You are on page 1of 12

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/233713174

Comparative Study of Agricultural Extension Systems: A Systemic View

Article  in  Outlook on Agriculture · December 2009


DOI: 10.5367/000000009790422133

CITATIONS READS
21 11,620

2 authors:

Hossein Azadi Glen Filson


University of Guelph
312 PUBLICATIONS   5,479 CITATIONS   
50 PUBLICATIONS   429 CITATIONS   
SEE PROFILE
SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

VN PhD View project

PhD Thesis: The Impacts of Industrialization on Farmer’s Livelihoods, Land Use and the Environment in Ethiopia: The Cases of Gelan and Dukem Towns View
project

All content following this page was uploaded by Glen Filson on 21 July 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Comparative study of
agricultural extension
systems
A systemic view
Hossein Azadi and Glen Filson

Abstract: An increasing volume of literature deals with different meanings of the


term ‘extension’ due to the many different agricultural extension systems (AESs) in
use. Acknowledging the diversity of AESs, the authors recognize that there is
usually a bias towards some specific aspect of these interventions that indicates a
need to consider a systemic framework for comparative studies. The main purpose of
this contribution is therefore to identify such a systemic view, which could be
applied to comparative studies of AESs. Three levels of analysis should be
scrutinized for considering a systemic view: micro (institutional), meso (national)
and macro (international). At the most basic level, all AESs are involved in both
intra-actions and interactions of the extension institution. For this reason, the aim
of many studies has been to evaluate the institutional functions of extension
practices. The functions at this lowest level are used to predict not only how
extension professionals think and act, but how they react to their different target
groups. The main question at the micro level is therefore to understand how a
country can reach its agri-rural development goals through extension institutions
and what institutional arrangements and funding trends help to achieve those goals.
At the meso level, the most important considerations are national expectations,
which lead to governmental support for or restrictions on the extension institution.
Socioeconomic conditions and their consequences largely determine what the
extension tasks should be. The main question at this level is why a country needs
extension services, which define the different missions for them in different
countries. Finally, at the macro level of analysis, it is important first to consider
international components and their impact on the level of socioeconomic
development of particular countries and, then, the extension missions. The main
issue at this level is therefore to understand what international forces and
considerations affect the present situation of a country and hence create new
expectations of the extension system.

Keywords: agricultural extension systems; comparative study; systemic view

Dr Hossein Azadi is with the Centre for Development Studies, Faculty of Spatial Sciences, University
of Groningen, PO Box 800, Landleven 1, 9747 AD Groningen, The Netherlands.
E-mail: hos.azadi@gmail.com. Glen Filson is Professor of Capacity Development and Extension at the
School of Environmental Design and Rural Development, University of Guelph, Canada.
E-mail: gfilson@uoguelph.

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4, 2009, pp 337–347 337


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

Many serious efforts have been made to develop the


agricultural sector under the label of ‘extension’, which Table 1. Public sector extension areas likely to be subjected to
traditionally comprises notions of ‘partnership agencies’ change in the next decade.
(Wilson, 1952), ‘learning by doing’ (Kelsey and Hearne,
Area of change Challenge for the next few years
1955), ‘accelerating factors’ (Mosher, 1976),
‘communicational tools’ (Roling, 1979), ‘non-formal The advice itself Complement the focus on agricultural
education’ (Boone, 1989), ‘adult education’ (Rivera, production with attention to rural
income, but with increasing concern
1998a), ‘bridges between scientists and farmers’ (Timmer,
for sustainability of natural resources
1982), ‘transfer of technology’ (Chambers and Ghildyal, and the environment, plus the
1985), ‘transferring knowledge (Roling, 1988) or organization of farmers into relevant
information’ (Umali and Schwartz, 1994), ‘clientele associations.
orientation’ (Tooker, 1987), ‘simulating factors’ (van den
The stakeholders Promote the participation of farmers in
Ban, 1986), ‘persuasive communication’ (Melkote, 1998), extension programme development
‘advisory services’ (Percy, 1999), ‘helping farmers to learn activities (programme planning,
how to organize themselves effectively’ (Azadi and implementation and evaluation), and
Karami, 1999) and ‘policy instruments’ (van den Ban and perhaps widen the present focus on
Hawkins, 1988). This label is then augmented by terms farmers to include the rural poor.
such as: ‘as a part of the Agriculture Knowledge and The source of Complement the present focus on
Information System (AKIS)’ (Roling, 1988), a ‘preparing information agricultural research as the exclusive
approach’ (Patton, 1993), ‘development support source of information with a
communication’ (Melkote, 1998), ‘farmer-led’ capitalization on local knowledge,
public–private dialogue and
(Scarborough et al, 1997), ‘empowering farmers’ (Shahvali
international networking.
and Azadi, 1999a), ‘promoting deprived rural people
participation’ (Oakley and Marsden, 1985; Bayer and Information channels Complement the dominant role of
Bayer, 1994; Pretty et al, 1995; Wilson, 1992; Chambers, face-to-face extension with
information technology, both for
1997) and ‘institutional input’ (Davidson et al, 2001). cost-effective delivery and for
Extension has most recently been termed ‘capacity empowerment of the rural poor.
building’ (Faure and Kleene, 2004), ‘social learning’
(Leeuwis, 2004), ‘customer-demand’ (Rivera and Zijp, Institutional Move from evaluation of performance-
management related extension to result-related
2002), ‘demand-driven’ (Bernet et al, 2001; Gustafson, extension; and facilitate interrelations
2004; Lightfoot, 2004; Rivera and Alex, 2004), ‘demand- coordination of public and private
led’, ‘contracting extension’ (Rivera and Zijp, 2002) and extension services.
‘responsive institution’ (Garforth, 2004). Public
The concept of transfer Shift away from a linear, sequential
agricultural extension services around the world are being model of generation, transfer and
forced to adapt to new funding constraints and a utilization of technology towards a
changing agricultural sector. The global perspective on model that recognizes each
extension is no longer that of a unified public sector stakeholder’s ability to gather and
service, but of a multi-institutional network of knowledge apply new information, and thus shift
and information support for rural people (Swanson and away from a message-oriented and
target-oriented audience approach to
Pehu, 2004). In discussions of what extension really is, concern for the quality of the
there is usually considerable confusion in that current interactions and the role of
practice is not distinguished from ideal practice (Rivera et government in providing a platform
al, 1989). While the most vital element of the extension for those interactions.
process is constituted by objectives (Karami, 1994), the Funding Balance public support for extension
emphasis on various extension objectives differs from with farmers‘ and private
country to country (van den Ban, 1986). The goals, for contributions, whereby government
example, shift from the creation of surpluses for a funding is primarily justified by
metropolitan context only, to providing income- positive externalities, poverty
generating opportunities for small farmers; to increasing targeting and infant industry support.
equity in rural areas; to broad, integrated rural Source: Adapted from Rivera, 1997.
development; or to organizing rural people to allow them
to bring about their own development and countervail elements, including ‘target group, offering, method, and
exploitative forces (Roling, 1982). organization’ may also change, because they all form an
An important question is how countries promote and interconnected set. In fact, the systemic character of this
achieve the changes in extension (Table 1) that will process has been insufficiently understood and has led to
advance extension’s potential to enhance agricultural and the comparison of individual fundamental notions in
rural development in the twenty-first century (Rivera, attempts to gain a better understanding of agricultural
1997). extension systems (AESs). Since a comparative study of
As Warner and Christenson (1984, p 124) have stated, agricultural extension should provide a holistic insight
‘extension needs to understand “what is” before it can and, thereby, a powerful basis for practical action, it is
predict where the agency “ought to be” in the future’. To important to avoid probable biases and understand
show the importance of this question, Roling (1982, p 87) all aspects of an AES by taking a systemic view into
discussed how, when extension objectives change, other account.

338 Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

International

National

Institutional

Macro Meso Micro Institutional intra-action and interaction, tasks, Micro Meso Macro
performance, arrangements, structural
tendencies, finances…

Extension institution
Food security, export, equity…

General goals of agri-rural development

International forces, demands, challenges…

International exchanges

Figure 1. The proposed framework: to make a systemic comparison of agricultural extension systems, three different levels – micro
(institutional), meso (national) and macro (international) should be considered.

The goal of this paper ‘micro’ (institutional), ‘meso’ (national) and ‘macro’
(international), as shown in Figure 1.
An ideal goal of the comparative research effort presented
Each level of analysis identifies particular sets of causal
here is to build a systematic framework for all comparable
factors. According to Jaffee (1998), the socioeconomic
cases and hence to generalize the findings as much as
considerations of a systemic view might include the
possible. This paper aims therefore to set up an
attitudes and values of individuals, the system of
appropriate systemic framework and to help policy
industrial relations, the rules and logic governing the
makers think through what it takes to design successful
economic system, the policies of the state, or a nation’s
ones. This can also help ‘researchers’ to ascend from the
position in an international interaction. These
initial level of exploratory case studies to the more
independent variables, or predictors of AES functions, are
advanced level of general theoretical models (Routio,
observed at different levels of analysis. The attitudes and
2006), and in so doing aid those policy makers who are
values of an extension agent, for instance, operate at the
concerned with where changes are needed and where
level of his or her professional ‘extension/institution’ role.
resources might best be allocated (Rivera et al, 1989).
The institution also establishes some intra/interrelations,
which should be considered when comparing two or more
A systemic view AESs.
The comparative study of AESs is a truly interdisciplinary
venture (see Blackburn, 1989). Analysing the causes and Micro level: institutional
consequences of extension interventions requires crossing At the most basic level, all AESs are involved in both
the conventional boundaries of extension approaches intra- and interactions of the extension institution. For this
(Axinn, 1988) because they shape and are shaped by reason, the aim of many studies has been the evaluation of
institutional intra/interaction, socio-political the many institutional functions of the extension system.
arrangements and the international economy. The The functions at this lowest level can be enlisted in the
working area of extension is broad and it is difficult to prediction not only of how extension staff think and act
discount the importance of any of these aspects. within their formal and informal institutional interactions
Explaining an AES is further complicated by the fact (Agunga and Ojomo, 1997), but also in how they react to
that each discipline is composed of subdisciplines, sub- their different target groups, which might be involved in
areas and subfields that tend to emphasize one particular other agri-rural development subsystems, mainly research
slice of agricultural and rural development (see institutions. Since socioeconomic, political and technical
Blackburn, 1989). It is therefore important to understand changes inevitably impact on the institution of
both inter and intra elements of AESs and their functions agricultural extension and also bring pressure on it to
in emphasizing a holistic view. These elements can be change (Rivera, 1997), the main question at the micro level
distinguished by their levels of analysis, which are mainly is therefore to understand how a country can reach its

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4 339


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

agri-rural development goals through extension and what (Bernet et al, 2001; Rivera and Zijp, 2002; Gustafson, 2004;
institutional arrangements need to be created to achieve Lightfoot, 2004; Rivera and Alex, 2004). In most cases,
these goals. The basic issues at this level might thus they involve changing the distribution of power and
include ‘what kinds of reward and structural responsibilities among three key actors: (i) clients,
arrangements might differentially influence the (ii) those who deliver the service and (iii) government.
performance of different kinds of extension professionals’ Many others have responsiveness to client demand high
and ‘what kinds of role playing might differentiate on their list of objectives, which is a primary rationale for
different kinds of the professionals for training and privatization (Garforth, 2004).
selection purposes’. In short, a few countries will follow one current
Van den Ban (1986) asks whether the task of the tendency to ‘privatize’ national public sector extension
extension service is to help farmers to learn how to systems; others will probably take major steps to
organize themselves effectively, or whether this should be ‘revitalize’ (Tchouamo and Steele, 1997) or otherwise
a function of some other governmental or non-govern- reform their national extension systems. Still others will
mental organization. He believes this to be a politically choose to ‘decentralize’ their system structurally, fiscally
sensitive and important question. While in many or managerially (Rivera, 1997). In the meantime, the
developed countries, farmers’ organizations play public versus private distribution of AESs has usually been
important roles in the economic and political life of the a source of debate. In the past decade or so, there has been
country (Esman and Uphoff, 1988; Chamala and Mortiss, a significant reduction in publicly funded AESs and a
1990; Kislev et al, 1991; Fulton, 1995; Kimhi, 1996; dramatic increase in the privately funded sector. Many of
Cristóvão and Pereira, 2004), the issue has not yet been these privatized systems present information provided by
clearly addressed for developing countries (Azadi and agribusinesses such as seed companies, which may be
Karami, 2001). biased towards the particular company dispensing the
Assessments at the institutional level also show that, information.
unlike tasks undertaken by organizations, which are In order to understand how the privatization of
predefined, and the functions identified in accordance extension systems relates to globalization and agricultural
with these tasks, the agent is not only concerned with the industrialization, it is useful to consider how capitalism’s
nature of the tasks themselves, but rather with the inter/ third agricultural revolution, which occurred in several
intra processes involved in the organization. On the other waves, developed. In the 1890s, mechanization, using
hand, extension agents, in the role of government steam and later fossil fuel-based tractors, was followed by
representatives in the village, are often asked to perform chemical farming in the 1950s and food manufacturing in
other functions, such as input distribution and tax North America and later Western Europe in the 1960s and
collection (Boone, 1989; Swanson et al, 1990). Neverthe- 70s, all of which accelerated the industrialization of
less, many studies have analysed the influence of agriculture worldwide. As agriculture became more
institutional attributes on the performance of extension industrialized, it became more concentrated (integrating
staff (Rogers and Shoemaker, 1971; Ntifo-Siaw and increasingly large farms with food processing) and
Agunga, 1994) and indicated why institutional attributes specialized (as particular products accounted for more of
should be considered as functional roles of extension each region’s output) (Bowler, 1992).
agents.
Considering the institutional performance of extension ‘The pace of globalization increases as production
staff, van den Ban (1986) for instance, points to becomes more internationalized, capital becomes more
McGregor’s X and Y theories. Theory X implies that mobile, nation-states are eroded, internet communica-
extension staff will only work if they are forced to do so, tion technologies become widespread, and ideology
whereas theory Y implies that the staff will only work if increasingly emphasizes trade and investment
they are mainly motivated by their desire to do their jobs liberalization [and] privatization.’ (Filson, 2004, p 37)
well.
Van den Ban (1986) also points to the theory of rate of Similar processes are under way internationally within
investment return. Remarking on a study by Evenson, he agricultural extension, even though agriculture is not
believes that investments in agricultural research and industrializing uniformly worldwide. Although publicly
extension often produce a higher rate of return than funded agricultural extension has existed in some form
investments in infrastructure, though the amounts for close to a thousand years (Mazoyer and Roudart,
invested in the latter are much larger than the amounts 1997), it became elaborated in North America and Europe
invested in extension and research. Investments in in the nineteenth century as legislation was passed to
infrastructural works, however, remain politically more improve the state of agriculture through education. In
attractive because they are more visible. The challenge is Ontario, Canada, for instance, agricultural representatives
to establish institutional arrangements that ensure clients (or extensionists) were being hired by the provincial
receive advisory and other services that satisfy their own government as early as 1906 (Blackburn and Vist, 1989).
demands within parameters compatible with government Just as the International Monetary Fund launched its
policy (Garforth et al, 2003). Structural Adjustment Programme in 1983, which among
Yet most case studies are less concerned with the other major changes involved extensive privatization of
specifics of the agent’s role, for example, his/her public resources in developing countries (Drafor et al,
techniques and methods, and more with making 2000), developed countries also often privatized their
institutional changes that will lead to extension service extension systems massively (Kidd et al, 1999). In both the
providers being more responsive to what clients want North and the South, public extension budgets collapsed,

340 Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

justified by the claim that they were often irrelevant to In fact, any prediction concerning the structural
farmers’ needs or that they were inefficient relative to the tendency of extension hinges critically on the mobilization
private sector (Anderson and Feder, 2004). One of the of additional funds. New extension approaches that are
biggest criticisms in developed capitalist countries was participatory and more responsive to client needs (Rivera
that public extension systems were incapable of and Zijp, 2002) must demonstrate their superiority over
responding to the specialized needs of farmers who were old approaches, including superior economic
now, more often than before, concentrating their performance. Financial sustainability of extension is
production on a few, particular types of products especially crucial in times of scarcity of public funds
(Davidson and Ahmad, 2003). (Quizon et al, 2001). However, data on the costs and
This notion that public extension services are no longer benefits of extension services have been particularly
adequate to meet the changing needs of farmers in many scarce (Fleischer et al, 2004; Azadi, 2007).
developing countries is increasingly emphasized in the Among the other major structural issues in the existing
literature and reflected in the strategies of development extension system is the source of research problems and
agencies (Fleischer et al, 2004). For instance, problems the technology being generated. It has too often been
encountered with the once popular Training and Visit assumed that research and technology are value-neutral
(T&V) system have generated frustration among donor (Rogers and Shoemaker, 1971). This assumption has been
agencies and caused an unwillingness to invest further in questioned several times (Roling et al, 1976; Goss, 1979;
large-scale public agricultural extension programmes. To Melkote, 1998). Research, like any other institution, grows
some, the solution is seen to lie in strengthening the role competitively by patronage and has over the years
of the private sector in the delivery of information and become progressively more expensive. Research
services (Umali-Deininger, 1997; van den Berg, 2001). institutions thus grew, and some became centres of
Indeed, since the early 1980s, important changes have excellence. The least developed countries could not afford
been taking place in both higher- (the North) and lower- such high-priced luxuries and had to depend on more
income countries (the South) with regard to the developed nations. In agriculture, this has turned out to
involvement of public and private sectors in the financing be disastrous for the disadvantaged, who are today the
and provision of extension. The central idea is that majority of the rural population in the less developed
farmers should be given opportunities for obtaining the countries (UNFPA, 2005). Agricultural research
advice and information they seek from those most able institutions oriented towards the problems of the rich
and willing to provide it. It is postulated that with farmers in rich countries have become distanced from the
reduced public involvement, private professionals will fill problems of poor farmers in the poor countries (Shahvali
the gap of information delivery, while competition would and Azadi, 1999b). Thus, technologies developed in
encourage them to do this at as low a cost as possible internationally funded research stations such as IRRI (the
(Maalouf et al, 1991; Rivera and Gustafson, 1991). Philippines), CIMMYT (Mexico), ICRISAT (India),
Others argue that the public sector should maintain its Rothamsted (UK) or the Royal Tropical Institute
role in knowledge and information transfer. The emerging (Netherlands), while being designed to save whole
renaissance of agricultural and rural development, as countries if not the world, were sometimes irrelevant to
reflected in updated strategies of major donors such as the small farmers (Roy, 1982).
World Bank, the International Fund for Agricultural The importance of an appropriate inter-linkage
Development and others, is likely again to draw the between research and extension systems is well
attention of public policy makers to public goods delivery, recognized (Cernea et al, 1985; Roling, 1988, Bennett, 1989;
involving food security, poverty alleviation and Kaimowitz et al, 1989; Merrill-Sands and Kaimowitz, 1989;
sustainable management of natural resources. Pray and Echeverria, 1989; Bennett, 1990; Uquillas and
Government extension services are one important vehicle, Navas, 1993; Falvey and Forno, 1997; Shahvali and Azadi,
if not the primary one, for reaching out and gaining access 1999b; Ison and Russell, 2000), as is the intra-linkage
to rural communities. Universal privatization of extension between the partners in some systems such as farming
may find its limitations where market failures, such as a systems research and extension work (Shaner et al, 1982;
monopolized supply structure and bundled services Sands, 1986; Dolly, 1997; Shahvali and Azadi, 1999b;
occur, or where incremental social benefits such as Schmitz, 2004). Nonetheless, the linkages between the
environmental externalities play a large role (Hanson and agricultural education system and agricultural researchers
Just, 2001). (Falvey and Maguire, 1997), market managers, credit
In many countries, existing agricultural extension providers and agricultural input suppliers tend to be
institutions are squeezed between the legacy of the T&V minimal, and the prevailing pattern throughout much of
scheme (Benor and Harrison, 1977) and the demands for the world is to have them administered separately by
new, more participatory approaches that respond better to different government agencies, although some systems,
the actual needs of clients (Shahvali and Azadi, 1999b). such as the Cooperative Extension Systems, have a better
This situation has several dimensions in terms of record of research/extension integration than others.
organizational structure and culture, partnerships and Generally speaking, close functional relationships need to
finances. Generic problems of centrally managed and be established and maintained (Rivera, 1998b).
highly bureaucratic extension agencies included a lack of In short, research and extension are often built into the
accountability to clients; poorly maintained linkages to lowest unit of implementation. Problems and projects
knowledge generation; few resources for training and emerge from the target group. One realizes that, given the
operations; and a top-down orientation towards world’s present store of traditional and modern
technology transfer (Feder et al, 1999). technology, very small alterations and optimal selection of

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4 341


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

technologies are sufficient to solve most local problems, production on a large number of farms. In fact, most
maximally utilizing local people’s motivation, knowledge nations would nowadays try to avoid those policies that
and skills (Roy, 1982). deliberately impoverish rural areas to boost metropolitan
As we see, at an institutional level, there are many consumption. Furthermore, most nations realize that,
factors that have been investigated by different notwithstanding the fact that farmers must pay for
researchers that are based primarily on their own view or national development including, for example, civil service
research problems. As a result, two important issues are salaries, one cannot expect them to do so without reaping
evident at this level: the diversity of factors and the some benefit for themselves.
number of completed research projects, often with a Van den Ban (1986, p 93) believes that to use extension
variety of theoretical perspectives. as a policy instrument to stimulate development, several
questions should be posed:
Meso level: national
(1) Which developments are desirable?
Jaffee (1998) argues that the performance of organizations
(2) Are the same developments desirable for all groups of
is influenced by the national environment, which mainly
farmers? If not, which group should the extension
includes social opportunities, norms, rules, etc, and can
service try to help most?
influence the function of all organizations. This environ-
(3) In which circumstances does national interest
ment and consequently the goals may change from time to
coincide/conflict with the interest of farmers?
time, especially due to new international relations, which
(4) To what extent are the policy makers themselves an
are discussed at the macro level. Sometimes, improving
important target group for the extension service?
the performance of the extension efforts or, alternatively,
diminishing it, provides a better environment. While in many developing countries, poverty alleviation
The most important factors at this level are concerned is nowadays an important goal of agricultural develop-
with national expectations within a society with regard to ment policies (van den Ban, 1986), Blackburn et al (1982)
the extension institution. These may, for example, be have shown, in a socioeconomic case study in Ontario,
expressed in governmental support for, or restrictions on, that much of Canada’s agricultural policy, along with
the institution. The general economic conditions in a those of many other nations, has traditionally been based
country and their consequences (behind the economic on theories of ‘a rational economic man’, which can easily
processes) would largely determine what the extension be followed by a private extension service. Most private
tasks should be. The main question at this level is extension services are, however, not interested in helping
therefore to understand why a country needs the extension poor subsistence farmers. This can only be done by
institution. The above argument results in different governments, but it requires that extension workers are
missions for extension between and sometimes within rewarded for working with these farmers, who are often
(mostly democratic) countries such as the USA and hard to reach. In general, the choice of the goals for an
Canada, and case studies are required to recognize the extension service depends on the reasons why the desired
national goals for agri-rural development and kind of modern agriculture has not yet been achieved
consequently the extension missions. (van den Ban, 1986). Still others are morally committed to
Roling (1982), for instance, believes that the most equitable policies because of ideological convictions and
common reason for a government to employ an extension because of the realization that rural areas must be viable
service is probably to guarantee the nation’s food security in their own right, since adequate alternative, non-rural
at first and export crop production thereafter. Only a employment opportunities will not be forthcoming in the
national objective such as this can legitimize the spending foreseeable future (Roling, 1982).
of taxpayers’ money to assist a specific professional With regard to equitable policies, Kumar and Roy
category. Even when alternative objectives are embraced (1979, cited in Roy, 1982) ask: ‘What are the new social
by the national extension service, the need to increase organizations needed, to re-structure the development of
national agricultural production usually remains very poverty groups?’ Roy (1982) points to one participative
much in evidence. One could propose that a focus on planning study, which showed that even among the
small farmers is the best way to increase national landless and near-landless, not all members are interested
production in poor countries where many small-scale or involved in the same project. One group of landless
farmers produce a large amount of agricultural and marginal farmers may be involved in a tube-well
production. In practice, however, short-term cooperative, another in a fishery cooperative, a third in a
considerations render the orientation to national dairy project, and a fourth in weaving. There may be some
production inconsistent with one source of the small overlap in families belonging to two cooperatives, but the
farmer ’s income. With an outlook on national food and skills needed, the management, marketing, financing and
export crop production, targets are set, and success is repayment schedules are all very different. One group
measured by, for example, the amount of surplus may be distributing water and repairing diesel pumps,
production. With such a measure, it is rational for while a second may be catching fish every day in half a
extension to focus on the optimal performance of either dozen tanks and getting them to market at dawn. The
small or large-scale farmers. On the other hand, increasing optimal size of unit needed and the most economic
farmer incomes can be a real alternative to increasing federation of units have to evolve over time as each
national production when the benefit to the farmer cooperative expands or declines. The term ‘non-formal
becomes the central issue: success is measured at the farm structure’ is purposely somewhat contradictory, as it is
level, and the focus is not only on increasing production meant to reflect a certain hesitance in being able to predict
on a large number of hectares, but also on increasing or prescribe the form an organization will take.

342 Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

The participative planning structure for working with indigenous knowledge of medicinal plants and trees to
poverty groups that employs a non-directive mode of create expensive drugs, without remunerating the
developing priority problems into feasible projects has, of indigenous peoples in developing countries who
necessity, to be extremely flexible, but is also time- discovered the medicinal value of these plant extracts in
consuming. The optimal size of a group, the type of the first place (Zweifal, 1996).
projects it undertakes, the non-formal education required In explaining the international components and their
for skills transfer and raising the consciousness and influence on extension, Karami (1986) concluded that
horizons through ‘key’ words, all begin to reveal a unique throughout sociology’s history, the two general theoretical
character to each group project. The diffusion of approach perspectives for the study of development have been
among similar poverty groups is likely to be achieved by ubiquitous: equilibrium and conflict. The equilibrium
members of the poverty groups themselves. The approach has been classified into that adopted by
measurement of success and failure would be on a mix of behaviourists, psycho-dynamicists and diffusionists,
material and non-material criteria and would change over while the conflict approach has been used by
time (Roy, 1982). structuralists. If one accepts the underlying assumption of
the diffusionist approach, development issues are largely
Macro level: international to do with mainly technical solutions to the problem of
According to Jaffee’s (1988) framework, it is important to increasing rates of growth. In most underdeveloped
consider international priorities and their impacts on the countries, in his opinion, the consequences of application
level of socioeconomic development of particular of a diffusionist approach in agricultural extension can be
countries first and of the extension’s missions last. The explained as follows:
main question at this level is therefore to understand what
(1) The objectives of extension services are frequently
international forces and functions affect the present
limited to the problem of increasing production.
situation of a country and finally create new expectations
(2) The agricultural extension strategy is designed to
from the extension. These relations can influence, both
create a group of so-called ‘progressive’ farmers
directly and indirectly, the national goals and
through whom new ideas and techniques can be
consequently the objectives of the extension institution.
diffused.
Unfortunately, international relations and their impacts on
(3) In order to access the impact of theoretical
extension (Azadi and Gorjievsky, 2005) have received little
assumptions of the diffusionist approach, not only the
attention, while, in contrast, numerous studies have been
‘how’ extension processes should be criticized, but
done at both the meso and especially the micro level.
also the ‘what’ of the extension content has to be
Starting from the idea that general social, economic and
scrutinized.
political processes manifest themselves in ever changing,
(4) Furthermore, diffusion of Western technology will
historically specific shapes, the reports imply that the
increase dependency relations. As Frank notes, these
impact of economic restructuring, the significance of
relations lead to continued enrichment of
governance at various levels and the conditional use of
metropolises and the perpetual stagnation and
social capital are critical elements for those wishing to
poverty of satellites.
supplement their knowledge of globalization, economics,
labour, technology and the extension institution. In the aftermath of the collapse of communism, Russian
Karami (1986), for example, has argued that the and Ukrainian large, former state and collective farms
diffusion of capital, technology, social values and were privatized to varying degrees. Under the communist
institutions may be seen to occur on three scales, which system, extension was largely an internal matter occurring
are mainly macroscale (metropolis to satellite), mesoscale within each state and in collective farms with very little
(urban to rural) and microscale (within rural). He believes connection to the relatively abundant agricultural research
that, at the macroscale, this model clarifies that institutes. In the post-Soviet period, small farmers in
development occurs through the transfer of capital from particular had limited funds to hire agricultural
developed to underdeveloped countries. Nonetheless, consultants. Under these conditions, there was a growing
most available statistics, including those compiled by the demand for publicly funded forms of agricultural
official agencies of developed countries, show precisely extension, as it was reckoned that ‘the main condition for
the opposite. Frank (1971) observed that the developed the sustainability of extension centres is government
countries transferred to the underdeveloped countries support’ (Gomeniuk, 2006, p 109). The growth of public
only those technologies that were consistent with their agricultural systems in the former USSR, China (Filson et
interest. There are, however, more altruistic transfers of al, 2003) and Vietnam (van Linh, 2001) runs counter to the
technology among developed countries and among tendency in many other parts of the world.
underdeveloped countries, in addition to technology Abell (cited by Karami, 1986) criticized most
transferred from underdeveloped to more economically internationally aided extension programmes and claimed
developed countries (Mazoyer and Roudart, 1997). that only a few of these programmes could extend
Ethnobotany, for example, is a field that has recognized tangible benefits to the rural people in the so-called
that substantial traditional ecological and agroecological developing countries. Roling (1982) believed that some
knowledge can be utilized for environmental governments embraced such objectives because that was a
management, thus showing that Northern-based science condition for getting support from major donor countries
has no monopoly on environmental management and international agencies. As part of a ‘new policy
knowledge (Freeman, 1992). On the other hand, some agenda’ among many donors and international
pharmaceutical companies have often appropriated the institutions, a fundamental review of the overall role of

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4 343


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

the state in society is under way in many countries in the extension on the yield of wheat and barley: an economic
North (Cary, 1993) and the South (Rivera, 1997). Still assessment’, Jihad (Agricultural Extension and Rural Development
Journal), Vol 27, pp 38–53.
others feel that it is only by way of such objectives that
Azadi, H., and Gorjievsky, M. (2005), ‘Factors influencing on
the purchasing power of the modal inhabitants of the success of immigrant entrepreneurship: a conceptual frame-
country can be increased, which is a prerequisite for work’, Proceedings of the European Congress of Work &
industrial development. Karami (1986) deems that these Organizational Psychology (EAWOP), 12–15 May, Istanbul.
discussions take us logically to the major question of what Azadi, H., and Karami, E. (1999), ‘Constructs affecting the
development is. Considering the three main questions of success of mechanization associations in Fars province’, A
Seers (1982): ‘What has been happening to poverty? What Quarterly Journal of Rural Development Studies, Vol 3, No 2,
pp 27–64.
has been happening to unemployment? What has been Azadi, H., and Karami, E. (2001), ‘Comparison of mechanization
happening to inequality?’ Todaro (1977) believes that such unit of rural cooperatives, production cooperatives and
questions are mainly concerned with the policies of mechanization companies in Fars province, Iran’, Journal of
economic development. The policies induce governments, Science and Technology of Agriculture and National Resources, Vol
either directly or indirectly, to dictate some new missions 5, No 3, pp 33–48.
for extension (Kidd et al, 1999). Economic theory and the Bayer, A. W., and Bayer, W. (1994), Planning with Pastoralists: PRA
and More. A Review of Methods Focused on Africa, German Agency
concepts of public and private goods can also frequently
for Technical Cooperation (GTZ), Eschborn.
be used to decide what extension services should finally Bennett, C. (1989), ‘Improving coordination of extension and
be rendered (Umali and Schwartz, 1994; Beynon, 1996). research’, in Blackburn, D. J., ed, Foundations and Changing
Issues of good governance also add to the pressure for Practices in Extension, University of Guelph, Guelph,
decentralization and a reduced role for extension services pp l18–128.
(Kidd et al, 1999). So it is obvious that the basic problem Bennett, C. (1990), Cooperative Extension Roles and Relationships for
of agricultural development policy is also a problem of a New Era: A New Interdependence Model and Evaluation Synthesis
to Foster Work with Other Agencies and Organizations, Extension
adjusting farming to socio-cultural changes in a changing Service, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington,
world (Eltahir Eltayeb, 2005). DC.
Benor, D., and Harrison, J. (1977), Agricultural Extension: The
Conclusion Training and Visit System, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bernet, T., Ortiz, O., Estrada, R. T., Quiroz, R., and Swinton, S. M.
Throughout this paper, the emphasis has been on the (2001), ‘Tailoring agricultural extension to different production
multitude of factors that need to be considered in contexts: a user-friendly farm household model to improve
comparative studies of agricultural extension systems. decision-making for participatory research’, Agricultural
The conclusion is drawn that the avoidance of probable Systems, Vol 69, pp 183–198.
Beynon, J. (1996), Financing of Agricultural Research and Extension
biases in such studies requires an understanding of all the
for Smallholder Farmers in Sub-Saharan Africa, ODI Natural
aspects of AESs, for which a systemic view involving Resource Perspectives No 15, ODI, London.
three (micro, meso and macro) levels of analysis is Blackburn, D. J. (1989), Foundations and Changing Practices in
needed. We believe that this systemic process has not yet Extension, University of Guelph, Guelph.
been sufficiently understood. Blackburn, D. J., Brinkman, G. L., and Driver, H. C. (1982),
The number of studies and the investigated factors ‘Understanding behavioural and economic characteristics in
identified clearly decrease as the three levels progress working with operators of small farms: a case study in Ontario,
Canada’, in Jones, G. E., and Rolls, M. J., eds, Progress in Rural
and become particularly sparse at the meso and micro Extension and Community Development, Vol 1, John Wiley & Sons,
levels. Thus, it is seen that most extension professionals Chichester, pp 171–188.
are, for the most part, committed to the investigation of Blackburn, D. J., and Vist, D. L. (1989), ‘Historical foundations
intra-/inter-institutional factors that are easier to source of extension’, in Blackburn, D. J., ed, Foundations and
and evaluate (and are more readily understood) and Changing Practices in Extension, University of Guelph, Guelph,
they tend to neglect meso and macro level extension pp l–10.
Boone, E. J. (1989), ‘Philosophical foundations of extension’, in
issues
Blackburn, D. J., ed, Foundations and Changing Practices in
To establish how to promote and adjust extension Extension, University of Guelph, Guelph, pp l–9.
efforts within the framework of an AES, we recommend Bowler, I. R. (1992), The Geography of Agriculture in Developed
that both extension professionals and policy makers Market Economies, Wiley, New York.
employ a systemic approach to the task. But the issues Cary, J. W. (1993), ‘Changing foundations for government support
included for consideration must incorporate notions of of agricultural extension in economically developed countries’,
Sociologica Ruralis, Vol 33, No 3/4, pp 336–347.
the level of development of the systems of agricultural
Cernea, M. M., Coulter, J. K., and Russell, J. F. A. (1985), Research,
production employed within the economy being studied. Extension Farmer: A Two-Way Continuum for Agricultural Develop-
ment, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Chamala, S., and Mortiss, P. D. (1990), Working Together for Land
References Care: Group Management Skills and Strategies, Australian
Agunga, R., and Ojomo, C. (1997), ‘Burnout, job satisfaction and Academic Press, Brisbane.
work situation as perceived by district extension officers, Ondo Chambers, R. (1997), Whose Reality Counts? Putting the Last
State, Nigeria’, Journal of International Agricultural and Extension First, Intermediate Technology Publications, Bath Press,
Education, Vol 4, No 1, pp 47–56. London.
Anderson, J. R., and Feder, G. (2004), ‘Agricultural extension: Chambers, R., and Ghildyal, B. P. (1985), ‘Agricultural resource-
good intentions and hard realities’, The World Bank Research poor farmers: the farmer-first-and-last model’, Agricultural
Observer, Vol 19, No 1, pp 41–60. Administration, Vol 20, pp 1–30.
Axinn, G. H. (1988), Guide on Alternative Extension Approaches, Cristóvão, A., and Pereira, F. (2004), ‘Portugal: extension reform
FAO, Rome. in the interior north of Portugal’, in Rivera, W., and Alex, G.,
Azadi, H. (2007), ‘Influencing the financial support of agricultural eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to Agriculture Extension. Case

344 Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

Studies of International Initiatives, Agriculture and Rural Devel- Garforth, C. (2004), ‘Demand-led approaches’, in Rivera, W., and
opment Discussion Paper 10, Extension Reform for Rural Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to Agriculture
Development, World Bank Publications, Vol 3, World Bank, Extension. Case Studies of International Initiatives, Agriculture and
Washington, DC, pp 96–103. Rural Development Discussion Paper 10, Extension Reform for
Davidson, A. P., and Ahmad, M. (2003), Privatization and the Crisis Rural Development. World Bank Publications, Vol 3, World
of Agricultural Extension: The Case of Pakistan, Ashgate Publish- Bank, Washington, DC, pp 1–6.
ing Ltd, Aldershot. Garforth, C., Angell, J., Archer, and Green, K. (2003), Improving
Davidson, A. P., Ahmad, M., and Ali, T. (2001), Dilemmas of Farmers’ Access to Advice on Land Management: Lessons from Case
Agricultural Extension in Pakistan: Food for Thought, Network Studies in Developed Countries, Agricultural Research and
Paper No 116, Agricultural Research and Extension, ODI, Extension Network (AgREN) Paper No 125. Overseas Develop-
London. ment Institute, London.
Dolly, D. (1997), ‘Accuracy, congruency, and agreement among Gomeniuk, M. (2006), ‘The role of extension centers in innovation
researchers, extension workers and pigeon pea farmers in activities of AIC enterprises. Problems and perspectives of
Trinidad and Tobago’, Journal of International Agricultural and agricultural extension services development’, Conference
Extension Education, Vol 4, No 1, pp 21–30. Proceedings, Sudak, Crimea, Tavria State Agrotechnical Academy/
Drafor, I., Filson, G. C., and Goddard, E. W. (2000), ‘Cereal Pennsylvania State University/National Association of Extension
producers and the structural adjustment programme in Ghana: Services of Ukraine (DORADA), pp 101–109.
a welfare analysis of the first decade of SAP’, Development Goss, K. F. (1979), ‘Consequences of diffusion of innovations’,
Southern Africa, Vol 17, No 4, pp 489–499. Rural Sociology, Vol 44, No 4, pp 754–772.
Eltahir Eltayeb, M. (2005), ‘Agricultural extension in Sudan, Gustafson, D. J. (2004), ‘Kenya: supporting the demand for
policies and reality. The case of Khartoum state’, Master ’s change – recent project experience with farmer learning grants’,
thesis, Department of Rural Development and Agroecology, in Rivera, W., and Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to
Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Uppsala. Agriculture Extension. Case Studies of International Initiatives,
Esman, M. J., and Uphoff, N. T. (1988), Local Organizations. Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper 10,
Intermediaries in Rural Development, Cornell University Press, Extension Reform for Rural Development, World
New York. Bank Publications, No 3, World Bank, Washington, DC,
Falvey, L., and Forno, D. (1997), ‘Institutional arrangements in pp 22–30.
agricultural education, extension and research: lessons for Hanson, J., and Just, R. E. (2001), ‘The potential for transition
international development’, Journal of International Agricultural to paid extension: some guiding economic principles’,
and Extension Education, Vol 4, No 1, pp 7–14. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol 83, No 3,
Falvey, L., and Maguire, C. (1997), ‘The emerging role for agricul- pp 777–784.
tural education in producing future research’, Journal of Ison, R., and Russell, D. (2000), Agricultural Extension and Rural
International Agricultural and Extension Education, Vol 4, No 1, pp Development: Breaking Out of Traditions, Cambridge University
15–20. Press, Cambridge.
Faure, G., and Kleene, P. (2004), ‘West Africa: management advice Jaffee, D. (1998), Levels of Socio-Economic Development Theory,
for family farms – the role of producers’ organizations in the Praeger, Westport, CT.
delivery of sustainable agricultural extension services’, in Karami, E. (1986), ‘Agricultural extension in development theory’,
Rivera, W., and Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to Journal of Extension Systems, Vol 2, No 2, pp 61–69.
Agriculture Extension. Case Studies of International Initiatives, Karami, E. (1994), ‘Alternative agricultural extension objectives’,
Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper 10, Agricultural Progress, Vol 68, pp 15–24.
Extension Reform for Rural Development, World Bank Kaimowitz, D., Snyder, M., and Engel, P. (1989), A Conceptual
Publications, Vol 3, World Bank, Washington, DC, Framework for Studying the Links between Agricultural Research
pp 104–113. and Technology Transfer in Developing Countries, ISNAR, The
Feder, G., Willett, A., and Zijp, W. (1999), Agricultural Extension – Hague.
Generic Challenges and Some Ingredients for Solutions, World Bank Kelsey, L. D., and Hearne, C. C. (1955), Co-operative Extension
Policy Research Working Papers No 2129, World Bank, Work, Comstock Publishing Association, Ithaca, NY.
Washington, DC. Kidd, A. D., Lamers, J. P. A., Ficarelli, P. P., and Hoffmann, V.
Filson, G. C. (2004), ‘Social implications of intensive (1999), ‘Privatising agricultural extension: caveat emptor ’,
agriculture’, in Filson, G. C., ed, Intensive Agriculture and Journal of Rural Studies, Vol 16, pp 95–102.
Sustainability: A Farming Systems Analysis, UBC Press, Kimhi, A. (1996), ‘Farmers’ time allocation between farm and off-
Vancouver, pp 34–50. farm work and the importance of unobserved group effects:
Filson, G. C., Stoskopf, N. C., Simpson, J., and Kannenberg, L. evidence from Israeli cooperatives’, Agricultural Economics, Vol
(2003), ‘Agroforestry extension and the Western China develop- 14, pp 135–142.
ment strategy’, in Nielson, W. A. W., and Ding, L., eds, West Kislev, Y., Lerman Z., and Zusman, P. (1991), ‘Recent experience
China Development: Domestic Strategies and Global Implications, with cooperative farm credit in Israel’, Economic Development
Centre for Asia-Pacific Initiatives, University of Victoria, British and Cultural Change, Vol 39, No 4, pp 773–790.
Columbia, pp 11–12. Leeuwis, C. (2004), Communication for Rural Innovation: Rethinking
Fleischer, G., Waibel, H., and Walter-Echols, G. (2004), ‘Egypt: Agricultural Extension, 3 ed, Blackwell Science, Oxford.
how much does it cost to introduce participatory extension Lightfoot, C. (2004), ‘East Africa: catalytic action for the
approaches in public extension services?’ in Rivera, W., and emergence of farmer empowerment for “demand-driven”
Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to Agriculture Exten- extension’, in Rivera, W., and Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven
sion. Case Studies of International Initiatives, Agriculture and Approaches to Agriculture Extension. Case Studies of International
Rural Development Discussion Paper 10, Extension Reform for Initiatives, Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion
Rural Development, World Bank Publications, Vol 3, World Paper 10, Extension Reform for Rural Development, World
Bank, Washington, DC, pp 40–49. Bank Publications, No 3, World Bank, Washington, DC,
Frank, A. G. (1971), Sociology of Development and Underdevelopment pp 16–22.
of Sociology, Pluto, London. Maalouf, W. D., Contado, T. E., and Adhikarya, R. (1991),
Freeman, M. M. R. (1992), ‘The nature and utility of traditional ‘Extension coverage and resource problems: the need for
ecological knowledge’, Northern Perspectives, Vol 20, No 1, public–private co-operation’, in Rivera, W. M., and
Website: http://www.carc.org/pubs/v20no1/utility.htm. Gustafson, D. J., eds, Agricultural Extension: Worldwide
Fulton, M. (1995), ‘The future of Canadian agricultural Institutional Evolution and Forces for Change, Elsevier,
cooperatives: a property rights approach’, American Journal of Amsterdam.
Agricultural Economics, Vol 77, pp 1144–1152. Mazoyer, M., and Roudart, L. (1997), Histoire des agricultures du

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4 345


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

Monde: Du neolithique a la crise contemporanine [History of Roling, N., Ascroft, J., and Chege, F. W. (1976), ‘The diffusion of
Worldwide Agriculture. Neolithic Times to the Contemporary Crisis], innovation and the issue of equity in rural development’,
Seiul, Paris, and Monthly Review Press, New York. Communication Research, Vol 3, pp 155–170.
Melkote, S. R. (1998), Communication for Development in the Third Routio, P. (2006), ‘Comparative study’, available from Website:
World: Theory and Practice, Sage Publications, London. http://www2.uiah.fi/projects/metodi/172.htm.
Merrill-Sands, D., and Kaimowitz, D. (1989), The Technology Roy, P. (1982), ‘Extension with the disadvantaged: a radical view’,
Triangle: Linking Farmers, Technology Transfer Agents, and in Jones, G. E., and Rolls, M. J., eds, Progress in Rural Extension
Agricultural Researchers, ISNAR, The Hague. and Community Development, Vol 1, John Wiley & Sons,
Mosher, A. T. (1976), Thinking about Rural Development, Chichester, pp 71–85.
Agricultural Development Council, New York. Sands, D. M. (1986), ‘Farming systems research: clarification
Ntifo-Siaw, E., and Agunga, R. A. (1994), ‘A comparative study of of terms and concepts’, Experimental Agriculture, Vol 22, pp 87–
management effectiveness under the training and visit and 104.
general extension systems in Ghana’, Journal of Agricultural Scarborough, V., Killough, S., Johnson, D. A., and Farrington, J.
Education, Vol 35, No 4, pp 36–41. (1997), Farmer-Led Extension: Concepts and Practices, Intermediate
Oakley, P., and Marsden, D. (1985), Approaches to Participation Technology Publications, London.
in Rural Development, International Labour Organization, Seers, D. (1982), ‘The meaning of development’, in Jones, G. E.,
Geneva. and Rolls, M. J., eds, Progress in Rural Extension and Community
Patton, M. Q. (1993), ‘World trends and challenges in extension’, Development, Vol 1, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp 7–24.
Proceedings Australia Pacific Extension Conference, 12–14 October, Schmitz, H. (2004), ‘Brazil: problems and possibilities in building
Surfers Paradise, Queensland, Australia, pp 644–654. partnerships among farmers, researchers, and extensionists in
Percy, R. (1999), ‘Gender analysis and participatory rural Para State’, in Rivera, W., and Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven
appraisal: assessing the current debate through an Ethiopian Approaches to Agriculture Extension. Case Studies of International
case study involving agricultural extension work’, Initiatives, Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion
International Journal of Educational Development, Vol 19, pp 395– Paper 10, Extension Reform for Rural Development, World
408. Bank Publications No 3, Washington, DC, pp 33–40.
Pray, C., and Echeverria, R. (1989), Private-Sector Agricultural Shahvali, M., and Azadi, H. (1999a), ‘Investigating philosophical
Research and Technology Transfer Links in Developing Countries, schools of thought to explain human development’, A
Linkages Paper No 3, ISNAR, The Hague. Quarterly Journal of Rural Development Studies, Vol 2, No 4,
Pretty, J., Guijt, I., Thompson, J., and Scoones, I. (1995), IIED pp 21–56.
Participatory Methodology Series. Participatory Learning and Shahvali, M., and Azadi, H. (1999b), ‘Designing of extension
Action, a Trainer’s Guide, Russell Press, Nottingham. research on the basis of paradisciplinary approach’, A Quarterly
Quizon, J., Feder, G., and Murgai, R. (2001), ‘A note on the fiscal Journal of Agricultural Development, Vol 6, No 24, pp 139–175.
sustainability of agricultural extension: the case of the farmer Shaner, W. W., Philip, P. F., and Schmehl, W. R. (1982), Farming
field school approach’, Journal of International Agricultural Systems Research and Development: Guidelines for Developing
Extension and Education, Vol 8, No 1. Countries, Westview Press, Boulder, CO.
Rivera, W. M. (1997), ‘Agricultural extension into the next Swanson, B. E., Farner, B. J., and Bahal, R. (1990), ‘The current
decade’, European Journal of Agricultural Extension, Vol 4, No 1, state of agricultural extension worldwide’, in Global Consulta-
pp 29–38. tion on Agricultural Extension, FAO Report, FAO, Rome, pp
Rivera, W. M. (1998a), ‘Agricultural extension as adult education: 42–76.
institutional evolution and forces for change’, International Swanson, J., and Pehu, E. (2004), ‘Foreword’, in Rivera, W., and
Journal of Lifelong Education, Vol 17, No 4, pp 260–264. Alex, G., eds, Demand-Driven Approaches to Agriculture Exten-
Rivera, W. M. (1998b), ‘Preparing and upgrading the extension sion. Case Studies of International Initiatives, Agriculture and
workforce: a comparative analysis of higher agricultural Rural Development Discussion Paper 10, Extension Reform for
education in Honduras, Malaysia, Nigeria and Peru’, in Rural Development, World Bank Publications, No 3,
Crowder, L., ed, Training for Agriculture and Rural Development Washington, DC, p viii.
(TARD), FAO Corporate Document Repository, Rome, Website: Tchouamo, I. R., and Steele, R. E. (1997), ‘Educational impacts of
http://www.fao.org/docrep/w9699e/w9699e10.htm. the training and visit extension system on small farmers in the
Rivera, W. M., and Alex, G. (2004), Demand-Driven Approaches to west province of Cameroon’, Journal of International Agricultural
Agriculture Extension. Case Studies of International Initiatives, and Extension Education, Vol 4, No 1, pp 31–37.
Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper 10, Timmer, W. J. D. (1982), The Human Side of Agriculture, Vantage
Extension Reform for Rural Development, Vol 3, World Bank Press, New York.
Publications, Washington, DC. Todaro, M. (1977), Economic Development in the Third World,
Rivera, W. M., and Gustafson, D. J. (1991), Agricultural Extension: Longmans, London.
Worldwide Institutional Evolution and Forces for Change, Elsevier, Tooker, N. E. (1987), ‘Universal principles of extension’, Proceed-
Amsterdam. ings of the Australian Agricultural Extension Conference, Brisbane,
Rivera, W. M., Seepersad, J., and Pletsch, H. (1989), ‘Comparative Australia.
agricultural extension systems’, in Blackburn, D. J., ed, Founda- Umali, D. L., and Schwartz, L. (1994), Public and Private Agricul-
tions and Changing Practices in Extension, University of Guelph, tural Extension: Beyond Traditional Frontiers, World Bank
Guelph, pp 139–148. Discussion Paper No 236, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Rivera, W. M., and Zijp, W. (2002), Contracting for Agricultural Umali-Deininger, D. (1997), ‘Public and private agricultural
Extension: International Case Studies and Emerging Practices, CABI extension: partners or rivals?’ The World Bank Research Observer,
Publishing, Oxford. Vol 12, No 2, pp 203–224.
Rogers, E. M., and Shoemaker, F. F. (1971), Communication of UNFPA (2005), ‘Population & demographic dynamics’, available
Innovations, Free Press, New York. from Website: http://www.unfpa.org/sustainable/
Roling, N. (1979), ‘The logic of extension’, Indian Journal of demographics.htm.
Extension Education, Vol XV, No 3&4, pp 1–8. Uquillas, J. E., and Navas, B. G. (1993), Linking Research, Extension
Roling, N. (1982), ‘Alternatives approaches in extension’, in Jones, and Agricultural Education: An Experience in Ecuador, ODI
G. E., and Rolls, M. J., eds, Progress in Rural Extension and Agricultural Administration (Research and Extension) Network
Community Development, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp 87– Paper No 39, ODI, London.
115. van den Ban, A. W. (1986), ‘Extension policies, policy types,
Roling, N. (1988), Extension Science: Information Systems in policy formulation and goals’, in Jones, G. E., ed, Investing in
Agricultural Development, Cambridge University Press, Rural Extension: Strategies and Goals, Elsevier Applied Science
Cambridge. Publishers, London.

346 Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4


Comparative study of agricultural extension systems

van den Ban, A. W., and Hawkins, H. S. (1988), Agricultural Wilson, J. (1992), Changing Agriculture: An Introduction to Systems
Extension, Longman, London. Thinking, Kangaroo Press, Kenthurst, Australia.
van den Berg, M. (2001), The Agricultural Knowledge Infrastructure: Wilson, M. L. (1952), Community Development Programme in India,
Public or Private? FAO, Rome. Ministry of CD and Co-operation, Government of India, New
van Linh, N. (200l), ‘Agricultural innovation: multiple grounds Delhi.
for technology policies in the Red River Delta of Vietnam’, Zweifal, H. (1996), ‘Biodiversity and the appropriation of
doctoral dissertation, Wageningen Universiteit, Wageningen. women’s knowledge’, Indigenous Knowledge and
Warner, P. D., and Christenson, J. A. (1984), The Cooperative Development Monitor, Vol 5, No 1, available from
Extension Service: A National Assessment, Westview Press, Website: http://www.nuffic.nl/ciran/ikdm/5-1/articles/
Boulder, CO. zweifel.htm.

Outlook on AGRICULTURE Vol 38, No 4 347

View publication stats

You might also like