
workplace: findings from the 2004 workplace Job insecurity, union involvement and union activism.
employment relations survey. London: Routledge. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 49–62.
Layard, R. (2005) Happiness. London: Penguin. Steffy, B. and Jones, J. (1988) Workplace stress and
Leonard, E. (2005) Governance and concerted regulation indicators of coronary heart-disease risk. Academy of
of employment in Europe. European Journal of Management Journal, 31: 686–98.
Industrial Relations, 11: 307–26. Sverke, M., Hellgren, J. and Naswall, K. (2005) We get
Marmot, M. (2004) The status syndrome. New York: by with a little help from our unions: psychological
Times Books. contract violations and downsizing. In H. De Witte
Natti, J., Happonen, M., Kinnunen, U. and Mauno, S. (ed.) Job insecurity, union involvement and union
(2005) Job insecurity, temporary work and trade activism. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 135–54.
union membership in Finland 1977–2003. In Van den Berg, A. and Masi, A. (2005) Responses
H. De Witte (ed.) Job insecurity, union involvement to downsizing under different adjustment regimes:
and union activism. Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 11–48. a two-country comparison. In H. De Witte (ed.) Job
Parker, S., Chmiel, N. and Wall, T. (1997) Work charac- insecurity, union involvement and union activism.
teristics and employee well-being within a context of Aldershot: Ashgate. pp. 155–86.
strategic downsizing. Journal of Occupational Health Veenhoven, R. (1999) Quality-of-life in individualistic
Psychology, 4: 289–303. society: a comparison of 43 nations in the early 1990s.
Patterson, M., West, M., Lawthom, R. and Nickell, S. Social Indicators Research, 48: 157–86.
(1997) Impact of people management practices on Veenhoven, R. (2005) Return of inequality in modern
business performance. London: IPD. society? Test by dispersion of life-satisfaction across
Ramsay, H., Scholarios, D. and Harley, B. (2000) time and nations. Journal of Happiness Studies, 6:
Employees and high performance work systems: 351–55.
WORKER WELL-BEING 547

Wanous, J., Reichers, A. and Hudy, M. (1997) Overall Wickert, I. (2002) Job insecurity and work intensification:
satisfaction: How good are single item measures? the effects on health and well-being. In B. Burchell,
Journal of Applied Psychology, 82: 247–52. D. Lapido and F. Wilkinson (eds) Job insecurity and
Warr, P. (1987) Work, unemployment and mental work intensification. London: Routledge. pp. 92–111.
health. Oxford: Oxford University Press. World Health Organization (1998). Definition of health.
Warr, P. (1990) The measurement of well-being http://www.who.ch/aboutwho/definition.htm
and other aspects of mental health. Journal of Wright, P and Boswell, W. (2002) Desegregating HRM:
Occupational Psychology, 63: 193–210. a review and synthesis of micro and macro human
Warr, P. (2002) The study of well-being, behaviour resource research. Journal of Management, 28:
and attitudes. In P Warr, (ed.) Psychology at work. 247–76.
(5th ed). London: Penguin. pp. 1–25. Wright, P., Gardner, T., Moynihan, L. and Allen, M.
Watson, D. and Clark, L. (1984) Negative affectivity: The (2005) The relationship between HR practices and
disposition to experience negative emotional affective firm performance: examining causal order. Personnel
states. Psychological Bulletin, 96: 465–98. Psychology, 58: 409–47.
29
Industrial Relations Climate
Ali Dastmalchian

The term industrial relations climate is (for example Katz et al., 1983; 1985).
generally used to describe the nature and A co-operative industrial relations climate
quality of relationships between labor and not only relates to improved organizational
management in the organization (for example performance (Cooke, 1992), it also has
Katz et al., 1983). More precisely, industrial been shown to be associated with higher
relations climate reflects the perceptions of organizational commitment and union loyalty
organizational members about the norms, (Angle and Perry, 1986; Deery et al., 1999).
conduct, practice and atmosphere of union- Therefore, the role of industrial relations
management relations in the workplace climate as a key variable that has an influence
(Blyton et al., 1987). on performance and successful change, has
In the last two decades, in response to gained a renewed centrality and importance.
increased levels of competition in the eco- In addition, in introducing and imple-
nomic environment, organizations have been menting workplace changes there is a need
forced to restructure their work arrangements to appreciate and overcome the enduring
and introduce changes in labor-management relationships, attitudes and behaviors that
relations in an attempt to improve organi- have developed over time in workplaces and
zational performance. In this context, there organizations. Industrial relations climate can
has been a renewed interest among academics provide a window to understanding and appre-
and practitioners in finding ways in which ciating this and explain why apparently simi-
management and unions can develop more lar workplace innovations may have different
co-operative relationships in the hope of outcomes in varied contexts. The work by
leading to more mutually beneficial industrial Ichniowski et al. (1996) reviewing barriers to
relations arrangements (for example Deery the successful adoption of high performance
and Iverson, 2005; Wagar, 1997a). For this work practices identified union-management
to happen, and for the workplace changes relationships as one of the key barriers.
and innovations to succeed, there is a need To reinforce the significance of industrial
for the creation of a more co-operative relations climate, it is appropriate to consider
industrial relations climate in the workplace the co-operative industrial relations climates
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 549

in workplaces of countries such as Japan and the concept seems to reflect the combined
Germany to explain the greater successful perceptions of organizational members of
adoption of high performance work practices descriptive attributes of their organization.
and higher levels of labor productivity. Some have viewed the concept of climate as
The use of the concept of industrial an intervening variable in that it is affected
relations climate in explaining the perfor- by a set of external and structural variables,
mance, outcomes and processes of industrial and at the same time has an influence on
relations in organizations and workplaces is outcomes, such as firm performance and
therefore essential. The literature in industrial employee-related performance and behavior
relations (for example Blyton et al., 1987; (for example Dastmalchian, 1986; Payne,
Deery et al., 1999; Wagar, 1997a) as well 1971; Payne and Mansfield, 1973; Payne and
as in the organizational studies and social Pugh, 1976).
psychology areas (for example Dastmalchian There are a number of key conceptual
et al., 1989; Iverson and Maguire, 2000; and methodological issues and debates that
Redman and Snape, 2004; Tetrick and Fried, have emerged regarding the concept of
1993) demonstrates this point. organizational climate, some of which have
In this chapter, I will review the develop- been resolved and others that are still the
ment of the concept of industrial relations subject of debate. Each one of these issues
(IR) climate by providing a brief overview has implications for IR climate that I will try
of the development of the climate concept and highlight in this section and or later in this
in the broader organizational literature. I will chapter. The following is an outline of these
then review the development of measuring key issues.
IR climate and assess the empirical evidence
regarding its relationship with other pertinent
Level of analysis
industrial relations concepts and variables,
and examine its possible role in the future This refers to the inappropriateness of focus-
development of the field of industrial rela- ing on an individual level of analysis for
tions. an ‘organizational’ concept (Schneider et al.,
2000). Many researchers have addressed the
individual vs. aggregate conceptualizations
THE CONCEPT OF CLIMATE by referring to the individual climate and
IN ORGANIZATIONS ‘psychological’ climate as distinct from
‘organizational’ climate (see Hellriegel and
The concept of organizational climate has its Slocum, 1974). Even though this issue seems
origins in the Gestalt psychology approach of to have been resolved, more recent research
Kurt Lewin in that it represents a characteristic appears to call for more clarification (for
of an organization as a whole which is greater, example Parker et al., 2003). Clearly, whether
or different, from the sum of the specifics of a workplace or an organization can have an
individual perceptions (Lewin et al., 1939). IR climate, or whether the perception of such
It has been employed by researchers climates is the property of the individuals and
to better understand the ways in which should be understood and studied as such, are
organizational structures affect the pattern of considerations that would affect the way in
behaviors within organizations, or perhaps which the concept and its implications are
more generally to understand the context of studied.
the organization and representing the norms,
attitudes, feelings and behaviors prevalent at
Climate and job satisfaction
the workplace (Litwin and Stringer, 1968;
Tagiuri and Litwin, 1968; Pugh and Payne, The issue is whether climate merely mea-
1977; Schneider and Bartlett, 1968; 1970; sures the older concept of job satisfaction.
Denison, 1996). For many of these writers, The issue also seems to have been adequately
550 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

addressed by researchers. Guion (1973), as critical when one tries to understand, measure
well as a number of other researchers (for and analyze IR climate within a workplace or
example Roberts et al., 1978; Rousseau, 1985; an organization.
Schneider and Snyder, 1975) have shown On the whole, it does appear that as far as
the distinction between the concepts of work the aggregation issue is addressed well by the
atmosphere and job satisfaction. For IR cli- work of Roberts et al. (1978) and the detailed
mate the same is true and, as will be seen later, analysis of the level issues by Jones and
most of the frameworks consider general sat- James (1979) addressed the issue well. The
isfaction as an outcome of a particular climate. procedure offered by James et al. (1984) for
indexing the reliability of aggregated data and
the methodological procedure suggestions by
Aggregation issues
Dansereau and Alutto (1990) seem to have
The question is the reliability of aggregating brought the aggregation issue into the light
individual measures to an organizational for resolution for quantitative researchers.
variable. This issue lies at the heart of the
methodological and conceptual debate on
Volatility of climate
climate and its utility and future direction as
a concept (for example also see Dastmalchian Another issue regarding the concept of climate
et al., 1991; Glick, 1985; James et al., 1978; is its volatility. According to Dastmalchian
James, 1982; James et al., 1984; James et al., et al. (1991) if climate is viewed as subject
1988). Aggregate concepts have a degree of to a great deal of turbulence, then its
ambiguity associated with them as the act of characterization and its measurement as an
aggregation will introduce confusion regard- enduring construct is problematic. It appears
ing individual vs. organizational ownership that most studies have viewed climate as
of the information (Roberts et al., 1978). But sufficiently broad to have a degree of
it is suggested here that such ambiguity is endurance over time. Perhaps the comparison
more methodological than conceptual and that between climate and weather in meteorology
pursuing the debate over whether climate is is appropriate, in that one could attribute
an individual or an organizational construct a description to the climate of a region
is unlikely to be productive (Denison, 1996; despite the fact that in certain months or
Glick, 1988). On the methodological front, days the weather patterns might fluctuate
it has been suggested that one way of away from the climate descriptions. How
addressing the issue is to focus on within- should one study IR climate in light of this
organization variance which will provide an issue? Should longer term, and longitudinal,
index tied to the organization rather than the designs be an appropriate approach to a better
individual (Roberts, 1978). In other words, an understanding of IR climate? Again, later in
acceptable measure of organizational climate this chapter I will look at cross-sectional vs.
is obtainable where there is a relatively high longitudinal evidence on IR climate.
agreement between individual respondents
(Angle and Perry, 1986; Lincoln and Zeitz,
Climate and culture
1980; Ansari et al., 1982; Kozlowski and
Holts, 1987). Since the early discussions on organizational
The work of Payne (1990) and Patterson climate in the 1950s there have been numerous
et al. (1996) have also introduced the idea of debates and discussions and many review arti-
the appropriate constituency for aggregation. cles on the subject (for exampleArgyris, 1958;
Should, for instance, IR climate be based Eckvall, 1987; James and Jones, 1974; Joyce
on sub-unit, department, similar locations, and Slocum, 1979; Payne and Pugh, 1976;
membership of different groups or unions Rousseau, 1988; Schneider and Reichers,
interacting with one another, or the whole 1983; Pettigrew, 1990). Ironically, as the
workplace? This is an issue that can be fairly literature tried to resolve many of the key
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 551

issues, organizational culture as an alternative IR climate in a workplace when the underlying


way to look at the gestalt of organizations values of the actors are grounded in a history
appeared on the scene, and has dominated of confrontation, mistrust and the absence
the debates in this area (Pettigrew, 1979 and of respect for the other party’s view point?
Trice and Beyer, 1993). Many articles have As we will discuss later, this has significant
been devoted to exploring culture and climate implications for further research in terms
similarities and differences (for example of understanding IR culture in an organiza-
Ashforth, 1985; Ashkanasy et al., 2000; tion, the role of leadership and a different
Denison, 1996; Rousseau, 1988; Schneider, perspective for unions and management.
1990; Reichers and Schneider, 1990). At some A consensus seems to have emerged among
level the distinction is fairly clear: climate many writers on climate and culture. The
is about feelings, thoughts and behavior, it two are different, but they are and should be
is temporal, subjective and is more likely to treated as closer to one another than we once
be subject to manipulation by organizational thought (Payne, 2000, p.176). Denison (1996)
members with ability to do so; culture on the similarly concludes that the two concepts and
other hand is an evolved context (Denison, their research traditions ‘should be viewed
1996), is based on shared beliefs and values, as differences in interpretation rather than
and is sufficiently embedded in the situation differences in the phenomenon’ (p. 645).
so that it may not be readily subject to
manipulation. On the other hand, there are
Climate and organizational models
many similarities and inconsistencies in the
treatment of the two concepts. Both are There has been a lack of agreement on the
consensual in nature, in that they both seek status of climate in organizational models,
to portray characteristics applicable across or on how climate variables should be
the organization, they are meant to be stable operationalized. Several authors have utilized
over time and they are both perceived climate as an intervening concept between
by individuals. In addition, the quantitative organizational inputs and constraints on the
(climate research) and qualitative (culture one hand, and individual or group behavior on
research) methods have become increasingly the other. That is, the impact of organizational
blurred in that several climate researchers and contextual factors such as structure and
have studied the evolution of social contexts technology on the individual is mediated by
from a social constructionist point of view (for the individual’s perception of the situation
example Ashforth, 1985; Poole, 1985; Poole (Rousseau, 1988). Such a position has been
and McPhee, 1983), and culture researchers reinforced explicitly and implicitly by the
have used quantitative, comparative, and work of many other researchers (for example
Lewinian approaches thought to be associated Dastmalchian, 1986; Joyce and Slocum,
more with climate research (Chatman, 1991; 1979; Litwin and Stringer, 1968; Payne and
O’Rilley et al., 1991). Mansfield, 1973; Payne and Pugh, 1976;
However, organizational culture does affect Mansfield and Payne, 1977). In reviewing the
climate. Organizational climate can be IR climate research in this chapter, we will
changed only to the degree that the desired see that the intervening nature of IR climate
climate is congruent with the underlying has been adopted by many researchers who
culture. According to Schein (2000: xxix) have studied the concept directly. The key
‘One cannot create…. a climate of teamwork implication of this perspective is that in many
and cooperation if the underlying assumptions ways it reinforces the impact of IR climate
in the culture are individual and competitive, on successful IR arrangements in workplaces
because those assumptions will have created in that any new and negotiated programs and
a reward and control system that encourages structures will be affected by the IR climate
individual competitiveness’. Given this, is it before they can be expected to lead to desired
possible to create and sustain a co-operative outcomes.
552 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Climate and performance measure of climate is based on ‘something’


of interest, the relationship between it and
The measurement-oriented climate literature
the other key organizational variables can be
has debated (and continues to debate) the rela-
expected to be modest at best. Using this logic
tionships between climate and key organiza-
I now move more directly to the notion of
tional variables such as performance. Reviews
industrial relations climate.
by Payne and Pugh (1976), Hellriegel and
Slocum (1974), Schneider (1975), Siehl and
Martin (1990) and Campbell et al. (1970) did
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE
not find convincing support for associations
between climate and organizational perfor-
Nicholson (1979) was one of the first authors
mance and effectiveness. The evidence in the
who identified the use of the concept of IR
IR climate literature largely supports this lack
climate and pointed out the possibilities for an
of relationship as well, as will be discussed
industrial relations climate concept that could
later (Deery and Iverson, 2005; Wagar, 1997).
provide both a theoretical bridge between the
structural characteristics of organizations and
outcomes such as conflict; and also act as
Issue specific climates
a diagnostic concept in industrial relations,
Most studies using this concept have used capable of recommending changes in the
a generalized approach without relating the industrial relations system. In this study and
notion of climate to a particular set of orga- in a small number of other studies in the
nizational activities or issues. As Schneider 1970s and the 1980s the climate concept was
and Reichers (1983) have pointed out ‘to used to underline the variety of attitudinal
speak of organizational climate per se without elements relevant to the study of IR climate,
attaching it to a referent is meaningless’ and relate climate to a number of individual
(p. 21). They called for the inclusion of the and organizational outcomes (for instance
idea of the concept of organizational climate Angle and Perry, 1986; Dastmalchian et al.,
that has a focus or target in that the researchers 1982; Katz et al., 1983; Kelly and Nicholson,
should be looking for climate for ‘something’. 1980; Nicholson, 1979; Warr et al., 1978).
This ‘something’ might involve issues such Warr et al. (1978) conducted a broad
as a climate for safety (Zohar, 1980; 2000; study of employee relations in which they
Zohar and Luria, 2005), climate for sexual highlighted the importance of IR climate.
harassment (Fitzgerald et al., 1997), climate One of the members of the research team,
for justice (Liao and Rupp, 2005), climate for Nigel Nicholson, took the idea of IR climate
well-being (Burke et al., 1992), climate for a step further in a steel plant study in the
service (Schneider, 1980; Schneider et al., UK (Nicholson, 1979). Using a case approach
1998; Schneider and Bowen, 1995), a whistle and collecting data from union and manage-
blowing climate (Micelli and Near, 1985) ment representatives in the plant, Nicholson
or – as is the case of this chapter – IR focused primarily on two dimensions of IR
climate (Dastmalchian et al., 1989; 1991). The climate: the one relating to the flow of the
principle is that organizational climate as a problems at the workplace (issue-centered
concept has many facets, and that researching climate) and the other to shaping the quality
it needs to focus on which of these facets is of interpersonal dealings between union and
being studied.As in the case of personality and management (people-centered climate) and
attitude literature, say Schneider et al. (2000), the extent of satisfaction of the parties with
unless the predictor variable is conceptually each. In general, he found that in this particular
and operationally linked to the criterion plant, the overall climate was not dependent
variable, the probability of a relationship on the quality of interpersonal relations, and
between them is low. The same logic applies as a whole IR climate was more issue-
to climate. That is, unless the concept and centered than people-centered. He argued that
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 553

IR climate as a concept can be used to integrate out of 5, s.d.0.5) reflecting the possibility of
organizational variables and IR outcomes managers and supervisors exaggerating the
including industrial conflict. He identified the climate score.
potential for using issue-centered vs. people- In another study Angle and Perry (1986)
centered IR climates as a means of diagnosing examined dual union commitment and union-
and addressing the quality and outcomes of management relationships in 22 municipal
industrial relations in the steel plant under bus companies in the US. They used 22
study. He pointed out that for the predictive items, which were adapted from the Michigan
power of the notion of IR climate to be fully Organizational Assessment Package (MOAP)
realized, research would have to consider at (Institute of Social Research, 1975). They
least three major problems and integrate them used a single aggregate dimension to oper-
into the research design: ationalize IR climate without conceptually
explaining this. They also did not provide
1) untapped organizational dimensions of IR climate evidence of the validity of the climate measure
at the workplace level; or specify the kinds of modifications they had
2) external influences on IR climate and made to MOAP (Dastmalchian et al., 1991:
3) the process of IR climate’s formation, transmission p.36).
and transformation (Nicholson, 1979, p. 25). In order for the concept of IR climate to
be of more utility and a better foundation,
Kelly and Nicholson (1980) took this latter there was a need to develop its concept
idea further and suggested the basis of a more systematically. Dastmalchian et al.
conceptual model to predict the incidence of approached this in the 1980s and early 1990s
strikes, with IR climate as an integral part by bridging the literatures from industrial
of that model. Dastmalchian et al. (1982) relations and organization behavior/theory
also utilized Nicholson’s idea of IR climate and establishing components of a model of
in a survey of manufacturing firms in Wales IR climate in which not only the dimensions
and found that IR climate was positively of IR climate were developed, but the model
related to company effectiveness in terms of specified the factors affecting climate and the
adaptability and readiness to change. These dimensions of IR systems and organization on
relationships were moderated by other factors which climate would impact.
such as scale of operation and the economic
conditions of the firm.
These early studies took the first steps
toward developing the concept of IR climate DEVELOPING A MODEL OF IR
and its measurement. Even though other CLIMATE: WORKPLACE INDUSTRIAL
subsequent studies used this concept in differ- RELATIONS CLIMATE (WIRC)
ent contexts, their measurements (reflecting
the depth and complexity of the concept The lack of IR theory and theory testing
of IR climate) were often problematic. becomes evident when one considers the fac-
For example, Katz et al. (1983) studied tors that influence IR processes and outcomes.
the introduction of Quality of Work Life Dunlop (1993) identifies the importance of
programs in 18 General Motors plants. They such factors as technology, product and
reported a positive relationship between IR labor markets and financial and budgetary
climate (a 5-item measure reflecting union- constraints, as well as power distribution in
management cooperation as perceived by less society. Even in this broad and relatively
than half (N=65) of their total sample of 176 simple model, no serious attempts have been
supervisors) and IR conflict, labor efficiency made to suggest the relative weight for dif-
and product quality. However, in addition to ferent input or contextual variables. The work
a low response, the standard deviation of the of Craig (1983) is another important example.
measure as reported was very low (mean=2.9 The impressive list of input variables ranging
554 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

from the legal system to the weather leaves of union-management relationships in the
us with the difficult task of adequately testing organization. Also, based on the work of
such a multi-variable and interactive model. Nicholson (1979) there is a clear expectation
Dastmalchian et al. (1991) and Blyton et al. that the concept of IR climate and its
(1987) have stressed the need to develop mod- measurement are not uni-dimensional. This
els that not only have useful and worthwhile belief in multi-dimensionality has its roots
taxonomies, but such models need to have in the work of authors such as Fox (1974)
the capacity to be operationalized. Since the who identified trust and distrust as containing
primary purpose of their work was to improve important explanatory power in the analysis
understanding of how IR climate as a concept of IR and in the broader study of society.
works in individual work organizations, it Other studies have also reinforced this notion
was necessary to create a more middle-range that climate and attitude dimensions such as
model, which could be treated rigorously in a co-operation, hostility, aggression/resistance,
sample of organizations (Blyton et al., 1987). apathy, support for trade unions, joint par-
This required a more organizational focus to ticipation, goal identification, trust, fairness
the model which meant an expansion of the and power balance can all represent different
factors more relevant at the organizational facets of IR climate (Martin and Biassatti,
level and not focusing on variables that were 1979; Biassatti and Martin, 1979; Brett, 1980;
broader and more external and macro. The Gandz and Whitehead, 1981; Dastmalchian
model developed by Dastmalchian et al. is et al., 1982; Osborne and Blyton, 1985).
shown in Figure 29.1. Dastmalchian et al. (1986) conducted a
pilot study involving a population of 258
IR/HRM managers, union officials and labor
DIMENSIONS OF IR CLIMATE arbitrators. In a validation study involving two
Canadian cases and a total of 728 respon-
IR climate refers to the workplace norms dents, Dastmalchian et al. (1989) refined the
and attitudes perceived by management measures to 26 items and the five IR climate
and employees (and their representatives) dimensions of: harmony, openness, hostility,
about industrial relations and the nature apathy and promptness. Dastmalchian et al.

Inputs Processes Outcomes


Organizational context IR climate
• Fairness
• Branch plant • Union-Management
orientation consultation IR outcomes
• Mutual regard
• Instability • (Positive)IR
• Support for unions
Organizational structure • Union legitimacy situation
• Employee
• Flexible responses
• Bureaucratic IR context

HR context • Facilitative relations


• HR changes • Member commitment
• Internal labor • Single union dominance
markets • Union age
• Training

Figure 29.1 The industrial relations climate model and summary of relevant factors
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 555

(1989) also tested the appropriateness of the studies on IR climate. For example Deery
model as a whole using both quantitative and et al. (1994) included external labor market
qualitative and case methods. and Wagar (1997) considered industry and
Based on the above, these authors product/service information in their studies,
embarked on a large-scale study of 51 though not in a comprehensive fashion.
organizations in Canada to test the model The first of the input variables was organi-
and finalize the IR climate measures zational context. This included organizational
(Dastmalchian et al., 1991). The organizations and workplace size (Payne and Mansfield,
were from across the country belonging to 1973), age (Ross and Hartman, 1960),
both manufacturing and service sectors ownership (Enderwick, 1985), technology
ranging in size from 19 to 7000 employees. (Eisele, 1974), environmental dependencies
The average firm was 63 years old. The on owners, and labor markets (Dastmalchian,
data were collected by semi-structured 1984; 1986), and the extent of turbulence
interviews with various managers and and change, all of which have a potential
union representatives, company records and impact on the IR climate. In the final
questionnaires (for IR climate and other stages of their study, Dastmalchian et al.
perceptual measures). The criteria used (1991), drawing on factor analysis, used
for questionnaire data collection was the two dimensions to measure organizational
distribution to a minimum of 10 per cent context: (1) branch plant orientation where a
of the employees in each firm. Of the total higher score on this dimension represents the
3000 questionnaires distributed, 1686 were context of an organization which resembles a
received representing 35 organizations in the typical manufacturing or operating plant, with
sample. After the analysis of validity and production technologies similar to that of an
reliability of the scales and items, including assembly line, relatively low skill requirement
interclass and agreement coefficient analyses, for labor (and thus likely to be less dependent
the final measure of IR climate consisted on labor markets), owned by a larger group
of 20-items measuring 5 dimensions of: (and is a branch or a subsidiary of the
fairness, union-management consultation, large group), and relatively older as a unit.
mutual regard, membership support for In contrast a lower score on this dimension
unions and union legitimacy. Appendix 29.1 represents a newer workplace with high
shows the details and statistical properties of interdependence among its various functions
the final IR climate measure. Details of the and units, less dependent on an owning group
20 items and the final factor analysis results (not a branch or a subsidiary), and with higher
are shown in Appendix 29.2. skill requirements (and thus more dependent
on labor markets); and (2) instability which
refers to a context characterized by significant
THE INPUT VARIABLES organizational change such as technological,
ownership, products or market change. It was
Blyton et al. (1987) developed a comprehen- predicted that more branch plant orientation
sive set of input variables that they argue had and instability would contribute to tension
the most direct impact on the development between union and management and thus
of an IR climate. Based on the works of adversely affect the IR climate dimensions of
Dunlop (1993), Poole (1986) and others, consultation, mutual regard and fairness.
they identified the broader environmental The second group of organizational fac-
factors such as demographics, legal and social tors was organizational structure that has
elements, in their earlier conceptualization. been shown in the literature to relate to
However in finalizing their model, they stayed organizational climate and industrial relations
closer to factors more immediately relevant at (Barbash, 1975; Brett, 1980; Brett and
the organizational level. Many of these factors Goldberg, 1979; Payne and Pugh, 1976;
have been mentioned by a variety of other Thompson, 1967). This group included the
556 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

degree of centralization of decision making are expected to have a direct effect on the
and formalization, which affect the nature of climate of union-management relationships.
grievance handling, the resolution of labor IR Climate also can be affected by the
disputes, attitudes toward unions and strikes. context and history of the interaction between
Research has shown that the more formalized management and unions (see Clegg, 1979; and
and thus more bureaucratic the structure the Hyman, 1972 on the evidence on the impact of
less favorable the IR climate is likely to be. context on strike action). Dastmalchian et al.
Ng and Dastmalchian (1989) have shown (1991) concentrated on a set of largely ‘given’
that centralization causing grievances to be factors (for example bargaining structure)
settled at a higher level in organizations is rather than the ‘process’ variable (for example
associated with more delays and frustrations. process of dispute handling). Even though
Dastmalchian and Ng (1990) further showed this latter group is not explicitly stated in
that this relates to IR climates of less co- the model, the authors have addressed the
operation between union and management. importance of process factors elsewhere (see
One can make the argument that the existence Blyton, et al.,1987). The model used nine
of decentralization and participation would indicators to measure IR Context, and then
lead to a more co-operative IR climate, as clustered these into four factors:
Katz et al. (1983) have shown through their
study of participation and quality of work life 1) Facilitative Relations (with higher score on this
programs and their association with positive referring to a positive history, informal methods
IR climates. Dastmalchian et al. (1991) used of grievance handling, higher rate of female
two dimensions to reflect aspects of orga- membership and industry rather than local
nizational structure and design: (1) flexible bargaining structures);
design (referring to more participative, shar- 2) Membership commitment (attendance and com-
ing and decentralized, as well as specialized, mitment);
3) Single union dominance (high union density and a
decision making); and (2) bureaucratic design
single or few union presence) and
(referring to a more formalized, centralized 4) Union age.
and complex, differentiated, organizational
structure). It was predicted that more flexible
It was anticipated in this framework
organization structures would contribute to
that more facilitative IR contexts would
the development of more co-operative IR
lead to the creation of more collaborative
climates (consultation, fairness and mutual
and harmonious IR climates. Single union
regard as well as union legitimacy and
dominance was expected to relate to more
support).
extreme situations (either very co-operative
The next category in the inputs for
or conflictual). Membership commitment and
the model is human resource context. The
union age were also expected to influence
composition of the labor force, existence of
the formation of IR climates relating to more
internal labor markets, provision of training
union support and union legitimacy.
and education and flexible HR practices are
potentially influential on the formation of
more positive IR climates (Dastmalchian and
IR outcomes
Blyton, 1992). Dastmalchian et al. (1991)
finalized their measure of this category by Following this proposed model, the question
focusing on: internal labor markets, training was how various IR climates impact upon
and HR changes. the outcomes of industrial relations in the
Finally, the IR context is expected to exert organization. The theoretical position was that
a significant influence on IR climate. The the structure and context variables influence
extent and pattern of unionization (including the IR climate, which in turn will impact
the gender split, bargaining structure, history on the outcomes of union-management rela-
of recent settlements, union involvement, etc.) tionships. That is, the relationships between
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 557

structural and contextual variables and IR The results showed that the path model
outcomes are mediated by the perception of explained 65 per cent of the variation of the
the IR climate. IR outcomes and between 36–38 per cent of
Viewing this in a broader context, one needs the variation in IR climate. One important
to consider the question of what constitutes the conclusion from this analysis was that the
output of an IR system. Dunlop (1958: 1993) indirect paths of variables such as context
and his followers viewed the development of (both IR and organizational) and organiza-
a web of rules (procedural and substantive) tional structure to outcomes are much stronger
as outcomes of an IR system. Craig (1983, than their respective direct paths. That is,
p.11) stated that rule making is the ‘allocation organizational context and structural variables
of rewards to employees for their services impact more strongly on outcomes through
and the determination of the conditions under their effects on perceived climate than by
which they work’. He then went on to suggest direct effects on those outcomes. Similarly,
two types of outputs: one that related to the it can be argued that the context within
organization of work and trade unions, and which the interaction between the union
a second type that focused more on wage- and management takes place has its greatest
effort bargaining, rights and other worker- influence on results through its potential
oriented bargaining. Craig (1983), however, impact on people’s perceptions of the climate,
did not recognize ‘conflict’ as an outcome rather than directly in the form of industrial
of the IR system, which by implication actions, higher turnover and the like (pp.111
emphasized the positive aspects of union- and 113). Appendix 29.3 shows the summary
management and IR relationships. In their of the results by providing averages of the
model, Dastmalchian et al. (1991) therefore path coefficients across the path analyses
incorporated two categories: consensual out- provided by Dastmalchian et al. (1991: 112).
comes which refer to positive IR negotiations, The coefficients reported in Appendix 29.3
effective grievance handling and agreements; are path coefficients, and E refers to R2 or
and conflictual outcomes such as absence, the per cent of variance in dependent variables
turnover and strikes. The measures proposed explained by each path.
in their model include both objective and
subjective outcomes. These were: IR events,
IR situation (management view), and success
Testing the model: case study
in negotiations, IR situation (union view), analyses
turnover, and absenteeism. These were then Dastmalchian et al. (1991) also offer empirical
clustered into two factors: (1) IR situation evidence for their model in a more qualitative
(views of both sides about the positive fashion by using six longitudinal case studies
outcomes, effective negotiation success and (over a period of 18 months – between 1987–
lack of major IR incidents); and (2) employee 1989) and three cross-sectional case studies.
responses (turnover and absenteeism). The purpose was to further validate their
model and also to provide insights into the
Testing the model: quantitative dynamics of IR climate, or what they referred
analysis to as Workplace Industrial Relations Climate
(WIRC).
In testing their model, Dastmalchian et al.
(1991) used quantitative and qualitative Longitudinal case study analysis
(longitudinal case analysis) approaches. The This was conducted in six Canadian organiza-
quantitative approach was concluded by tions:
a series of regression techniques (path
analysis) examining the multi-variate asso- 1) A sports and recreational facility employing
ciations among the key variables in the professional people which reduced its size from
model (Dastmalchian et al., 1991: 112–14). 160 to 100 people;
558 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

2) A public library with high union density employing climate was not associated with a decline on
about 105 people in 1987 and experiencing a outcomes.
healthy growth of its unionized professional staff Therefore the case studies as well as
to a 160 strong staff by 1989; the quantitative analysis provided by
3) and (4) Two breweries both branches of larger Dastmalchian et al. (1991) showed the
organizations employing some 121 and 153
value of the general model proposed in their
people respectively which represented a 20–5 per
cent decline for its heavily unionized employees
work for understanding the determinants
compared to 1987; of workplace IR climate and its possible
5) An large agricultural co-operative business consequences at the level of the organization.
employing some 2600 people in 1987 growing The longitudinal case studies have also
to 2824 in 1989; and brought to bear the complexities of the
6) A private graphic and printing firm which due to relationships between various external and
a merger went through downsizing and reduced internal factors that could have a substantial
its employees from 170 to 70 in 18 months. impact on the process of climate formation
and change. Overall, based on their work,
Table 29.1 summarizes their findings. In IR climate does appear to provide a useful
four of the six cases, the findings of the vehicle to better understand the factors
quantitative analyses were confirmed. That involved in the processes of industrial
is, the impact of change in inputs on IR relations and their outcomes. With the
outcomes can better be understood through potential of a much wider range of influences
their effects on IR climate perceptions than than one can incorporate in any model or
by examining their direct impacts on IR framework designed to understand attitudes
outcomes. In three of the cases (the sports and behaviors regarding firms’ industrial
and recreation facility – Western Recreation relations, it is important to be able to utilize
Facility, the City library and a brewery – concepts such as climate both to evaluate
Merton Brewery) a decline in flexibility the significance of individual input and to
of organizational design and decrease in compare the industrial relations scene across
participation, coupled with a reduction in diverse settings.
extent of training, growth in size and increased
dependency on the parent company, led to The utility of the concept
a deterioration of the IR climate (in terms
of IR climate
of co-operation and trust) and resulted in a
reduction in favorability of IR outcomes. In Since the work by Dastmalchian, Blyton,
another brewery (Clark Brewery), an increase Adamson and colleagues was published in
in structural flexibility and a greater emphasis the late 1980s and early 1990s, there have
on training had contributed to improvements been a fairly large number of studies that
in climate and outcomes. In the other two have employed the concept and measures
cases, the authors noted the complexity of of IR climate to explore issues relating to
the model and the possible interrelationships industrial relations, dual commitment, high
among the variables. For example, in the performance work practices, teamworking
case of the printing company (Graphica), a and a series of other changes and innovations
merger with another firm in the same industry in the workplace. An overview of the empir-
during the period under study resulted in a ical and conceptual evidence shows that the
substantial change in the role of the main concept of IR climate has been accepted as a
union and thus a decline in positive IR legitimate variable that can gauge the context
climate perceptions. But as the financial within which labor-management interactions
performance of the merged organization was take place.
strong and the merger had allowed access Following on the suggestion made by
to different labor markets and the prosperity Thornicroft (1993) that the quality of
of the firm had improved, the decline in the labor-management relationship is a
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 559

Table 29.1 A Summary of the six longitudinal case studies


Cases Change in key input variables Change in workplace IR Change in outcome
climate variables
Western • A sharp decline in structural Climate deteriorated An increase in conflictual
Recreational flexibility (particularly union outcomes.
Association • Declines in training and ILM support and legitimacy)
(internal labour market)

City Library • An increase in size Climate deteriorated An increase in conflictual


• A decrease in structural (particularly fairness and outcomes, and decrease
flexibility mutual regard) in actors’ ratings of IR
• Moderate increase in ILM and situation.
technical training

Merton Brewery • A substantial drop in structural Climate deteriorated A decrease in favorability


flexibility (consultation, mutual of negotiation outcomes
• A reduction in size regard and union from union’s view.
• An increase in technical support)
training
• Change in ownership structure
(merger)

Clark Brewery • An increase in structural Improvement in climate Overall decrease in


flexibility and slight decrease in (fairness, consultation conflictual outcomes.
bureaucracy and mutual regard)
• An increase in HR related
practices (training and ILM)
• A decrease in branch plant
orientation

Canadian • An increase in structural Deterioration of climate A slight improvement in


Co-Operative bureaucracy (fairness, consultation positive aspects of
Services • A decrease in HR practices and mutual regard) outcomes (reductions in
(training) absenteeism and
turnover)
Graphica • Ownership changes (merger) Deterioration of climate Improvement in positive
• Increases in structural (fairness, consultation aspects of outcomes
bureaucracy and size and union support) (turnover, grievances
• Reduction in emphasis on HR and absenteeism)
practices (ILM and training)

more important determinant of organiza- was perceptions of performance, and the main
tional performance than unionization, Wagar independent variable was six IR climate items
(1997a) addressed the question ‘Is Labor- drawn from Dastmalchian et al. (1991). Other
Management Climate Important?’ He con- control variables in the study were: market
ducted an empirical study of organizations and demand, technology/automation, investment,
unions in Canada, by collecting data from a unionization rate, workforce reduction, exis-
national sample of unionized firms (N=367), tence of team-based programs, incidence
a sample of unionized organizations from of strikes, union concessions and major
the province of Nova Scotia (N=392), and change in company strategy, size and industry
a sample of union officials in Nova Scotia sector. The data from the two employer
(N=280). He analyzed the three data sets sep- samples and one union sample showed clearly
arately and concluded that labor-management that more favorable union-management cli-
climate is important. The dependent variable mates were associated with more favorable
560 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

perceptions of organizational performance as a uni-dimensional construct), was related


(with a stronger relationship reported in case to company commitment but not to union
of ‘present’ performance rather than perfor- commitment. The dual commitment issue has
mance ‘change’ over time). This is despite the attracted the interest of many researchers
fact that the union sample rated the climates and its association with IR climate has also
less optimistically than the employers. The been studied by other authors (for instance
study also showed that achieving a positive Angle and Perry, 1986; Barling et al., 1990;
labor-management climate is not easy and Gallagher and Clark, 1989). Based on the
requires long-term commitment on both sides. assumptions of role theory, it argues that in
In a related study, using the employer data tense and hostile climates, undue pressure
from 752 Canadian organizations, Wagar is placed upon employees to choose their
(1997b) reinforced the finding from the allegiance, whereas in positive climates those
study referred to above in that a more perceived role conflicts exist less strongly
co-operative relationship between labor and (Angle and Perry, 1986). It has been suggested
management was associated with a number of that the reason for divergent findings on the
positive organizational outcomes (for instance impact of climate on organizational and union
employees’ willingness to support change outcomes is that the role that management
and innovation, and lower levels of conflict, and unions play in employees’ views their
turnover and absenteeism). attachment to the company or the union, or
In another, more recent, study of labor- their instrumentality in employees achieving
management climate in Canadian health care, valued goals, is underestimated. Deery et al.
Wagar and Rondeau (2002) collected data (1999) emphasizing this point developed a
from 260 union officials/representatives in the framework of antecedents and consequences
health care sector. The results, again using an on IR climate that is based on this notion
IR climate measure drawn from Dastmalchian of management and union’s instrumentality
et al. (1991), showed that climate is an and relates climate to outcomes such as dual
important variable affecting the satisfaction commitment and absenteeism. One difference
of the union members, or change in their level between this and Dastmalchian et al.’s (1991)
of satisfaction (climate was as important in framework is that in Deery et al.’s (1999) case,
this respect as the presence of joint labor- the level of analysis is individual rather than
management committees). Climate on the organizational. Similar to the model presented
other hand, was not seen to be as important earlier, their framework also has a number
a predictor of workplace performance as of variables as inputs (demographic variables
was the adoption of joint labor-management of individuals; work setting variables such
committees (workplace performance refers to as routinization, autonomy, job security and
service quality and client satisfaction). This satisfaction; and environmental variables such
latter finding is not surprising. In the language as job market and union instrumentality).
of the model presented by Dastmalchian et al. These affect the IR climate, which in turn
(1991), the presence of the joint committees impacts upon organizational commitment,
is a feature of organizational structure which union loyalty and absenteeism.
impacts on climate which in turn affects Deery et al. (1999) collected data from a
outcomes. random sample of 525 blue-collar employees
Other researchers have also incorporated in a large American auto manufacturer
IR climate as an integral concept in their firm in Australia. For IR climate, they
research framework and measures. Deery used Dastmalchian et al.’s (1989) ten-item
et al. (1994) studied dual commitment among ‘harmony’ dimension. They found that the
a sample of Australian white-collar unionists more employees reported their unions as
and found that IR climate, measured using instrumental in achieving their valued goals,
the six items from Hammer et al.’s (1991) the more favorable they perceived the IR
investigation (where climate was measured climate and the more loyal to the union and
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 561

committed to the organization they were. That three time periods from unionized and non-
is, they demonstrated a greater likelihood unionized employees, plus additional data
of having dual commitment. Higher union on performance measures from company
instrumentality, through its effects on climate, records. They found that a co-operative labor
also had a positive impact on reducing relations climate was associated with higher
absenteeism. In short, they found that unions levels of branch productivity and service
that provided effective workplace represen- quality. Also, more positive climate percep-
tation could, through the creation of positive tions were related to higher commitment to
IR climates, facilitate positive organizational the organization and more loyalty to the
outcomes. union.
In a more recent study Deery and Iverson Bacon and Blyton also included IR climate
(2005) developed their earlier framework in their study of the UK steel industry
and in addition to union instrumentality, (Bacon and Blyton, 2004; 2006; Bacon et al.,
included variables reflecting the structure and 2005). They used a four-item scale from
context of both management and union activ- Dastmalchian et al.’s (1991) measure and
ities that are specific to union-management utilized it to determine co-operative and
dealings. These included: the perception conflictual IR climate. Their findings showed
of procedural justice, and management’s that IR climate collected by survey from the
willingness to share information and facilitate unionized employees had significant relation-
union business; and on the union side, their ships to co-operative and conflict behaviors
interest in integrative bargaining approaches during negotiations by managers and unions.
and union responsiveness to members. Thus Positive IR climates were shown to be
union, management and individual-related associated with collaborations between union
variables (belief in co-operation and in good and management when introducing changes
relationships) as inputs will impact upon in teamworking, shift and work patterns
the perception of IR climate, which in turn (Bacon et al., 2005). Bacon and Blyton (2006)
influence dual commitment as well as three also showed that whereas most literature
additional types of outcomes (productivity, tends to favor positive IR climates, in such
quality of service and absenteeism). Deery climates workers may actually fare worse
and Iverson’s causal model and the direction when organizational changes are introduced.
of relationships found are summarized in In addition to the above studies, the concept
Figure 29.2. of IR climate has been used in understand-
Deery and Iverson (2005) conducted a ing the dynamics of industrial relations in
further study of 305 branches of a unionized Asian counties. Wan et al. (1997) used the
Australian-based multi-national bank using a concept in a study of 73 manufacturing
longitudinal design with data collected over firms in Singapore and a more in-depth

(+)
Management-related variables
Shares information with union Productivity
Facilitates union business (+) (+)
Procedural justice (+) Organizational (+)
commitment (+)
(+) Quality of (−)
(+) (+) (+) service
Union-related variables (+)
(+)
Integrative bargaining approach Co-operative
(−)
Union instrumentality (intrinsic) Labor relations
climate (+) Absenteeism
(+) (−)
Individual-related variables (+) Union loyalty
Ensure good relationship

(+)

Figure 29.2 Simplified model of organizational performance


Source: Based on the findings of Deery and Iverson (2005), p. 603.
562 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

analysis of eight of the organizations in their say that the field of industrial relations has not
sample. Their study revealed that positive kept pace with those deeper conceptual and
industrial relations climates reflected the methodological issues surrounding the notion
changes and improvement that had happened of IR climate that organizational studies have
in Singapore’s manufacturing sector. This had been grappling with. For example, none of
coincided with improved union membership the studies utilizing the concept has shown
and the perceived increase in the role and interest in looking more closely to examine
influence of unions in workplace industrial the aggregation issues: how it should be
relations. They also found differences in the aggregated to represent the IR climate at the
climate perceptions among union officials, plant level; what is the level of ‘agreement’
management and employees and concluded on climate; or which sub-groups should
that there is a need to strengthen the constitute the basis of aggregation – union
communication among the three parties. Wu types, departments, geographical regions and
and Lee (2001) examined the relationships so on. The industrial relations field appears to
between IR climate and participatory manage- have been less interested in these conceptual
ment approaches in Chinese-, Japanese-, and and methodological issues than in the utility
American-owned firms in Taiwan. Using data of the notion of IR climate. However, one can
from 303 individual employees from 12 firms, argue that without due attention and care about
they found that IR climate dimensions of such matters as level of ‘agreement’, and
harmony and openness had a significant aggregation biases, what is being measured
relationship with the effective use of par- may not reflect what IR climate is intended to
ticipatory management. Lee (2004) studied capture.
the association between dual commitment A related issue raised earlier in this chapter
and IR climate by collecting data from is the ‘issue-specific’ climate concept. It is
331 respondents in one automobile plant in clear from the evidence that an issue-specific
Korea. Lee (2004) similar to Deery et al. concept of climate is more useful and can
(1994) he found that co-operative IR climate clarify the impact of climate on organizations,
had a positive relationship with company unions, management and employees. At a
commitment and a negative association with broader level, our focus on IR climate (rather
union commitment. than general organizational climate) has partly
achieved this shift in attention. Looking
ahead, there is a need to develop more specific
CONCLUSION IR climate constructs that deal with issues
that are pertinent to the research questions.
It does appear that over the past 25 years These include climates of safety (Zohar,
the concept of IR climate has made its 2000), harassment (Fitzgerald et al., 1997),
way into the list of critical variables to grievances (Dastmalchian and Ng, 1990; Ng
be examined and paid close attention to in and Dastmalchian, 1989), absence (Iverson
the field of industrial relations and human et al., 2003). Such a direction will likely
resource management. It has provided a result in studies and research frameworks that
much improved explanatory ability in various more clearly link the causes and consequences
studies. It consistently has been shown to of a particular aspect of work and IR and
be associated with positive organizational the influence of the specific climate under
and industrial relations outcomes. That is, study. Another example would be the climate
the concept of IR climate has proved to of human resource management (HRM) in
be useful, and in many ways critical, in the organization. Building on the notion
understanding the complexities of the atmo- of HR ‘bundles’ (for example MacDuffie,
sphere of workplace industrial relations and 1995) where synergies among HR policies
employee commitment to the organization are the focus, the idea of HRM climate could
and the union. At the same time, it is fair to provide insights into the role of climate in
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 563

successful implementation of HR practices unlikely to lead to the intended outcome


and bundles and be a fruitful research avenue unless the appropriate IR climate is created
to pursue for both unionized and non- to facilitate their successful implementation.
unionized firms. This has serious implications for the roles
It clear from the review of the recent each party plays in the process of change.
literature that IR climate has been used to This also has direct implications for the
better understand the dynamics of change leadership skills and perspectives of unions
in the workplace. IR climate has been an and management and their significance for
important variable included in a variety of any successful change and transformation –
different studies to explain either the impetus success as defined by all stakeholders. By
for change or the context within which accepting the concept of IR climate as a key
change in organizational and employment factor in the study of industrial relations,
practices has taken place (see for example, we are also accepting the legitimacy and
the work of Deery et al., 1999, and of Bacon significance of behavioral and organizational
and Blyton, 2006). In an attempt to better concepts such as leadership, managing change
understand the dynamics of change and the and creativity, and the political model of
outcome of interactions between unions and organizations (Pfeffer, 1981) for industrial
management and their changing relationships, relations.
IR climate has been shown to be a key factor There is little doubt, based on research
to help understand the process and predict evidence, that co-operative IR climates con-
outcomes. The issue of climate vs. culture tribute to firm performance (productivity
is an ongoing debate. In terms of the future levels, quality and service), higher levels of
direction of research, it is understood that commitment to the organization and loyalty
the two concepts are connected, but differ in to unions (for example Deery and Iverson,
terms of what they represent – with culture 2005; Ichniowski et al., 1997; Katz et al.,1983;
signifying deeply rooted values, and climate 1985; Wagar, 1997a; 1997b). The nature of
referring to the atmosphere and the context of the relationships and the resultant IR climate
the relationships. have been identified as significant facilitating
The early work by of Nicholson (1979) and factors for successful change and the adoption
the framework developed by Dastmalchian of innovative work practices (Ichniowski
et al. (1989; 1991) have been shown to et al., 1996). This has important strategic
be useful and constructive concepts and implications for union and management IR
measures in the development of the notion strategies and for the future of IR climate
of IR climate. Many of the empirical studies research and its application. IR actors make
conducted in the UK, Canada, Australia, choices about their approach and strategy.
the US and Asian countries (Singapore, The discussion in this chapter shows that
Korea, China, Japan and Taiwan) have strategies based on creating IR climates
employed the concept, the measures and rooted in trust, fairness and genuine desire
the suggested framework. The implication to provide support and legitimacy for unions
of the suggested framework by the above (and management) pay off and need to be an
authors is far reaching. In order for new integral part of the process of IR development.
programs, new structures and new workplace Some recent evidence has suggested that
arrangements to be successfully implemented, perhaps co-operative IR climates may not
there needs to be an atmosphere, or an always lead to better outcomes for the
IR climate, created by the parties involved, employees (Bacon and Blyton, 2006). Perhaps
their members and leaders. It is only then the underlying assumptions (for instance IR
that innovative work practices will lead to culture) on which the more temporal IR
the desired outcomes by both parties. This climate is based need also be changed and
framework shows that the creation of new re-examined. This takes time and leadership
structures and new programs in isolation are on the part of both unions and management
564 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and a clear desire to recognize the importance Brett, J. and Goldberg, S. (1979) Wildcat strikes
of creating such enduring IR climates as a in bituminous coal mining. Industrial and Labor
strategic direction for the future of industrial Relations Review, 32: 465–83.
relations. Burke, M., Borucki, C. and Hurley, A. (1992) ‘Recon-
ceptualizing psychological climate in a retail service
environment: a multiple stakeholder perspective’,
Journal of Applied Psychology, 77 (5): 557–79.
REFERENCES Campbell, J., Dunnette, M., Lawler, E. and Weick, K.
(1970) Managerial Behavior, Performance, and
Angle, H. and Perry, J. (1986) Dual commitment and Effectiveness. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
labor management relationship climates, Academy of Chatman, J. (1991) Matching people and organizations:
Management Journal, 29 (1): 31–50. selection and socialization in public accounting firms,
Ansari, M., Baumgartel, H. and Sullivan, G. (1982) Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (3): 459–84.
The personal orientation – organizational climate Clegg, H. (1979) The System of Industrial Relations in
fit and managerial success, Human Relations, 35: Great Britain. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell.
1159–78. Cooke, W.N. (1992). Product quality improvement
Argyris, C. (1958) Some problems in conceptualizing through employee participation: the effect of union-
organizational climate: a case study of a bank, ization and joint union-management administration.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 2 (4): 501–20. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 46 (1):
Ashforth, B. (1985) Climate formation: issues and 119–34.
extensions. Academy of Management Review, 10 (4): Craig, A. (1983) The System of Industrial Relations in
837–47. Canada. Scarborough, ON: Prentice-Hall.
Ashkanasy, N. M., Wilderom, C. P. M. and Peterson M.F. Dansereau, F. and Alutto, J.A. (1990) Level of
(eds), (2000) Handbook of Organizational Culture analysis issues in climate and culture research. In
and Climate. London: Sage. B. Schneider, (ed.) Organizational climate and culture.
Bacon, N. and Blyton, P. (2004). Trade union San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. pp.193–236.
responses to workplace restructuring: exploring union Dastmalchian, A. (1984) Environmental dependencies
orientations and actions, Human Relations, 18 (4): and company structure in Britain, Organization
749–73. Studies, 5 (3): 227–41.
Bacon, N. and Blyton, P. (2006) Union co-operation in a Dastmalchian, A. (1986) Environmental characteris-
context of job insecurity: negotiated outcomes from tics and organizational climate: An exploratory
teamworking, British Journal of Industrial Relations, study, Journal of Management Studies, 23 (6):
44 (2): 215–38. 609–33.
Bacon, N., Blyton, P. and Dastmalchian, A. (2005) Dastmalchian, A., Adamson, R. and Blyton, P. (1986)
The significance of working time arrangements Developing a measure of industrial relations climate.
accompanying the introduction of teamworking: Relations Industrielles, 41 (4): 851–59.
evidence from the employees, British Journal of Dastmalchian, A. and Blyton, P. (1992) Organizational
Industrial Relations, 43 (4): 681–701. structure, human resource practices and industrial
Barbash, J. (1975) The unions as a bargaining organi- relations, Personnel Review, 21 (1): 58–67.
zation: some implications to organizational behavior. Dastmalchian, A., Blyton, P. and Abdollahian, R.
Proceedings of Industrial Relations Research Associ- (1982) Industrial relations climate and company
ation. Maddison Wis: IRRA Press. effectiveness. Personnel Review, 11 (1): 35–9.
Barling, J. Wade, B. and Fullager, C. (1990) Journal of Dastmalchian, A., Blyton, R. and Adamson, R. (1989)
Occupational Psychology, 63 (1): 49–61. Industrial relations climate: testing a construct.
Biassatti, L. and Martin, J. (1979) A measure of the Journal of Occupational Psychology, 62: 21–32.
quality of union-management relationships. Journal Dastmalchian, A., Blyton, P. and Adamson, R. (1991)
of Applied Psychology, 64 (4): 387–90. The Climate of Workplace Relations. London, UK:
Blyton, P., Dastmalchian, A. and Adamson, R. (1987) Routledge.
Developing the concept of industrial relations climate, Dastmalchian, A. and Ng, I. (1990) Examining the
Journal of Industrial Relations, 29 (2): 207–16. relationship between industrial relations climate and
Brett, J. (1980) Behavioral research on unions and union grievance outcomes, Relations Industrielles, 45 (2):
management systems. In B. Staw and L. Cumming 311–24.
(eds), Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 2. Deery, S., Erwin, P. and Iverson, R. (1999) Industrial
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. pp. 177–213. relations climate, attendance, behaviour and the role
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 565

of trade unions, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Hammer, T., Currall, S. and Stern, R. (1991) Worker
37 (4): 533–58. representation on boards of directors: a study of
Deery, S., Iverson, R. and Erwin, P. (1994) Predicting competing roles, Industrial and Labor Relations
organizational and union commitment: The effect Review, 44 (4): 661–80.
of industrial relations climate, British Journal of Hellriegel, D. and Slocum, J. (1974) Organizational
Industrial Relations, 32: 581–97. climate: measures, research and contingencies,
Deery, S. and Iverson, R. (2005) Labor-management Academy of Management Journal, 17 (2): 255–79.
cooperation: antecedents and impact on organiza- Hyman, R. (1972) Strikes. London, UK: Fontana.
tional performance, Industrial and Labor Relations Ichniowski, C., Kochan, T., Levine, D., Olson, C. and
Review, 58 (4): 588–609. Strauss, G. (1996) What works at work: overview and
Denison, D. (1996) What is the difference between assessment, Industrial Relations, 35 (3): 299–333.
organizational culture and organizational Climate? Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G. (1997) The
A native’s point of view on a decade of paradigm effects of human resource management practices on
wars? Academy of Management Review, 21 (3): productivity: a study of steel finishing lines, American
619–54. Economic Review, 87 (3): 291–313.
Dunlop, J. (1958) Industrial Relations System. New York: Institute of Social Research. (1975) Michigan Organiza-
Holt. tional Assessment Package: Progress Report II. Ann
Dunlop, J. (1993) Industrial Relations Systems: Revised Arbor, MI: Survey Research Center, ISR.
Edition. Boston, MA.: Harvard Business School Iverson, R., Buttigieg, D. and Maguire, C. (2003)
Press. Absence culture: the effects of union membership
Eckvall, G. (1987) The climate metaphor in organization status and union-management climate, Relations
theory. In B. Bass and P. Deneth (eds), Advances in Industrielles, 58 (3): 483–514.
Organizational Psychology: An International Review. Iverson, R. and Maguire, C. (2000) The relationship
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. pp. 177–90. between job and life satisfaction: evidence from a
Eisele, C.F. (1974). Organizational size, technology and remote mining community, Human Relations, 53 (6):
frequency of strikes, Industrial and Labor Relations 807–39.
Review, 27 (4): 566–71. James, L.A. (1982) Aggregation bias in estimates of
Enderwick, P. (1985) Ownership nationality and indus- perceptual agreement, Journal of Applied Psychology,
trial relations practices in British non-manufacturing 67 (2): 219–29.
industries, Industrial Relations Journal, 16 (2): James, L., Demaree, R. and Wolf, G. (1984) Estimating
50–9. within-group interrater reliability with and without
Fitzgerald, L.F. , Drasgow, F., Hulin, C.L., Gelfand, response bias, Journal of Applied Psychology, 69:
M.J. and Magley, V.J. (1997) Antecedents and 85–90.
consequences of sexual harassment in organizations: James, L.R., Hater, J.J., Gent, M.J. and Bruni, J.R.(1978)
a test of an integrated model, Journal of Applied Psychological climate: implications for cognitive
Psychology, 82 (4): 578–89. social theory and interactional psychology, Personnel
Fox, A. (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power, and Trust Psychology, 31 (6): 781–813.
Relations. London, UK: Faber. James, L. and Jones, A. (1974) Organizational climate:
Gallagher, D. and Clark, P. (1989) Research on union a review of theory and research, Psychological
commitment: Implications for labor, Labor Studies Bulletin, 84 (12): 1096–112.
Journal, 14: 531–71. James, L., Joyce, W. and Slocum, J. (1988) Com-
Gandz, J. and Whitehead, J. (1981) The relationship ment: organizations do not cognize, Academy of
between industrial relations climate and grievance ini- Management Review, 13 (1): 129–32.
tiation and resolution. IRRA 34th Annual Proceedings, Jones, A. and James, L. (1979) Psychological climate:
Madison, Wis. pp. 320–28. dimensions and relationships of individual and aggre-
Glick, W. (1985) Conceptualizing and measuring gated work environment perceptions, Organizational
organizational and psychological climate, Academy Behavior and Human Performance, 23: 201–50.
of Management Review, 10: 601–16. Joyce, W. and Slocum, J. (1979) Climates in organi-
Glick, W. (1988) Organizations are not central zations. In S. Kerr (ed.), Organizational Behavior,
tendencies: shadowboxing in the dark, round 2, Columbus, OH: Grid. pp. 317–33.
Academy of Management Review, 13 (1): 133–37. Katz, H.C., Kochan, T.A and Gobeille, K.R. (1983). Indus-
Guion, R. (1973) A note on organizational climate, trial relations performance, economic performance,
Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, and QWL programs: an interplay analysis, Industrial
9 (1): 120–125. and Labor Relations Review, 37 (1): 3–17.
566 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Katz, H.C., Kochan, T.A. and Weber, M.R. (1985). Ng, I. and Dastmalchian, A. (1989) Determinants of
Assessing the effects of industrial relations systems grievance outcomes: a case study. Industrial and
and efforts to improve the quality of working Labor Relations Review, 42 (3): 393–403.
life on organizational effectiveness, Academy of Nicholson, N. (1979) Industrial relations climate: a case
Management Journal, 28 (3): 509–26. study approach, Personnel Review, 8 (1): 20–5.
Kelly, J. and Nicholson, N. (1980) The causation O’Rilley, C., Chatman, J. and Caldwell, D. (1991) People
of strikes: review of theoretical approaches and and organizational culture: a profile comparison
potential contribution of social psychology, Human approach to assessing person-environment fit,
Relations, 33 (12): 853–83. Academy of Management Journal, 34 (3): 487–516.
Kozlowski, S. and Hults, B. (1987) An exploration of Osborne, D. and Blyton, P. (1985) Contrasting
climates for technical updating and performance, perspectives on productivity bargaining, Journal of
Personnel Psychology, 40 (3): 539–67. General Management, 10 (3): 65–78.
Lee, J. (2004) Company and union commitment: Parker, C.P., Baltes, B.B., Young, S.A, Huff, R.W.,
evidence from an adversarial industrial relations Altman, H.A., LaCost, J. and Roberts, E. (2003) ‘Rela-
climate at a Korean auto plant, Human Resource tionships between psychological climate perceptions
Management, 15 (8): 1463–80. and work outcomes: a meta-analytic review’, Journal
Lewin, K., Lippitt, R. and White, R. (1939) Patterns of Organizational Behavior, 24 (4): 389–416.
of aggressive behavior in experimentally created Patterson, M., Payne, R. and West, M. (1996)
social climates, Journal of Social Psychology, 10 (2): Collective climates: a test of their socio-psychological
271–99. significance, Academy of Management Journal,
Liao, H. and Rupp, D.E (2005) The impact of justice 39 (6): 1675–91.
climate and justice orientation on work outcomes: Payne, R. (1971) Organizational climate: the concept
a cross-level multifoci framework, Journal of Applied and some research findings. Prakseologia 39/40,
Psychology, 90 (2): 242–56. ROK. pp. 143–58.
Lincoln, J. and Zeitz, G. (1980) Organizational properties Payne, R.L. (1990) ‘Madness in our method: a comment
from aggregate data: separating individual and of Jackofsky and Slocum’s paper’ A longitudinal
structural effects, American Sociological Review, 45: study of climates, Journal of Organizational Behavior,
391–408. 11 (1): 77–80.
Litwin, G. and Stringer, R. (1968) Motivation and Payne, R.L. (2000) ‘Climate and culture: How close can
Organizational Climate. Cambridge, MA: Harvard they get?’ In N.M., Ashkanasy, C.P.M. Wilderom,
University Press. and M.F. Peterson (eds), Handbook of Organizational
MacDuffie, J.P. (1995) Human resource bundles and Culture and Climate. London: Sage. pp. 163–76.
manufacturing performance: organizational logic and Payne, R. and Mansfield, R. (1973) Relationships of
flexible production systems in the world auto industry, perceptions of organizational climate to organiza-
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48 (2): tional structure, context and hierarchical position,
197–221. Administrative Science Quarterly, 18 (4): 515–26.
Mansfield, R. and Payne, R. (1977) Correlates of variance Payne, R.L. and Pugh, D.S. (1976) ‘Organizational struc-
in perceptions of organizational climate. In D. Pugh ture and climate’. In M.D. Dunnette, (ed.), Handbook
and R. Payne (eds), Organizational Behavior in its of Industrial and Organizational Psychology. Chicago:
Context: The Aston Programme III. Farnborough, Rand-McNally. pp. 1125–73.
Hants: Saxon House. pp. 149–59. Pettigrew, A. (1979) On studying organizational
Martin, J. and Biassatti, L. (1979) A hierarchy of cultures, Administrative Science Quarterly, 24 (4):
important elements in union-management relations, 570–81.
Journal of Management, 5 (2): 229–40. Pettigrew, A. (1990) Organizational climate and culture:
McGregor, D. (1960) The Human Side of Enterprise. two constructs in search of a role. In B. Schneider
New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. (ed.), Organizational Climate and Culture. London:
Micelli, M. and Near, J. (1985) Characteristics of Sage. pp. 413–33.
organizational climate and perceived wrongdoing Pfeffer, J. (1981) Power in Organizations. Marshfield,
associated with whistleblowing, Personnel Psychol- MA: Pitman Publishing.
ogy, 38 (3): 525–44. Poole, M. (1985) Communication and organization
Morse, N. and Reimer, E. (1956) The experimental climates. In R. McPhee and P. Thompkins (eds),
change of a major organizational variable, Journal Organizational Communication: Traditional Themes
of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 52 (1): and New Directions. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
120–29. pp. 79–108.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 567

Poole, M. (1986) Industrial Relations: Origins and Pat- Schneider, B., Bowen, D.E., Ehrhart M.G. and
terns of National Diversity. London, UK: Routledge. Holcombe, K.M. (2000) ‘The climate for service:
Poole, M.S. and McPhee, R.D. (1983) A structural evolution of a construct’. In N.M. Ashkanasy,
analysis for organizational climates. In L. Putnam C.P.M. Wilderom and M.F. Peterson (eds.), Handbook
and M. Pacanowsky (eds), Communication and of Organizational Culture and Climate. London: Sage.
Organizations: An Interpretive Approach. Beverly pp. 21–36.
Hills, CA: Sage. pp. 195–220. Schneider, B. and Reichers, A. (1983) On the etiology of
Pugh, D. and Payne, R. (1977) Organizational Behavior climates, Personnel Psychology, 36 (1): 19–39.
in its Context: The Aston Programme III. Farnborough, Schneider, B. and Snyder, R. (1975) Some relationships
UK: Saxon House. between job satisfaction and organizational climate,
Redman, T. and Snape, E. (2004) Kindling activism? Journal of Applied Psychology, 60 (3): 318–28.
Union commitment and participation in the UK fire Schneider, B., White, S.and Paul, M.C. (1998) Linking
service, Human Relations, 57 (7): 845–69. service climate and customer perceptions of service
Reichers, A. and Schneider, B. (1990) Climate and cul- quality: test of a causal model, Journal of Applied
ture: an evolution of constructs. In B. Schneider (ed.), Psychology, 83 (2): 150–63.
Organizational Climate and Culture. San Francisco, Schneider, B. (ed.) (1990) Organizational Climate and
CA: Sage. pp. 5–39. Culture. San Francisco, CA: Sage.
Roberts, K., Hulin, C. and Rousseau, D. (1978) Devel- Siehl, C. and Martin, J. (1990) Organizational culture:
oping an Interdisciplinary Science of Organizations. a key to financial performance? In B. Schneider (ed.),
San Francisco, CA: Jossey Bass. Organizational Climate and Culture. San Francisco,
Ross, A. and Hartman, P. (1960) Changing Patterns of CA: Jossey-Bass. pp. 241–81.
Industrial Conflict. New York, NY: Wiley. Tagiuri, R. and Litwin, G. (1968) Organizational Climate:
Rousseau, D.M. (1985) Issues of level in organizational Exploration of a Concept. Boston, MA: Harvard
research: multi-level and cross-level perspectives. In University Press.
L.L. Cummings and B. M. Staw (eds), Research in Tetrick, L.E. and Fried, Y. (1993) Industrial relations:
Organizational Behavior, Vol. 7. Greenwich, CT: Jai. stress induction or stress reduction?, Journal of
pp. 1–37. Organizational Behavior, 14 (5): 511–35.
Rousseau, D. (1988) The construction of climate Thompson, J. (1967) Organizations in Action. New York,
in organizational research. In C. Cooper and NY: Wiley.
I. Robertson (eds), International Review of Industrial Thornicroft, K. W. (1993) Does labor climate matter?
and Organizational Psychology. Chichester, UK: 1992 Canadian Industrial Relations Association
Wiley. pp. 139–58. Proceedings. Fredericton, New Brunswick. pp. 69–81.
Schein, E.H. (2000) Sense and nonsense about Trice, H. M. and Beyer, J.M.(1993) The Cultures of Work
culture and climate. In N.M. Ashkanasy, C.P.M. Organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Wilderom and M.F. Peterson, (eds), Handbook of Trice, H. and Beyer, J. (1984) Studying organizational
organizational culture and climate. London: Sage. cultures through rites and ceremonials, Academy of
pp. xxiii–xxxiii. Management Review, 9 (4): 653–69.
Schneider, B. (1975) Organizational climate: individual Wagar, T. (1997a) Is labor-management climate
preferences and organizational realities revisited, important? Some Canadian evidence, Journal of
Journal of Applied Psychology, 60 (4): 459–65. Labor Research, XVIII (1): 163–74.
Schneider, B. (1980) The service organization: climate is Wagar, T. (1997b) The labor-management relationship
crucial, Organizational Dynamics, 9 (2): 52–65. and organization outcomes, Relations Industrielles,
Schneider, B. (1990) Organizational Climate and 52 (2): 430–46.
Cultures. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Wagar, T. and Rondeau, K. (2002) Labor-management
Schneider, B. and Bartlett, J. (1968) Individual forums and workplace performance. Evidence from
differences and organizational climate I: the research union officials in health care organizations, Journal of
plan and questionnaire development, Personnel Management in Medicine, 16 (6): 408–21.
Psychology, 21 (3): 323–33. Wan, D., Huat, O. and Yuee, L. (1997) Industrial relations
Schneider, B. and Bartlett, J. (1970) Individual differ- climate in the manufacturing sector in Singapore,
ences and organizational climate II: measurement Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 14 (2):
of organizational climate by the multitrait-multirater 123–41.
matrix, Personnel Psychology, 23 (4): 493–512. Warr, P., Fineman, S., Nicholson, N. and Payne, R. (1978)
Schneider, B. , and Bowen, D.E. (1995). Winning the Developing Employee Relations. Farnborough, UK:
Service Game. Boston, MA: Harvard Business press. Teakfield.
568 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Wu, W. and Lee, Y. (2001) Participatory management Zohar, D. (2000) A group-level model of safety climate:
and industrial relations climate: a study of Chinese, testing the effect of group climate on microaccidents
Japanese and US firms in Taiwan, Human Resource in manufacturing jobs, Journal of Applied Psychology,
Management, 12 (5): 827–44. 85 (4): 587–96.
Zohar, D. (1980) Safety climate in industrial Zohar, D. and Luria, G. (2005) A multilevel model
organizations: theoretical and applied implica- of safety climate: cross-level relationships between
tions, Journal of Applied psychology, 65 (1): organization and group-level climates, Journal of
96–102. Applied Psychology, 90 (4): 616–28.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 569

APPENDIX

Appendix 29.1 No. of items, reliability estimates, and within-organization agreement


coefficients for Workplace Industrial Relations Climate Scales
Climate scales Number Cronbach’s Within-organization
of items alpha agreement coefficient (ICC)
Fairness 6 0.926 0.904
Union-management 6 0.931 0.875
consultation
Mutual regard 3 0.947 0.943
Membership support 3 0.782 0.489
for unions
Union legitimacy 2 0.747 0.734
Average 0.789
Source: Based on Dastmalchian et al. (1991), p.85.

Appendix 29.2 Factor analysis of the Workplace Industrial Relations Climate Items (with
varimax rotation)
N = 1686 Climate items Factor Factor 2 (U/M Factor Factor 4 Factor 5
1 (fairness) consultation) 3 (mutual (member (union
regard) support) legitimacy)
1 The collective 0.611
agreement is
regarded as fair by
employees in this
organization.
2 A sense of fairness is 0.592 0.452
associated with
management
dealings in this
place.
3 In this organization, 0.519
negotiations take
place in an
atmosphere of good
faith.
4 The parties in the 0.503 0.440
organization keep
their word.
5 Employees generally 0.496
view the conditions
of their employment
here as fair.
6 Grievances are 0.436
normally settled
promptly in this
organization.
7 Unions and 0.551
management in this
organization make
sincere efforts to
solve common
problems.
(Continued )
570 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Appendix 29.2 Cont’d


N = 1686 Climate items Factor 1 Factor 2 (U/M Factor 3 Factor 4 Factor 5
(fairness) consultation) (mutual (member (union
regard) support) legitimacy)
8 Management often 0.532
seeks input from
unions before
initiating changes.
9 Management and 0.474 0.496
unions cooperate to
settle disputes in this
organization.
10 The parties exchange 0.453
information freely in
this organization.
11 There is a great deal of 0.429 0.403
concern for the other
party’s point of view
in the union-
management
relationship.
12 Joint union- 0.421
management
committees are a
common means of
implementing
important changes
in conditions.
13 Unions and 0.404 0.601
management work
together to make
this organization a
better place to work.
14 Unions and 0.596
management have
respect for each
other’s goals.
15 In this organization, 0.439
joint union-
management
committees achieve
definite results.
16 Generally, employees −0.529
do not have much
interest in the
quality of the
union-management
relationship.
17 In this organization, 0.495
unions have the
strong support of
their members.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS CLIMATE 571

Appendix 29.2 Cont’d


N = 1686 Climate items Factor 1 Factor 2 (U/M Factor 3 Factor 4 Factor 5
(fairness) consultation) (mutual (member (union
regard) support) legitimacy)
18 Unions make a positive 0.408 0.401
contribution to this
organization.
19 Shop stewards in this 0.490
organization
generally play a
helpful role.
20 People are encouraged 0.476
to get involved in
union activities here.
% Variance 37.6 44.6 49.1 53.5 57.3
Eigenvalue 9.030 1.665 1.077 1.029 0.939
Source: Dastmalchian et al. (1991), p.112.

Appendix 29.3 Tests of the overall model (path analysis)


Source: Dastmaclchian et al. (1991), p. 112.

E1=0.61
E2=0.81
Organizational 0.16
context
0.02

Workplace Industrial
Organizational Industrial relations
structure 0.45 Relations 0.46 outputs
(flexibility) Climate

−.04 0.05
0.25
HR practices
(training) IR context
(facilitative)

0.47
30
Equality at Work
Barbara Pocock

Equality – and its shadow, inequality – has of industrial relations has been built around
long been a concern in the field of industrial analysis of the practices and outcomes of a
relations (IR). Such inequality has many relationship between unequals.
fault lines and some have received more The discipline has generally characterized
attention than others. It is measured in several the terms of the employment relationship, and
different ways, most commonly through wage its outcomes, as shaped by several factors: the
outcomes, but also through differences in life- personal characteristics of workers, the prod-
term earnings in retirement income, hours of uct or service location of those who buy labor,
work, the security of employment, employee and the institutional environment in which
voice at work, and access to promotion and a their exchanges occur. These factors have
variety of other conditions and rights. distinct national characteristics and much of
Inequality is at the heart of the employment the study of IR – a great deal of it occurring
relationship. Employers and employees gen- at the national level – takes international
erally exercise unequal power, and the inequality between workers as a naturalized
outcomes of this inequality and its moderation fact. However, international inequality con-
are core concerns of employment relations, stitutes an important fault line of inequality,
including regulation to mitigate this inequal- one that has received much less attention
ity, the collective organization of workers in the field than some other sources. Wide
to ‘rebalance’ their power vis a vis their patterns of inequality exist at the international
employers, and analysis of the perpetual level between workers in different national
contest between these two sides and its systems of industrial relations, even where
outcomes as reflected in the wage/effort their effort, skill and contributions are broadly
bargain. comparable. This inequality is expressed
There are those who extract discussion through wages most obviously, but is also
of employer/employee inequality from their reflected in rights at work, safety, employment
analysis (for example, the unitarist school security and other markers of work quality.
and some proponents in human resources Workers in the footwear production zones
schools) but for the most part, the discipline of Asia are paid less than 5 per cent of the rates
EQUALITY AT WORK 573

for US and Australian workers, while workers these, and some of the theoretical insights that
in large shoe production plants in China in have been generated along the way.
February 2006 were paid US$ 0.40 per hour I focus on three aspects of inequality:
(National Labor Committee and China Labor inequality at the international level, between
Watch, February 2006). Given that the hours the top and bottom of the labor market, and
of these workers, their job security, voice gender inequality. These boundaries reflect
at work and their occupational health and my own research preoccupations rather than
safety are also very inferior, this is inequality any defensible hierarchy of disadvantage.
on an extraordinary scale, where equal pay With growing international immigration, the
for equal work has little real meaning. By question of the international movement of
any measure, such inequality in employment people, and the labor market fortunes of
outcomes deserves close analysis. However, immigrants and workers of different ethnic
the national preoccupations of IR scholars and racial origins, are of growing importance
(shaped by the national location of regulation in framing inequality. As the ILO notes ‘the
and most data collection) mean that they combined effect of global migration, the
receive all too little. redefinition of national boundaries in some
Further sources of work-based inequality parts of the world, and growing economic
lie between sub-groups of workers at national problems and inequalities have exacerbated
and regional levels, arising from their relative problems of xenophobia and racial and
labor market power, including factors like religious discrimination’ (2003, p xi)
skill, age, gender, ‘race’ and ethnicity. Some However, I put these complex questions –
of these cross international bounds: in all as well as other sources of labor market
countries, women are paid on average less inequality such as sexual preference, age and
than men, black workers less than white, perceived or actual HIV/AIDS status – to one
and there are wide gaps in most countries side in the interests of giving some depth of
between the top and the bottom of the labor discussion to other areas. It should be noted,
market. These fault lines of inequality are however, that questions of multiple sources
not so under-attended by the discipline, and of inequality at work are of growing interest
many have received a great deal of substantial in many settings, encouraging research about
and illuminating study, most significantly intersecting inequalities as well as policy pro-
inequality structured around the personal posals like single equality statutes that address
characteristics of workers. the ‘mosaic’ of inequality (Fitzpatrick, 2003).
Despite this detailed study, legitimate
critiques have been mounted of the field of
industrial relations, about its blindness to the INTERNATIONAL INEQUALITY
gendered character of the employment rela-
tionship and the embodied worker (Forrest, Wide employment-based inequalities remain
1993; Pocock, 1997; Wajcman, 2000). Much at the international level. Growing global
remains to be done to deepen analysis in trade has been accompanied by widening
the field so that it accurately analyzes this inequality between countries over recent
aspect of employment and industrial life, as decades according to the United Nations
well as other sources of inequality like those (UN), as well as within many countries
arising from immigration, ethnicity, sexual (United Nations, 2005). Work – or its
orientation and age. absence – significantly shapes these inequal-
In this chapter, I canvass the current state of ities with many citizens unable to find
empirical evidence about some of the signifi- work, or enough of it, when they want it.
cant inequalities that are expressed around and Unemployment is high in many countries
through employment relationships, the ways and as Kofi Annan puts it ‘the best anti-
in which national and international bodies poverty program is employment. And the best
have attempted to contain, moderate or redress road to economic empowerment and social
574 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

well-being lies in decent work’(Annan, 2004). industrial regulation make clear (Statement
Work can be a vehicle creating inequality by a group of Australian Industrial Relations
whilst at the same time ‘a privileged entry Academics, Workchoices Bill Submission,
point from which to liberate society from 2005).
discrimination’ (ILO, 2003). The question of the true relationship
Around the world young people are espe- between employment regulation (sometimes
cially affected by high levels of unem- characterized as ‘flexibility’) and employment
ployment. Despite growing attention to the creation is critical in relation to inequality
importance of transitional labor markets created through work. The nature of the trade-
and the need to develop institutions which off remains controversial. Richard Freeman’s
smooth transitions like that from education recent analysis finds that ‘the best summary
to work (Schmid, 1995), some transitions, of the data – what we really know – is that
especially for groups like youth, remain labor institutions reduce earnings inequality
hazardous in many countries. In 2005 young but that they have no clear relation to other
people made up around 47 per cent of the aggregate outcomes, such as unemployment’
186 million unemployed people worldwide (Freeman, 2005). Such institutions include,
(United Nations, 2005). Unemployment is for example, minimum wage legislation or
increasingly accompanied in many countries tribunals, active trade unions and industrial
by growth in informal employment with relations mediators or tribunals. The OECD
very limited effective labor market regulation. have also recently agreed that ‘a considerable
Once again, young people are especially number of studies’ have found that evidence
affected. of an adverse impact of minimum wages
Debates about employment generation on employment is ‘modest or non-existent’
have fueled an ongoing debate between inter- and that there may be positive effects of
national agencies about the trade-offs between minimum wages ‘as one part of employment-
regulation of minimal labor standards on the centered social policy intended to mitigate
one hand and employment and economic poverty while fostering high employment
growth on the other. These debates have reso- rates’ (OECD, 2006).
nance in domestic politics and policy settings Scholars in employment studies have
in many countries. The IMF has argued that increasingly turned their attention to the issue
regulation of employment relations through of informal and precarious employment as it
minimum wages, unemployment payments has grown apace, partly explaining the growth
and employment security rights distort the in the working poor and widening inter-
market for labor and depress growth whilst national inequality. Individual and household
increasing unemployment (IMF, 2003). On poverty – once certainly alleviated by entry to
the other side of this international duel, the formal employment – is now growing in many
ILO has promoted core labor standards and locations around the world. A large majority
regulation for ‘decent work’. of the working poor are in precarious or
This debate is sometimes cast as a contest informal employment outside the agricultural
between the regulation of work and its sector, most of them in developing countries.
deregulation in favor of market forces. This According to UN estimates, in 2000 over
is an inaccurate characterization in countries 1,100 million people were living in absolute
like Australia where current reforms are poverty on less than a dollar a day. While
re-regulatory, designed to constrain and con- this is down from 1,237 million 10 years
strict past practices of collective bargaining earlier, mostly through reductions in poverty
and national and industry minima, and to in China and India, the numbers of very poor
make strikes, collective organization, rising rose during the decade to 2000 in sub-Saharan
minimum wages and protection against unfair Africa, Europe and Central Asia, and Latin
dismissal more difficult. This is hardly America and the Caribbean (by 82, 14 and
‘deregulation’ as thousands of pages of new 8 million respectively (United Nations, 2005).
EQUALITY AT WORK 575

These changes, along with growth in the supplemented since 1998, with the adoption
number of highly paid, help explain widening of four fundamental labor standards that ILO
income inequalities in many countries. These members are expected to support: freedom
have seen the ratio of the income of the richest of association (including the right of workers
10 per cent of the world’s population increase to collectively organize and bargain), the
from 20 times that of the poorest 10 per cent abolition of forced labor, equality at work,
in 1994, to 29 times in 2004 (United Nations, and the elimination of child labor. The
2005). Even amongst the majority of higher ILO system of exhortation and advocacy
income countries, gross earnings inequality but weak ‘name and shame’ powers of
widened in the decade to 2006 – and at a enforcement has restricted the capacity of
faster pace that the widening that occurred such international agencies to stem widening
in the previous decade. Further, ‘a persistent international employment-based inequalities.
increase in the proportion of the working poor’ Increasing earnings at the top end of the labor
is evident in OECD countries widened in the market in many countries, and continuing
decade to 2006 (2006: 38–40). inequalities in wage rates between countries,
International inequality is not, of course means that the international focus on minimal
confined to incomes and wages, but also can standards has had little effect on narrowing
be seen in the polarization around ‘good’ and inequality either between nations or within
‘bad’ jobs and around levels of skills. Wage them.
differentials in many countries have been However, such attempts have at least given
widening between those with qualifications legitimacy to the notion that the employment
and those without (Ocampo, 2002; United relationship, in all its inequality, cannot
Nations, 2005). be left to the market and that minimal
While the ILO holds as its founding rights should exist. That said, established
principle the notion that labor is not a employment standards in many countries
commodity and that the terms of its exchange are under powerful downward pressure and
should be regulated and moderated, growth in some countries count for little – and
in precarious employment and in forms not just in developing countries. The ILO’s
of employment that are outside traditional Committee on the Application of Standards
employer/employee contracts has seen a is currently investigating Australia alongside
recommodification of labor on terms that Burma, Zimbabwe, Saudi Arabia, Nepal
are regulated only lightly, if at all. The and Colombia for labor standard breaches.
consequences for inequality are significant. Indeed this committee has previously said
For example, in Australia the proportion of that Australia’s federal industrial law does
workers employed as ‘casuals’ (that is, on an not adequately protect from discrimination
hourly hour contract with few formal rights workers who choose to bargain collectively,
and little job security at least in formal legal a fundamental right according to the ILO.
terms) has risen to over a quarter of the Further, more radical changes to Australian
workforce at present (Campbell, 2000). This law in March 2006 create new grounds
employment form allows employers to closely for investigation in relation to the minimal
match their purchases of labor to production standards embodied in the ILO fundamental
needs, but reduces those selling their labor standards (Burrow, 2005).
to commodity status rather than assuring Since 1999 employment analysts, including
workers of a predictable, regular income or a at the ILO, have turned their attention to the
‘living’wage. This has important implications issue of ‘decent work’, widening policy goals
for the dignity of labor and social reproduction from inequalities located around access to
(Pocock et al., 2004). work to a broader discussion of the quality
The traditional ILO approach of setting of work and the opportunities it creates.
minimum standards through tripartite agree- Questions of the security of work, and the
ment, which countries then ratify, has been conditions attached to it, are of critical
576 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

importance to a full discussion of equality modest increases in earnings and profit in


at work (Sennett, 1998; Standing, 2002). many FTSE companies (Froud et al., 2006).
The ILO’s decent work agenda has several The ratio is much wider in the US, with CEO
strategic objectives: the provision for all of a pay in 2002, 281 times the rate of ordinary
productive job for fair pay; security and social workers up from 50 times in 1980 (Elliott,
protection; freedom of organization and voice 2006). In Australia, the average pay of chief
and equal opportunities for women (ILO, executives in 2005 reached 63 times that
1999). The ‘decent work’ focus of the ILO of average workers compared to 18 times
responds to the outcomes of globalization and in 1989/90 (based on the earnings of Chief
its effects on employment, social disruption Executive who are members of the Business
and inequality (Ghai, 2002). It has profound Council of Australia (Shields, 2005)).
implications for issues like working time and This widening chasm between the top
the larger work/effort bargain (Boulin et al., and bottom of pay scales occurs as greater
2006; Messenger, 2004). dispersion in earnings generally characterizes
pay outcomes in many locations in indus-
trialized countries (OECD, 2006). Attention
INEQUALITY BETWEEN THE TOP to inequality through employment in this
AND BOTTOM environment has generally focused upon
the minimum wage and containing poverty
Guy Standing has observed that the post- through small or larger movements in base
1945 era in many industrializing countries rates. There is an accepted linkage between
was an ‘egalitarian age’ when policy to the characteristics of employment relations
narrow inequality through the regulation of systems and their effects on wages and
employment as well as the provision of other industrial outcomes for workers in
welfare support was seen as a valid goal different countries as well as groups of
(Standing, 1999). However, since the 1980s workers such as women (Rodgers and Rubery,
policy attention and discourse has moved 2003). Richardson concludes in a recent
away from direct discussion of inequality survey that this relationship is now widely
to analysis of ‘exclusion’, the basic premise confirmed with ‘clear evidence of the US,
being concern about those left behind or UK, Australia, New Zealand and several
excluded, not the comparison between top European countries that changes in the level
and bottom. Analysts of the social effects of minimum wages are directly inversely
of inequality however, argue that there are correlated with the level of wage inequality’
specific social consequences of widening and ‘where minimum wages fall, inequality
inequality, much of it driven by changes increases and where it falls by a lot, inequality
at work, that are independent of growth in increases by a lot’ (Richardson, 2005). She
poverty alone (Wilkinson, 2005). points to the growth in low paid jobs in most
Interestingly, just as this focus on the English-speaking member countries in recent
excluded base strengthens, drawing attention years. The OECD suggests that rises have
away from analysis of the top and the bottom been especially sharp in the past decade in
and the gap between them, these gaps are Germany (reaching 15.8 per cent in 2003/04),
widening – in some cases on a breathtaking Hungary (24.4 per cent), the Netherlands
scale. This inequality is observable both (16.6 per cent), Poland (22.1 per cent) and the
between countries and within them. In the UK UK (23.4 per cent). Levels are also high in the
for example, inequality in the labor market has US (23.3 per cent) (OECD, 2006 (see Statlink
widened dramatically. In 1979 UK executives to Table 5.7)).
earned around ten times the pay of typical Awareness of the effects of different
British workers but by 2002 executives of a industrial systems and their implications for
FTSE company earned, on average, 54 times inequality is ‘relatively rare’ according to
the pay of such workers, despite only very some (Almond and Rubery, 1998). This lack
EQUALITY AT WORK 577

of awareness can result in important policy longitudinal dynamics of low pay, and the
disconnects: for example, European Union relationships between individual pay rates,
(EU) activities to constrain minimum wages taxes, benefits and household income (OECD,
and contract the public sector to meet 2006).
Maastricht convergence criteria in the 1990s Some international agencies would like to
ran counter to the EU policy goal of pro- see policies to moderate inequality (where
viding equal opportunities in all its activities they see them as necessary at all) located out-
(Almond and Rubery, 1998; Rubery, 2002). In side national employment systems. However,
contrast, the British move to create and lift the employment primarily shapes social and eco-
minimum wage was deliberately adopted as a nomic standing for many citizens and is likely
means of increasing gender pay equity, and to do so for a long time. Having a job, a career
it did so with two-thirds of the beneficiaries and an identity through work are important
of its 2004 increases being women (Low Pay signifiers of social status and citizenship, as
Commission, 2005). well as sources of independence, dignity,
Employment and industrial relations anal- pleasure and income. While this remains the
ysis in general has established a connection case, employment remains a primary engine
between industrial systems and the equity of of inequality.
their outcomes. Systems providing relatively While international attention to narrowing
higher minimal wage protection, greater inequality has waned in many countries,
levels of centralism, collective instruments particular groups have been affected in
of pay setting and collective forms of consistent and negative ways by changes at
worker representation, wider coverage of work and I now turn to these. The effects
different types of employees and effective of the engine of inequality are not randomly
enforcement of standards and agreements, are distributed.
generally associated with narrower dispersion
of outcomes and a lower level of inequality.
Such institutional arrangements and systems LOW PAY AND INEQUALITY
mediate the operation of raw power imbal-
ances in the labor market that otherwise see The problem of low pay has been a cen-
poorer outcomes for weak or disadvantaged tral concern of employment analysis and
individuals or groups of workers. inequality with general consensus that some
Increasingly those who wish to understand form of regulation is necessary to ensure
employment-based inequalities must under- that the most disadvantaged citizens do not
stand the intersections between pay rates find themselves in employment relationships
and social security systems. Earned income with unacceptable pay rates. While there
tax credits (or their equivalent) mean that are a variety of ways of defining low pay
inequality analysis must now encompass both (see for example the discussion of Berstein
the work and social security spheres and and Hartmann (2000) in the US) the ILO
cannot be understood only from an industrial conventionally define it as around 60 per cent
relations or workplace perspective. Critics of of the median wage.
wage supplements through the tax or welfare Four issues have recently received attention
system make the point that such income in relation to low pay: one is the perennial
supplements effectively subsidize low wage issue of the relationship between level of
jobs and create positive incentives for their minimum wages and employment which I
expansion and continuity, thus significantly have referred to, second is the issue of
shaping employment and industrial outcomes. labor market mobility and the opportunity for
Clearly the field of industrial relations has transitions out of low paid work, third is the
increasing incentive to understand the phe- issue of whether low pay afflicts individuals
nomena of labor market churning between or households, and fourth is the need to take
low paid jobs and welfare systems, the a broader look at the dimensions of ‘bad’
578 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

jobs beyond hourly pay, including especially to the argument about the trade off between
the number of hours of employment, their high minima and employment. While the
security, work safety and the nature of initial UK minimum was set cautiously,
working time. its gradual improvement in recent years
For many workers, low hourly rates are has been accompanied by strong growth in
compounded by limited labor mobility and employment, including in sectors where the
a small number of paid working hours, as low paid are concentrated. Rates for the low
well as poor working-time predictability and paid have risen faster than average wages,
job security. Defining low pay at the level but employment growth has continued to be
of the household rather than the individual robust and inflation low, allowing the Low Pay
has important implications for individual Commission to claim their interventions as a
autonomy. As Almond and Rubery have ‘great success’ (Low Pay Commission, 2005).
pointed out defining social justice at the level In other countries the effect of minimum
of the household rather than the individual wages remains rather more contentious. Low
‘undermines the case for equal pay and minima are, however, incontrovertibly linked
is indeed inimical to gender quality at a to persistent employment-based inequality.
more general level … and tantamount to For example, in the US, the federal minimum
putting employment rights at the level of wage has remained at around US$ 5.15 per
the household rather than the individual’ hour since 1997 (http://www.dol.gov/esa/
(1998: 676). As these writers observe such minwage/america.htm), contributing to growth
an approach is most common in countries in the working poor and high levels of
where the remnants of the male-breadwinner employment-based inequality in that country.
wage model are strong, as in Australia. They Australia has traditionally had both relatively
are also resurgent at moments of political high minimum wage rates and until the
conservatism. late 1980s a relatively centralized system
Low pay around the world affects par- of industrial relations. As in Sweden, these
ticular groups of workers, with an over- arrangements have been associated with low
representation of women, immigrant, low dispersion in earnings and relatively more
skilled, young and disabled workers amongst equal societies (including in relation to gender
their number (Richardson, 2005). In indus- equity as I discuss below). Since the late
trialized nations, low pay especially affects 1980s, both Labor and conservative national
workers in the service sectors most notably Governments in Australia have facilitated
in the retail sector. For example, in the a move away from centralized wage
UK around three-quarters of the six million fixing towards enterprise-based bargaining,
jobs that are low paid are in the retail and albeit in the presence of a national and
hospitality sectors (Low Pay Commission, regularly updated minimum wage. Widening
2005). dispersion in wage outcomes has been the
Low pay can be countered through strong result (Saunders, 2005). Since 1996, this
collective bargaining or minimum wage de-centralization has been extended through
arrangements that extend the results of a push towards individual bargaining in
collective bargains to categories of workers the presence of lowered general minimum
(Almond and Rubery, 1998). The gradual con- standards. Very substantial legislative
traction of the reach of collective bargaining changes in March 2006 further restructure
instruments to workers in growth sectors like Australia’s minimum wage system, encourage
the services sector has led some countries to more individual contracts, lower minimum
adopt wage minima as a means of protecting employment standards again, and focus a new
the low paid. ‘Fair Pay Commission’ upon the economic
Initiatives like the establishment of a outcomes of minimum changes rather than
national minimum wage in Britain in April fairness. The outcomes are likely to include
1999 provide interesting evidence in relation widening wages dispersion.
EQUALITY AT WORK 579

GENDER INEQUALITY is usually lower while it tends to be wider


in decentralized systems where the market
Gender inequality is an international fact of exercises greater effect (Gregory et al., 1989).
employment life. Whilst its dimensions vary, Overall reductions in wages dispersion are
women’s disadvantage at work is profound generally associated with a lower gender pay
around the world. Key outcomes that have gap (Blau and Kahn, 1996a). Higher levels
been of interest to feminist analysis for of inequality are generally associated with
decades include the questions of gender pay the Anglo-Saxon ‘firm-based voluntaristic
gaps, the gender segregation of the labor systems’ and the lowest with ‘solidaris-
market, the sexual division of labor and tic bargaining’ as in the Nordic countries
the devaluation of women’s work and skill (Almond and Rubery, 1998, p. 689). The kinds
(Bradley, 1998; Reskin and Padavic, 1994). of decentralized fragmented systems of the
Existing data show that both gendered US, Canada and the UK have traditionally
pay gaps and vertical and horizontal gender been associated with relatively wide gender
segregation remain entrenched with women pay gaps. The weakening of Australia’s
confined to a relatively narrow range of centralized system of wage fixing has been
occupations, industries and levels in many associated with widening inequality in wages
places. Unemployment rates are higher for outcomes for workers, including in relation
women than men in many countries and to gender (Heiler et al., 1999; Whitehouse,
women are disproportionately concentrated 2001). However, understanding gender pay
amongst the hidden unemployed (ILO, 2003). gaps requires a more disaggregated analysis
While the nature and trajectory of these than broad averaged ratios allow, given that
indicators varies from country to country, very different outcomes can be experienced
the gender comparison remains consistently by different groups of workers across the
against women. pay spectrum as several writers make clear
(Bruegel and Perrons, 1998; Whitehouse,
2001).
Pay inequality
Beyond the nature of pay fixing systems
Gender inequality is measured in persistent broadly, powerful cultures of direct and
pay differentials, and scholars in the field indirect discrimination, under-valuation of
of industrial relations have been particularly traditional feminized skills and cultures of
attentive to this issue (Wajcman, 2000). traditional motherhood and femininity help
These gaps have narrowed in many countries explain wider gender pay gaps in places like
but far from all, despite women’s rapid Japan, though they are far from irrelevant in
increase in qualifications and experience. In many other countries as well (Appelbaum,
countries like Britain, women at the top 2002; ILO, 2003).
of the female employment hierarchy have Industrial systems – and wage bargaining
increased the ratio of their earnings to average in particular – are shaped by many factors
male incomes and this has resulted in greater and gender equality is not high on the list of
gender pay equity overall, while at the same framing ideas. However, these systems and
time widening inequality between women. their characteristics have important effects
This reflects the fact that in most countries on gender outcomes. This has made the
women are concentrated in low status jobs study of pay systems, the level at which
that are poorly paid (Bruegel and Perrons, bargaining occurs (individual, firm, industry),
1998). and the nature and pervasiveness of minimum
The nature of industrial regulation is standards of considerable interest to those
viewed as very important in explaining gender trying to understand and remediate gender
pay gaps. Where bargaining is centralized inequality.
(either through legislated systems or patterns Evidence suggests that the presence of
of collective bargaining), the gender pay gap properly enforced minimum wage systems
580 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

have important effects on gender and negative employment effects (Low Pay
broader inequality. For example, over the Commission, 2005). Similarly, workers with
past 15 years economic restructuring in many work-limiting disabilities have been affected
Central and Eastern European countries has positively.
been associated with very significant falls in
earnings for both women and men. In the case
Participation rates and a supportive
of the UK Low Pay Commission, as I have
work/care regime
noted, most of those benefiting from sizeable
increases in minimum wages are women Participation rates of women have been
workers (Low Pay Commission, 2005). In increasing in most countries in the past three
Australia, increases in minimum wages help decades, with some exceptions; for example,
explain the unchanging gender pay gap in the in the transition economies of Europe and
presence of more decentralized bargaining. areas of sub-Saharan Africa (ILO, 2003).
Studies comparing the relative roles of However, participation rates vary widely
anti-discrimination measures vs. centralized from country to country reflecting in sig-
mechanisms suggest that anti-discrimination nificant part the adequacy of support for
measures are relatively ineffective in nar- workers who are also carers – most of
rowing the gender pay gap compared to the whom are women. Jaumotte (2004) analyzes
effects of more centralized systems (Kidd and participation rates in 17 OECD countries
Meng, 1997). This partly reflects the more over the period 1985–1999 controlling for
generalized effects of system-wide measures education, proportion of married women,
like minimum wage increases compared to number of children and overall labor market
the weaker more partial ripples that might conditions. She finds that the determinants
flow from individual, complaint-based, anti- of participation include the flexibility of
discrimination cases. working-time arrangements, the taxation of
second earners, childcare subsidies, child
benefits and paid parental leave. Employment-
based supports like leave and employee
THE CONTAGIOUS EFFECTS OF say over working time arrangements help
MINIMUM WAGE PROTECTION: shape participation rates and affect under-
GENDER, RACE AND ETHNICITY employment and hidden unemployment.
Their absence constructs gender inequality
Some US evidence suggests that the ‘racial and closes down true choice for women
pay penalty’ is higher for black men than around their labor market participation. They
black women (Bayard et al., 1999). Further also have important policy significance. For
that it is greater for men at the top of example, Jaumotte calculates that providing
the employment hierarchy than towards the a neutral tax environment for second earners,
bottom, and increases with levels of educa- higher tax incentives to share paid work and
tion (ILO, 2003). However, evidence differs an increase in public childcare spending to
from country to country about the complex the highest level obtaining in the OECD
intersections of ethnicity, race and gender and would lift participation rates by an average
the impact on employment outcomes (ILO, of ten percentage points in OECD countries
2003). (2004: 12–15). This analysis is reinforced
Minimum wage protections have some by recent analysis of work and family in a
important effects for groups beyond women. number of OECD countries (OECD, 2002,
For example, in the UK low paid ethnic 2003, 2003, 2005). These studies show that
minorities have benefited from the min- high rates of female labor market participation
imum wage law, especially workers of and high fertility rates are possible in countries
Bangladeshi and Pakistani background, and that implement effective care, leave and
these groups have suffered no obvious tax/benefit policies (OECD, 2006)
EQUALITY AT WORK 581

Rapid expansion in precarious forms of male partner, tea-towel in hand. This deeply
employment has occurred in many countries, inscribed sexual division of labor continues
simultaneous with women’s rising participa- to shape women’s place at work (Williams,
tion (Fudge and Owens, 2006). In Australia 2000).
and Spain – the extreme cases in the OECD –
over a quarter of the workforce is now
employed on casual or limited term contracts.
Women (and youths) are disproportionately CONCEPTUALIZING GENDER
concentrated in these forms of employment. INEQUALITY IN THE FIELD OF
In Australia 42 per cent of all women work INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
part-time (surpassed in the OECD only by
the Netherlands with 61 per cent) (OECD, Not surprisingly gender inequality has been a
2006), and these jobs are associated with high concern of scholars in the field of industrial
levels of insecurity with two-thirds of part- relations for some years. Wajcman (2000)
time jobs being casual (Pocock et al., 2004a). argues that this concern and the sophistication
In addition, voluntary part-time employment of its analysis has been led by feminist schol-
has grown significantly and now affects many ars largely outside the discipline of industrial
women (ILO, 2002). relations. However, the necessity to locate
In sum, over recent decades women across analysis of employment within the larger
the world have joined men in paid work schema of households and social systems
and found economic security through their has now been more widely acknowledged
employment, as well as enjoyment, social (Hyman quoted in Hantrais andAckers, 2005).
connection and a sense of contribution. The growing feminization of the workforce
However, on most measures they continue to necessitates such a larger analysis, given the
be disadvantaged relative to men, not least very different household locations of women
in relation to their disproportionate share over the life cycle and the depressing effect
of unpaid work. Time use surveys in many that having children creates upon women’s
countries record that women do twice as earnings, especially in countries with con-
much domestic work as men on average, servative welfare states and strong traditions
and their growing role at paid work has of maternal childcare and domesticity like
been met with little change on the domestic Germany (see for example Lehndorff, 2006;
front (for Australian evidence, for example, Klammer, 2005). Women’s growing presence
see Baxter 2002 and for Swedish evidence at work disrupts the comfortable assumptions
see Lundberg 2002, SCB 1991, 2002). In of male norms and advantage (Eveline, 1994)
Australia there are few signs that men are which lie at the centre of the workplace even
on average increasing their unpaid labor if this has all too little disruptive effect upon
very significantly. The hours women spend the material effects of these norms.
on unpaid domestic work remain at around At the same time, the significant contribu-
double those of men (33 hours on average a tions of women and men writing from within
week compared to men’s 17 in 1997 (ABS, the discipline of industrial relations – criti-
1999)). While men are spending a few minutes cizing its blind spots and ‘bolt on’ approach
more a week on childcare, women are turning to gender analysis – have been increas-
to the market to find relief from their overwork ing in number (Ackers, 2002; Cockburn,
(buying in many services and prepared meals) 1991; Dickens,1999; Forrest, 1993; Hantrais
or lowering their domestic standards. The and Ackers, 2005; Pocock, 1997; Wajcman,
decline of the breadwinner household in many 2000).
countries where women’s participation in paid Several tensions are evident in research
work – as in many other countries – has and policy around gender inequality at work:
increased rapidly in three decades has not been tension between legislation pursuing negative
matched by the rise of a sensitive new age duties vs. legislation in favor of positive
582 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

duties; tensions between focus on inequality a vital component of action but is far from
vs. focus on diversity management and ten- an adequate basis for gender-based equality,
sion between specific direct action in response creating strong arguments for more aggressive
to inequality versus ‘mainstreaming’. Each models of positive action.
of these pairings is not necessarily mutually As a result governments in several countries
exclusive, and some like Dickens favor a have taken further steps to establish ‘positive
multiple response including for example, duties’ in relation to inequality, including
state legislative action, union initiatives and regular audits of employment in larger
voluntary employer action (Dickens, 1999). companies (as in Australia). However, these
However, it is analytically helpful to consider positive duties have very variable traction
these differences. in relation to systemic inequality, depending
upon the nature and effect of penalties and
enforcement, and upon the changing polit-
Negative duties versus positive
ical environment. For example, Australia’s
action
experimentation with affirmative action –
Initially much concern around women’s always confined to the public sector and larger
disadvantage was focused on discrimination companies – has been in hasty retreat in
against women (especially in relation to recent years (Summers, 2004) and was always
unequal pay and gender segregation by weakly enforced through paltry penalties.
occupation). This resulted in early legal Alongside the positive actions of some
initiatives to create a ‘negative duty’ not to governments, some unions have adopted
discriminate on the basis of sex. These impor- more assertive positive measures in relation
tant laws generally enable individual women to women or other groups, including the
to seek legal remedies to discrimination and organization of supported causes of particular
harassment. Unfortunately these mechanisms groups, affirmative action positions, leader-
are all too infrequently exercised by lower ship quotas and so on, (Colgan and Ledwith,
paid, lower status or non-unionized women. 2002). These have not been uncommon in
Despite 30 years of anti-discrimination the UK, Canada and Australia though they
legislation in countries like the US, Australia, are less obvious in the US. Similarly, some
Britain and many others, gender inequal- employers have moved well ahead of their
ity remains wide. Legal measures creating legislative obligations to create advanced paid
negative duties were always seen by many leave, childcare, leadership development and
as inadequate to the systemic nature of other positive actions. They remain in the
discrimination, and so they have proved. ‘An minority in most places, however, although
indispensable first step’, as the ILO (2003) many companies now have some kind of
characterizes them, they have not shifted deep policy. Two-thirds of UK organizations had an
seated sources of inequality, and this can be equality or diversity policy targeting race and
said of such laws whether focused upon single gender in 1998 (Cully et al., 1999). By the time
grounds of discrimination as in the UK or var- of the 2004 Workplace Employment Relations
ious grounds as in Australia. Discrimination Survey, 96 per cent of larger UK workplaces
legislation has not had the effect of stamping (with 100 employees or more) had an equal
out the raw expression of discrimination opportunity policy and most unionized and
through behaviors like sexual harassment: in public sector workplaces had such policies
1993, 54 per cent of British women reported (compared to 63 per cent of workplaces
experiencing sexual harassment at work but without recognized unions (Kersley et al.,
only 5 per cent had ever made a complaint 2005)). Of course such policy is a long way
(Institute of Employment Rights, 2003). The from action (see for example Wajcman, 1998).
individual complaint-based legislative road ‘Equal opportunities’ policies essentially
to equality has proved slow and personally seek treatment of women on a par with men:
expensive for many complainants. It remains that is, without discrimination. This analysis
EQUALITY AT WORK 583

implicitly accepts male norms, which place physical abilities – alongside gender – under
women as ‘disadvantaged’. Greater aware- the rubric of ‘diversity’.
ness and critique of ‘male advantage’ at work In policy terms, this line of analysis aligns
and the normalization of male advantage in itself with human resources policies and prac-
practical terms in workplace and labor market tices that recognize and celebrate diversity at
cultures entered the literature in the 1990s, work, and promulgate adaption to them as
along with greater awareness about male resis- a source of profit and potential competitive
tance to female workers and their progress advantage at the enterprise level, especially
(Cockburn, 1991; Eveline, 1994). This line where the costs of recruitment and high labor
of analysis takes power differences, based turnover are high or labor shortages loom.
significantly around gender, as core concerns Not surprisingly this individualistic approach
that cannot be disrupted by individual women to ‘diversity’ is especially promulgated by
or by ‘weak’ equal opportunity measures, managers. Its origins lie mostly within the US
but require significant positive measures and (Green et al., 2005). Nonetheless the diversity
the remaking of workplace norms to meet literature and policy approach has grown in
women’s difference (Appelbaum, 2002). This significance beyond the US to parts of Europe
‘sameness/difference’ debate encourages a and Australia amongst other countries.
shift from discourses of ‘equality with men’, Green et al. define ‘diversity’at three levels:
to new terms that recognize the different as a mere descriptor of the workforce (diverse
realities of women (Bacchi, 1990). This line for example, in its gender, ethnicity, age
of analysis insists that care work is work and disability), as a particular management
(a ‘powerfully subversive’ notion as Standing approach (which values a diverse workforce
recognizes (2002: 268)), that understanding in order to make the best of it), and as
the sexual division of labor is vital to making a theoretical approach which moves away
sense of paid work, and that the terms of paid from traditional liberal or radical analysis
work need radical reform. of disadvantage defined around groups and
finding equality between them, to a theoretical
interest in the individual and multiple social
Enter diversity management
identities (Green et al., 2005). They go on to
Conceptual differences have shaped policy point out that diversity policies can occur as
proposals, ranging from the moderate anti- individualizing responses, or deal with diver-
discrimination legislative reforms mentioned sity at the group level within a more conven-
above through to recommendations for more tional equal opportunity approach oriented to
general transformations of the terms of address a broader set of social characteristics.
work, including the redistribution of unpaid They note that different social actors (unions,
labor. The more individualistic focus on employers, government), employ discourses
discrimination was generally advanced by around diversity with more or less enthusiasm
liberal claimants and included employers, and at different levels of meaning in different
government and some unions. Others who countries. For example, UK unions remain
argued for greater systemic responses to skeptical about the individualized policies
deeply embedded gendered orders, recreated of managerially-led diversity initiatives that
through both paid and unpaid work and do not come to grips with deep structural
industrial life, included feminists and activists inequalities around gender and class, while
within the labor movement who sought more Danish unionists are much more comfortable
collective responses to employment inequities with diversity management.
rooted in class as well as gender. Essentially the diversity movement takes
More recently there have been further shifts different forms in different hands. Union
in direction. One focus is towards analysis of movements in many countries facing declin-
equalities located around a broader range of ing union density recognize that they must
characteristics including ethnicity, race and appeal to the diversity of the workforce,
584 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

directly addressing the needs of women, along with the astonishing resilience of the
immigrants, skilled and unskilled and eth- gendered division of domestic labor (Bittman
nically diverse workers. Many recognize and Pixley, 1997). In policy terms this line of
diversity as a meaningful descriptor and their thinking continues the argument for structural
policies also reflect this. At the same time in and systemic responses to women’s difference
countries with declining birth rates and the from men (rather than the need for mere equal
prospect of labor market shortages, unionists treatment). It has led to a greater focus on work
readily mobilize notions of diversity and and family in industrial relations literature.
making the best of the workforce to secure In many countries work and family issues
traction for better workplace outcomes for draw into discussion some of the core ideas of
their members, actual and potential. However, employment relations, including the nature of
they do not support human resources policies working time and regulation, as well as the
that deliberately appeal to individual workers provision of rest and leave (OECD, 2006).
in order to draw them away from collective New critical issues also emerge including
mobilization on the promise of an individual the nature of care regimes provided by the
solution to discrimination or pay inequity or state, employers, the family and the larger
other sources of inequality. community. For example, the existence of
The ‘bottom line’ arguments for diversity quality, accessible, affordable childcare is a
have developed some traction in some larger vital work support for many workers (OECD,
companies in particular. However, in many 2005b).
settings the connection between profits and Analysis of ‘work and family’ issues and
fair practices is hard to measure within a the uneasy reconciliation of the two in many
time frame that has operational meaning. countries has spawned a significant strain
In some studies of motivations for good of employment analysis (Harrington, 1999;
equal opportunity or ‘diversity’ practices, the Hochschild, 1997; Pocock, 2003; Williams,
commitment of a management ‘champion’ 2000). Some gender experts in the field of
(who sees fair treatment and even positive industrial relations regret the softening of
action as simply the right thing to do) is much a direct focus on women that this growth
more significant to their adoption than any in work and family interest constitutes,
bottom line argument, and indeed in many with the category ‘women’ subsumed within
locations managers do not make any real the maternal identity. This focus is only
cost/benefit calculation about the merit of likely to increase in strength, however, as
equal opportunity or diversity management policy regimes in industrialized countries,
before taking action (Charlesworth et al., at least, come to grips with rising rates of
2005). female participation in paid work, a growing
By contrast, another stream of gender dependence upon the productive contribution
analysis at work has focused on the embodied of women and the prospect of an aging
nature of gendered identities and the substan- workforce and labor supply shortages (OECD,
tive and ethereal practices of ‘doing gender’ 2006). While trends like lower birth rates
at work and at home, with the latter sphere do not affect all countries evenly (the US
significantly shaping the possibilities for both being the outstanding case in the OECD
women and men in the former (Williams, area), these issues will remain significant
2000). This strain of analysis makes it policy concerns in many locations and are
increasingly evident that gendered realities at likely to continue as a significant strain of
work cannot be understood – or changed – industrial research, if only because of their
without careful attention to the embodied connection to core employment concerns
experience of the worker (increasingly selling like an adequate supply of suitably skilled
her emotional labor and physicality – her workers. While the goal of gendered equality
thinness, her prettiness, her smilingness) and might remain a concern for feminist analysts
the conditioning possibilities of household life in the field of industrial relations, adapting the
EQUALITY AT WORK 585

terms of employment to better accommodate work, conflict over its terms and the outcomes
women workers and relieve their double of that conflict – especially in relation to
day of paid and unpaid work, as well as wages. It has traveled a great distance since.
the discrimination which holds them back Understanding industrial life now demands
occupationally or financially, is now more a broad canvass that encompasses wages,
motivated by labor market factors than any working time, employment security, control
devotion to alleviating gender inequality per over ‘flexibility’, paid and unpaid leave
se. This may not be all bad for the gender and the nature of the employment contract
equality objective. itself.
In understanding these questions, inequal-
ity remains of considerable theoretical and
empirical importance, although the axes
INEQUALITY AT WORK: WHAT HAVE of analysis of inequality have multiplied,
WE LEARNED? WHAT MORE DO WE morphed and now often intersect in complex
NEED TO KNOW? ways. Understanding inequality at work today
demands analysis of both the top and bottom
Some important quandaries have arisen of the labor market, comparing the relative
for scholars in the field. Looking ahead, experiences of high and low paid workers
inequality seems likely to remain a central and the factors that shape them – at both the
fissure in the world of industrial relations, national and international levels. This analysis
and scholars that ignore it handicap their must increasingly also embrace consideration
analysis and its relevance. There are signs of the embodied character of the worker
in some industrialized countries – at the including their gender, ethnicity/‘race’ and/or
policy level at least – that concern about disability.
unemployment and economic growth threaten
to crowd out attention to policy and research
about inequality, especially around gender, REFERENCES
race and ethnicity. However, there are few
signs that these categories of analysis do ABS (1999) How Australians Use Their Time. Cat No
not, and will not, remain important lines of 4153.0. Canberra, ABS.
both empirical and theoretical significance. Ackers, P. (2002) ‘Reframing employment relations: The
Indeed the feminization of paid work, and case for neo-pluralism.’ Industrial Relations Journal
33 (1): 2–19.
the growing and complex flows of labor
Almond and Rubery (1998) ‘The gender pay impact
across national borders, makes the pursuit of
of recent European trends in wage determination.’
gender and ethnicity/‘race’ issues of growing Work, Employment and Society 12 (4): 675–93.
importance in the field of industrial relations. Annan, K. (2004) ‘Secretary-General affirms com-
Inequality is also increasingly shaped by mitment to achieving fair, inclusive globalization
changes in employment that, for exam- in remarks to headquarters event,’ Press Release,
ple, decollectivize employment relationships, SG/SM/9487 , DEV/2487 New York, United Nations.
create new large groups of informal and Appelbaum, E. (2002) ‘Introductory Remarks: Shared
insecure workers, and foster increasingly work/valued care: New norms for organizing market
porous boundaries around the wage/effort work and unpaid care work. The Future of Work,
bargain and especially working time. In fact, Employment and Social Protection: The dynamics of
change and the protection of workers.’ P. Auer and
analysis of each of these cannot proceed in a
P. Gazier. Geneva, International Institute for Labour
thorough way without attention to the ways in
Studies. ILO.
which they exacerbate and shape employment Bacchi, C. L. (1990) Same difference: Feminism and
inequality and are gendered (Fagan et al., sexual difference. Sydney: Allen & Unwin.
2006). Baxter, J. (2002) ‘Patterns of Change and Stability in the
Industrial relations began its scholarly life Gender Division of Labour in Australia, 1986–1997.’
preoccupied with the formal regulation of Journal of Sociology 38 (4): 399–424.
586 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Bayard, K., J. Hellerstein, et al. (1999) ‘Why are racial and Fagan, C., A. Hegewisch, et al. (2006) About Time: a new
ethnic gaps larger for men than for women. Exploring agenda for shaping working hours. London: Trades
the role of segregation using the new worker- Union Congress.
establishment characteristics database.’ Cambridge, Fitzpatrick, B. (2003) Foreword. Achieving equality
MA.: National Bureau of Economic Research Working at work. In A. McColgan (ed.) The Institute of
Paper No 6997. Employment Rights. London. pp. 1–2.
Bernstein, J. and H. Hartmann. (2000) ‘Defining and Forrest, A. (1993) A view from outside the whale:
characterizing the low-wage labor market.’ In K. Kaye the treatment of women and unions in industrial
and D. S. Nightingale (eds) U.S. The Low-Wage Labor relations, A. Forrest Women challenging unions:
Market: Challenges and Opportunities for Economic Feminism, democracy, and militancy Linda Briskin
Self-Sufficiency. Department of Health and Human and P. McDermott. Toronto, University of Toronto
Services. Press
Bittman, M. and J. Pixley (1997) The Double Life of the Freeman, R. (2005) Labor market institutions without
Family: Myth, Hope and Experience. Sydney: Allen & blinders: The debate over flexibility and labor market
Unwin. performance. Working Paper 11286, NBER, April
Boulin, J.-Y., M. Lallement, et al. (2006) ‘Decent 2005.
working time in industrialized countries: issues, Froud, J., S. Johal, et al. (2006) Financialisation
scopes and paradoxes. Decent working time.’ In and strategy: Narrative and numbers. London:
J.-Y. Boulin, M. Lallement, J. C. Messenger and Routledge.
F. Michon (eds) New Trends, New Issues. Geneva: ILO. Ghai, D. (2002) Decent Work: Concepts, Models and
pp. 13–40. Indicators. Geneva: ILO.
Bruegal, I. and D. Perrons (1998) ‘Deregulation and Green, A.-M., G. Kirton, et al. (2005) ‘Trade union
womens’ employment: The diverse experiences of perspectives on diversity management: A comparison
women in Britain.’ Feminist Economics 4 (1): of the UK and Denmark.’ European Journal of
103–25. Industrial Relations 11 (2): 179–86.
Burrow, S. (2005) ‘ILO decides to put Howard Hantrais, L. and P. Ackers (2005) ‘Women’s
Government on trial over employee rights violations,’ choices in Europe: striking the work-life balance.’
Media Release, ACTU, 2 June 2005. Melbourne, European Journal of Industrial Relations 11 (2):
ACTU. 197–212.
Campbell, I. (2000) ‘The spreading net: age and gender
Harrington, M. (1999) Care and Equality. Inventing a
in the process of casualisation in Australia.’ 45:
New Family Politics. New York: Alfred K. Knopf.
65–100.
Heiler, K., B. Asovska, et al. (1999) ‘Good and bad
Charlesworth, S., P. Hall, et al. (2005) Drivers
bargaining for women: Do unions make a difference?’
and Contexts of Equal Opportunity and Diversity
Labour & Industry 10 (2): 101–28.
Action in Australian Organizations. Melbourne: RMIT
Hochschild, A. (1997) The Time Bind. When Work
Publishing.
Becomes Home and Home Becomes Wor. New York:
Cockburn, C. (1991) In the Way of Women. Men’s
Metropolitan Books.
Resistance to Sex Equality in Organizations. London:
Macmillan. ILO (1999) Report of the Director-General: Decent Work,
Colgan, F. and S. Ledwith (eds) (2002) Gender, Diver- 87th Session, Geneva, June 1999. Geneva: ILO.
sity and Trade Unions: International Perspectives. ILO (2002) Key Indicators of the Labour Market
London: Routledge. 2001–2002. Geneva: ILO.
Cully, M., S. Woodland, et al. (1999) Britain at Work: ILO (2003) Time for Equality at Work. Geneva: ILO.
As Depicted by 1998 Workplace Employee Relations ILO (2004) Fair Globalization: Creating Opportunities for
Survey. London: Routledge. All. Geneva: ILO.
Dickens, L. (1999) ‘Beyond the business case: IMF (2003) World Economic Outlook. Washington,
A three-pronged approach to equality action.’ Human DC: IMF.
Resource Management Journal 9 (1): 9–19. Institute of Employment Rights (2003) Federation News.
Elliott, L. (23 January 2003) ‘Nice work if you can London: Institute of Employment Rights.
get it: cheif exectives quielty enrich themselves Isaac, J. and R. D. Lansbury (eds) (2005)Labour Market
for mediocrity.’ The Guardian 23 January 2006 Deregulation. Rewriting the Rules. Sydney: Federation
(www.guardian,co.uk/executives/story/0,,1692589,00. Press.
html accessed March 1 2006). Jaumotte, F. (2004) Female Labour Force Participation:
Eveline, J. (1994) ‘The politics of male advantage.’ Past Trends and Main Determinants in OECD Coun-
Australian Feminist Studies 19 (Autumn): 129–54. tries. Geneva: OECD Economics Department. p. 10.
EQUALITY AT WORK 587

Kersley, B., C. Alpin, et al. (2005) Inside the employment strategy.’ Industrial Relations Journal
Workplace: First Findings from the 2004 Workplace 33 (5): 500–22.
Employment Relations Survey (WERS 2004). London: Rubery, J. (2004) ‘The Dynamics of National Social
Routledge. Economic Models and the Lifecycle.’ Unpublished
Kidd, M. P. and Xin Meng (1997) ‘Trends in the paper presented at ‘Quality Part-time Work’ Seminar,
Australian gender wage differential over the 1980s: CASR, RMIT, Melbourne, June 2004.
some evidence on the effectiveness of legislative Saunders, P. (2005) ‘Reviewing recent trends in
reform.’ The Australian Economic Record 30 (1): wage income inequality in Australia. Labour market
31–44. deregulation. Rewriting the rules.’ J. Isaac and
Low Pay Commission (2005) National Minimum Wage, R. D. Lansbury. Sydney, Federation Press: 68–89.
Low Pay Commission Report. London: Low Pay SCB (Statistics Sweden) (1991) The Time Use Study.
Commission. Stockholm: Statistics Sweden.
Lundberg, U. (2002) Has the Total Workload of Swedish SCB (Statistics Sweden) (2002) The Time Use Study.
Men and Women Become More Equal during the Last Stockholm: Statistics Sweden.
Ten Years? Stockholm: National Institute for Working Schmid, G. (1995) ‘A New Conribution to Labour
Life. Market Policy: A Contribution to the Current Debate
Messenger, J. C. (ed.) (2004) Working Time and on Efficient Employment Policies.’ Economic and
Workers’ Preferences in Industrialized Countries. Industrial Democracy 16 (?): 429–56.
London: Routledge. Sennett, R. (1998) The Corrosion of Character.
National Labor Committee and China Labor Watch The Personal Consequences of Work in the New
(February 2006) Workers in China: Facing an Capitalism. New York: W.W. Norton and Company.
Olympian Struggle to Survive. New York: China Labor Shields, J. (2005) ‘Setting the double standard: Chief
Watch. executive pay the BCA way.’ Journal of Australian
Ocampo, J. A. (2002) ‘Rethinking the development Political Economy 56 (December): 299–324.
agenda.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26 (3): Standing, G. (1999) Global Labour Flexibility: Seeking
393–407. Distributive Justice. London: MacMillan.
OECD (2002) Employment outlook. Paris: OECD. Standing, G. (2002) Beyond Paternalism: Basic Security
Pocock, B. (1997) ‘Gender and Australian industrial as Equality. New York: Verso.
relations theory and research practice’, Labour & Statement by a Group of 151 Australian Industrial
Industry 8 (1): 1–20. Relations, L. M. A. L. A. (2005) Research evidence
Pocock, B. (2003) The Work/Life Collison. Sydney: about the effects of the ‘Work Choices’ Bill.
Federation Press. A submission to the Inquiry into the Workplace
Pocock, B., J. Buchanan, et al. (2004a) Securing Quality Relations Amendment (Work Choices) Bill 2005,
Employment: Policy Options for Casual and Part-time Unpublished.
Workers in Australia. Sydney: Chifley Foundation. Summers, A. (2004) An End of Equality. Prospects
Pocock, B., R. Prosser, et al. (2004b) Only A Casual... for a Feminist Agenda? Adelaide: University of
How Casual Work Affects Employees, Households and Adelaide.
Communities in Australia. Adelaide: Labour Studies, United Nations (2005) Report on the World
University of Adelaide. Social Situation 2005: the Inequality Predicament.
Padavic, I. and Reskin, B. (2002) Women and Men at New York: United Nations.
Work. Sage: London. Wajcman, J. (1998) Managing like a man. St. Leonards:
Richardson, S. (2005) Are Low Wage Jobs for Life? Allen and Unwin.
Labour Market Deregulation. Rewriting the Rules. Wajcman, J. (2000) ‘Feminism facing industrial relations
Sydney: Federation Press. pp. 149–81. in Britain,’ British Journal of Industrial Relations 38
Rodgers, J. and J. Rubery (2003) ‘Perspectives: the (2): 183–204.
minimum wage as a tool to combat discrimination Whitehouse, G. (2001) ‘Recent trends in pay equity:
and promote equality.’ International Labour Review Beyond the aggregate statistics.’ Journal of Industrial
142 (4): 543–59. Relations 43 (1): 66–78.
Rubery, J. (1998) Part-time Work. A Threat to Labour Wilkinson, R. G. (2005) The Impact of Inequality.
Standards? Part-time Prospects. J. O’Reilly and New York: New Press.
C. Fagan. London, Routledge: 137–55. Williams, J. (2000) Unbending gender. Why family
Rubery, J. (2002) ‘Gender mainstreaming and gender and work conflict and what to do about it.
equality in the EU: the impact of the EU New York: OUP.
31
Conflict at Work
Gregor Gall and Robert Hebdon

INTRODUCTION with the traditionally understood means of


production and distribution of goods, within
Just as ‘industrial relations’ is not the most the term ‘conflict at work’. So the location
appropriate term to encapsulate work relations of ‘conflict at work’ concerns where work is
in employment (Blyton and Turnbull, 1994), spatially performed, the social relations that
neither is ‘industrial conflict’ the most appro- surround work and those social relations that
priate term to encapsulate both conflict at work gives rise to.
work and in employment.1 Whilst ‘industrial This more carefully framed definition
relations’ has been superseded by the term would have been required even at the height of
‘employment relations’, the term ‘conflict industrialization many decades ago because of
at work’ is superior to ‘industrial conflict’ the hitherto relative importance of agriculture
because, inter alia, it would be wrong to and the private and state service sectors.
imply conflict in employment is confined to Moreover, and following from this move
industry, that is, workplaces of production away from the spatially-bounded implication
and distribution. The term ‘conflict at work’ of ‘industrial conflict’ to ‘industry’, another
(Edwards, 1986) is thus able to generically benefit of a temporal nature is evident, namely,
encapsulate conflict both within employment that with the de-industrialization of western
and employment relations, and regardless of economies, the majority of employment in
whether the conflict is to be found in agricul- these economies is now service sector-based.
ture, industry, manufacturing or the (public However, several other benefits also accrue
and private) service sectors and regardless from deploying the term ‘conflict at work’
whether it concerns managers, supervisors rather than ‘industrial conflict’. Thus, it should
or blue-collar (manual), white-collar (non- not be assumed that conflict (at work) is
manual), skilled, semi- or unskilled workers. necessarily predicated on collective conflict,
Consequently, for industrialized or post- primarily organized through trade unionism.
industrialized societies, the means of the pro- Neither should it be assumed that societies
vision of services and the exchange of goods which currently proclaim like China, or
and services are also encapsulated, along formerly proclaimed like the Soviet Union, to
CONFLICT AT WORK 589

be socialist or communist – thus having the- The strengthening of management power, for
oretically abolished the historical antagonism example as a result of increasing capital
between capital and labor – do not and did not, mobility and union disorganization, has meant
nonetheless, experience conflict at work. For that management is able to bear down
some theorists, this confirmed the symmetry more on labor to extract more from it.
of capitalism with socialism or communism, In tandem, competitive globalization over
while for other theorists, it confirmed that the the last few decades has increased tensions
‘actually existing socialism’ was not socialist in the workplace and so the potential for
at all but a form of state capitalism. conflict because workers are working harder
The purpose of this chapter is to examine for the same or less economic reward than
the definition, theory, basis, context, historical before. A third is that the individualization
and contemporary trends and possible future of risk and workplace relations through the
direction of conflict at work. Thus, this chapter individualization of reward has led to a shift
is concerned with not just strikes but the from more collective to more individualized
wider array of conflict at work as well as its conflict. A further point is that the relative,
scale, character and causation. Our underlying contemporary decline in strike activity is
theoretical premise is that conflict, whatever indicative of what we term ‘method dis-
its source, is a central, ever-present and on- placement’, such that the inability to express
going dynamic of contemporary work and grievances and discontent through strikes
employment where conflict is both a ‘means’ finds expression through other alternative or
and an ‘end’ in a cycle of perpetual motion. covert means. A final illustrative point here
Thus, conflict at work should be viewed in a is that conflict at work is defined not just as
holistic, grounded manner, where a complex open struggle or clashes between workers and
social relationship exists between latent and employers but as also involving more hidden
manifest conflict. A number of points, inter tensions and frictions, taking place between
alia, flow from this. different and differing social groups. Thus, we
One is that conflict at work is convention- pursue a radical, sociological line of enquiry
ally seen as an outcome of the interaction of in order to concentrate on issues of power
two (or more) parties in the workplace. But resources, authority relations and interests of
it is not simply an outcome of employment social groups.
or work relations. Conflict at work does
not just have a ‘process’ by which the
outcome is arrived at for conflict is also DEFINING THE PARAMETERS
a process in itself reflecting subterranean OF CONFLICT AT WORK
dynamics. This situation is derived from
the primary, underlying source of conflict, Industrial relations scholars have agreed on
namely, differing or incompatible interests of the need for a wide definition of industrial
different social groups, being a fundamental conflict. When ‘industrial conflict’ was used
and quintessential component of work and as the common term some 20 or more years
employment relations. It is also because ago, the expressions of industrial conflict were
conflict, particularly of the more collective taken to be ‘as unlimited as the ingenuity
and conscious types, is an example of an act of man’ (Kerr, 1964), being a ‘multifaceted
of agency whereby a particular actor does not phenomenon which was conceptually defined
just seek to indicate that there is conflict but in in broad terms to include such events
so doing change the balance of power between as grievances, job actions, sabotage, and
itself and the other party. So conflict is both turnover’ (Feuille and Wheeler, 1981: 290,
reflective and creative, and of a systemic see also Kornhauser, 1954). Fox (1966: 8)
character. also adopted a broad definition that included
A second point flows from the net individual expressions of conflict he labeled
effect of contemporary contextual changes. as ‘unorganized conflict: … labour turnover,
590 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

absenteeism, poor time-keeping and disci- from threats and acts of dismissal, sacking,
pline, and negative attitudes’. Meanwhile, victimization, suspension and lock-outs of
Wheeler (1985: 4) offered three types of workers to closures, outsourcing, subcontract-
collective expressions of industrial conflict ing as well as speed-ups, disciplinaries and
based on union organizing, striking and other unsafe working conditions (see, for example,
forms of industrial action. Bronfenbrenner, 2000; Feuille and Wheeler,
In line with the direction of this thinking, 1981; Hyman, 1980). What we are suggesting
we suggest a holistic and comprehensive here is two-fold: management actions in
definition of the parameters of conflict at work employment relations should not just be seen
in terms of ‘conflict over what?’, ‘between as the likely cause of conflict with workers
who?’ and ‘by what means?’ The ‘conflict but these actions should be also seen as
over what?’ concerns differing (for example, expressions of management interests and thus
opposing, contradictory and incompatible) a fundamental, underlying conflict of interest
interests over the material terms of the within the employment relationship between
wage-effort bargain (for instance, wages management and workers. Thus, management
and conditions of work and employment) and management actions are also, in our
as well as clashes over values and ide- definitional terms, part and parcel of conflict
ologies, the exercise of managerial power at work.
and the determination of organizational Moreover, conflict at work is normally
goals. The ‘conflict between who?’ con- thought of as conflict between employers and
cerns different social groups within the their agents (management or supervisors),
workforce, primarily arranged around the on the one hand, and employees or workers
subordinate-superordinate axis (for example, and their agents (trade unions and other
worker/supervisor, worker/manager, supervi- representatives) on the other hand. And whilst
sor/manager). The ‘conflict by what means?’ this is in the main correct, this should not
concerns any means chosen or used to preclude recognition that conflict at work
give expression to the conflict of interests. can take place between different sections of
Consequently, our boundary definition is management and between different sections
necessarily as wide as possible and includes of employees (Fox, 1971). Such conflict may
all forms of collective or organized conflict reflect occupational, job or status boundaries,
and individual or unorganized actions. but even here management per se is still an
Although conflict at work is commonly important actor because of the role it plays in
perceived as conflict between workers and creating and influencing these boundaries as
employers or managers, there has been very well as mediating, resolving or subduing the
little focus on employer action being seen as a conflict. Conflict at work within or between
form of conflict (for example, over industrial groups of workers or managers may not prima
accidents and injuries) or of employers facie seem to involve senior management.
engaging pro-actively in conflict and taking However, senior management is implicitly
‘industrial action’. This is derived from the involved because either it has contributed to
belief that the onus is on the wronged party the conflict by setting out the parameters in
to take corrective action, otherwise there is no which it exists or because it has the choice to
evidence of conflict; that the power imbalance exercise the power of remedy.
at work means that it is only workers that Before moving on, it is important to
are compelled to take action; and that what note that, despite general agreement on a
employers or managers do vis-à-vis coercion broader definition of conflict, research has
and control of workers is legitimate and in practice focused on single expressions of
part of a ‘natural order’. If any or all of the variety of the means of conflict at any
these are stripped away, then there is ample one time (Feuille and Wheeler, 1981: 290;
room to consider an array of managerial Hyman, 1982). This narrowness of focus has
actions as actions of conflict. These range ignored the inter-linkages between different
CONFLICT AT WORK 591

forms of expressions and omitted to consider the subordinate–supervisor relationship, or


the impact of important processes, such as material rewards and other conditions of
method displacement, thus causing errors of employment. Where conflict is sometimes
calculation of extant conflict in empirical derived from management, it is the result of
work. ‘bad’ or unenlightened management practices
(Mayo, 1933; Taylor, 1911). This unitarist
perspective denies the existence of an inherent
THE THEORIZING OF CONFLICT conflict of interest between management and
AT WORK labor (see, for example, Godard, 1994). Thus,
as long as sound management practices and
The setting out of the parameters or bound- policies are followed, conflict is neither
aries of conflict is essential to, but not necessary nor inevitable.
synonymous with, defining conceptually the Although always a strain in management
causation and dynamics of conflict at work. thought, the unitarist perspective has now
Thus, we briefly review the contending come to dominate the managerialist paradigm
theoretical perspectives-but first we note that over the last 20 years in the form of human
conflict at work can be conceived in a ‘com- resource management (HRM), albeit it has
mon sense’, almost atheoretical, way. Here, harder and softer versions where the softer
the basis of conflict of interest thus concerns version has pragmatic pluralist tinges. All
workers wanting to work less (intensively or other frames of references and perspectives
extensively) for more pay and better terms such as pluralism, radicalism, materialism
of employment while employers want to pay and Marxism recognize that conflict at
less in remuneration for more intensive or work is a socialized process involving an
extensive work. This is conventionally termed array of social groups and their different
the ‘wage-effort bargain’. Another type of and sometimes conflicting interests (see, for
‘common sense’ explanation is that work example, Jackson, 1991). However, thereafter
requires social organization such as authority this elementary degree of consensus ends.
and discipline being established, whereby A radical or materialist analysis focuses
those who conceive of and direct are managers upon such conflict of interests but locates
and those who execute are workers. This mere the dynamics of conflict in two specific
‘fact’ and any accompanying social status arenas (Edwards, 1986). The first concerns
and remuneration differentiation are believed a conflict over the distribution of an orga-
to provide the basis for potential conflict nization’s resources between workers and
along the manager–worker axis. However, no employers or managers. The second concerns
grander generalizations about wider social employers seeking to turn purchased labor
structuration are necessarily derived from time into (useful) labor power which requires
these insights. managerial direction and control at the
Extant conflict theories and theories of same time as providing for opportunities for
conflict at work may be distinguished along insubordination and resistance. Meanwhile,
several dimensions. Two aspects of particular a Marxist perspective would broadly concur
importance for this enquiry are the source with both the former but stress the collective
and inevitability of conflict at work. The nature of the workplace struggle between
unitarist perspective explains conflict at work workers and employers with this merely
as derived from dysfunctionality, where being a microcosm of a wider, societal class
order and harmony are the natural state struggle between the working class and the
of affairs. Conflict is deviancy and thus employing class (see, for example, Hyman,
illegitimate and unproductive. Consequently, 1975). Therefore, for Marxists, the central
most conflict is derived from workers, in par- dynamic revolves around the exploitation of
ticular individual and pathological deviants workers or wage labor by the capitalist in
and malcontents, be it over the nature of the capitalist’s search for generating surplus
592 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

value (for instance, profit) in a competitive exchange. Second, they normally have a
regime of accumulation. And here, the strike legitimate right to do so as a result of the
represents an important example of workers ideology of capitalism, the rights of private
taking some control over their working lives, property and their experience and expertise.
which may in turn build workers’own fighting The latter are normally subsumed within
capacity in terms of their class consciousness the concept of the ‘managerial prerogative’.
and mobilizing capability. However, for workers and employees not
For a pluralist, albeit itself a broad school of only must they construct a counter-authority
thought, conflict at work can take place along a and power resource which do not ordinarily
multiplicity of axes and between a multiplicity exist, but they must do so in addition
of groups, of which none are inherently more to their requirement to work. Therefore, it
significant than others. Conflict at work, to is misguided to interpret the absence of
a pluralist, is an indication of interchange, significant levels of strikes as evidence of
exchange and dialogue which can be healthy, the lack of conflict or evidence of harmony
functional and productive so long as it does not at work.
become endemic, widespread or embedded. Depending on the opportunities for acting
Moreover, means of institutionalizing, and and the power resources available to each
thus ameliorating, conflict into acceptable group, conflict of interests will be expressed
forms and levels are deemed a prerequisite for in different ways and in different degrees at
responsible management. different points in time and space. Quite apart
Whatever perspective is adopted in study- from stressing the contingent nature to their
ing conflict at work (other than unitarism),2 expression, this perspective suggests that con-
to one degree or another, all do not make flict can be managed but not abolished within
the presence of overt, manifest symptoms the existing social structuration of society
of conflict at work synonymous with the and that management is not so omnipotent,
existence of conflict at work per se. In omnicompetent, omniscient and omnipresent
other words, the articulation and expression as to be able to abolish or prevent conflict.
of conflict at work is not the sine qua Thus, we contend that sophisticated HRM
non for conflict itself because conflict of practices cannot end the conflict of interests
interest between groups can exist without at work, particularly of that between workers
manifest and deliberate attempts to pursue and managers, because of the maintenance
those interests. Of course, the point should not of differing material interests. We also thus
be pushed so far that the complete absence contend that ‘method displacement’ exists
of expressed conflict would not then raise such that if workers are less able to strike,
questions about the existence of conflict then there is likely to be, all other things being
per se. However, the primary point here is equal, a relative growth in the expression
that for manifest conflict, such as resistance of grievance by other means. Consequently,
to take place, requires the construction and later in this chapter we examine both semi-
mobilization of social agency, and attendant collective and individualized expressions of
means and tools, for its expression. Thus, conflict.
strikes, for example, are a symptom of
conflict, not the cause of conflict.
This discussion has focused attention on THE CONTEXT OF CONFLICT
power and authority relations (for a wider
discussion, see Offe and Wiesenthal, 1985). It is neither particularly contentious nor
For employers and management, these issues insightful to recognize that conflict is not
are less problematic in two senses. First, they the only feature of work and employment
have the means at their disposal to pursue relations.Abasic perspective would recognize
their interests through owning and controlling that conflict has it anti-thesis, namely, co-
the means of production, distribution and operation. The foundation of co-operation
CONFLICT AT WORK 593

is normally acknowledged to be common or absence of manifest expressions of conflict


or compatible interests, particularly between at work. Thus, the impact of the levels
employers and workers. The perceived need of workers’ consciousness (sectional, class-
for both employers and workers to work for-itself) and ideologies (radical militancy,
together in pursuit of common or compatible co-operative mutual-gains) held within labor
goals is most readily observed in the belief that movements must also be borne in mind (Gall,
profitable operations are the best guarantor 1999b).
of security of employment. However, a fuller Conflict at work is more commonly con-
understanding of the context of conflict cerned with the subordinate group negotiating
demands that we appreciate that co-operation the terms of its subordination with the
is not the simple, zero sum anti-thesis of superordinate group rather than seeking to
conflict. Both not only exist alongside each end the subordination itself and the existence
other in different measures and forms at any of the superordinate group (Edwards, 1986).
one point in time, but they also interact with This is because structures of power and
each other to synthetically produce an array ideology provide defenses for the status quo.
of outcomes (which Marxists, for example, Put another way, consent is bargained over
conceptualize as a dialectical relationship and mixes with the use of commitment and
between the two elements). One such outcome coercion. Therefore, we can also say that
is termed ‘accommodation’, whereby neither order and control are also negotiated over.
party finds itself in agreement with the So, for example, unions seek to better the
other’s interests or goals but is compelled terms of exploitation or wage-labor rather
by the balance of power to accept, in part, than abolish the exploitation or wage-labor
the existence and pursuit of each others’ itself. For some Marxists, this indicates that
interests. Conflict and co-operation are not trade unions are merely reformist organiza-
just outcomes derived from the struggle by tions without the potential for revolutionary
workers and employers to generate consent purposes.
and commitment for their interests but they are
also emblematic of attempts by management
and workers to determine and resist each TYPES AND FORMS OF CONFLICT
others’ terms for wage-labor. Thus, workers AT WORK
with varying degrees of power may be subject
to ‘responsible autonomy’ or ‘direct control’ Conventionally, conflict at work has been
(Friedman, 1977). understood by way of a number of simple
The ability to collectively mobilize to dichotomies: latent (hidden, covert)/manifest
express conflict of interest requires a sequen- (open, overt), organized/unorganized and
tial process which involves the formation individualized/ collectivized (Edwards, 1986;
of interest definition, the construction of Hyman, 1977; Kornhauser, 1954). The
collective organization, analyzing the costs latent/manifest dichotomy indicates that con-
and benefits of the action and identifying flict is ever present in terms of interests and
the opportunity to act (Kelly, 1998). Pay- attitudes but is not always acted upon. When
ing attention to the latter components is it becomes acted upon, through behavior,
particularly useful in recognizing that not it becomes more visible. Here manifest
all groups feel in a position to express instances of conflict at work are normative
their conflict of interest because of their actions in the senses that the actions are
‘poor’ labor scarcity and ‘poor’ strategic reactions against the norms of employers and
work position. Indeed, difficulties in these their managers and that the actions display
areas may impede the formation of interest the components of a different and contrasting
definition and construction of collective orga- set of norms. ‘Unorganized’ conflict has
nization. Nonetheless, such a perspective is traditionally been used to denote individual
not entirely sufficient to explain the presence means of withdrawing physically or mentally
594 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

from the work situation while organized conflict concerns the outcomes of the way
conflict has been used to denote collective people are treated at work vis-à-vis, for
conflict which seeks to change the exist- example, pay rises while ‘procedural’ conflict
ing situation without withdrawal. Another concerns the way in which substantive
dichotomy is that the articulation of conflict outcomes are decided. An example would
inherently concerns expressing discontent or be the presence or absence of collective
grievance. However, articulation may not bargaining, as well as the nature of collective
necessarily also seek resolution of those bargaining, over pay.
causes. Nonetheless, both are deliberate, Collective expressions of conflict at work
conscious human actions. necessarily involve conscious and directed
In addition to these elementary human action and interaction because the
dichotomies, there are a number of other expressions of conflict are neither accidental
ways of classifying the different types of nor inevitable. Two or more persons are
conflict at work. One is to group the types required to act in concert for the action
of conflict on a horizontal axis ranging from to become collective and this necessarily
individual to semi-collective to collective requires a degree of heightened cognitive
conflict, where each of these clusters are awareness concerning identification of the
viewed as poles of attraction for the purposes grievance, recognition of a commonality of
of locating cases of conflict. The function interests and attribution to another party.
of this type of classification is to understand This then provides the basis for discussion,
the underlying nature and character of the agreement and planning on the taking of
example of conflict without becoming fixated an action. Consequently, one is able to
on the form of conflict. In other words, it is understand why the majority of collective
to try to comprehend elements of the social actions are organized by unionized workers
group dynamics involved, the means by or through trade unions, albeit the desire by
which different actors pursue their interests workers to pursue their interests as workers
as well as how one example relates to another. may lead to unions being formed. Unions and
Under this classification, one could observe their workplace organizations then represent
that what appears at first sight as an individual a semi-permanent resource for workers who
conflict between a worker and management want, or may wish, to pursue their interests.
may be symptomatic of a wider collective The resource is not just a simple organiza-
conflict between workers and management, tional one of connecting individual workers to
because the individual is taking a de jure or each other for trade unionism also represents
de facto test case against management for behavioral or attitudinal resources conducive
other workers. This example could indicate to collectively prosecuting their interests
a semi-collective or collective dimension. inside the workplace. For this reason, the
In other words, some actions have both location of manifest collective conflict reflects
individualized and collectivized components the location of trade unionism, which is now
(see, for example, Dowding et al., 2000; increasingly a public sector phenomenon.
Kelly, 1998; Morill et al., 2003). However, However, trade unions are not the only
this type of simple continuum cannot shed organizations representing workers for non-
much light on the nature and context of governmental organizations like faith groups,
the actors’ interests. For example, it is of secular community organizations and political
little help in understanding why the conflict parties can also assist workers in these
took a particular form, namely, individual, regards. Nonetheless, it can be understood
semi-collective or collective. Another way that the decline in unionization densities
to view conflict at work is to regard all has significant implications for the ability
types of conflict as falling under two generic of workers to express their discontent and
categories, namely, conflict over substantive grievances in a collective and purposeful
and procedural outcomes. ‘Substantive’ manner.
CONFLICT AT WORK 595

‘INDUSTRIAL’ ACTION and expressions of conflict vary according


to their social visibility (for example, the
Although the strike has traditionally con- degrees to which the acts are intended to be
stituted the dominant focus of industrial visible and the participant’s identities known
relations’ study of conflict, the strike is far to authorities) and their outcome (for example,
from the only means by which discontent the potential for covert action to lead to wider,
can be collectively expressed. Traditionally, in overt conflict) (Morill et al., 2003: 399).
Western societies, the term ‘industrial action’ Theft and sabotage are the most commonly
has been used to describe conscious, proactive studied forms of covert conflict which concern
collective mobilizations of workers, primarily the ‘subversion of organizational technologies
through unions, which involve not just strikes, and resources’ (Morill et al., 2003: 394, see
but also ‘industrial action short of a strike’ also Fortado, 2001; Robinson and Bennett,
comprising work-to-rules, go-slows and over- 1995). Studies have reported a wide array
time bans. Work-to-rules, or the withdrawal of of means: mental health workers defacing
goodwill, involve only doing particular work and debilitating property in mental wards
or working in a certain way as laid down to ‘protest’ against managerial practices
in a job specification, organizational rules (Spector, 1975), construction workers break-
or employment contract. Employing orga- ing tools on construction sites to express
nizations commonly work more efficiently their discontent with their working conditions
and effectively when workers do what is (Tucker, 1993), and civil servants in public
operationally required rather than what is bureaucracies who subvert various policies
laid down in their rules and regulations. This (Brehm and Gates, 1997; Morill et al., 2003:
goodwill to do what is required is, thus, the 395). More recently, some of these types
‘oil’ that lubricates the ‘wheels’. Go-slows of more informal acts of ‘deviancy’ have
involve the restricting of the work rate from been termed ‘organizational misbehavior’
that which is commonly regarded by workers (Ackroyd and Thompson, 1999; Thompson
and management as a ‘normal’ (and higher) and Ackroyd, 1995).
rate. Overtime bans involve the withdrawal of However, it should not be assumed that
the willingness to work either compulsory or all instances of resistance by workers are in
voluntary overtime and are predicated on the direct and clear contradiction of management
belief that working overtime is necessary to and employer’s instructions or interests for in
sustain the employing organization in meeting some instances, management and employers
its goals and objectives. The former type of are complicit in these prima facie cases of
industrial action – work-to-rules, go-slows – conflict. This situation arises because it may
concerns the intensity of work while the be in the interests of management/employer
latter – overtime bans – concerns the extensity to restrict output or work due to market
of work. or political conditions. More commonly,
In addition to these well-known examples management and employers will tolerate
of industrial action, there are a host of expressions of worker conflict as a form
lesser known forms ranging from sabo- of ‘letting off steam’ to prevent further or
tage, vandalism, fiddles, pilfering, output greater conflagration as well as to keep the
restriction, so-called ‘restrictive practices’, wheels of ‘industry’ turning whereby clamp-
soldiering, absenteeism, turnover, grievance ing down on this right would, in fact, lead to
taking to individual and collective law suits conflagration. Furthermore, not all instances
and political (extra-workplace) actions (see, of absenteeism and turnover reflect conflict
for example, Edwards and Scullion, 1982). for some may be ‘genuine’, and absenteeism
These acts of resistance can be carried out by and turnover/quitting rates cannot be taken
individuals and collectives and in individual, as straightforward measures because they are
semi-collective and collective ways as laid influenced by the opportunity to be absent and
out above. Moreover, these lesser known acts quit depending on organizational policy, labor
596 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

market conditions and the social wage. But formal structures that facilitate ‘voice’ will
by the same token, it would be mistaken to reduce covert conflict and the complementar-
conceptualize conflict as only existing where ity hypothesis predicts that formally enabling
it finds some level of conscious expression by voice is associated with ‘corresponding
workers. Thus, for example, occupational ill- increases in other forms of ... [submerged]
health and accidents at work of workers may conflict’ (Sapsford and Turnbull, 1994: 250).
indicate conflicting interests at work between Empirical research reveals support for the
workers and employers (Nichols, 1997). substitution hypothesis (Hebdon and Stern,
1998; Sapsford and Turnbull, 1994). And
since much of the research that has analyzed
DYNAMICS OF CONFLICT more than one form of conflict at a time has
either implicitly or explicitly employed the
The literature on the causes, frequency tradeoff or substitution hypothesis, it is worth
and dynamics of strikes on national, inter- recognizing that an apparent assumption is the
and trans-national bases, let alone that on notion that the total amount of conflict is fixed.
‘industrial’ action and conflict, is sufficiently But unless the amount of conflict is assumed to
large and complex as to defy summary here. be constant, the tradeoff hypothesis cannot be
Suffice it to say, however, that considerable rigorously tested. Hebdon (2005) has called
controversy has raged in this decades-old this into serious question. For example, a
debate on this field of study, and this has often decrease in strikes, that is associated with
centered upon the consequences of the use of an increase in absenteeism, may be due to a
different levels or units of analysis as well as change in total conflict that has unequal effects
competing theories or hypotheses. For exam- on strikes and absenteeism.
ple, and particularly with regard to strikes,
theoretical analysis has focused, inter alia, on
the ‘business cycle’, the rise and fall of cor- REGULATION OF CONFLICT
poratism, institutionalization and paradigm
shifts (for example, Fordism/post-Fordism, Conflict at work is regulated for a number
industrialism/post-industrialism) while deter- of economic, political and social reasons
minant analysis has considered the influence and in a number of different ways (legal,
of different economic conditions like unem- voluntary, institutional, social, ideological).
ployment or inflation, and workforce and For example, collective expressions of con-
economic sector compositions. A number of flict at work are commonly believed by
authors like Edwards and Hyman (1994), mainstream commentators to be disruptive
Hyman (1977), Jackson (1987, 1991) and to economic efficiency and social cohesion
Kelly (1998) have provided overviews of the at organizational and societal levels. If
salient debates. the disruption is viewed as unwarranted
Given that analysis of overt collective or disproportionate then state regulation is
conflict, that is strikes, has tended to be the exercised. Thus, conflict at work can be
traditional focus of attention, it is also worth ‘political’ even where there is not a party
noting analysis of the dynamics of covert of organized labor. At the micro-level, such
conflict has focused on the individual and collective mobilizations are also regulated
organizational levels. With the former, the because of the challenges potentially posed
primary factors are perceived loss of control to the managerial prerogative. That said,
over the regulation of work and the wage- regimes of regulation are extremely varied.
effort bargain (see Morill et al., 2003: 402), For example, arbitration is compulsory in
while for the latter attention has focused on some sectors like the US postal service while
‘substitution’and ‘complementarity’hypothe- in Germany strikes are unlawful within the
ses (Morill et al., 2003; Sapsford and Turnbull, duration of a collective bargaining contract
1994). The substitution hypothesis predicts and works councils cannot call strikes.
CONFLICT AT WORK 597

Systems of macro-regulation (and attendant in terms of who is the target of leverage.


collective bargaining structures) are regarded The first, the economic strike, is an attempt
as important determinants of the manner in to exert leverage over an employer (or
which conflict at work is expressed in both group of employers acting in concert through
intended and unintended ways. Thus, the employers’ federations) to better the terms
institutionalization of conflict may channel and conditions of employment within the
it at certain times, but, as in contemporary immediate workplace and as determined by
Burma, China, Indonesia and South Korea, the contract of employment. This type of strike
it may compel workers to step outside its is the most common in Anglo-Saxon coun-
confines by rioting where the strike option is tries. This does not mean that the economic
curtailed. strike does not and cannot have a political
dimension. Every economic strike challenges,
albeit it momentarily, the prevailing micro-
STRIKES political workplace order. By contrast, large
or widespread economic strikes by many
The preoccupation of industrial relations workers can present a political threat to
scholars with strikes is well known (Feuille employer control or government economic
and Wheeler, 1981). This tendency to overly policy (particularly where the government is
concentrate on the more visible expressions of the de facto employer in the state or public
conflict in both theory and empirical work is sector).
not limited to the field of industrial relations The second, the political strike, is an
(see, for example, political science and social attempt to exert leverage over an extra-
movement studies (Morill et al., 2003: 392)). workplace actor, like the government or
The concentration on strikes as the ‘premier’ a state regulatory body, and usually on
form of collective ‘industrial action’ arises an extra-workplace issue. In this attempt,
for a number of reasons. Compared to the the workers seek to change the course of
overtime ban or work-to-rule, strikes are behavior of the external actor which in due
regarded as being relatively more open, visi- course is believed will either change, regulate
ble and important, in turn, making them more or constrain the behavior of the employer
worthy of measurement and more measurable. over determining the terms and conditions
The sense of importance is derived from the of employment. For example, workers may
strike aiming to stop rather than just hinder strike to challenge a piece of employment
work and from presenting a clear challenge law or change an element of the social wage.
to the managerial prerogative. So they are This type of strike is necessarily a multi-
regarded as representing the starkest form of employer strike and mass strike. Such strikes,
industrial conflict. Consequently, some like in the form of general strike, are relatively
Olson (1988) attributed the narrow focus on common in a number of southern European
strikes to the ease of obtaining data and countries like Greece, Italy, Portugal and
the difficulty of researching other conflict Spain. Here, there is some sense of an
expressions. However, it should be noted that economic connection to the workplace and the
the preoccupation of scholars with such a workers seek to use the economic dislocation
visible and measurable conflict expression and disruption emanating from their strike as
results from the undeveloped state of conflict the means of political leverage.Amore overtly
theory, particularly the lack of comprehensive political strike concerns those which attempt
frameworks of workplace conflict which take to influence the course of behavior of the
into account less visible expressions and their external actor such a government on an issue
inter-relationships (Hebdon, 2005). without regard to trying to exert influence
A strike is conventionally defined as a over employers. Examples concern attempts
collective withdrawal of the willingness to by pro-democracy movements to remove
work. Two basic types can be identified authoritarian governments or dictatorships as
598 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in Brazil (1987), Indonesia (1998), Poland (union, employer, state body) to register strike
(1980–2), South Africa (late 1980s), South activity (see www.laborsta.ilo.org). Where
Korea (1987, 1997) and the Ukraine (2004–5). statistical data do exist for instances of
As the former and latter lists of countries ‘industrial action short of strike’, this is
suggest, the political strike is not common derived from one-off, episodic surveys in a
in the Anglo-Saxon countries. However, this few particular countries making comparative
does not mean that the economic strike is not work and generalization extremely difficult.
also common in non-Anglo-Saxon countries.
The salient point here is that strikes can
have different meanings and representations CONFLICT AT WORK: NORTH
vis-à-vis demands, mobilization and targets AMERICA AND EUROPE
depending on their spatial location. The same
is true with regard to the temporal location of We now turn to examine the decline in strikes
strikes. Suffice it so say that while strikes are in North America and Europe as well as con-
an inter- and trans-national phenomenon, the sider evidence of other conflict expressions.
specific context of the strike is important to Flowing from our conflict framework, we
understanding the character and nature of any expect to see some evidence of increases in
particular strike. collective expressions other than strikes and
Given this, it is worth briefly noting that in individual conflict forms. Given that we are
for westernized economies, there has been a considering conflict at work in these western
broad cross-national trend of decline in the economies, we are not in a position to offer any
extent and intensity of strike activity since definite insights regarding the experience of
the late 1970s. The major caveats are that the conflict at work in Eastern Europe, South East
decline has taken place from different pre- Asia, India or China. Nonetheless, we would
existing levels for different countries and that anticipate some broad similarities in terms of
there are some exceptions. This highlights that the underlying existence of conflict and the
while cross-national trends can be discerned, available menu of methods of expression but
these are subject to and expressed within differences in the choice of which methods
differing national-based systems of industrial are utilized over time, reflecting national
relations. However, the main conclusion differences in systems and traditions of
drawn from the data is that whilst the late employment regulation.
1960s and early 1970s represented a period of
rising strike activity, subsequently a period of
North America
quiescence (Shalev, 1992) has set in, leading
some to speculate on the ‘withering away’ Much of the North American economic
of the strike (again, see, Ross and Hartman, literature on strikes focuses on the incidence
1960). and duration of strikes in large bargaining
units – in the US, usually units with 1,000
or more workers and in Canada, units with
DATA PROBLEMS 500 or more, but sometimes upwards of 200.
There is evidence, however, that these large
Throughout the world, in both developed and unit samples are unrepresentative of all strikes
developing economies, statistical data for the (Harrison and Stewart, 1993; Skeels et al.,
annual frequency of different types of ‘indus- 1988). Despite this data limitation, there is
trial action’ are absent, incomplete and non- strong evidence of a long term decline in
standardized. Annual statistics for one type, strikes in North America.
the strike, do exist in a more complete form The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) in
but even here there are problems concerning the US only collect data on large strikes
the minimum threshold for inclusion (size, (involving n>1,000 workers), covering both
sector) and the obligation on parties concerned public and private sectors. Despite the
CONFLICT AT WORK 599

problem of the raising of the minimum unions in terms of legal barriers and greater
threshold for inclusion in the BLS data, a management power under globalization (see
long term decline in the US strike activity Piazza, 2005, and for Europe, Scheuer, 2006).
is evident, and is shown in Figure 31.1. Over the same period, the long-term decline
Although subject to big swings, days not in strikes in Canada is similar to that seen in
worked peaked in the immediate post-war the US (Figure 31.2). As the Canadian data
period before peaking again in 1970 and include work stoppages of bargaining units
experiencing a sharp and sustained decline of all sizes, it is much more representative
thereafter. Without identifying the strict order than the US data.3 Union density is less of an
of causation, there are two primary factors to explanatory factor here because Canada has
explain the decline that stand out. The first not experienced the same decline (see Godard,
is the well-documented decline in US union 2003), remaining around 30 per cent for the
density from a peak of 32.5 per cent (1953) last decade. After a decline from an annual
to just 12 per cent (2006) (BLS 2006b). The average of 754 in the 1980s, to 394 in the
second is due to the more hostile context to 1990s, to 221 in 2003, work stoppages rose to

1000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
48

52

56

60

64

68

72

76

80

84

88

92

96

00

04
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

20

Figure 31.1 US – strike days per 1,000 workers, 1948–2006


Source: Computed from BLS (2006a).
Note: From 1984 onwards, the BLS data only measures strikes involving more than 1,000 workers. Previous to
that it was 500 workers.

90 1400
80 1200
nu mb er of strikes

70
Days on Strike

1000
60
Avera ge

50 800
40 600
30
400
20
10 200

0 0
46 50 54 58 62 6 6 7 0 7 4 7 8 8 2 8 6 9 0 9 4 9 8 2
Ye a rs
Strike Du r a t io n St r ik e I n c id e n c e

Figure 31.2 Canada – strike incidence and duration, 1946–2005


600 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

261 in 2004 and again in 2005. Alongside this, to discuss bargaining such that McCammon
the duration of work stoppages have increased (2001: 145) argued ULPs now constitute
in Canada since the 1950s (Campoletti et al., ‘a legalistic mode of struggle [which has]
2005). Most work stoppages that commenced increasingly become labor’s mainstay’. The
between 2003 and 2005 concerned wage and second concerns absenteeism, and although it
benefits. It is interesting that job security is difficult to isolate the conflict aspects, there
and subcontracting, issues that might be is evidence from Canada that absenteeism
associated with the more manifest aspects rates have been rising and that increased on-
of the recent business turn to globalization, the-job stress is a significant cause (Statistics
represented only 9 per cent of all stoppages Canada, 2005; Tomlinson, 2002). The third
over this period (Statistics Canada, 2006). concerns quit rates. Statistics Canada (2007)
The notion of method displacement sug- found that 5.5 per cent of men and 7.0
gests, inter alia, a trade-off between strikes per cent of women quit their jobs in 1984.
and other forms of conflict (reviewed in By 2002, these were 7.7 per cent and
Hebdon, 2005). When strikes are structurally 7.6 per cent, respectively. Whilst higher levels
blocked by laws or institutions, and capi- of unemployment impeded quitting in 1984,
talist globalization helps weaken organized it is unlikely that the higher rates of quitting
labor, alternative expressions of conflict may in 2002 can be fully explained by greater
increase. The prevailing wisdom from the opportunities. Some of the increase is likely
covert conflict literature suggests that conflict due to an increased demand to leave but more
may be redirected in two ways; collective research is needed to settle this issue.
actions will be more covert, appearing in
the form of collective job actions (for
Europe
example, sick-outs, slowdowns, work-to-
rules), and there will also be more individual Like other Western economies, there has been
conflict expressions (for example turnover, a broad cross-national trend of decline in the
absenteeism, grievances). These form two extent and intensity of strike activity since
hypotheses, and while it is beyond this the late 1970s in European economies, albeit
chapter’s scope to rigorously test these, we subject to the caveats outlined above (see also
can, however, highlight a body of work that is Gall, 1999a). Given the number of economies
generally supportive of them. within the European Union (EU) itself, the
The first is a study of unfair labor survey of strike activity here will merely focus
practices (ULPs) in the US from 1950–97 on the four of the largest economies with the
(McCammon, 2001). The creation of the EU, namely, Britain, France, Germany and
offence of a ULP within the National Labor Italy between 1955 and 2005 using the relative
Relations Act 1935 (commonly known as the measure of days not worked per 1,000 workers
‘Wagner Act’ after it’s creator, Senator Robert per annum (DNW/1,000W). Another reason
Wagner) was underpinned by an intention for focusing on these four economies is that
to channel conflict away from strikes and there is annual data for this entire half century
lockouts (see Hurd, 1976). ULPs are (over- unlike that for Greece or Spain. However,
whelmingly) union actions alleging employer in both France and Germany, strike activity
violation of the National Labor Relations in public administration has been excluded
Act (bargaining in bad faith, management for all or much of the period, this having an
interference with a lawful union activity, increased salience given the de facto shift in
etc.) (McCammon, 2001: 167). While initially the location of most strike activity from the
ULPs concerned employers resisting a grow- private to public sector in western economies.
ing number of assertive organizing drives, At the low end is Germany, where from
under the decline in their strike capability, 1955 to the late 1980s, few years saw more
much weakened unions now file ULPs to than 150 DNW/1,000W, while subsequently
pressurize employers to come to the table it has been less than 15 per year. By contrast,
CONFLICT AT WORK 601

in Britain, most years until the late 1980s have remained broadly similar since 1989,
experienced more than 250 DNW/1,000W, being annually around 160–200 million days
but since the early 1990s, the number has not worked, equating to between 6,000–9,000
been considerably less than 100. Meanwhile, days not worked per thousand workers and
in France, most years until the late 1970s ‘costing’ £10–14 billion (www.cbi.org.uk).
saw more than 250 DNW/1,000W whereupon The CBI believes that between 10–20 per cent
almost all subsequent years experienced is not genuine sickness/absence, which does
less than 100. From the mid-1960s, Italy indicate conflict at work, and the degree of
experienced upwards of 1,000 DNW/1,000W unauthorized absence is higher in unionized
until the early 1980s, and thereafter a fall than non-unionized workplaces. Whatever
to around 100 by 2005. (Although Italy has the veracity of these figures, it is not
been by far the most strike prone of the four possible to discern a trend in non-genuine
economies, relatively speaking, it has been sickness/absence given the absence of stan-
put in the shade by Greece, which from the dardized data. Moreover, the CBI does not
mid-1980s to mid-1990s experienced well in produce figures which show the extent of
excess of 2,000 DNW/1,000W.) Nonetheless, sickness/absence that is or may be attributable
what all four economies have in common to mental stress, injury or accident at work
is that their general patterns are punctuated or resulting from work, which would also
by individual years of ‘uncommonly’ high indicate conflict at work. Nonetheless, given
strike activity. More generally, much strike that employers believe much is not genuine
activity has concerned resistance to gov- sickness/absence, they are now dedicating
ernment austerity measures, exclusions from more time and resources to trying to reduce
the political process, retrenchment in public it and to monitoring workers more stringently
sector employment and pay rises. (Edwards and Whitston, 1989). Other than
When we turn to examine other instances a few examples like British Airways in
of collective, non-strike ‘industrial’ action, 1997, almost all these conflict-based sick-
available data is woefully incomplete and ness/absences have been conducted on an
non-standardized. Nonetheless, focusing on atomized, individual basis, even if the actions
Britain gives some indication of the processes are commonly taken by many workers.
at play. Milner (1993) and Gall (2006) found The union peak organization, the Trades
that ‘industrial’ action short of a strike and Union Congress (TUC) has regularly pub-
other means of collectively exerting influence lished estimates of the amount of unpaid
(through balloting, collective conciliation) overtime that employers obtain from workers.
were prevalent and concluded that it was These have averaged out in the last five years
plausible that they have increased over the to constitute £23 billion per annum carried
last 30 years. Several authors have noted the out by 5 million workers. And while not all
decline in the reach of trade unionism since unpaid overtime is forced overtime, for some
the late 1970s and the likely attendant rise of workers may regard it as a career investment,
individual workers’ approaches to Citizens’ and not all workers like professionals have
Advice Bureaux – the state funded body for set contractual hours, clearly employers are
providing advice about legal and regulatory still extracting much coerced, unpaid work.
matters to private individuals – from below Thereafter, there are scattered and isolated
0.2 million cases per annum then to more data on the extent of employer evasion of the
than 0.5 million cases in the last twenty years statutory minimum wage and on the extent
(Abbot, 2004: 245; Kelly, 1998: 45). of theft and pilfering; for example, some
The main employers’ federation, the Con- 3 million workers were believed to be engaged
federation of British Industry (CBI), has in workplace theft in recent years in Britain
annually estimated, from an annual survey, (Financial Times, 7 March 2007).
the extent and cost of sickness/absence from Unfortunately, similar data, even of
the workplace since 1987. Annual estimates an incomplete, non-standardized type, on
602 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

non-strike expressions of conflict is not of employment creates the worker/employer


readily available for the other three European divide. Thus, workers can perform paid work
economies through the European Industrial for an employing organization although they
Relations Observatory or national-based are not employed as such. We subsumed all
studies. Although it is known that overtime these points within the framework of conflict
bans and work-to-rules are sometimes of interests where conflict exists even if it is
used, the absence of inclusive survey data not consciously acted upon.
represents a major gap in our knowledge here. Given that overt and covert conflict at
We also know that absenteeism, turnover and work is inherent and endemic in society, the
the like have a presence in these countries but salient substantive issues concern how it is
again little is known of their specific extent expressed, at what volumes and what factors
and causation. influence these. Indeed, the thrust of what we
have argued is that it would be unwarranted
to predict a genuine paradigm shift in the
CONCLUSION historically important method of expression
through strikes. So rather than a secular trend –
In discussing conflict at work, we concen- ‘the withering way of the strike’ – the notion
trated on the workforce as workers or produc- of waves and cycles (for example, Kelly,
ers of goods and services rather than workers 1998) stresses the contingent nature of their
as citizens or consumers. This established expression within a framework of conflict at
an order and primacy of relationship even work as an ever-present underlying dynamic.
if the subsequent pursuit of the interests Here, the upswings and downswings in the
of workers may have involved workers bargaining power of labor, and organized
as consumers (for example organizing a labor in particular, are likely to be critical
consumer boycott of their employer) or as parts of an understanding and explanation,
citizens (for example using the services of and these upswings and downswings also
a lawyer or citizens’ advice bureau), and relate to the usage of political action and
where either or both involve working in political parties by unions. And in historical
alliances with non-governmental actors such terms, it is likely that the current period of
as pressure groups and political parties. In that ‘labor quiescence’ (Shalev, 1992) refers only
sense, our use of the term ‘conflict at work’ to a single method of collective mobilization,
was also preferable to the term ‘conflict about namely, the strike, for the notion of method
work’for it focused attention on the workplace displacement has highlighted the prevalence
but, with our theoretical approach, without of other semi-collective and individualized
losing the sense of the totality. We also methods of conflict expression. Clearly, much
used the term ‘employing organization’ to more research is needed to put flesh on the
denote our concern was with more than just bones of this hypothesis. Nonetheless, the
companies and businesses or profit-seeking reconfiguration of conflict at work continues
organizations. Thus, any organization which to present unions and associated leftist
employs people as workers or managers was political parties with a major conundrum
the subject of our analysis where our concern given that they are both predicated, in different
was conflict within an employing organization ways, on the collective association of workers.
and not between employing organizations or Finally, it is now becoming more apparent that
the workforces thereof. That conflict is better where unions continue to exist, globalization
conceived, at source, as being competition has forced them to internationalize conflict.
between different employing organizations Although still in their early days, international
over resources, market shares and profits. union solidarity, coalition building with new
In a similar holistic vein, we used the term social actors, global human rights campaigns
‘workers’ rather than ‘employees’ as the and corporate campaigns are consequently on
act of work rather the contractual status the rise around the world. So, to focus only on
CONFLICT AT WORK 603

strikes as the primary form of the expression Ackroyd, S. and Thompson, P. (1999) Organizational
of conflict at work would be to ignore these Misbehavior. London: Sage.
important new directions in conflict. Bernstein, J. and Gould, E. (2006) Working Families Fall
More generally, and given that a major, Behind. Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute.
explicit or implicit, cause of wider societal Blyton, P. and Turnbull, P. (1994) The Dynamics of
conflict under capitalism is the degree of Employee Relations. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Brehm, J. and Gates, S. (1997) Working, Shirking, and
income inequality and that the existence of
Sabotage: Bureaucratic Response to a Democratic
wage labor has a role to play in explaining Public. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
this inequality, political tensions and turmoil Bronfenbrenner, K. (2000) ‘Raw power: Plant-closing
are likely in the future. Increasing trade threats and the threat to union organizing’ Multina-
through globalization, according to the theory tional Monitor, 21 (12): 24–30.
of comparative advantage, ought to cause an Bureau of Labor Statistics (2006a) Press release.
increase in national incomes. But, without (<www.bls.gov/news.release/wkstp.nr0.htm>).
mediating institutions and policies to redis- Bureau of Labor Statistics (2006b) Press release.
tribute income, national income inequality (<www.bls.gov/news.release/union2.nr0.htm>).
will persist. Higher paid manufacturing jobs Campoletti, M., Hebdon, R. and Hyatt, D. (2005) ‘Strike
continue to be replaced by lower income incidence and strike duration: some new evidence
service jobs. There is growing evidence that from Ontario’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
58 (4): 610–30.
income inequality is, indeed, growing in North
Dowding, K., Peter, J., Mergoupis, T. and van Vugt, M.
America and Britain (Bernstein and Gould,
(2000) ‘Exit, voice and loyalty: Analytic and empirical
2006; Hills and Stewart, 2005, Yalnizyan, developments’ European Journal of Political Research
2007). Conflict about work and employment 37 (?): 469–95.
is, therefore, set to continue, even if it is Edwards, P. (1986) Conflict at Work: a Materialist
not always or only based on conflict at Analysis of Workplace Relations. Oxford: Basil
work and in employment. Whether it is, in Blackwell.
the traditional sense of manifest collective Edwards, P. and Hyman, R. (1994) ‘Strikes and
conflict, will be largely dependent upon the industrial conflict: peace in Europe?’ in R. Hyman and
ability of workers to work in concert with P. Edwards (eds) New Frontiers in European Industrial
each and mobilize through different forms of Relations. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 250–80.
common organization. Edwards, P. and Scullion, H. (1982) The Social
Organisation of Industrial Conflict. Oxford: Blackwell.
Edwards, P. and Whitston, C. (1989) ‘Industrial
discipline, the control of attendance and the
NOTES
subordination of labour: towards an integrated
analysis’ Work, Employment and Society, 3 (1): 1–28.
1 Although it should be noted that the term
‘industrial’ is synonymous with all non-agricultural Feuille, P. and Wheeler, H. (1981) ‘Will the Real
workers in the eyes of many authorities. Industrial Conflict Please Stand Up?’ in US Indus-
2 The absence of manifest conflict is often mistak- trial Relations 1950–1980: A Critical Assessment.
enly interpreted by those of a unitarist perspective as Madison, Wisconsin: IRRA. pp. 255–91.
evidence of ‘good management’. Fortado, B. (2001) ‘The Metamorphosis of Workplace
3 The Canadian data also permit a close examina- Conflict’ Human Relations, 54 (9): 1189–221.
tion of strike duration. The duration variable shown Fox, A. (1966) Industrial Sociology and Industrial
in Figure 31.2 is simply the number of calendar days
Relations, Research Paper No. 3, Royal Commission
that the workers were on strike.
on Trade Unions and Employers’ Associations.
London: HMSO.
Fox, A. (1971) A Sociology of Work in Industry. London:
REFERENCES Macmillan.
Friedman, A. (1977) Industry and Labour: Class Struggle
Abbot, B. (2004) ‘Worker representation through the and Monopoly Capitalism. London: Macmillan.
Citizen’s Advice Bureaux’ in Healy, G., Heery, E., Gall, G. (1999a) ‘A review of strike activity in Western
Taylor, P. and Brown, W. (eds) The Future of Worker Europe at the end of the second millennium’ Employee
Representation. Basingstoke: Palgrave. pp. 245–63. Relations, 21 (4–5): 357–77.
604 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Gall, G. (1999b) ‘What is to be done with organized Mayo, E. (1933) The Human Problems of an Industrial
labour?’ Historical Materialism, 5: 327–43. Civilisation. New York: Macmillan.
Gall, G. (2006) ‘Collective alternatives to striking’ McCammon H. (2001) ‘Labor’s legal mobilization – Why
Research Report No. 5. Hatfield: Employment and when do workers file unfair labor practices?’
Research Service, Centre for Research in Employment Work and Occupations, 28 (2): 143–75.
Studies, University of Hertfordshire. Milner, S. (1993) ‘Overtime bans and strikes: Evidence
Godard, J. (1994) Industrial Relations, the Economy, and on Relative Incidence’ Industrial Relations Journal,
Society. Scarborough: McGraw-Hill Ryerson. 24 (3): 201–10.
Godard, J. (2003) ‘Do labor laws matter? The density Morrill C., Zald, M. and Rao, H. (2003) ‘Covert political
decline and convergence thesis revisited’, Industrial conflict in organizations: challenges from below’
Relations, 42 (3): 458–92. Annual Review of Sociology, 29: 391–415.
Harrison, A. and Stewart, M. (1993) ‘Strike duration and Nichols, T. (1997) The Sociology of Industrial Injury.
strike size’ Canadian Journal of Economics, 26 (4): London: Mansell.
830–48. Offe, C. and Wisenthal, H. (1985) ‘Two logics of
Hebdon, R. (2005) ‘Toward a theory of workplace collective action’ in C. Offe, (ed.) Disorganised
conflict: The case of US municipal collective bargain- Capitalism: Contemporary Transformation of Work
ing’ Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations, 14: and Politics. Cambridge: Polity Press. pp. 170–220.
35–67. Olson, C. (1988) ‘Dispute resolution in the public sector’
Hebdon, R. and Stern, R. (1998) ‘Tradeoffs among in Public Sector Bargaining. Madison, Wisconsin:
expressions of industrial conflict: public sector strike Industrial Relations Research Association.
bans and grievance arbitrations’ Industrial and Labor Piazza, J. (2005) ‘Globalizing quiescence: globalization,
Relations Review, 51 (2): 204–21. union density and strikes in 15 industrialized
Hills, J. and Stewart, K. (eds) (2005) A More countries’ Economic and Industrial Democracy, 26 (2):
Equal Society? New Labour, Poverty, Inequality and 289–314.
Exclusion. Bristol: Policy Press. Robinson, S. and Bennett, R. (1995) ‘A typology of
Hurd, R. (1976) ‘New deal labor policy and the deviant workplace behaviors: A multi-dimensional
containment of radical union activity’ Review of scaling study’ Academy of Management Journal,
Radical Political Economics, 8 (1): 32–43. 38 (2): 555–73.
Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: a Marxist Ross, A. and Hartman, P. (1960) Changing Patterns of
Introduction. London: Macmillan. Industrial Conflict. New York: Wiley.
Hyman, R. (1977) Strikes. second edition. Glasgow: Sapsford, D. and Turnbull, P. (1994) ‘Strikes and
Collins. industrial conflict in Britain’s docks: balloons or
Hyman, R. (1980) ‘Theory in industrial relations: towards icebergs?’ Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
a materialist analysis’ in P. Boreham and G. Dow 56 (3): 249–65.
(eds) Work and Inequality. Melbourne: Macmillan. Scheuer, S. (2006) ‘A novel calculus? Institutional
pp. 38–59. change, globalization and industrial conflict in
Hyman, R. (1982) ‘Pressure, protest, and struggle: Europe’ European Journal of Industrial Relations,
some problems in the concept and theory of 12 (2): 143–64.
Industrial Conflict’ in G. Bomers and R. Peterson Shalev, M. (1992) ‘The resurgence of labor quiescence’
(eds) Conflict Management and Industrial Relations. in M. Regini (ed.) The Future of Labor Movements.
Boston: Kluwer. pp. 96–119. London: Sage. pp. 102–32.
Jackson, M. (1987) Strikes: Industrial Conflict in Britain, Skeels, J., McGrath, P. and Arshanapalli, G. (1988)
USA and Australia. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books. ‘The importance of strike size in strike research’
Jackson, M. (1991) Introduction to Industrial Relations. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 41 (4):
Routledge: London. 582–91.
Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobi- Spector, P. (1975) ‘Relationships of organizational
lization, Collectivism and Long Waves. London: frustration with reported behavioral reactions of
Routledge. employees’ Journal of Applied Psychology, 60 (5):
Kerr, C. (1964) Labor and Management in Industrial 635–37.
Society. New York: Doubleday. Statistics Canada (2005) ‘Fact Sheet on Work Absences’,
Kornhauser, A. (1954) ‘Human motivations underlying Perspectives on Labor and Income, April, 6/4.
industrial conflict’ in R. Dubin, A. Kornhauser and Statistics Canada (2006) ‘Increased Work Stop-
M. Ross (eds) Industrial Conflict. New York: McGraw- pages’, Perspectives on Labor and Income,
Hill. pp. 62–85. August, 7/8.
CONFLICT AT WORK 605

Statistics Canada (2007) ‘Gender Differences in Quits Tucker J. (1993) ‘Everyday forms of employee
and Absenteeism’, The Daily, 23 February, p. 5. resistance: How temporary workers handle conflict
Taylor, F. (1911) The Principles of Scientific Manage- with their employers’ Sociological Forum, 8 (1):
ment. New York: Harper and Row. 25–45.
Thompson, P. and Ackroyd, S. (1995) ‘All quiet on the Wheeler, H. (1985) Industrial Conflict: An Integrative
workplace front? A critique of recent trends in British Theory. Columbia, South Carolina: University of South
industrial sociology’ Sociology, 29 (4): 615–33. Carolina Press.
Tomlinson, A. (2002) ‘Healthy living a remedy for Yalnizyan, A. (2007) The Rich and the Rest of Us: the
burgeoning employee absentee rates.’ Canadian HR Changing Face of Canada’s Growing Gap. Ottawa:
Reporter, 15/6, 25 March. Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.
32
Skill Formation
Irena Grugulis

Skill has always been a central element of system, provide specialist publicly-funded or
industrial relations (IR). In Britain many of subsidized vocational education and training
the early trade unions and friendly societies (VET), or rely on individual firms to offer
formed around skilled trades, to negotiate continuing development. Such differences
pay levels, the differentials available for skill seem to be stable; despite the rhetoric on
or experience and ensure the development globalization there seems to be little sign of
of skills (see, for example Cockburn,1983; convergence between states. Korea remains
Penn, 1984; Thelen, 2004). Skill affects the different to the US and France’s system
way work is designed and organized and is not the same as that in Hungary. Nor
influences, or stems from, the levels of do these differences in vocational training
power, discretion and autonomy that workers occur in isolation. Rather, each is embedded
have over work processes (Turner, 1962). in systems of institutional structures and
It is also a key aspect in the way that relationships, managerial strategies, market
firms, industrial sectors and nations compete. relations and national systems. Indeed, it is
Indeed, high skills have the potential to likely that these structures make the differ-
both raise wages and improve firm and ences between the various systems of skill
national competitiveness (Culpepper, 2001). formation meaningful. After all, once a skill
Unsurprisingly then, what skills are formed, has been learned it must be put into practice in
how they are developed and the way they the workplace so the markets in which a firm
are exercised in the workplace is a matter of competes, the way managerial authority is
key interest to all parties in the employment exercised and the discretion that is allowed to
relationship. workers are all likely to be highly influential.
It is also an area of enduring vari- According to Whitley (2003) there are five key
ation between nations with systems of elements in these differences (680):
skill formation and employment relations
often differing dramatically from country • the extent and nature of the state’s coordinating
to country (Crouch et al., 1999; Whitley, role in economic development;
1999). Nations vary greatly in the extent • the organizational basis, and particularly the
that they rely on the general education cohesion of business associations;
SKILL FORMATION 607

• the strength of the market for corporate control; involvement from public institutions. Some
• the organization and effectiveness of the public states regulate particular industry sectors
training system; but this intervention is being abandoned
• the extent and form of labour market regulation. rather than extended, as in the construction
industry. Such a withdrawal of influence
Ashton (2004) describes this far more does little to encourage investment, indeed,
concisely as the relationship between capital, training levels have slumped in the states
labour and the state. Both of these authors which have deregulated, as has investment
are careful to emphasize that the skills in physical capital and productivity (Bosch,
that are developed and exercised depend 2003; Crouch et al., 1999). One brief attempt
on many more factors than the relative to devise national skill standards never got
vocational education and training practices. off the ground (Ashton, 2004). In the absence
Job design, employment security and inter- of nationally recognized qualifications most
firm relations (among others) will influence learning is by doing, quality is uneven and
and be influenced by the way firms compete, provision polarized. Workers who are not
their ownership structures and the trust and already qualified to degree level are unlikely
authority that is delegated or withheld. to receive firm-sponsored training and, when
Accordingly, this chapter seeks to present they do, the opportunities they are presented
various different skill formation systems with are often narrowly based, while firms
in their national and institutional settings. complain that much of their training spend
It starts by describing practices in three is remedial. Many organizations rely on
very different systems: the US, Japan and outside training providers or immigration
Germany; noting particularly the nature and to supply them with skills (Rubery and
role of state involvement, the extent to which Grimshaw, 2003). By contrast, employees
decisions are left to individual firms and the who are already extremely highly educated
legacy of VET that exists; before exploring may benefit from extensive (and expensive)
the reasons for the differences observed provision (Crouch et al., 1999).
and considering the relative advantages and At firm level high turnover and low wages
disadvantages of each system. It then focuses make investing in skills unattractive. The US
on the firms themselves and the choices they is the only developed economy where wages
make (since firms within the same sector can have actually fallen over the last 20 years
and do make very different choices about the (Green, 2006). But as Crouch et al. (1999)
skills they require from, and are prepared to point out, this seems to be a deliberate
develop in, their workers). Finally it considers strategy rather than a pre-determined feature
the impact that trade unions have on skill of the labor market. Organizations that seek
formation in both regulated economies (where to reduce turnover (by offering greater job
unions are often pivotal and institutionalized security, linking pay to performance and
elements of the system) and market ones involving employees in decision making)
(where individual firms choose whether or not are generally successful. Yet these are, and
to recognize a union presence). remain, a minority. It seems that most US firms
would rather treat labor as a variable cost,
preserving numerical flexibility when demand
THE US slackens. Despite this, the US enjoys both high
capital productivity and reasonably high labor
In the US there is little state involvement productivity in most sectors and is particularly
in learning and the system of vocational effective at producing highly skilled elites in
education is market-led and decentralized financial services, aero engineering, entertain-
(Rubery and Grimshaw, 2003). Almost all ment, biotechnology and software. But the
decisions on skills development are taken exceptional performance of those with most
by individual firms or workers with little skills effectively conceals a far less impressive
608 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

average performance and a wide distribution workers have further incentives to stay with
of skills, which is growing yet wider. More the same employer and are not penalized for
recently too, US job growth has been achieved abandoning their specialism and learning new
by trading off skills against employment. skills (Cole, 1992; McMillan, 1996).

JAPAN GERMANY

Japan, like the US, leaves VET decisions The lynchpin of German VET is its rig-
and activities to individual firms. State orous system of three-year apprenticeships,
intervention took the form of encouraging which are long established in the old West
large firms to develop, post war, then giving Germany and were extended to the East
them free rein internally (Thelen, 2004). But after unification, a process which, as noted
while companies are free to decide their own below, was not without problems. These
strategies and set their own training stan- are designed by consensus with input from
dards both skill formation and employment employers’ associations, trade unions and
practices are very different to those in the educationalists and costs are shared between
US. In Japan, large ‘institutional companies’ all parties to the employment relationship
provide workers with employment security (including the apprentices who accept a wage
and put a great deal of effort into encouraging set at about a third of the adult wage for
active social engagement and identity with the duration of their studies, Crouch et al.,
the firm (Dore and Sako, 1989; Sako, 1999; 1999; Rubery and Grimshaw, 2003; Streeck
Keizer, 2005). A high proportion of young et al., 1987). Time on the program is split
people stay on in general education and between formal taught courses in colleges
this is then reinforced by a remarkable and and on-the-job learning, generally structured
extensive system of continuing education around a series of problem solving activities
and development once in employment. Skill that become progressively more challenging.
formation is broad and extends to the majority Apprentices are taught by Meister (master
of the workforce (Cole, 1992). One study, craftspeople) who are both qualified experts in
cited in Crouch et al. (1999) calculated that their occupation and still actively practicing so
the average Japanese firm provided newly workplace innovations are incorporated into
recruited assembly workers with 310 hours of the program (Culpepper, 1999; Lane, 1987,
training, Japanese-owned subsidiaries in the 1989).
US offer 280 hours while US plants provide This intensive and highly regarded prepa-
only 48 hours. ration for work is supported by several
This in-company training is key since features: low turnover; employee involvement
some of the initial skills of Japanese workers both directly in work design and process
compare poorly with those in Britain and and indirectly through the trade unions and
Germany (particularly among engineering works councils; and comparative employment
graduates). This formal learning is rarely security once employees are in work. The state
accredited (since workers may expect to stay is involved in supporting apprenticeship but
with one firm for most of their working also, more directly, by regulating employment
lives) but is supplemented by extensive far more closely than do national governments
on-the-job training. Flexibility is ensured in either the US or Japan. Because such
by moving workers between departments regulation makes labor more expensive, it
which has the added advantage of providing provides an incentive to employers to use
skills development beyond the traditional it differently (Streeck, 1992). Lane’s (1987)
functional work areas so materially assisting study of the banking and insurance industries
workplace problem solving. Since pay and shows how automation was used to eliminate
promotions are heavily based on seniority, almost all the low-skilled jobs. Other tasks
SKILL FORMATION 609

were combined in a way that retained (and that businesses operate most effectively when
occasionally raised) skill levels, including a unfettered by regulation and that they are best
greater focus on customer service. In Britain, placed to assess their own skill needs and react
by contrast the introduction of technology in to changes as the market dictates. Competitive
banks resulted in work being standardized pressures will ensure businesses remain
with 91 per cent of clerks and 50 per cent of responsive and offer suitable training. The
supervisors doing deskilled work (Crompton government’s role is to minimize intervention
and Jones, 1984: 61). and ensure that appropriate legal and other
These three national systems develop skills frameworks are in place to facilitate the free
in very different ways, supporting dramat- play of market forces.
ically different levels and distributions of Alternatively, in regulated systems, gov-
skills in the economy. The US, as noted ernments may take the view that skills
above, is highly successful at producing small development is a public good, that it is in
numbers of expert elite workers, Reich’s everyone’s interest to have a highly skilled
(1991) ‘symbolic analysts’ who compete population but that, left to themselves, indi-
against the best in the world, but in the process vidual businesses will be unable or unwilling
average and low-skilled workers are (often to invest sufficiently in the long-term skills of
badly) neglected. In Japan, male workers in their employees. Indeed, where a competitive
large firms receive continued and extensive market exists between firms, it may be rational
skills development on- and off-the-job and for them to choose not to train since there is
the way those skills are learned ensures no obligation on their competitors to invest
a competence that is very broadly based. similar amounts of money and skilled workers
While in Germany about two-thirds of the may be poached by other firms. So activities
workforce are qualified to intermediate level that make sense at firm level may effectively
in vocationally relevant skills (Bosch, 2003; sabotage the sector or the economy’s chance
Steedman, 2001). In the workplace these skills of up-skilling. It then becomes the state’s task
are harnessed to workplace innovations. to provide such skills or ensure that systems
These variations stem from a range of are in place which will guarantee that business
different choices made by states, employers provides them.
and occasionally trade unions on a range of Regulation may take a variety of forms.
factors including the form and nature of state The state can supply the necessary skills
intervention, the relations that exist between directly or put systems in place to ensure
firms, the way those firms compete and the that businesses invest in development. Taiwan
product markets in which they compete. These and Denmark provide interesting examples
are worth exploring in more detail since they of both of these approaches. Both economies
help to reveal both the depth of variation in the are dominated by small and medium sized
different systems and something about their enterprises (which are far less likely to
relative prospects for the future. train and develop workers than their larger
competitors) and in both nations the state has
intervened to ensure that VET takes place
and that activities are of high quality but
ACCOUNTING FOR DIFFERENCES
these interventions take very different forms.
In Taiwan extensive technical and vocational
Voluntarism and regulation
skills were introduced into the education sys-
A key aspect in all skill formation systems tem. Despite the fact that most of the demand
is the role played by the state. This can be was for (high status) academic courses,
voluntarist (also known as liberal or market- and that these would have been cheaper to
based) or regulated (educational). The central provide, the Taiwanese government invested
assumption in a voluntarist system, as is extensively in the education of scientists
broadly the case in the US and Britain, is and engineers. Access to academic courses
610 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

was officially restricted, more than half of William Hewlett and David Packard) even
school-children were channeled into techni- set up the first university science park to
cal training and, at university level, more provide fledgling firms with support services.
courses were made available for scientists and The infrastructure is conducive to growth with
engineers and new Institutes of Technology good local transport, an international airport
launched. Student numbers, textbooks and and a state-of-the-art telecommunications
curricula were state controlled and this meant system while the availability of venture
that Taiwan succeeded in both increasing capital, low levels of regulation and limited
the numbers of low-cost industrial products penalties on bankruptcy encourage start-ups.
for export and also managed the transition These small and often highly focused firms
from this to higher value-added production prosper through inter-dependency forming
across many if not all sectors without partnerships with other organizations and
significant reported skills shortages (Green participating in employer groups to pur-
et al., 1999a). In Denmark, a long legacy of sue initiatives such as improving technical
strong and collaborative trade unions meant training in city colleges, that are to their
that workplace learning programs could be mutual benefit. Individuals also collaborate
set centrally (by both employers and unions) through professional associations, continuing
to ensure high standards and consistency, education courses and alumni associations. In
while state subsidy provided for a high uptake firms there is little formal training but skills
by firms and apprentices (Ashton, 2004). and expertise are developed through project
Elsewhere, state imposed levies and ‘licenses work on cutting edge technical challenges.
to practice’ for particular occupations help Even labor mobility, a point of concern
to ensure high skills and high competence. elsewhere, assists knowledge diffusion and
In France, employers are required to support adds to personal and professional networks.
training or pay a levy of 1.5 per cent However, these two ways of operating are
of turnover plus an apprenticeship tax of successful at different activities and, with the
0.5 per cent of turnover to the state. While very notable exception of Japan it is difficult
in Austria, Germany, Switzerland and the to find an example of a market economy which
Netherlands there are systems of extensive provides high quality skills development for
and rigorous apprenticeships which attract the majority of the workforce.
high proportions of young people entering the Such inactivity presents voluntarist
labor market (Steedman, 2001). economies with a dilemma. Most support
Both voluntarist and regulated approaches high skills competition with other nations and
can be successful. Regulation is particularly believe this can best be achieved by market
effective at ensuring that large sections of means, leaving firms unregulated so that the
the working population acquire a broad fittest survive to compete internationally.
range of vocationally relevant skills while Yet in practice this lack of intervention may
Finegold’s (1999) work in Silicon Valley result in low-skills competition (Finegold
demonstrates how this intensely competitive and Soskice, 1988). Not only is such activity
labor market can support a ‘high skills less desirable than knowledge-based, high
ecosystem’. Silicon Valley is famously the skills competitiveness, since the margins
site of a cluster of extremely high-tech earned are likely to be narrower; it may also,
computing firms. These are supported by outside person-to-person services which are
the proximity of universities (University not readily sent off-shore, be a finite strategy
of California campuses in Berkeley, San for the developed world as India and China
Francisco, San Diego and Los Angeles provide increasing access to cheap, highly
and private institutions such as Stanford, skilled labor. When the hourly labor costs
USC and CalTech) that supply expert labor, in inland China are 41 US cents an hour
share research and stimulate start-up com- and those in Sri Lanka 40 US cents an hour
panies. Stanford (whose graduates include (Freeman, 2005) it is difficult to imagine
SKILL FORMATION 611

how the developed world can compete on Moreover, it is difficult to apply either label to
labor cost alone. In Britain and Australia Japan. Large firms are certainly given a great
this dilemma has resulted in extensive deal of freedom by the state to decide whether,
official intervention to encourage and exhort when and what skills to invest in, but limited
employers to provide more skill development labor mobility ensures that their investments
(Buchanan et al., 2004; Hampson, 2004; are far safer than those made by firms in
Keep and Mayhew, 1999; Keep and Stasz, other nations and it required extensive and
2004). However, these campaigns are often active state regulations for earlier generations
based on the assumption that the problem (including insisting on official approval for
is one of information, that once firms know firms hiring experienced workers, approval
how positive VET can be and what programs which would only be granted with the
are available they will invest in workforce consent of their previous employer) to limit
skills. Yet, there is no evidence to suggest this mobility (Thelen, 2004). This extensive
that non-training firms do not appreciate employer-provided training is also limited
the potential advantages that training can to the large firms and (generally) the male
confer (quite the contrary, as shown in employees. Kondo’s (1990) account of the
Matlay, 1998). It may be, as noted above, experiences of women and marginalized
that not training is a rational, economic workers presents a very different picture of
decision. Moreover, interventions tend to working life in Japan. Nonetheless, despite
be targeted only at the supply of skills, so these reservations, it is still useful to know
this widespread activity does little to address the extent to which states are market-led or
the fact that firms may still compete on the regulated, particularly over issues of skill
basis of unskilled labor. More worryingly, formation since it is here that many will
by exempting employers from responsibility intervene.
for VET, these interventions may mean that
governments get stuck with both the role Competitive and co-operative relations
of skills provider and the need to subsidize Another key area of difference is in the
the private sector, and all in the name of relations that exist between firms. In Japan
voluntarism (Felstead et al., 2002; Keep and there are strong collaborative inter-firm net-
Ashton, 2004). works. Some of these are drawn together on
Both voluntarism and regulation are sim- a regional or craft basis but most are created
plifications. Few nations are prepared to and maintained by large corporations. Unlike
completely abandon economic intervention large US firms, which may have thousands
and even regulated states will not legislate for of suppliers, used for one-off contracts or
every activity. The dominance of the market switched when a price advantage is seen
in the US does not preclude the extensive elsewhere, even the largest Japanese firms will
(if variable) mass education system (Whitley, have only a few hundred suppliers, but their
1999) and many of the most highly skilled (tiered) relations with these are generally close
are selected on the basis of their educational and stable. Members of networks provide high
achievements or actively use their academic quality, just-in-time supply closely tailored
qualifications in the workplace (Estevez- to the needs of the central organization
Abe et al., 2001). While the British and with products adapted to suit changes in
Australian governments intervene extensively demand where necessary. In return they
in attempts to improve the supply of skills receive security of contract and long-term
(Keep and Ashton, 2004; Buchanan et al., partnership. Such close and sustained links
2004). German apprenticeships provide high mean that firms do not have to renegotiate
quality and widely recognized qualifications contracts and prices every time an order is
for young people but, after that, much contin- placed and processes, financial arrangements
uing development is as ad hoc and variable and management systems are often open to
as in market economies (Culpepper, 1999). supply chain partners for collective discussion
612 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and improvement. Since the members of long-term collaboration and close personal
networks are also linked to one another friendships between key workers. They are
they may combine to purchase expensive key elements in the success of VET provision
plant and equipment or help redistribute and collaborative inter-firm developments. As
work when deadlines are tight while their Culpepper (2001) points out in his account
central organizations are likely to invest in of changes to youth training in France
developing suppliers’ skills or providing tech- and the introduction of the apprenticeship
nology and expertise. Trust is strengthened system to East Germany after unification,
and maintained by the fact that effort goes many of the problems these interventions
into keeping personal, as well as institutional, experienced could be directly attributable
ties within the network with managers in to weak employer associations. Such col-
the whole supplier community encouraged to laborations are not confined to nations that
socialize together and to develop and maintain are ‘institutionally dense’ (Ashton, 2004).
friendships (Crouch et al., 1999; Dore and Networks do exist in Silicon Valley and the
Sako, 1989; Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995; Los Angeles concentration of multi-media
Whitley, 1999). companies (Finegold, 1999); they may be
In Germany links tend to be sectoral, rather created around Japanese transplants abroad
than supply-chain based. Wage bargaining (Brown, 2001a); supported by state and local
is still conducted sectorally with employer authority initiatives (Edwards et al., 2002);
associations negotiating for all their members. or grow around strong employer associations
Because of this, there is less incentive for (Grugulis et al., 2003). But they are far rarer
newly qualified apprentices to gain a premium in market-based economies where contracts
on their salary by moving employers (Rubery respond largely to price. Indeed, in the US,
and Grimshaw, 2003). Such collective agree- legislation actively discourages collaborative
ments also mean that firms do not compete inter-firm activities so shared interests gener-
by slashing wages and prices. Chambers of ally result in mergers or competition (Whitley,
Commerce rigorously police apprenticeship 1999). In market systems, when small supplier
programs to ensure that companies are not firms adjust their processes to suit their larger
exploiting trainees or exempting themselves customers there is no promise of contractual
from the obligation to provide training, and security (Blyton and Turnbull, 2004; Rainnie,
that all provision is of high quality. This 1988) and no expectation that developments
intervention is tolerated since the chambers will be mutual or gains shared. Some may be,
are controlled by the employers themselves albeit unequally but competition may also be
and they also provide a basis for sharing zero sum with firms competing to drive others
information on good practice; firms may come out of the market and small firms vulnerable
together to fund joint projects, invest in R&D to exploitation and insolvency.
or develop specific workplace innovations. These institutional links extend to the
Sanctions against firms that fail to train way firms are funded. Mutual shareholdings
range from formally removing apprentice in Japan and long-term bank investment
training powers or depriving them of access in Germany ensure that organizations are
to technology transfer networks as well supported on a long-term basis (Rubery and
as (widely used) more informal deterrents Grimshaw, 2003). In the US and Britain,
(Culpepper, 1999). where many large firms are publicly quoted,
In each of these networks the desire shareholders are far more likely to demand
to be competitive drives firms to improve short-term performance. To the extent that, as
their products, enhance the performance Cappelli (1995) notes, redundancy programs
of every member of their supply chain result in share price gains. Given the links
or invest in research and these positive noted elsewhere between job security and
reactions are fostered by the institutional investment in skills it is easy to see why
structures, the expectation (and reality) of such regular rounds of ‘de-knowledging
SKILL FORMATION 613

the firm’ have been criticized (Littler and high quality foodstuffs with 90 per cent
Innes, 2003). As Lloyd (1999) demonstrates of the workforce skilled bakers and most
in her comparative study of the British concentrated in areas of production which
and French aerospace industries, making would add value, such as decoration or adding
skilled workers redundant during economic fillings to the biscuits (as compared to British
downturns (the option taken by the British mass produced simple biscuits where most
firms) meant that they were far less well labor was unskilled). German workers were
equipped to take on orders when conditions able to take on more tasks, with one worker
improved. More broadly, co-operative and often monitoring several production lines and
collaborative relations between firms may accepting responsibility for quality (indeed,
encourage trust-based relations within them. such a concern is an integral element of
Such collaboration may take very different pride in the occupation or Beruf ). Similarly,
forms. In Germany and Denmark for example the German and Dutch construction sites
it is common for employees to be involved studied by Clarke and Wall (2000) had
in issues of job design and work process higher numbers of skilled workers, fewer
(Ashton, 2004), works councils and trade managers and far fewer faults reported than
union representatives have a formal role in their British counterparts. Indeed repeated
management and consultation has a statutory comparative studies of a range of different
basis (French, 2001). In Japan, where work industries and services show that German
processes tend to be designed in detail, little firms employ more skilled workers and pay
worker input is expected but a great deal higher wages but that those workers are
of effort is put into securing participation in far more productive, take more individual
detailed problem solving activities (Whitley, responsibility for quality and work very
1999). By contrast, in the market economies, differently to their counterparts elsewhere.
even where formal consultation mechanisms Moreover, when work is reorganized or
exist there is far less evidence of constructive new technologies introduced the priority for
collaboration on workplace problems. automation is to eliminate low-skilled jobs
and the remaining tasks are recombined in
Products and product markets ways that often increase skills still further
The markets that firms choose to compete in (Finegold et al., 2000; Jarvis et al., 2002; Lane,
are also significant since these have a key 1987).
influence on the skills that are developed
and the way they are used. Large numbers Firm level choices
of standardized products mass produced National systems of skill formation,
require very different forms of labor to employment and business are important.
customized, small batch, high quality or They provide the institutional and regulatory
innovative products. Thelen (2004) points out structures against which firms operate and
that since US companies have access to a they are, as noted above, comparatively
large and reasonably homogeneous domestic stable. Yet the existence of these structures
market, many went into mass production does not mean that choices at firm level
early, deskilling workers and selling large are irrelevant nor that every organization
numbers of standardized goods. In Germany, is a mirror image of all its compatriots.
by contrast, an emphasis on quality, cus- The choices that firms make: to enter
tomized service and products in all areas of certain markets and withdraw from others; to
the economy creates a very different demand compete on quality or compete on cost; to hire
for and supply of goods. It also involves and fire workers as orders are lost and won or
a very different way of organizing labor. to multi-skill them so that they can contribute
Mason et al.’s (1996) detailed study of biscuit at all levels of the production process; are
manufacturing shows how German firms all important and all have implications for
concentrated on producing small batches of skill formation. The emphasis in all of
614 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

these is on choice. As will be seen below, in organizations that introduced bundles of


certain decisions make it more likely (or more human resource practices such as ‘lean
rational) for organizations to invest in training production’ or ‘high performance work sys-
but such choices are not pre-determined since tems’ (Whitfield, 2000). But again, while
employment practices do not arrive as all these elements are positively linked
pre-formed templates, to be ‘read off’ once with higher levels of training they are not
decisions have been taken on products or deterministic. Firms can and do introduce new
strategies. Different firms can and do choose management practices without linking these
to enter the same market or adopt the same to employee training.
technology in very different ways (Ashton It may be that these, and other, choices
and Sung, 2006; Boxall and Purcell, 2003). are inextricably intertwined with the way
One choice that firms make is the market organizations choose to treat their employees,
in which they compete and the products or as dependable or disposable. Interchangeable
services they compete on. Mason et al.’s unskilled laborers are likely to be engaged on
(1996) study of biscuit manufacture, consid- very different types of work and have very
ered above, shows the links between such different expectations of skill formation to
strategies and skills; high skill levels are trusted expert workers. As numerous studies
generally associated with a high value added note, higher levels of training are associated
product strategy (Mason, 2004). Arthur’s with higher than average salaries, generous
(1999) study of US steel mini-mills reinforces fringe benefits, internal labor markets and
this. When production focused on small promotions based on seniority (Fairris, 2004;
batches of different products workers’ skills Frazis et al., 2000; Arthur, 1999). These are
were an integral part of the process since the generally explained by the fact that well-
changeover between batches could be com- treated employees are more likely to stay
plicated. Firms engaged on large production with their employer, reducing the risk that
runs, by contrast, required far less input and training investments will be lost to rival firms.
far fewer skills of their workers (who simply But, as Keep and Mayhew (1996) note, the
monitored the machinery). This intuitive causality is rather more complex than this
link does not invariably hold true. High as investments in skills and training may
value added production can be undertaken also justify others in sophisticated human
by predominantly low-skilled employees and resource practices, as workers contribute more
low cost production by highly skilled workers to production and perks are devised to reward
(Ashton and Sung, 2006). Aldi, the discount status.
supermarket chain, employs comparatively
few members of staff for the number of Trade unions and skill formation within
customers it serves but provides high levels firms
of training and above average wages. By There is also, particularly given this book’s
contrast Hannon (2005), in his study of focus, another area over which firms make
the Irish dairy industry observes how some choices and which can significantly impact
firms dramatically upgraded production but on skill formation and that is the role of
still kept tight control over work processes, trade unions. In Japan, Germany and Denmark
ensuring that skill levels remained low. unions’ roles are institutionalized. Indeed,
Another much cited predictor of training it is their co-operation which makes skill
levels is change at work and the introduction formation effective in each of these three
of new working practices since workers nations. There is extensive consultation with
need to familiarize themselves with new establishment level unions in Japan and
procedures, technologies and ways of working high levels of consensus and security in
(Ashton and Sung, 2006; Frazis et al., large firms; in Germany unions underpin
2000; Leigh and Gifford, 1999; Lynch and sectoral bargaining, collaborate on the design
Black,1998). With training particularly high and implementation of apprenticeships and
SKILL FORMATION 615

contribute to workplace decision making candidates who are less likely to complete
through local representation and works their apprenticeships (see also Berik and
councils; while in Denmark unions bring Bilginsoy, 2000). Elsewhere however the
together workplace interests from numerous evidence is less clear cut. Shibata (1999)
small and medium sized enterprises. Else- contrasts the reluctance of unions in the US
where, where unions are not automatically to let front-line workers acquire skills in
involved in the skill formation process, their basic maintenance (for fear that specialist
role is more debatable. maintenance workers would be laid off) with
In theory, unions can impact on skill the attitude of Japanese unions (in matched
formation and training in a number of plants), who had no such fears. Surveys have
ways. On the negative side they may reduce variously reported positive (Lynch, 1992),
workplace flexibility, increase pay levels or insignificant (Knoke and Kalleberg, 1994;
distort the premia available for skills and so Lynch and Black,1998) and negative (Frazis
make it less viable, or less attractive, for et al., 2000) correlations between union
employers to fund training. On the positive, presence and training levels.
they may increase workers’ security, raising In Britain the link between trade union
morale and commitment and so make training recognition and training is both more con-
more attractive for employers (by reducing sistent and more positive. Here, repeated
employee turnover and safeguarding invest- studies reveal a strong, positive association
ments in skill development), actively bargain with both the amount and the intensity of
with employers for skills, support skill for- training (Boheim and Booth, 2004; Green
mation practices such as apprenticeships and et al., 1999b; Booth et al., 2003). Not only
work with employers to justify higher wages are workers in unionized workplaces more
via productivity improvements. According to likely to receive training (and to receive
Stevens (1996), higher wages may also bring more training) than their non-unionized peers,
advantages to firms because they stimulate they are also more likely to be rewarded
productivity gains and productivity gains for this in the form of greater returns to
made through training (see, for example, training and higher wages (Booth et al., 2003).
Zwick, 2006) are likely to rise faster than The reasons for this seem to be less that
wages. unions bargain over training or implement
So much then for the theory, what of the training schemes themselves (they do, but
evidence? This is rather more mixed and there on a comparatively small scale) and more,
are distinct differences between the US and as Green et al. (1999b) note, to do with the
the British evidence. Several US studies have general environment for employee relations
revealed positive links between trade unions in these firms.
and training. Parker’s (1997) historical anal-
ysis of Milwaukee reveals how co-operation
with trade unions made its successful adop- DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS
tion of the German apprenticeship possible
between 1911 and 1933 (attempts to introduce These various and varying systems each boast
apprenticeships into unorganized industries very different advantages and disadvantages.
and areas met with repeated failure). More The flexibility of the market allows firms
recently, Bilginsoy’s (2003) research into to respond quickly to changing needs and
apprenticeships in the construction industry may provide a stimulus for them to support
shows dramatically higher success rates in the development of a ‘skills elite’ but it is
schemes funded by both unions and employers also far more likely to be the reason for a
than those run by employers alone (58 per cent problem in skill formation than the means
as opposed to 30 per cent) and this despite the of its solution. Organizations that compete
fact that the joint programs had significantly against one another may save training costs
higher numbers of women and minority by free-riding on the investments of their
616 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

competitors and poaching skilled workers. to ensure that workers acquired skills (Crouch
But one of the consequences of this for the et al., 1999). Yet recently this consensus
economy as a whole is that the workforce is has been challenged, not because of flaws
likely to be under-trained since few employers in the various systems of skill formation
will wish to risk their funds in developing but because increasingly integrated national
skills (Bosch, 2004) and employers are likely economies may make individual divergence
to suffer from the problems of skills shortages less viable and because the dramatic changes
and skills gaps (Hillage et al., 2002). This in technology and labor markets since the
also creates problems for employees since start of the 1990s may make formal systems
poaching makes skill premia unpredictable so of VET, which rely on stability and a
their investments of time or money may be consensus over which skills are needed and
at risk and, in the absence of training and will be rewarded in the future, much less
development, unskilled work is rarely well relevant.
paid, more likely to be casual or temporary Let us examine these two challenges.
and may not be linked to the sort of career Surprisingly perhaps globalization seems to
ladders which could improve both work and be the lesser one. Economies are connecting
life chances (Green, 2006). and international trade is growing (although
By contrast, the consensus required for this is not a new phenomenon) but different
regulated systems makes institutions less institutional frameworks mean that national
responsive to the needs of individual employ- economies develop very distinctive capabili-
ers (firms in Sweden complained repeatedly ties, competing in different sectors and with
but without success, at the start of the 1990s different technologies (Whitley, 2003). As
that the vocational training system needed Whitley (1999) notes, they are effectively
to be adapted to the shifts in technology competing by differentiating their goods,
and the market, Crouch, 2005). But they rather than by harmonizing practice against
are far more successful in providing high- some universal template. Even multi-national
quality, vocationally-relevant skills for the companies, which might be expected to be
majority of the working population. This the harbingers of shared practice generally
allows firms to compete on the basis of remain rooted in their own national and
quality goods, innovation or incremental cultural systems (Bradley et al., 2000), while
customization; earning more in both domestic employment practices are adapted to local
and international markets. Individual workers circumstances (Edwards and Ferner, 2002;
are more productive and are paid more, Ferner and Varul, 2000a, 2000b; Ramirez
which improves their standard of living and and Mabey, 2005). Markets are social as
has positive implications for society (Brown, well as economic institutions and firms may
2001b; Lloyd and Payne, 2003, 2004). shape the markets they are in as much as
It seems that, following Finegold and they respond to them (Djelic et al., 2005).
Soskice (1988), systems of skill formation As the descriptions of the various systems
may help to create ‘path dependencies’ which in this chapter have shown, differences
either enable nations to compete on the basis are embedded in competition and are far
of skills and knowledge or restrict them to more deeply rooted than simply divergent
low-wage, low-skill markets. Small wonder approaches to the same goal.
then that the consensus among commentators Set against this however, several of the reg-
was that some form of intervention was ulated economies are struggling. The Japanese
needed in national VET systems and that it economy has been in a prolonged slump for
was the role of the state to intervene through more than a decade while Germany is beset
regulation, by supporting tertiary bodies of by high levels of unemployment (Federal
employer and employee associations, by Statistical Office, 2005). Commentators vary
developing and insisting on occupational in their reactions to this, and particularly in
qualifications or by supporting skills directly, their predictions for the future health of the
SKILL FORMATION 617

German regulated system. None blame the 1997 and proved so popular that, even in work
country’s ills on its skill formation practices with no tradition of apprenticeships 60,000
but there are queries over whether, after the young people were in training by the end of
expenses and economic ills of unification, 2001, and this figure was in addition to the
these are sustainable. According to Crouch 10,000 apprentices enrolled on the ‘old’ ICT
(2005) ‘many’ employers are trying to free apprenticeship (Steedman et al., 2003:13).
themselves from the costly VET system By contrast, in the Anglo-American labor
and French’s (2000) study of IG Metall markets, where efforts have been put into
reveals how the firm’s activities in old reducing regulation and the focus is on
East German are effectively creating a dual numerically flexible workers (often employed
market, undermining the whole system of on temporary or part-time contracts) job
collective bargaining. Yet elsewhere in East growth is healthy and unemployment low. It
Germany, Culpepper (1999) notes how few seems that skills-based competition no longer
firms are attempting to introduce low-wage or secures economic advantage.
numerically flexible forms of labor (see also Yet what such accounts neglect is the
Bluhm, 2001). It may be that the service sector quality of the jobs that are available. Some
presents a greater danger here than unification. years ago The Economist, a publication
In the retail sector the old model of apprentice- known for its support of deregulated labor
trained assistants is being abandoned in favor (and other) markets greeted the news that
of small numbers of key, functionally flexible 10,000 new jobs had been created in the
‘anchor’ workers who support larger numbers US by publishing a joke that noted ‘you
of lower paid, numerically flexible employees need three of them to live’. As Green (2006)
(Kirsch et al., 2000), while in hotels the points out, in the US, alone among the
highly skilled and multi-lingual qualified developed world, real wages have declined
German employees are set against poorly paid over the last 20 years (elsewhere they have
East European domestics (Finegold et al., more than doubled). In Britain part-time
2000). work, undertaken predominantly by women
Despite some claims (Sloane and Ertl, working in the service sector, is significantly
2003) demand for apprenticeships by young less well paid than its full time equivalent
people is still strong (and falls only slightly and part-time workers generally have little
short of record-breaking levels) although the access to career ladders or job-related training.
majority of East German trainees are on When an economy is dominated by such jobs
schemes subsidized by the state, which raises it may be trapped in a ‘low-skills equilibrium’
questions about employer commitment to where the existence of low-skilled, low-
co-funding (Culpepper, 1999). Encouragingly paid labor creates a demand for low priced
too the system for designing apprenticeships products which themselves create a demand
is becoming more adept at responding to for low-skilled labor (Finegold and Soskice,
change and technological innovation. In the 1988). Nor is there any evidence that future
past Germany certainly struggled to provide job generation will restrict the numbers of
qualifications for developing industries such such undesirable jobs. As Brown (2001b)
as ICT since the tri-partite arrangements for notes, sweatshops have been observed again
agreeing standards were so time consuming in the US, and the existence of so many
that qualifications in fast developing fields part-time workers provides a considerable
were out of date before they were launched. economic advantage. Most of the new jobs
However, this development process has been being created are confined to front-line service
considerably shortened and the dominance work and characterized by low skill, low
and longevity of systems like Microsoft mean pay and low prospects (see, for example
that computing skills that do not date rapidly Nolan and Slater, 2003). Yet there is no
can be supported (Bosch, 2003). Four new requirement for these jobs to be poorly
technical apprenticeships were launched in paid. In Sweden many person-to-person care
618 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

services are undertaken by the public sector will be attempting to acquire skills and that
and workers enjoy reasonable earnings and some will succeed in acquiring the ‘right’
good terms and conditions (Esping-Andersen, ones (whatever these turn out to be). He
1999). In opting for high numbers of badly acknowledges that such a system is wasteful.
paid jobs in the private sector employers and While some workers will succeed in this
their governing states have noted the trade-off blindfolded game of the survival of the fittest
between skill and employment and embarked many will not and since those who fail
on the low road to prosperity (Crouch et al., to guess correctly may have education but
1999; Ebbinghaus and Kittel, 2005; Maurin few vocationally relevant skills he suggests
and Postel-Vinay, 2005). that their alternative source of employment
Any contrast between economies cannot be is the unskilled part of the service sector,
reduced to a simple headcount between the work that is likely to prove alienating and
numbers employed or unemployed (although unfulfilling.
such headline figures are important). It is Worryingly though it is these free-market
also significant that US firms pay low wages, approaches that seem to be being taken up by
provide few forms of social protection, invest many rapidly developing economies. Russia’s
little in skills and cope with high levels new market economy relies almost entirely
of employee turnover while their German on old Soviet-era skills or the vocational
counterparts treat workers very differently. training carried out in what remains of the
It may be more worrying to consider public sector. In the private sector poaching is
areas of job growth and skills change. As the most widely used substitute for training,
noted above, some of the most problematic although some firms do hire highly educated
developments for the German system can be graduates in the hope that they may be able
observed in the service sector where long to learn what is necessary on the job. On the
traditions of high skill, high quality and rare occasions that training is provided it is
responsible autonomy are being abandoned seen as a privilege of rank, rather than an
in favor of low skill and direct control. This activity required to do work well, so those
area has been the site of most dramatic job with high status in the firm may be sent on
growth in recent years and in the US more courses, regardless of whether they can benefit
people are now employed by McDonald’s than from them. One knitwear firm in Kemerovo
US Steel (Macdonald and Sirianni, 1996). got a new computerized knitting machine but
At the same time, manufacturing has been sent the designer rather than the operator to be
in decline, effectively, as Crouch (2005) trained in how to use it, so were never able to
observes, removing a major source of stable, deploy it to full capacity (Clarke and Metalina,
middle skill occupations. Since many existing 2000). Even in Hungary, which has attempted
skill formation systems thrive on the stability to support a gentle transition from a managed
of sectors, and many successful programes economy to capitalism, most up-grading of
are located in manufacturing this may cause production and up-skilling of the workforce is
problems. observable in the foreign-owned firms. While
The model of skills development proposed Korea, although heavily influenced by the
by Crouch (2005) in response to this seems Japanese system in other ways, is heavily
more of a problem than a solution. When dependent on cheap, unskilled labor and firms
no-one knows what skills are likely to be provide little VET and very limited access
needed in the future because demand has to career ladders for these workers (Whitley,
become much more unpredictable, an absence 1999). It seems unlikely that this is the result
of provision coupled with a tendency of of free choice or due consideration over which
governments to defer responsibility for skills skill formation system is most effective.
acquisition to the young people entering the Rather, the absence of strong intermediary
labor market (who need to be flexible and bodies (including trade unions, professional
to ‘learn to learn’) means that many workers bodies or employers’associations) and limited
SKILL FORMATION 619

resources drive both firms and nations towards Berik, G. and Bilginsoy, C. (2000) ‘Do unions help or
a laissez faire free market approach. hinder women in training? Apprenticeship programs
To some extent, this is simply a new gloss in the United States.’ Industrial Relations 39 (4):
on an old problem. The dilemma of providing 600–24.
skills remains and, for the majority, it is Bilginsoy, C. (2003) ‘The hazards of training: attrition
and retention in construction industry apprenticeship
likely that market systems will fail (there have
programs.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review
always been a minority who have succeeded
57 (1): 54–67.
under these conditions). The rapid changes Bluhm, K. (2001) ‘Exporting or abandoning the “German
in technology, in skills required and the Model”? Labour policies of German manufacturing
eternal impossibility of predicting the future firms in Central Europe.’ European Journal of
may make the skills dilemma less easy to Industrial Relations 7 (2): 153–73.
resolve than in times when policymakers and Blyton, P. and Turnbull, P. (2004) The Dynam-
employers could assert with confidence what ics of Employee Relations. Basingstoke: Palgrave
industry’s requirements would be in 20 years Macmillan.
time, but they do not change the fact that the Boheim, R. and Booth, A. (2004) ‘Trade union presence
skills available in the labor force are a major and employer-provided training in Great Britain.’
influence on the way companies use labor Industrial Relations 43 (3): 520–45.
nor that markets can be and are constantly Booth, A., Francesconi, M. and Zoega, G. (2003)
‘Unions, work-related training, and wages: evidence
actively shaped. It may well be that in nations
for British men.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review
and sectors where young people are equipped 57 (1): 68–91.
with skills they will have to re-learn them or Bosch, G. (2003) ‘Skills and innovation – a
acquire new ones in the course of their careers German perspective.’ Presented at The Future of
but it is surely better to provide skills and Work/SKOPE/Centre for Organization and Innovation
decent jobs to go with these expectations of Conference on Skills, Innovation and Performance,
flexibility than to abandon the labor market 31 March–1 April, Cumberland Lodge, Windsor Great
entrants to their fate. As experience in Japan Park.
shows, skilled workers are not necessarily Bosch, G. (2004) ‘Towards a new standard employment
inflexible and gaining new skills may add to relationship in Western Europe.’ British Journal of
their abilities and capacity to problem solve. Industrial Relations 42 (4): 617–36.
Whichever predictions on the future of the Boxall, P. and Purcell, J. (2003) Strategy and Human
Resource Management. London: Palgrave.
labor market prove correct it seems unlikely
Bradley, H., Erickson, M., Stephenson, C. and
that skill formation systems will converge in
Williams, S. (2000) Myths at Work. Cambridge: Polity
the future. Press.
Brown, A. (2001a) ‘Supporting learning in advanced
supply systems in automotive and aerospace
REFERENCES industries.’ Presented at Joint Network/SKOPE/TLPRP
international workshop, 8–10 November, University
Arthur, J.B. (1999) ‘Explaining variation in human College Northampton.
resource practices in US steel mini-mills.’ in P. Cappelli Brown, P. (2001b) ‘Skill formation in the twenty-first
(ed.) Employment Practices and Business Strategy. century.’ in P. Brown, A. Green, and H. Lauder
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. (eds) High Skills: Globalization, Competitiveness and
pp. 11–42. Skill Formation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ashton, D. (2004) ‘The political economy of workplace pp. 1–55.
learning.’ in H. Rainbird, A. Fuller, and A. Munro Buchanan, J., Watson, I. and Briggs, C. (2004) ‘Skill
(eds) Workplace Learning in Context. London and and the renewal of labour: the classical wage-
New York: Routledge. pp. 31–59. earner model and left productivism in Australia.’
Ashton, D.and Sung, J. (2006) ‘How competitive strategy in C. Warhurst, I. Grugulis, and E. Keep (eds) The
matters? Understanding the drivers of training, Skills that Matter. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
learning and performance at the firm level.’ in pp. 186–206.
SKOPE Research Paper. Warwick and Oxford: SKOPE, Cappelli, P. (1995) ‘Rethinking employment.’ British
Universities of Warwick and Oxford. Journal of Industrial Relations 33 (4): 563–602.
620 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Clarke, L. and Wall, C. (2000) ‘Craft versus industry: the Esping-Andersen, G. (1999) Social Foundations of
division of labour in European housing construction.’ Postindustrial Economies. Oxford: Oxford University
Construction Management and Economics 18: Press.
689–98. Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2001)
Clarke, S. and Metalina, T. (2000) ‘Training in the ‘Social production and the formation of skills: a
new private sector in Russia.’ International Journal reinterpretation of the welfare state.’ in P. Hall and
of Human Resource Management 11 (1): 19–36. D. Soskice (eds) Varieties of Capitalism: The
Cockburn, C. (1983) Brothers: Male Dominance and Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage.
Technological Change. London: Pluto Press. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
Cole, R.E. (1992) ‘Issues in skill formation in Japanese pp. 145–83.
approaches to automation.’ in P. Adler (ed.) Fairris, D. (2004) ‘Internal labor markets and worker
Technology and the Future of Work. New York and quits.’ Industrial Relations 43 (3): 573–94.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 187–209. Federal Statistical Office, G. (2005) Press Release.
Crompton, R. and Jones, G. (1984) White Collar Felstead, A., Gaillie, G. and Green, F. (2002) Work
Proletariat: Deskilling and Gender in the Clerical Skills in Britain 1986–2002. Nottingham: DfES
Labour Process. London: Macmillan. Publications.
Crouch, C. (2005) ‘Skill formation systems.’ in Ferner, A. and Varul, M.Z. (2000a) ‘Internationalisation
S. Ackroyd, R. Batt, P. Thompson, and P.S. Tolbert of the personnel function in German multinationals.’
(eds) The Oxford Handbook of Work and Organiza- Human Resource Management Journal 10 (3):
tion. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. 79–96.
pp. 95–115. Ferner, A. and Varul, M.Z. (2000b) ‘ “Vanguard”
Crouch, C., Finegold, D. and Sako, M. (1999) Are Skills subsidiaries and the diffusion of new practices: a case
the Answer? The Political Economy of Skill Creation study of German multinationals.’ British Journal of
in Advanced Industrialised Countries. Oxford: Oxford Industrial Relations 38 (1): 115–40.
University Press. Finegold, D. (1999) ‘Creating self-sustaining, high-
Culpepper, P.D. (1999) ‘The future of the high-skill skill ecosystems.’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy
equilibrium in Germany.’ Oxford Review of Economic 15 (1): 60–81.
Policy 15 (1): 43–59. Finegold, D. and Soskice, D. (1988) ‘The failure of
Culpepper, P.D. (2001) ‘Employers, public policy and training in Britain: Analysis and prescription.’ Oxford
the politics of decentralized co-operation in Germany Review of Economic Policy 4 (3): 21–43.
and France.’ in P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds) Finegold, D., Wagner, K. and Mason, G. (2000) ‘National
Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations skill-creation systems and career paths for service
of Comparative Advantage. Oxford and New York: workers: hotels in the United States, Germany and
Oxford University Press. pp. 275–306. the United Kingdom.’ International Journal of Human
Djelic, M.-L., Nooteboom, B. and Whitley, R. (2005) Resource Management 11 (3): 497–516.
‘Introduction: dynamics of interaction between insti- Frazis, H., Gittleman, M. and Joyce, M. (2000)
tutions, markets and organizations.’ Organization ‘Correlates of training: an analysis using both
Studies 26 (12): 1733–1741. employer and employee characteristics’. Industrial
Dore, R. and Sako, M. (1989) How the Japanese Learn to and Labor Relations Review 53 (3): 443–62.
Work : Nissan Institute/Routledge. Japanese Studies Freeman, R. (2005) ‘What are the implications of glob-
Series. London: Routledge. alization for worker well-being and trade unions?’
Ebbinghaus, B. and Kittel, B. (2005) ‘European Presented at British Universities Industrial Relations
rigidity versus American flexibility? The institutional Association, 7–9 July, Northumbria University.
adaptability of collective bargaining.’ Work and French, S. (2000) ‘The impact of unification on
Occupations 32 (2): 163–95. German industrial relations.’ German Politics 9 (2):
Edwards, P., Gilman, M. Ram, M. and Arrowsmith, J. 195–216.
(2002) ‘Public policy, the performance of firms and French, S. (2001) ‘Works councils in Germany. Still
the “missing middle”: the case of the employment loyal to the trade unions?’ International Journal of
regulations and a role for local business networks.’ Manpower 22 (6): 560–78.
Policy Studies 23 (1): 5–20. Green, F. (2006) Demanding Work: The Paradox of
Edwards, T. and Ferner, A. (2002) ‘The renewed Job Quality in the Affluent Economy. Princeton and
“American Challenge”: a review of employment Oxford: Princeton University Press.
practices in US multinationals.’ Industrial Relations Green, F., Ashton, D., James, D. and Sung, J. (1999a)
Journal 33 (2): 94–111. ‘The role of the state in skill formation: evidence from
SKILL FORMATION 621

the republic of Korea, Singapore and Taiwan.’ Oxford Kondo, D.K. (1990) Crafting Selves: Power, Gender
Review of Economic Policy 15 (1): 82–96. and Discourse of Identity in a Japanese Workplace.
Green, F., Machin, S. and Wilkinson, D. (1999b) ‘Trade Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
unions and training practices in British workplaces.’ Lane, C. (1987) ‘Capitalism or culture? A comparative
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 52 (2): analysis of the position in the labour process and labor
179–95. market of lower white-collar workers in the financial
Grugulis, I., Vincent, S. and Hebson, G. (2003) ‘The services sector of Britain and the Federal Republic
rise of the “network organization” and the decline of Germany.’ Work, Employment and Society 1 (1):
of discretion.’ Human Resource Management Journal 57–83.
13 (2): 45–59. Lane, C. (1989) Management and Labour in Europe.
Hampson, I. (2004) ‘Training reform in a weakened Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
state: Australia 1987–2000.’ in C. Warhurst, Leigh, D. and Gifford, K.D. (1999) ‘Workplace
I. Grugulis, and E. Keep (eds) The Skills that Matter. transformation and worker upskilling: the perspective
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 72–90. of individual workers.’ Industrial Relations 38 (2):
Hannon, E. (2005) ‘Prospects for the upskilling of general 174–91.
workers in liberal market economies.’ Presented at Littler, C.R. and Innes, P. (2003) ‘Downsizing and
British Universities Industrial Relations Association, de-knowledging the firm.’ Work, Employment and
7–9 July, Northumbria University. Society 17 (1): 73–100.
Hillage, J., Regan, J., Dickson, J. and McLoughlin, K. Lloyd, C. (1999) ‘Regulating employment: implications
(2002) ‘Employers Skill Survey 2002.’ in Research for skill development in the Aerospace industry.’
Report. Nottingham: DfES. European Journal of Industrial Relations 5 (2):
Jarvis, V., O’Mahoney, M. and Wessels, H. (2002) 163–85.
‘Product quality, productivity and competitiveness: Lloyd, C. and Payne, J. (2003) ‘What is the “high skills
a study of the British and German ceramic society”? Some reflections on current academic and
and tableware industries.’ in Occasional Paper. policy debates in the UK.’ Policy Studies 24 (2/3):
London: National Institute of Economic and Social 115–33.
Research. Lloyd, C. and Payne, J. (2004) ‘The political economy of
Keep, E. and Ashton, D. (2004) ‘The state.’ Presented at skill.’ in C. Warhurst, I. Grugulis, and E. Keep (eds) The
SKOPE High Skills Vision Conference, 28–29 October, Skills that Matter. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Lumley Castle. pp. 207–24.
Keep, E. and Mayhew, K. (1996) ‘Evaluating the Lynch, L.M. (1992) ‘Private sector training and the
assumptions that underlie training policy.’ in A. Booth earnings of young workers.’ American Economic
and D.J. Snower (eds) Acquiring Skills. Cambridge: Review 82 (1): 299–312.
Cambridge University Press. pp. 305–34. Lynch, L.M. and Black, S.E. (1998) ‘Beyond the incidence
Keep, E. and Mayhew, K. (1999) ‘The assessment: of employer-provided training.’ Industrial and Labor
knowledge, skills and competitiveness.’ Oxford Relations Review 52 (1): 64–81.
Review of Economic Policy 15 (1):1–15. Macdonald, C.L. and Sirianni, C. (1996) ‘The service
Keep, E. and Stasz, C. (2004) ‘The Employers.’ Presented society and the changing experience of work.’ in
at SKOPE High Skills Vision Conference, 28–29 C.L. Macdonald and C. Sirianni (eds) Working in the
October, Lumley Castle. Service Society. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Keizer, A.B. (2005) The Changing Logic of Japanese pp. 1–26.
Employment Practices: A Firm-Level Analysis of Four Mason, G. (2004) ‘Enterprise product strategies and
Industries. Rotterdam: Erasmus Research Institute of employer demand for skills in Britain: evidence from
Management. the employers skill surveys.’ in SKOPE Working Paper.
Kirsch, J., Klein, M., Lehndorff, S. and Voss-Dahm, D. Warwick and Oxford: Universities of Warwick and
(2000) ‘The organization of working time in large Oxford.
German food retail firms’ in C. Baret, S. Lehndorff, Mason, G., Van Ark, B. and Wagner, K. (1996)
and L. Sparks (eds) Flexible Working in Food Retailing: ‘Workforce skills, product quality and economic
A Comparison between France, Germany, the UK performance.’ in A. Booth and D.J. Snower (eds)
and Japan. London and New York: Routledge. Acquiring Skills. Cambridge: Cambridge University
pp. 58–82. Press. pp. 175–97.
Knoke, D. and Kalleberg, A.L. (1994) ‘Job training in U.S. Matlay, H. (1998) ‘The paradox of training in the small
organizations.’ American Sociological Review 59 (4): business sector of the British economy.’ Journal of
537–46. Vocational Education and Training 49 (4): 573–89.
622 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Maurin, E. and Postel-Vinay, F. (2005) ‘The European job Steedman, H. (2001) Benchmarking Apprenticeship: UK
security gap.’ Work and Occupations 32 (2): 229–52. and Continental Europe Compared. London: Centre
McMillan, C.J. (1996) The Japanese Industrial System. for Economic Performance, LSE.
Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter. Steedman, H., Wagner, K. and Foreman, J. (2003)
Nolan, P. and Slater, G. (2003) ‘The labour market: The Impact on Firms of ICT Skill-Supply Strategies:
history, structure and prospects.’ in P. Edwards (ed.) an Anglo-German Comparison. London: Centre for
Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice. Oxford: Economic Performance, LSE.
Blackwell. pp. 58–80. Stevens, M. (1996) ‘Transferable training and poaching
Nonaka, I. and Takeuchi, H. (1995) The Knowledge externalities.’ in A. Booth and D.J. Snower (eds)
Creating Company: How Japanese Companies Create Acquiring Skills: Market Failures, Their Symptoms and
the Dynamics of Innovation. New York and Oxford: Policy Responses. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Oxford University Press. Press. pp. 19–40.
Parker, E. (1997) ‘Youth apprenticeship in a laboratory Streeck, W. (1992) Social Institutions and Economic
of democracy.’ Industrial Relations 36 (3): 302–23. Performance: Studies of Industrial Relations in
Penn, R. (1984) Skilled Workers in the Class Structure. Advanced Capitalist Economies. London: Sage.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Streeck, W., Hilber, J. van Kevalaer, K. Maier, F. and
Rainnie, A. (1988) Employment Relations in the Small Weber, H. (1987) ‘The role of the social partners in
Firm. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. vocational education and training in the FRG.’ Berlin:
Ramirez, M. and Mabey, C. (2005) ‘A labour CEDEFOP.
market perspective on management training and Thelen, K. (2004) How Institutions Evolve: The Political
development in Europe.’ International Journal of Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain the United
Human Resource Management 16 (3): 291–310. States and Japan. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Reich, R. (1991) The Work of Nations: Preparing Press.
ourselves for 21st century Capitalism. New York: Turner, H.A. (1962) Trade Union Growth, Structure and
Vintage Books. Policy. London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.
Rubery, J. and Grimshaw, D. (2003) The Organization of Whitfield, K. (2000) ‘High performance workplaces,
Employment. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. training and the distribution of skills.’ Industrial
Sako, M. (1999) ‘From individual skills to organizational Relations 39 (1): 1–25.
capability in Japan.’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy Whitley, R. (1999) Divergent Capitalisms: The Social
15 (1): 114–26. Structuring and Change of Business Systems. Oxford:
Shibata, H. (1999) ‘A comparison of American and Oxford University Press.
Japanese work practices: skill formation, communi- Whitley, R. (2003) ‘The institutional structuring of
cations and conflict resolution.’ Industrial Relations organizational capabilities: the role of authority
38 (2): 192–214. sharing and organizational careers.’ Organization
Sloane, P. and Ertl, H. (2003) ‘Current challenges and Studies 24 (5): 667–95.
reforms in German VET.’ Presented at Vocational Zwick, T. (2006) ‘The impact of training intensity
learning for the twenty-first century: international on establishment productivity.’ Industrial Relations
perspectives, 22–23 July, Oxford. 45 (1): 26–46.
33
Industrial Relations and
Business Performance
John T. Delaney

At the start of the twenty-first century, relevant research and report general IR effects
economic performance indicators seem to on organizational performance. After the
serve as society’s ultimate scorecard. Much review, I consider whether studies of these
attention is paid to measures of the econ- IR-performance links can adequately capture
omy, wealth, and performance. Witness the the essence and nature of IR – for workers and
prominence given to reports on the stock society.
market in the media. Inevitably, it seems today
that nations are judged by their economic
output and firms by their revenues and profits. WHAT IS ‘INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS?’
Only to a slightly lesser extent have people
come to be evaluated in these ways. ‘In a In this analysis, IR is viewed broadly as
capitalist society,’ as Alan Wolfe (1997: 566) a field covering activities related to unions,
has written, ‘we value work to the degree collective bargaining, human resource (HR)
that we establish a value for work.’ That the policies, and workplace rules that have
value and cost to society of people (usually the potential to alter interactions between
women) staying home to raise children is employers and employees. This approach
given less attention than the value of the reflects the origins of the field. As Kaufman
minimum wage illustrates our desire to use (2004: 3) reported, ‘the term industrial
metrics to summarize life. This makes it relations developed a broad, generic meaning
essential to examine links between industrial connoting the tenor or state of relations
relations (IR) and business performance.After between the different parties to the employ-
all, society will judge IR that way too. Such ment relationship.’Simultaneously, over time,
an analysis must begin, however, with a the field also developed more specific mean-
determination of the bounds of IR. Based ings, such as ‘the corporate employment
on the bounds, it is possible to discuss department and personnel policies used to
624 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

co-ordinate, control, and motivate labor,’ and Given the substantial decline in union
‘progressive labor policies’ such as collective density over the past 50 years, the association
bargaining and employee voice (Kaufman, of AWPs and performance has become a
2004: 3). Such an approach accepts the more prominent indication of the effect
notion that the adoption of alternative work of IR. For example, if used strategically by
practices (AWPs), creation of works councils, employers, such practices may shape and
or existence of systematic workplace discord reflect the likelihood of unionization. AWPs
may influence business performance. The may represent the firm’s preferred work rules,
approach also stipulates that IR is broader in contrast to the terms of typical collec-
than the study of unions and collective tive bargaining agreements, which reflect
bargaining. union and management preferences on many
Whereas this formulation claims that IR work rules. AWPs may also reflect workers’
encompasses most aspects of work and changing views and preferences regarding
employment, the measures of IR available the organization of work and need for union
for association with business performance are representation.
much more limited. For example, economists Accordingly, the review presented below
have long studied the relationship between focuses on three streams of research. First,
unionization and firm performance. To get attention is devoted to studies of the rela-
beyond theory, they examined measures of tionship between indicators of unionization
union representation (or coverage), union (including union and collective bargaining
density, and collective bargaining coverage. coverage) and measures of organizational
The indicators have been aggregated and performance (‘Old IR’). This is the oldest
disaggregated, and cover one point in time and most traditional way to link IR and firm
or many years. Essentially, the approach performance. Second, it is unsurprising that
treats unions as a ‘black box’ that influences this research stream gave rise to examinations
employment and organizational outcomes. of the types of rules enacted in union and
Conveniently, this allows the union effect to non-union workplaces. Accordingly, attention
be summed up empirically in the parameter is given to the association of union status
on the union measure in a regression equation. measures and the adoption of AWPs. This
Unfortunately, in addition to failing to show extension of ‘Old IR’ is important because
how unions influence outcomes, studies like it offers an opportunity to assess whether
this often ignore other workplace factors that unions indirectly influence business outcomes
could be associated with performance. For through the creation of certain HR policies
example, the organizational rules adopted and work rules. Third, in an era of declining
by employers influence the nature and unionization, it is necessary to study the link
effectiveness of workplace interactions. In between AWPs and firm performance. This
recent years, this has been demonstrated most ‘New IR’ view is premised on the notion that
clearly by the attention devoted to examining HR and organizational rules may be associ-
AWPs. Research has used many names for ated with performance. In particular, certain
AWPs, including innovative HR practices, approaches, such as ones emphasizing team-
high involvement management (HIM), high work and co-operation, may lead to stronger
performance work practices (HPWPs), high performance. And even if it is impossible to
performance work systems (HPWSs), sophis- disentangle precisely the relationship among,
ticated HRM, and so on. Regardless of the unions, AWPs, and performance, it is critical
name used, researchers have spent much to recognize that each component represents
time trying to estimate the association of part of the effect of IR. Prior to beginning the
AWPs with firm performance (see Becker research assessment, it is necessary to give
and Gerhart, 1996; Bryson et al., 2005; attention to several methodological concerns
Combs et al., 2006; Delaney, 1996; Huselid, and issues associated with studies of IR and
1995). business performance.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 625

A NOTE ON METHODOLOGICAL view was new to IR. In general, Freeman and


ISSUES AND CONCERNS Medoff accepted that unions had monopolistic
tendencies in some instances, but argued
One of the hallmarks of studies of IR and that the voice-enhancing aspects of unions
business performance is enduring criticism outweighed the monopoly aspects. This view
of research methods, designs, and results. was contentious then and continues to be so
Indeed, reviews of relevant literature, such as now. Freeman and Medoff’s new perspective
studies of unions and firm performance (see inspired considerable research on the two
Hirsch, 2004) or AWPs and organizational faces of unionism. As much of the research
outcomes (see Wright et al., 2005) pay sought to provide evidence of the effects of
significant attention to the methodological unions, it is relevant to an assessment of
problems of covered studies. The criticisms IR’s effects on business performance. For the
are often so strong that it would seem purpose of this review, research is divided
necessary to discount results of much of into three streams covering union effects on
the published research. Of course, in areas productivity, financial performance, and other
where theory is indeterminate – for example, business outcomes, such as organizational
economic theory suggests unions could raise stability and survival.
or lower productivity – this provides little
help. But the extent of the criticism needs
Unions and productivity
to be kept in mind when assessing the
research trends noted below. While specific Union effects on productivity are controver-
problems will be mentioned, I spend little time sial because economic theory does not provide
reviewing methodological concerns. Instead, clear guidance. Unions may lower productiv-
references are provided to reviews that closely ity by raising wages and other costs, putting
examine these problems. limits on work practices, promoting concerted
activities (for example, slowdowns), reducing
trust between managers and workers, and
encouraging less investment in operations by
THE OLD IR AND BUSINESS the organization. At the same time, unions
PERFORMANCE could increase productivity by encouraging
better management practices (to overcome the
Although economists have discussed the potential negative effects), monitoring output
effects of unions for many years (for a quality, and enhancing employee morale.
review, see Kaufman, 2004), studies linking How these conflicting theoretical premises
unionization and organizational outcomes are sort out is a matter for empirical analysis.
a recent phenomenon. The new attention Such analysis began in the late 1970s as
is due primarily to advances in computa- data and technology combined to permit more
tional power and the publication in 1984 careful studies than could be conducted in
of What Do Unions Do?, Richard Freeman earlier years. Freeman and Medoff (1984)
and James Medoff’s classic book on union assessed available empirical studies on the
effects. Freeman and Medoff’s book provided association between unions and productivity
empirical backing to their earlier assertion and concluded that ‘productivity is generally
that unions have ‘two faces’ (Freeman and higher in unionized establishments than in
Medoff, 1979). The first face was a monopoly otherwise comparable establishments that are
view that economists widely embraced. The non-union’ (p. 180). Moreover, they asserted
other face was a collective voice view that, that the positive results were driven by good
among other things, suggested unions helped IR, for instance, the positive elements of
organizations by improving circumstances voice promoted by unionism. Underlying
for workers. Although based on Hirschman’s Freeman and Medoff’s conclusion, however,
(1971) book Exit, Voice, and Loyalty, this was the strong evidence marshaled in a
626 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

single study (Brown and Medoff, 1978). That This view was generally supported in a
study suggested that unions were associated meta-analysis of 73 studies published between
with greater total factor productivity of 1977 and 2002 (Doucouliagos and Laroche,
10–25 per cent depending on capital usage 2003). The first panel of Table 33.1 presents
assumptions. Other studies, such as Clark’s general results from this meta-analysis.
(1980a, 1980b) examinations of the cement Although the general union productivity effect
industry, suggested positive, albeit more appeared to be close to zero, variation
modest, union productivity effects (about occurred across nations and industries. For
6 per cent). example, small positive effects were evident
Freeman and Medoff’s conclusion regard- in US studies. Larger effects were evident
ing productivity was assailed almost from in US manufacturing studies. And negative
the beginning. As Ashenfelter (1985: 247) effects were estimated using data from the UK
cautioned in his generally positive review of and Japan.
Freeman and Medoff’s book: ‘Until better Research on the association between unions
evidence is available, it may be more and productivity growth, which is shown in
reasonable to conclude that unions have little the second panel of Table 33.1, suggests
or no effect on productivity.’To a large extent, a negative relationship. These findings are
Ashenfelter’s admonition was prescient as drawn from another meta-analysis conducted
the strong results presented by Freeman by Doucouliagos and Laroche (2002). That
and Medoff have not been reproduced in assessment examined 26 empirical studies
subsequent work. Even Freeman (2005: 657) published between 1980 and 2000, including
admitted that subsequent research reported 20 from the US and others from the UK,
union productivity effects much more modest Canada, Australia, and Austria. Doucouliagos
in magnitude, though he felt the results and Laroche (2002: 15) concluded that
were likely due to the nature of empirical ‘taking all the studies together and for all
production function methodologies and the time periods, the overall association between
reality that productivity effects are due to the unions and productivity growth is negative.’
‘interaction of unions and management, which The results were more negative in the US
can differ across industries, firms, and even than in the other nations and more negative
establishments within a firm’. in studies relating changes in union density
In a 20 year assessment of Freeman and and changes in productivity growth. While
Medoff, Hirsch (2004) reviewed work on the Doucouliagos and Laroche stressed that the
relationship between unions and productivity. magnitude of the effect was small, and
He concluded that ‘the evidence produced seemed to be less negative over time, their
since What Do Unions Do? suggests that the findings are consistent with the observed
authors’ characterization of union effects on pattern in the US where large positive union
productivity was overly optimistic’ (p. 430). productivity effects have declined over time.
Although Hirsch suggested that Freeman One explanation of the pattern may be the
and Medoff correctly identified several ele- negative productivity growth results shown
ments potentially related to unionization that in the earlier Doucouliagos and Laroche
affected productivity, he felt they were wrong (2002) meta-analysis. That meta-analysis
in their assessment of union productivity also illustrates how the characteristics of
effects. Based on his assessment of the individual studies – sample size, measurement
literature, Hirsch (2004: 430) concluded that of key variables, and comprehensiveness of
‘the average union effect [on productivity] control variables – can dramatically influence
is very close to zero, and as likely to be estimated results. Such variability has been
somewhat negative as somewhat positive.’ cited by many researchers as influencing
In general, Hirsch’s (2004) assessment is estimated union productivity effects.
reflective of the general view taken by For example, based on data generated
economists today. in the US, Addison (2005: 416) concluded
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 627

Table 33.1 Summary of meta–analyses of union effects


Number of studies Total sample Mean correlationa Total union effect
1. Union effects on
productivity
All studies 73 58,403 .03 4%
US studies 55 47,549 .05 7%
US Mfg studies 10 5,004 .12 10%
UK studies 7 1,687 −.17 −11%
Japanese studies 5 4,045 −.01 −13%
2. Union effects on
productivity growth
All studies 26 25,965 −.19
US studies 21 21,844 −.24
Change in unionization 9 3,119 .02
3. Union effects on profits
All studies 37 29,771 −.12
US studies 20 18,188 −.20
Probit studies 20 12,122 −.08
UK studies 14 9,313 −.06
4. AWP effects on
performance
Overall SHRM 92 19,319 .15
Individual practices 61 11,928 .11
AWP systems 38 8,615 .21
Mfg organizations 29 3,989 .24
Service organizations 19 3,013 .13
Notes: a Measure is the average correlation between union measures (for example, density) and the outcomes noted in
panels 1–3 and the average correlation between AWPs and the performance measures noted in panel 4.
Sources: Panel 1) Doucouliagos and Laroche (2003); Panel 2) Doucouliagos and Laroche (2002); Panel 3) Doucouliagos and
Laroche (2004–2005); Panel 4) Combs et al. (2006).

that: ‘on average union effects on productivity enterprises or sectors’ (1984: 190). This
are small.’ But, based on research using conclusion has been generally accepted and
data from Germany, Addison simultaneously confirmed in many studies. For example,
concluded that ‘works councils and innova- Addison and Hirsch (1989: 160) concluded:
tive practices may have favorable effects on ‘the evidence points rather clearly to negative
productivity’ (Addison, 2005: 446). Given union effects on firm profitability, irrespective
such conclusions and the size of the estimates of the particular profit indicator used (rate of
calculated in meta-analyses, discussions of return on capital, Tobin’s q, price-cost margin,
union productivity effects will likely remain etc.) and level of aggregation.’
contentious. The third panel of Table 33.1 reports
data from a meta-analysis of studies of
union effects on firm profits (Doucouliagos
Unions and profits
and Laroche, 2004–2005). In this meta-
Whereas the literature on unions and pro- analysis of 57 studies of the union-profitability
ductivity has been inconsistent (in results relationship in 9 countries, Doucouliagos
and interpretations), studies of the effects of and Laroche (2004–2005: 23) concluded that
unions on organizational profitability show ‘unions have a negative impact on financial
remarkable agreement. Freeman and Medoff performance and that this is strongest in US
concluded that ‘the evidence on profitability manufacturing.’ Indeed, with one exception,
shows that, on average, unionism is harmful no matter how the data in the Table are
to the financial well-being of organized disaggregated, the association between unions
628 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

and profits remains negative. The estimated and expanding their non-union ones. That
association is positive and very small in approach is consistent with the steady erosion
France – one of the eight countries studied. of union density in the US and also supports
Although Metcalf (2003: 143) provided the notion that unionized firms could slowly
a similar assessment of the literature, he go bankrupt as leaner non-union firms invade
noted that some recent studies seemed to their territory. This idea has been studied by a
suggest a different picture. In particular, variety of scholars.
Batt and Welbourne’s (2002) analysis of Several US studies have indicated that
entrepreneurial firms (those going through unionized firms make smaller investments in
an initial public offering) reported strong capital (tangible and intangible) than similar
positive associations between unionization non-union firms (Becker and Olson, 1992;
and measures of profitability. Metcalf’s (2003: Bronars and Deere, 1993; Bronars et al.,
145) surprise at this is suggested by his 1994; Cavanaugh, 1998; Hirsch 1990, 1991,
comment that ‘the results are pretty remark- 1992). In addition, Fallick and Hassett (1999)
able.’ In combination with some research suggested that union organizing victories
conducted in Japan (Tachibanaki and Noda, led to substantial reductions in company
2000), which suggested positive profitability investments in capital. Research conducted
effects, Metcalf speculated that the union- in Canada (Betts et al., 2001; Odgers and
profitability relationship might somehow be Betts, 1997) and Germany (Schedlitzki, 2002)
evolving. Perhaps because of the decline in suggested the same pattern of results, though
union density, the increase in the use of evidence from the UK (Metcalf, 1993) and
innovative HR practices, and the reduction in Japan (Benson, 1994) presents a mixed and
labor-management conflict, unionization no more complex pattern. Studies examining
longer reduces profits. At the same time, as R&D expenditures in union and non-union
Metcalf (2003: 145) opines, ‘if unions really firms have also concluded that organized
do boost profits, this begs the question of why establishments invest less. Although these
firms are not asking to be unionized.’ results are especially pronounced in the
Overall, evidence still points to a negative US, they appear to vary across nations
relationship between unionization and prof- (Blanchflower and Bryson, 2003; Menezes-
itability. This is likely an indication that firms Filho and Van Reenen, 2003; Menezes-Filho,
cannot completely recapture the increased et al., 1998). Evidence also suggests that
labor costs that result from unionization unionized firms experience slower employ-
among workers; in competitive markets, ment growth than non-union ones in Australia
prices cannot be raised enough to offset (Wooden and Hawke, 2000), the US (Leonard,
cost increases, so shareholders receive lower 1992; Dunne and Macpherson, 1994), and the
profits in return. It is taken as a given in the UK (Addison and Belfield, 2004).
literature that this lower profit stream fuels Smaller capital and R&D investment does
employer opposition to unionization (Kleiner, not translate into more bankruptcies among
2001). unionized firms than similar non-union ones,
however, as research suggests that the union
effect on organizational survival is negligible
Unions, employment, investment,
(DiNardo and Lee, 2002; Freeman and
and firm survival
Kleiner, 1999; LaLonde et al., 1996). As
If unions cause lower profits, managers might Hirsch (2004: 437–38) noted, these results are
be less inclined to invest in unionized firms potentially inconsistent. He interpreted them
(or in unionized business lines within a to indicate that unions act rationally in pushing
firm). Two decades ago, Kochan et al. (1986) firms towards the edge of bankruptcy but not
suggested that unionized firms dealt with such into bankruptcy. Support for his view comes
cost disadvantages by divesting and reducing from evidence of concessions unions make
their unionized operations while nourishing when organizations experience significant
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 629

economic problems. Certainly, developments to those in non-union firms, innovative


in the US airline industry at the start of the personnel policies seemed more likely in non-
twenty-first century have borne this out, as union firms. Subsequent research suggested
employees have made substantial concessions a negative association between unions and
at United, Delta, and Northwest, among AWPs (Delaney, 1991; Huselid and Rau,
others. 1996; Ichniowski and Shaw, 1995; Osterman,
1994). Several explanations were given for
the finding, including the inertial effects of
THE NEW IR AND BUSINESS existing HR systems in older union plants
PERFORMANCE and the fact that many non-union plants with
extensive AWPs were built on greenfield sites.
Unions influence the rules used by organi- And to the extent that AWPs were more
zations. The union effect occurs as a result likely to be adopted in new establishments,
of bargaining, as part of a union avoidance a negative association with unionization was
campaign, or as part of a concerted company unsurprising.
effort to improve management effectiveness. But some studies have suggested a more
As Kaufman (2004) carefully delineated, the complex relationship. For example, recent
personnel management (PM) wing of IR work using British data indicated no relation-
was established more than a century ago. ship between unions and AWPs (Machin and
Although PM researchers gradually shifted Wood, 2005). Similarly, in an early evaluation
their allegiance from IR to HR, scholars of the literature on unions and HR policies,
provided substantial evidence showing that I concluded that union effects on many HR
unions influenced organizational arrange- policies were inconsistent or inconclusive
ments at work. Slichter et al.’s (1960) classic across studies (Delaney, 1991). In particular,
book served for many years as the bench- there was no systematic evidence that unions
mark assessment of unions and personnel resisted ‘innovative HR practices’ or that the
management. During the 1980s and 1990s, non-union sector led the way in adopting
however, researchers increasingly studied this AWPs. The latter point emerged clearly in
area to estimate the relationship between an analysis of HR policies across business
organizational rules and firm performance. units of ‘double-breasted’ companies – firms
While early streams of this research treated that had unionized and non-union employees
union status measures as control variables (Ichniowski et al., 1989).
in performance equations, subsequent studies To gain more insight into this inconsistent
examined the effects of unions on the adoption relationship, I calculated the association
of AWPs and the effects of union status and between unions and the introduction of
AWP measures on performance outcomes. AWPs, and then examined the effects of
unions and AWPs on various performance
measures (Delaney, 1996). The empirical
Unions and the adoption of AWPs
results suggested that the extensiveness of
Despite recognition that unions influence AWPs was greater for non-union employees
organizational structures and rules, few stud- in non-union workplaces than for union
ies have examined the relationship holis- or non-union employees in double-breasted
tically. In one of the earliest empirical workplaces. Neither industry nor company
studies, Jackson and her colleagues (1989) union density measures were significantly
reported a mixed relationship. Unionization associated with the introduction of AWPs,
was positively associated with the existence but an inverse relation existed between a
of certain personnel policies and negatively measure of ‘opposition to unions’ and AWPs
associated with the existence of others. In (Delaney, 1996: 226). Additional analysis of
addition, although unionized firms appeared double-breasted firms indicated that company
to adopt personnel policies that were similar union density was positively associated with
630 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

the introduction of AWPs covering unionized some extent outrun its underlying theoretical
workers and negatively associated with the basis.
introduction of AWPs covering non-union AWPs reflect another way that IR influ-
workers. Examinations of the relationship ences business performance. While seldom
among unionization, AWPs, and performance acknowledged as IR, researchers have studied
produced mixed results. AWPs were neg- the practices and evaluated their associ-
atively related to turnover and positively ation with various performance measures,
related to employees’ support for change, including employee indicators (for example,
ceteris paribus. But both turnover and support turnover), establishment indicators (for exam-
for change were higher among non-union ple, productivity or profitability), and firm
employees in non-union firms than among indicators (for example, stock price). To do so,
union or non-union employees in double- research on this subject has adopted a variety
breasted firms. The findings suggested that of formulations. Initially, scholars examined
there is a systematic link among union status, the correlation between limited outcome
AWPs, and performance outcomes, though measures and individual HR practices, such
the study could not disentangle completely as training (Bartel, 1994), information sharing
the pattern of relationships. Overall, the (Morishima, 1991), and grievance resolution
nature of the relationship is still unclear, systems (Ichniowski, 1986). Subsequently,
though it would appear to be necessary studies examined HR practices more gener-
to include union status control measures ally (for example, through an index, factor
in studies linking AWPs and organizational score, or some other combination) and
performance. estimated the association between HR and
organizational outcome measures – stressing
that the more extensive the practices, the
AWPs and firm performance
stronger the performance effect (Delaney,
Over the past two decades, increasing atten- 1996; Delaney and Huselid, 1996; Huselid,
tion has been paid to the existence and 1995; Ichniowski, et al., 1996). In this regard,
development of HR practices that promote AWP systems – combinations of practices that
superior organizational outcomes. As noted, were in alignment – were seen as conceptually
the practices have been given many names, the most promising measures.
including several that presume a positive rela- Simultaneously, another group of scholars
tionship with organizational outcomes (for followed a different conceptualization –
example, high performance work practices). focusing on ‘bundles’ of HR practices that
Some studies have identified the terminology complement each other – arguing that com-
issue as a serious problem (see Cappelli and plementarities among the practices enhance
Neumark, 2001; Wood, 1999). Nonetheless, performance and that non-complementary HR
despite the growing number of studies on practices do not drive organizational results
this topic, consensus has not developed on (MacDuffie, 1995; Pil and MacDuffie, 1996).
what the construct should be called, how it As scholars examined the research approaches
should be measured or even what it means. and offered constructive criticism of the
Such conceptual problems are amplified by underlying theory, samples, and methods,
inconsistent results. For example, Wood’s another group of researchers concluded that
(1999) review of research on AWPs and the role of HR practices is contingent and
performance reported diverse measures and that innovative HR practices are more or
mixed results. Still, the idea that AWPs might less effective depending on the context into
enhance performance has generated much which they are introduced (Godard, 2001,
credence. It has likely been propelled forward 2004).
by estimation of favorable empirical results, Other researchers suggested a more
narrow interpretation of results, and some complex relationship in which the AWP-
wishful thinking. The research stream has to performance effect was moderated by an
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 631

organization’s business strategy (Huselid performance has generated an increasingly


and Becker, 2000). From this view, optimal bitter debate about the true nature of AWP
results occur when business strategy drives effects. The debate is framed around method-
a set of HR practices that are internally ological and research design problems, though
consistent. Overall, regardless of the name the critics seem to be more concerned with
given to these HR practices or the approach disparaging existing studies than producing
followed by researchers, the underlying better ones. This is apparent in the com-
notion is that certain HR practices or sets mentary and responses by Wright and his
of practices affect performance outcomes. associates (Gerhart et al., 2000a, 2000b;
For example, organizations employ various Wright et al., 2001) on the work of Huselid
types of teamwork and teams, engage in and Becker (1996, 2000). Regardless of the
sophisticated recruitment and selection, share merits of specific points raised in the debate,
information, and provide communication and the nature of the arguments distracts from
conflict management assistance. For various the purpose of the debate. For example,
reasons, these approaches are believed to Wright and his associates (2005: 415) draw
encourage good work habits, stimulate peer the following conclusion regarding the vast
monitoring of work behavior, and promote majority of research on the subject: ‘it does
peer pressure to avoid shirking. These factors make one wonder how such studies can
represent the mechanisms through which the legitimately suggest that HR practices “cause”
practices influence performance outcomes. performance.’ Of course, few of the authors
Studies of alternative work practices made any such suggestion and many made
(AWP) and organizational outcomes sug- explicit efforts to address methodological
gest three general findings. First, there issues, as well as simultaneity problems in
is tremendous variance in the approach the data. In general, the debate is reminiscent
used by researchers to operationalize AWPs. of the kinds of arguments made in response
Not only are many different HR practice to Freeman and Medoff’s (1984) suggestion
variables examined, but some practices are of a positive relationship between unions and
measured differently across studies. Cappelli productivity. The hyper-negative commentary
and Neumark (2001: 743) cautioned that this serves primarily to create competing camps,
contextualization across studies limits the whose purpose in part seems to be to
validity and generalizability of the results. discredit each other rather than to identify
Second, many studies find significant pos- the links and relationships among AWPs and
itive relationships between AWP measures performance.
and organizational performance measures, A recent meta-analysis of research on the
though only one well-designed national study AWP-performance link by Combs and his
reported strong associations between AWP colleagues (2006) reported strong positive
measures and firm financial performance effects in all instances. The fourth panel of
(Huselid, 1995). While Cappelli and Neumark Table 33.1 presents some of these findings.
(2001) assert that the cost of enacting AWP In addition to strong positive overall AWP-
measures may offset any value they produce, performance associations, findings suggest
many studies of different indicators – with that AWP systems have significantly larger
stronger and weaker study designs and empir- effects than individual HR policies and
ical controls – report positive associations AWPs produce significantly greater benefits
between AWP and performance indicators. in manufacturing industries than in the service
It seems curious to dismiss the potential sector.
relationship, given the sheer number of studies Even the critics of the AWP literature
reporting that AWPs enhance organizational agree that research has reported consistent
performance. positive relationships between AWPs and
Third, for reasons that are unclear, research performance measures (Wright et al., 2005:
on the link between AWPs and firm 416). Although the inclusion of longitudinal
632 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

data has typically led to a reduction in Metcalf (2003: 158–159) reported a similar
reported AWP-performance effects (see Guest conclusion:
et al., 2003; Huselid and Becker, 1996;
A HRM [for instance, AWP] workplace with no
Ichniowski et al., 1997), such approaches
union has a superior productivity and financial
have not caused the effects to disappear. performance to a unionized workplace with
This reinforces the need to understand more no HRM. But when the workplace with union
precisely any relationships among manage- recognition also has the various HRM practices
ment, AWPs, and performance (Wright et al., its performance is much enhanced, indeed in
2005). In an increasingly competitive world, the case of labour productivity growth the best
performing workplaces are those with both HRM
policies and processes that systematically and recognition.
enhance performance should be seriously
considered. Expanding on these notions, a recent review
A potential extension of research on of research in the UK by Bryson and his
AWPs and performance is the examination colleagues (2005) suggested positive union
of how union status is related to AWPs productivity effects and negative performance
and performance. As Addison (2005: 447) effects in the 1990s (especially after the
warned, because considerable research on strength of the union was considered). The
the relationship between unions and per- results suggested consistent cross-national
formance outcomes suggests a small effect patterns. In the UK, AWPs seemed to work
on average, it is important to ‘look to better in union settings than non-union ones
factors such as innovative work practices (Bryson et al., 2005: 483). Bryson and
in explaining the diversity in the effects of his colleagues interpreted this to be due
worker representation in different settings’. to concession bargaining rather than some
Based on an examination of US and German advantage accruing in the union sector. Given
studies, Addison (2005: 447) concluded that that studies of the US suggest a similar pattern
‘combinations of innovative practices and but do not attribute it to concessions, further
worker representation can yield substantial analysis of the associations among unions,
productivity gains.’ AWPs, and performance outcomes is needed.
Interestingly, these findings are a natural
extension of research reporting that union
Unions, AWPs, and performance
involvement in participation programs was
Research on the links among unions, positively associated with the longevity and
AWPs, and performance has speculated that success of such programs (see Eaton, 1990,
union effects operate through communication, 1994; Eaton and Nocerno, 2000). In many
cooperation, and monitoring (see Addison, ways, the underlying driver of positive results
2005; Bryson et al., 2005; Kleiner, 2001; in such studies is the ‘voice’effect of unionism
Metcalf, 2003). Partly because of this, some (Freeman and Medoff, 1984). Workers seem
researchers have reported that certain AWPs more inclined to co-operate when they feel
work best in unionized workplaces (see a part of participative work arrangements.
Cooke, 1992; 1994). Similarly, other studies Although these conjectures suggest the need
have suggested that co-operative relations to examine the association between union-
between unions and employers could magnify ization and the enactment of AWPs and the
the effects of AWPs. For example, Metcalf effect of union representation and AWPs on
(2003) concluded that limited evidence from organizational performance, studies have not
the US and UK was consistent with this consistently done so.
argument. He cited a US study by Black Research has, on an inconsistent basis,
and Lynch (2001) reporting that the best per- included various measures of union status in
formance results occurred in establishments equations estimating the effect of AWPs on
with AWPs and union representation. Based organizational performance (see for example,
on an assessment of research in the UK, Huselid, 1995; Delaney and Huselid, 1996;
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 633

Addison and Belfield, 2001; Arthur, 1994; productivity, and lower profits. Unionization
Huselid and Becker, 1996; Bae and Lawler, also appears to reduce employment and
2000; Guest et al., 2003). Coefficients on retard employment growth. The results are
the union variables have been mixed, though consistent with the reality that unions were
the patterns generally conform to research not intended mainly to promote efficiency
on turnover and profitability (for instance, (Turnbull, 2003: 513). While evidence does
negative union effects). Results for AWP not indicate that unions make enterprises
measures are also generally consistent across insolvent, this combination of union effects
dependent variables when union status is offers a solid clue into the ardent employer
included or excluded. For example, in an opposition to unionization. That opposition
analysis of data from the UK, Guest and has helped reduce union density in the US and
his associates (2003) reported strong positive other nations.
associations between AWPs and productivity Second, while studies have suggested that
and performance outcomes and generally unions foster a more formalized approach to
negative though rarely significant associations HRM (see Ng and Maki, 1994; Slichter et al.,
between different union measures (industry 1960), some research on businesses in the
union density greater than 25 per cent US suggests a negative relationship between
and a single union deal at the workplace) union status measures and AWPs. Various
and the same performance and productivity explanations for this pattern have been
outcomes. Because Guest et al. (2003) did provided by researchers. Whether the result is
not examine the association between union due to inertia, as unionized workplaces seem
measures and AWPs, however, their results to be older on average than non-union ones,
don’t address any potential indirect relation- or deliberate employer investment decisions,
ship among unions, AWPs, and organizational it is not good news for unions. Surveys
performance. have shown that workers prefer alternative
workplace arrangements (see Freeman and
Rogers, 1999), so negative union associations
A SUMMARY OF IR EFFECTS ON with AWPs may signal a disconnection
BUSINESS PERFORMANCE between today’s workers and traditional union
approaches. Given that research suggests that
The research discussed above suggests several non-union organizations are more likely to
observations about the relationship between have AWPs than unionized ones, continued
IR and the performance of business organi- growth of the non-union sector seems likely.
zations. The observations must be considered Third, although substantial criticism has
in light of the caveats noted above, however, been voiced about the literature, evidence
especially the methodological and estimation suggests positive relationships between AWP
issues limiting research and the two ideologi- measures and firm performance. The asso-
cal disputes roiling the field: between theorists ciation may be due to increased workplace
and empiricists in economics and between co-operation or better communication or for
advocates of competing methodologies in some other reason, but it nonetheless suggests
management and psychology. that organizational structures may affect out-
First, studies examining the relation- comes. To the extent that union status is related
ship between union measures (for example, to the adoption of AWPs and few studies have
union status, collective bargaining coverage, examined associations between union status
etc.) and business performance measures and AWPs, indirect union effects may not be
do not offer good news to supporters of apparent in this research stream. The bulk
unions. In particular, since the publication of research on AWPs and performance fails
of Freeman and Medoff’s (1984) classic to control for union effects on performance
book, research has consistently suggested that and very few studies have examined the link
unions increase costs, have little effect on between unions and the adoption of AWPs.
634 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

At the same time, because union contracts unions will survive. This may magnify the
are substantially affected by laws regulating effects of unions, as the powerful are able to
the scope of mandatory bargaining, there extract large concessions from employers (for
has been little recent interest in examining example, US dock workers, New York City
links between unions and specific HR practice Transit Workers). At the same time, because
outcomes. In addition, in studies that have the strong union cases are so unique, they may
included measures of AWPs and unionization, be the exception to the rule. After all, demand
little discussion is offered on the interaction for unions has not grown when strong unions
among these measures and performance. have achieved great bargaining results and in
More importantly, some of the most careful some instances, members of unions presumed
and comprehensive studies of AWPs and per- to be strong (for example, US airline pilots)
formance ignore union status and unionization have been forced to make large concessions
altogether. In general, because non-union to keep their jobs. This may mean that union
organizations are less likely than unionized effects today are much more contingent than
ones to haveAWPs, union performance effects was the case in the past (Bryson, et al., 2005:
may be even more disappointing than research 455). But it may also mean that unions and
shows. IR should not be judged by the metric of
Overall, on the dimensions noted, IR business performance. Other metrics may be
does not appear to enhance organizational more appropriate – ones that capture worker
performance. The effect does not appear to and societal interests. Societal wellbeing may
be large, but it is seemingly persistent. In be more dependent on employment, social
addition, the effect seems consistent across justice, and equity than it is on organizational
nations (though it is most evident in the US). efficiency. In other words, IR’s effect on
And whereas most research on the subject has business performance is just one indicator of
been conducted using US data samples, the its overall effect – just as a parent’s earnings
strongest data sets analyzed are government represent one possible indicator of his or her
surveys conducted in Canada, the UK, and overall effectiveness in raising a child.
Australia. Based on this, it appears that IR
detracts from or, at best, does not contribute
How should IR be measured?
to organizational performance. This finding
explains the negative view of IR held by US Given what the data suggest about IR’s effect
managers and offers a rational explanation on business performance, what should be
for explicit business opposition to unions concluded about the value of IR? On the basis
and the tacit opposition to IR. Even within of the data, IR seems to be more a cost than
the scholarly community, IR has come to be a benefit. Unions raise costs and there is no
viewed as more tangential and less important guarantee that the costs are offset by increased
than other fields (see Kaufman, 2004). productivity, performance, or other outcomes.
From the perspective of economic rationality,
it seems that IR, at least as it is defined by
SHOULD IR BE JUDGED BY BUSINESS unions, collective bargaining, and mediating
PERFORMANCE ALONE? institutions at work, does not help businesses
maximize profits. In some but not all instances
The past three decades have not been kind to IR hinders business in the search for efficiency
unions or IR. The union sector has declined and performance. This is probably why so
nearly everywhere. The decline, in turn, many economists see unions and bargaining
raises questions about the future of unions as an impediment.
and the field of IR. On the one hand, the Underneath this, however, lies the question
decline may precipitate a Darwinian effect, of whether business should be judged only
causing a survival of the fittest. In such a by the concept of economic efficiency. While
case, weak unions will vanish and strong postulated as a rational, neutral approach,
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 635

the framework of neoclassical economics The results presented in this study support
contains its own biases. As Kaufman (2004) the notion that some variation exists in
and Stiglitz (2002) have noted, the theory union effects on business performance across
assumes away many of the aspects of work nations. Because of methodological concerns
that really affect people. This leaves social and small differences in some instances,
scientists to ponder whether IR should be this pattern may be statistically significant
measured solely by metrics on which it but practically meaningless. Nonetheless, it
can never prevail. If so, elimination of the demonstrates that IR may need to be judged
institutions of IR will serve to make business differently in different nations. To do so, it is
more successful – at least in theory. Such critical to examine data from many nations.
elimination will also create real problems for Research shows that governments in other
millions of people who work for a living (see countries systematically collect much better
Godard and Delaney, 2000). If not, IR must data on unions and AWPs than occurs in
be examined based on the extent to which it the US
creates workplace justice – a concept that is
loose and means different things to different
IR in a flat world
people.
This creates another dilemma for the field. In his recent book, Thomas Friedman (2005)
At a time when performance measurement makes a compelling case that world-wide
is an accepted and expected way to assess competition has escalated and will continue
institutions, IR is in a difficult position. On to grow. He also asserts that life in a ‘flat
economic efficiency measures, it performs world’ can be better than life is today. But
poorly. On workplace justice measures, it better is achieved only by the relentless
performs in an uncertain manner. Uncertainty press for innovations, improvements, and
occurs because there is no clear indicator efficiencies. Friedman asserts that such a
of workplace justice. Is it necessary for a situation changes the competition that has
union or mediating institution to be present characterized the last century from one of
for workplace justice to occur? That is, can firms vs. firms to one of individuals vs.
it ever occur in non-union firms? Because individuals. The reason for the change is that
IR has focused so much on the role of talent is not randomly distributed and that
unions, scholars have paid little attention to technologies increasingly allow organizations
the possibility that justice can occur in other to seek out top talent wherever it is. The
ways (at least other than laws). The field must advantage currently enjoyed by people in the
identify performance measures that allow a US or Western Europe evaporates in the flat
systematic assessment of justice or democracy world. Indeed, people who have long been
or sensibility at work. held back by restrictive governments (for
example, Russia, India, China) suddenly have
opportunities that never before existed. As
Cross-national IR differences
they choose those opportunities and compete
Because of differences in labor legisla- in the global economy, they could swamp
tion across nations, union engagement with the westerners who take for granted a high
management varies. For example, company standard of living. Put differently, in a flat
unionism is illegal in the US, but permissible world, people with talent who are hungry
in many other nations. Where allowed, will outperform others. The talent advantage
company unions have more latitude to bargain of the US has declined as its schools have
over any issue of concern to workers. This performed at levels below many other nations,
allows unions to be more responsive to chang- as the population has grown at slower rates,
ing conditions as the nature of bargaining can as the government has restricted immigration
evolve more rapidly than is the case where (for instance, to keep out future Bin Ladens,
the scope of bargaining is narrowly restricted. we’ve chosen to keep out future Einsteins and
636 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Schwarzeneggers), and as the work ethic of school to crime), and dissatisfaction at work
Americans has dwindled. Regardless of what provide a huge opportunity for scholars and
American politicians say, absent some change, practitioners eager to shape a better world.
our economic future is going to be more That is after all what John R. Commons,
balkanized and societal inequality is going to Sidney and Beatrice Webb, and ironically,
grow. Karl Marx sought. Which of their visions will
Ironically, many of the problems shaping prevail? I don’t know the answer. But I am
and reflecting a flat world are relevant to sure that IR must move beyond a ritualistic
the subjects long studied by IR scholars. acceptance of its traditional institutions and a
The field could be vibrant in a flat world, narrow analysis of economic data if it is to
but it must change to be so. The change make future contributions.
requires a new and clear thinking of the
purpose of the field and its long accepted
institutions. For example, in a flat world, REFERENCES
mediating institutions may not offer security
for workers. This is because competition is Addison, John T. (2005) ‘The determinants of
increasingly among individuals and therefore firm performance: Unions, works councils, and
efforts to institute protections in companies, employee involvement/high-performance work prac-
nations, and sectors are doomed to failure. tices.’ Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52 (3):
Does this mean that unions are doomed? No. 406–50.
It does mean that organized labor may need Addison, John T. and Hirsch, Barry T. (1989) ‘Union
effects on productivity, profits, and growth: Has the
to take a different path to aiding workers.
long run arrived?’ Journal of Labor Economics, 7 (1):
For example, if collective bargaining is no
72–105.
longer successful, perhaps it should be de- Addison, John T. and Belfield, Clive. (2004) ‘Unions and
emphasized. Instead, unions could focus on employment growth: The one constant.’ Industrial
providing the highest level of skills to enrolled Relations, 43 (2): 305–23.
workers. A union movement that represents Arthur, Jeffrey B. (1994) ‘Effects of human resource sys-
workers in the same way that professional tems on manufacturing performance and turnover.’
athletes and entertainers are represented today Academy of Management Journal, 37 (3): 670–87.
is more likely to grow in a flat world Ashenfelter, Orley. (1985) ‘Comment on What do Unions
than a movement that represents employees Do?’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 38 (2):
in the way that assembly line workers are 245–47.
Bae, Johngseok and Lawler, John J. (2000) ‘Organiza-
represented. In the entertainment industry,
tional and HRM strategies in Korea: Impact on firm
unions seek to negotiate wage and benefit
performance in an emerging economy.’ Academy of
floors that can be exceeded by individuals with Management Journal, 43 (3): 502–17.
very high skills. Since the flat world will be Bartel, Ann P. (1994) ‘Productivity gains from the
ruled by skilled workers, it is possible that an implementation of employee training programs.’
entertainment industry model of unions would Industrial Relations, 33 (4): 411–25.
be accepted by workers. Batt, Rose and Welbourne, Theresa. (2002) ‘Perfor-
This means that unions could be a strong mance growth in entrepreneurial firms: Revisiting
force in a flat world. Strength will be derived the union–performance relationship.’ In Jerome A.
from a new model that recognizes that skills Katz and Theresa Welbourne (eds), Research on
are in demand and allows workers to receive Entrepreneurship, Vol. 5. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
pp. 1–29.
different outcomes based on their skills.
Becker, Brian and Gerhart, Barry. (1996) ‘The impact
What I see instead, however, is an effort
of human resource management on organizational
to promote barriers (for example, tariffs, performance: Progress and prospects.’ Academy of
immigration restrictions) that will ultimately Management Journal, 39 (4): 779–801.
fail. This is unfortunate as ample evidence Becker, Brian E. and Olson, Craig A. (1992).
of corporate scandals, unethical behavior ‘Unionization and firm profits.’ Industrial Relations,
throughout society (ranging from cheating in 31 (3): 395–415.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 637

Betts, Julian R., Odgers, Cameron W. and Wilson, Cooke, William N. (1992) ‘Product quality improvement
Michael K. (2001) ‘The effects of unions on research through employee participation: the effects of union-
and development: An empirical analysis using multi– ization and joint union-management administration.’
year data.’ Canadian Journal of Economics, 34 (3): Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 46 (1):
785–806. 119–34.
Black, Sandra E. and Lynch, Lisa M. (2001) ‘How to Delaney, John T. (1991) ‘Unions and human resource
compete: The impact of workplace practices and policies.’ In Research in Personnel and Human
information technology on productivity.’ Review of Resource Management, Vol. 9. Greenwich, CT: JAI
Economics and Statistics, 83 (3): 434–45. Press. pp. 39–71.
Blanchflower, David G. and Bryson, Alex. (2003) Delaney, John T. (1996) ‘Unions, human resource inno-
‘Changes over time in union relative wage effects vations, and organizational outcomes.’ In Advances
in the UK and the US revisited.’ In John T. Addison in Industrial and Labor Relations, Vol. 7. Greenwich,
and Claus Schnabel (eds), International Handbook CT: JAI Press. pp. 207–45.
of Trade Unions. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Delaney, John T. and Huselid, Mark A. (1996) ‘The
pp. 197–245. impact of human resource management practices on
Bronars, Stephen G. and Deere, Donald R. (1993) perceptions of organizational performance.’ Academy
‘Unionization, incomplete contracting, and cap- of Management Journal, 39 (4): 949–69.
ital investment.’ Journal of Business, 66 (1): DiNardo, John and Lee, David S. (2002) ‘The impact of
117–32. unionization on establishment closure: A regression
Bronars, Stephen G., Deere, Donald R. and Tracy, Joseph discontinuity analysis of representation elections.’
S. (1994) ‘The effects of unions on firm behavior: An National Bureau of Economic Research Working
empirical analysis using firm–level data.’ Industrial Paper 8993 (June).
Relations, 33 (4): 426–51. Doucouliagos, Chris and Laroche, Patrice. (2004–2005)
Brown, Charles and Medoff, James. (1978) ‘Trade ‘The Impact of Unions on Profits: A Meta-Analysis.’
unions in the production process.’ Journal of Political Université Nancy. Unpublished manuscript.
Economy, 86 (3): 355–78. Doucouliagos, Chris and Laroche, Patrice (2003) ‘What
Bryson, Alex, Forth, John and Kirby, Simon. (2005) do unions do to productivity? A meta–analysis.’
‘High involvement management practices, trade Industrial Relations, 42 (4): 650–91.
union representation and workplace performance in Doucouliagos, Chris and Laroche, Patrice (2002) ‘Unions
Britain.’ Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52 (3): and Productivity Growth: A Meta–Analytic Review.’
451–91. Deakin University. Unpublished manuscript.
Cappelli, Peter and Neumark, David. (2001) ‘Do ‘high- Dunne, Timothy and Macpherson, David A. (1994)
performance’ work practices improve establishment- ‘Unionism and gross employment flows.’ Southern
level outcomes?’ Industrial and Labor Relations Economic Journal, 60 (3): 727–38.
Review, 54 (4): 737–75. Eaton, Adrienne E. (1990) ‘The Extent and Determinants
Cavanaugh, Joseph K. (1998) ‘Asset specific investment of Local Union Control of Participative Programs.’
and unionized labor.’ Industrial Relations, 37 (1): Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43 (5):
35–50. 604–20.
Clark, Kim B. (1980a) ‘The impact of unionization Eaton, Adrienne E. (1994) ‘The Survival of Employee Par-
on productivity: A case study.’ Industrial and Labor ticipation Programs in Unionized Settings.’ Industrial
Relations Review, 33 (4): 451–69. and Labor Relations Review, 47 (3): 371–89.
Clark, Kim B. (1980b) ‘Unionization and productivity: Eaton, Adrienne E. and Nocerno, Tom. (2000) ‘The
Micro-econometric evidence.’ Quarterly Journal of effectiveness of health and safety committees: Results
Economics, 95 (4): 613–39. of a survey of public sector workplaces.’ Industrial
Combs, James G., Liu, Yongmei, Hall, Angela T. and Relations, 39 (2): 265–90.
Ketchen, David J., Jr. (2006) ‘How much do high Fallick, Bruce C. and Hassett, Kevin A. (1999)
performance work practices matter? A meta–analysis ‘Investment and union certification.’ Journal of Labor
of their effects on organizational performance.’ Economics, 17 (3): 570–82.
Personnel Psychology, 59 (3): 501–28. Freeman, Richard B. (2005) ‘What do unions do? –
Cooke, William N. (1994) ‘Employee Participation The m-brane stringtwister edition.’ Journal of Labor
Programs, Group–Based Incentives, and Company Research, 26 (4): 641–68.
Performance: A Union-Non-union Comparison.’ Freeman, Richard B. and Rogers, Joel. (1999) What
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 47 (4): Workers Want. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
594–609. Press.
638 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Freeman, Richard B. and Kleiner, Morris M. (1999) ‘Do Huselid, Mark A. (1995) ‘The impact of human resource
unions make enterprises insolvent?’ Industrial and management practices on turnover, productivity,
Labor Relations Review, 52 (4): 510–27. and corporate financial performance.’ Academy of
Freeman, Richard B. and Medoff, James L. (1979) ‘The Management Journal, 38 (3): 635–72.
two faces of unionism.’ The Public Interest, 57: Huselid, Mark A. and Becker, Brian E. (2000)
69–93. ‘Comment on “Measurement error in research on
Freeman, Richard B. and Medoff, James L. (1984) What human resources and firm performance: How much
Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books. error is there and how does it influence effect
Friedman, Thomas L. (2005) The World is Flat: A Brief size estimates?”’ Personnel Psychology, 53 (4):
History of the Twenty-First Century. New York: Farrar, 835–54.
Straus, and Giroux. Huselid, Mark A. and Becker, Brian E. (1996)
Gerhart, Barry, Wright, Patrick M., McMahan, Gary C. ‘Methodological issues in cross–sectional and panel
and Snell, Scott A. (2000a) ‘Measurement error in estimates of the HR-firm performance link.’ Industrial
research on human resources and firm performance: Relations, 35 (3): 400–22.
How much error is there and how does it influence Huselid, Mark A. and Rau, Barbara L. (1996) ‘The deter-
effect size estimates?’ Personnel Psychology, 53 (4): minants of high performance work systems: Cross
803–34. sectional and longitudinal analyses.’ Unpublished
Gerhart, Barry, Wright, Patrick M. and McMahan, paper, Rutgers University.
Gary C. (2000b) ‘Measurement error in research on Ichniowski, Casey. (1986) ‘The effects of grievance activ-
the human resources and firm performance rela- ity on productivity.’ Industrial and Labor Relations
tionship: Further evidence and analysis.’ Personnel Review, 40 (1): 75–89.
Psychology, 53 (4): 855–72. Ichniowski, Casey and Shaw, Kathryn. (1995) ‘Old dogs
Godard, John. (2001) ‘High performance and the trans-
and new tricks: Determinants of the adoption of
formation of work? The implications of alternative
productivity–enhancing work practices.’ Brookings
work practices for the experience and outcomes of
Papers on Economic Activity, 1–65.
work.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54 (4):
Ichniowski, Casey, Shaw, Kathryn and Prennushi,
776–805.
Giovanna. (1997) ‘The effects of human resources
Godard, John. (2004) ‘A critical assessment of the high
management practices on productivity: A study of
performance paradigm.’ British Journal of Industrial
steel finishing lines.’ American Economic Review,
Relations, 42 (2): 349–78.
87 (3): 291–313.
Godard, John and Delaney, John T. (2000) ‘Reflections
Jackson, Susan E., Schuler, Randall S. and Rivero, J.
on the “high performance” paradigm’s implications
Carlos (1989) ‘Organizational characteristics as pre-
for industrial relations as a field.’ Industrial and Labor
dictors of personnel practices.’ Personnel Psychology,
Relations Review, 53 (3): 482–502.
Guest, David E., Michie, Jonathan, Conway, Neil 42 (4): 727–86.
and Sheehan, Maura (2003) ‘Human resource Kaufman, Bruce E. (2004) The Global Evolution of
management and corporate performance in the Industrial Relations: Events, Ideas, and the IIRA.
UK.’ British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41 (2): Geneva: International Labour Office.
291–314. Kleiner, Morris M. (2001) ‘Intensity of Management
Hirsch, Barry T. (2004) ‘What do unions do for economic Resistance: Understanding the Decline of Unioniza-
performance?’ Journal of Labor Research, 25 (3): tion in the Private Sector.’ Journal of Labor Research,
415–55. 22 (3): 519–40.
Hirsch, Barry T. (1990) ‘Market structure, union rent Kochan, Thomas A., Katz, Harry C. and McKersie,
seeking, and firm profitability.’ Economics Letters, Robert B. (1986) The Transformation of American
32 (1): 75–79. Industrial Relations. New York: Basic Books.
Hirsch, Barry T. (1991) Labor Unions and the Economic LaLonde, Robert J., Marschke, Gérard and Troske,
Performance of US Firms. Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Kenneth (1996) ‘Using longitudinal data on estab-
Institute. lishments to analyze the effects of union organizing
Hirsch, Barry T. (1992) ‘Firm investment behavior and campaigns in the United States.’ Annales d’ Économie
collective bargaining strategy.’ In Mario F. Bognanno et de Statistique, 41/42: 155–85.
and Morris M. Kleiner (eds), Labor Market Institutions Leonard, Jonathan S. (1992) ‘Unions and employment
and the Future Role of Unions. Cambridge, MA: growth.’ Industrial Relations, 31 (1): 80–94.
Blackwell. pp. 95–121. MacDuffie, John Paul (1995) ‘Human resource bundles
Hirschman, Albert O. (1971) Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. and manufacturing performance: Organizational logic
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. and flexible production systems in the world
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND BUSINESS PERFORMANCE 639

auto industry.’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Pil, Fritz K. and MacDuffie, John Paul. (1996) ‘The
48 (2): 197–221. adoption of high involvement work practices.’
Machin, Stephen and Wood, Stephen (2005) ‘Human Industrial Relations, 35 (3): 423–55.
resource management as a substitute for trade unions Schedlitzki, Doris (2002) ‘German works councils,
in British workplaces.’ Industrial and Labor Relations employee involvement programmes and their impact
Review, 58 (2): 201–18. on establishment profitability.’ London School of
Menezes–Filho, Naercio and van Reenen, John (2003) Economics. CEP Working Paper No. 1191.
‘Unions and innovation: A survey of the theory Slichter, Sumner H., Healy, James J. and Livernash,
and empirical evidence.’ Center for Economic Policy E. Robert (1960) The Impact of Collective Bargaining
Research, Discussion Paper 3792 (January). on Management. Washington, D.C.: Brookings
Menezes–Filho, Naercio, Ulph, David and van Reenen, Institution.
John (1998) ‘R&D and unionism: Comparative Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2002) ‘Employment, social jus-
evidence from British companies and establishments.’ tice, and societal well–being.’ International Labour
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52 (1): Review, 141 (1–2): 9–29.
45–63. Tachibanaki, Toshiaki and Noda, Tomohiko. (2000)
Metcalf, David. (2003) ‘Unions and productivity, The Economic Effects of Trade Unions in Japan.
financial performance, and investment: Inter- Basingstoke: Macmillan Press.
national evidence.’ In John T. Addison and Turnbull, Peter. (2003) ‘What Do Unions Do Now?’
Claus Schnabel (eds), International Handbook of Journal of Labor Research, 24 (3): 491–527.
Trade Unions. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Wolfe, Alan (1997) ‘The moral meaning of work.’ Journal
pp. 118–71. of Socio–Economics, 26 (6): 559–70.
Morishima, Motohiro (1991) ‘Information sharing and Wood, Stephen (1999) ‘Human resource management
firm performance in Japan.’ Industrial Relations, and performance.’ International Journal of Manage-
30 (1): 37–61. ment Reviews, 1 (4): 367–413.
Ng, Ignace and Maki, Dennis (1994) ‘Trade union Wooden, Mark and Hawke, Anne (2000) ‘Unions and
influence on human resource management practices.’ employment growth: Panel data evidence.’ Industrial
Industrial Relations, 33 (1): 121–35. Relations, 39 (1): 88–107.
Odgers, Cameron W. and Betts, Julian R. (1997) ‘Do Wright, Patrick M., Gardner, Timothy M., Moynihan,
unions reduce investment? Evidence from Canada.’ Lisa M., Park, Hyeon Jeong, Gerhart, Barry and Delery,
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 51 (1): John E. (2001) ‘Measurement error in research on
18–36. human resources and firm performance: Additional
Osterman, Paul (1994) ‘How common is workplace data and suggestions for future research.’ Personnel
transformation and who adopts it?’ Industrial and Psychology, 54 (4): 875–902.
Labor Relations Review, 47 (2): 173–88. Wright, Patrick M., Gardner, Timothy M., Moynihan, Lisa
Osterman, Paul (2000) ‘Work Reorganization in an era M. and Allen, Matthew R. (2005) ‘The relationship
of restructuring: Trends in diffusion and effects on between HR practices and firm performance: Exam-
employee welfare.’ Industrial and Labor Relations ining causal order.’ Personnel Psychology, 58 (2):
Review, 53 (2): 179–96. 409–46.
34
Labor Market Institutions
Around the World
Richard B. Freeman

It was six men of Hindustan programs, job-finding assistance to workers,


To learning much inclined, subsidies to employers to hire the long-term
Who went to see the Elephant
unemployed and special programs for youths
(Though all of them were blind)
That each by observation leaving school.
Might satisfy the mind. (Saxe) This perspective marked a giant shift in
the attitude of mainstream economics toward
At the turn of the twenty-first century, labor institutions. From the 1970s through
questions regarding labor market institu- to the mid-1980s or so, most economists
tions replaced macro-economic policy at the favored macro-economic explanations and
center of much policy debate in advanced cures for economic problems (recall the
economies. By ascribing the high unem- battles between monetarist and Keynesian
ployment in European Union (EU) countries policies). They viewed labor institutions as
to labor institutions that reduced wage and peripheral to economic performance. In the
employment flexibility, the OECD’s 1994 1990s, however, the higher employment rate
Jobs Study (OECD, 1994a, 1994b) directed and more rapid productivity growth of the US
the attention of policy-makers and economists than of major European countries despite sim-
to institutions that mainstream economics ilar ‘responsible’ macro-economic policies
had previously viewed as peripheral to directed attention to the possible role of labor
aggregate economic performance. The Jobs market institutions in explaining differences
Study recommended that countries dereg- in aggregate economic performance.
ulate labor markets to increase flexibility How much of the varying economic perfor-
in working time; make wages and labor mance of capitalist economies can reasonably
costs more responsive to market pressures; be attributed to labor institutions? Which
weaken employment security provisions and outcomes do those institutions influence –
unemployment benefit systems; and intro- the distribution of income, allocation of
duce active labor market policies – training labor across sectors, productivity, inflation,
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 641

economic growth? Through what channels do of specific institutional arrangements, and the
institutions affect outcomes? share of social expenditures in GDP. Column 1
This chapter reviews what economists gives the ranking of countries by the market
know about these questions. Section I doc- orientation of their labor market from the
uments the large cross-country differences in Fraser Institute’s ‘economic freedom’ index.
labor institutions that make them a candidate Since the 1980s the Institute has produced an
explanatory factor for the divergent economic index of economic freedom based on metrics
performance of countries. Section II examines for ‘personal choice, voluntary exchange,
the ways institutions can affect behavior and freedom to compete, and protection of person
outcomes by altering incentives, enabling and property’ (Fraser Institute, 2003: 5).
groups to engage in efficient bargaining per Beginning in 2001 the Institute included 6
the Coase Theorem,1 and by improving infor- indicators of labor institutions in its economic
mation, communication, and trust. Turning freedom index for 58 countries. The Fraser
from what labor institutions might do to rankings give high rank (low numbers) to
evidence on what they actually do, Section III countries that rely more on markets, so
shows that labor institutions reduce income that the rank1 implies that a country is the
inequality but has equivocal effects on other leading country in using market forces to
aggregate outcomes, such as employment and set employment, wages, working conditions
unemployment in the advanced countries on while a country with rank of, say 57, implies
which most research has focused. Section IV that that country relies greatly on institutions.
considers three possible interpretations of the The conservative orientation of the Fraser
empirical findings and ways to improve our Institute leads it to define economic freedom
knowledge of how the institutional ‘Elephant’ in a way that privileges the rights of capital
affects economic performance. compared to the rights of labor. The Institute
regards protection of property as contributing
to economic freedom but protection of labor
as reducing that freedom (on the grounds
VARIATION IN LABOR INSTITUTIONS that protective institutions limit the ability
AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE of businesses to make purely market-based
AMONG COUNTRIES decisions). As a result in 2003 countries
with little or no labor protection, such as
The starting fact for analyzing labor market Uganda, the United Arab Emirates, Zambia,
institutions across countries is that coun- and Haiti, ranked at the top of its index of labor
tries evince widely varying institutional market freedom while countries with well-
arrangements. The list at the outset of the developed legal systems to protect workers,
paper can be easily extended: apprenticeship such as Germany and Sweden, ranked near
programs, occupational health and safety the bottom.3 But, nomenclature aside, the
rules, defined benefit and defined contribution Institute’s index measures the market vs.
pension plans; mandated works councils; institutional orientation of economies in a way
equal employment legislation; and so on. that fits with general observation for advanced
While economists do not have a single tight countries, in that its index places the US
definition of an institution, per Justice Potter’s higher in reliance on markets than European
famous statement about pornography, they economies.
know institutions when they see them, and Column 2 gives the rankings of countries
they see them everywhere.2 in the market orientation of their labor
Table 34.1 documents the variety of labor market from a very different survey – the
institutions among OECD countries and in the Harvard Labor and Work Life Program’s
Asian ‘Tiger’ economies. It records quantita- Global Labor Survey (GLS). This Internet-
tive rankings of country labor markets by their based survey asked union leaders, labor law
market vs. institutional orientation, measures professors, and other experts around the
642 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 34.1 Measures of the variation of labor institutions across advanced countries
Country Fraser, GLS, Per cent Per cent Employment Gov. social
group 2003 2005 union collective protection spending/
labor 2003 bargaining legislation NNI, 2003
index 2000
Anglo-American
US 10 6 12 14 0.7 18.7
UK 19 13 29 30 1.1 23.3
NZ 38 16 22 25 1.3 22
Ireland 47 17 35 − 1.3 22.2
Australia 32 17 25 80 1.5 25.4
Canada 25 15 26 32 1.1 20.9
Other Advanced
Switzerland 34 19 18 40 1.6 31.6
Netherlands 52 29 23 80 2.3 25.5
Finland 90 26 74 90 2.1 31.8
Denmark 71 26 70 90 1.8 34.3
Austria 83 25 35 95 2.2 32.3
Belgium 63 29 55 90 2.5 31.4
Germany 101 23 23 68 2.5 34.6
Portugal 77 − 24* 80 3.5 29
Sweden 96 29 78 90 2.6 36.3
Japan 28 17 20 15 1.8 22.9
Norway 89 27 53 70 2.6 31.3
Spain 54 − 16 80 3.1 24.3
Italy 95 24 34 80 2.4 30.8
France 58 26 6 90 2.9 33.7
Greece 94 − 27* − 2.9 23.2
Four Asian Tigers
Hong Kong 5 − −
Singapore 42 9 −
Taiwan 61 7 −
Korea 81 10 11 11 9.2
Source: Column 1, Fraser Institute (2005) Economic Freedom of the World: 2005Annual Report. http://www.freetheworld.
com/download.html; Column 2, Global Labor Survey (2005), Freeman and Chor (2005); Column 3 from Visser, J., “Union
membership statistics in 24 countries”, in Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 129, No. 1, January 2006, with * for 2000 from
OECD 2004; Table 3.3; Column 4, OECD, 2004, Table 3.3 Column 5, OECD, 2004, Table 2. A2.4, version 2; Column 6, Society
at a Glance: OECD Social Indicators 2006 Edition 2007 – Data GE1.2 Share of non-health and total social spending in
national income, 2003. Note: the numbers in the ranking in columns 1 and 2 exceed the number of countries in the figure
because the rankings include developing economies that I do not report in the table.

world to report on the actual situation of collective bargaining has been the main
labor in their country. Because respondents mechanism by which they raise wages.
were generally favorable to labor institutions The density data show wide and increasing
(Chor and Freeman, 2005), it provides a variation in the percentage of workers in
useful counterpart to the Fraser index. The unions among advanced countries. In 1980,
rankings in column 2 correspond closely to the 5 countries with the highest union density
those in column 1, demonstrating that persons averaged 67.8 per cent while the five countries
with differing ideological persuasions see the with the lowest density averaged 18.9 per cent,
institution/market orientation of economies in for a ratio of 3.6 to 1.0. In 2000, the 5 most
analogous ways. unionized countries had an average density
Columns 3 and 4 turn to measures of of 66.2 per cent while the 5 least unionized
union density and collective bargaining cov- countries had a density of 12.5 per cent,
erage. Historically unions have been the giving a ratio of 5.3 to 1.0 (data from Visser,
major organization representing workers, and 2006). The percentage of workers covered
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 643

by collective bargaining in column 4 shows country with the highest social expenditure
greater variation. In the US, UK, Canada, ratio is the UK, whose spending falls below
New Zealand, and Japan, the rate of collective all of the other countries save Japan and
bargaining coverage approximates the rate of Spain. At the other end of the spectrum
unionization, so that declining union density the Scandinavian countries have relatively
produces commensurate declines in collective high social expenditure shares of national
bargaining coverage. By contrast, many income.
EU countries extend collective bargaining As a crude statistical test of the difference
contracts to all workers and firms in a sector, in labor institutions between the Anglo-
so that the majority of workers are covered American economies and other advanced
by collective bargaining regardless of union economies, Freeman et al. (2007) calculated
density. This pattern is most striking for t-statistics of differences in the mean values of
France, whose collective bargaining coverage several measures of labor institutions between
is among the highest in the world despite the Anglo-American and other advanced
France having a rate of unionization below countries. Table 34.2 shows that most of
that in the US! In 1980, the 5 countries the differences are large and statistically sig-
with the highest level of collective bargaining nificant. Executives in the Anglo-American
coverage had 2.8 times the coverage of the countries, for example, report greater control
5 countries with the lowest level of collective over wages, ability to link pay to productivity;
bargaining coverage. In 2000, the ratio of and power over hiring and firing than do
coverage in the five most highly covered executives in the other advanced countries.
countries to coverage in the five least covered Similarly, labor practitioners in the Anglo-
countries had risen to 4.6.4 American countries report a greater tilt toward
Column 5 records OECD measures of business in labor market conditions and
employment protection legislation (EPL) – regulations, in government’s attitude in labor
legal rules protect workers against layoffs by disputes provision of employee benefits, and
requiring sizeable severance pay if the firm in forming unions than practitioners in the
lays them off and in many cases require that other advanced countries.
the firm negotiate with a works council on a
social plan for retraining. The Table shows
Classifying wage-setting institutions
that the US and the other Anglo-American
countries (UK, Canada, Ireland, Australia, From the 1970s through to the mid-1980s,
New Zealand) have weak employment protec- analyses of labor institutions viewed the
tion legislation compared to other advanced aggregate economic outcomes of countries
economies. (Freeman et al., 2007). TheAnglo- with ‘neo-corporatist’ labor arrangements –
American economy with the strongest EPL centralized wage-setting between peak level
regulations, Australia, had weaker regulations national union organizations and employer
than the European countries with the weak- associations – as superior to outcomes in
est protection, Denmark, and Switzerland. countries where market forces or decentral-
The US, which operates in large part by ized collective bargaining set wages and
employment-at-will has the lowest EPL score. conditions of work. The studies explained the
In the US firms own jobs and can replace success of centralized bargaining in terms of
workers for any business or other (non- the ability of national bargainers to adjust
discriminatory) reason. readily to aggregate economic shocks, notably
The last column of Table 34.1 gives the the 1970s oil price increases. By contrast,
ratio of government social expenditures to from the late 1980s through to the mid-
net national income. High shares of national 2000s, most studies focused on the superior
income going to social expenditures imply employment and productivity growth of the
more extensive welfare states. The US and US compared to the EU, with due allowance
Japan have low ratios. The Anglo-American for high employment in Scandinavia.
644 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

Table 34.2 Mean values of ranks of Anglo-American and other advanced economies labor
institutions (low value=market-oriented) and t-tests of their statistical significance
Panel A: Reports by executives on World Economic Forum 2003

Mean, t-test Wage Pay link to Hiring and Delegation of Co-operative


flexibility productivity firing authority labor-mgt
relations
Mean, Anglo- 26 11 27 11 25
American
Mean, Other 60 39 53 18 25
Advanced
t-test 2.6 5.09 2.72 1.4 0.08
Implications Anglo-American Anglo-American Anglo-American Anglo-American No difference
have more firms link pay firms have delegate perceived in
control over to productivity greater power slightly more labor-mgt
wages more than to hire and fire authority cooperation
others

Panel B: Reports by labor practitioners, Global Labor Survey 2004

Mean, t-test Labor market Freedom of Labor Regulations Employee


conditions association/ disputes and working benefits
collective conditions
bargaining
Mean, Anglo- 16 15 12 13 13
American
Mean, Other 26 26 22 25 26
t-test 4.13 5.03 3.34 3.29 5.67
Implications Labor market is Freedom of Anglo-American Labor regulations Fewer benefits
more business- association have more are more in Anglo-
friendly in and collective pro-business pro-business in American
Anglo- bargaining stance in Anglo-
American more difficult disputes American
in Anglo-
American
Source: Freeman, Boxall, Haynes, 2007, Chapter 1.

To measure country wage-setting institu- on the basis of its Shunto offensive and strong
tions researchers developed indices of central- business-government relations; while others
ization and/or co-ordination in wage setting. view Japan as decentralized on the basis of its
Although these indices relied on limited enterprise level unionism, bonus pay system,
descriptive data on wage practices and varied and lack of a centralized bargaining structure
among analysts, they gave a roughly similar or strong government wage-setting regula-
picture of the role of institutions in wage set- tions. Given Japan’s success in overcoming
ting (see OECD Employment Outlook, 1997, wage and price inflation in the 1970s, whether
Table 3.4) – one that resembles the pattern analysts place Japan as corporatist or liberal
in Table 34.1. All the indices rate the US as colors how one assesses the relation between
having one of the most decentralized systems institutions and outcomes in that period.5
of wage-setting and the Scandinavian coun- Another country that has created problems
tries as among the most institution-driven. is Switzerland, which has also had good
Analysts have, however, disagreed about aggregate economic performance.
the placement of some countries along the In the ensuing years, the OECD has devel-
institutional/market scale (Kenworthy, 2001). oped new and improved measures of wage set-
For instance, some view Japan as ‘corporatist’ ting and other institutions in OECD countries
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 645

over time. In 2004 it placed countries’ wage Outside the advanced OECD countries,
setting into five categories reflecting the quantitative information on de facto differ-
centralization of bargaining; and into five ences in labor market practices is sparse.
categories reflecting co-ordination of bargain- The Global Competitiveness Report, the
ing. Both categorizations resemble those in Global Labor Survey, and the Fraser Insti-
Table 34.1, albeit with changes over time. tute include developing countries in their
Looking at the Anglo-American economies, data sets. The ILO measured unioniza-
the OECD places the US, UK, Canada, and tion and collective bargaining coverage for
New Zealand in the most market determined some developing countries in its World
wage group; Australia in the second most Labour Report 1997–1998, (ILO, 1997) and
market determined group; and puts Ireland, records the ILO conventions that coun-
which sets pay through a national wage tries have signed (http://www.ilo.org/ilolex/
pact, into the second most centralized wage- english/convdisp1.htm). But counts of union
setting group (OECD, 2004, Table 3.5).6 membership or coverage and conventions
Still, there are problems with some classifi- signed have different meanings in different
cations. The OECD categorized Italy in the countries. In 2007 the national union feder-
1980s as have company-based wage setting ation with the largest reported membership
although during that period Italy set wages in the world is the All Chinese Federation
through the centralized Scala Mobile, which of Trade Unions, which is a branch of the
reduced dispersion of pay to Scandinavian government/party rather than an independent
levels (Erickson and Ichino, 1995). Taking union organization, though it may be moving
a different approach, Botero, et al. (2004) more toward protecting workers in China’s
coded laws regulating employment contracts, new labor market. Neither the ILO, World
industrial relations, and the social security Bank, nor other organization concerned with
regulations of 85 countries to form indices of economic development has studied labor
de jure regulation of labor procedures. This institutions in developing countries with
analysis extends the measures of institutions the depth that the OECD has done for
to many developing countries and links the advanced countries.7 The biggest lacuna is
institutions to the legal traditions of the in data for workers in the informal sector,
country. But because countries differ in where most developing country employees
the way they implement legal statutes, the work, and where the government regulations
indices provide only a crude measure of the and traditional unions that underlie most
de facto institutions that can affect economic taxonomies are largely irrelevant.
outcomes. Indices based on legal regulations
are particularly suspect for developing coun-
Variation in economic performance
tries, many of whom do not have strong
among countries
rules of law. Consistent with this, the legal
indices are more weakly correlated with other The dependent variables in cross-country
measures of the institutional orientation of analyses of labor market institutions are mea-
countries than are the measures of actual sures of aggregate economic performance,
practices correlated among themselves (Chor such as rates of growth of GDP per capita,
and Freeman, 2005). The legal indices show income inequality, employment and unem-
that the advanced Anglo-American countries ployment, productivity growth, inflation, and
rely less on labor regulation and have weaker growth of real earnings. These outcomes
protections for workers than other (non- have varied greatly among advanced and
Asian Tiger) advanced countries in industrial developing countries over time. Among
relations and employment laws but their advanced countries, much attention has been
measures of social security regulations miss on employment differences between the US
the huge difference in social spending shown and Western Europe and on productivity
in Table 34.1. growth differences between the US and Japan.
646 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

But, the US aside, there is wide variation in in African cities to high urban wages
outcomes among other OECD countries. For resulting from government policies and trade
instance, Ireland more than doubled its GDP unions (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Harris-
per capita from 1979 to 2005 while France Todaro_Model). In this analysis, institutions
increased its GDP per capita more slowly. created excessively high wages in urban areas;
Spain had 20 plus per cent unemployment which in turn drew rural migrants to cities
for two decades while unemployment was where they would wait unemployed for jobs.
low in Japan. In the 1990s through to the In 1990, the World Bank warned countries
mid-2000s small European Union countries that institutions designed to improve worker
had lower unemployment rates than Germany, well-being in fact harmed those workers:
France, and Italy, while in the 1990s through
Labor market policies – minimum wages, job
the mid-2000s Australia had lower unemploy- security regulations, and social security – are usually
ment and more rapid economic growth than intended to raise welfare or reduce exploitation. But
New Zealand. they actually work to raise the cost of labor in the
Economic performance has varied even formal sector and reduce labor demand … increase
more widely among developing countries the supply of labor to the rural and urban informal
sectors, and thus depress labor incomes where most
(Easterly et al., 1993). In the 1960s and of the poor are found (World Bank, 1990: 63).
1970s Africa had better growth experience
than much of Asia, and higher GDP per In the ensuing years, the accumulation of
capita than India or China. In the 1980s evidence on these policies led the World Bank
through to the mid-2000s, China and then to modify its views (World Bank, 1995) but its
India had rapid growth, albeit with different 1990 statement still represents a widely held
labor institutions and economic and political perspective.
structures. In the Maoist era, China had
essentially no labor market (Walder, 1986).
Labor bureaus assigned jobs to workers in SHOULD LABOR INSTITUTIONS
state-owned enterprises. Managers of firms MATTER?
had little right to hire and fire or determine
pay. A national grid determined wages. The hypothesis that labor institutions are a
Mobility of labor was restricted to local prime determinant of aggregate economic
areas as the need to have hukou residence outcomes is a flattering one to specialists in
permits kept potential migrants from moving comparative labor analysis. But, flattery aside,
to the large cities. This situation changed is it reasonable to expect labor practices to
when China began its market reforms so have large effects on aggregate economies?
that by the early 2000s, the labor market There is an alternative perspective that
determined wages and employment. Over institutions are largely veneer in a world
the same period, many Latin American dominated by fundamental economic forces.
economies stagnated, and the share of the When I was in graduate school, John Dunlop –
work force in informal sector employment an institutionalist par excellence – used the
grew. Within Latin America, however, some fable of Cantillon’s cock (which I believe he
countries did well and others poorly. In Africa, learned from John Hicks) to express this view.
many economies stagnated or deteriorated, Every morning the cock awakens moments
though again with considerable cross-country before sunrise and does what nature has
variation. programmed it to do: let out a mighty ‘cock-
Research on labor institutions in devel- a-doodle-do’. Observing the time sequence
oping economies has largely focused on of cause and effect, the cock concludes
the danger that institutional interventions that crowing induces the sun to rise. So
distort market outcomes and reduce growth. too, warned Dunlop, might union leaders,
The Harris-Todaro model of unemployment business, and government officials believe
and migration attributed high unemployment that what they say or do, the way institutions
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 647

operate, determines economic success. When reservation wages and reduce job search,
you hear a union leader attribute trend growth increasing unemployment. The extent to
of real wages to unionism, a politician which collective bargaining and UI ‘distort’
credit prosperity to their stewardship, or outcomes from what would exist in an ideal
a business leader attribute lucrative stock competitive market rests on the degree of
options in a rising share market to their responsiveness of decision-makers to the
productivity, you know there is truth to the institutionally determined incentives. If firms
fable. have high elasticity of demand for labor,
Economic theory does not provide clear the change in the allocation of labor can
guidance to the effect of labor institutions be considerable. If the unemployed have a
on economic performance. Comparative static high elasticity of response to unemployment
analyses based on optimizing behavior in benefits, they may remain jobless for long
competitive markets predict that institutions periods, which will depreciate their skills and
affect outcomes, usually in ways that reduce reduce supply-side pressures on wages to clear
economic efficiency compared to what a the labor market.
perfect market would do. But analyses that Institutions also affect market outcomes by
posit efficient bargaining among economic changing the maximand of decision-makers.
decision-makers predict that institutions may Since optimizing conditions equate marginal
affect distribution but not efficiency. When benefits from an action to the marginal costs
competition gives firms little discretion to set of the action, an institution that changes the
prices or quantities, institutions have little marginal benefit function will alter outcomes
scope to affect allocation or distribution. just as does an institution that changes the
By contrast, analyses that stress the role marginal costs. Institutions that alter marginal
of information, communication, and trust in benefits can affect behavior in subtle ways.
economic behavior, and that regard resolving Compare for instance the predicted effects
prisoner’s dilemma problems as critical in of employee ownership on labor demand
economic success, suggest that institutions relative to the predicted effects of profit
can improve efficiency. I consider each of sharing on demand behavior. Since both of
these perspectives in turn. these institutions are designed to increase
the rewards to workers from capitalism, one
might expect that they have similar effects on
Institutions affect outcomes
labor demand and employment, but analysis
Standard models in which decision-makers shows the opposite. In a price theoretic model
respond to price/wage incentives in market of employee ownership, where the employee
settings show that responses to institution- owned firm seeks to maximize net revenues
ally determined incentives can substantially per worker, comparative statics predicts that
impact distribution and efficiency. Consider the firm will admit fewer members to the
the traditional analysis of union wage effects. enterprise than a competitive firm would
The union bargains for wages above the hire. Even more striking, the employee-
market level, but does not bargain over owned firm will reduce employment when
employment. Faced with higher costs of the price of output rises. This is because
labor, firms in unionized sectors reduce lower employment raises net revenues per
employment, which reallocates labor to lower worker when prices rise. But this is not
paid less productive activities in the non-union the end of the story. The employee-owned
sector. The result is lower economic efficiency firm can make more for its members by
and higher inequality since otherwise similar hiring additional workers without giving them
workers now receive different pay depending ownership in the firm. By doing this, the
on union status. Or consider labor supply employee owned firm will employ the same
analyses of unemployment insurance (UI) number of workers and respond similarly to
which predict that job losers raise their prices as a competitive firm while creating a
648 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

dual class of workers, employee-owners and


Institutions do not matter
standard wage-employees.
By contrast, consider labor demand by a Models of efficient bargaining predict that
profit-maximizing firm that shares profits with when firms/workers engage in bargaining,
workers by paying them a fixed proportion they ‘leave no money on the table’ and
of profits rather than fixed wages. Weitzman thus make the same decisions as a profit-
(1984) has shown that when a firm pays maximizing firm. This is the Coase Theorem
workers a fixed share of profits per worker, the at work in the world of labor institutions
firm seeks to hire more workers than would (Freeman, 1993b). As long as transactions
a competitive firm. In fact, the firm always costs are negligible and someone has clear
tries to hire more workers, giving it an infinite property rights to decisions, the bargaining
demand for labor. Each additional worker parties produce efficiently and agree over
adds to sales and profits, just as an additional some division of the rewards from their joint
commissioned salesperson adds to the profits effort. The analysis suggests that institution-
of a marketing firm even if it cannibalizes ally determined rules, such as employment
some sales from existing salespersons. The protection legislation, which some blame for
firm’s employment is limited by workers’ European high unemployment by making
alternative opportunities rather than by the firms leery of hiring workers they cannot
cost of labor to the firm. As a result profit shar- readily lay off in the future in fact have
ing can maintain full employment in the face no effect on employment. In the efficient
of adverse economic shocks. To the extent that bargaining model, the firm makes the efficient
Japan’s bonus compensation system – which layoff regardless of whether the worker or the
pays of 4–6 months of earnings via winter firm ‘owns’ the job. What EPL does is alter
and summer bonuses – operates as profit- the division of the profits from the efficient
sharing (Freeman and Weitzman, 1987), this choice. With EPL the firm pays some of the
can help explain Japan’s more rapid recovery profit from a layoff to the worker to induce the
from economic shocks than countries that pay worker to leave. Absent EPL the firm gets all
fixed wages. of the profit from the decision. In this model,
Employee ownership and profit sharing institutions alter the distribution of income but
also affect supply behavior. Most proponents not the efficiency of production.
of these institutions favor them because they When market forces are so constraining
give greater incentives to workers to work that firms must choose profit-maximizing
hard than do fixed wages. But to succeed, these outcomes or go out of business, institutional
modes of compensation must overcome the arrangements affect neither distribution nor
‘free rider’ problem – the incentive that each efficiency. If a firm has a U-shaped average
worker has to shirk and live off the effort of cost curve and operates in a competitive
other employees when all workers share the market with free entry and exit, it either
fruits of any individual’s extra effort. In an produces at the bottom of the U-shaped curve
N employee workplace this is often called the or loses money and goes out of business.
1/N problem since the worker gets only 1/Nth The need to make non-zero or positive
of the reward for their effort. Overcoming the profits dictates decisions. Models of ‘zero
free rider problem may require institutions – intelligent agents’(Gode and Sunder, 1993) –
work groups of different types, weekly team computer code that randomly selects the
meetings and discussion of work problems – amount produced or price charged subject to
and a ‘participative’ corporate culture that the profits constraint – show the power of
complements the incentive system. the profits constraint to produce competitive
The bottom line is that by influencing equilibrium rapidly absent any optimizing
both demand and supply, institutions have behavior. This argument has been applied to
the potential for impacting the aggregate the adverse impact of employee ownership
economy. on employment. If an employee-owned firm
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 649

makes large profits and limit entry, the that labor markets fall short of the competitive
workers whom the firm does not admit ideal is associated with evidence that the
have an incentive to form a new firm and wages of workers in the same local labor
enter the market. As a result a market with market and occupation vary widely rather than
worker-owned firms ends up in the same cluster tightly around a single market wage.
long run equilibrium as a market with profit- This result, found in diverse US data sets over
seeking firms. The logic also dictates that the years greatly impressed US institutional
union wage effects do not persist over time, economists (Slichter, 1950; Dunlop, 1956).
since the firm that pays a higher wage To the extent that the large dispersion in
cannot survive competition from lower cost pay reflects a failure of the competitive
competitors. When firms do not have ‘rents’to labor market to establish a single price of
share with workers, institutions cannot affect labor, institutionally determined reductions in
distribution. dispersion could bring the market closer to
the competitive ideal. Institutions can also
make the dynamics of wage-setting closer to
Situations when institutions
the competitive model. Looking at changes
improve outcomes
over time in pay across industries, analysts
Institutions can increase information and have noted that changes in countries with
communication flows inside firms, which can centralized bargaining more closely resemble
in turn improve decisions by management and the predictions of the competitive model
labor (Freeman and Lazear, 1995). Unions than changes in the market-driven US. The
or works councils, for instance, can facilitate competitive model predicts that exogenous
the flow of information from workers to changes in industrial productivity change the
management because they give workers some price of output but do not affect wages in
control over how the firm uses the information an industry; while exogenous changes in
that workers provide. These institutions can output prices raise output and employment
also increase the flow of information from but also do not affect wages (Council of
management to workers by bargaining for Economic Advisors, 1962; Salter, 1960).
open books, which raises the likelihood that These predictions hold in the Nordic countries
workers will give wage concessions when the where centralized or co-ordinated bargaining
firm is truly in crisis and avoid being fooled link wages to national economic conditions
into doing so when the firm cries ‘wolf’ while rather than to sectoral conditions but do
continuing to earn profits. In addition, workers not hold in the US, where changes in
with grievances will use firm-level institutions wages depend substantively on changes in
of voice to resolve problems rather than quit sectoral prices and productivity (Holmlund
their employer, which should reduce turnover and Zetterberg, 1991; Teulings and Hartog,
costs and lead to greater investments in firm- 1998).
specific skills. In the Freeman-Lazear model, At the macro-level, the case for institutions
increasing the power of works councils raises is that they deal better with macro-economic
output up to a point, after which increasing problems, such as inflation and balance
output falls. The reason is that in this analysis of payments difficulties, than decentralized
worker groups and management maximize labor markets. The Nordic Model of the
their own income rather than their joint output, open macro-economy posits that peak level
so that the worker-dominated firm would unions and employers’ associations negotiate
shortchange capital, just as the management- changes in wages equal to productivity growth
dominated firm would shortchange labor. in traded sectors and changes in world
Institutions can also improve market out- prices for those goods, which maintains
comes if they enable real markets to come fixed exchange rates (Aukrust, 1977; Milner
closer to the competitive ideal than those mar- and Wadensjö, 2001). By contrast, wage-
kets otherwise would have done. The belief setting in local labor markets risks inflationary
650 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

spirals, with wage increases in non-traded countries with more market-oriented labor
sectors inducing wage increases in the markets (Bruno and Sachs, 1985; Crouch,
traded goods sector that exceed productivity 1985; Tarantelli, 1986). But it is difficult to
growth and increases in global prices for make strong statements about the effects of
the traded goods. Mancur Olson (1990) wage-setting institutions from cross-country
argued that centralized collective bargaining data. Countries differ in many other dimen-
in small open economies works because all- sions and policies. Maybe income tax policy,
encompassing union organizations internalize or employment protection legislation, or
the negative externalities from wage bar- product market regulations, or unemployment
gaining at the firm or industry level. The benefits rather than wage-setting mechanisms
International Labor Organization goes further underlie differences in aggregate outcomes.
to claim that economic systems based on Since the number of advanced countries is
labor-management dialog improves aggregate small relative to the number of institutions
efficiency: ‘Successful social dialogue struc- or policies, it is hard to estimate effects for
tures and processes have the potential to particular institutions. This is one reason why
resolve important economic and social issues, many analyses link the configurations of insti-
encourage good governance, advance social tutions/policies captured in the taxonomies of
and industrial peace and stability and boost the institutional/market orientation of coun-
economic progress’. (ILO, Social Dialogue, tries to outcomes. But this still leaves open
2007) Finally, even if institutions reduce the possibility that an omitted cross-country
efficiency, they can still improve societal well- factor outside the labor market underlies the
being if they redistribute income in ways pattern.
consistent with the country’s social welfare The second type of study looks at changes
function. in institutions. A generic model would be:
In sum, there are arguments that institutions
raise efficiency, reduce efficiency, and have (1) Yct = a + b Xct + T + I + uct , where c refers
to country and t refers to time; Y is the outcome
no effect on outcomes beyond distribution.
variable of interest (or a vector of such variables);
To determine which arguments are valid for X are measures of institutions, T is a vector of year
which institutions under which economic dummies; and I is a vector of country dummies.
conditions requires evidence on the actual link
between institutions and outcomes, to which By holding fixed country and year, this
I turn next. analysis infers the effects of policy by
comparing the change in outcomes in the
country that changed policy (the treatment)
INSTITUTIONS AND OUTCOMES with the change in outcomes in countries
IN PRACTICE that maintained policies (the controls). But
developments in other countries are not
‘Give your evidence,’ said the King; ‘and don’t be necessarily a good measure of what might
nervous, or I’ll have you executed on the spot’. have happened for the country that changed
(Alice’s Adventures in Wonderland, Chapter 11, policies. Abadie et al. (2007) have developed
‘Who Stole the Tarts?’)
a more sophisticated counterfactual in which
Since cross-country differences in per- the analyst uses a composite of countries
formance motivate many studies of labor that give the best predictor of outcomes for
institutions, it is natural that the first wave the country prior to its change in policy.
of empirical analysis examined the cross- Evidence that the proposed counterfactual
section relation between institutional arrange- predicts what might have happened in the
ments and economic outcomes. These studies country before it changed policy increases
reported that countries with neo-corporatist the likelihood that the counterfactual is valid.
arrangements did better in adjusting to Even if a given institutional change produced
the economic problems of the 1980s than a particular outcome in one country, moreover,
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 651

it is uncertain that it will produce the same Table 34.3 90/10 Wage differentials and
outcome elsewhere. Institutions that work one Gini coefficients for advanced countries,
way in one country may work differently circa 2000
in another country where it interacts with Dispersion Gini
other institutions. Enact a law on temporary US 4.59 40.8
contracts in Spain and new entrants are UK 3.45 36.0
NZ 3.28 36.2
hired under those contracts. Enact a similar Ireland 3.97 35.9
law in Germany, and firms continue to hire Australia 2.94 35.2
apprentices for permanent jobs. To the extent Canada 3.65 33.1
that labor institutions form a unified consistent Switzerland 2.69 33.1
system, one cannot simply extrapolate the Netherlands 2.85 30.9
Finland 2.36 26.9
effects of changing a single institution in one Denmark 2.16 24.7
labor system to another. Austria 3.56 30.0
A third type of study compares outcomes Belgium 2.28 25.0
between workers covered by different labor Germany 2.87 28.3
institutions within countries in which such Portugal 3.76 38.5
Sweden 2.23 25.0
intra-country differences exist. The virtue of Japan 2.99 24.9
this approach is that it holds fixed the factors Norway 1.96 25.8
that affect an economy in its entirety. Making Spain 3.94* 32.5
within-country comparisons of union and Italy 2.40 36.0
non-union workers is how economists study France 3.07 32.7
Greece 3.62* 35.4
the effects of unions in countries where union
Source: Ratio of Wages, from OECD, 2004, Table 3.2, where
and non-union arrangements coexist – such
the data are from 1995–99 with figures from Austria,
as in the Anglo-American countries (Freeman Belgium, Denmark, Portugal are for 1990–94; Data for
and Medoff, 1984; Lewis, 1963). Such com- Spain and Greece from Pereira and Martins (2004), Table 1.
parisons measure differences between insti- Gini coefficients from United Nations 2005, Table 15.
tutionally determined and market determined
outcomes but do not necessarily identify the
structural impact of the institutions. They that rely on institutions to set wages and
miss the potential spillover of institutionally working conditions have lower rates of
determined outcomes on other workers, who inequality or dispersion of earnings – here
can be helped or harmed depending on the measured by the ratio of the pay of persons
nature of the interaction between the sectors. in the 90th percentile of wages and salaries
In sum, determining how institutions affect relative to the pay of persons in the 10th
outcomes across countries is difficult. Find- percentile – and lower levels of overall
ings must be put through several sieves – income inequality – here measured by the
cross-section analysis, before/after analyses, Gini coefficient for total income. The US,
within-country analyses, and over different which ranks as the most market-driven labor
time periods – before one can hazard a market, has the highest dispersion of wages
generalization. and the highest Gini. Other economies with
relatively market-driven labor markets also
have high levels of inequality. By contrast,
One strong finding and some
Norway, where institutions set wages, has the
problematic results
lowest dispersion.
For all of the difficulties in pinning down the Studies that look at dispersion of pay when
impact of institutions on aggregate economic institutions change, ranging from declines
performance across countries, analyses have in collective bargaining coverage as in the
found that institutions have a major impact US or UK to the breakdown of central-
on one important outcome: the distribution ized negotiations between the major union
of income. As Table 34.3 shows, countries federation and major employer association
652 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

in Sweden or the end of the Scala Mobile diagnosis that institutions adversely affect
mode of centralized wage setting in Italy aggregate outcomes are not robust. The
(Manacorda, 2004), show a comparable pat- estimated coefficients on labor institutions
tern. Movement toward market-determined become statistically insignificant with modest
pay widens earnings distributions. Movement changes in the measures of institutions,
toward more institutional wage determination countries covered, and time period. Models
narrows earnings inequality. Within-country that cover more years, countries, and measures
data on the level of dispersion in union than the early studies did ‘provide little sup-
and non-union workplaces, also shows that port for those who advocate comprehensive
inequalities are smaller in union settings and deregulation of OECD labor markets’(p. 106).
decline among workers who shift from non- Baker et al. conclude that there is a ‘yawning
union jobs to union jobs; and increase among gap between the confidence with which the
workers who move in the other direction case for labor market deregulation has been
(Card et al., 2004; Freeman, 1984). What is asserted and the evidence that the regulating
true of collective bargaining also holds for institutions are the culprits’ (p. 198). Earlier
government-mandated wage payments and Blanchflower (2001) told a similar story,
taxation. Minimum-wage laws raise pay at the noting ‘only a weak positive relation in the
bottom of the distribution and are generally OECD between unemployment and benefits
associated with lower dispersion of earnings. (p. 390) and ‘no support (from a 1999 OECD
By contrast, despite considerable effort, report) … for the belief that unions, benefits,
researchers have not pinned down the effects, the tax wedge, ALMP (Active labor market
if any, of institutions on other aggregate programs) spending or earnings dispersion
economic outcomes, such as unemployment influence unemployment … contrary to the
and employment. This statement may seem claims made in Layard et al. (1994), which
surprising in light of the numerous policy appear to be based on mis-specified cross-
pronouncements in the 1990s and 2000s country unemployment regressions (p. 392)’.
that particular market-oriented changes would Assessing results in the mid 2000s, Howell
raise employment. The OECD Jobs Study was et al. (2006) and Baccaro and Rei (2005) come
accompanied by two volumes of supporting to a similar conclusion.
research and followed by studies and reviews Given these studies and its own work,
of studies, many given in the OECD’s annual the OECD has backed away from the
Employment Outlook (Layard et al., 1994). strong claims of the early 1990s. The 2004
Nickell (1997) with various co-authors and OECD Employment Outlook argued for ‘the
diverse other economists estimated the effect plausibility (my italics) of the Jobs Strategy
of institutions on outcomes and asserted that diagnosis that excessively high aggregate
they had nailed it down: In the January wages and/or wage compression have been
2005 Economic Journal Nickell et al. (2005) impediments’ to jobs, while admitting that
summarized this work with the claim that ‘the ‘this evidence is somewhat fragile’, and that
broad movements in unemployment in the the effect of collective bargaining ‘appears
OECD can be explained by shifts in labor to be contingent upon other institutional and
market institutions’ (p. 1). policy factors that need to be clarified to
But as economists have examined the provide robust policy advice’ (p. 165). The
evidence more critically, they have rejected 2006 Outlook stressed that the institutions
these strong claims in favor of a more of low unemployment European countries
cautious stance about what the evidence differ greatly from those in the US and UK
shows about the impact of institutions on (Table 6.3). This implies that there is no
aggregate economic outcomes. Baker et al. single way to attain full employment and
(2005) documented that the time series thus no single ‘peak’ form of capitalism to
models on which the OECD and independent which each country should strive (Freeman,
researchers have relied to support their 2000). But the debate continues. In a study
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 653

that takes account of many of the criticisms this pattern. Market wage setting presumably
of earlier cross-country time series data, attains low unemployment through compet-
Bassanini and Duval (2006) estimated that itive pressures on firms and workers while
changes in tax and labor policies explain about centralized wage setting attains low unem-
half of 1982–2003 changes in unemployment ployment by forcing bargainers to consider
among countries, with tax policies playing a the impacts of wages on national unem-
particularly important role. ployment, among other aggregate outcomes.
The potential effect of employment The ‘villain’ in the story is industry or
protection legislation on employment and other intermediate level collective bargaining,
unemployment has attracted particular which allow unions and firms to ignore the
attention. Countries pass these laws to effects of their decisions on the aggregate
reduce layoffs and raise job security for economy (someone else pays the bulk of
existing workers. But by making layoffs more the unemployment compensation for workers
expensive to the firm, the laws also makes it whose jobs are lost due to high wages)
more expensive to hire workers since the firm and thus can produce high wages and
must factor in the greater expense of layoffs unemployment.
if it has to reduce output. The net effect of But in ensuing years the inverse U relation
employment protection laws on aggregate disappeared. In the early 1990s Sweden’s
employment thus depends on the degree to economic crisis reduced employment con-
which they reduce layoffs compared to the siderably. Two market-oriented economies,
degree to which they reduce hires. After over Canada and New Zealand, also experi-
two decades of analysis, the consensus from enced high unemployment. By contrast, the
studies of aggregate country data is that the Netherlands, the archetype of a country with
regulations have little effect on the overall intermediate institutions, had modest wage
rate of unemployment. Rather, EPL shifts settlements and altered some of its benefits to
unemployment from older workers to younger increase employment (Teulings and Hartog,
jobseekers (OECD Employment Outlook, 1998). Some other European countries,
2004). Micro-economic studies of the effect including those with industry bargaining,
of EPL for Chile show little evidence of a improved their economic performance. In its
negative impact on labor demand but find that 2004 review, the OECD reported no indication
EPL increases the within-firm gap between of an inverse U in cross-country comparisons
the marginal revenue product of labor and the of wage institutions and unemployment in the
wage, which it should since it creates a wedge 1990s. Rather, the data showed wide variation
between marginal product and the wage cost in aggregate outcomes among countries
of employment (Petrin et al., 2006). classified as highly centralized, decentralized,
and intermediate that belies any simple
generalization even in the earlier periods
The disappearing inverse U
(OECD, 2004, Table 3.6). Soskice (1990)
In the 1980s the pattern of unemployment pointed out that analyses that adjust measures
among OECD countries changed. Whereas of wage setting for coordination of bargaining
in the 1960s and 1970s, unemployment was in countries with industry-wide bargaining
lower in countries with highly centralized produced no inverse U even in the 1980s. The
bargaining systems than in countries with inverse U appears to be more of a historical
decentralized wage-setting systems, in the description of patterns at one period of time,
1980s unemployment was lower in both rather than any general rule about the link
of those groups than in countries with between institutions and outcomes.
collective bargaining institutions between the In short, the evidence is that institutions
extremes, at least according to some measures reduce inequality but have uncertain or time
of wage-setting institutions (Calmfors and varying impacts on other aggregate outcomes,
Driffill, 1988). There is, moreover, logic to including those likely to be affected by wages.
654 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

INTERPRETATION Lungquist and Sargent, 1998, 2004; OECD,


2006). In the case of unemployment, perhaps
There are three possible interpretations of this EU institutions were well suited to produce
evidence. First, it could be that labor insti- low unemployment in the 1960s–1980s while
tutions impact other outcomes substantially US institutions were better suited for low
which extant measures of institutions and unemployment for the globalized digital econ-
aggregate cross-section time series data are omy of the 1990s and 2000s. Alternatively,
too weak to identify. From this perspective, perhaps the behavior of institutions changed
the OECD’s continual improvement of mea- over time as decision-makers learnt from
sures of institutions and the passage of time experience what does or does not work. This
will eventually pin down the true relations. would produce different responses to the same
Doing more of the same with better and longer circumstances over time, shades of the Lucas
time series will surely add to our knowledge, critique of macro-economic models. While
but I am dubious that it will definitively appealing, the ‘changing economy/behavior
uncover institutional effects beyond those on interpretation’ of the link between institutions
the dispersion of pay. Analyses of micro-data and outcomes is difficult to test. It makes
sets that focus on measuring labor practices – great demands on data and risks creating
such as the UK’s Workplace Employment the social science equivalence of epicycles
Relations Survey (WERS) – offer a better to account for observed patterns. A model
chance for illuminating how institutions that says EU style institutions helped attain
operate on the ground and their impact on full employment in the 1960s–1980s and
outcomes. Adding measures of labor policies reduced employment in the 1990s–2000s, or
and practices to matched employee-employer that posits that institutional decision-makers
panel data sets would create even greater behaved differently in the latter period than
potential for increasing knowledge. It would in the former because they learned from their
allow researchers to compare the behavior of mistakes, can fit the observed experiences,
the same worker under different practices, the but leaves little data to test the proposed
effect of practices on selectivity of workers, explanations.8 With enough interactions, one
and the effects of practices on productivity. can readily over-fit any model.
Studies of firms that change labor practices A third reading of the evidence is that in fact
(ideally under experimental conditions) or labor institutions have a well-defined impact
operate differently across countries due to on income distribution but only modest effects
country-specific rules and norms could also on other outcomes. One reason their effects
illuminate how institutions or policies work may be modest is that the political economy of
at workplaces. institutional interventions rules out collective
The second possible interpretation of bargaining settlements and regulations that
empirical results is that the effects of are truly expensive to an economy. No
institutions on outcomes change over time country would impose a minimum wage that
due to changes in the economic environment disemployed a large fraction of the work
or to changes in institutional responses force; and no union or employer would sign
to particular economic stimuli. The rough a collective bargaining agreement that forced
stability between US and advanced European the firm to close. If countries adopt only
institutions from the 1950s through the early interventions with the most favorable benefit-
2000s when unemployment rose in the EU cost ratios, one would observe reductions in
relative to the US rules out any simple causal dispersion only if they raise efficiency or
link between institutions and outcomes. If produce minimal losses. In the same vein,
essentially unchanged institutions caused this it is possible that institutions have both the
change in unemployment and other outcomes, negative and positive effects hypothesized
the impact of institutions must have changed earlier, but that the two factors balance out,
over time (Blanchard and Wolfers, 2000; producing inconclusive results beyond those
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 655

on distribution, again for political economy of artificial agent modeling, analysts would
reasons via some form of bargaining among ideally ‘grow’ artificial economies with
parties. Taking this line of thinking to its specified institutional arrangements (Epstein,
logical conclusion the economies that rely on 2005) and then simulate the effects of
institutions may have reduced the transactions institutional changes on economic outcomes.
costs of bargaining and developed long run In short, because the problem of determin-
relations among parties such that they produce ing whether labor institutions do more than
efficient outcomes per the Coase Theorem reduce income inequality; and if so, whether
more often than not. they improve or worsen economic outcomes
To help assess these interpretations and is such a hard one – on par with the six blind
increase our knowledge of institutions men trying to understand the elephant – we
requires inputs from areas of research need all of the tools at our disposal. It is only
that have played little role in the debate by combining insights and observations from
over the link between labor institutions different perspectives that we will be able to
on aggregate outcomes. One such area is capture the institutional reality and not:
experimental economics. Evidence from
Rail on in utter ignorance
laboratory experiments that people care about Of what each other mean,
fair processes and outcomes and cooperate And prate about an Elephant
more than rational optimizing models of Not one of them has seen!
human behavior opens the door for studies (Saxe)
of the conditions when institutions can
improve market outcomes. Experiments
that reflected real world institutions, such NOTES
as group decisions, would at the minimum
provide researchers with realistic priors 1 The Coase Theorem holds that absent transaction
about what to expect from those institutions costs, decision-makers will bargain to efficient
outside the laboratory. Another area is game outcomes regardless of the initial distribution
of property rights. See http://en.wikipedia.org/
theory and the related field of implementation wiki/Coase_Theorem
theory (Jackson, 2001). Theories of behavior 2 The Justice wrote, ‘I shall not today attempt fur-
under different bargaining rules could help ther to define the kinds of material I understand to be
illuminate the conditions under which embraced within that shorthand description; and per-
European social dialogue institution can haps I could never succeed in intelligibly doing so. But
I know it when I see it’. http://caselaw.lp.findlaw.com/
yield efficient bargains and direct attention scripts/getcase.pl?court=US&vol=378&invol=184
at institutional reforms that would increase 3 This scoring creates a negative relation between
the potential for Coase-theorem bargains ‘economic freedom’ in the labor market and GDP per
(Freeman, 2007). Finally, because labor capita for all countries, while the overall freedom index
institutions interact in ways that go beyond is positively correlated with GDP per capita (Freeman,
2002).
theory and experiments, artificial agent 4 The coverage for the top five was 87 per cent in
simulations could illuminate hypothesized 1980 and 91 per cent in 2000. The coverage for the
interactions among institutions and between bottom five was 31 per cent in 1980 and 20 per cent
institutions and economic shocks and in 2000. OECD Employment Outlook 2004, Table 3.3.
behavior, building on matching models of I have excluded the transition economy new entrants
to the OECD from this analysis.
firms and workers (Pingle and Tesfatsion, 5 The range for Japan is from the 3rd or 4th most
2003; Neugart, 2004). Roth and co-workers centralized or coordinated to among the most highly
(1999, 2002) have shown the value of decentralized. Soskice 1990 finds that the categoriza-
combining such modeling in analyzing tion of countries changes some generalizations.
the market for medical residents, which 6 The six Anglo-American economies averaged 1.8
on the wage-setting centralization scale while the
seemingly works better through a centralized other advanced OECD countries averaged 2.8, where
allocative matching algorithm than through the scaling places lower value on more market-reliant
standard competitive behavior. In the spirit systems.
656 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

7 Rama and Artetcona (2002) developed a World Bruno, Michael and Sachs, Jeffrey (1985) Economics
Bank labor database for all countries by gathering of Worldwide Stagflation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
labor indicators from various sources into a single University Press.
place, but the Bank did not pursue an on-going effort Calmfors, Lars and Driffill, John (1988) ’Bargaining
to improve the measures.
structure, corporatism, and. macroeconomic perfor-
8 To illustrate, consider a model in which
mance’, Economic Policy, 6 (April): 14–61.
economies determine wages by collective bargaining
or market forces and experience a price shock or Card, David, Lemieux, Thomas, and Riddell, W. Craig
competition from low wage countries or both. An (2004) ‘Unions and wage inequality’, Journal of Labor
experimental design to assess the link between shocks Research, 25 (4): 519–62.
and institutions would require 16 (= 23 ) treatments If Carroll, Lewis (2006) Alice’s Adventures in
institutions reacted depending on which shock they Wonderland. Harold Bloom (ed.) NY: Chelsea House
faced first, the number of treatments would increase. Publishers.
Chor, Davin and Freeman, Richard (2005) ’The 2004
global labor survey: Workplace institutions and
REFERENCES practices around the world’, NBER Working Paper
11598.
Abadie, Alberto, Diamond, Alexis, and Hainmueller, Council of Economic Advisors (1962) Economic Report of
Jens (2007) ‘Synthetic control methods for the President. Washington, DC: Government Printing
comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of Office.
California’s Tobacco Control Program’, January. Crouch, Colin (1985) ‘Conditions for trade union wage
http://www.people.fas.harvard.edu/∼jhainm/Paper/ restraint’, in Leon N. Lindberg and Charles S.
ADH2007.pdf Maier (eds) The Politics of Inflation and Economic
Aukrust, Odd (1977) ‘Inflation in the open economy: Stagflation. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
A Norwegian model’, in L.B. Krause and W.S. Salant Easterly, William, Kremer, Michael, Pritchett, Lant, and
(eds), Worldwide Inflation; Theory and Recent Summers, Lawrence H. (1993) ‘Good policy or good
Experience. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. luck? Country growth performance and temporary
Baccaro, Lucio and Diego, Rei (2005) ‘Institutional shocks’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 32 (3):
determinants of unemployment in OECD countries: 459–83.
a time series cross-section analysis (1960–98)’, Epstein, Joshua M. (2005) ‘Remarks on the foundations
International Institute for Labour Studies Discussion of agent-based generative social science’, Brookings,
Paper DP/160/2005, International Institute for Labour CSED, Working Paper 41 (July).
Studies, Geneva Erickson, Christopher L. and Ichino, Andrea (1995)
Baker, D., Glyn, A., Howell, D., and Schmitt, J. (2005) ‘Wage differentials in Italy: Market Forces, Institutions
‘Labour market institutions and unemployment: and Inflation’, in Richard B. Freeman and Lawrence
A critical assessment of the cross-country evidence’, F. Katz (eds), Differences and Changes in Wage
in David R. Howell (ed.), Fighting Unemployment: Structures. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for
The Limits of Free Market Orthodoxy. Oxford: Oxford NBER.
University Press. Fraser Institute (2001) Economic Freedom of the World:
Bassanini, Andrea and Duval, Romain (2006) ‘Employ- 2001 Annual Report. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser
ment patterns in OECD countries: Reassessing the Institute.
role of policies and institutions’, OECD Economic Fraser Institute (2003) Economic Freedom of the World:
Department Working Paper 486, June. 2003 Annual Report. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser
Blanchard, Olivier and Wolfers, Justin (2000) ’Shocks Institute.
and institutions and the rise of European unemploy- Freeman, Richard B. (1984) ‘Longitudinal analyses of the
ment: The Aggregate Evidence’, Economic Journal, effects of trade unions’, Journal of Labor Economics,
110 (1): 1–33. 2 (1): 1–26.
Blanchflower, David G. (2001) ‘Unemployment, well- Freeman, Richard B. (1993a) ‘Labor market institutions
being, and wage curves in Eastern and Central and policies: Help or hindrance to economic
Europe’, Journal of the Japanese and International development?’ Proceedings of the World Bank
Economies, 15: 364–402. Annual Conference on Development Economics
Botero, Juan, Djankov, Simeon, La Porta, Rafael, López 1992. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
de Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei (2004) ‘The Freeman, Richard B. (1993b) ‘Labor markets and
Regulation of Labor’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, institutions in economic development’, American
119: 1339–82. Economic Review, 83 (2) (May): 403–8.
LABOR MARKET INSTITUTIONS AROUND THE WORLD 657

Freeman, Richard B. (2000) ‘Single peaked vs. Jackson, Matthew O. (2001) ‘A crash course in
diversified capitalism: The relation between economic implementation theory’, Social Choice and Welfare,
institutions and outcomes’, in Richard B. Freeman 18 (4): 655–708.
(ed.), Inequality around the World. London, UK: Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds) (1995) The
Palgrave. Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ:
Freeman, Richard B. (2002) ‘Varieties of labor market Princeton University Press.
institutions and economic performance’, presented at Kenworthy, Lane (2001) ‘Wage-setting measures,
the IRRA Session on Labor Market Institutions and a survey and assessment’, World Politics 55 (October):
Economic Outcomes, January 4. 57–98.
Freeman, Richard B. (2005) ‘Labour market institutions Layard, Richard, Nickell, Stephen, and Jackman, Richard
without blinders: The debate over flexibility and (1994) The Unemployment Crisis. Oxford, UK: Oxford
labour market performance’, International Economic University Press.
Journal RIEJ, 19 (2): 129–45. Lewis, H. Gregg (1963) Unionism and Relative Wages in
Freeman, Richard B. (2007) ‘Searching for the EU the United States. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.
social dialogue model’, in Nicola Acocella and Ljungqvist, Lars and Sargent, Thomas J. (1998)
Riccardo Leoni (eds), Social Pacts, Employment and ‘The European unemployment dilemma’, Journal of
Growth: A Reappraisal of Ezio Tarantelli’s Thought. Political Economy, 106 (3): 514–50.
Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag. Ljungqvist, Lars and Sargent, Thomas J. (2004)
Freeman, Richard B., Boxall, Peter and Haynes, ‘European unemployment and turbulence revisited in
Peter (eds) (forthcoming, 2007) What Workers Say: a matching model’, Journal of the European Economic
Employee Voice in the Anglo-American Workplace. Association, 2(2–3)( April/May): 456–68.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Manacorda, Marco (2004) ‘Can the Scala Mobile explain
Freeman, Richard B. and Lazear, Edward P. (1995) the fall and rise of earnings inequality in Italy?
‘An economic analysis of works councils’, in A semiparametric analysis, 1977–1993’, Journal of
Joel Rogers and Wolfgang Streeck (eds), Works Labor Economics, 22 (3): 585–613.
Councils: Consultation, Representation, Cooperation. Manning, Alan (2005) Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press for NBER. Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ:
pp. 27–50. Princeton University Press.
Freeman, Richard B. and Medoff, James (1984) What do Martin, John Paul (1998) ‘What works among active
Unions Do? New York: Basic Books. labour market policies: Evidence from OECD
Freeman, Richard B. and Weitzman, Martin L. (1987) Countries’ Experiences’. Available at: www.rba.
‘Bonuses and employment in Japan’, Journal of gov.au/PublicationsAndResearch/Conferences/1998/
the Japanese and International Economies, 1: Martin.pdf
168–94. Milner, Henry and Wadensjö, Eskil (eds) (2001) Gösta
Gode, Dhananjay K. and Sunder, Shyam (1993) Rehn, the Swedish Model and Labour Market Policies:
‘Allocative efficiency of markets with zero-intelligence International and National Perspectives. Aldershot:
traders: Market as a partial substitute for individual Ashgate.
rationality’, Journal of Political Economy, 101 (1): Neugart, Michael (2004) ‘Endogenous matching func-
119–37. tions: an agent-based computational approach’,
Holmlund, Bertil and Zetterberg, Johnny (1991) ‘Insider Advances in Complex Systems, 7 (2): 187–202.
effects in wage determination: Evidence from five Nickell, Stephen J. and Brian Bell (1996) ‘Changes in
countries’, European Economic Review, July. the distribution of wages and unemployment in the
Howell, David, Baker, Dean, Glyn, Andrew, and OECD countries’,American Economic Review, Papers
Schmitt, John (2006) ‘Are protective labour market and Proceedings, 86 (5): 302–08.
institutions really at the root of unemployment? Nickell, Stephen, Nunziata, Luca, and Ochel, Wolfgang
A critical perspective on the statistical evidence’, (2005) ‘Unemployment in the OECD since the 1960s:
July 14. http://www.cepr.net/documents/2006_07_ What do we know?’, The Economic Journal, 115
unemployment_institutions.pdf (January): 1–27, Royal Economic Society.
International Labour Office (1997) World Labour Report Nickell, Stephen (1997) ‘Unemployment and labor
1997–98. Industrial Relations, Democracy and Social market rigidities: Europe versus North America’,
Stability. Geneva: ILO. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (3) (Summer):
International Labour Office (2007) Social Dialogue. 55–74.
http://www.ilo.org/public/english/dialogue/themes/ Olson, Mancur (1990) How Bright Are the
sd.htm Northern Lights?: Some questions about Sweden
658 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS

(Crafoord lectures). Lund, Sweden: Institute of Salter, Wilfred E.G (1960) Productivity and Technical
Economic Research, Lund University. Change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Develop- Saxe, John Godfrey, ‘Blind men and an Elephant’,
ment (OECD) (1994a) OECD Jobs Study, Evidence http://en.wikisource.org/wiki/The_Blindmen_and_the_
and Explanations, Part I: Labor Market Trends and Elephant
Underlying Forces of Change. Paris: OECD. Slichter, Sumner H. (1950 ‘Notes on the structure of
OECD (1994b) OECD Jobs Study, Evidence and wages’, The Review of Economics and Statistics,
Explanations, Part II: The Adjustment Potential of the 32 (1) (February): 80–91.
Labor Market. Paris: OECD. Soskice, David (1990) ‘Wage determination: The chang-
OECD (1995) OECD Jobs Study, Taxation, Employment, ing role of institutions in advanced industrialized
and Unemployment. Paris: OECD. countries’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 6 (4):
OECD (1996) OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. 36–61.
OECD (1997) ‘Economic performance and the structure Tarentelli, Ezio (1986) ‘The Regulation of Inflation and
of collective bargaining’, OECD Employment Outlook Unemployment’, Industrial Relations, 25 (1): 1–15.
(July). Paris: OECD. Teulings, Coen and Hartog, Joop (1998) Corporatism
OECD (1997) Implementing the Jobs Study. Paris: OECD. or Competition? Labour Contracts, Institutions
OECD (2002) OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. and Wage Structures in International Competition.
OECD (2004) OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
OECD (2006) OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Traxler, Franz (2002) ‘Bargaining (de)centralization,
Pereira, Pedro Telhado and Martins, Pedro Silva (2004) macro-economic performance and control over the
‘Returns to education and wage equations’, Applied employment relationship’, British Journal of Industrial
Economics, 36 (6) (April): 525–31. Relations, 1(March): 1–27.
Petrin, Amil and Sivadasan, Jagadeesh (2006) ‘Job Traxler, Franz and Kittel , Bernhard (2000) ‘The
security does affect economic efficiency: Theory, a bargaining system and performance: A comparison
new statistic, and evidence’, NBER Working Paper of 18 OECD countries’, Comparative Political Studies,
12757 (December). 33 (?): 1154–90.
Pingle, Mark and Tesfatsion, Leigh (2003) ‘Evolution United Nations (2005) United Nations Human Develop-
of worker-employer networks and behaviors under ment Report 2005. New York: UNDP.
alternative non-employment benefits: An agent- Visser, Jelle (2006) ‘Union membership statis-
based computational study’, Computing in Economics tics in 24 countries’, Monthly Labor Review,
and Finance, 7, Society for Computational Economics. 129(1)(January). Available at: http://www.bls.gov/
Rama, Martin and Artecona, Raquel (2002) ‘A database opub/mlr/2006/01/art3abs.htm
of labor market indicators across countries’, Walder, Andrew (1986) Communist Neotraditionalism:
Washington, DC: World Bank, Development Research Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. Berkeley, CA:
Group. University of California Press.
Roth, Alvin E. and Peranson, Elliott (1999) ‘The redesign Weitzman, Martin L. (1984) The Share Economy:
of the matching market for American physicians: Conquering Stagflation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Some engineering aspects of economic design’, University Press.
American Economic Review, 89 (4) (September): World Bank (1990) World Development Report 1990.
748–80. New York: Oxford University Press.
Roth, Alvin E. (2002) ‘The economist as engineer: World Bank (1995) World Development Report.
Game theory, experimentation, and computation as Washington, DC: The World Bank.
tools for design economics’, Fisher-Schultz Lecture, World Economic Forum (2003) Global Competitiveness
Econometrica, 70 (4) (July): 1341–78. Report. Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum.
Index

absenteeism 595, 600 applied social science 61 AWP. see alternative work practices
ACAS. see Advisory, Conciliation apprenticeships 608, 617 (AWP)
and Arbitration Service (ACAS) Arbeitskraft 289
accountability 371 Arbeitsverhältnis 290 bank: central 268
activation 268–9 Argentina: tariffs 274 bargaining 414. see also Collective
actors 2–3. see also International ASEAN. see Association of bargaining; capitalism 137–8;
actors; centered approaches Southeast Asian Nations centralized 410, 413; company
VoC 132–5; system 71–2; (ASEAN) level 413; coordination index 138;
workplace 71 Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation vs. corporatism 407;
ACTU. see Australian Council of (APEC) 331 decentralization 171; fractional
Trade Unions (ACTU) Association of Southeast Asian 197; multi-employer 115, 116,
ADR. see alternative dispute Nations (ASEAN) 331, 339 230–3, 239, 410; plant level 413;
resolution (ADR) attitudes: contingent work rent 123; structure break up
advanced economies labor arrangements 480; managers 117–20; structure competitive
institutions: mean values 644 247–8; surveys 178; variables 177 influences 114–6; wage 143
Advisory, Conciliation and bargaining unit: defined 232;
at-will model 289
Arbitration Service (ACAS) 453 size 387
audits: equal pay 504; ethical Belgium: employer organizations
AFL. see American Federation of trading 126
Labor (AFL) 232; extension practices 233;
Australia: bargaining union density 130, 132, 137, 316
Africa: economic performance 646; decentralization 171; economic
poverty 574 best practices 243
performance 646; employer Beyond Contract: Work, Power and
aging: healthcare needs 307; public organizations 234; EPL 643;
services 307 Trust Relations (Fox) 39
ESOP 441; gender inequality 579, bias 179
agreements. see Collective 582; inequality 576; IR climate Black Death 288
agreements 561; laissez-faire state 271; liberal Blair, Tony 57
ALP. see Australian Labour Party and coordinated market blockholding 299
(ALP) economies 439–40; limited term BLS. see Bureau of Labor Statistics
alternative dispute resolution contracts 581; minimum wage (BLS)
(ADR) 452 578; re-regulatory reforms 574; boutique unionism 193
alternative work practices (AWP) takeover code 299; working hours Brazil: working time 518
624; firm performance 630–2; 516, 541; working time Bretton Woods 328, 329
unions 629–30 patterns 521 Britain. see also United Kingdom
AMA. see American Management Australian Council of Trade Unions (UK): central bank 268; CIPD 53;
Association (AMA) (ACTU) 440 collective agreements 266;
American Federation of Labor Australian Industrial Relations common law 288; corporatist
(AFL) 191, 192, 193; CIO merger Survey (AWIRS95) 440 arrangements 130; disciplinary
191; CIO split 213 Australian Labour Party (ALP) structure 46; employer
American industry changes 421 439–40 organizations 236;
American Lean Production 423 Austria: capitalism 144; corporatism epistemological traditions 46;
American Management Association 275; decline in union density 137; evolving union structures 191–2;
(AMA) 37–8 employer density 232; employer HRM 171; industrial democracy
American Team Production 423 organizations 232, 235; union 48; institutional histories 39–41;
Amicus 191 density 137, 316 international competition 119;
Amnesty and Oxfam 331 authority: supranational 326 laissez-faire legal structure 117;
analytical method 77–8 autocratic unions 194 liberalism 48; management role
Anglophone labor law 48 autonomy: union formation 384 171; Marxism 43; organizing-
APEC. see Asia-Pacific Economic AWIRS95. see Australian Industrial driven unions 200; political
Cooperation (APEC) Relations Survey (AWIRS95) traditions 47–8; politics 56–7;
660 INDEX

Britain (continued) CBHRT. see context-based human Cold War 307


post-war engineering industry resource theory (CBHRT) collective action: sociological
125; private contracts 48; private CBI. see Confederation of British theories 177
property 48; public employees Industry (CBI) collective agreements 266;
265; public sector proxy product Central Arbitration Committee employment law 4; legal status
markets 120–1; shop-floor labour- (CAC) 396–8 265–6; management rights clauses
management relations 171; social central bank 268 4; simplification 421
sciences 47, 56; takeover code centralized bargaining 410, 413; collective bargaining 117–8, 139,
299; trade union morphology 189; negotiation levels 413 406–19; coverage 643;
unions 171; work-life balance 64; centralized negotiators 413 decentralization 414–5; decline 4;
work organization 171 centralized wage setting: Scala feminism 17; free 276;
British Universities Industrial Mobile model of: Italy 652 international 8, 340–1; laws 408;
Relations Association change: catastrophic model 81; macroeconomic outcomes 412–3;
(BUIRA) 38 endogenous models 81–2; product markets 126; structural
Brough, Ian 72–3 exogenous models 79–80; components 3–4; structure 406–7;
BUIRA. see British Universities stakeholder regimes 361–4; structure and power 408–9;
Industrial Relations Association systems thinking 78–9; technical structure determinants 407–8;
(BUIRA) 79–80, 175–6 structure future 415; structure
Bundesbank 268, 276 Change to Win Federation 204 measurement 413–4; transnational
bundling 422 Chartered Institute of Personnel and structures 415–6
bureaucratic-civil service model Development (CIPD) 53 collective labor law 297
308–9 childcare leave 524 collective labor relations: corporate
bureaucratization 194 Chile: EPL 653; working time 518 governance and labor law
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) China: competition 117–8; 299–300; employee
598–9 developmental state 274; representatives information and
Bush, George 321 economic performance 646; IR consultation 297–8; worker
business case 21; unionism 203 climate 562; poverty 574; skill representation and corporate
Business Council of Australia 239 formation 610; transmission belt governance 295–300
business performance: HR trade union 274; wage-setting 645 Collectivism and Long Waves
practices 5; new IR 629–30 choice-makers 13 (Kelly) 10
business-process model 309 CIO. see Congress of Industrial collusion: product markets 116
business schools: social sciences Organizations (CIO) common law 288
59–60 CIPD. see Chartered Institute of communism 64
Personnel and Development community 191
(CIPD) company level bargaining 413
CAC. see Central Arbitration Citizens’ Advice Bureaux 601 compensating differentials theory
Committee (CAC) citizenship: industrial 270–1 454, 464
calculations 175 civil law: French and German compensation 317–9
Canada: absenteeism 600; collective models 289–90 competition 117–8; international 119
bargaining coverage 643; Civil Service Reform Act of 1978: Competitive Advantage Through
employer density 232; employer Title VII 321 People 483
organizations 229; gender civil systems: career-based, competitive markets: imperfectly
inequality 579, 582; grievance department based 318 495–6
mediation 452; high performance classic economic theory 533 conceptual tools 183–4
organizations 162; multi- classic unionism 215 concertation model 263
employer bargaining 239; strikes clients 71 concertive control: rational
599; ULP 397–8; unemployment climate 552–3; aggregation issues control 428
653; union investments 628; 550; analysis level 549; case study conduct: codes 340–1
wage-setting 645; working hours analysis 557–8; culture 550–1; Confederation of British Industry
516; work intensification 429 dimensions 554–5; human (CBI) 601
Canadian Auto Workers union resources context 556; input configurational approach: high
(CAW) 428 variables 555–62; issue specific performance model 153–4
capitalism 129–48, 144; bargaining 552; job satisfaction 549–50; conflict: fear 381; industrial 141
structure 137–8; IR institutions longitudinal case study analysis conflict at work: context 592–3; data
135–6; managed 134; market 134; 557–9; organizational concept problems 598; dynamics 596;
modern trajectories 275–7; state 549–50; organizational context Europe 600–2; industrial action
134; training and welfare 555; organizational models 551; 595–6; Marxism 591–2; North
regimens 136; varieties 76–7, organizational structure 555–6; America 598–600; parameters
136–7; wage inequality 136 outcomes 556–7; performance 589–91; pluralism 592; regulation
Capitalist Diversity and Change 552; quantitative analysis 557; 596–7; resource allocation 591–2;
(Crouch) 77 utility 558–61; volatility 550 strikes 597–8; theorizing 591–2;
capitalist economies: institutional Clinton, William 320 types and forms 593–4
embeddedness 10; types 134 CME. see Coordinated Market conflicting interests 104–5
Caribbean 574 Economies (CME) conflict resolution 447–68, 588–605;
case studies 172, 178; analysis Coarse Theorem 648, 655 availability vs. use 464;
557–8 codes of conduct 340–1 employment relationship conflict
case study: longitudinal 557–9 Codetermination Commission sources 447–8
catastrophic model 81 (1998) 299 Congress of Industrial Organizations
CAW. see Canadian Auto Workers coercive rule-making 62 (CIO) 191–3, 213
union (CAW) cognitive approach 62 Connect 191, 200
INDEX 661

conservatism 194 corporatist trade unions 274 discrimination: employment 449,


Conservative People’s Party cost economics: transaction 177 451–2
(ÖVP) 145 Council of Europe 531 dismissed employees:
construct validity 173, 176 craft unions 191 reinstatement 460
consultancy unionism 216 craft vs. industrial debate 191 displacement theory 455
consumer campaigns: product Creating a Government that Works dissatisfaction 533
market globalization 126 Better and Costs Less 320 distrust: quality circles 427; self-
consumption expenditure: critical employment relationship 104 managed teams 427; union
governance 311 critical model: employment formation 380
contact extension law 407 relations 93 diversity management: gender
contemporary employment relations: critical theory 102 inequality 583–4
outcomes 532 cross-national diversity: state 262–4 DoD. see Department of Defence
contestation 263 Crouch, Colin 77 (DoD)
context: sensitivity 184; cultural approach 62 domestic competition 408
specificity 184 customers 71 Donovan Commission 172
context-based human resource cyclical approach: direct Dunlop Commission 172
theory (CBHRT) 164 participation 436
contingency approach: high Czech Republic: working time 518 earnings: gross hourly 493
performance model 153–4 econometric techniques 174
contingent bundles: high economic context 62; employment
performance model 155–6 data availability 175–6
relationship conflict 448
contingent work arrangements data sources 178–9 economic development 274
471–90; attitudes 480; decentralization: bargaining 171 economic efficiency 635
consequences 478–9; defined decentralized collective bargaining economic evidence: product markets
471–2; direct-hire temporaries structures 407 121–4
473; forces driving 476–8; future decent work 575–6 economic globalization 307
483–4; high performance work decision making. see also Choice- economic growth 276
systems 483–4; independent makers: Germany 441 economic performance: variation
contractors 473–4; motivation decision-making: international 641–2; variation among countries
480, 482; psychological contracts actors 326–7; WERS 542 645–6
481; relational 481–2; security decision-making process: economics 56; labor 9; national
481; social comparison 481; stakeholder regimes 359 performance 8; neoclassical 635
spillover 484; vs. standard work decommodification 261, 269, 272–3 economic strike 597
arrangements 475–6; structural deductive research 172, 179 economic theory: classic 533
differences 474–5; temporary- demand-control model: work economies: capitalist 10, 134
help staffing firm arrangements control 542 economists: heterodox 9
472–3; theoretical perspective demand management 268 economy: global 273; politics 10;
480–2; transaction-based 481; democracy 194; industrial 48 postindustrial 54; regulated 616;
unexpected consequences 484; democracy vs. oligarchy: trade state 271–3
unionization 477, 484–6; unions 12 EEC. see European Economic
volition 482 Denmark: decentralized bargaining Community (EEC)
contract 315–6. see also 413; employer organizations 227, efficiency theory 464
Employment contract; limited 235; EPL 643; industrial conflict effort-reward models 535
term 581; private 48; 141; job satisfaction 536; skill egoist employment relationship
psychological 481–2; seasonal formation 610, 614–5; trade 102–3
473; social 48; temporary 651 unions 614–5 egoist model: employment
contrat de travail 290 dense networks 198–9 relations 93
control: employee interests 96–7 Department of Defence (DoD): new egoist theory 102–3
convergence hypothesis 130 personnel system 321 Egypt: working time 518
converging production systems 130 Department of Homeland Security elections: NLRB 176
coordinated bargaining 4 (DHS): new personnel system 321 election units 406–7
coordinated market economies 8 depression 533 elite: dominance 101
Coordinated Market Economies deregulation 19 empiricism 47
(CME) 129, 133, 264, 435, 437–8; developmental state 273–4, 274 employability 268–9
vs. LME 270–1; substantive DHS. see Department of Homeland employees 94–5; corporate board
employment rights 266–7; union Security (DHS) 298; equity and voice 95–6;
density 137; unions 135–43; wage direct-hire temporaries: contingent fulfillment and social identity 96;
bargaining 143 work arrangements 473 involvement 63, 434–46, 436–7,
coordinated market systems 296, 299 direct-hire temporary workers 481–2 437–8; power and control 96–7;
corporate board: employee direct participation 434–46; cyclical professional organization 476;
membership 298 approach 436; evolutionary public 265; reinstatement 460;
corporate governance and labor law: approach 436; forms and representatives 297–8;
collective labor relations 299–300 theoretical frameworks 435–6; satisfaction 534; survival and
corporate strategy 10 sociological approach 436 income 94–5; working time 521–3
corporatism 8, 12–3, 263, 275; vs. disappearing inverse U 653–4 employee share ownership plans
bargaining structure 407; disciplinary backgrounds 174 (ESOP) 19, 435, 439, 648
economic growth 276; quality of disciplinary influences: IR 9–10 employer 97–8; peak organization
life 407–8; rise, decline, revival disciplinary structure: Britain 46; 228; power and control 97–8;
275–7 United States 46 profit maximization 97–8;
corporatist arrangements 130 discourse: postmodern emphasis 107 stakeholder value 98–9;
662 INDEX

employer (continued) endogenous models 81–2 fair wage hypothesis 501


state 264–5; union formation 382, end-users 71 family-friendly work practices
388–90 enforcement 371 63, 524
employer density 232; determinants engineering: scientific 37 fear: of conflict 381; of
232–3; measurement 239 engineering consultancy 165 reprisal 381
employer organizations 225–40; enthusiasm 533 Federal Mediation and Conciliation
activities 226–30; collective environmental processes 72 Service (FMCS): US 452
bargaining 228; interest EOI. see export-oriented Federal Service Labor Management
representation 226–7; industrialization (EOI) Relations Statute (FSLMRS) 321
membership domains and epistemological traditions 46–7 feminism 16–8, 104; collective
hierarchical differentiation 233–4; EPL. see employment protection bargaining 17; theory 102
multi-employer bargaining and legislation (EPL) financial institutions:
membership 230–3; service EPOC. see European Participation in international 329
activities 229–30; structure Organizational Change (EPOC) financial measures: high
233–5; system 234; unit of survey performance model 152
membership legal effects 235–6 equality 572–87; international 573–6 Finland: centralized bargaining 413;
employment: fairness 95; global Equal Pay Act 504 employer organizations 227, 235;
relationship 8; long-term vs. equal pay audits 504 extension practices 233; industrial
ongoing 472; ongoing vs. long- equity: employee interests 95–6 conflict 141; job insecurity 539;
term employment 472; ERS. see employment relations work-life balance 64
psychological fulfillment 96; system (ERS) fixed-term: workers 474
public 313; governance 310; ESOP. see employee share fixed-term workers 474
regulation 260–2; unions 628 ownership plans (ESOP) flexibility: regulated 521
employment-at-will 102–3 ethical trading audits 126 flexible work practices 518; high
employment conflict resolution ethics 5 performance model 155
456–7; future directions 461–2; ethnicity: minimum wage protection flextime 524
grievance procedure and 580–1; union formation 385 FMCS. see Federal Mediation and
organizational performance ethnography 175, 179; unions 385 Conciliation Service (FMCS)
460–1; grievance procedure EU. see European Union (EU) focus groups 178
dynamics 456–8; post-grievance Eurobarometer surveys 533, 535 formal institutions 8
settlement outcomes 458 Europe: aging healthcare needs 307; FPO. see Freedom Party (FPO)
employment contract 289; laissez-faire legal structure 117; fractional bargaining 197
alternatives 294–5; conceptual poverty 574 frame of reference 104–5, 174;
evolution and change 290–5; European Charter of Fundamental defined 93–4
economic dismissals 292–4; Rights 297 France: collective agreements 266;
historical emergence 287–8; shifts European Community Household collective bargaining coverage
290–2; unfair dismissal Survey 536 643; corporatism 276; economic
legislation 292 European Directive on Working performance 646; employer
employment discrimination 451–2; Time 518 organizations 232; 35 hour work
litigation 449 European Economic Community week 519, 520; job insecurity
Employment in Europe 295 (EEC) 331 539; skill formation 606; union
employment law: collective European Employment Strategy 269 density 316; union density
agreements 4 European Participation in decline 137; unionization 233;
employment practices: high Organizational Change (EPOC) union-management relations 520;
commitment 252–3 survey 435 working time 520
employment protection legislation European Union (EU) 325, 339, 346; Fraser Institute: economic freedom
(EPL) 643, 648 collective bargaining coverage index 641
employment relations 533; choices 643; working time 518 Free Agent Nation (Pink) 478
246; critical model 93; egoist European Working Time free collective bargaining 276
model 93; equitable outcomes Directive 516 freedom: employment relations
101; freedom and rule of law European Works Council (EWC) 63, 100–1
100–1; interest compatibility 351–2; national developments Freedom Party (FPO) 144–5
101–2; job satisfaction 534–6; 352–4 free enterprise zones 274
legal framework 284–304; evolutionary approach 436 Freeman-Lazear model 649
pluralist model 93; regulations EWC. see European Works Council From Red Tape to Results (1993):
100; spatial dimension 10; state (EWC) Creating a Government that
interests 100–1; theories 102; exit-voice-loyalty theory 454, 459 Works Better and Costs
traditional: being 531–2; unitarist exogenous models 79–80 Less 320
model 93; values, ideologies, and expectations theories 535 FSLMRS. see Federal Service Labor
frames of reference 92–112 explanatory models 11 Management Relations Statute
employment relations conflict export-oriented industrialization (FSLMRS)
453–4; conflict resolution 447–8; (EOI) 274 fulfillment: employee interests 96
grievance procedures 453–4; extension practices 233 Future of Worker-Management
solutions 449–50 external fit 155–6 Relations 172
employment relations system (ERS) external validity 173
75–6 gender: equality 5–6; minimum
employment rights: substantive face theory 102 wage protection 580–1;
266–7 factor analysis 174 participation rates 580–1;
employment standards: government fairness: employment 95 pay gap 12; unfair dismissal 464;
lobbying 126 fair wage-effort model 501 union formation 386
INDEX 663

gender inequality 579–80, 582; Great Depression 409 History of Trade Unionism (Webb)
conceptualizing 581–5; diversity Greece: union density 137; working 38, 58, 260
management 583–4; negative hours 541 Holland: job insecurity 539; job
duties vs. positive action 582–3; grievances: mediation 452; satisfaction 536
pay inequality 579–80; work and procedures 449–51, 453–4, homeland security 321
family issues 584 456–8; vs. quitting 454; work hospital mortality rates 155
General Agreement on Tariffs and attendance 464 hourly earnings: gross 493
Trade (GATT) 329, 339, 414–5 gross hourly earnings 493 HPWO. see high performance work
General Motors 439 GUF. see Global Union Federation organizations (HPWO)
geography: social 10 (GUF) HPWS. see high performance work
Germany: apprenticeships 608; system (HPWS)
capitalism 137; central bank 268; Haiti: labor market freedom 641 HRM. see human resource
1998 Codetermination Hancock Committee 172 management (HRM)
Commission 299; collective Harris-Todaro model of human capital: scientific
agreements 266; corporate board unemployment and migration 646 engineering 37
employee membership 298; Harvard Labor and Work Life human dignity 95
corporatism 276; decision making Program: GLS 641 humanized Taylorism 439
441; economic performance 646; HCM. see high commitment human resource management
employer organizations 227, 229, management (HCM) (HRM) 13, 59–61, 62, 171, 241;
233, 236; epistemological healthcare needs: aging 307 best practices 65; Britain 171;
traditions 46; 35 hour work week healthy lifestyle: worker well- business performance 5; new
520; Humboldtian reforms 46; being 531 realism 13; personal development
industrial sociologists 42; heterodox economists 9 479; trends 316–9; US 156
institutional histories 41–2; hierarchy 448 human resources: context 556
intellectual traditions 43; internal high commitment employment Humboldtian reforms: Germany 46
labor markets 300; job insecurity practices 252–3 Hungary: skill formation 606
539; job satisfaction 536; labor high commitment management hybrid public-private entity 308
market freedom 641; liberal and (HCM) 151 Hyman, Richard 72–3
coordinated market economies high involvement management hypothetico-deductive
441–2; liberalism 48; political (HIM) 151, 624 approach 172
traditions 47–8; positivism 48; high performance management 160;
production systems 441; quasi- assessment 158; importance IBEW. see International
public firms 48; regulated 159–60; institutional/cultural Brotherhood of Electrical Workers
economy 616–7; sectoral links context 160–1; issues 158–65; (IBEW)
612; skill formation 608, 614–5; methodological issues 164–5; ICD. see Information and
social contracts 48; state 262; model diffusion 158–9; mutual Consultation Directive (ICD)
temporary contracts 651; trade gains 161; social architecture 163; ICFTU. see International
unions 42, 614–5; union density supply chain 160; transmission Confederation of Free Trade
132, 316; work councils 297, mechanisms 162; underpinning Unions (ICFTU)
347–51; working hours 541 theory 163–4 identity: social 96
Gesamtmentall 236 high performance model: ideology 73; defined 93–4
Gini coefficients 651 approaches 153–5; best practice/ IFCTU. see International Federation
global economy: vs. social best fit 153–4; configurational of Christian Trade Unions
models 273 approach 153–4; contingency (IFCTU)
global employment relationship 8 approach 153–4; contingent IFI. see international financial
globalization 193; product markets bundles 155–6; definition and institutions (IFIs)
126; state capacity 277–9 context 150–3; external fit 155–6; IFTU. see International Federation
global labor market institutions financial measures 152; flexible of Trade Unions (IFTU)
640–55 work practices 155; historical IG Metall 442
Global Labor Survey (GLS): context 152–3; internal fit 155–6; ILE. see Institutional Labor
Harvard Labor and Work Life lean production 151; management Economics (ILE)
Program 641 150–1; performance 151–2; profit ILO. see International Labour
Global Public Management 152; terminology 150; TQM 151; Organization (ILO)
Revolution (Kettl) 319 universal bundles 155–6; import substitution (IS) 274
Global Union Federation (GUF) universalistic approach 153–4; IMVP. see International Motor
193, 330, 341 universal practices 155–6; Vehicle Program (IMVP)
GLS. see Global Labor Survey universal super-bundles 157–8 incentive pay setting 499
(GLS) high performance paradigm 149–69 income: employee interests 94–5
Gore, Albert 320 high performance work income inequality 139
go-slows 595 organizations (HPWO) 161 independent contractors: contingent
governance: consumption high performance work system work arrangements 473–4
expenditure 311; dimensions 308; (HPWS) 5, 150–1, 420–33, 435, India: competition 117–8; skill
functions 310; outsourcing or 442, 624; contingent work formation 610
contracting 315–6; privatization arrangements 483–4; critiques individualism: market 271–2
312–5; public sector employment 427–8; developments 423–4; individual working time accounts
310; size trends 309–10 industry generalizability 425–7; 349–50
government lobbying: employment union effects 424–5; worker inductive research 172, 179
standards 126 impact 423–4 industrial citizenship 270–1
government regulations: state HIM. see high involvement industrial conflict 141
264–71 management (HIM) industrial democracy 48
664 INDEX

Industrial Democracy (Webb) 38 integrative approach 296 International Trade Union


Industrialism and Industrial Man integrative ideology 72–3 Confederation (ITUC) 331
(Kerr) 72, 79, 85, 129, 258 integrative theory 75 international trade unions 8;
industrialization: export- intellectual traditions 43 difficulties 335–6; political self-
oriented 274 interdisciplinary research 176–7 interest 335
industrial psychology 37 internal fit: high performance model interpersonal networks 197
industrial relations (IR) 1–32; 155–6 interviewing 175
agency model 13–4; broadening internal labor markets 300 investment: unions 628
scope 171; business performance Internal Revenue Service (IRS) 474 investments: unions 628
623–39; changing problems internal validity 173 IOE. see International Organization
171–2; cross-national differences international: unions 334 of Employers (IOE)
635; defined 623–4; definition and international actors: analysis 326; IR. see industrial relations (IR)
scope 2–3; disciplinary influences decision-making 326–7; defined IRAA. see Industrial Relations
9–10; distinct field 184; 326; governance 327–8; Association of America (IRAA)
epistemological traditions 46–7; international regulation 325–45 Ireland: bargaining 138; CME 144;
explanatory models 11; flat world International Brotherhood of collective labor law 297;
635–6; history 35–52; Electrical Workers (IBEW) 191 economic performance 646;
institutional models 11–2; levels international collective bargaining 8, employer organizations 227, 235;
6–8; management strategy 340–1 LME 144
241–57; measurement 634–5; IRS. see Internal Revenue Service
international competition 119
methodological issues 625–6; (IRS)
International Confederation of Free
organizational model 12–3; IS. see import substitution (IS)
Trade Unions (ICFTU) 193, 331,
outcomes 5–6; political traditions ISSP. see International Social
339, 341
47–8; practices 44; processes 3–5; Survey Programme (ISSP)
scientific traditions 44–5; scope international equality 573–6
International Federation of Christian Isuzu 427–8
184; societal models 11; state Italy: capitalism varieties 136–7;
258–83; state of flux 171–2; Trade Unions (IFCTU) 331
International Federation of Trade corporatism 276; corporatist
system and change 69–91; theory arrangements 130; economic
and explanation 9–10; university Unions (IFTU) 330–1
international financial institutions performance 646; employer
structures 45–6 organizations 229, 235; industrial
Industrial Relations Association of (IFIs) 329
international framework agreements conflict 141; multi-employer
America (IRAA) 36 bargaining 239; union density
industrial relations-due process 340–1
internationalism 326 316; union density decline 137;
theory 454–5 wage-setting 645
Industrial Relations Systems International Labour Organization
(ILO) 101, 327, 328, 341; core ITS. see International Trade
(Dunlop) 69–70 Secretariats (ITS)
industrial sociologists 42 conventions 338; influence 329
International Metalworkers’ ITUC. see International Trade Union
industrial unions 370 Confederation (ITUC)
Industrial Workers of the World 193 Federation 339, 515
industry evolution: phases 213 International Monetary Fund 329
inelastic labor demand 408–9 International Motor Vehicle Program Japan: aging healthcare needs 307;
inequality 576; future 585; low pay (IMVP): MIT 422 collective bargaining coverage
577–8; between top and bottom International Motor Vehicle 643; company and plant level
576–7 Project 178 bargaining 413; decentralized
information: social processing 385 international organization: collective bargaining structures
Information and Consultation effectiveness 337; instruments 407; economic performance
Directive (ICD) 352–4 and outcomes 337–8; law and 645–6; ESOP 435; gender
Information and Consultation of labor standards 337–8; member inequality 579; inter-firm
Employees Directive of 2002: information 337; motives and networks 611; internal labor
(ICE) 297 constraints 331–3 markets 300; IR climate 562; job
information technology 193 International Organization of satisfaction 536; lean production
injustice: union formation 381 Employers (IOE) 329 130; lean production plant 428–9;
insecurity: job 534, 538–9 international regulation 327; liberal and coordinated market
insider-oriented market systems 299 bodies 8; international actors economies 442; management style
institutionalism: new 62 325–45 and typologies 245; regulated
Institutional Labor Economics International Social Survey economy 616; skill formation
(ILE) 56 Programme (ISSP) 535 608; social expenditures to net
institution-centered approaches international system: actors and national income 643; stakeholder
132–5 institutions 328–9; codes of regimes 363; TQM 442; union
institutions: affect outcomes 648–9; conduct 340–1; employers’ density decline 137; union profits
complementarities 437; cultural associations and multinational 628; wage-setting 644; welfare
cognitive approach 62; corporations 329–30; future state 269; work hours calculation
embeddedness 10; formal 8; 341–2; non-governmental reference period 519; working
histories 35–42; improving organizations (NGO) 331–2; time 518
outcomes 649–50; models 11–2; regional dimension 331–2; states JIT. see just-in-time (JIT) system
outcomes 650–1; pillars 62; and intergovernmental jobs: characteristics 383–4;
process approach 62; theory 61–2; organizations 328–9; voluntary insecurity 534, 538–9, 539;
variance approach 62 measures 340–1 movement between countries 119;
Institutions and Organizations International Trade Secretariats rotation 155; satisfaction 534–6,
(Scott) 61–2 (ITS) 330, 341 536; employment relations 534–6
INDEX 665

joint labor-management committees employment rights 266–7; union Mediation Research and Education
560 decline 144; union density Project (MREP) 452
Jordan: working time 518 137–43; unions 135–6; wage Mediterranean economies (ME) 133,
journals: change 179–83; changing bargaining 143 136–7; bargaining 138; collective
preferences 175; research liberal model 131 bargaining 139; income inequality
methods 183 life satisfaction: job satisfaction 535 139; industrial conflict 141
juridical subordination 290 limited term contract 581 membership: employer
justice: organizations 177; linear regression analysis 174 organizations 233–4
procedural 177; workplace 635 litigation: employment mental health 530
just-in-time (JIT) system 157 discrimination 449 Michigan Organizational
livret 289 Assessment Package (MOAP) 553
Kerr, Clark 72 LME. see Liberal Market micro-organizational behavior 177
Keynesianism 267–8 Economies (LME) Microsoft Corporation 474
Korea: company and plant level lobbying: employment standards 126 migration: Harris-Todaro model 646
bargaining 413; decentralized locatio conductio 289–90 militancy: workplace 8
collective bargaining structures London School of Economics mini-mill strategy: human resources
407; high performance (LSE) 38 strategy 422
management 160; IR climate 562; longevity: work control 542 minimum wage 578; protection
skill formation 606; structural longitudinal case study: IR climate 580–1
adjustment programmes 274 557–9 MIT. see Massachusetts Institute of
long-term employment: vs. ongoing Technology (MIT)
labor: demand 418, 648; division employment 472 MNC. see multinational companies
and control 104; economics 9; low pay: inequality 577–8 (MNC)
geography 58; inelastic demand LSE. see London School of MOAP. see Michigan Organizational
408–9; new 63 Economics (LSE) Assessment Package (MOAP)
Labor and Employment Relations mobilizing model: trade unions
Association (LERA) 36 Machine that Changed the World 196–7
labor institutions: advanced (Womack) 422, 441 model diffusion: high performance
economies 644; importance macroeconomic management 267–8 management 158–9
646–7; variation 641–2 macroeconomic outcomes: Model Employment Termination
labor law 285–7, 390–1; collective bargaining 412–3 Act 292
Anglophone 48; collective 297; Malaysia: working time 518 modern labor market: origins 287–8
transition 300–1; union density managed capitalism 134 monopoly: pay setting 495–6
391; US vs. Canadian 390 management. see also High mortality rates: hospital 155
labor management: business performance management; motivation: contingent work
strategy 252 Human resource management; arrangements 480, 482
labor market 261; freedom 641; Total Quality Management MREP. see Mediation Research and
institutions 640–55; internal 300; (TQM): decisions 26–7; demand Education Project (MREP)
modern 287–8; regulation 296; 268; diversity 583–4; high Mueller-Jentsch, Walther 42
structure 267–8 commitment 151; high multi-employer bargaining 115, 116,
labor relations: collective 295–300; involvement 151, 624; labor 252; 239, 410; employer organizations
state as employer 316 macroeconomic 267–8; personnel 230–3
labor standards: national statutory 59, 629; rights clauses 4; role 171; multi-method research 178
126–7; worker representation style and typologies 244–8; styles multinational companies (MNC)
295–6 246–7; Taylorist scientific 245; 277, 325, 330, 339, 341
laissez-faire state 117, 271–2 working time 521–3 multivariate analysis 179
Latin America: corporatism 275; managerialists 37 mutual gains 421, 438–9
poverty 574; structural adjustment managers: attitudes 247–8; corporate Mutual Gains Enterprise (Kochan
programmes 274; tariffs 274 strategy and structure 250–2; and Osterman) 421
laws. see also Labor law: collective strategic choice 248–50
bargaining 408; common 288; markets. see also Product markets: NAFTA. see North American Free
contact extension 407; capitalism 134; ideals 104; Trade Area (NAFTA)
employment protection 643, 648; individualism 271–2 National Association of
labor standards 337–8 market systems: coordinated 296, Employment Managers 36
lean production 130, 151, 157; plant 299; insider-oriented 299 National Insurance Act 1946, 289
428–9 Marshall Plan 335 national knowledge systems 47
leave: childcare 524 Martin v. New York Life Insurance National Labor Relations (or
legislation. see Laws Co 289 Wagner) Act of 1935, 295,
legitimation: state 262 Marxism 16, 39, 57, 104; alternative 362, 363
Lend Lease 441 65; Britain 43; conflict at work National Labor Relations Board
LERA. see Labor and Employment 591–2; Germany 47 (NLRB) 232; elections 176;
Relations Association (LERA) Marxist Introduction (Hyman) 39 laissez-faire state 272
liberal and coordinated market Massachusetts Institute of National Performance Review
economies 438–9 Technology (MIT): IMVP 422 (NPR) 320
liberalism 48 master-servant model 288 National Security Personnel
Liberal Market Economies (LME) Matsushita 443 System 321
129, 133, 264, 435, 437–8; mature phase: trade union strategy national statutory labor standards
bargaining 137; vs. CME 270–1; 214–8 126–7
laissez-faire state 272; vs. laissez- ME. see Mediterranean economies national vs. international 326–7
faire state 271; substantive (ME) need fulfillment theory 535
666 INDEX

negotiated wage pressures 412 coefficients 651; job insecurity overtime bans 595
negotiating units 406–7 539; job satisfaction 536 ÖVP. see conservative People’s
negotiations 371; regulatory 370; NPM. see New Public Management Party (ÖVP)
tripartite 413 (NPM) model ownership: employee 648
negotiators: centralized 413 NPR. see National Performance
neoclassical economics 635 Review (NPR) pacification: state 262
neoclassical labor market theory NUMMI. see New United Motor paid professional organizers 201
494–5; criticisms 495 Manufacturing Inc. (NUMMI) Panel Study of Income
neoclassical orthodoxy 9 Dynamics 176
neo-corporatist stakeholder regime OECD. see Organization for paper-tiger unionism 215–6
359, 371; decline 360–1 Economic Cooperation and partial gift exchange model 501
neo-liberalism: normative Development (OECD) partisanship 144
orientation 18–9 Office of Management and Budget partnership unionism 216
Netherlands: bargaining 138; (OMB) 321 Patient Care Associate (PCA) 426–7
corporatism 275, 277; employer oil shocks 448 pay. see also Wages: disparities 494;
organizations 230, 232; flexible oligarchy 194 equal 504; incentive 499;
working 518; trade union oligopoly: pay setting 495–6; inequality 577–8; performance-
morphology 189; union density product markets 409–10 related 318–9, 499–500; union
132, 137; work hours calculation OMB. see Office of Management formation 384
reference period 519 and Budget (OMB) Payne v. Western & Atlantic
New Deal 56, 57, 247 OMC. see Open method of Railroad 289
new industrial relations: business coordination (OMC) pay setting 491–512, 498–9, 501–2;
performance 629–30 ongoing employment: vs. long-term fairness, norms and reciprocity
new institutionalism 62 employment 472 500–1; imperfectly competitive
new labor 63 open macro-economy: Nordic markets 495–6; indeterminacy
New Public Management (NPM) Model 649 495; labor contract uniqueness
model 309 open method of coordination 497–8; monopoly or oligopoly
(OMC) 340 495–6; monopsony and
new realism: HRM 13
Open Society and its Enemies oligopsony 497; neoclassical
new right 57, 63, 74 labor market theory 494–5;
(Popper) 65
new trading countries 117–8 ordre public social 290, 294 neoclassical labor market theory
New United Motor Manufacturing organic phase: trade union criticisms 495; oligopoly 495–6;
Inc. (NUMMI) 439 strategy 214 patterns 493–4; performance
New Zealand: bargaining 138; Organising Academy 201 499–500; segmentation and
collective agreements 266; Organization for Economic discrimination 503–4; state as
collective bargaining coverage Cooperation and Development employer 504–5; state as regulator
643; company and plant level (OECD) 328, 339, 341; 505–6; unions 496
bargaining 413; decentralized bargaining coordination 414; PCA. see Patient Care Associate
collective bargaining structures bargaining coordination index (PCA)
407; economic performance 646; 138; bargaining structures 414; peer support: unions 385
employer organizations 227, 229, Business and Industry Advisory PEO. see Professional Employee
230; engineering consultancy 165; Committee 330; collective Organization (PEO)
inequality 576; laissez-faire state bargaining 139; core government performance: climate 552
271; unemployment 653; wage- functions 312; Declaration on performance-related pay (PRP)
setting 645; working time 518 International Investment and 318–9, 499–500
NGO. see non-governmental Multinational Enterprises 338; personal human resource
organizations (NGO) employment protection legislation development 479
Nigeria: working time 518 140; income inequality 139, 140; personal interests 175
NLRB. see National Labor Relations industrial conflict 141; personal utility 95
Board (NLRB) standardized unemployment rates person-environment fit theory 535
non-governmental organizations 142; union density 138 personnel management 59. see also
(NGO) 331–2 organizations: characteristics 387; Human resource management
Nordic Model of the open macro- justice 177, 454; models 551; (HRM)
economy 649 performance 561; punishment- personnel system 321
normative orientation 14–21; industrial discipline theory 455 Pink, Daniel 478
challenge and critique 16–7; neo- organizers: paid professional 201 plant level bargaining 413
liberalism 18–9; pluralist organizing-driven unions 200 pluralism 74, 102; conflict at work
responses 20–1 Organizing Institute 201 592; employment relationship 93,
North America: company and plant organizing model: trade unions 104; fragmentation 263;
level bargaining 413; lean 196–7 industrialism 263; normative
production plant 428–9; organizing works 201 orientation 20–1
management style and outcomes 650–1; contemporary PNR. see Programme for National
typologies 245 employment relations 532; Recovery (PNR)
North American Free Trade Area employment relations 101; political economy theory 102
(NAFTA) 6, 331, 339 improving 649–50; international political parties: welfare state
Norway: centralized bargaining 413; organization 337–8; IR 5–6; IR development 132
contingent work arrangements: climate 556–7; macroeconomic politics 56–7, 143–4; beliefs and
unionization 477; employer 412–3; post-grievance settlement affiliations 382; economy 10;
organizations 227, 233, 234; 458; worker 531–2 isolation 263; self-interest 335;
father’s paternal leave 519; Gini outsourcing 308, 315–6 strike 597–8; traditions 47–8
INDEX 667

poor: working 574, 575 QES. see Quality of Employment Roosevelt, Franklin 56
Popper, Karl 65 Survey (QES) rule-making: coercive 62
portfolio: unions 217 qualitative research 173–4 Russia: free-market economy 618;
Portugal: decentralized bargaining quality circles 155. see also Total job satisfaction 536
413; employer organizations 229, Quality Management (TQM);
234, 235; industrial conflict 141; distrust 427 sabotage 595
job insecurity 539; union quality control circles (QCC) 442 SAGE Handbook of Industrial
density 137 Quality of Employment Survey Relations: structure 21–6
post-grievance settlement outcomes: (QES) 379 satisfaction: employee 534;
employment conflict resolution quality of life: corporatism 407–8 employees 534; job 522; jobs
effectiveness 458 Quality of Work Life programs 553 534–6; life 535
postindustrial economy 54 quantitative analysis: IR climate 557 Scala Mobile model of centralized
postmodern emphasis: discourse 107 quantitative discourse 177 wage setting: Italy 652
post-war British engineering quantitative research 173–4 Scandinavia: income inequality 139;
industry: weak product market quasi-public firms 48 union density stability 130
competition 125 quit rates 424, 426 scientific engineering: human
poverty 574 quitting: vs. grievances 454 capitol 37
power: employee interests 96–7 scientific traditions 44–5
pragmatism 47 race: minimum wage protection seasonal contract 473
private contracts 48 580–1; union formation 385 Second Industrial Divide (Piore and
private property 48 rational control: concertive Sabel) 421
privatization 315; amounts raise control 428 sectoral agreement 115, 116
314; governance 312–5 RBV. see resource-based view security: contingent work
procedural justice 177 (RBV) arrangements 481
procedural regulation: state 265–6 realism: new 13 selection: state as employer 317–8
process approach: institutions 62 recruitment: state as employer 317–8 self-directed work teams 426
production-based paradigm 71 Red International of Labor self-help 197, 200
production systems: Germany 441 Unions 331 self-managed teams 424;
product markets 113–28; bargaining regressions 174 distrust 427
structure break up 117–20; regulated economy 616 sensitivity 184
bargaining structure competitive regulated flexibility 521 service contract 289
influences 114–6; collective regulations. see also Laws: conflict servicing model: trade unions 196–7
bargaining 126; collusion 116; at work 596–7; employment shop-floor labor-management
economic evidence 121–4; 260–2; employment relations 100; relations 171
globalization 126; international 325–45, 327; Silicon Valley: networks 612; skill
internationalization 119; procedural 265–6; soft vs. hard 4; formation 610
oligopoly 409–10; workplace state 264–71; working time 517–8 Singapore: high performance
relations 124–5 regulatory negotiation 370 management 160; IR climate
professional employee organization reinstatement: dismissed 561–2; working time 518
(PEO) 476 employees 460 skill formation 606–22; competitive
professional organizers: paid 201 reinvention model 309, 319–20 and cooperative relations 611–2;
profits: high performance model rent bargaining: trade unions 123 differences 609–10; firm level
152; maximization 97–8, 648; repetitive strain injuries 428 choices 613–4; products and
unions 627–8 representation: union formation product markets 613; trade unions
profit-sharing plan (PSP) 19, 380–1 614–5; voluntarism and regulation
443, 648 reprisal: fear 381 609–10
Programme for National Recovery research 43–4; analytical levels 176; skill levels 132
(PNR) 144 British institutional histories Sloan Foundation funding: high-
property: private 48 39–41; change evidence 179; commitment workplaces 172
proxy measures 174 deductive 172, 179; design 184–5; Slovakia: multi-employer
PRP. see performance-related pay future 183–4; German bargaining 239
(PRP) institutional histories 41–2; Slovenia: employer density 232;
PSP. see Profit-sharing plan (PSP) inductive 172, 179; institutional employer organizations 232;
psychological contract: contingent histories 35–42; interdisciplinary multi-employer bargaining 239
work arrangements 481; 176–7; journals 183; multi- small and medium-sized enterprises
reciprocity 482 method 178; qualitative 173–4; (SME) 251; management styles
psychological fulfillment 96 quantitative 173–4; traditions 246–7
psychology: industrial 37 170–86; US institutional histories SME. see small and medium-sized
psychometric techniques 174 35–9; variations and national enterprises (SME)
public employees 265 embeddedness 43–4 SMU. see social movement
public employment 313; residence: union formation 385–6 unionism (SMU)
governance 310 resource allocation: conflict at work social architecture: high
public governance: new paradigms 591–2 performance management 163
trends 319 resource-based view (RBV) 163 social comparison: contingent work
public sector proxy product markets Rethinking Industrial Relations: arrangements 481; theory 482
120–1 Mobilization, Collectivism and social contract 48
public services: aging 307 Long Waves (Kelly) 10 social geography 10
retirement practices 525 social identity 96
QCC. see quality control circles right: new 57, 63, 74 social information processing 385
(QCC) Roman law 289 social institution 54–5
668 INDEX

social models: vs. global standards: employment 126; labor System of Industrial Relations in
economy 273 126–7, 295–6, 337–8; national Britain 284
social movements 10; statutory labor 126–7 systems thinking 69–74; causation
organizations 71 standard work arrangements: vs. 72; change models 78–9; critique
social movement unionism contingent work arrangements 70–1; integrative ideology 72–3;
(SMU) 203 475–6 recent thinking 74–8; system
social networks 197 state: accumulation 261–2; vs. civil actors 71–2; system boundaries
social sciences 46–7, 53–68; applied society 260; community 260; 70–1; system outcomes 73–4
61; business schools 59–60; cross-national diversity 262–4;
institutional theory 61–2; IR defined 259; economy 271–3; as Taft-Hartley Act of 1947, 295
interdisciplinary genesis 55–9; employer 264–5; employment Taiwan: high performance
social democratic reform 64–6 relations 100–1; functions 261–2; management 160–1; skill
social state 272–3 government regulations 264–71; formation 609–10
social unionism 390 legitimation 262; macroeconomic takeover code 299
Social Values and Industrial management 267–8; management Tarifautonomie 276
Relations (Hyman and Brough) decisions regulation 26–7; market tariffs 274
72–3 260–2; pacification 262; Tatbestand 290
societal models 11 procedural regulation 265–6; Taylor, Frederick W. 37
Socio Economic Panel 176 substantive employment rights Taylorist scientific management
socioeconomics 10; union 266–7 strategy 245
formation 385 state as employer 305–24; teams: lean production plant 428;
sociological approach: direct compensation 317–9; self-directed work 426; self-
participation 436 environmental contexts 306–7; managed 424, 427; social function
sociological theories: collective governance 307–9; HRM trends 428; work 155; work
action 177 316–9; labor relations and unions organization 426
316; performance management technical change 79–80, 175–6
sociologists: industrial 42
316–7; public governance temporary contract 651
Sociology of Industrial Relations
paradigms 319–20; recruitment temporary-help staffing firm
(Mueller-Jentsch) 42
and selection 317–8 arrangements: contingent work
SOP. see standard operating arrangements 472–3
state capitalism 134
procedures (SOP) temporary workers: demand 476
statistical data 175
Soviet Union: collapse 307; Thailand: high performance
statutory regulation: working time
competition 117–8 management 160; working
517–8
Spain: decentralized bargaining 413; time 518
strategic choice: managers 248–50;
employer organizations 229; Thatcher, Margaret 56, 144, 266
theory 243
industrial conflict 141; limited theft 595
term contracts 581; multi- strategic human resource theory
455–6 theory 9–10, 172; backgrounds 174;
employer bargaining 239; social to ideology 104–5; paradigms 174
expenditures to net national stress 530; work-related 540–1
stressors 533 thinking. see Systems thinking
income 643; temporary contracts Third Way 57
651; union density 137; stress-related illness 542–3; UK 530
strikes 599; conflict at work 597–8; Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
unionization 233; work hours (Esping-Andersen) 131
calculation reference period 519; politics 597–8
structural adjustment Title VII: Civil Service Reform Act
working time 518 of 1978, 321
specialization 448 programmes 274
total quality control (TQC) 442
specificity 184 Subaru-Isuzu 427–8
Total Quality Management (TQM)
Sri Lanka: skill formation 610 subordination 287 63, 151, 155, 157, 423, 426,
stage-models 27 substantive employment rights 440, 442
stakeholder regimes 358–60, 266–7 Toyota 439, 443
358–74, 363; advanced capitalist super unions 192 TQC. see total quality control (TQC)
societies 362–3; change dynamics supply chain: high performance TQM. see Total Quality
364–7; change model 361–4; management 160 Management (TQM)
current discontinuity 366–7; supranational authority 326 Trade Secretariats 193
decision-making process 359, surveys 172; attitudes 178; Trades Union Congress (TUC) 601
370–1; development stages workplace 177, 178 Trade Union Advisory Committee
364–5; economic and social survival: employee interests 94–5 (TUAC) 329, 339
change 363–4; economic and Sweden: corporatist arrangements trade union morphology 189–208;
social stability 362–3; emergency 130; decentralized bargaining configurations 202–3; external
regime 367–8; globalization 413; employer organizations 227, structure 190–3; internal structure
resistance 369; impasse 368–9; 233, 235; labor market freedom 193–6; mobilization 199, 200;
new stakeholders 370; old 641; minimum wage 578; multi- models 196–7; organizing-driven
stakeholders 369–70; stabilizing employer bargaining 239; supply unions 200–2; scope 189;
modern social orders 362–3; ways and demand 268; trade union servicing vs. organizing 199;
forward 369–70 morphology 189; unemployment union crisis 195–203; union goals
stakeholder value: employer 653–4 and strategic choice 190; union
interests 98–9 Switzerland: employer organizations renewal 195–203; union soul and
standardized unemployment 227; EPL 643; job satisfaction union renewal 202–3
rates 142 536; wage-setting 644 trade unions 614–5; challenge
standard operating procedures symbols 62 117–8; comparative analysis
(SOP) 157 system actors 71–2 11–2; democracy vs. oligarchy 12;
INDEX 669

history 57; international 335–6; demographic characteristics flexible working 518; gender
international competition 119; 385–6; influence 384; job inequality 579, 582; grievance
internationalism 334; life cycle characteristics 383–4; macro mediation 452; gross hourly
213–4; mobilizing model 196–7; economic, political, and earnings 493; Health and Safety
organizing model 196–7; rent institutional determinants 393–5; Executive 542–3; high
bargaining 123; servicing model organizer characteristics 387; commitment employment
196–7; worker well-being 543–5 organizing activities 387–8; practices 252–3; hospital
trade union strategy 209–24; organizing process 387–8; pay mortality rates 155; job insecurity
contexts 211–2; economic 384; perceived injustice 381; 539; job satisfaction 536; labor
contexts 211–2; employer political beliefs and affiliations market inequality 576; LME 144;
movement contexts 211–2; mature 382; race 385; residence 385–6; management style and typologies
phase 214–8; organic phase 214; social influences 384–5; 245, 248; minimum wage 578;
renewal crisis 218–9; socioeconomics 385; studies and skill formation 609–10, 615; skill
sociopolitical contexts 211–2; data sets 378; US, Canadian, and levels 132; social expenditures to
strategic choice 209–11; trade UK labor law regimes 396–8; net national income 643; state
union life cycle 213–4; worker voice and representation 380–1; 262; stress-related illness 530,
and labor movement contexts worker voting propensities 542–3; trade unions 615; union
211–2 377–38; working conditions 384; density 316; union investments
trading: ethical 126; new countries work orientations 381–2 628; unionization 477; union-
117–8 Union Image Survey (UIS) 379 management relations 519–20;
traditional employment relations: unionization: boutique 193; classic wage-setting 645; wage subsidies
worker well-being 531–2 215; consultancy 216; contingent 505; work control 542; working
traditions: scientific 44–5 work arrangements 477, 484–6; time 267, 519–20; working time
training regimens: capitalism 136 paper-tiger 215–6; partnership decentralization 521; working
transaction cost economics 177 216; social 390 time duration 515; work
Transfer of Undertakings unions 71, 171. see also Trade intensification 429; work-related
(Protection of Employment) unions; autocratic 194; AWP stress 541
Regulations 2006, 295 629–30, 632–3; CME 135–43; United Motor Manufacturing,
Transformation of American commitment 177; decline 144; Incorporated (UMMI) 461
Industrial Relations (Kochan) density 132, 316, 317; density United Nations (UN) 326
77, 421 stability 130; effects 626; United States (US): aging healthcare
transmission belt trade union 274 employee satisfaction 537; needs 307; collective agreements
tripartite negotiations 413 employment 628; ethnography 266; collective bargaining
tripartite neo-corporatist model 359 385; evolving structures 191–2; coverage 643; common law 288;
TRW 450 firm performance 632–3; firm contingent work arrangements
TUAC. see Trade Union Advisory survival 628; high performance 478; corporatist arrangements
Committee (TUAC) work systems literature 424–5; 130; disciplinary structure 46;
TUC. see Trades Union Congress industrial 370; international 8; economic performance 645–6;
(TUC) investment 628; investments 628; economics 56; employee
LME 135–6; organizing-driven satisfaction 534; employer density
UAW. see United Auto Workers 200; pay setting 496; peer support 232; employer organizations 229;
(UAW) 385; portfolio 217; productivity epistemological traditions 46;
UCATT 192 growth 626; profits 627–8; EPL 643; FMCS 452; gender
Uganda: labor market freedom 641 revitalization 78, 80, 81; super inequality 579, 582; Gini
UIS. see Union Image Survey (UIS) 192; wage effects 648; wage coefficients 651; grievance
UK. see United Kingdom (UK) premium 496; work pressure mediation 452; high commitment
ULP. see unfair labor practices 541–2 employment practices 252–3;
(ULP) Unison 191, 200 industrial democracy 48;
UMMI. see United Motor unitarist model 93, 103 inequality 576; institutional
Manufacturing, Incorporated unitarist theory 102 histories 35–9; job satisfaction
(UMMI) United Arab Emirates: labor market 536; liberal and coordinated
UN. see United Nations (UN) freedom 641 market economies 438–9;
underpinning theory: high United Auto Workers (UAW) 191 liberalism 48; managerial
performance management 163–4 United Kingdom (UK): bargaining strategic choice 248; minimum
unemployment 534; Harris-Todaro 138; CME 144; collective wage 578; organizing-driven
model 646; standardized rates bargaining coverage 643; unions 200; political traditions
142; young people 574 collective labor law 297; company 47–8; positivism 48; pragmatism
unfair dismissal: gender 464; and plant level bargaining 413; 47; private contracts 48; private
legislation 292 Company Level Industrial property 48; public employees
unfair labor practices (ULP) 397–8 Relations Survey 250; conflict at 265; reinvention 319–20; skill
union formation 377–405; work 601; contingent work formation 606–8, 609–10; skill
alternative explanations 380–1; arrangements 477; corporate levels 132; social expenditures to
autonomy 384; bargaining unit strategy and structure 250; net national income 643; steel
size 387; complexity 384; decentralized collective HRM 156; strikes 599; trade
conventional explanations 378–9; bargaining structures 407; union morphology 189; ULP 600;
distrust 380; employer activities declining wages 505; employee union density decline 137; union
388–90; employer practices 382; discrimination 453; employee investments 628; wage-setting
external determinants 382–5; fear satisfaction 534; employer 645; wage subsidies 505; welfare
of conflict 381; fear of reprisal organizations 229, 236; family- state 269; working hours 516, 541
381; gender 386; individual and friendly work practices 524; UNITE-HERE 192, 200
670 INDEX

universal bundles: high performance weak product market competition: working hours 516, 541;
model 155–6 post-war British engineering diversification 514
universalism: labor market industry 125 working poor 574, 575
regulation 296 Webb, Beatrice 38, 101, 172, 260 working time 518; arrangement and
universalistic approach: high Webb, Sidney 38, 101, 172, 260 utilization 516–7; decentralization
performance model 153–4 Weber, Max 40 521; developments 515–6;
universal practices: high welfare: capitalism 136 duration 515–6; individual
performance model 155–6 welfare state 269–70; political 349–50; job satisfaction 522;
universal super-bundles: high parties 132; types 132; VoC management and employees
performance model 157–8 131–2, 135–6 521–3; regulation 517–8;
university structures: IR 45–6 well being: work-related stress statutory regulation 517–8; union-
US. see United States (US) 540–1 management relations 519–20
utilitarianism: Britain 47 WERS. see Workplace Employment work-life balance 63–4, 513–28,
Relation Surveys (WERS) 523–4; managers’ attitudes 247–8
WFTU. see World Federation of work organization 171. see also
validity 173; external 173;
Trade Unions (WFTU) High performance work
internal 173
What Do Unions Do? (Medoff) 162 organizations (HPWO)
value-added unionism (VAU) 203
WIRC. see workplace industrial work organization teams 426
values 62, 175 workplace: justice 635; militancy 8;
relations climate (WIRC)
variance approach: institutions 62 surveys 177, 178
WIRS. see Workplace Industrial/
Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) 129, workplace actors 71
Employee Relations Survey
143–4, 435, 436–7; actor- and Workplace Employment Relation
(WIRS/WERS)
institution-centered approaches Surveys (WERS) 56, 58, 123, 156,
Woolworths 441
132–5; approaches 131–2; 162, 242, 522, 537, 540; decision-
work. see also Alternative work
evidence interpretation 141–2; making 542; interpretation 654;
practices (AWP); Contingent
liberal model 131; school 77–8; universal bundle 160
work arrangements: attendance
social-democratic type 131; Workplace Industrial/Employee
464; conflict 592–600; demands
welfare-state centered approaches Relations Survey (WIRS/
541; flexible practices 155, 518;
131–2, 135–6 WERS) 156
gender inequality 584; hours
VAU. see value-added unionism workplace industrial relations
calculation reference period 519;
(VAU) climate (WIRC) 553–4, 557–8;
intensification 428; orientations
VET. see vocational education and factor analysis 569–71
381–2; pressure 541–2; standard
training (VET) workplace relations: product
vs. contingent work arrangements
Visser scale 145 markets 124–5
475–6
VoC. see Varieties of Capitalism Work, Power and Trust Relations work-related stress: well-being
(VoC) (Fox) 39 540–1
vocational education and training work control 542; demand-control Works Continuation Act 348
(VET) 606. see also Skill model 542; longevity 542 works councils 346–57
formation work councils 297, 347–51 work-setting 533
voice: employee interests 95–6; worker outcomes: worker well-being work system. see High performance
union formation 380–1 531–2 work system (HPWS)
volition: contingent work workers protection vs. good work work teams 155; lean production
arrangements 482 promotion: worker well-being 531 157; self-directed 426
volunteers 197, 296 worker voting propensities: union work-to-rules 595
formation 377–82 World Bank (WB) 329; structural
wages: bargaining 143; centralized worker well-being 529–47; adjustment programmes 274
setting 652; declining 505; collective vs. individual deals World Confederation of Labor
differentials 651; disparities 494; 530; growing interest 529–30; (WCL) 331
drift 410; effects 648; equal 504; healthy lifestyle 531, 532–3; World Federation of Trade Unions
incentive 499; inequality 136, nature 532–3; old vs. new (WFTU) 331
577–8; Italy 652; minimum 578, employment relations 543–5; world strike wave of 1968–1974,
580–1; negotiated pressures 412; traditional employment relations 130
performance-related 318–9, 531–2; work changing nature 530; World Trade Organization (WTO)
499–500; premium 496; subsidies worker outcomes 531–2; workers 326, 328, 339, 341, 414–5
505; union formation 384 protection vs. good work WTO. see World Trade Organization
wage setting. see also pay setting: promotion 531; workforce (WTO)
institutions classification 643–5 changing nature 529–30
War on Want 331 working conditions: union young people: unemployment 574
WB. see World Bank (WB) formation 384
WCL. see World Confederation of Working for the Union (Kelly and Zambia: labor market freedom 641
Labor (WCL) Heery) 196 zero intelligent agents 648

You might also like